Measuring Investment Reurns II

Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 52

Aswath Damodaran 0

MEASURING INVESTMENT RETURNS


II. INVESTMENT INTERACTIONS,
OPTIONS AND REMORSE…
Life is too short for regrets, right?
First Principles
1

Maximize the value of the business (firm)

The Investment Decision The Financing Decision The Dividend Decision


Invest in assets that Find the right kind of If you cannot find
earn a return greater debt for your firm and investments that make
than the minimum the right mix of debt your minimum acceptable
rat hurdle
acceptable and equity to fund rate, return the cash to
e your operations owners of your business

The hurdle rate The return How much How you


should reflect The optimal The right
should reflect cash you choose to
the riskiness mix of debt kind of
the magnitude can return return cash to
of the and equity debt
and the timing depends the owners
investment maximizes matches
of the upon will depend
and the mix of firm value the tenor
cashflows as current & on whether
debt and of your
welll as all side potential they prefer
equity used to assets
effects. investment dividends or
fund it. opportunitie buybacks
s

Aswath Damodaran
1
Independent investments are the exception…
2

 In all of the examples we have used so far, the


investments that we have analyzed have stood alone.
Thus, our job was a simple one. Assess the expected
cash flows on the investment and discount them at the
right discount rate.
 In the real world, most investments are not
independent. Taking an investment can often mean
rejecting another investment at one extreme (mutually
exclusive) to being locked in to take an investment in the
future (pre-­requisite).

 More generally, accepting an investment can create side
costs for a firm’s existing investments in some cases and
benefits for others.
Aswath Damodaran
2
I. Mutually Exclusive Investments
3

 We have looked at how best to assess a stand-­alone



investment and concluded that a good investment will have
positive NPV and generate accounting returns (ROC and ROE)
and IRR that exceed your costs (capital and equity).
 In some cases, though, firms may have to choose between
investments because
🞑 They are mutually exclusive: Taking one investment makes the other
one redundant because they both serve the same purpose
🞑 The firm has limited capital and cannot take every good investment
(i.e., investments with positive NPV or high IRR).
 Using the two standard discounted cash flow measures, NPV
and IRR, can yield different choices when choosing between
investments.
Aswath Damodaran
3
Comparing Projects with the same (or similar)
lives..
4

 When comparing and choosing between investments


with the same lives, we can
🞑 Compute the accounting returns (ROC, ROE) of the investments
and pick the one with the higher returns
🞑 Compute the NPV of the investments and pick the one with the
higher NPV
🞑 Compute the IRR of the investments and pick the one with the
higher IRR
 While it is easy to see why accounting return measures
can give different rankings (and choices) than the
discounted cash flow approaches, you would expect NPV
and IRR to yield consistent results since they are both
time-­weighted,
‐ incremental cash flow return measures.

Aswath Damodaran
4
Case 1: IRR versus NPV
5

 Consider two projects with the following cash flows:


Year Project 1 CF Project 2 CF
0 -­1000
‐ -­1000

1 800 200
2 1000 300
3 1300 400
4 -­2200
‐ 500

Aswath Damodaran
5
Project’s NPV Profile
6

Aswath Damodaran
6
What do we do now?
7

 Project 1 has two internal rates of return. The first is


6.60%, whereas the second is 36.55%. Project 2 has one
internal rate of return, about 12.8%.
 Why are there two internal rates of return on project 1?

 If your cost of capital is 12%, which investment would


you accept?
a. Project 1
b. Project 2
 Explain.
Aswath Damodaran
7
Case 2: NPV versus IRR
8

Project A

Cash Flow $ 350,000 $ 450,000 $ 600,000 $ 750,000

Investment $ 1,000,000

NPV = $467,937
IRR= 33.66%

Project B

Cash Flow $ 3,000,000 $ 3,500,000 $ 4,500,000 $ 5,500,000

Investment $ 10,000,000
NPV = $1,358,664
IRR=20.88%

Aswath Damodaran
8
Which one would you pick?
9

 Assume that you can pick only one of these two projects.
Your choice will clearly vary depending upon whether
you look at NPV or IRR. You have enough money
currently on hand to take either. Which one would you
pick?
a. Project A. It gives me the bigger bang for the buck and more
margin for error.
b. Project B. It creates more dollar value in my business.
 If you pick A, what would your biggest concern be?

 If you pick B, what would your biggest concern be?

Aswath Damodaran
9
Capital Rationing, Uncertainty and Choosing a
Rule
10

 If a business has limited access to capital, has a stream


of surplus value projects and faces more uncertainty in
its project cash flows, it is much more likely to use IRR as
its decision rule.
🞑 Small, high-­growth
‐ companies and private businesses are much
more likely to use IRR.
 If a business has substantial funds on hand, access to
capital, limited surplus value projects, and more
certainty on its project cash flows, it is much more likely
to use NPV as its decision rule.
 As firms go public and grow, they are much more likely
to gain from using NPV.

Aswath Damodaran
10
The sources of capital rationing…
11

Cause Number of firms Percent of total


Debt limit imposed by outside agreement 10 10.7
Debt limit placed by management external 3 3.2
to firm
Limit placed on borrowing by internal 65 69.1
management
Restrictive policy imposed on retained 2 2.1
earnings
Maintenance of target EPS or PE ratio 14 14.9

Aswath Damodaran
11
An Alternative to IRR with Capital Rationing
12

 The problem with the NPV rule, when there is capital


rationing, is that it is a dollar value. It measures success
in absolute terms.
 The NPV can be converted into a relative measure by
dividing by the initial investment. This is called the
profitability index.
🞑 Profitability Index (PI) = NPV/Initial Investment
 In the example described, the PI of the two projects
would have been:
🞑 PI of Project A = $467,937/1,000,000 = 46.79%
🞑 PI of Project B = $1,358,664/10,000,000 = 13.59%
🞑 Project A would have scored higher.

Aswath Damodaran
12
Case 3: NPV versus IRR
13

Project A

Cash Flow $ 5,000,000 $ 4,000,000 $ 3,200,000 $ 3,000,000

Investment $ 10,000,000

NPV = $1,191,712
IRR=21.41%

Project B

Cash Flow $ 3,000,000 $ 3,500,000 $ 4,500,000 $ 5,500,000

Investment $ 10,000,000
NPV = $1,358,664
IRR=20.88%

Aswath Damodaran
13
Why the difference?
14

 These projects are of the same scale. Both the NPV


and IRR use time-­weighted
‐ cash flows. Yet, the
rankings are different. Why?

 Which one would you pick?


a. Project A. It gives me the bigger bang for the buck and
more margin for error.
b. Project B. It creates more dollar value in my business.

Aswath Damodaran
14
NPV, IRR and the Reinvestment Rate
Assumption
15

 The NPV rule assumes that intermediate cash flows on


the project get reinvested at the hurdle rate (which is
based upon what projects of comparable risk should
earn).
 The IRR rule assumes that intermediate cash flows on
the project get reinvested at the IRR. Implicit is the
assumption that the firm has an infinite stream of
projects yielding similar IRRs.
 Conclusion: When the IRR is high (the project is creating
significant surplus value) and the project life is long,
the IRR will overstate the true return on the project.

Aswath Damodaran
15
Solution to Reinvestment Rate Problem
16

Aswath Damodaran
16
Why NPV and IRR may differ.. Even if projects
have the same lives
17

 A project can have only one NPV, whereas it can have


more than one IRR.
 The NPV is a dollar surplus value, whereas the IRR is a
percentage measure of return. The NPV is therefore
likely to be larger for “large scale” projects, while the
IRR is higher for “small-­‐scale” projects.
 The NPV assumes that intermediate cash flows get
reinvested at the “hurdle rate”, which is based upon
what you can make on investments of comparable risk,
while the IRR assumes that intermediate cash flows get
reinvested at the “IRR”.

Aswath Damodaran
17
Comparing projects with different lives..
18
Project A

$400 $400 $400 $400 $400

-$1000
NPV of Project A = $
442 IRR of Project A =
28.7%
Project B
$350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350

-$1500 NPV of Project B = $ 478


IRR for Project B = 19.4%
Hurdle Rate for Both Projects =
12%

Aswath Damodaran
18
Why NPVs cannot be compared.. When projects
have different lives.
19

 The net present values of mutually exclusive projects


with different lives cannot be compared, since there
is a bias towards longer-­life
‐ projects. To compare
the NPV, we have to
🞑 replicate the projects till they have the same life (or)
🞑 convert the net present values into annuities
 The IRR is unaffected by project life. We can choose
the project with the higher IRR.

Aswath Damodaran
19
Solution 1: Project Replication
20

Project A:
Replicated
$400 $400 $400 $400 $400
$400 $400 $400 $400 $400

-$1000 -$1000 (Replication)


NPV of Project A replicated = $
693
Project B
$350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350

-$1500
NPV of Project B= $ 478

Aswath Damodaran
20
Solution 2: Equivalent Annuities
21

 Equivalent Annuity for 5-­‐year project


🞑 = $442 * PV(A,12%,5 years)
🞑 = $ 122.62

 Equivalent Annuity for 10-­‐year


project
🞑 = $478 * PV(A,12%,10 years)
🞑 = $ 84.60

Aswath Damodaran
21
What would you choose as your investment
tool?
22

 Given the advantages/disadvantages outlined for


each of the different decision rules, which one
would you choose to adopt?
a. Return on Investment (ROE, ROC)
b. Payback or Discounted Payback
c. Net Present Value
d. Internal Rate of Return
e. Profitability Index
 Do you think your choice has been affected by the
events of the last quarter of 2008? If so, why? If not,
why not?
Aswath Damodaran
22
What firms actually use ..
23

Decision Rule % of Firms using as primary decision rule in


1976 1986 1998
IRR 53.6% 49.0% 42.0%
Accounting Return 25.0% 8.0% 7.0%
NPV 9.8% 21.0% 34.0%
Payback Period 8.9% 19.0% 14.0%
Profitability Index 2.7% 3.0% 3.0%

Aswath Damodaran
23
II. Side Costs and Benefits
24

 Most projects considered by any business create side


costs and benefits for that business.
🞑 The side costs include the costs created by the use of resources
that the business already owns (opportunity costs) and lost
revenues for other projects that the firm may have.
🞑 The benefits that may not be captured in the traditional capital
budgeting analysis include project synergies (where cash flow
benefits may accrue to other projects) and options embedded in
projects (including the options to delay, expand or abandon a
project).
 The returns on a project should incorporate these costs
and benefits.

Aswath Damodaran
24
A. Opportunity Cost
25

 An opportunity cost arises when a project uses a


resource that may already have been paid for by the
firm.
 When a resource that is already owned by a firm is being
considered for use in a project, this resource has to be
priced on its next best alternative use, which may be
🞑 a sale of the asset, in which case the opportunity cost is the
expected proceeds from the sale, net of any capital gains taxes
🞑 renting or leasing the asset out, in which case the opportunity
cost is the expected present value of the after-­tax
‐ rental or
lease revenues.
🞑 use elsewhere in the business, in which case the opportunity
cost is the cost of replacing it.

Aswath Damodaran
25
Case 1: Foregone Sale?
26

 Assume that Disney owns land in Rio already. This land is


undeveloped and was acquired several years ago for $ 5
million for a hotel that was never built. It is anticipated,
if this theme park is built, that this land will be used to
build the offices for Disney Rio. The land currently can be
sold for $ 40 million, though that would create a capital
gain (which will be taxed at 20%). In assessing the theme
park, which of the following would you do:
🞑 Ignore the cost of the land, since Disney owns its already
🞑 Use the book value of the land, which is $ 5 million

🞑 Use the market value of the land, which is $ 40 million


🞑 Other:

Aswath Damodaran
26
Case 2: Incremental Cost?
An Online Retailing Venture for Bookscape
27

 The initial investment needed to start the service, including the


installation of additional phone lines and computer equipment, will be $1
million. These investments are expected to have a life of four years, at
which point they will have no salvage value. The investments will be
depreciated straight line over the four-­year
‐ life.
 The revenues in the first year are expected to be $1.5 million, growing
20% in year two, and 10% in the two years following. The cost of the
books will be 60% of the revenues in each of the four years.
 The salaries and other benefits for the employees are estimated to be
$150,000 in year one, and grow 10% a year for the following three
years.
 The working capital, which includes the inventory of books needed for the
service and the accounts receivable will be10% of the revenues; the
investments in working capital have to be made at the beginning of each
year. At the end of year 4, the entire working capital is assumed to be
salvaged.
 The tax rate on income is expected to be 40%.
Aswath Damodaran
27
Cost of capital for investment
28

 We will re-­estimate
‐ the beta for this online project by looking at
publicly traded online retailers. The unlevered total beta of online
retailers is 3.02, and we assume that this project will be funded
with the same mix of debt and equity (D/E = 21.41%, Debt/Capital
= 17.63%) that Bookscape uses in the rest of the business. We will
assume that Bookscape’s tax rate (40%) and pretax cost of debt
(4.05%) apply to this project.
Levered Beta Online Service = 3.02 [1 + (1 – 0.4) (0.2141)] = 3.41
Cost of Equity Online Service = 2.75% + 3.41 (5.5%) = 21.48%
Cost of CapitalOnline Service= 21.48% (0.8237) + 4.05% (1 – 0.4) (0.1763) =
18.12%
 This is much higher than the cost of capital (10.30%) we computed
for Bookscape earlier, but it reflects the higher risk of the online
retail venture.

Aswath Damodaran
28
Incremental Cash flows on Investment
29

0 1 2 3 4
Revenues $1,500,000 $1,800,000 $1,980,000 $2,178,000

Operating Expenses
Labor $150,000 $165,000 $181,500 $199,650
Materials $900,000 $1,080,000 $1,188,000 $1,306,800
Depreciation $250,000 $250,000 $250,000 $250,000

Operating Income $200,000 $305,000 $360,500 $421,550


Taxes $80,000 $122,000 $144,200 $168,620
After-tax Operating
Income $120,000 $183,000 $216,300 $252,930
+ Depreciation $250,000 $250,000 $250,000 $250,000
- Change in
Working Capital $150,000 $30,000 $18,000 $19,800 -$217,800
+ Salvage Value
of Investment $0
Cash flow after taxes -$1,150,000 $340,000 $415,000 $446,500 $720,730
Present Value -$1,150,000 $287,836 $297,428 $270,908 $370,203

NPV of investment = $76,375


Aswath Damodaran
29
The side costs…
30

 It is estimated that the additional business associated with


online ordering and the administration of the service itself
will add to the workload for the current general manager of
the bookstore. As a consequence, the salary of the general
manager will be increased from $100,000 to $120,000 next
year; it is expected to grow 5 percent a year after that for the
remaining three years of the online venture. After the online
venture is ended in the fourth year, the manager’s salary will
revert back to its old levels.
 It is also estimated that Bookscape Online will utilize an office
that is currently used to store financial records. The records
will be moved to a bank vault, which will cost $1000 a year to
rent.
Aswath Damodaran
30
NPV with side costs…
31

 Additional salary costs = PV of $34,352

 Office Costs
🞑 After-­Tax
‐ Additional Storage Expenditure per Year = $1,000 (1 – 0.40) = $600
🞑 PV of expenditures = $600 (PV of annuity, 18.12%,4 yrs) = $1,610
 NPV with Opportunity Costs = $76,375 – $34,352 – $1,610= $ 40,413
 Opportunity costs aggregated into cash flows
Year Cashflows Opportunity costs Cashflow with opportunity costs Present Value
0 ($1,150,000) ($1,150,000) ($1,150,000)
1 $340,000 $12,600 $327,400 $277,170
2 $415,000 $13,200 $401,800 $287,968
3 $446,500 $13,830 $432,670 $262,517
4 $720,730 $14,492 $706,238 $362,759
Adjusted NPV $40,413
Aswath Damodaran
31
Case 3: Excess Capacity
32

 In the Vale example, assume that the firm will use its
existing distribution system to service the
production out of the new iron ore mine. The mine
manager argues that there is no cost associated with
using this system, since it has been paid for already
and cannot be sold or leased to a competitor (and
thus has no competing current use). Do you agree?
a. Yes
b. No

Aswath Damodaran
32
A Framework for Assessing The Cost of Using
Excess Capacity
33

 If I do not add the new product, when will I run out


of capacity?
 If I add the new product, when will I run out of
capacity?
 When I run out of capacity, what will I do?
🞑 Cut back on production: cost is PV of after-­‐tax cash flows
from lost sales
🞑 Buy new capacity: cost is difference in PV between earlier
& later investment

Aswath Damodaran
33
Product and Project Cannibalization: A Real
Cost?
34

 Assume that in the Disney theme park example, 20% of the


revenues at the Rio Disney park are expected to come from
people who would have gone to Disney theme parks in the
US. In doing the analysis of the park, you would
a. Look at only incremental revenues (i.e. 80% of the total revenue)
b. Look at total revenues at the park
c. Choose an intermediate number
 Would your answer be different if you were analyzing
whether to introduce a new show on the Disney cable
channel on Saturday mornings that is expected to attract 20%
of its viewers from ABC (which is also owned by Disney)?
a. Yes
b. No

Aswath Damodaran
34
B. Project Synergies
35

 A project may provide benefits for other projects within the firm.
Consider, for instance, a typical Disney animated movie. Assume
that it costs $ 50 million to produce and promote. This movie, in
addition to theatrical revenues, also produces revenues from
🞑 the sale of merchandise (stuffed toys, plastic figures, clothes ..)
🞑 increased attendance at the theme parks
🞑 stage shows (see “Beauty and the Beast” and the “Lion King”)
🞑 television series based upon the movie
 In investment analysis, however, these synergies are either left
unquantified and used to justify overriding the results of
investment analysis, i.e,, used as justification for investing in
negative NPV projects.
 If synergies exist and they often do, these benefits have to be
valued and shown in the initial project analysis.

Aswath Damodaran
35
Case 1: Adding a Café to a bookstore:
Bookscape
36

 Assume that you are considering adding a café to the bookstore. Assume
also that based upon the expected revenues and expenses, the café
standing alone is expected to have a net present value of -­$87,571.

 The cafe will increase revenues at the book store by $500,000 in year 1,
growing at 10% a year for the following 4 years. In addition, assume that
the pre-­‐tax operating margin on these sales is 10%.

1 2 3 4 5
Increased Revenues $500,000 $550,000 $605,000 $665,500 $732,050
Operating Margin 10.00% 10.00% 10.00% 10.00% 10.00%
Operating Income $50,000 $55,000 $60,500 $66,550 $73,205
Operating Income after Taxes $30,000 $33,000 $36,300 $39,930 $43,923
PV of Additional Cash Flows $27,199 $27,126 $27,053 $26,981 $26,908
PV of Synergy Benefits $135,268

 The net present value of the added benefits is $135,268. Added to the
NPV of the standalone Café of -­$87,571
‐ yields a net present value of
$47,697.

Aswath Damodaran
36
Case 2: Synergy in a merger..
37

 We valued Harman International for an acquisition by Tata Motors and


estimated a value of $ 2,476 million for the operating assets and $ 2,678
million for the equity in the firm, concluding that it would not be a value-­‐
creating acquisition at its current market capitalization of $5,248 million.
In estimating this value, though, we treated Harman International as a
stand-­alone
‐ firm.
 Assume that Tata Motors foresees potential synergies in the combination
of the two firms, primarily from using its using Harman’s high-­end
‐ audio
technology (speakers, tuners) as optional upgrades for customers buying
new Tata Motors cars in India. To value this synergy, let us assume the
following:
🞑 It will take Tata Motors approximately 3 years to adapt Harman’s products to Tata
Motors cars.
🞑 Tata Motors will be able to generate Rs 10 billion in after-­tax
‐ operating income in
year 4 from selling Harman audio upgrades to its Indian customers, growing at a
rate of 4% a year after that in perpetuity (but only in India).

Aswath Damodaran
37
Estimating the cost of capital to use in valuing
synergy..
38

 Business risk: The perceived synergies flow from optional add-­ons‐


in auto sales. We will begin with the levered beta of 1.10, that we
estimated for Tata Motors in chapter 4, in estimating the cost of
equity.
 Geographic risk: The second is that the synergies are expected to
come from India; consequently, we will add the country risk
premium of 3.60% for India, estimated in chapter 4 (for Tata
Motors) to the mature market premium of 5.5%.
 Debt ratio: Finally, we will assume that the expansion will be
entirely in India, with Tata Motors maintain its existing debt to
capital ratio of 29.28% and its current rupee cost of debt of 9.6%
and its marginal tax rate of 32.45%.
🞑 Cost of equity in Rupees = 6.57% + 1.10 (5.5%+3.60%) = 16.59%
🞑 Cost of debt in Rupees = 9.6% (1-­‐.3245) = 6.50%
🞑 Cost of capital in Rupees = 16.59% (1-­.2928)
‐ + 6.50% (.2928) = 13.63%

Aswath Damodaran
38
Estimating the value of synergy… and what Tata
can pay for Harman
39

 Value of synergyYear 3 = Expected Cash FlowYear 4 10,000


  Rs 103,814 million
(Cost of Capital - g) (.1363-.04)
 Value of synergy today = Value of Synergy
(1+Cost of Capital)
103,814
year 3
 Rs 70,753 million
(1.1363)
3 3

 Converting the synergy value into dollar terms at the prevailing


exchange rate of Rs 60/$, we can estimate a dollar value for the
synergy from the potential acquisition:
🞑 Value of synergy in US $ = Rs 70,753/60 = $ 1,179 million
 Adding this value to the intrinsic value of $2,678 million that we
estimated for Harman’s equity in chapter 5, we get a total value for
the equity of $3,857 million.
🞑 Value of Harman = $2,678 million + $1,179 million = $3,857 million
 Since Harman’s equity trades at $5,248 million, the acquisition still
does not make sense, even with the synergy incorporated into
value.

Aswath Damodaran
39
III. Project Options
40

 One of the limitations of traditional investment analysis


is that it is static and does not do a good job of capturing
the options embedded in investment.
🞑 The first of these options is the option to delay taking a project,
when a firm has exclusive rights to it, until a later date.
🞑 The second of these options is taking one project may allow us
to take advantage of other opportunities (projects) in the future
🞑 The last option that is embedded in projects is the option to
abandon a project, if the cash flows do not measure up.
 These options all add value to projects and may
make a
“bad” project (from traditional analysis) into a good
Aswath Damodaran
one. 40
The Option to Delay
41

 When a firm has exclusive rights to a project or product for a specific


period, it can delay taking this project or product until a later date. A
traditional investment analysis just answers the question of whether the
project is a “good” one if taken today. The rights to a “bad” project can
still have value.
PV of Cash Flows

Initial Investment in
Project NPV is positive in this section

Present Value of Expected


Cash Flows on Product

Aswath Damodaran
41
Insights for Investment Analyses
42

 Having the exclusive rights to a product or project is


valuable, even if the product or project is not viable
today.
 The value of these rights increases with the volatility
of the underlying business.
 The cost of acquiring these rights (by buying them or
spending money on development -­‐ R&D, for
instance) has to be weighed off against these
benefits.

Aswath Damodaran
42
The Option to Expand/Take Other Projects
43

 Taking a project today may allow a firm to consider and take other
valuable projects in the future. Thus, even though a project may have a
negative NPV, it may be a project worth taking if the option it provides
the firm (to take other projects in the future) has a more-­than-­
‐ ‐
compensating value.
PV of Cash Flows
from Expansion

Additional
Investment to Expand

Cash Flows on Expansion


Expansion becomes
Firm will not expand in attractive in this section
this section

Aswath Damodaran
43
The Option to Abandon
44

 A firm may sometimes have the option to abandon a project, if the cash
flows do not measure up to expectations.
 If abandoning the project allows the firm to save itself from further
losses, this option can make a project more valuable.

PV of Cash Flows
from Project

Cost of Abandonment

Present Value of Expected


Cash Flows on Project

Aswath Damodaran
44
IV. Assessing Existing or Past investments…
45

 While much of our discussion has been focused on


analyzing new investments, the techniques and
principles enunciated apply just as strongly to
existing investments.
 With existing investments, we can try to address one
of two questions:
🞑 Post –mortem: We can look back at existing investments
and see if they have created value for the firm.
🞑 What next? We can also use the tools of investment
analysis to see whether we should keep, expand or
abandon existing investments.

Aswath Damodaran
45
Analyzing an Existing Investment
46

In a post-mortem, you look at the actual cash You can also reassess your expected cash
flows, relative to forecasts. flows, based upon what you have learned,
and decide whether you should expand,
continue or divest (abandon) an investment

Aswath Damodaran
46
a. Post Mortem Analysis
47

 The actual cash flows from an investment can be greater than or less than
originally forecast for a number of reasons but all these reasons can be
categorized into two groups:
🞑 Chance: The nature of risk is that actual outcomes can be different from
expectations. Even when forecasts are based upon the best of information, they
will invariably be wrong in hindsight because of unexpected shifts in both
macro (inflation, interest rates, economic growth) and micro (competitors,
company) variables.
🞑 Bias: If the original forecasts were biased, the actual numbers will be different from
expectations. The evidence on capital budgeting is that managers tend to be over-­‐
optimistic about cash flows and the bias is worse with over-­confident
‐ managers.
 While it is impossible to tell on an individual project whether chance or
bias is to blame, there is a way to tell across projects and across time. If
chance is the culprit, there should be symmetry in the errors – actuals
should be about as likely to beat forecasts as they are to come under
forecasts. If bias is the reason, the errors will tend to be in one direction.

Aswath Damodaran
47
b. What should we do next?
48

t
NF
n
n ........ Liquidate the project
 n
t 0 (1  r)  0

t
NF
n
n ........ Terminate the project

t 0 (1  r)  Salvage Value
n


t
 n
NFn
 Divestiture Value ........ Divest the project
n
t (1 
 0
r)
t
NFn

n
n
 0  Divestiture Value ........ Continue the project
t (1 
0
r)
Aswath Damodaran
48
Example: Disney California Adventure –
The 2008 judgment call
49

 Disney opened the Disney California Adventure (DCA) Park in 2001, at a


cost of $1.5 billion, with a mix of roller coaster ridesand movie nostalgia.
Disney expected about 60% of its visitors to Disneyland to come across to
DCA and generate about $ 100 million in annual after-­cash
‐ flows for the
firm.
 By 2008, DCA had not performed up to expectations. Of the 15 million
people who came to Disneyland in 2007, only 6 million visited California
Adventure, and the cash flow averaged out to only $ 50 million between
2001 and 2007.
 In early 2008, Disney faced three choices:
🞑 Shut down California Adventure and try to recover whatever it can of its initial
investment. It is estimated that the firm recover about $ 500 million of its investment.
🞑 Continue with the status quo, recognizing that future cash flows will be closer to the
actual values ($ 50 million) than the original projections.
🞑 Invest about $ 600 million to expand and modify the par, with the intent of increasing
the number of attractions for families with children, is expected to increase the
percentage of Disneyland visitors who come to DCA from 40% to 60% and increase the
annual after tax cash flow by 60% (from $ 50 million to $ 80 million) at the park.

Aswath Damodaran
49
DCA: Evaluating the alternatives…
50

 Continuing Operation: Assuming the current after-­tax ‐ cash flow of


$ 50 million will continue in perpetuity, growing at the inflation
rate of 2% and discounting back at the theme park cost of capital in
2008 of 6.62% yields a value for continuing with the status quo
Expected Cash Flow next year 50(1.02)
Value of DCA = (Cost of capital - g)  (.0662  $1.103
billion
 Abandonment: Abandoning this investment currently would allow
 .02)

Disney to recover only $ 500 million of its original investment.


Abandonment value of DCA = $ 500 million
 Expansion: The up-­front
‐ cost of $ 600 million will lead to more
visitors in the park and an increase in the existing cash flows from $
50 to $ 80 million.
Value of CF from expansion = Increase in CF next year  30(1.02)  $662
million (Cost of capital - g) (.0662  .02)

Aswath Damodaran
50
First Principles
51

Maximize the value of the business (firm)

The Investment Decision The Financing Decision The Dividend Decision


Invest in assets that Find the right kind of If you cannot find
earn a return greater debt for your firm and investments that make
than the minimum the right mix of debt your minimum acceptable
acceptable hurdle rate and equity to fund rate, return the cash to
your operations owners of your business

The hurdle rate The return How much How you


should reflect The optimal The right
should reflect cash you choose to
the riskiness mix of debt kind of
the magnitude can return return cash to
of the and equity debt
and the timing depends the owners
investment maximizes matches
of the upon will depend
and the mix of firm value the tenor
cashflows as current & on whether
debt and of your
welll as all side potential they prefer
equity used to assets
effects. investment dividends or
fund it. opportunitie buybacks
s

Aswath Damodaran
51

You might also like