Hindu Predictive Astrology of B V Raman

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 353

Aswath Damodaran 1

Valuation: Lecture Note Packet 1


Intrinsic Valuation
Aswath Damodaran
Updated: January 2017
The essence of intrinsic value
2

 In intrinsic valuation, you value an asset based upon its


fundamentals (or intrinsic characteristics).
 For cash flow generating assets, the intrinsic value will
be a function of the magnitude of the expected cash
flows on the asset over its lifetime and the uncertainty
about receiving those cash flows.
 Discounted cash flow valuation is a tool for estimating
intrinsic value, where the expected value of an asset is
written as the present value of the expected cash flows
on the asset, with either the cash flows or the discount
rate adjusted to reflect the risk.

Aswath Damodaran
2
The two faces of discounted cash flow valuation
3

 The value of a risky asset can be estimated by discounting the


expected cash flows on the asset over its life at a risk-adjusted
discount rate:

where the asset has an n-year life, E(CFt) is the expected cash flow in period t
and r is a discount rate that reflects the risk of the cash flows.
 Alternatively, we can replace the expected cash flows with the
guaranteed cash flows we would have accepted as an alternative
(certainty equivalents) and discount these at the riskfree rate:

where CE(CFt) is the certainty equivalent of E(CFt) and rf is the riskfree rate.

Aswath Damodaran
3
Risk Adjusted Value: Two Basic Propositions
4

 The value of an asset is the risk-adjusted present value of the cash flows:

1. The “IT” proposition: If IT does not affect the expected cash flows or the riskiness
of the cash flows, IT cannot affect value.
2. The “DUH” proposition: For an asset to have value, the expected cash flows have
to be positive some time over the life of the asset.
3. The “DON’T FREAK OUT” proposition: Assets that generate cash flows early in
their life will be worth more than assets that generate cash flows later; the latter
may however have greater growth and higher cash flows to compensate.

Aswath Damodaran
4
DCF Choices: Equity Valuation versus Firm
Valuation
5

Firm Valuation: Value the entire business

Assets Liabilities
Existing Investments Fixed Claim on cash flows
Generate cashflows today Assets in Place Debt Little or No role in management
Includes long lived (fixed) and Fixed Maturity
short-lived(working Tax Deductible
capital) assets

Expected Value that will be Growth Assets Equity Residual Claim on cash flows
created by future investments Significant Role in management
Perpetual Lives

Equity valuation: Value just the


equity claim in the business

Aswath Damodaran
5
Equity Valuation
6

Figure 5.5: Equity Valuation


Assets Liabilities

Assets in Place Debt


Cash flows considered are
cashflows from assets,
after debt payments and
after making reinvestments
needed for future growth Discount rate reflects only the
Growth Assets Equity cost of raising equity financing

Present value is value of just the equity claims on the firm

Aswath Damodaran
6
Firm Valuation
7

Figure 5.6: Firm Valuation


Assets Liabilities

Assets in Place Debt


Cash flows considered are
cashflows from assets, Discount rate reflects the cost
prior to any debt payments of raising both debt and equity
but after firm has financing, in proportion to their
reinvested to create growth
assets use
Growth Assets Equity

Present value is value of the entire firm, and reflects the value of
all claims on the firm.

Aswath Damodaran
7
Firm Value and Equity Value
8

 To get from firm value to equity value, which of the following


would you need to do?
a. Subtract out the value of long term debt
b. Subtract out the value of all debt
c. Subtract the value of any debt that was included in the cost of
capital calculation
d. Subtract out the value of all liabilities in the firm
 Doing so, will give you a value for the equity which is
a. greater than the value you would have got in an equity valuation
b. lesser than the value you would have got in an equity valuation
c. equal to the value you would have got in an equity valuation

Aswath Damodaran
8
Cash Flows and Discount Rates
9

 Assume that you are analyzing a company with the following


cashflows for the next five years.
Year CF to Equity Interest Expense (1-t) CF to Firm
1 $ 50 $ 40 $ 90
2 $ 60 $ 40 $ 100
3 $ 68 $ 40 $ 108
4 $ 76.2 $ 40 $ 116.2
5 $ 83.49 $ 40 $ 123.49
Terminal Value $ 1603.0 $ 2363.008
 Assume also that the cost of equity is 13.625% and the firm can
borrow long term at 10%. (The tax rate for the firm is 50%.)
 The current market value of equity is $1,073 and the value of debt
outstanding is $800.

Aswath Damodaran
9
Equity versus Firm Valuation
10

 Method 1: Discount CF to Equity at Cost of Equity to get value


of equity
 Cost of Equity = 13.625%
 Value of Equity = 50/1.13625 + 60/1.136252 + 68/1.136253 +
76.2/1.136254 + (83.49+1603)/1.136255 = $1073
 Method 2: Discount CF to Firm at Cost of Capital to get value
of firm
 Cost of Debt = Pre-tax rate (1- tax rate) = 10% (1-.5) = 5%
Cost of Capital = 13.625% (1073/1873) + 5% (800/1873) = 9.94%
 PV of Firm = 90/1.0994 + 100/1.09942 + 108/1.09943 + 116.2/1.09944 +
(123.49+2363)/1.09945 = $1873
 Value of Equity = Value of Firm - Market Value of Debt
= $ 1873 - $ 800 = $1073

Aswath Damodaran
10
First Principle of Valuation
11

 Discounting Consistency Principle: Never mix and


match cash flows and discount rates.
 Mismatching cash flows to discount rates is deadly.
 Discounting cashflows after debt cash flows (equity cash
flows) at the weighted average cost of capital will lead to
an upwardly biased estimate of the value of equity
 Discounting pre-debt cashflows (cash flows to the firm) at
the cost of equity will yield a downward biased estimate of
the value of the firm.

Aswath Damodaran
11
The Effects of Mismatching Cash Flows and
Discount Rates
12

 Error 1: Discount CF to Equity at Cost of Capital to get equity


value
 PV of Equity = 50/1.0994 + 60/1.09942 + 68/1.09943 + 76.2/1.09944 +
(83.49+1603)/1.09945 = $1248
 Value of equity is overstated by $175.
 Error 2: Discount CF to Firm at Cost of Equity to get firm value
 PV of Firm = 90/1.13625 + 100/1.136252 + 108/1.136253 +
116.2/1.136254 + (123.49+2363)/1.136255 = $1613
 PV of Equity = $1612.86 - $800 = $813
 Value of Equity is understated by $ 260.
 Error 3: Discount CF to Firm at Cost of Equity, forget to
subtract out debt, and get too high a value for equity
 Value of Equity = $ 1613
 Value of Equity is overstated by $ 540

Aswath Damodaran
12
Aswath Damodaran 13

DISCOUNTED CASH FLOW


VALUATION: THE INPUTS
The devil is in the details..
Discounted Cash Flow Valuation: The Steps
14

1. Estimate the discount rate or rates to use in the valuation


1. Discount rate can be either a cost of equity (if doing equity valuation) or a cost of
capital (if valuing the firm)
2. Discount rate can be in nominal terms or real terms, depending upon whether
the cash flows are nominal or real
3. Discount rate can vary across time.
2. Estimate the current earnings and cash flows on the asset, to either
equity investors (CF to Equity) or to all claimholders (CF to Firm)
3. Estimate the future earnings and cash flows on the firm being valued,
generally by estimating an expected growth rate in earnings.
4. Estimate when the firm will reach “stable growth” and what
characteristics (risk & cash flow) it will have when it does.
5. Choose the right DCF model for this asset and value it.

Aswath Damodaran
14
Generic DCF Valuation Model
15

Aswath Damodaran
15
Same ingredients, different approaches…
16

Input Dividend Discount FCFE (Potential FCFF (firm)


Model dividend) discount valuation model
model
Cash flow Dividend Potential dividends FCFF = Cash flows
= FCFE = Cash flows before debt
after taxes, payments but after
reinvestment needs reinvestment needs
and debt cash and taxes.
flows
Expected growth In equity income In equity income In operating
and dividends and FCFE income and FCFF
Discount rate Cost of equity Cost of equity Cost of capital
Steady state When dividends When FCFE grow at When FCFF grow at
grow at constant constant rate constant rate
rate forever forever forever
Aswath Damodaran
16
Start easy: The Dividend Discount Model
17

Aswath Damodaran
17
Moving on up: The “potential dividends” or FCFE
model
18

Aswath Damodaran
18
To valuing the entire business: The FCFF model
19

Aswath Damodaran
19
Aswath Damodaran 20

DISCOUNT RATES
The D in the DCF..
Estimating Inputs: Discount Rates
21

 While discount rates obviously matter in DCF valuation, they


don’t matter as much as most analysts think they do.
 At an intuitive level, the discount rate used should be
consistent with both the riskiness and the type of cashflow
being discounted.
 Equity versus Firm: If the cash flows being discounted are cash flows to
equity, the appropriate discount rate is a cost of equity. If the cash
flows are cash flows to the firm, the appropriate discount rate is the
cost of capital.
 Currency: The currency in which the cash flows are estimated should
also be the currency in which the discount rate is estimated.
 Nominal versus Real: If the cash flows being discounted are nominal
cash flows (i.e., reflect expected inflation), the discount rate should be
nominal

Aswath Damodaran
21
Risk in the DCF Model
22

Aswath Damodaran
22
Not all risk is created equal…
23

 Estimation versus Economic uncertainty


 Estimation uncertainty reflects the possibility that you could have the “wrong
model” or estimated inputs incorrectly within this model.
 Economic uncertainty comes the fact that markets and economies can change over
time and that even the best models will fail to capture these unexpected changes.
 Micro uncertainty versus Macro uncertainty
 Micro uncertainty refers to uncertainty about the potential market for a firm’s
products, the competition it will face and the quality of its management team.
 Macro uncertainty reflects the reality that your firm’s fortunes can be affected by
changes in the macro economic environment.
 Discrete versus continuous uncertainty
 Discrete risk: Risks that lie dormant for periods but show up at points in time.
(Examples: A drug working its way through the FDA pipeline may fail at some stage
of the approval process or a company in Venezuela may be nationalized)
 Continuous risk: Risks changes in interest rates or economic growth occur
continuously and affect value as they happen.

Aswath Damodaran
23
Risk and Cost of Equity: The role of the marginal
investor
24

 Not all risk counts: While the notion that the cost of equity should
be higher for riskier investments and lower for safer investments is
intuitive, what risk should be built into the cost of equity is the
question.
 Risk through whose eyes? While risk is usually defined in terms of
the variance of actual returns around an expected return, risk and
return models in finance assume that the risk that should be
rewarded (and thus built into the discount rate) in valuation should
be the risk perceived by the marginal investor in the investment
 The diversification effect: Most risk and return models in finance
also assume that the marginal investor is well diversified, and that
the only risk that he or she perceives in an investment is risk that
cannot be diversified away (i.e, market or non-diversifiable risk). In
effect, it is primarily economic, macro, continuous risk that should
be incorporated into the cost of equity.

Aswath Damodaran
24
The Cost of Equity: Competing “ Market Risk” Models
25

Model Expected Return Inputs Needed


CAPM E(R) = Rf + b (Rm- Rf) Riskfree Rate
Beta relative to market portfolio
Market Risk Premium
APM E(R) = Rf + Sbj (Rj- Rf) Riskfree Rate; # of Factors;
Betas relative to each factor
Factor risk premiums
Multi E(R) = Rf + Sbj (Rj- Rf) Riskfree Rate; Macro factors
factor Betas relative to macro factors
Macro economic risk premiums
Proxy E(R) = a + S bj Yj Proxies
Regression coefficients

Aswath Damodaran
25
Classic Risk & Return: Cost of Equity
26

 In the CAPM, the cost of equity:


Cost of Equity = Riskfree Rate + Equity Beta * (Equity Risk
Premium)
 In APM or Multi-factor models, you still need a risk
free rate, as well as betas and risk premiums to go
with each factor.
 To use any risk and return model, you need
 A risk free rate as a base
 A single equity risk premium (in the CAPM) or factor risk
premiums, in the the multi-factor models
 A beta (in the CAPM) or betas (in multi-factor models)
Aswath Damodaran
26
27 Discount Rates: I
The Risk Free Rate

Aswath Damodaran
The Risk Free Rate: Laying the Foundations
28

 On a riskfree investment, the actual return is equal to the expected


return. Therefore, there is no variance around the expected return.
 For an investment to be riskfree, then, it has to have
 No default risk
 No reinvestment risk
 It follows then that if asked to estimate a risk free rate:
1. Time horizon matters: Thus, the riskfree rates in valuation will
depend upon when the cash flow is expected to occur and will
vary across time.
2. Currencies matter: A risk free rate is currency-specific and can be
very different for different currencies.
3. Not all government securities are riskfree: Some governments
face default risk and the rates on bonds issued by them will not
be riskfree.

Aswath Damodaran
28
Test 1: A riskfree rate in US dollars!
29

 In valuation, we estimate cash flows forever (or at


least for very long time periods). The right risk free
rate to use in valuing a company in US dollars would
be
a. A three-month Treasury bill rate (0.5%)
b. A ten-year Treasury bond rate (2.5%)
c. A thirty-year Treasury bond rate (3.5%)
d. A TIPs (inflation-indexed treasury) rate (0.5%)
e. None of the above
What are we implicitly assuming about the US treasury when
we use any of the treasury numbers?

Aswath Damodaran
29
Test 2: A Riskfree Rate in Euros
30

Euro Government Bond Rates - January 1, 2017


10.00%

9.00%

8.00%

7.00%

6.00%

5.00%

4.00%

3.00%

2.00%

1.00%

0.00%

Aswath Damodaran
30
Test 3: A Riskfree Rate in Indian Rupees
31

 The Indian government had 10-year Rupee bonds


outstanding, with a yield to maturity of about 6.40% on
January 1, 2017.
 In January 2017, the Indian government had a local currency
sovereign rating of Baa3. The typical default spread (over a
default free rate) for Baa3 rated country bonds in early 2017
was 2.54%. The riskfree rate in Indian Rupees is
a. The yield to maturity on the 10-year bond (6.40%)
b. The yield to maturity on the 10-year bond + Default spread (8.94%)
c. The yield to maturity on the 10-year bond – Default spread (3.86%)
d. None of the above

Aswath Damodaran
31
Sovereign Default Spread: Three paths to
the same destination…
32

 Sovereign dollar or euro denominated bonds: Find


sovereign bonds denominated in US dollars, issued by an
emerging sovereign.
 Default spread = Emerging Govt Bond Rate (in US $) – US
Treasury Bond rate with same maturity.
 CDS spreads: Obtain the traded value for a sovereign
Credit Default Swap (CDS) for the emerging government.
 Default spread = Sovereign CDS spread (with perhaps an
adjustment for CDS market frictions).
 Sovereign-rating based spread: For countries which don’t
issue dollar denominated bonds or have a CDS spread,
you have to use the average spread for other countries
with the same sovereign rating.

Aswath Damodaran
32
Local Currency Government Bond Rates – January
2017
33

Currency Govt Bond Rate 12/31/16 Currency Govt Bond Rate 12/31/16
Australian $ 2.76% Malyasian Ringgit 4.24%
Brazilian Reai 11.37% Mexican Peso 7.63%
British Pound 1.35% Nigerian Naira 15.97%
Bulgarian Lev 2.04% Norwegian Krone 1.61%
Canadian $ 1.70% NZ $ 3.25%
Chilean Peso 4.12% Pakistani Rupee 8.03%
Chinese Yuan 3.25% Peruvian Sol 6.43%
Colombian Peso 6.76% Phillipine Peso 4.75%
Croatian Kuna 3.13% Polish Zloty 3.67%
Czech Koruna 0.49% Romanian Leu 3.44%
Danish Krone 0.42% Russian Ruble 8.38%
Euro 0.29% Singapore $ 2.45%
HK $ 1.69% South African Rand 8.80%
Hungarian Forint 3.41% Swedish Krona 0.62%
Iceland Krona 5.06% Swiss Franc -0.19%
Indian Rupee 6.40% Taiwanese $ 1.17%
Indonesian Rupiah 7.60% Thai Baht 2.70%
Israeli Shekel 2.06% Turkish Lira 11.00%
Japanese Yen 0.06% US $ 2.45%
Kenyan Shilling 14.02% Venezuelan Bolivar 20.43%
Korean Won 2.08% Vietnamese Dong 6.10%

Aswath Damodaran
33
Approach 1: Default spread from Government
Bonds

The Brazil Default Spread


Brazil 2018 Bond: 4.86%
US 2018 T.Bond: 1.22%
Spread: 3.64%

34
Approach 2: CDS Spreads – January 2017
35

CDS Spread adj CDS Spread adj CDS Spread adj


Country CDS Spread Country CDS Spread Country CDS Spread
for US for US for US
Abu Dhabi 0.97% 0.59% Hungary 1.67% 1.29% Peru 1.73% 1.35%
Argentina 5.14% 4.76% Iceland 1.10% 0.72% Philippines 1.61% 1.23%
Australia 0.49% 0.11% India 1.76% 1.38% Poland 1.17% 0.79%
Austria 0.52% 0.14% Indonesia 2.25% 1.87% Portugal 3.42% 3.04%
Bahrain 3.17% 2.79% Ireland 1.02% 0.64% Qatar 1.17% 0.79%
Belgium 0.60% 0.22% Israel 1.12% 0.74% Romania 1.51% 1.13%
Brazil 3.59% 3.21% Italy 2.22% 1.84% Russia 2.46% 2.08%
Bulgaria 1.87% 1.49% Japan 0.62% 0.24% Saudi Arabia 1.45% 1.07%
Chile 1.29% 0.91% Kazakhstan 2.13% 1.75% Slovakia 0.85% 0.47%
China 1.65% 1.27% Korea 0.67% 0.29% Slovenia 1.52% 1.14%
Colombia 2.42% 2.04% Latvia 1.02% 0.64% South Africa 2.87% 2.49%
Costa Rica 3.40% 3.02% Lebanon 5.57% 5.19% Spain 1.25% 0.87%
Croatia 2.60% 2.22% Lithuania 0.94% 0.56% Sweden 0.40% 0.02%
Cyprus 2.67% 2.29% Malaysia 1.94% 1.56% Switzerland 0.50% 0.12%
Czech Republic 0.74% 0.36% Mexico 2.20% 1.82% Thailand 1.28% 0.90%
Denmark 0.41% 0.03% Morocco 2.11% 1.73% Tunisia 5.00% 4.62%
Egypt 4.76% 4.38% Netherlands 0.51% 0.13% Turkey 3.44% 3.06%
Estonia 0.81% 0.43% New Zealand 0.50% 0.12% Ukraine 7.64% 7.26%
Finland 0.45% 0.07% Nigeria 5.76% 5.38% United Kingdom 0.61% 0.23%
France 0.70% 0.32% Norway 0.34% 0.00% United States 0.38% 0.00%
Germany 0.44% 0.06% Pakistan 4.18% 3.80% Venezuela 30.82% 30.44%
Hong Kong 0.58% 0.20% Panama 1.94% 1.56% Vietnam 2.61% 2.23%

Aswath Damodaran
35
Approach 3: Typical Default Spreads: January
2017
36

S&P Sovereign Rating Moody's Sovereign Rating Default Spread


AAA Aaa 0.00%
AA+ Aa1 0.46%
AA Aa2 0.57%
AA- Aa3 0.70%
A+ A1 0.81%
A A2 0.98%
A- A3 1.39%
BBB+ Baa1 1.84%
BBB Baa2 2.20%
BBB- Baa3 2.54%
BB+ Ba1 2.89%
BB Ba2 3.47%
BB Ba3 4.16%
B+ B1 5.20%
B B2 6.36%
B- B3 7.51%
CCC+ Caa1 8.66%
CCC Caa2 10.40%
CCC- Caa3 11.55%
CC+ Ca1 13.86%
CC Ca2 15.25%
CC- Ca3 16.50%
C+ C1 18.00%
C C2 20.00%
Aswath Damodaran 25.00%
C- C3 36
Getting to a risk free rate in a currency: Example
37

 The Brazilian government bond rate in nominal reais on


January 1, 2017 was 11.37%. To get to a riskfree rate in
nominal reais, we can use one of three approaches.
 Approach 1: Government Bond spread
 The 2018 Brazil bond, denominated in US dollars, has a spread of
3.64% over the US treasury bond rate.
 Riskfree rate in $R = 11.37% - 3.64% = 7.73%
 Approach 2: The CDS Spread
 The CDS spread for Brazil, adjusted for the US CDS spread was
3.21%.
 Riskfree rate in $R = 11.37% - 3.21% = 8.16%
 Approach 3: The Rating based spread
 Brazil has a Ba2 local currency rating from Moody’s. The default
spread for that rating is 3.47%
 Riskfree rate in $R = 11.37% - 3.47% = 7.90%

Aswath Damodaran
37
Test 4: A Real Riskfree Rate
38

 In some cases, you may want a riskfree rate in real terms


(in real terms) rather than nominal terms.
 To get a real riskfree rate, you would like a security with
no default risk and a guaranteed real return. Treasury
indexed securities offer this combination.
 In January 2017, the yield on a 10-year indexed treasury
bond was 0.50%. Which of the following statements
would you subscribe to?
a. This (0.5%) is the real riskfree rate to use, if you are valuing US
companies in real terms.
b. This (0.5%) is the real riskfree rate to use, anywhere in the
world
Explain.

Aswath Damodaran
38
No default free entity: Choices with riskfree rates….
39

 Estimate a range for the riskfree rate in local terms:


 Approach 1: Subtract default spread from local government bond rate:
Government bond rate in local currency terms - Default spread for
Government in local currency
 Approach 2: Use forward rates and the riskless rate in an index currency
(say Euros or dollars) to estimate the riskless rate in the local currency.
 Do the analysis in real terms (rather than nominal terms) using a
real riskfree rate, which can be obtained in one of two ways –
 from an inflation-indexed government bond, if one exists
 set equal, approximately, to the long term real growth rate of the economy
in which the valuation is being done.
 Do the analysis in a currency where you can get a riskfree rate, say
US dollars or Euros.

Aswath Damodaran
39
Risk free Rate: Don’t have or trust the
government bond rate?
1. Build up approach: The risk free rate in any currency can be
written as the sum of two variables:
Risk free rate = Expected Inflation in currency + Expected real interest rate
The expected real interest rate can be computed in one of two ways: from
the US TIPs rate or set equal to real growth in the economy. Thus, if the
expected inflation rate in a country is expected to be 15% and the TIPs rate
is 1%, the risk free rate is 16%.
2. US $ rate & Differential Inflation: Alternatively, you can scale up
the US $ risk free rate by the differential inflation between the US
$ and the currency in question:
Risk free rateCurrency=

Thus, if the US $ risk free rate is 2.00%, the inflation rate in the foreign
currency is 15% and the inflation rate in US $ is 1.5%, the foreign currency risk
free rate is as follows:
Risk free rate =

40
Aswath Damodaran ‹#›
One more test on riskfree rates…
42

 On January 1, 2017, the 10-year treasury bond rate in


the United States was 2.45%, low by historic standards.
Assume that you were valuing a company in US dollars
then, but were wary about the risk free rate being too
low. Which of the following should you do?
a. Replace the current 10-year bond rate with a more reasonable
normalized riskfree rate (the average 10-year bond rate over
the last 30 years has been about 5-6%)
b. Use the current 10-year bond rate as your riskfree rate but
make sure that your other assumptions (about growth and
inflation) are consistent with the riskfree rate
c. Something else…

Aswath Damodaran
42
43

-5.00%
10.00%
15.00%
20.00%

0.00%
5.00%
1954

Aswath Damodaran
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974

Inflation rate
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985

Real GDP growth


1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
Ten-year T.Bond rate
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Interest rate fundamentals: T. Bond rates, Real growth and inflation

2007
2008
2009
Some perspective on risk free rates

2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
43
Negative Interest Rates?
44

 In 2016, there were at least three currencies (Swiss


Franc, Japanese Yen, Euro) with negative interest
rates. Using the fundamentals (inflation and real
growth) approach, how would you explain negative
interest rates?
 How negative can rates get? (Is there a bound?)
 Would you use these negative interest rates as risk
free rates?
 If no, why not and what would you do instead?
 If yes, what else would you have to do in your valuation to
be internally consistent?
Aswath Damodaran
44
45 Discount Rates: II
The Equity Risk Premium

Aswath Damodaran
The ubiquitous historical risk premium
46

 The historical premium is the premium that stocks have historically


earned over riskless securities.
 While the users of historical risk premiums act as if it is a fact (rather than
an estimate), it is sensitive to
 How far back you go in history…

 Whether you use T.bill rates or T.Bond rates

 Whether you use geometric or arithmetic averages.

 For instance, looking at the US:


Arithmetic Average Geometric Average
Stocks - T. Bills Stocks - T. Bonds Stocks - T. Bills Stocks - T. Bonds
1928-2016 7.96% 6.24% 6.11% 4.62%
Std Error 2.13% 2.28%
1967-2016 6.57% 4.37% 5.26% 3.42%
Std Error 2.42% 2.74%
2007-2016 7.91% 3.62% 6.15% 2.30%
Error Damodaran 6.06%
StdAswath 8.66%
46
The perils of trusting the past…….
47

 Noisy estimates: Even with long time periods of history,


the risk premium that you derive will have substantial
standard error. For instance, if you go back to 1928
(about 80 years of history) and you assume a standard
deviation of 20% in annual stock returns, you arrive at a
standard error of greater than 2%:
Standard Error in Premium = 20%/√80 = 2.26%
 Survivorship Bias: Using historical data from the U.S.
equity markets over the twentieth century does create a
sampling bias. After all, the US economy and equity
markets were among the most successful of the global
economies that you could have invested in early in the
century.
Aswath Damodaran
47
Risk Premium for a Mature Market? Broadening
the sample to 1900-2015
48

Country Geometric ERP Arithmetic ERP Standard Error


Australia 5.00% 6.60% 1.70%
Austria 2.60% 21.50% 14.30%
Belgium 2.40% 4.50% 2.00%
Canada 3.30% 4.90% 1.70%
Denmark 2.30% 3.80% 1.70%
Finland 5.20% 8.80% 2.80%
France 3.00% 5.40% 2.10%
Germany 5.10% 9.10% 2.70%
Ireland 2.80% 4.80% 1.80%
Italy 3.10% 6.50% 2.70%
Japan 5.10% 9.10% 3.00%
Netherlands 3.30% 5.60% 2.10%
New Zealand 4.00% 5.50% 1.70%
Norway 2.30% 5.20% 2.60%
South Africa 5.40% 7.20% 1.80%
Spain 1.80% 3.80% 1.90%
Sweden 3.10% 5.40% 2.00%
Switzerland 2.10% 3.60% 1.60%
U.K. 3.60% 5.00% 1.60%
U.S. 4.30% 6.40% 1.90%
Europe 3.20% 4.50% 1.50%
World-ex U.S. 2.80% 3.90% 1.40%
World 3.20% 4.40% 1.40%
Aswath Damodaran
48
The simplest way of estimating an additional
country risk premium: The country default spread
49

 Default spread for country: In this approach, the country equity risk
premium is set equal to the default spread for the country,
estimated in one of three ways:
 The default spread on a dollar denominated bond issued by the country.
(In January 2017, that spread was 3.64% for the Brazilian $ bond)
 The sovereign CDS spread for the country. In January 2017, the ten year
CDS spread for Brazil, adjusted for the US CDS, was 3.21%.
 The default spread based on the local currency rating for the country.
Brazil’s sovereign local currency rating is Ba2 and the default spread for a
Ba2 rated sovereign was about 3.47% in January 2017.
 Add the default spread to a “mature” market premium: This default
spread is added on to the mature market premium to arrive at the
total equity risk premium for Brazil, assuming a mature market
premium of 5.69%.
 Country Risk Premium for Brazil = 3.47%
 Total ERP for Brazil = 5.69% + 3.47% = 9.16%

Aswath Damodaran
49
An equity volatility based approach to
estimating the country total ERP
50

 This approach draws on the standard deviation of two equity


markets, the emerging market in question and a base market
(usually the US). The total equity risk premium for the
emerging market is then written as:
 Total equity risk premium = Risk PremiumUS* Country Equity / US Equity
 The country equity risk premium is based upon the volatility
of the market in question relative to U.S market.
 Assume that the equity risk premium for the US is 5.69%.
 Assume that the standard deviation in the Bovespa (Brazilian equity) is
30% and that the standard deviation for the S&P 500 (US equity) is
18%.
 Total Equity Risk Premium for Brazil = 5.69% (30%/18%) = 9.48%
 Country equity risk premium for Brazil = 9.48% - 5.69% = 3.79%

Aswath Damodaran
50
A melded approach to estimating the additional
country risk premium
51

 Country ratings measure default risk. While default risk premiums


and equity risk premiums are highly correlated, one would expect
equity spreads to be higher than debt spreads.
 Another is to multiply the bond default spread by the relative
volatility of stock and bond prices in that market. Using this
approach for Brazil in January 2016, you would get:
 Country Equity risk premium = Default spread on country bond* Country
Equity / Country Bond
 Standard Deviation in Bovespa (Equity) = 30%
 Standard Deviation in Brazil government bond = 20%
 Default spread for Brazil= 3.47%
 Brazil Country Risk Premium = 3.47% (30%/20%) = 5.21%
 Brazil Total ERP = Mature Market Premium + CRP = 5.69% + 5.21% =
11.00%

Aswath Damodaran
51
A Template for Estimating the ERP

Aswath Damodaran
52
ERP : Jan 2017

Black #: Total ERP


Red #: Country risk premium
AVG: GDP weighted average
From Country Equity Risk Premiums to
Corporate Equity Risk premiums
54

 Approach 1: Assume that every company in the country is equally


exposed to country risk. In this case,
 E(Return) = Riskfree Rate + CRP + Beta (Mature ERP)
 Implicitly, this is what you are assuming when you use the local Government’s
dollar borrowing rate as your riskfree rate.
 Approach 2: Assume that a company’s exposure to country risk is similar
to its exposure to other market risk.
 E(Return) = Riskfree Rate + Beta (Mature ERP+ CRP)
 Approach 3: Treat country risk as a separate risk factor and allow firms to
have different exposures to country risk (perhaps based upon the
proportion of their revenues come from non-domestic sales)
 E(Return)=Riskfree Rate+ (Mature ERP) + (CRP)
Mature ERP = Mature market Equity Risk Premium
CRP = Additional country risk premium

Aswath Damodaran
54
Approaches 1 & 2: Estimating country risk
premium exposure
55

 Location based CRP: The standard approach in valuation is to


attach a country risk premium to a company based upon its
country of incorporation. Thus, if you are an Indian company,
you are assumed to be exposed to the Indian country risk
premium. A developed market company is assumed to be
unexposed to emerging market risk.
 Operation-based CRP: There is a more reasonable modified
version. The country risk premium for a company can be
computed as a weighted average of the country risk
premiums of the countries that it does business in, with the
weights based upon revenues or operating income. If a
company is exposed to risk in dozens of countries, you can
take a weighted average of the risk premiums by region.
Aswath Damodaran
55
Operation based CRP: Single versus Multiple
Emerging Markets
56

 Single emerging market: Embraer, in 2004, reported that it derived 3% of


its revenues in Brazil and the balance from mature markets. The mature
market ERP in 2004 was 5% and Brazil’s CRP was 7.89%.

 Multiple emerging markets: Ambev, the Brazilian-based beverage


company, reported revenues from the following countries during 2011.

Aswath Damodaran
56
Extending to a multinational: Regional breakdown
Coca Cola’s revenue breakdown and ERP in 2012
57

Things to watch out for


1. Aggregation across regions. For instance, the Pacific region often includes Australia & NZ with Asia
2. Obscure aggregations including Eurasia and Oceania
57
Two problems with these approaches..
58

 Focus just on revenues: To the extent that revenues are


the only variable that you consider, when weighting risk
exposure across markets, you may be missing other
exposures to country risk. For instance, an emerging
market company that gets the bulk of its revenues
outside the country (in a developed market) may still
have all of its production facilities in the emerging
market.
 Exposure not adjusted or based upon beta: To the extent
that the country risk premium is multiplied by a beta, we
are assuming that beta in addition to measuring
exposure to all other macro economic risk also measures
exposure to country risk.

Aswath Damodaran
58
A Production-based ERP: Royal Dutch Shell
in 2015
59

Country Oil & Gas Production % of Total ERP


Denmark 17396 3.83% 6.20%
Italy 11179 2.46% 9.14%
Norway 14337 3.16% 6.20%
UK 20762 4.57% 6.81%
Rest of Europe 874 0.19% 7.40%
Brunei 823 0.18% 9.04%
Iraq 20009 4.40% 11.37%
Malaysia 22980 5.06% 8.05%
Oman 78404 17.26% 7.29%
Russia 22016 4.85% 10.06%
Rest of Asia & ME 24480 5.39% 7.74%
Oceania 7858 1.73% 6.20%
Gabon 12472 2.75% 11.76%
Nigeria 67832 14.93% 11.76%
Rest of Africa 6159 1.36% 12.17%
USA 104263 22.95% 6.20%
Canada 8599 1.89% 6.20%
Brazil 13307 2.93% 9.60%
Rest of Latin America 576 0.13% 10.78%
Royal Dutch Shell 454326 100.00% 8.26%

Aswath Damodaran
59
Approach 3: Estimate a lambda for country risk
60

 Country risk exposure is affected by where you get your


revenues and where your production happens, but there are
a host of other variables that also affect this exposure,
including:
 Use of risk management products: Companies can use both options/futures
markets and insurance to hedge some or a significant portion of country risk.
 Government “national” interests: There are sectors that are viewed as vital to
the national interests, and governments often play a key role in these
companies, either officially or unofficially. These sectors are more exposed to
country risk.
 It is conceivable that there is a richer measure of country risk
that incorporates all of the variables that drive country risk in
one measure. That way my rationale when I devised
“lambda” as my measure of country risk exposure.

Aswath Damodaran
60
A Revenue-based Lambda

 The factor “l” measures the relative exposure of a firm to country


risk. One simplistic solution would be to do the following:
l = % of revenues domesticallyfirm/ % of revenues domesticallyaverage firm
 Consider two firms – Tata Motors and Tata Consulting Services,
both Indian companies. In 2008-09, Tata Motors got about 91.37%
of its revenues in India and TCS got 7.62%. The average Indian firm
gets about 80% of its revenues in India:
l Tata Motors= 91%/80% = 1.14
l TCS= 7.62%/80% = 0.09
 There are two implications
 A company’s risk exposure is determined by where it does business and
not by where it is incorporated.
 Firms might be able to actively manage their country risk exposures

61
A Price/Return based Lambda
62

ReturnEmbraer = 0.0195 + 0.2681 ReturnC Bond


ReturnEmbratel = -0.0308 + 2.0030 ReturnC Bond
Embraer versus C Bond: 2000-2003 Embratel versus C Bond: 2000-2003
40 100

80

20
60

Return on Embratel
Return on Embraer

40
0
20

0
-20
-20

-40 -40

-60

-60 -80
-30 -20 -10 0 10 20 -30 -20 -10 0 10 20

Return on C-Bond Return on C-Bond

Aswath Damodaran
62
Estimating a US Dollar Cost of Equity for
Embraer - September 2004
63

 Assume that the beta for Embraer is 1.07, and that the US $ riskfree rate
used is 4%. Also assume that the risk premium for the US is 5% and the
country risk premium for Brazil is 7.89%. Finally, assume that Embraer
gets 3% of its revenues in Brazil & the rest in the US.
 There are five estimates of $ cost of equity for Embraer:
 Approach 1: Constant exposure to CRP, Location CRP
 E(Return) = 4% + 1.07 (5%) + 7.89% = 17.24%
 Approach 2: Constant exposure to CRP, Operation CRP
 E(Return) = 4% + 1.07 (5%) + (0.03*7.89% +0.97*0%)= 9.59%
 Approach 3: Beta exposure to CRP, Location CRP
 E(Return) = 4% + 1.07 (5% + 7.89%)= 17.79%
 Approach 4: Beta exposure to CRP, Operation CRP
 E(Return) = 4% + 1.07 (5% +( 0.03*7.89%+0.97*0%)) = 9.60%
 Approach 5: Lambda exposure to CRP
 E(Return) = 4% + 1.07 (5%) + 0.27(7.89%) = 11.48%

Aswath Damodaran
63
Valuing Emerging Market Companies with
significant exposure in developed markets
64

 The conventional practice in investment banking is to add the country


equity risk premium on to the cost of equity for every emerging market
company, notwithstanding its exposure to emerging market risk. Thus, in
2004, Embraer would have been valued with a cost of equity of 17-18%
even though it gets only 3% of its revenues in Brazil. As an investor, which
of the following consequences do you see from this approach?
a. Emerging market companies with substantial exposure in developed
markets will be significantly over valued by equity research analysts.
b. Emerging market companies with substantial exposure in developed
markets will be significantly under valued by equity research analysts.
Can you construct an investment strategy to take advantage of the misvaluation?
What would need to happen for you to make money of this strategy?

Aswath Damodaran
64
Implied Equity Premiums
65

 Let’s start with a general proposition. If you know the price


paid for an asset and have estimates of the expected cash
flows on the asset, you can estimate the IRR of these cash
flows. If you paid the price, this is what you have priced the
asset to earn (as an expected return).
 If you assume that stocks are correctly priced in the aggregate
and you can estimate the expected cashflows from buying
stocks, you can estimate the expected rate of return on stocks
by finding that discount rate that makes the present value
equal to the price paid. Subtracting out the riskfree rate
should yield an implied equity risk premium.
 This implied equity premium is a forward looking number and
can be updated as often as you want (every minute of every
day, if you are so inclined).

Aswath Damodaran
65
Implied Equity Premiums: January 2008
66

 We can use the information in stock prices to back out how risk averse the market is and how much of a risk
premium it is demanding.
After year 5, we will assume that
Between 2001 and 2007 Analysts expect earnings to grow 5% a year for the next 5 years. We earnings on the index will grow at
dividends and stock will assume that dividends & buybacks will keep pace.. 4.02%, the same rate as the entire
buybacks averaged 4.02% Last year’s cashflow (59.03) growing at 5% a year economy (= riskfree rate).
of the index each year.
61.98 65.08 68.33 71.75 75.34

January 1, 2008
S&P 500 is at 1468.36
4.02% of 1468.36 = 59.03

 If you pay the current level of the index, you can expect to make a return of 8.39% on stocks (which is obtained by
solving for r in the following equation)
61.98 65.08 68.33 71.75 75.34 75.35(1.0402)
1468.36 = + + + + +
(1+ r) (1+ r) 2 (1+ r) 3 (1+ r) 4 (1+ r) 5 (r - .0402)(1+ r) 5
 Implied Equity risk premium = Expected return on stocks - Treasury bond rate = 8.39% - 4.02% = 4.37%

Aswath Damodaran
66
A year that made a difference.. The implied
premium in January 2009
67
Year Market value of index Dividends Buybacks Cash to equity Dividend yield Buyback yield Total yield
2001 1148.09 15.74 14.34 30.08 1.37% 1.25% 2.62%
2002 879.82 15.96 13.87 29.83 1.81% 1.58% 3.39%
2003 1111.91 17.88 13.70 31.58 1.61% 1.23% 2.84%
2004 1211.92 19.01 21.59 40.60 1.57% 1.78% 3.35%
2005 1248.29 22.34 38.82 61.17 1.79% 3.11% 4.90%
2006 1418.30 25.04 48.12 73.16 1.77% 3.39% 5.16%
2007 1468.36 28.14 67.22 95.36 1.92% 4.58% 6.49%
2008 903.25 28.47 40.25 68.72 3.15% 4.61% 7.77%
Normalized 903.25 28.47 24.11 52.584 3.15% 2.67% 5.82%

Aswath Damodaran
67
The Anatomy of a Crisis: Implied ERP from
September 12, 2008 to January 1, 2009
68

Aswath Damodaran
68
An Updated Equity Risk Premium: January
2017
69

Aswath Damodaran
69
Aswath Damodaran ‹#›
A Buyback Adjusted Version of the US ERP
71

Aswath Damodaran
71
Implied Premium versus Risk Free Rate
72

Aswath Damodaran
72
Aswath Damodaran ‹#›
Aswath Damodaran ‹#›
Why implied premiums matter?
75

 In many investment banks, it is common practice (especially


in corporate finance departments) to use historical risk
premiums (and arithmetic averages at that) as risk premiums
to compute cost of equity. If all analysts in the department
used the arithmetic average premium (for stocks over T.Bills)
for 1928-2016 of 7.96% to value stocks in January 2017, given
the implied premium of 5.69%, what are they likely to find?
a. The values they obtain will be too low (most stocks will look
overvalued)
b. The values they obtain will be too high (most stocks will look
under valued)
c. There should be no systematic bias as long as they use the
same premium to value all stocks.

Aswath Damodaran
75
Which equity risk premium should you use?
76
If you assume this Premium to use
Premiums revert back to historical norms Historical risk premium
and your time period yields these norms

Market is correct in the aggregate or that Current implied equity risk premium
your valuation should be market neutral

Marker makes mistakes even in the Average implied equity risk premium over
aggregate but is correct over time time.
Predictor Correlation with implied Correlation with actual Correlation with actual return
premium next year return- next 5 years – next 10 years
Current implied premium 0.750 0.475 0.541
Average implied premium: Last 5 0.703 0.541 0.747
years
Historical Premium -0.476 -0.442 -0.469
Default Spread based premium 0.035 0.234 0.225

Aswath Damodaran
76
An ERP for the Sensex
77

 Inputs for the computation


 Sensex on 9/5/07 = 15446
 Dividend yield on index = 3.05%
 Expected growth rate - next 5 years = 14%
 Growth rate beyond year 5 = 6.76% (set equal to riskfree rate)
 Solving for the expected return:
537.06 612.25 697.86 795.67 907.07 907.07(1.0676)
15446 = + + + + +
(1+ r) (1+ r) 2 (1+ r) 3 (1+ r) 4 (1+ r) 5 (r - .0676)(1+ r) 5

 Expected return on stocks = 11.18%


 Implied equity risk premium for India = 11.18% - 6.76% =
4.42%

Aswath Damodaran
77
Changing Country Risk: Brazil CRP & Total
ERP from 2000 to 2015
78

Aswath Damodaran
78
The evolution of Emerging Market Risk
79

Growth Growth Cost of Cost of


PBV PBV ROE ROE US T.Bond Rate Rate Equity Equity Differential
Start of year Developed Emerging Developed Emerging rate Developed Emerging (Developed) (Emerging) ERP
2004 2.00 1.19 10.81% 11.65% 4.25% 3.75% 5.25% 7.28% 10.63% 3.35%
2005 2.09 1.27 11.12% 11.93% 4.22% 3.72% 5.22% 7.26% 10.50% 3.24%
2006 2.03 1.44 11.32% 12.18% 4.39% 3.89% 5.39% 7.55% 10.11% 2.56%
2007 1.67 1.67 10.87% 12.88% 4.70% 4.20% 5.70% 8.19% 10.00% 1.81%
2008 0.87 0.83 9.42% 11.12% 4.02% 3.52% 5.02% 10.30% 12.37% 2.07%
2009 1.20 1.34 8.48% 11.02% 2.21% 1.71% 3.21% 7.35% 9.04% 1.69%
2010 1.39 1.43 9.14% 11.22% 3.84% 3.34% 4.84% 7.51% 9.30% 1.79%
2011 1.12 1.08 9.21% 10.04% 3.29% 2.79% 4.29% 8.52% 9.61% 1.09%
2012 1.17 1.18 9.10% 9.33% 1.88% 1.38% 2.88% 7.98% 8.35% 0.37%
2013 1.56 1.63 8.67% 10.48% 1.76% 1.26% 2.76% 6.02% 7.50% 1.48%
2014 1.95 1.50 9.27% 9.64% 3.04% 2.54% 4.04% 6.00% 7.77% 1.77%
2015 1.88 1.56 9.69% 9.75% 2.17% 1.67% 3.17% 5.94% 7.39% 1.45%
2016 1.89 1.59 9.24% 10.16% 2.27% 1.77% 3.27% 5.72% 7.60% 1.88%

Aswath Damodaran
79
80 Discount Rates: III
Relative Risk Measures

Aswath Damodaran
The CAPM Beta: The Most Used (and
Misused) Risk Measure
81

 The standard procedure for estimating betas is to regress


stock returns (Rj) against market returns (Rm) -
Rj = a + b Rm
where a is the intercept and b is the slope of the regression.
 The slope of the regression corresponds to the beta of
the stock, and measures the riskiness of the stock.
 This beta has three problems:
• It has high standard error
• It reflects the firm’s business mix over the period of the
regression, not the current mix
• It reflects the firm’s average financial leverage over the period
rather than the current leverage.

Aswath Damodaran
81
Unreliable, when it looks bad..
82

Aswath Damodaran
82
Or when it looks good..
83

Aswath Damodaran
83
One slice of history..
84

During this time period, Valeant was a


stock under siege, without a CEO,
under legal pressure & lacking
financials.

Aswath Damodaran
And subject to game playing
85

Aswath Damodaran
Measuring Relative Risk: You don’t like betas or
modern portfolio theory? No problem.
86

Aswath Damodaran
86
Don’t like the diversified investor focus,
but okay with price-based measures
87

1. Relative Standard Deviation


• Relative Volatility = Std dev of Stock/ Average Std dev across all stocks
• Captures all risk, rather than just market risk
2. Proxy Models
• Look at historical returns on all stocks and look for variables that
explain differences in returns.
• You are, in effect, running multiple regressions with returns on
individual stocks as the dependent variable and fundamentals about
these stocks as independent variables.
• This approach started with market cap (the small cap effect) and over
the last two decades has added other variables (momentum, liquidity
etc.)
3. CAPM Plus Models
• Start with the traditional CAPM (Rf + Beta (ERP)) and then add other
premiums for proxies.

Aswath Damodaran
87
Don’t like the price-based approach..
88

1. Accounting risk measures: To the extent that you don’t trust


market-priced based measures of risk, you could compute
relative risk measures based on
• Accounting earnings volatility: Compute an accounting beta or relative
volatility
• Balance sheet ratios: You could compute a risk score based upon accounting
ratios like debt ratios or cash holdings (akin to default risk scores like the Z
score)
2. Qualitative Risk Models: In these models, risk assessments
are based at least partially on qualitative factors (quality of
management).
3. Debt based measures: You can estimate a cost of equity,
based upon an observable costs of debt for the company.
• Cost of equity = Cost of debt * Scaling factor
• The scaling factor can be computed from implied volatilities.

Aswath Damodaran
88
Determinants of Betas & Relative Risk
89

Aswath Damodaran
89
In a perfect world… we would estimate the beta of a
firm by doing the following
90

Aswath Damodaran
90
Adjusting for operating leverage…
91

 Within any business, firms with lower fixed costs (as a


percentage of total costs) should have lower unlevered
betas. If you can compute fixed and variable costs for
each firm in a sector, you can break down the unlevered
beta into business and operating leverage components.
 Unlevered beta = Pure business beta * (1 + (Fixed costs/ Variable
costs))
 The biggest problem with doing this is informational. It is
difficult to get information on fixed and variable costs for
individual firms.
 In practice, we tend to assume that the operating
leverage of firms within a business are similar and use
the same unlevered beta for every firm.
Aswath Damodaran
91
Adjusting for financial leverage…
92

 Conventional approach: If we assume that debt carries


no market risk (has a beta of zero), the beta of equity
alone can be written as a function of the unlevered beta
and the debt-equity ratio
bL = bu (1+ ((1-t)D/E))
In some versions, the tax effect is ignored and there is no (1-t) in
the equation.
 Debt Adjusted Approach: If beta carries market risk and
you can estimate the beta of debt, you can estimate the
levered beta as follows:
bL = bu (1+ ((1-t)D/E)) - bdebt (1-t) (D/E)
While the latter is more realistic, estimating betas for debt can be
difficult to do.

Aswath Damodaran
92
Bottom-up Betas
93

Aswath Damodaran
93
Why bottom-up betas?
94

 The standard error in a bottom-up beta will be significantly


lower than the standard error in a single regression beta.
Roughly speaking, the standard error of a bottom-up beta
estimate can be written as follows:
Std error of bottom-up beta = Average Std Error across Betas
Number of firms in sample

 The bottom-up beta can be adjusted to reflect changes in the


firm’s business mix and financial leverage. Regression betas
reflect the past.
 You can estimate bottom-up betas even when you do not
have historical stock prices. This is the case with initial public
offerings, private businesses or divisions of companies.

Aswath Damodaran
94
Estimating Bottom Up Betas & Costs of
Equity: Vale
Sample Unlevered beta Peer Group Value of Proportion of
Business Sample size of business Revenues EV/Sales Business Vale

Global firms in metals &


Metals & mining, Market cap>$1
Mining billion 48 0.86 $9,013 1.97 $17,739 16.65%

Iron Ore Global firms in iron ore 78 0.83 $32,717 2.48 $81,188 76.20%

Global specialty
Fertilizers chemical firms 693 0.99 $3,777 1.52 $5,741 5.39%

Global transportation
Logistics firms 223 0.75 $1,644 1.14 $1,874 1.76%
Vale
Operations 0.8440 $47,151 $106,543 100.00%

Aswath Damodaran
95
Embraer’s Bottom-up Beta
96

Business Unlevered Beta D/E Ratio Levered beta


Aerospace 0.95 18.95% 1.07

 Levered Beta = Unlevered Beta ( 1 + (1- tax rate) (D/E Ratio)


= 0.95 ( 1 + (1-.34) (.1895)) = 1.07

 Can an unlevered beta estimated using U.S. and European


aerospace companies be used to estimate the beta for a Brazilian
aerospace company?
a. Yes
b. No
What concerns would you have in making this assumption?

Aswath Damodaran
96
Gross Debt versus Net Debt Approaches
97

 Analysts in Europe and Latin America often take the difference between
debt and cash (net debt) when computing debt ratios and arrive at very
different values.
 For Embraer, using the gross debt ratio
 Gross D/E Ratio for Embraer = 1953/11,042 = 18.95%
 Levered Beta using Gross Debt ratio = 1.07
 Using the net debt ratio, we get
 Net Debt Ratio for Embraer = (Debt - Cash)/ Market value of Equity
= (1953-2320)/ 11,042 = -3.32%
 Levered Beta using Net Debt Ratio = 0.95 (1 + (1-.34) (-.0332)) = 0.93
 The cost of Equity using net debt levered beta for Embraer will be much
lower than with the gross debt approach. The cost of capital for Embraer
will even out since the debt ratio used in the cost of capital equation will
now be a net debt ratio rather than a gross debt ratio.

Aswath Damodaran
97
The Cost of Equity: A Recap
98

Aswath Damodaran
98
99 Discount Rates: IV
Mopping up

Aswath Damodaran
Estimating the Cost of Debt
100

 The cost of debt is the rate at which you can borrow at


currently, It will reflect not only your default risk but also the
level of interest rates in the market.
 The two most widely used approaches to estimating cost of
debt are:
 Looking up the yield to maturity on a straight bond outstanding from
the firm. The limitation of this approach is that very few firms have
long term straight bonds that are liquid and widely traded
 Looking up the rating for the firm and estimating a default spread
based upon the rating. While this approach is more robust, different
bonds from the same firm can have different ratings. You have to use a
median rating for the firm
 When in trouble (either because you have no ratings or
multiple ratings for a firm), estimate a synthetic rating for
your firm and the cost of debt based upon that rating.
Aswath Damodaran
100
Estimating Synthetic Ratings
101

 The rating for a firm can be estimated using the financial


characteristics of the firm. In its simplest form, the rating
can be estimated from the interest coverage ratio
Interest Coverage Ratio = EBIT / Interest Expenses
 For Embraer’s interest coverage ratio, we used the
interest expenses from 2003 and the average EBIT from
2001 to 2003. (The aircraft business was badly affected
by 9/11 and its aftermath. In 2002 and 2003, Embraer
reported significant drops in operating income)
Interest Coverage Ratio = 462.1 /129.70 = 3.56

Aswath Damodaran
101
Interest Coverage Ratios, Ratings and Default
Spreads: 2003 & 2004
102

If Interest Coverage Ratio is Estimated Bond Rating Default Spread(2003) Default Spread(2004)
> 8.50 (>12.50) AAA 0.75% 0.35%
6.50 - 8.50 (9.5-12.5) AA 1.00% 0.50%
5.50 - 6.50 (7.5-9.5) A+ 1.50% 0.70%
4.25 - 5.50 (6-7.5) A 1.80% 0.85%
3.00 - 4.25 (4.5-6) A– 2.00% 1.00%
2.50 - 3.00 (4-4.5) BBB 2.25% 1.50%
2.25- 2.50 (3.5-4) BB+ 2.75% 2.00%
2.00 - 2.25 ((3-3.5) BB 3.50% 2.50%
1.75 - 2.00 (2.5-3) B+ 4.75% 3.25%
1.50 - 1.75 (2-2.5) B 6.50% 4.00%
1.25 - 1.50 (1.5-2) B– 8.00% 6.00%
0.80 - 1.25 (1.25-1.5) CCC 10.00% 8.00%
0.65 - 0.80 (0.8-1.25) CC 11.50% 10.00%
0.20 - 0.65 (0.5-0.8) C 12.70% 12.00%
< 0.20 (<0.5) D 15.00% 20.00%
 The first number under interest coverage ratios is for larger market cap companies and the second in
brackets is for smaller market cap companies. For Embraer , I used the interest coverage ratio table for
smaller/riskier firms (the numbers in brackets) which yields a lower rating for the same interest coverage
ratio.

Aswath Damodaran
102
Cost of Debt computations
103

 Companies in countries with low bond ratings and high default risk
might bear the burden of country default risk, especially if they are
smaller or have all of their revenues within the country.
 Larger companies that derive a significant portion of their revenues
in global markets may be less exposed to country default risk. In
other words, they may be able to borrow at a rate lower than the
government.
 The synthetic rating for Embraer is A-. Using the 2004 default
spread of 1.00%, we estimate a cost of debt of 9.29% (using a
riskfree rate of 4.29% and adding in two thirds of the country
default spread of 6.01%):
Cost of debt
= Riskfree rate + 2/3(Brazil country default spread) + Company default spread
=4.29% + 4.00%+ 1.00% = 9.29%

Aswath Damodaran
103
Synthetic Ratings: Some Caveats
104

 The relationship between interest coverage ratios and


ratings, developed using US companies, tends to travel
well, as long as we are analyzing large manufacturing
firms in markets with interest rates close to the US
interest rate
 They are more problematic when looking at smaller
companies in markets with higher interest rates than the
US. One way to adjust for this difference is modify the
interest coverage ratio table to reflect interest rate
differences (For instances, if interest rates in an
emerging market are twice as high as rates in the US,
halve the interest coverage ratio.
Aswath Damodaran
104
Default Spreads: The effect of the crisis of
2008.. And the aftermath
105

Default spread over treasury

Rating 1-Jan-08 12-Sep-08 12-Nov-08 1-Jan-09 1-Jan-10 1-Jan-11


Aaa/AAA 0.99% 1.40% 2.15% 2.00% 0.50% 0.55%
Aa1/AA+ 1.15% 1.45% 2.30% 2.25% 0.55% 0.60%
Aa2/AA 1.25% 1.50% 2.55% 2.50% 0.65% 0.65%
Aa3/AA- 1.30% 1.65% 2.80% 2.75% 0.70% 0.75%
A1/A+ 1.35% 1.85% 3.25% 3.25% 0.85% 0.85%
A2/A 1.42% 1.95% 3.50% 3.50% 0.90% 0.90%
A3/A- 1.48% 2.15% 3.75% 3.75% 1.05% 1.00%

Baa1/BBB+ 1.73% 2.65% 4.50% 5.25% 1.65% 1.40%


Baa2/BBB 2.02% 2.90% 5.00% 5.75% 1.80% 1.60%

Baa3/BBB- 2.60% 3.20% 5.75% 7.25% 2.25% 2.05%


Ba1/BB+ 3.20% 4.45% 7.00% 9.50% 3.50% 2.90%
Ba2/BB 3.65% 5.15% 8.00% 10.50% 3.85% 3.25%
Ba3/BB- 4.00% 5.30% 9.00% 11.00% 4.00% 3.50%
B1/B+ 4.55% 5.85% 9.50% 11.50% 4.25% 3.75%
B2/B 5.65% 6.10% 10.50% 12.50% 5.25% 5.00%
B3/B- 6.45% 9.40% 13.50% 15.50% 5.50% 6.00%

Caa/CCC+ 7.15% 9.80% 14.00% 16.50% 7.75% 7.75%


ERP 4.37% 4.52% 6.30% 6.43% 4.36% 5.20%105
Aswath Damodaran ‹#›
Subsidized Debt: What should we do?
107

 Assume that the Brazilian government lends money to


Embraer at a subsidized interest rate (say 6% in dollar
terms). In computing the cost of capital to value
Embraer, should be we use the cost of debt based upon
default risk or the subsidized cost of debt?
a. The subsidized cost of debt (6%). That is what the
company is paying.
b. The fair cost of debt (9.25%). That is what the company
should require its projects to cover.
c. A number in the middle.

Aswath Damodaran
107
Weights for the Cost of Capital Computation
108

 In computing the cost of capital for a publicly traded


firm, the general rule for computing weights for debt
and equity is that you use market value weights (and
not book value weights). Why?
a. Because the market is usually right
b. Because market values are easy to obtain
c. Because book values of debt and equity are meaningless
d. None of the above

Aswath Damodaran
108
Estimating Cost of Capital: Embraer in 2004
109

 Equity
 Cost of Equity = 4.29% + 1.07 (4%) + 0.27 (7.89%) = 10.70%
 Market Value of Equity =11,042 million BR ($ 3,781 million)
 Debt
 Cost of debt = 4.29% + 4.00% +1.00%= 9.29%
 Market Value of Debt = 2,083 million BR ($713 million)
 Cost of Capital
Cost of Capital = 10.70 % (.84) + 9.29% (1- .34) (0.16)) = 9.97%
 The book value of equity at Embraer is 3,350 million BR.
 The book value of debt at Embraer is 1,953 million BR; Interest
expense is 222 mil BR; Average maturity of debt = 4 years
 Estimated market value of debt = 222 million (PV of annuity, 4 years,
9.29%) + $1,953 million/1.09294 = 2,083 million BR

Aswath Damodaran
109
If you had to do it….Converting a Dollar Cost of
Capital to a Nominal Real Cost of Capital
110

 Approach 1: Use a BR riskfree rate in all of the calculations


above. For instance, if the BR riskfree rate was 12%, the cost
of capital would be computed as follows:
 Cost of Equity = 12% + 1.07(4%) + 0.27 (7. 89%) = 18.41%
 Cost of Debt = 12% + 1% = 13%
 (This assumes the riskfree rate has no country risk premium
embedded in it.)
 Approach 2: Use the differential inflation rate to estimate the
cost of capital. For instance, if the inflation rate in BR is 8%
and the inflation rate in the U.S. is 2%
é 1+ Inflation ù
Cost of capital= (1+ Cost of Capital$ )ê ú
BR
ë 1+ Inflation$ û
= 1.0997 (1.08/1.02)-1 = 0.1644 or 16.44%

Aswath Damodaran
110
Dealing with Hybrids and Preferred Stock
111

 When dealing with hybrids (convertible bonds, for


instance), break the security down into debt and equity
and allocate the amounts accordingly. Thus, if a firm has
$ 125 million in convertible debt outstanding, break the
$125 million into straight debt and conversion option
components. The conversion option is equity.
 When dealing with preferred stock, it is better to keep it
as a separate component. The cost of preferred stock is
the preferred dividend yield. (As a rule of thumb, if the
preferred stock is less than 5% of the outstanding market
value of the firm, lumping it in with debt will make no
significant impact on your valuation).
Aswath Damodaran
111
Decomposing a convertible bond…
112

 Assume that the firm that you are analyzing has $125 million
in face value of convertible debt with a stated interest rate of
4%, a 10 year maturity and a market value of $140 million. If
the firm has a bond rating of A and the interest rate on A-
rated straight bond is 8%, you can break down the value of
the convertible bond into straight debt and equity portions.
 Straight debt = (4% of $125 million) (PV of annuity, 10 years, 8%) + 125
million/1.0810 = $91.45 million
 Equity portion = $140 million - $91.45 million = $48.55 million
 The debt portion ($91.45 million) gets added to debt and the
option portion ($48.55 million) gets added to the market
capitalization to get to the debt and equity weights in the cost
of capital.
Aswath Damodaran
112
Recapping the Cost of Capital
113

Aswath Damodaran
113
Aswath Damodaran 114

ESTIMATING CASH FLOWS


Cash is king…
Steps in Cash Flow Estimation
115

 Estimate the current earnings of the firm


 If looking at cash flows to equity, look at earnings after interest
expenses - i.e. net income
 If looking at cash flows to the firm, look at operating earnings after
taxes
 Consider how much the firm invested to create future growth
 If the investment is not expensed, it will be categorized as capital
expenditures. To the extent that depreciation provides a cash flow, it
will cover some of these expenditures.
 Increasing working capital needs are also investments for future
growth
 If looking at cash flows to equity, consider the cash flows from
net debt issues (debt issued - debt repaid)

Aswath Damodaran
115
Measuring Cash Flows
116

Cash flows can be measured to

Just Equity Investors


All claimholders in the firm

EBIT (1- tax rate) Net Income Dividends


- ( Capital Expenditures - Depreciation) - (Capital Expenditures - Depreciation) + Stock Buybacks
- Change in non-cash working capital - Change in non-cash Working Capital
= Free Cash Flow to Firm (FCFF) - (Principal Repaid - New Debt Issues)
- Preferred Dividend

Aswath Damodaran
116
Measuring Cash Flow to the Firm: Three
pathways to the same end game
117

Where are the tax savings from interest expenses?

Aswath Damodaran
117
118 Cash Flows I
Accounting Earnings, Flawed but Important

Aswath Damodaran
From Reported to Actual Earnings
119

Aswath Damodaran
119
I. Update Earnings
120

 When valuing companies, we often depend upon financial


statements for inputs on earnings and assets. Annual reports are
often outdated and can be updated by using-
 Trailing 12-month data, constructed from quarterly earnings reports.
 Informal and unofficial news reports, if quarterly reports are unavailable.
 Updating makes the most difference for smaller and more volatile
firms, as well as for firms that have undergone significant
restructuring.
 Time saver: To get a trailing 12-month number, all you need is one
10K and one 10Q (example third quarter). Use the Year to date
numbers from the 10Q. For example, to get trailing revenues from
a third quarter 10Q:
 Trailing 12-month Revenue = Revenues (in last 10K) - Revenues from first 3
quarters of last year + Revenues from first 3 quarters of this year.

Aswath Damodaran
120
II. Correcting Accounting Earnings
121

 Make sure that there are no financial expenses mixed in with


operating expenses
 Financial expense: Any commitment that is tax deductible that you have to
meet no matter what your operating results: Failure to meet it leads to
loss of control of the business.
 Example: Operating Leases: While accounting convention treats operating
leases as operating expenses, they are really financial expenses and need
to be reclassified as such. This has no effect on equity earnings but does
change the operating earnings
 Make sure that there are no capital expenses mixed in with the
operating expenses
 Capital expense: Any expense that is expected to generate benefits over
multiple periods.
 R & D Adjustment: Since R&D is a capital expenditure (rather than an
operating expense), the operating income has to be adjusted to reflect its
treatment.

Aswath Damodaran
121
The Magnitude of Operating Leases
122

Aswath Damodaran
122
Dealing with Operating Lease Expenses
123

 Operating Lease Expenses are treated as operating expenses


in computing operating income. In reality, operating lease
expenses should be treated as financing expenses, with the
following adjustments to earnings and capital:
 Debt Value of Operating Leases = Present value of Operating
Lease Commitments at the pre-tax cost of debt
 When you convert operating leases into debt, you also create
an asset to counter it of exactly the same value.
 Adjusted Operating Earnings
 Adjusted Operating Earnings = Operating Earnings + Operating Lease
Expenses - Depreciation on Leased Asset
As an approximation, this works:
 Adjusted Operating Earnings = Operating Earnings + Pre-tax cost of
Debt * PV of Operating Leases.

Aswath Damodaran
123
Operating Leases at The Gap in 2003
124

 The Gap has conventional debt of about $ 1.97 billion on its balance sheet and its
pre-tax cost of debt is about 6%. Its operating lease payments in the 2003 were
$978 million and its commitments for the future are below:
Year Commitment (millions) Present Value (at 6%)
1 $899.00 $848.11
2 $846.00 $752.94
3 $738.00 $619.64
4 $598.00 $473.67
5 $477.00 $356.44
6&7 $982.50 each year $1,346.04
 Debt Value of leases = $4,396.85 (Also value of leased asset)
 Debt outstanding at The Gap = $1,970 m + $4,397 m = $6,367 m

 Adjusted Operating Income = Stated OI + OL exp this year - Deprec’n


= $1,012 m + 978 m - 4397 m /7 = $1,362 million (7 year life for assets)
 Approximate OI = $1,012 m + $ 4397 m (.06) = $1,276 m

Aswath Damodaran
124
The Collateral Effects of Treating Operating
Leases as Debt
125

Conventional Accounting Operating Leases Treated as Debt


Income Statement Income Statement
EBIT& Leases = 1,990 EBIT& Leases = 1,990
- Op Leases = 978 - Deprecn: OL= 628
EBIT = 1,012 EBIT = 1,362
Interest expense will rise to reflect the
conversion of operating leases as debt. Net
income should not change.
Balance Sheet Balance Sheet
Off balance sheet (Not shown as debt or as an Asset Liability
asset). Only the conventional debt of $1,970 OL Asset 4397 OL Debt 4397
million shows up on balance sheet Total debt = 4397 + 1970 = $6,367 million

Cost of capital = 8.20%(7350/9320) + 4% Cost of capital = 8.20%(7350/13717) + 4%


(1970/9320) = 7.31% (6367/13717) = 6.25%
Cost of equity for The Gap = 8.20%
After-tax cost of debt = 4%
Market value of equity = 7350
Return on capital = 1012 (1-.35)/(3130+1970) Return on capital = 1362 (1-.35)/(3130+6367)
= 12.90% = 9.30%

Aswath Damodaran
125
The Magnitude of R&D Expenses
126

Aswath Damodaran
126
R&D Expenses: Operating or Capital Expenses
127

 Accounting standards require us to consider R&D as an


operating expense even though it is designed to
generate future growth. It is more logical to treat it as
capital expenditures.
 To capitalize R&D,
 Specify an amortizable life for R&D (2 - 10 years)
 Collect past R&D expenses for as long as the amortizable life
 Sum up the unamortized R&D over the period. (Thus, if the
amortizable life is 5 years, the research asset can be obtained by
adding up 1/5th of the R&D expense from five years ago, 2/5th
of the R&D expense from four years ago...:

Aswath Damodaran
127
Capitalizing R&D Expenses: SAP
128

 R & D was assumed to have a 5-year life.


Year R&D Expense Unamortized Amortization this year
Current 1020.02 1.00 1020.02
-1 993.99 0.80 795.19 € 198.80
-2 909.39 0.60 545.63 € 181.88
-3 898.25 0.40 359.30 € 179.65
-4 969.38 0.20 193.88 € 193.88
-5 744.67 0.00 0.00 € 148.93
Value of research asset = € 2,914 million
Amortization of research asset in 2004 = € 903 million
Increase in Operating Income = 1020 - 903 = € 117 million

Aswath Damodaran
128
The Effect of Capitalizing R&D at SAP
129

Conventional Accounting R&D treated as capital expenditure


Income Statement Income Statement
EBIT& R&D = 3045 EBIT& R&D = 3045
- R&D = 1020 - Amort: R&D = 903
EBIT = 2025 EBIT = 2142 (Increase of 117 m)
EBIT (1-t) = 1285 m EBIT (1-t) = 1359 m
Ignored tax benefit = (1020-903)(.3654) = 43
Adjusted EBIT (1-t) = 1359+43 = 1402 m
(Increase of 117 million)
Net Income will also increase by 117 million
Balance Sheet Balance Sheet
Off balance sheet asset. Book value of equity at Asset Liability
3,768 million Euros is understated because R&D Asset 2914 Book Equity +2914
biggest asset is off the books. Total Book Equity = 3768+2914= 6782 mil
Capital Expenditures Capital Expenditures
Conventional net cap ex of 2 million Net Cap ex = 2+ 1020 – 903 = 119 mil
Euros
Cash Flows Cash Flows
EBIT (1-t) = 1285 EBIT (1-t) = 1402
- Net Cap Ex = 2 - Net Cap Ex = 119
FCFF = 1283 FCFF = 1283 m
Return on capital = 1285/(3768+530) Return on capital = 1402/(6782+530)
Aswath Damodaran
129
III. One-Time and Non-recurring Charges
130

 Assume that you are valuing a firm that is reporting a


loss of $ 500 million, due to a one-time charge of $ 1
billion. What is the earnings you would use in your
valuation?
a. A loss of $ 500 million
b. A profit of $ 500 million
 Would your answer be any different if the firm had
reported one-time losses like these once every five
years?
a. Yes
b. No

Aswath Damodaran
130
IV. Accounting Malfeasance….
131

 Though all firms may be governed by the same accounting


standards, the fidelity that they show to these standards can vary.
More aggressive firms will show higher earnings than more
conservative firms.
 While you will not be able to catch outright fraud, you should look
for warning signals in financial statements and correct for them:
 Income from unspecified sources - holdings in other businesses that are
not revealed or from special purpose entities.
 Income from asset sales or financial transactions (for a non-financial firm)
 Sudden changes in standard expense items - a big drop in S,G &A or R&D
expenses as a percent of revenues, for instance.
 Frequent accounting restatements
 Accrual earnings that run ahead of cash earnings consistently
 Big differences between tax income and reported income

Aswath Damodaran
131
V. Dealing with Negative or Abnormally Low
Earnings
132

Aswath Damodaran
132
133 Cash Flows II
Taxes and Reinvestment

Aswath Damodaran
What tax rate?
134

 The tax rate that you should use in computing the after-
tax operating income should be
a. The effective tax rate in the financial statements (taxes
paid/Taxable income)
b. The tax rate based upon taxes paid and EBIT (taxes paid/EBIT)
c. The marginal tax rate for the country in which the company
operates
d. The weighted average marginal tax rate across the countries in
which the company operates
e. None of the above
f. Any of the above, as long as you compute your after-tax cost of
debt using the same tax rate

Aswath Damodaran
134
The Right Tax Rate to Use
135

 The choice really is between the effective and the marginal


tax rate. In doing projections, it is far safer to use the
marginal tax rate since the effective tax rate is really a
reflection of the difference between the accounting and the
tax books.
 By using the marginal tax rate, we tend to understate the
after-tax operating income in the earlier years, but the after-
tax tax operating income is more accurate in later years
 If you choose to use the effective tax rate, adjust the tax rate
towards the marginal tax rate over time.
 While an argument can be made for using a weighted average
marginal tax rate, it is safest to use the marginal tax rate of the country

Aswath Damodaran
135
A Tax Rate for a Money Losing Firm
136

 Assume that you are trying to estimate the after-tax


operating income for a firm with $ 1 billion in net
operating losses carried forward. This firm is expected to
have operating income of $ 500 million each year for the
next 3 years, and the marginal tax rate on income for all
firms that make money is 40%. Estimate the after-tax
operating income each year for the next 3 years.
Year 1 Year 2 Year 3
EBIT 500 500 500
Taxes
EBIT (1-t)
Tax rate

Aswath Damodaran
136
Net Capital Expenditures
137

 Net capital expenditures represent the difference


between capital expenditures and depreciation.
Depreciation is a cash inflow that pays for some or a
lot (or sometimes all of) the capital expenditures.
 In general, the net capital expenditures will be a
function of how fast a firm is growing or expecting to
grow. High growth firms will have much higher net
capital expenditures than low growth firms.
 Assumptions about net capital expenditures can
therefore never be made independently of
assumptions about growth in the future.
Aswath Damodaran
137
Capital expenditures should include
138

 Research and development expenses, once they have been


re-categorized as capital expenses. The adjusted net cap ex
will be
 Adjusted Net Capital Expenditures = Net Capital Expenditures +
Current year’s R&D expenses - Amortization of Research Asset
 Acquisitions of other firms, since these are like capital
expenditures. The adjusted net cap ex will be
 Adjusted Net Cap Ex = Net Capital Expenditures + Acquisitions of other
firms - Amortization of such acquisitions
 Two caveats:
1. Most firms do not do acquisitions every year. Hence, a normalized
measure of acquisitions (looking at an average over time) should be
used
2. The best place to find acquisitions is in the statement of cash flows,
usually categorized under other investment activities

Aswath Damodaran
138
Cisco’s Acquisitions: 1999
139

Acquired Method of Acquisition Price Paid


GeoTel Pooling $1,344
Fibex Pooling $318
Sentient Pooling $103
American Internet Purchase $58
Summa Four Purchase $129
Clarity Wireless Purchase $153
Selsius Systems Purchase $134
PipeLinks Purchase $118
Amteva Tech Purchase $159
$2,516

Aswath Damodaran
139
Cisco’s Net Capital Expenditures in 1999
140

Cap Expenditures (from statement of CF) = $ 584 mil


- Depreciation (from statement of CF) = $ 486 mil
Net Cap Ex (from statement of CF)= $ 98 mil
+ R & D expense = $ 1,594 mil
- Amortization of R&D = $ 485 mil
+ Acquisitions = $ 2,516 mil
Adjusted Net Capital Expenditures = $3,723 mil

 (Amortization was included in the depreciation number)


Aswath Damodaran
140
Working Capital Investments
141

 In accounting terms, the working capital is the difference


between current assets (inventory, cash and accounts
receivable) and current liabilities (accounts payables,
short term debt and debt due within the next year)
 A cleaner definition of working capital from a cash flow
perspective is the difference between non-cash current
assets (inventory and accounts receivable) and non-debt
current liabilities (accounts payable)
 For firms in some sectors, it is the investment in working
capital that is the bigger part of reinvestment.

Aswath Damodaran
141
Working Capital: General Propositions
142

1. Working Capital Detail: While some analysts break down


working capital into detail (inventory, deferred taxes,
payables etc.), it is a pointless exercise unless you feel that
you can bring some specific information that lets you
forecast the details.
2. Working Capital Volatility: Changes in non-cash working
capital from year to year tend to be volatile. So, building of
the change in the most recent year is dangerous. It is better
to either estimate the change based on working capital as a
percent of sales, while keeping an eye on industry averages.
3. Negative Working Capital: Some firms have negative non-
cash working capital. Assuming that this will continue into
the future will generate positive cash flows for the firm and
will get more positive as growth increases.

Aswath Damodaran
142
Volatile Working Capital?
143

Amazon Cisco Motorola


Revenues $ 1,640 $12,154 $30,931
Non-cash WC -$419 -$404 $2547
% of Revenues -25.53% -3.32% 8.23%
Change from last year $ (309) ($700) ($829)
Average: last 3 years -15.16% -3.16% 8.91%
Average: industry 8.71% -2.71% 7.04%
My Prediction
WC as % of Revenue 3.00% 0.00% 8.23%

Aswath Damodaran
143
144 Cash Flows III
From the firm to equity

Aswath Damodaran
Dividends and Cash Flows to Equity
145

 In the strictest sense, the only cash flow that an investor


will receive from an equity investment in a publicly
traded firm is the dividend that will be paid on the stock.
 Actual dividends, however, are set by the managers of
the firm and may be much lower than the potential
dividends (that could have been paid out)
 managers are conservative and try to smooth out dividends
 managers like to hold on to cash to meet unforeseen future
contingencies and investment opportunities
 When actual dividends are less than potential dividends,
using a model that focuses only on dividends will under
state the true value of the equity in a firm.

Aswath Damodaran
145
Measuring Potential Dividends
146

 Some analysts assume that the earnings of a firm represent its


potential dividends. This cannot be true for several reasons:
 Earnings are not cash flows, since there are both non-cash revenues and
expenses in the earnings calculation
 Even if earnings were cash flows, a firm that paid its earnings out as
dividends would not be investing in new assets and thus could not grow
 Valuation models, where earnings are discounted back to the present, will
over estimate the value of the equity in the firm
 The potential dividends of a firm are the cash flows left over after
the firm has made any “investments” it needs to make to create
future growth and net debt repayments (debt repayments - new
debt issues)
 The common categorization of capital expenditures into discretionary and
non-discretionary loses its basis when there is future growth built into the
valuation.

Aswath Damodaran
146
Estimating Cash Flows: FCFE
147

 Cash flows to Equity for a Levered Firm


Net Income
- (Capital Expenditures - Depreciation)
- Changes in non-cash Working Capital
- (Principal Repayments - New Debt Issues)
= Free Cash flow to Equity
 I have ignored preferred dividends. If preferred stock
exist, preferred dividends will also need to be netted
out

Aswath Damodaran
147
Estimating FCFE when Leverage is Stable
148

Net Income
- (1- DR) (Capital Expenditures - Depreciation)
- (1- DR) Working Capital Needs
= Free Cash flow to Equity
DR = Debt/Capital Ratio
For this firm,
 Proceeds from new debt issues = Principal Repayments +
(Capital Expenditures - Depreciation + Working Capital Needs)
 In computing FCFE, the book value debt to capital ratio
should be used when looking back in time but can be
replaced with the market value debt to capital ratio,
looking forward.
Aswath Damodaran
148
Estimating FCFE: Disney
149

 Net Income=$ 1533 Million


 Capital spending = $ 1,746 Million
 Depreciation per Share = $ 1,134 Million
 Increase in non-cash working capital = $ 477 Million
 Debt to Capital Ratio (DR) = 23.83%
 Estimating FCFE (1997):
Net Income $1,533 Mil
- (Cap. Exp - Depr)*(1-DR) $465.90 [(1746-1134)(1-.2383)]
Chg. Working Capital*(1-DR) $363.33 [477(1-.2383)]
= Free CF to Equity $ 704 Million

Dividends Paid $ 345 Million

Aswath Damodaran
149
FCFE and Leverage: Is this a free lunch?
150

Aswath Damodaran
150
FCFE and Leverage: The Other Shoe Drops
151

Aswath Damodaran
151
Leverage, FCFE and Value
152

 In a discounted cash flow model, increasing the debt/equity


ratio will generally increase the expected free cash flows to
equity investors over future time periods and also the cost of
equity applied in discounting these cash flows. Which of the
following statements relating leverage to value would you
subscribe to?
a. Increasing leverage will increase value because the cash flow effects
will dominate the discount rate effects
b. Increasing leverage will decrease value because the risk effect will be
greater than the cash flow effects
c. Increasing leverage will not affect value because the risk effect will
exactly offset the cash flow effect
d. Any of the above, depending upon what company you are looking at
and where it is in terms of current leverage

Aswath Damodaran
152
Aswath Damodaran 153

ESTIMATING GROWTH
Growth can be good, bad or neutral…
The Value of Growth
154

 When valuing a company, it is easy to get caught up in


the details of estimating growth and start viewing
growth as a “good”, i.e., that higher growth translates
into higher value.
 Growth, though, is a double-edged sword.
 The good side of growth is that it pushes up revenues and
operating income, perhaps at different rates (depending on how
margins evolve over time).
 The bad side of growth is that you have to set aside money to
reinvest to create that growth.
 The net effect of growth is whether the good outweighs the bad.

Aswath Damodaran
154
Ways of Estimating Growth in Earnings
155

 Look at the past


 The historical growth in earnings per share is usually a
good starting point for growth estimation
 Look at what others are estimating
 Analysts estimate growth in earnings per share for many
firms. It is useful to know what their estimates are.
 Look at fundamentals
 Ultimately, all growth in earnings can be traced to two
fundamentals - how much the firm is investing in new
projects, and what returns these projects are making for
the firm.

Aswath Damodaran
155
156 Growth I
Historical Growth

Aswath Damodaran
Historical Growth
157

 Historical growth rates can be estimated in a number of


different ways
 Arithmetic versus Geometric Averages
 Simple versus Regression Models
 Historical growth rates can be sensitive to
 The period used in the estimation (starting and ending points)
 The metric that the growth is estimated in..
 In using historical growth rates, you have to wrestle with
the following:
 How to deal with negative earnings
 The effects of scaling up

Aswath Damodaran
157
Motorola: Arithmetic versus Geometric Growth
Rates
158

Aswath Damodaran
158
A Test
159

 You are trying to estimate the growth rate in


earnings per share at Time Warner from 1996 to
1997. In 1996, the earnings per share was a deficit of
$0.05. In 1997, the expected earnings per share is $
0.25. What is the growth rate?
a. -600%
b. +600%
c. +120%
d. Cannot be estimated

Aswath Damodaran
159
Dealing with Negative Earnings
160

 When the earnings in the starting period are negative,


the growth rate cannot be estimated. (0.30/-0.05 = -
600%)
 There are three solutions:
 Use the higher of the two numbers as the denominator
(0.30/0.25 = 120%)
 Use the absolute value of earnings in the starting period as the
denominator (0.30/0.05=600%)
 Use a linear regression model and divide the coefficient by the
average earnings.
 When earnings are negative, the growth rate is
meaningless. Thus, while the growth rate can be
estimated, it does not tell you much about the future.

Aswath Damodaran
160
The Effect of Size on Growth: Callaway Golf
161

Year Net Profit Growth Rate


1990 1.80
1991 6.40 255.56%
1992 19.30 201.56%
1993 41.20 113.47%
1994 78.00 89.32%
1995 97.70 25.26%
1996 122.30 25.18%
 Geometric Average Growth Rate = 102%

Aswath Damodaran
161
Extrapolation and its Dangers
162

Year Net Profit


1996 $ 122.30
1997 $ 247.05
1998 $ 499.03
1999 $ 1,008.05
2000 $ 2,036.25
2001 $ 4,113.23
 If net profit continues to grow at the same rate as it has
in the past 6 years, the expected net income in 5 years
will be $ 4.113 billion.

Aswath Damodaran
162
163 Growth II
Analyst Estimates

Aswath Damodaran
Analyst Forecasts of Growth
164

 While the job of an analyst is to find under and over


valued stocks in the sectors that they follow, a significant
proportion of an analyst’s time (outside of selling) is
spent forecasting earnings per share.
 Most of this time, in turn, is spent forecasting earnings per share
in the next earnings report
 While many analysts forecast expected growth in earnings per
share over the next 5 years, the analysis and information
(generally) that goes into this estimate is far more limited.
 Analyst forecasts of earnings per share and expected
growth are widely disseminated by services such as
Zacks and IBES, at least for U.S companies.

Aswath Damodaran
164
How good are analysts at forecasting growth?
165

 Analysts forecasts of EPS tend to be closer to the actual EPS than


simple time series models, but the differences tend to be small
Study Group tested Analyst Time Series
Error Model Error
Collins & Hopwood Value Line Forecasts 31.7% 34.1%
Brown & Rozeff Value Line Forecasts 28.4% 32.2%
Fried & Givoly Earnings Forecaster 16.4% 19.8%
 The advantage that analysts have over time series models
 tends to decrease with the forecast period (next quarter versus 5 years)
 tends to be greater for larger firms than for smaller firms
 tends to be greater at the industry level than at the company level
 Forecasts of growth (and revisions thereof) tend to be highly
correlated across analysts.

Aswath Damodaran
165
Are some analysts more equal than others?
166

 A study of All-America Analysts (chosen by Institutional


Investor) found that
 There is no evidence that analysts who are chosen for the All-America
Analyst team were chosen because they were better forecasters of
earnings. (Their median forecast error in the quarter prior to being
chosen was 30%; the median forecast error of other analysts was 28%)
 However, in the calendar year following being chosen as All-America
analysts, these analysts become slightly better forecasters than their
less fortunate brethren. (The median forecast error for All-America
analysts is 2% lower than the median forecast error for other analysts)
 Earnings revisions made by All-America analysts tend to have a much
greater impact on the stock price than revisions from other analysts
 The recommendations made by the All America analysts have a
greater impact on stock prices (3% on buys; 4.7% on sells). For these
recommendations the price changes are sustained, and they continue
to rise in the following period (2.4% for buys; 13.8% for the sells).

Aswath Damodaran
166
The Five Deadly Sins of an Analyst
167

 Tunnel Vision: Becoming so focused on the sector and


valuations within the sector that you lose sight of the bigger
picture.
 Lemmingitis: Strong urge felt to change recommendations &
revise earnings estimates when other analysts do the same.
 Stockholm Syndrome: Refers to analysts who start identifying
with the managers of the firms that they are supposed to
follow.
 Factophobia (generally is coupled with delusions of being a
famous story teller): Tendency to base a recommendation on
a “story” coupled with a refusal to face the facts.
 Dr. Jekyll/Mr.Hyde: Analyst who thinks his primary job is to
bring in investment banking business to the firm.

Aswath Damodaran
167
Propositions about Analyst Growth Rates
168

 Proposition 1: There if far less private information and far more


public information in most analyst forecasts than is generally
claimed.
 Proposition 2: The biggest source of private information for
analysts remains the company itself which might explain
 why there are more buy recommendations than sell recommendations
(information bias and the need to preserve sources)
 why there is such a high correlation across analysts forecasts and revisions
 why All-America analysts become better forecasters than other analysts
after they are chosen to be part of the team.
 Proposition 3: There is value to knowing what analysts are
forecasting as earnings growth for a firm. There is, however, danger
when they agree too much (lemmingitis) and when they agree to
little (in which case the information that they have is so noisy as to
be useless).

Aswath Damodaran
168
169 Growth III
It’s all in the fundamentals

Aswath Damodaran
Fundamental Growth Rates
170

Aswath Damodaran
170
Growth Rate Derivations
171

Aswath Damodaran
171
Estimating Fundamental Growth from new
investments: Three variations
172

Earnings Measure Reinvestment Measure Return Measure


Earnings per share Retention Ratio = % of net Return on Equity = Net
income retained by the Income/ Book Value of
company = 1 – Payout Equity
ratio
Net Income from non-cash Equity reinvestment Rate = Non-cash ROE = Net
assets (Net Cap Ex + Change in Income from non-cash
non-cash WC – Change in assets/ (Book value of
Debt)/ (Net Income) equity – Cash)

Operating Income Reinvestment Rate = (Net Return on Capital or ROIC


Cap Ex + Change in non- = After-tax Operating
cash WC)/ After-tax Income/ (Book value of
Operating Income equity + Book value of
debt – Cash)

Aswath Damodaran
172
I. Expected Long Term Growth in EPS
173

 When looking at growth in earnings per share, these inputs


can be cast as follows:
 Reinvestment Rate = Retained Earnings/ Current Earnings = Retention
Ratio
 Return on Investment = ROE = Net Income/Book Value of Equity
 In the special case where the current ROE is expected to
remain unchanged
gEPS = Retained Earnings t-1/ NI t-1 * ROE
= Retention Ratio * ROE
= b * ROE
 Proposition 1: The expected growth rate in earnings for a
company cannot exceed its return on equity in the long term.
Aswath Damodaran
173
Estimating Expected Growth in EPS: Wells Fargo
in 2008
174

 Return on equity (based on 2008 earnings)= 17.56%


 Retention Ratio (based on 2008 earnings and
dividends) = 45.37%
 Expected growth rate in earnings per share for Wells
Fargo, if it can maintain these numbers.
Expected Growth Rate = 0.4537 (17.56%) = 7.97%

Aswath Damodaran
174
Regulatory Effects on Expected EPS growth
175

 Assume now that the banking crisis of 2008 will have


an impact on the capital ratios and profitability of
banks. In particular, you can expect that the book
capital (equity) needed by banks to do business will
increase 30%, starting now.
 Assuming that Wells continues with its existing
businesses, estimate the expected growth rate in
earnings per share for the future.
New Return on Equity =
Expected growth rate =

Aswath Damodaran
175
One way to pump up ROE: Use more debt
176

ROE = ROC + D/E (ROC - i (1-t))


where,
ROC = EBITt (1 - tax rate) / Book value of Capitalt-1
D/E = BV of Debt/ BV of Equity
i = Interest Expense on Debt / BV of Debt
t = Tax rate on ordinary income
 Note that Book value of capital = Book Value of Debt
+ Book value of Equity- Cash.

Aswath Damodaran
176
Decomposing ROE: Brahma in 1998
177

 Brahma (now Ambev) had an extremely high return


on equity, partly because it borrowed money at a
rate well below its return on capital
 Return on Capital = 19.91%
 Debt/Equity Ratio = 77%

 After-tax Cost of Debt = 5.61%

 Return on Equity = ROC + D/E (ROC - i(1-t))

= 19.91% + 0.77 (19.91% - 5.61%) = 30.92%


 This seems like an easy way to deliver higher growth
in earnings per share. What (if any) is the downside?
Aswath Damodaran
177
Decomposing ROE: Titan Watches (India)
in 2000
178

 Return on Capital = 9.54%


 Debt/Equity Ratio = 191% (book value terms)
 After-tax Cost of Debt = 10.125%
 Return on Equity = ROC + D/E (ROC - i(1-t))
= 9.54% + 1.91 (9.54% - 10.125%) = 8.42%

Aswath Damodaran
178
II. Expected Growth in Net Income from non-
cash assets
179

 The limitation of the EPS fundamental growth equation is that it


focuses on per share earnings and assumes that reinvested
earnings are invested in projects earning the return on equity. To
the extent that companies retain money in cash balances, the
effect on net income can be muted.
 A more general version of expected growth in earnings can be
obtained by substituting in the equity reinvestment into real
investments (net capital expenditures and working capital) and
modifying the return on equity definition to exclude cash:
 Net Income from non-cash assets = Net income – Interest income from
cash (1- t)
 Equity Reinvestment Rate = (Net Capital Expenditures + Change in Working
Capital) (1 - Debt Ratio)/ Net Income from non-cash assets
 Non-cash ROE = Net Income from non-cash assets/ (BV of Equity – Cash)
 Expected GrowthNet Income = Equity Reinvestment Rate * Non-cash ROE

Aswath Damodaran
179
Estimating expected growth in net income from
non-cash assets: Coca Cola in 2010
180

 In 2010, Coca Cola reported net income of $11,809 million. It had a


total book value of equity of $25,346 million at the end of 2009.
 Coca Cola had a cash balance of $7,021 million at the end of 2009,
on which it earned income of $105 million in 2010.
 Coca Cola had capital expenditures of $2,215 million, depreciation
of $1,443 million and reported an increase in working capital of
$335 million. Coca Cola’s total debt increased by $150 million
during 2010.
 Equity Reinvestment = 2215- 1443 + 335-150 = $957 million
 Non-cash Net Income = $11,809 - $105 = $ 11,704 million
 Non-cash book equity = $25,346 - $7021 = $18,325 million
 Reinvestment Rate = $957 million/ $11,704 million= 8.18%
 Non-cash ROE = $11,704 million/ $18,325 million = 63.87%
 Expected growth rate = 8.18% * 63.87% = 5.22%

Aswath Damodaran
180
III. Expected Growth in EBIT And Fundamentals:
Stable ROC and Reinvestment Rate
181

 When looking at growth in operating income, the


definitions are
 Reinvestment Rate = (Net Capital Expenditures + Change in
WC)/EBIT(1-t)
 Return on Investment = ROC = EBIT(1-t)/(BV of Debt + BV of
Equity-Cash)
 Reinvestment Rate and Return on Capital
Expected Growth rate in Operating Income
= (Net Capital Expenditures + Change in WC)/EBIT(1-t) * ROC
= Reinvestment Rate * ROC
 Proposition: The net capital expenditure needs of a firm,
for a given growth rate, should be inversely proportional
to the quality of its investments.
Aswath Damodaran
181
Estimating Growth in Operating Income, if
fundamentals stay unchanged
182

 Cisco’s Fundamentals
 Reinvestment Rate = 106.81%
 Return on Capital =34.07%
 Expected Growth in EBIT =(1.0681)(.3407) = 36.39%
 Motorola’s Fundamentals
 Reinvestment Rate = 52.99%
 Return on Capital = 12.18%
 Expected Growth in EBIT = (.5299)(.1218) = 6.45%
 Cisco’s expected growth rate is clearly much higher than Motorola’s sustainable
growth rate. As a potential investor in Cisco, what would worry you the most
about this forecast?
a. That Cisco’s return on capital may be overstated (why?)
b. That Cisco’s reinvestment comes mostly from acquisitions (why?)
c. That Cisco is getting bigger as a firm (why?)
d. That Cisco is viewed as a star (why?)
e. All of the above

Aswath Damodaran
182
The Magical Number: ROIC (or any
accounting return) and its limits
183

Aswath Damodaran
183
IV. Operating Income Growth when Return on
Capital is Changing
184

 When the return on capital is changing, there will be a


second component to growth, positive if the return on
capital is increasing and negative if the return on capital
is decreasing.
 If ROCt is the return on capital in period t and ROC t+1 is
the return on capital in period t+1, the expected growth
rate in operating income will be:
Expected Growth Rate = ROC t+1 * Reinvestment rate
+(ROC t+1 – ROCt) / ROCt
 If the change is over multiple periods, the second
component should be spread out over each period.
Aswath Damodaran
184
Motorola’s Growth Rate
185

 Motorola’s current return on capital is 12.18% and its reinvestment rate


is 52.99%.
 We expect Motorola’s return on capital to rise to 17.22% over the next 5
years (which is half way towards the industry average)
Expected Growth Rate
= ROC New Investments*Reinvestment Rate Current+ {[1+(ROC In 5 years-ROC Current)/ROC
1/5
Current] -1}
= .1722*.5299 +{ [1+(.1722-.1218)/.1218]1/5-1}
= .1629 or 16.29%
 One way to think about this is to decompose Motorola’s expected growth
into
Growth from new investments: .1722*5299= 9.12%
Growth from more efficiently using existing investments: 16.29%-9.12%= 7.17%

Note that I am assuming that the new investments start making 17.22%
immediately, while allowing for existing assets to improve returns
gradually

Aswath Damodaran
185
The Value of Growth
186

Expected growth = Growth from new investments + Efficiency growth


= Reinv Rate * ROC + (ROCt-ROCt-1)/ROCt-1
Assume that your cost of capital is 10%. As an investor, rank these
firms in the order of most value growth to least value growth.

Aswath Damodaran
186
187 Growth IV
Top Down Growth

Aswath Damodaran
Estimating Growth when Operating Income is
Negative or Margins are changing
188

 All of the fundamental growth equations assume that the firm has a
return on equity or return on capital it can sustain in the long term.
 When operating income is negative or margins are expected to change
over time, we use a three step process to estimate growth:
 Estimate growth rates in revenues over time
 Determine the total market (given your business model) and estimate the
market share that you think your company will earn.
 Decrease the growth rate as the firm becomes larger
 Keep track of absolute revenues to make sure that the growth is feasible
 Estimate expected operating margins each year
 Set a target margin that the firm will move towards
 Adjust the current margin towards the target margin
 Estimate the capital that needs to be invested to generate revenue growth and
expected margins
 Estimate a sales to capital ratio that you will use to generate reinvestment needs
each year.

Aswath Damodaran
188
Tesla in July 2015: Growth and Profitability
189

Aswath Damodaran
189
Tesla: Reinvestment and Profitability
190

Aswath Damodaran
190
Expected Growth Rate

Equity Earnings Operating Income

Analysts Fundamentals Historical Fundamentals Historical

Stable ROC Changing ROC Negative Earnings

ROCt+1*Reinvestment Rate
ROC *
Reinvestment Rate + (ROCt+1-ROCt)/ROCt

1. Revenue Growth
2. Operating Margins
Earnings per share Net Income 3. Reinvestment Needs

Stable ROE Changing ROE Stable ROE Changing ROE

ROEt+1*Retention Ratio ROEt+1*Eq. Reinv Ratio


ROE * Retention Ratio ROE * Equity
+ (ROEt+1-ROEt)/ROEt + (ROEt+1-ROEt)/ROEt
Reinvestment Ratio

191 Aswath Damodaran


Aswath Damodaran 192

CLOSURE IN VALUATION
The Big Enchilada
Getting Closure in Valuation
193

 A publicly traded firm potentially has an infinite life. The value is therefore
the present value of cash flows forever.

t=¥ CF
Value = å t
t
t=1 (1+r)

 Since we cannot estimate cash flows forever, we estimate cash flows for a
“growth period” and then estimate a terminal value, to capture the value
at the end of the period:

t=N CF
Value = å t + Terminal Value
t (1+r) N
t=1 (1+r)

Aswath Damodaran
193
Ways of Estimating Terminal Value
194

Aswath Damodaran
194
1. Obey the growth cap
195

 When a firm’s cash flows grow at a “constant” rate forever, the present
value of those cash flows can be written as:
Value = Expected Cash Flow Next Period / (r - g)
where,
r = Discount rate (Cost of Equity or Cost of Capital)
g = Expected growth rate
 The stable growth rate cannot exceed the growth rate of the economy but
it can be set lower.
• If you assume that the economy is composed of high growth and stable growth firms,
the growth rate of the latter will probably be lower than the growth rate of the
economy.
• The stable growth rate can be negative. The terminal value will be lower and you are
assuming that your firm will disappear over time.
• If you use nominal cashflows and discount rates, the growth rate should be nominal in
the currency in which the valuation is denominated.
 One simple proxy for the nominal growth rate of the economy is the
riskfree rate.

Aswath Damodaran
195
Risk free Rates and Nominal GDP Growth

 Risk free Rate = Expected Inflation +  Nominal GDP Growth = Expected Inflation
Expected Real Interest Rate + Expected Real Growth
 The real interest rate is what borrowers  The real growth rate in the economy
agree to return to lenders in real measures the expected growth in the
goods/services. production of goods and services.

The argument for Risk free rate = Nominal GDP growth


1. In the long term, the real growth rate cannot be lower than the real interest rate,
since the growth in goods/services has to be enough to cover the promised rate.
2. In the long term, the real growth rate can be higher than the real interest rate, to
compensate risk taking. However, as economies mature, the difference should get
smaller and since there will be growth companies in the economy, it is prudent to
assume that the extra growth comes from these companies.

10-Year T.Bond Nominal GDP Nominal GDP - T.Bond


Period Rate Inflation Rate Real GDP Growth growth rate Rate
1954-2015 5.93% 3.61% 3.06% 6.67% 0.74%
1954-1980 5.83% 4.49% 3.50% 7.98% 2.15%
1981-2008 6.88% 3.26% 3.04% 6.30% -0.58%
2009-2015 2.57% 1.66% 1.47% 3.14% 0.57%
A Practical Reason for using the Risk free
Rate Cap – Preserve Consistency
197

 You are implicitly making assumptions about nominal growth


in the economy, with your risk free rate. Thus, with a low risk
free rate, you are assuming low nominal growth in the
economy (with low inflation and low real growth) and with a
high risk free rate, a high nominal growth rate in the
economy.
 If you make an explicit assumption about nominal growth in
cash flows that is at odds with your implicit growth
assumption in the denominator, you are being inconsistent
and bias your valuations:
 If you assume high nominal growth in the economy, with a low risk
free rate, you will over value businesses.
 If you assume low nominal growth rate in the economy, with a high
risk free rate, you will under value businesses.

Aswath Damodaran
197
2. Don’t wait too long…
198

 Assume that you are valuing a young, high growth firm with
great potential, just after its initial public offering. How long
would you set your high growth period?
a. < 5 years
b. 5 years
c. 10 years
d. >10 years
 While analysts routinely assume very long high growth
periods (with substantial excess returns during the periods),
the evidence suggests that they are much too optimistic.
Most growth firms have difficulty sustaining their growth for
long periods, especially while earning excess returns.

Aswath Damodaran
198
And tie to competitive advantages
199

 Recapping a key lesson about growth, it is not


growth per se that creates value but growth with
excess returns. For growth firms to continue to
generate value creating growth, they have to be able
to keep the competition at bay.
 Proposition 1: The stronger and more sustainable
the competitive advantages, the longer a growth
company can sustain “value creating” growth.
 Proposition 2: Growth companies with strong and
sustainable competitive advantages are rare.

Aswath Damodaran
199
3. Don’t forget that growth has to be earned..
200

 In the section on expected growth, we laid out the fundamental


equation for growth:
Growth rate = Reinvestment Rate * Return on invested capital
+ Growth rate from improved efficiency
 In stable growth, you cannot count on efficiency delivering growth
and you have to reinvest to deliver the growth rate that you have
forecast.
 Consequently, your reinvestment rate in stable growth will be a
function of your stable growth rate and what you believe the firm
will earn as a return on capital in perpetuity:
 Reinvestment Rate = Stable growth rate/ Stable period ROC = g/ ROC
 Your terminal value equation can then be rewritten as:
g
EBITn+1 1−t (1−ROC)
Terminal Value in year n =
(Cost of Capital−g)

Aswath Damodaran
200
The Big Assumption
201

Return on capital in perpetuity


6% 8% 10% 12% 14%
0.0% $1,000 $1,000 $1,000 $1,000 $1,000
Growth rate forever

0.5% $965 $987 $1,000 $1,009 $1,015


1.0% $926 $972 $1,000 $1,019 $1,032
1.5% $882 $956 $1,000 $1,029 $1,050
2.0% $833 $938 $1,000 $1,042 $1,071
2.5% $778 $917 $1,000 $1,056 $1,095
3.0% $714 $893 $1,000 $1,071 $1,122

Terminal value for a firm with expected after-tax operating income of


$100 million in year n+1 and a cost of capital of 10%.

Aswath Damodaran
201
Excess Returns to Zero?
202

 There are some (McKinsey, for instance) who argue that the return on
capital should always be equal to cost of capital in stable growth.
 But excess returns seem to persist for very long time periods.

Aswath Damodaran
202
And don’t fall for sleight of hand…
203

 A typical assumption in many DCF valuations, when it


comes to stable growth, is that capital expenditures
offset depreciation and there are no working capital
needs. Stable growth firms, we are told, just have to
make maintenance cap ex (replacing existing assets ) to
deliver growth. If you make this assumption, what
expected growth rate can you use in your terminal value
computation?

 What if the stable growth rate = inflation rate? Is it okay


to make this assumption then?

Aswath Damodaran
203
4. Be internally consistent
204

 Risk and costs of equity and capital: Stable growth firms tend
to
 Have betas closer to one
 Have debt ratios closer to industry averages (or mature company
averages)
 Country risk premiums (especially in emerging markets should evolve
over time)
 The excess returns at stable growth firms should approach (or
become) zero. ROC -> Cost of capital and ROE -> Cost of
equity
 The reinvestment needs and dividend payout ratios should
reflect the lower growth and excess returns:
 Stable period payout ratio = 1 - g/ ROE
 Stable period reinvestment rate = g/ ROC

Aswath Damodaran
204
Aswath Damodaran 205

BEYOND INPUTS: CHOOSING AND


USING THE RIGHT MODEL
Choosing the right model
Summarizing the Inputs
206

 In summary, at this stage in the process, we should have


an estimate of the
 the current cash flows on the investment, either to equity
investors (dividends or free cash flows to equity) or to the firm
(cash flow to the firm)
 the current cost of equity and/or capital on the investment
 the expected growth rate in earnings, based upon historical
growth, analysts forecasts and/or fundamentals
 The next step in the process is deciding
 which cash flow to discount, which should indicate
 which discount rate needs to be estimated and
 what pattern we will assume growth to follow

Aswath Damodaran
206
Which cash flow should I discount?
207

 Use Equity Valuation


(a) for firms which have stable leverage, whether high or not, and
(b) if equity (stock) is being valued
 Use Firm Valuation
(a) for firms which have leverage which is too high or too low, and
expect to change the leverage over time, because debt payments
and issues do not have to be factored in the cash flows and the
discount rate (cost of capital) does not change dramatically over
time.
(b) for firms for which you have partial information on leverage
(eg: interest expenses are missing..)
(c) in all other cases, where you are more interested in valuing the
firm than the equity. (Value Consulting?)

Aswath Damodaran
207
Given cash flows to equity, should I discount
dividends or FCFE?
208

 Use the Dividend Discount Model


(a) For firms which pay dividends (and repurchase stock) which are
close to the Free Cash Flow to Equity (over a extended period)
(b)For firms where FCFE are difficult to estimate (Example: Banks
and Financial Service companies)
 Use the FCFE Model
(a) For firms which pay dividends which are significantly higher or
lower than the Free Cash Flow to Equity. (What is significant? ... As
a rule of thumb, if dividends are less than 80% of FCFE or dividends
are greater than 110% of FCFE over a 5-year period, use the FCFE
model)
(b) For firms where dividends are not available (Example: Private
Companies, IPOs)

Aswath Damodaran
208
What discount rate should I use?
209

 Cost of Equity versus Cost of Capital


 If discounting cash flows to equity -> Cost of Equity
 If discounting cash flows to the firm -> Cost of Capital
 What currency should the discount rate (risk free rate)
be in?
 Match the currency in which you estimate the risk free rate to
the currency of your cash flows
 Should I use real or nominal cash flows?
 If discounting real cash flows -> real cost of capital
 If nominal cash flows -> nominal cost of capital
 If inflation is low (<10%), stick with nominal cash flows since
taxes are based upon nominal income
 If inflation is high (>10%) switch to real cash flows
Aswath Damodaran
209
Which Growth Pattern Should I use?
210

 If your firm is
 large and growing at a rate close to or less than growth rate of the economy, or
 constrained by regulation from growing at rate faster than the economy
 has the characteristics of a stable firm (average risk & reinvestment rates)
Use a Stable Growth Model
 If your firm
 is large & growing at a moderate rate (≤ Overall growth rate + 10%) or
 has a single product & barriers to entry with a finite life (e.g. patents)
Use a 2-Stage Growth Model
 If your firm
 is small and growing at a very high rate (> Overall growth rate + 10%) or
 has significant barriers to entry into the business
 has firm characteristics that are very different from the norm
Use a 3-Stage or n-stage Model

Aswath Damodaran
210
The Building Blocks of Valuation
211

Aswath Damodaran
211
Aswath Damodaran 212

TYING UP LOOSE ENDS


The trouble starts after you tell me you are done..
But what comes next?
213

Aswath Damodaran
213
1. The Value of Cash
214

 The simplest and most direct way of dealing with cash and
marketable securities is to keep it out of the valuation - the
cash flows should be before interest income from cash and
securities, and the discount rate should not be contaminated
by the inclusion of cash. (Use betas of the operating assets
alone to estimate the cost of equity).
 Once the operating assets have been valued, you should add
back the value of cash and marketable securities.
 In many equity valuations, the interest income from cash is
included in the cashflows. The discount rate has to be
adjusted then for the presence of cash. (The beta used will be
weighted down by the cash holdings). Unless cash remains a
fixed percentage of overall value over time, these valuations
will tend to break down.

Aswath Damodaran
214
An Exercise in Cash Valuation
215

Company A Company B Company C

Enterprise Value $1,000.0 $1,000.0 $1,000.0

Cash $100.0 $100.0 $100.0

Return on invested capital 10% 5% 22%

Cost of capital 10% 10% 12%

Trades in US US Argentina
In which of these companies is cash most likely to be
a) A Neutral Asset (worth $100 million)
b) A Wasting Asset (worth less than $100 million)
c) A Potential Value Creator (worth >$100 million)
Aswath Damodaran
215
Should you ever discount cash for its low
returns?
216

 There are some analysts who argue that companies with a lot of
cash on their balance sheets should be penalized by having the
excess cash discounted to reflect the fact that it earns a low return.
 Excess cash is usually defined as holding cash that is greater than what the
firm needs for operations.
 A low return is defined as a return lower than what the firm earns on its
non-cash investments.
 This is the wrong reason for discounting cash. If the cash is invested
in riskless securities, it should earn a low rate of return. As long as
the return is high enough, given the riskless nature of the
investment, cash does not destroy value.
 There is a right reason, though, that may apply to some
companies… Managers can do stupid things with cash (overpriced
acquisitions, pie-in-the-sky projects….) and you have to discount for
this possibility.

Aswath Damodaran
216
Cash: Discount or Premium?
217

Aswath Damodaran
217
A Detour: Closed End Mutual Funds
218

 Assume that you have


a closed-end fund that
invests in ‘average
risk” stocks. Assume
also that you expect
the market (average
risk investments) to
make 11.5% annually
over the long term. If
the closed end fund
underperforms the
market by 0.50%,
estimate the discount
on the fund.

Aswath Damodaran
Aswath Damodaran ‹#›
2. Dealing with Holdings in Other firms
220

 Holdings in other firms can be categorized into


 Minority passive holdings, in which case only the dividend
from the holdings is shown in the balance sheet
 Minority active holdings, in which case the share of equity
income is shown in the income statements
 Majority active holdings, in which case the financial
statements are consolidated.

Aswath Damodaran
220
An Exercise in Valuing Cross Holdings
221

 Assume that you have valued Company A using consolidated


financials for $ 1 billion (using FCFF and cost of capital) and that the
firm has $ 200 million in debt. How much is the equity in Company
A worth?

 Now assume that you are told that Company A owns 10% of
Company B and that the holdings are accounted for as passive
holdings. If the market cap of company B is $ 500 million, how
much is the equity in Company A worth?

 Now add on the assumption that Company A owns 60% of


Company C and that the holdings are fully consolidated. The
minority interest in company C is recorded at $ 40 million in
Company A’s balance sheet. How much is the equity in Company A
worth?
Aswath Damodaran
221
More on Cross Holding Valuation
222

 Building on the previous example, assume that


 You have valued equity in company B at $ 250 million
(which is half the market’s estimate of value currently)
 Company A is a steel company and that company C is a
chemical company. Furthermore, assume that you have
valued the equity in company C at $250 million.
 Estimate the value of equity in company A.

Aswath Damodaran
222
If you really want to value cross holdings right….
223

 Step 1: Value the parent company without any cross


holdings. This will require using unconsolidated financial
statements rather than consolidated ones.
 Step 2: Value each of the cross holdings individually. (If
you use the market values of the cross holdings, you will
build in errors the market makes in valuing them into
your valuation.
 Step 3: The final value of the equity in the parent
company with N cross holdings will be:
 Value of un-consolidated parent company
 – Debt of un-consolidated parent company
 + j= N
å% owned of Company j * (Value of Company j - Debt of Company j)
j=1

Aswath Damodaran
223
Valuing Yahoo as the sum of its intrinsic
pieces
224

Aswath Damodaran
224
If you have to settle for an approximation, try this…
225

 For majority holdings, with full consolidation, convert the


minority interest from book value to market value by applying
a price to book ratio (based upon the sector average for the
subsidiary) to the minority interest.
 Estimated market value of minority interest = Minority interest on
balance sheet * Price to Book ratio for sector (of subsidiary)
 Subtract this from the estimated value of the consolidated firm to get
to value of the equity in the parent company.
 For minority holdings in other companies, convert the book
value of these holdings (which are reported on the balance
sheet) into market value by multiplying by the price to book
ratio of the sector(s). Add this value on to the value of the
operating assets to arrive at total firm value.

Aswath Damodaran
225
Yahoo: A pricing game?
226

Aswath Damodaran
226
3. Other Assets that have not been counted
yet..
227

 Assets that you should not be counting (or adding on to DCF values)
 If an asset is contributing to your cashflows, you cannot count the market value of
the asset in your value. Thus, you should not be counting the real estate on which
your offices stand, the PP&E representing your factories and other productive
assets, any values attached to brand names or customer lists and definitely no non-
assets (such as goodwill).
 Assets that you can count (or add on to your DCF valuation)
 Overfunded pension plans: If you have a defined benefit plan and your assets
exceed your expected liabilities, you could consider the over funding with two
caveats:
 Collective bargaining agreements may prevent you from laying claim to these
excess assets.
 There are tax consequences. Often, withdrawals from pension plans get taxed at
much higher rates.
 Unutilized assets: If you have assets or property that are not being utilized to
generate cash flows (vacant land, for example), you have not valued them yet. You
can assess a market value for these assets and add them on to the value of the
firm.

Aswath Damodaran
227
An Uncounted Asset?
228

Price tag: $200 million

Aswath Damodaran
228
4. A Discount for Complexity:
An Experiment
229

Company A Company B
Operating Income $ 1 billion $ 1 billion
Tax rate 40% 40%
ROIC 10% 10%
Expected Growth 5% 5%
Cost of capital 8% 8%
Business Mix Single Multiple
Holdings Simple Complex
Accounting Transparent Opaque
Which firm would you value more highly?
Aswath Damodaran
229
Measuring Complexity: Volume of Data in
Financial Statements
230

Company Number of pages in last 10Q Number of pages in last 10K


General Electric 65 410
Microsoft 63 218
Wal-mart 38 244
Exxon Mobil 86 332
Pfizer 171 460
Citigroup 252 1026
Intel 69 215
AIG 164 720
Johnson & Johnson 63 218
IBM 85 353

Aswath Damodaran
230
Measuring Complexity: A Complexity Score
231

Aswath Damodaran
231
Dealing with Complexity
232

 In Discounted Cashflow Valuation


 The Aggressive Analyst: Trust the firm to tell the truth and value the firm
based upon the firm’s statements about their value.
 The Conservative Analyst: Don’t value what you cannot see.
 The Compromise: Adjust the value for complexity
 Adjust cash flows for complexity
 Adjust the discount rate for complexity
 Adjust the expected growth rate/ length of growth period
 Value the firm and then discount value for complexity
 In relative valuation
 In a relative valuation, you may be able to assess the price that the market
is charging for complexity:
 With the hundred largest market cap firms, for instance:
PBV = 0.65 + 15.31 ROE – 0.55 Beta + 3.04 Expected growth rate – 0.003 #
Pages in 10K

Aswath Damodaran
232
5. Be circumspect about defining debt for cost of
capital purposes…
233

 General Rule: Debt generally has the following characteristics:


 Commitment to make fixed payments in the future
 The fixed payments are tax deductible
 Failure to make the payments can lead to either default or loss of
control of the firm to the party to whom payments are due.
 Defined as such, debt should include
 All interest bearing liabilities, short term as well as long term
 All leases, operating as well as capital
 Debt should not include
 Accounts payable or supplier credit
 Be wary of your conservative impulses which will tell you to
count everything as debt. That will push up the debt ratio and
lead you to understate your cost of capital.

Aswath Damodaran
233
Book Value or Market Value
234

 You are valuing a distressed telecom company and have


arrived at an estimate of $ 1 billion for the enterprise value
(using a discounted cash flow valuation). The company has $
1 billion in face value of debt outstanding but the debt is
trading at 50% of face value (because of the distress). What is
the value of the equity to you as an investor?
a. The equity is worth nothing (EV minus Face Value of Debt)
b. The equity is worth $ 500 million (EV minus Market Value of Debt)

 Would your answer be different if you were told that the


liquidation value of the assets of the firm today is $1.2 billion
and that you were planning to liquidate the firm today?

Aswath Damodaran
234
But you should consider other potential
liabilities when getting to equity value
235

 If you have under funded pension fund or health care


plans, you should consider the under funding at this
stage in getting to the value of equity.
 If you do so, you should not double count by also including a
cash flow line item reflecting cash you would need to set aside
to meet the unfunded obligation.
 You should not be counting these items as debt in your cost of
capital calculations….
 If you have contingent liabilities - for example, a
potential liability from a lawsuit that has not been
decided - you should consider the expected value of
these contingent liabilities
 Value of contingent liability = Probability that the liability will
occur * Expected value of liability

Aswath Damodaran
235
6. Equity to Employees: Effect on Value

 In recent years, firms have turned to giving employees (and


especially top managers) equity option or restricted stock
packages as part of compensation. If they are options, they
usually are long term and on volatile stocks. If restricted
stock, the restrictions are usually on trading.
 These equity compensation packages are clearly valuable and
the question becomes how best to deal with them in
valuation.
 Two key issues with employee options:
 How do options or restricted stock granted in the past affect equity
value per share today?
 How do expected grants of either in the future affect equity value
today?

236
The Easier Problem: Restricted Stock Grants
237
Aswath
Damodaran

 When employee compensation takes the form of


restricted stock grants, the solution is relatively simple.
 To account for restricted stock grants in the past, make
sure that you count the restricted stock that have
already been granted in shares outstanding today. That
will reduce your value per share.
 To account for expected stock grants in the future,
estimate the value of these grants as a percent of
revenue and forecast that as expense as part of
compensation expenses. That will reduce future income
and cash flows.

237
The Bigger Challenge: Employee Options
238

 It is true that options can increase the number of shares


outstanding but dilution per se is not the problem.
 Options affect equity value at exercise because
 Shares are issued at below the prevailing market price. Options
get exercised only when they are in the money.
 Alternatively, the company can use cashflows that would have
been available to equity investors to buy back shares which are
then used to meet option exercise. The lower cashflows reduce
equity value.
 Options affect equity value before exercise because we
have to build in the expectation that there is a
probability of and a cost to exercise.
Aswath Damodaran
238
A simple example…
239

 XYZ company has $ 100 million in free cashflows to the firm, growing 3% a
year in perpetuity and a cost of capital of 8%. It has 100 million shares
outstanding and $ 1 billion in debt. Its value can be written as follows:
Value of firm = 100 / (.08-.03) = 2000
Debt = 1000
= Equity = 1000
Value per share = 1000/100 = $10
 XYZ decides to give 10 million options at the money (with a strike price of
$10) to its CEO. What effect will this have on the value of equity per
share?
a. None. The options are not in-the-money.
b. Decrease by 10%, since the number of shares could increase by 10 million
c. Decrease by less than 10%. The options will bring in cash into the firm but they
have time value.

Aswath Damodaran
239
I. The Diluted Share Count Approach
240

 The simplest way of dealing with options is to try to


adjust the denominator for shares that will become
outstanding if the options get exercised. In the example
cited, this would imply the following:
Value of firm = 100 / (.08-.03) = 2000
Debt = 1000
= Equity = 1000
Number of diluted shares = 110
Value per share = 1000/110 = $9.09
 The diluted approach fails to consider that exercising
options will bring in cash into the firm. Consequently,
they will overestimate the impact of options and
understate the value of equity per share.
Aswath Damodaran
240
II. The Treasury Stock Approach
241

 The treasury stock approach adds the proceeds from the exercise of
options to the value of the equity before dividing by the diluted number
of shares outstanding.
 In the example cited, this would imply the following:
Value of firm = 100 / (.08-.03) = 2000
Debt = 1000
= Equity = 1000
Number of diluted shares = 110
Proceeds from option exercise = 10 * 10 = 100
Value per share = (1000+ 100)/110 = $ 10
 The treasury stock approach fails to consider the time premium on the
options. The treasury stock approach also has problems with out-of-the-
money options. If considered, they can increase the value of equity per
share. If ignored, they are treated as non-existent.

Aswath Damodaran
241
III. Option Value Drag
242

 Step 1: Value the firm, using discounted cash flow or other


valuation models.
 Step 2: Subtract out the value of the outstanding debt to arrive at
the value of equity. Alternatively, skip step 1 and estimate the of
equity directly.
 Step 3:Subtract out the market value (or estimated market value)
of other equity claims:
 Value of Warrants = Market Price per Warrant * Number of Warrants
: Alternatively estimate the value using option pricing model
 Value of Conversion Option = Market Value of Convertible Bonds - Value of
Straight Debt Portion of Convertible Bonds
 Value of employee Options: Value using the average exercise price and
maturity.
 Step 4:Divide the remaining value of equity by the number of
shares outstanding to get value per share.

Aswath Damodaran
242
Valuing Equity Options issued by firms… The Dilution
Problem
243

 Option pricing models can be used to value employee options


with four caveats –
 Employee options are long term, making the assumptions about
constant variance and constant dividend yields much shakier,
 Employee options result in stock dilution, and
 Employee options are often exercised before expiration, making it
dangerous to use European option pricing models.
 Employee options cannot be exercised until the employee is vested.
 These problems can be partially alleviated by using an option
pricing model, allowing for shifts in variance and early
exercise, and factoring in the dilution effect. The resulting
value can be adjusted for the probability that the employee
will not be vested.
Aswath Damodaran
243
Valuing Employee Options
244

 To value employee options, you need the following


inputs into the option valuation model:
 Stock Price = $ 10, Adjusted for dilution = $9.58
 Strike Price = $ 10
 Maturity = 10 years (Can reduce to reflect early exercise)
 Standard deviation in stock price = 40%
 Riskless Rate = 4%
 Using a dilution-adjusted Black Scholes model, we arrive
at the following inputs:
 N (d1) = 0.8199
 N (d2) = 0.3624
 Value per call = $ 9.58 (0.8199) - $10 e -(0.04) (10)(0.3624) = $5.42

Aswath Damodaran
244
Value of Equity to Value of Equity per share
245

 Using the value per call of $5.42, we can now estimate the
value of equity per share after the option grant:
Value of firm = 100 / (.08-.03) = 2000
Debt = 1000
= Equity = 1000
Value of options granted = $ 54.2
= Value of Equity in stock = $945.8
/ Number of shares outstanding / 100
= Value per share = $ 9.46
 Note that this approach yields a higher value than the
diluted share count approach (which ignores exercise
proceeds) and a lower value than the treasury stock
approach (which ignores the time premium on the options)

Aswath Damodaran
245
To tax adjust or not to tax adjust…
246

 In the example above, we have assumed that the


options do not provide any tax advantages. To the
extent that the exercise of the options creates tax
advantages, the actual cost of the options will be
lower by the tax savings.
 One simple adjustment is to multiply the value of
the options by (1- tax rate) to get an after-tax option
cost.

Aswath Damodaran
246
Option grants in the future…
247

 Assume now that this firm intends to continue granting


options each year to its top management as part of
compensation. These expected option grants will also
affect value.
 The simplest mechanism for bringing in future option
grants into the analysis is to do the following:
 Estimate the value of options granted each year over the last
few years as a percent of revenues.
 Forecast out the value of option grants as a percent of revenues
into future years, allowing for the fact that as revenues get
larger, option grants as a percent of revenues will become
smaller.
 Consider this line item as part of operating expenses each year.
This will reduce the operating margin and cashflow each year.
Aswath Damodaran
247
When options affect equity value per share the
most…
248

 Option grants affect value more


 The lower the strike price is set relative to the stock price
 The longer the term to maturity of the option

 The more volatile the stock price

 The effect on value will be magnified if companies


are allowed to revisit option grants and reset the
exercise price if the stock price moves down.

Aswath Damodaran
248
NARRATIVE AND NUMBERS:
VALUATION AS A BRIDGE
Tell me a story..
Valuation as a bridge

Number Crunchers Story Tellers


Favored Tools Favored Tools
- Accounting statements - Anecdotes
- Excel spreadsheets - Experience (own or others)
- Statistical Measures - Behavioral evidence
- Pricing Data
A Good Valuation

The Numbers People The Narrative People

Illusions/Delusions
Illusions/Delusions
1. Creativity cannot be quantifie d
1. Precision: Data is precise
2. If the story is good, the
2. Objectivity: Data has no bias
investment will be.
3. Control: Data can control reality
3. Experience is the best teacher

250
Step 1: Survey the landscape

 Every valuation starts with a narrative, a story that


you see unfolding for your company in the future.
 In developing this narrative, you will be making
assessments of
 Your company (its products, its management and its
history.
 The market or markets that you see it growing in.

 The competition it faces and will face.

 The macro environment in which it operates.

251
Step 2: Create a narrative for the future

 Every valuation starts with a narrative, a story that


you see unfolding for your company in the future.
 In developing this narrative, you will be making
assessments of your company (its products, its
management), the market or markets that you see it
growing in, the competition it faces and will face and
the macro environment in which it operates.
 Rule 1: Keep it simple.
 Rule 2: Keep it focused.

 Rule 3: Stay grounded in reality.

253
The Uber Narrative

In June 2014, my initial narrative for Uber was that it would be


1. An urban car service business: I saw Uber primarily as a
force in urban areas and only in the car service business.
2. Which would expand the business moderately (about 40%
over ten years) by bringing in new users.
3. With local networking benefits: If Uber becomes large
enough in any city, it will quickly become larger, but that will
be of little help when it enters a new city.
4. Maintain its revenue sharing (20%) system due to strong
competitive advantages (from being a first mover).
5. And its existing low-capital business model, with drivers as
contractors and very little investment in infrastructure.

254
Step 3: Check the narrative against history,
economic first principles & common sense
255

Aswath Damodaran
255
The Impossible, The Implausible and the
Improbable
256

Aswath Damodaran
256
Uber: Possible, Plausible and Probable

257
The Impossible: The Runaway Story
The Story The Checks (?)

+ +
+ Money
The Implausible: The Big Market Delusion
The Improbable: Willy Wonkitis
Step 4: Connect your narrative to key
drivers of value

261
Step 4: Value the company (Uber)
262

Aswath Damodaran
262
Step 5: Keep the feedback loop
263

1. Not just car service company.: Uber is a car company,


not just a car service company, and there may be a day
when consumers will subscribe to a Uber service,
rather than own their own cars. It could also expand
into logistics, i.e., moving and transportation
businesses.
2. Not just urban: Uber can create new demands for car
service in parts of the country where taxis are not used
(suburbia, small towns).
3. Global networking benefits: By linking with technology
and credit card companies, Uber can have global
networking benefits.

Aswath Damodaran
263
Valuing Bill Gurley’s Uber narrative

264
Different narratives, Different Numbers

265
Step 6: Be ready to modify narrative as
events unfold
266

Narrative Break/End Narrative Shift Narrative Change


(Expansion or Contraction)
Events, external (legal, Improvement or Unexpected entry/success
political or economic) or deterioration in initial in a new market or
internal (management, business model, changing unexpected exit/failure in
competitive, default), that market size, market share an existing market.
can cause the narrative to and/or profitability.
break or end.
Your valuation estimates Your valuation estimates Valuation estimates have
(cash flows, risk, growth & will have to be modified to to be redone with new
value) are no longer reflect the new data about overall market potential
operative the company. and characteristics.
Estimate a probability that Monte Carlo simulations or Real Options
it will occur & scenario analysis
consequences

Aswath Damodaran
266
Aswath Damodaran 267

Let the games begin… Time to


value companies..
Let’s have some fun!
Equity Risk Premiums in Valuation
268

 The equity risk premiums that I have used in the valuations that follow
reflect my thinking (and how it has evolved) on the issue.
 Pre-1998 valuations: In the valuations prior to 1998, I use a risk premium of 5.5%
for mature markets (close to both the historical and the implied premiums then)
 Between 1998 and Sept 2008: In the valuations between 1998 and September
2008, I used a risk premium of 4% for mature markets, reflecting my belief that risk
premiums in mature markets do not change much and revert back to historical
norms (at least for implied premiums).
 Valuations done in 2009: After the 2008 crisis and the jump in equity risk premiums
to 6.43% in January 2008, I have used a higher equity risk premium (5-6%) for the
next 5 years and will assume a reversion back to historical norms (4%) only after
year 5.
 After 2009: In 2010, I reverted back to a mature market premium of 4.5%,
reflecting the drop in equity risk premiums during 2009. In 2011, I used 5%,
reflecting again the change in implied premium over the year. In 2012 and 2013,
stayed with 6%, reverted to 5% in 2014 and will be using 5.75% in 2015.

Aswath Damodaran
268
The Valuation Set up
269

 With each company that I value in this next section, I


will try to start with a story about the company and
use that story to construct a valuation.
 With each valuation, rather than focus on all of the
details (which will follow the blueprint already laid
out), I will focus on a specific component of the
valuation that is unique or different.

Aswath Damodaran
269
270 Training Wheels On?
Stocks that look like Bonds, Things Change and
Market Valuations

Aswath Damodaran
271
A break even growth rate to get to market price…
272

Con Ed: Value versus Growth Rate


$80.00

$70.00

$60.00

Break even point: Value = Price


$50.00
Value per share

$40.00

$30.00

$20.00

$10.00

$0.00
4.10% 3.10% 2.10% 1.10% 0.10% -0.90% -1.90% -2.90% -3.90%
Expected Growth rate

Aswath Damodaran
272
From DCF value to target price and returns…
273

 Assume that you believe that your valuation of Con Ed


($42.30) is a fair estimate of the value, 7.70% is a
reasonable estimate of Con Ed’s cost of equity and that
your expected dividends for next year (2.32*1.021) is a
fair estimate, what is the expected stock price a year
from now (assuming that the market corrects its
mistake?)

 If you bought the stock today at $40.76, what return can


you expect to make over the next year (assuming again
that the market corrects its mistake)?

Aswath Damodaran
273
274 Aswath Damodaran
275 Aswath Damodaran
276
277
278 Aswath Damodaran
279 The Dark Side of Valuation
Anyone can value a company that is stable,
makes money and has an established
business model!

Aswath Damodaran
The fundamental determinants of value…
280

Aswath Damodaran
280
The Dark Side of Valuation…
281

 Valuing stable, money making companies with


consistent and clear accounting statements, a long and
stable history and lots of comparable firms is easy to do.
 The true test of your valuation skills is when you have to
value “difficult” companies. In particular, the challenges
are greatest when valuing:
 Young companies, early in the life cycle, in young businesses
 Companies that don’t fit the accounting mold
 Companies that face substantial truncation risk (default or
nationalization risk)

Aswath Damodaran
281
Difficult to value companies…
282

 Across the life cycle:


 Young, growth firms: Limited history, small revenues in conjunction with big operating losses
and a propensity for failure make these companies tough to value.
 Mature companies in transition: When mature companies change or are forced to change,
history may have to be abandoned and parameters have to be reestimated.
 Declining and Distressed firms: A long but irrelevant history, declining markets, high debt loads
and the likelihood of distress make them troublesome.
 Across markets
 Emerging market companies are often difficult to value because of the way they are
structured, their exposure to country risk and poor corporate governance.
 Across sectors
 Financial service firms: Opacity of financial statements and difficulties in estimating basic
inputs leave us trusting managers to tell us what’s going on.
 Commodity and cyclical firms: Dependence of the underlying commodity prices or overall
economic growth make these valuations susceptible to macro factors.
 Firms with intangible assets: Accounting principles are left to the wayside on these firms.

Aswath Damodaran
282
I. The challenge with young companies…
283

Aswath Damodaran
283
Upping the ante.. Young companies in young
businesses…
284

 When valuing a business, we generally draw on three sources of information


 The firm’s current financial statement
 How much did the firm sell?
 How much did it earn?
 The firm’s financial history, usually summarized in its financial statements.
 How fast have the firm’s revenues and earnings grown over time?
 What can we learn about cost structure and profitability from these trends?
 Susceptibility to macro-economic factors (recessions and cyclical firms)
 The industry and comparable firm data
 What happens to firms as they mature? (Margins.. Revenue growth… Reinvestment
needs… Risk)
 It is when valuing these companies that you find yourself tempted by the dark
side, where
 “Paradigm shifts” happen…
 New metrics are invented …
 The story dominates and the numbers lag…

Aswath Damodaran
284
285 Aswath Damodaran
Lesson 1: Don’t sweat the small stuff

 Spotlight the business the


company is in & use the beta of
that business.
 Don’t try to incorporate failure
risk into the discount rate.
 Let the cost of capital change
over time, as the company
changes.
 If you are desperate, use the
cross section of costs of capital
to get your estimation going
(use the 90th or 95th percentile
across all companies).
Lesson 2: Work backwards and keep it simple…

287
Lesson 3: Scaling up is hard to do & failure
is common
 Lower revenue growth
rates, as revenues
scale up.
 Keep track of dollar
revenues, as you go
through time,
measuring against
market size.
Lesson 4: Don’t forget to pay for growth…

289
Lesson 5: The dilution is taken care off..

 With young growth companies, it is almost a given that the number


of shares outstanding will increase over time for two reasons:
 To grow, the company will have to issue new shares either to raise cash to
take projects or to offer to target company stockholders in acquisitions
 Many young, growth companies also offer options to managers as
compensation and these options will get exercised, if the company is
successful.
 In DCF valuation, both effects are already incorporated into the
value per share, even though we use the current number of shares
in estimating value per share
 The need for new equity issues is captured in negative cash flows in the
earlier years. The present value of these negative cash flows will drag
down the current value of equity and this is the effect of future dilution.
 The options are valued and netted out against the current value. Using an
option pricing model allows you to incorporate the expected likelihood
that they will be exercised and the price at which they will be exercised.

290
Lesson 6: If you are worried about failure,
incorporate into value

291
Lesson 7: There are always scenarios
where the market price can be justified…

292
Lesson 8: You will be wrong 100% of the
tim and it really is not your fault…
 No matter how careful you are in getting your inputs and
how well structured your model is, your estimate of
value will change both as new information comes out
about the company, the business and the economy.
 As information comes out, you will have to adjust and
adapt your model to reflect the information. Rather than
be defensive about the resulting changes in value,
recognize that this is the essence of risk.
 A test: If your valuations are unbiased, you should find
yourself increasing estimated values as often as you are
decreasing values. In other words, there should be equal
doses of good and bad news affecting valuations (at least
over time).

293
And the market is often “more wrong”….

Amazon: Value and Price

$90.00

$80.00

$70.00

$60.00

$50.00

Value per share


$40.00 Price per share

$30.00

$20.00

$10.00

$0.00
2000 2001 2002 2003
Time of analysis

294
Assessing my 2000 forecasts, in 2014
295

Aswath Damodaran
295
Amazon: My “Field of Dreams” Valuation – October 2014

296 Aswath Damodaran


Amazon: World Dominator in October 2014

297 Aswath Damodaran


Amazon: Bezos, the Change-maker

298 Aswath Damodaran


II. Mature Companies in transition..
299

 Mature companies are generally the easiest group to


value. They have long, established histories that can be
mined for inputs. They have investment policies that are
set and capital structures that are stable, thus making
valuation more grounded in past data.
 However, this stability in the numbers can mask real
problems at the company. The company may be set in a
process, where it invests more or less than it should and
does not have the right financing mix. In effect, the
policies are consistent, stable and bad.
 If you expect these companies to change or as is more
often the case to have change thrust upon them,

Aswath Damodaran
299
The perils of valuing mature companies…
300

Aswath Damodaran
300
301 Aswath Damodaran
Lesson 1: Cost cutting and increased efficiency are easier
accomplished on paper than in practice… and require
commitment
302

Aswath Damodaran
302
Lesson 2: Increasing growth is not always a value
creating option.. And it may destroy value at times..
303

Aswath Damodaran
303
Lesson 3: Financial leverage is a double-edged
sword..
304

Aswath Damodaran
304
III. Dealing with decline and distress…
305

Aswath Damodaran
305
a. Dealing with Decline
306

 In decline, firms often see declining revenues and lower margins,


translating in negative expected growth over time.
 If these firms are run by good managers, they will not fight decline.
Instead, they will adapt to it and shut down or sell investments that
do not generate the cost of capital. This can translate into negative
net capital expenditures (depreciation exceeds cap ex), declining
working capital and an overall negative reinvestment rate. The best
case scenario is that the firm can shed its bad assets, make itself a
much smaller and healthier firm and then settle into long-term
stable growth.
 As an investor, your worst case scenario is that these firms are run
by managers in denial who continue to expand the firm by making
bad investments (that generate lower returns than the cost of
capital). These firms may be able to grow revenues and operating
income but will destroy value along the way.

Aswath Damodaran
306
307 Aswath Damodaran
b. Dealing with the “downside” of Distress
308

 A DCF valuation values a firm as a going concern. If there is a significant


likelihood of the firm failing before it reaches stable growth and if the
assets will then be sold for a value less than the present value of the
expected cashflows (a distress sale value), DCF valuations will overstate
the value of the firm.
 Value of Equity= DCF value of equity (1 - Probability of distress) + Distress
sale value of equity (Probability of distress)
 There are three ways in which we can estimate the probability of distress:
 Use the bond rating to estimate the cumulative probability of distress over 10 years
 Estimate the probability of distress with a probit
 Estimate the probability of distress by looking at market value of bonds..
 The distress sale value of equity is usually best estimated as a percent of
book value (and this value will be lower if the economy is doing badly and
there are other firms in the same business also in distress).

Aswath Damodaran
308
309 Aswath Damodaran
Adjusting the value of LVS for distress..
310

 In February 2009, LVS was rated B+ by S&P. Historically, 28.25% of B+


rated bonds default within 10 years. LVS has a 6.375% bond, maturing in
February 2015 (7 years), trading at $529. If we discount the expected cash
flows on the bond at the riskfree rate, we can back out the probability of
distress from the bond price:
t=7
63.75(1-PDistress )t 1000(1- PDistress )7
529 = å t + 7
t=1
(1.03) (1.03)
 Solving for the probability of bankruptcy, we get:
 pistress = Annual probability of default = 13.54%
 Cumulative probability of surviving 10 years = (1 - .1354)10 = 23.34%
 Cumulative probability of distress over 10 years = 1 - .2334 = .7666 or 76.66%
 If LVS is becomes distressed:
 Expected distress sale proceeds = $2,769 million < Face value of debt
 Expected equity value/share = $0.00
 Expected value per share = $8.12 (1 - .7666) + $0.00 (.7666) = $1.92

Aswath Damodaran
310
IV. Emerging Market Companies
311

Aswath Damodaran
311
Lesson 1: Country risk has to be incorporated… but
with a scalpel, not a bludgeon
312

 Emerging market companies are undoubtedly exposed to


additional country risk because they are incorporated in
countries that are more exposed to political and
economic risk.
 Not all emerging market companies are equally exposed
to country risk and many developed markets have
emerging market risk exposure because of their
operations.
 You can use either the “weighted country risk premium”,
with the weights reflecting the countries you get your
revenues from or the lambda approach (which may
incorporate more than revenues) to capture country risk
exposure.
Aswath Damodaran
312
313 Aswath Damodaran
Lesson 2: Currency should not matter
314

 You can value any company in any currency. Thus, you


can value a Brazilian company in nominal reais, US
dollars or Swiss Francs.
 For your valuation to stay invariant and consistent, your
cash flows and discount rates have to be in the same
currency. Thus, if you are using a high inflation currency,
both your growth rates and discount rates will be much
higher.
 For your cash flows to be consistent, you have to use
expected exchange rates that reflect purchasing power
parity (the higher inflation currency has to depreciate by
the inflation differential each year).

Aswath Damodaran
314
Lesson 3: The “corporate governance” drag
315

 Stockholders in Asian, Latin American and many European


companies have little or no power over the managers of the
firm. In many cases, insiders own voting shares and control
the firm and the potential for conflict of interests is huge.
 This weak corporate governance is often a reason for given
for using higher discount rates or discounting the estimated
value for these companies.
 Would you discount the value that you estimate for an
emerging market company to allow for this absence of
stockholder power?
a. Yes
b. No.

Aswath Damodaran
315
316 Aswath Damodaran
317 Aswath Damodaran
318 Aswath Damodaran
Lesson 4: Watch out for cross holdings…
319

 Emerging market companies are more prone to having


cross holdings that companies in developed markets.
This is partially the result of history (since many of the
larger public companies used to be family owned
businesses until a few decades ago) and partly because
those who run these companies value control (and use
cross holdings to preserve this control).
 In many emerging market companies, the real process of
valuation begins when you have finished your DCF
valuation, since the cross holdings (which can be
numerous) have to be valued, often with minimal
information.
Aswath Damodaran
319
8. The Tata Group – April 2010

320 Aswath Damodaran


Tata Companies: Value Breakdown
321

1.62% 2.97% 0.22%


100.00% 5.32% 4.64%

80.00% 36.62%
47.45%
47.06%

60.00% % of value from cash


% of value from holdings
95.13%
% of value from operating assets
40.00%

60.41%
47.62% 50.94%

20.00%

0.00%
Tata Chemicals Tata Steel Tata Motors TCS

Aswath Damodaran
321
Lesson 5: Truncation risk can come in many forms…
322

 Natural disasters: Small companies in some economies


are much exposed to natural disasters (hurricanes,
earthquakes), without the means to hedge against that
risk (with insurance or derivative products).
 Terrorism risk: Companies in some countries that are
unstable or in the grips of civil war are exposed to
damage or destruction.
 Nationalization risk: While less common than it used to
be, there are countries where businesses may be
nationalized, with owners receiving less than fair value
as compensation.

Aswath Damodaran
322
V. Valuing Financial Service Companies
323

Aswath Damodaran
323
324 Aswath Damodaran
325 Aswath Damodaran
Lesson 1: Financial service companies are opaque…
326

 With financial service firms, we enter into a Faustian bargain.


They tell us very little about the quality of their assets (loans,
for a bank, for instance are not broken down by default risk
status) but we accept that in return for assets being marked
to market (by accountants who presumably have access to
the information that we don’t have).
 In addition, estimating cash flows for a financial service firm is
difficult to do. So, we trust financial service firms to pay out
their cash flows as dividends. Hence, the use of the dividend
discount model.
 During times of crises or when you don’t trust banks to pay
out what they can afford to in dividends, using the dividend
discount model may not give you a “reliable” value.

Aswath Damodaran
326
327 Aswath Damodaran
Lesson 2: For financial service companies, book value
matters…
328

 The book value of assets and equity is mostly irrelevant when valuing
non-financial service companies. After all, the book value of equity is a
historical figure and can be nonsensical. (The book value of equity can be
negative and is so for more than a 1000 publicly traded US companies)
 With financial service firms, book value of equity is relevant for two
reasons:
 Since financial service firms mark to market, the book value is more likely to reflect
what the firms own right now (rather than a historical value)
 The regulatory capital ratios are based on book equity. Thus, a bank with negative
or even low book equity will be shut down by the regulators.
 From a valuation perspective, it therefore makes sense to pay heed to
book value. In fact, you can argue that reinvestment for a bank is the
amount that it needs to add to book equity to sustain its growth
ambitions and safety requirements:
 FCFE = Net Income – Reinvestment in regulatory capital (book equity)

Aswath Damodaran
328
FCFE for a bank…
329

 To estimate the FCFE for a bank, we redefine reinvestment as investment


in regulatory capital. Since any dividends paid deplete equity capital and
retained earnings increase that capital, the FCFE is:
FCFEBank= Net Income – Increase in Regulatory Capital (Book Equity)

Deutsche Bank: FCFE

Aswath Damodaran
329
330 Aswath Damodaran
VI. Valuing Companies with “intangible” assets
331

Aswath Damodaran
331
Lesson 1: Accounting rules are cluttered with
inconsistencies…
332

 If we start with accounting first principles, capital expenditures are


expenditures designed to create benefits over many periods. They
should not be used to reduce operating income in the period that
they are made, but should be depreciated/amortized over their
life. They should show up as assets on the balance sheet.
 Accounting is consistent in its treatment of cap ex with
manufacturing firms, but is inconsistent with firms that do not fit
the mold.
 With pharmaceutical and technology firms, R&D is the ultimate cap ex but
is treated as an operating expense.
 With consulting firms and other firms dependent on human capital,
recruiting and training expenses are your long term investments that are
treated as operating expenses.
 With brand name consumer product companies, a portion of the
advertising expense is to build up brand name and is the real capital
expenditure. It is treated as an operating expense.

Aswath Damodaran
332
333 Aswath Damodaran
334 Aswath Damodaran
Lesson 2: And fixing those inconsistencies can
alter your view of a company and affect its value
335

Aswath Damodaran
335
VII. Valuing cyclical and commodity companies
336

Aswath Damodaran
336
Lesson 1: With “macro” companies, it is easy to get
lost in “macro” assumptions…
337

 With cyclical and commodity companies, it is undeniable that


the value you arrive at will be affected by your views on the
economy or the price of the commodity.
 Consequently, you will feel the urge to take a stand on these
macro variables and build them into your valuation. Doing so,
though, will create valuations that are jointly impacted by
your views on macro variables and your views on the
company, and it is difficult to separate the two.
 The best (though not easiest) thing to do is to separate your
macro views from your micro views. Use current market
based numbers for your valuation, but then provide a
separate assessment of what you think about those market
numbers.

Aswath Damodaran
337
Lesson 2: Use probabilistic tools to assess value as a
function of macro variables…
338

 If there is a key macro variable affecting the value of your


company that you are uncertain about (and who is not), why
not quantify the uncertainty in a distribution (rather than a
single price) and use that distribution in your valuation.
 That is exactly what you do in a Monte Carlo simulation,
where you allow one or more variables to be distributions
and compute a distribution of values for the company.
 With a simulation, you get not only everything you would get
in a standard valuation (an estimated value for your
company) but you will get additional output (on the variation
in that value and the likelihood that your firm is under or over
valued)

Aswath Damodaran
338
339 Aswath Damodaran
Aswath Damodaran ‹#›
341 Aswath Damodaran
Aswath Damodaran 342

VALUE, PRICE AND


INFORMATION:
CLOSING THE DEAL
Value versus Price
Are you valuing or pricing?
343

Tools for pricing


Tools for intrinsic analysis Tools for "the gap" - Multiples and comparables
- Discounted Cashflow Valuation (DCF) - Behavioral finance - Charting and technical indicators
- Intrinsic multiples - Price catalysts - Pseudo DCF
- Book value based approaches
- Excess Return Models

Value of cashflows, INTRINSIC THE GAP


adjusted for time PRICE
VALUE Value Is there one? Price
and risk Will it close?

Drivers of intrinsic value


- Cashflows from existing assets Drivers of "the gap" Drivers of price
- Information - Market moods & momentum
- Growth in cash flows
- Quality of Growth - Liquidity - Surface stories about fundamentals
- Corporate governance

Aswath Damodaran
343
Test 1: Are you pricing or valuing?
344

Aswath Damodaran
344
Test 2: Are you pricing or valuing?
345

Aswath Damodaran
345
The drivers of value
346

Aswath Damodaran
346
The determinants of price
347

Aswath Damodaran
347
Three views of “the gap”

View of the gap Investment Strategies


The Efficient The gaps between price and value, if Index funds
Marketer they do occur, are random.
The “value” You view pricers as dilettantes who Buy and hold stocks
extremist will move on to fad and fad. where value < price
Eventually, the price will converge on
value.
The pricing Value is only in the heads of the (1) Look for mispriced
extremist “eggheads”. Even if it exists (and it is securities.
questionable), price may never (2) Get ahead of shifts in
converge on value. demand/momentum.

348
The “pricers” dilemma..

 No anchor: If you do not believe in intrinsic value and make


no attempt to estimate it, you have no moorings when you
invest. You will therefore be pushed back and forth as the
price moves from high to low. In other words, everything
becomes relative and you can lose perspective.
 Reactive: Without a core measure of value, your investment
strategy will often be reactive rather than proactive.
 Crowds are fickle and tough to get a read on: The key to being
successful as a pricer is to be able to read the crowd mood
and to detect shifts in that mood early in the process. By their
nature, crowds are tough to read and almost impossible to
model systematically.

349
The valuer’s dilemma and ways of dealing with it…

 Uncertainty about the magnitude of the gap:


 Margin of safety: Many value investors swear by the notion of the
“margin of safety” as protection against risk/uncertainty.
 Collect more information: Collecting more information about the
company is viewed as one way to make your investment less risky.
 Ask what if questions: Doing scenario analysis or what if analysis gives
you a sense of whether you should invest.
 Confront uncertainty: Face up to the uncertainty, bring it into the
analysis and deal with the consequences.
 Uncertainty about gap closing: This is tougher and you can
reduce your exposure to it by
 Lengthening your time horizon
 Providing or looking for a catalyst that will cause the gap to close.

350
Strategies for managing the risk in the “closing” of
the gap

 The “karmic” approach: In this one, you buy (sell short) under
(over) valued companies and sit back and wait for the gap to
close. You are implicitly assuming that given time, the market
will see the error of its ways and fix that error.
 The catalyst approach: For the gap to close, the price has to
converge on value. For that convergence to occur, there
usually has to be a catalyst.
 If you are an activist investor, you may be the catalyst yourself. In fact,
your act of buying the stock may be a sufficient signal for the market to
reassess the price.
 If you are not, you have to look for other catalysts. Here are some to
watch for: a new CEO or management team, a “blockbuster” new
product or an acquisition bid where the firm is targeted.

Aswath Damodaran
351
351
An example: Apple – Price versus Value
(my estimates) from 2011 to 2015
352

Aswath Damodaran
352
A closing thought…
353

Aswath Damodaran
353

You might also like