Aswath Lecture Notes 1

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 322

Aswath

Damodaran 0

CORPORATE FINANCE
B40.2302
LECTURE NOTES: PACKET 1
Aswath Damodaran
Aswath Damodaran 1

THE OBJECTIVE IN CORPORATE


FINANCE
If you dont know where you are going, it doesnt
matter how you get there
First Principles
2

Maximize the value of the business (firm)

The Investment Decision The Financing Decision The Dividend Decision


Invest in assets that earn a Find the right kind of debt If you cannot find investments
return greater than the for your firm and the right that make your minimum
minimum acceptable hurdle mix of debt and equity to acceptable rate, return the cash
rate fund your operations to owners of your business

The hurdle rate The return How much How you choose
should reflect the The optimal The right kind
should reflect the cash you can to return cash to
riskiness of the mix of debt of debt
magnitude and return the owners will
investment and and equity matches the
the timing of the depends upon depend on
the mix of debt maximizes firm tenor of your
cashflows as well current & whether they
and equity used value assets
as all side effects. potential prefer dividends
to fund it. investment or buybacks
opportunities

Aswath Damodaran
2
The Objective in Decision Making
3

In traditional corporate finance, the objective in decision making is to


maximize the value of the firm.
A narrower objective is to maximize stockholder wealth. When the stock
is traded and markets are viewed to be efficient, the objective is to
maximize the stock price.
Maximize equity Maximize market
Maximize value estimate of equity
firm value
value
Assets Liabilities
Existing Investments Fixed Claim on cash flows
Generate cashflows today Assets in Place Debt Little or No role in management
Includes long lived (fixed) and Fixed Maturity
short-lived(working Tax Deductible
capital) assets

Expected Value that will be Growth Assets Equity Residual Claim on cash flows
created by future investments Significant Role in management
Perpetual Lives
Aswath Damodaran
3
Maximizing Stock Prices is too narrow an
objective: A preliminary response
4

Maximizing stock price is not incompatible with


meeting employee needs/objectives. In particular:
Employees are often stockholders in many firms
Firms that maximize stock price generally are profitable
firms that can afford to treat employees well.
Maximizing stock price does not mean that
customers are not critical to success. In most
businesses, keeping customers happy is the route to
stock price maximization.
Maximizing stock price does not imply that a
company has to be a social outlaw.
Aswath Damodaran
4
Why traditional corporate financial theory
focuses on maximizing stockholder wealth.
5

Stock price is easily observable and constantly updated


(unlike other measures of performance, which may not
be as easily observable, and certainly not updated as
frequently).
If investors are rational (are they?), stock prices reflect
the wisdom of decisions, short term and long term,
instantaneously.
The objective of stock price performance provides some
very elegant theory on:
Allocating resources across scarce uses (which investments to
take and which ones to reject)
how to finance these investments
how much to pay in dividends

Aswath Damodaran
5
The Classical Objective Function
6

STOCKHOLDERS

Hire & fire Maximize


managers stockholder
- Board wealth
- Annual Meeting

Lend Money No Social Costs


BONDHOLDERS/ Managers SOCIETY
LENDERS Protect All costs can be
bondholder traced to firm
Interests
Reveal Markets are
information efficient and
honestly and assess effect on
on time value

FINANCIAL MARKETS

Aswath Damodaran
6
What can go wrong?
7

STOCKHOLDERS

Have little control Managers put


over managers their interests
above stockholders

Lend Money Significant Social Costs


BONDHOLDERS Managers SOCIETY
Bondholders can Some costs cannot be
get ripped off traced to firm
Delay bad
news or Markets make
provide mistakes and
misleading can over react
information

FINANCIAL MARKETS

Aswath Damodaran
7
I. Stockholder Interests vs. Management
Interests
8

In theory: The stockholders have significant control over


management. The two mechanisms for disciplining
management are the annual meeting and the board of
directors. Specifically, we assume that
Stockholders who are dissatisfied with managers can not only
express their disapproval at the annual meeting, but can use
their voting power at the meeting to keep managers in check.
The board of directors plays its true role of representing
stockholders and acting as a check on management.
In Practice: Neither mechanism is as effective in
disciplining management as theory posits.
Aswath Damodaran
8
The Annual Meeting as a disciplinary venue
9

The power of stockholders to act at annual meetings is


diluted by three factors
Most small stockholders do not go to meetings because the cost
of going to the meeting exceeds the value of their holdings.
Incumbent management starts off with a clear advantage when
it comes to the exercise of proxies. Proxies that are not voted
becomes votes for incumbent management.
For large stockholders, the path of least resistance, when
confronted by managers that they do not like, is to vote with
their feet.
Annual meetings are also tightly scripted and controlled
events, making it difficult for outsiders and rebels to
bring up issues that are not to the managements liking.

Aswath Damodaran
9
And institutional investors go along with incumbent
managers
10

Aswath Damodaran
10
Board of Directors as a disciplinary mechanism
11

Directors are paid well: In 2010, the median board member at a Fortune
500 company was paid $212,512, with 54% coming in stock and the
remaining 46% in cash. If a board member was a non-executive chair, he
or she received about $150,000 more in compensation.
Spend more time on their directorial duties than they used to: A board
member worked, on average, about 227.5 hours a year (and that is being
generous), or 4.4 hours a week, according to the National Associate of
Corporate Directors. Of this, about 24 hours a year are for board
meetings. Those numbers are up from what they were a decade ago.
Even those hours are not very productive: While the time spent on being
a director has gone up, a significant portion of that time was spent on
making sure that they are legally protected (regulations & lawsuits).
And they have many loyalties: Many directors serve on three or more
boards, and some are full time chief executives of other companies.

Aswath Damodaran
11
The CEO often hand-picks directors..
12

CEOs pick directors: A 1992 survey by Korn/Ferry revealed that 74% of


companies relied on recommendations from the CEO to come up with
new directors and only 16% used an outside search firm. While that
number has changed in recent years, CEOs still determine who sits on
their boards. While more companies have outsiders involved in picking
directors now, CEOs exercise significant influence over the process.
Directors dont have big equity stakes: Directors often hold only token
stakes in their companies. Most directors in companies today still receive
more compensation as directors than they gain from their stockholdings.
While share ownership is up among directors today, they usually get these
shares from the firm (rather than buy them).
And some directors are CEOs of other firms: Many directors are
themselves CEOs of other firms. Worse still, there are cases where CEOs
sit on each others boards.

Aswath Damodaran
12
Directors lack the expertise (and the willingness)
to ask the necessary tough questions..
13

Roberts Rules of Order? In most boards, the CEO


continues to be the chair. Not surprisingly, the CEO sets
the agenda, chairs the meeting and controls the
information provided to directors.
Be a team player? The search for consensus overwhelms
any attempts at confrontation.
The CEO as authority figure: Studies of social psychology
have noted that loyalty is hardwired into human
behavior. While this loyalty is an important tool in
building up organizations, it can also lead people to
suppress internal ethical standards if they conflict with
loyalty to an authority figure. In a board meeting, the
CEO generally becomes the authority figure.
Aswath Damodaran
13
The worst board ever? The Disney Experience -
1997
14

Aswath Damodaran
14
The Calpers Tests for Independent Boards
15

Calpers, the California Employees Pension fund,


suggested three tests in 1997 of an independent
board:
Are a majority of the directors outside directors?
Is the chairman of the board independent of the company
(and not the CEO of the company)?
Are the compensation and audit committees composed
entirely of outsiders?
Disney was the only S&P 500 company to fail all
three tests.
Aswath Damodaran
15
Business Week piles on The Worst Boards in 1997..
16

Aswath Damodaran
16
Application Test: Whos on board?
17

Look at the board of directors for your firm.


How many of the directors are inside directors (Employees of the firm,
ex-managers)?
Is there any information on how independent the directors in the firm
are from the managers?
Are there any external measures of the quality of corporate
governance of your firm?
Yahoo! Finance now reports on a corporate governance score for firms,
where it ranks firms against the rest of the market and against their
sectors.
Is there tangible evidence that your board acts independently
of management?
Check news stories to see if there are actions that the CEO has wanted
to take that the board has stopped him or her from taking or at least
slowed him or her down.

Aswath Damodaran
17
So, what next? When the cat is idle, the mice
will play ....
18

When managers do not fear stockholders, they will often put


their interests over stockholder interests
No stockholder approval needed.. Stockholder Approval needed

Greenmail: The (managers of ) target of a hostile takeover buy out the


potential acquirer's existing stake, at a price much greater than the
price paid by the raider, in return for the signing of a 'standstill'
agreement.
Golden Parachutes: Provisions in employment contracts, that allows
for the payment of a lump-sum or cash flows over a period, if
managers covered by these contracts lose their jobs in a takeover.
Poison Pills: A security, the rights or cashflows on which are triggered
by an outside event, generally a hostile takeover, is called a poison pill.
Shark Repellents: Anti-takeover amendments are also aimed at
dissuading hostile takeovers, but differ on one very important count.
They require the assent of stockholders to be instituted.
Overpaying on takeovers: Acquisitions often are driven by
management interests rather than stockholder interests.

Aswath Damodaran
18
Overpaying on takeovers
19

The quickest and perhaps the most decisive way to


impoverish stockholders is to overpay on a takeover.
The stockholders in acquiring firms do not seem to share
the enthusiasm of the managers in these firms. Stock
prices of bidding firms decline on the takeover
announcements a significant proportion of the time.
Many mergers do not work, as evidenced by a number of
measures.
The profitability of merged firms relative to their peer groups,
does not increase significantly after mergers.
An even more damning indictment is that a large number of
mergers are reversed within a few years, which is a clear
admission that the acquisitions did not work.

Aswath Damodaran
19
A case study in value destruction:
Eastman Kodak & Sterling Drugs

Kodak enters bidding war Kodak wins!!!!


In late 1987, Eastman Kodak
entered into a bidding war with
Hoffman La Roche for Sterling
Drugs, a pharmaceutical
company.
The bidding war started with
Sterling Drugs trading at about
$40/share.
At $72/share, Hoffman dropped
out of the bidding war, but Kodak
kept bidding.
At $89.50/share, Kodak won and
claimed potential synergies !
explained the premium.
Earnings and Revenues at Sterling Drugs
21

Sterling Drug under Eastman Kodak: Where is the synergy?

5,000
4,500
4,000
3,500
3,000
2,500
2,000
1,500
1,000
500
0
1988 1989 1990 1991 1992

Revenue Operating Earnings

Aswath Damodaran
21
Kodak Says Drug Unit Is Not for Sale but
22

An article in the NY Times in August of 1993 suggested that Kodak was eager to
shed its drug unit.
In response, Eastman Kodak officials say they have no plans to sell Kodaks Sterling Winthrop
drug unit.
Louis Mattis, Chairman of Sterling Winthrop, dismissed the rumors as massive speculation,
which flies in the face of the stated intent of Kodak that it is committed to be in the health
business.
A few months laterTaking a stride out of the drug business, Eastman Kodak said
that the Sanofi Group, a French pharmaceutical company, agreed to buy the
prescription drug business of Sterling Winthrop for $1.68 billion.
Shares of Eastman Kodak rose 75 cents yesterday, closing at $47.50 on the New York Stock
Exchange.
Samuel D. Isaly an analyst , said the announcement was very good for Sanofi and very good
for Kodak.
When the divestitures are complete, Kodak will be entirely focused on imaging, said George
M. C. Fisher, the company's chief executive.
The rest of the Sterling Winthrop was sold to Smithkline for $2.9 billion.

Aswath Damodaran
22
The connection to corporate governance: HP buys
Autonomy and explains the premium
23

Aswath Damodaran
23
A year later HP admits a mistakeand explains it
24

Aswath Damodaran
24
Application Test: Who owns/runs your firm?
25

Look at: Bloomberg printout HDS for your firm


Who are the top stockholders in your firm?
What are the potential conflicts of interests that you see
emerging from this stockholding structure?
Government
Outside stockholders Managers
- Size of holding - Length of tenure
- Active or Passive? - Links to insiders
- Short or Long term? Control of the firm

Employees Lenders

Inside stockholders
% of stock held
Voting and non-voting shares
Control structure
Aswath Damodaran
25
Case 1: Splintering of Stockholders
Disneys top stockholders in 2003

Aswath Damodaran
26
Case 2: Voting versus Non-voting Shares &
Golden Shares: Vale

Valespar(ownership Brazilian(Govt.( Valespar(


4%( 1%(
Brazilian(retail(
5%(
Brazilian(
Litel&Participao 49.00%
Brazilian(Ins=tu=onal(
6%(
Govt.(
6%(
Eletron&S.A. 0.03%
Bradespar&S.A. 21.21%
Mitsui&&&Co. 18.24% Brazilian(retail(
18%(
BNDESPAR 11.51%

Valespar( Golden (veto)


Non/Brazilian( 54%( Brazilian(Ins<tu<onal( Non.Brazilian(
(ADR&Bovespa)( shares owned 18%( (ADR&Bovespa)(
29%( 59%(
by Brazilian govt

Common (voting) shares Preferred (non-voting)


3,172 million 1,933 million
Vale Equity

Vale has eleven members on its board of directors, ten of


whom were nominated by Valepar and the board was
chaired by Don Conrado, the CEO of Valepar.
Aswath Damodaran
27
Case 3: Cross and Pyramid Holdings
Tata Motors top stockholders in 2013

Aswath Damodaran
28
Case 4: Legal rights and Corporate
Structures: Baidu
The Board: The company has six directors, one of whom is Robin Li,
who is the founder/CEO of Baidu. Mr. Li also owns a majority stake
of Class B shares, which have ten times the voting rights of Class A
shares, granting him effective control of the company.
The structure: Baidu is a Chinese company, but it is incorporated in
the Cayman Islands, its primary stock listing is on the NASDAQ and
the listed company is structured as a shell company, to get around
Chinese government restrictions of foreign investors holding shares
in Chinese corporations.
The legal system: Baidus operating counterpart in China is
structured as a Variable Interest Entity (VIE), and it is unclear how
much legal power the shareholders in the shell company have to
enforce changes at the VIE.

Aswath Damodaran
29
Things change.. Disneys top stockholders in 2009
30

Aswath Damodaran
30
II. Stockholders' objectives vs. Bondholders'
objectives
31

In theory: there is no conflict of interests between


stockholders and bondholders.
In practice: Stockholder and bondholders have
different objectives. Bondholders are concerned
most about safety and ensuring that they get paid
their claims. Stockholders are more likely to think
about upside potential

Aswath Damodaran
31
Examples of the conflict..
32

A dividend/buyback surge: When firms pay cash out as


dividends, lenders to the firm are hurt and stockholders
may be helped. This is because the firm becomes riskier
without the cash.
Risk shifting: When a firm takes riskier projects than
those agreed to at the outset, lenders are hurt. Lenders
base interest rates on their perceptions of how risky a
firms investments are. If stockholders then take on
riskier investments, lenders will be hurt.
Borrowing more on the same assets: If lenders do not
protect themselves, a firm can borrow more money and
make all existing lenders worse off.

Aswath Damodaran
32
An Extreme Example: Unprotected Lenders?
33

Aswath Damodaran
33
III. Firms and Financial Markets
34

In theory: Financial markets are efficient. Managers


convey information honestly and and in a timely manner
to financial markets, and financial markets make
reasoned judgments of the effects of this information on
'true value'. As a consequence-
A company that invests in good long term projects will be
rewarded.
Short term accounting gimmicks will not lead to increases in
market value.
Stock price performance is a good measure of company
performance.
In practice: There are some holes in the 'Efficient
Markets' assumption.

Aswath Damodaran
34
Managers control the release of information to
the general public
35

Information management (timing and spin):


Information (especially negative) is sometimes
suppressed or delayed by managers seeking a better
time to release it. When the information is released,
firms find ways to spin or frame it to put
themselves in the best possible light.
Outright fraud: In some cases, firms release
intentionally misleading information about their
current conditions and future prospects to financial
markets.
Aswath Damodaran
35
Evidence that managers delay bad news?
36

DO MANAGERS DELAY BAD NEWS?: EPS and DPS Changes- by


Weekday

8.00%

6.00%

4.00%

2.00%

0.00%

-2.00%

-4.00%

-6.00%
Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Friday

% Chg(EPS) % Chg(DPS)

Aswath Damodaran
36
Some critiques of market efficiency..
37

Investor irrationality: The base argument is that investors


are irrational and prices often move for no reason at all.
As a consequence, prices are much more volatile than
justified by the underlying fundamentals. Earnings and
dividends are much less volatile than stock prices.
Manifestations of irrationality
Reaction to news: Some believe that investors overreact to
news, both good and bad. Others believe that investors
sometimes under react to big news stories.
An insider conspiracy: Financial markets are manipulated by
insiders; Prices do not have any relationship to value.
Short termism: Investors are short-sighted, and do not consider
the long-term implications of actions taken by the firm

Aswath Damodaran
37
Are markets short sighted and too focused
on the near term? What do you think?
38

Focusing on market prices will lead companies towards short term


decisions at the expense of long term value.
a. I agree with the statement
b. I do not agree with this statement
Allowing managers to make decisions without having to worry
about the effect on market prices will lead to better long term
decisions.
a. I agree with this statement
b. I do not agree with this statement
Neither managers nor markets are trustworthy. Regulations/laws
should be written that force firms to make long term decisions.
a. I agree with this statement
b. I do not agree with this statement

Aswath Damodaran
38
Are markets short term? Some evidence that
they are not..
39

Value of young firms: There are hundreds of start-up and


small firms, with no earnings expected in the near future,
that raise money on financial markets. Why would a myopic
market that cares only about short term earnings attach high
prices to these firms?
Current earnings vs Future growth: If the evidence suggests
anything, it is that markets do not value current earnings and
cashflows enough and value future earnings and cashflows
too much. After all, studies suggest that low PE stocks are
under priced relative to high PE stocks
Market reaction to investments: The market response to
research and development and investment expenditures is
generally positive.

Aswath Damodaran
39
If markets are so short term, why do they react to big
investments (that potentially lower short term earnings) so
positively?
40

Aswath Damodaran
40
But what about market crises?
41

Markets are the problem: Many critics of markets point to market


bubbles and crises as evidence that markets do not work. For
instance, the market turmoil between September and December
2008 is pointed to as backing for the statement that free markets
are the source of the problem and not the solution.
The counter: There are two counter arguments that can be offered:
The events of the last quarter of 2008 illustrate that we are more
dependent on functioning, liquid markets, with risk taking investors, than
ever before in history. As we saw, no government or other entity (bank,
Buffett) is big enough to step in and save the day.
The firms that caused the market collapse (banks, investment banks) were
among the most regulated businesses in the market place. If anything,
their failures can be traced to their attempts to take advantage of
regulatory loopholes (badly designed insurance programs capital
measurements that miss risky assets, especially derivatives)

Aswath Damodaran
41
IV. Firms and Society
42

In theory: All costs and benefits associated with a


firms decisions can be traced back to the firm.
In practice: Financial decisions can create social costs
and benefits.
A social cost or benefit is a cost or benefit that accrues to society
as a whole and not to the firm making the decision.
n Environmental costs (pollution, health costs, etc..)
n Quality of Life' costs (traffic, housing, safety, etc.)
Examples of social benefits include:
n creating employment in areas with high unemployment
n supporting development in inner cities
n creating access to goods in areas where such access does not
exist

Aswath Damodaran
42
Social Costs and Benefits are difficult to quantify
because ..
43

Cannot know the unknown: They might not be known at


the time of the decision. In other words, a firm may
think that it is delivering a product that enhances
society, at the time it delivers the product but discover
afterwards that there are very large costs. (Asbestos was
a wonderful product, when it was devised, light and easy
to work with It is only after decades that the health
consequences came to light)
Eyes of the beholder: They are person-specific, since
different decision makers can look at the same social
cost and weight them very differently.
Decision paralysis: They can be paralyzing if carried to
extremes.
Aswath Damodaran
43
A test of your social consciousness:
Put your money where you mouth is
44

Assume that you work for Disney and that you have an opportunity
to open a store in an inner-city neighborhood. The store is
expected to lose about a million dollars a year, but it will create
much-needed employment in the area, and may help revitalize it.
Would you open the store?
Yes
No
If yes, would you tell your stockholders and let them vote on the
issue?
Yes
No
If no, how would you respond to a stockholder query on why you
were not living up to your social responsibilities?

Aswath Damodaran
44
So this is what can go wrong...
45

STOCKHOLDERS

Managers put
Have little control their interests
over managers above stockholders

Lend Money Significant Social Costs


BONDHOLDERS Managers SOCIETY
Bondholders can Some costs cannot be
get ripped off traced to firm
Delay bad
news or Markets make
provide mistakes and
misleading can over react
information

FINANCIAL MARKETS

Aswath Damodaran
45
Traditional corporate financial theory breaks
down when ...
46

Managerial self-interest: The interests/objectives of the


decision makers in the firm conflict with the interests of
stockholders.
Unprotected debt holders: Bondholders (Lenders) are
not protected against expropriation by stockholders.
Inefficient markets: Financial markets do not operate
efficiently, and stock prices do not reflect the underlying
value of the firm.
Large social side costs: Significant social costs can be
created as a by-product of stock price maximization.

Aswath Damodaran
46
When traditional corporate financial theory
breaks down, the solution is:
47

A non-stockholder based governance system: To choose a


different mechanism for corporate governance, i.e, assign the
responsibility for monitoring managers to someone other
than stockholders.
A better objective than maximizing stock prices? To choose a
different objective for the firm.
Maximize stock prices but minimize side costs: To maximize
stock price, but reduce the potential for conflict and
breakdown:
Making managers (decision makers) and employees into stockholders
Protect lenders from expropriation
By providing information honestly and promptly to financial markets
Minimize social costs

Aswath Damodaran
47
I. An Alternative Corporate Governance System
48

Germany and Japan developed a different mechanism for


corporate governance, based upon corporate cross holdings.
In Germany, the banks form the core of this system.
In Japan, it is the keiretsus
Other Asian countries have modeled their system after Japan, with family
companies forming the core of the new corporate families
At their best, the most efficient firms in the group work at bringing
the less efficient firms up to par. They provide a corporate welfare
system that makes for a more stable corporate structure
At their worst, the least efficient and poorly run firms in the group
pull down the most efficient and best run firms down. The nature
of the cross holdings makes its very difficult for outsiders (including
investors in these firms) to figure out how well or badly the group
is doing.

Aswath Damodaran
48
II. Choose a Different Objective Function
49

Firms can always focus on a different objective function.


Examples would include
maximizing earnings
maximizing revenues
maximizing firm size
maximizing market share
maximizing EVA
The key thing to remember is that these are
intermediate objective functions.
To the degree that they are correlated with the long term health
and value of the company, they work well.
To the degree that they do not, the firm can end up with a
disaster

Aswath Damodaran
49
III. Maximize Stock Price, subject to ..
50

The strength of the stock price maximization objective


function is its internal self correction mechanism. Excesses on
any of the linkages lead, if unregulated, to counter actions
which reduce or eliminate these excesses
In the context of our discussion,
managers taking advantage of stockholders has led to a much more
active market for corporate control.
stockholders taking advantage of bondholders has led to bondholders
protecting themselves at the time of the issue.
firms revealing incorrect or delayed information to markets has led to
markets becoming more skeptical and punitive
firms creating social costs has led to more regulations, as well as
investor and customer backlashes.

Aswath Damodaran
50
The Stockholder Backlash
51

Activist Institutional investors have become much more


active in monitoring companies that they invest in and
demanding changes in the way in which business is done.
They have been joined by private equity funds like KKR and
Blackstone.
Activist individuals like Carl Icahn specialize in taking large
positions in companies which they feel need to change their
ways (Blockbuster, Time Warner, Motorola & Apple) and push
for change.
Vocal stockholders, armed with more information and new
powers: At annual meetings, stockholders have taken to
expressing their displeasure with incumbent management by
voting against their compensation contracts or their board of
directors

Aswath Damodaran
51
The Hostile Acquisition Threat
52

The typical target firm in a hostile takeover has


a return on equity almost 5% lower than its peer group
had a stock that has significantly under performed the peer
group over the previous 2 years
has managers who hold little or no stock in the firm
In other words, the best defense against a hostile
takeover is to run your firm well and earn good returns
for your stockholders
Conversely, when you do not allow hostile takeovers, this
is the firm that you are most likely protecting (and not a
well run or well managed firm)

Aswath Damodaran
52
In response, boards are becoming more
independent
53

Boards have become smaller over time. The median size of a board
of directors has decreased from 16 to 20 in the 1970s to between 9
and 11 in 1998. The smaller boards are less unwieldy and more
effective than the larger boards.
There are fewer insiders on the board. In contrast to the 6 or more
insiders that many boards had in the 1970s, only two directors in
most boards in 1998 were insiders.
Directors are increasingly compensated with stock and options in
the company, instead of cash. In 1973, only 4% of directors
received compensation in the form of stock or options, whereas
78% did so in 1998.
More directors are identified and selected by a nominating
committee rather than being chosen by the CEO of the firm. In
1998, 75% of boards had nominating committees; the comparable
statistic in 1973 was 2%.

Aswath Damodaran
53
Disney: Eisners rise & fall from grace

In his early years at Disney, Michael Eisner brought about long-delayed changes in
the company and put it on the path to being an entertainment giant that it is
today. His success allowed him to consolidate power and the boards that he
created were increasingly captive ones (see the 1997 board).
In 1996, Eisner spearheaded the push to buy ABC and the board rubberstamped
his decision, as they had with other major decisions. In the years following, the
company ran into problems both on its ABC acquisition and on its other
operations and stockholders started to get restive, especially as the stock price
halved between 1998 and 2002.
In 2003, Roy Disney and Stanley Gold resigned from the Disney board, arguing
against Eisners autocratic style.
In early 2004, Comcast made a hostile bid for Disney and later in the year, 43% of
Disney shareholders withheld their votes for Eisners reelection to the board of
directors. Following that vote, the board of directors at Disney voted unanimously
to elect George Mitchell as the Chair of the board, replacing Eisner, who vowed to
stay on as CEO.

Aswath Damodaran
54
Eisners concession: Disneys Board in 2003
55

Board Members Occupation


Reveta Bowers Head of school for the Center for Early Education,
John Bryson CEO and Chairman of Con Edison
Roy Disney Head of Disney Animation
Michael Eisner CEO of Disney
Judith Estrin CEO of Packet Design (an internet company)
Stanley Gold CEO of Shamrock Holdings
Robert Iger Chief Operating Officer, Disney
Monica Lozano Chief Operation Officer, La Opinion (Spanish newspaper)
George Mitchell Chairman of law firm (Verner, Liipfert, et al.)
Thomas S. Murphy Ex-CEO, Capital Cities ABC
Leo ODonovan Professor of Theology, Georgetown University
Sidney Poitier Actor, Writer and Director
Robert A.M. Stern Senior Partner of Robert A.M. Stern Architects of New York
Andrea L. Van de Kamp Chairman of Sotheby's West Coast
Raymond L. Watson Chairman of Irvine Company (a real estate corporation)
Gary L. Wilson Chairman of the board, Northwest Airlines.

Aswath Damodaran
55
Changes in corporate governance at Disney
56

1. Required at least two executive sessions of the board, without the CEO
or other members of management present, each year.
2. Created the position of non-management presiding director, and
appointed Senator George Mitchell to lead those executive sessions and
assist in setting the work agenda of the board.
3. Adopted a new and more rigorous definition of director independence.
4. Required that a substantial majority of the board be comprised of
directors meeting the new independence standards.
5. Provided for a reduction in committee size and the rotation of
committee and chairmanship assignments among independent
directors.
6. Added new provisions for management succession planning and
evaluations of both management and board performance
7. Provided for enhanced continuing education and training for board
members.

Aswath Damodaran
56
Eisners exit and a new age dawns? Disneys board
in 2008
57

Aswath Damodaran
57
But as a CEOs tenure lengthens, does
corporate governance suffer?
1. While the board size has stayed compact (at twelve members),
there has been only one change since 2008, with Sheryl
Sandberg, COO of Facebook, replacing the deceased Steve Jobs.
2. The board voted reinstate Iger as chair of the board in 2011,
reversing a decision made to separate the CEO and Chair
positions after the Eisner years.
3. In 2011, Iger announced his intent to step down as CEO in 2015
but Disneys board convinced Iger to stay on as CEO for an extra
year, for the the good of the company.
4. There were signs of restiveness among Disneys stockholders,
especially those interested in corporate governance. Activist
investors (CalSTRS) starting making noise and Institutional
Shareholder Services (ISS), which gauges corporate governance at
companies, raised red flags about compensation and board
monitoring at Disney.

Aswath Damodaran
58
Igers non-exit and the Domino effect
59

When Iger stayed on as CEO, the ranks below him


thinned out, as executives who were waiting to
move up moved on instead.
Igers rumored successor, Tom Staggs, resigned (in a
surprise) in April 2016, leaving a vacuum in the
leadership ranks.
The board considered asking Iger to postpone his
retirement again.

Aswath Damodaran
59
What about legislation?
60

Every corporate scandal creates impetus for a


legislative response. The scandals at Enron and
WorldCom laid the groundwork for Sarbanes-Oxley.
You cannot legislate good corporate governance.
The costs of meeting legal requirements often exceed the
benefits
Laws always have unintended consequences

In general, laws tend to be blunderbusses that penalize


good companies more than they punish the bad
companies.

Aswath Damodaran
60
Is there a payoff to better corporate
governance?
61

In the most comprehensive study of the effect of corporate governance


on value, a governance index was created for each of 1500 firms based
upon 24 distinct corporate governance provisions.
Buying stocks that had the strongest investor protections while simultaneously
selling shares with the weakest protections generated an annual excess return of
8.5%.
Every one point increase in the index towards fewer investor protections decreased
market value by 8.9% in 1999
Firms that scored high in investor protections also had higher profits, higher sales
growth and made fewer acquisitions.
The link between the composition of the board of directors and firm value
is weak. Smaller boards do tend to be more effective.
On a purely anecdotal basis, a common theme at problem companies and
is an ineffective board that fails to ask tough questions of an imperial CEO.

Aswath Damodaran
61
The Bondholders Defense Against Stockholder
Excesses
62

More restrictive covenants on investment, financing and dividend


policy have been incorporated into both private lending
agreements and into bond issues, to prevent future Nabiscos.
New types of bonds have been created to explicitly protect
bondholders against sudden increases in leverage or other actions
that increase lender risk substantially. Two examples of such bonds
Puttable Bonds, where the bondholder can put the bond back to the firm
and get face value, if the firm takes actions that hurt bondholders
Ratings Sensitive Notes, where the interest rate on the notes adjusts to
that appropriate for the rating of the firm
More hybrid bonds (with an equity component, usually in the form
of a conversion option or warrant) have been used. This allows
bondholders to become equity investors, if they feel it is in their
best interests to do so.

Aswath Damodaran
62
The Financial Market Response
63

While analysts are more likely still to issue buy rather


than sell recommendations, the payoff to uncovering
negative news about a firm is large enough that such
news is eagerly sought and quickly revealed (at least to a
limited group of investors).
As investor access to information improves, it is
becoming much more difficult for firms to control when
and how information gets out to markets.
As option trading has become more common, it has
become much easier to trade on bad news. In the
process, it is revealed to the rest of the market.
When firms mislead markets, the punishment is not only
quick but it is savage.
Aswath Damodaran
63
The Societal Response
64

If firms consistently flout societal norms and create


large social costs, the governmental response
(especially in a democracy) is for laws and
regulations to be passed against such behavior.
For firms catering to a more socially conscious
clientele, the failure to meet societal norms (even if
it is legal) can lead to loss of business and value.
Finally, investors may choose not to invest in stocks
of firms that they view as socially irresponsible.

Aswath Damodaran
64
The Counter Reaction
65

STOCKHOLDERS

1. More activist Managers of poorly


investors run firms are put
2. Hostile takeovers on notice.

Protect themselves Corporate Good Citizen Constraints


BONDHOLDERS Managers SOCIETY
1. Covenants 1. More laws
2. New Types 2. Investor/Customer Backlash
Firms are
punished Investors and
for misleading analysts become
markets more skeptical

FINANCIAL MARKETS

Aswath Damodaran
65
So what do you think?
66

At this point in time, the following statement best describes


where I stand in terms of the right objective function for
decision making in a business
a. Maximize stock price, with no constraints
b. Maximize stock price, with constraints on being a good social citizen.
c. Maximize stockholder wealth, with good citizen constraints, and
hope/pray that the market catches up with you.
d. Maximize profits or profitability
e. Maximize earnings growth
f. Maximize market share
g. Maximize revenues
h. Maximize social good
i. None of the above

Aswath Damodaran
66
The Modified Objective Function
67

For publicly traded firms in reasonably efficient markets,


where bondholders (lenders) are protected:
Maximize Stock Price: This will also maximize firm value
For publicly traded firms in inefficient markets, where
bondholders are protected:
Maximize stockholder wealth: This will also maximize firm value,
but might not maximize the stock price
For publicly traded firms in inefficient markets, where
bondholders are not fully protected
Maximize firm value, though stockholder wealth and stock
prices may not be maximized at the same point.
For private firms, maximize stockholder wealth (if
lenders are protected) or firm value (if they are not)
Aswath Damodaran
67
Aswath Damodaran 68

THE INVESTMENT PRINCIPLE: RISK


AND RETURN MODELS

You cannot swing upon a rope that is attached only


to your own belt.
First Principles
69

Aswath Damodaran
69
The notion of a benchmark
70

Since financial resources are finite, there is a hurdle that


projects have to cross before being deemed acceptable.
This hurdle should be higher for riskier projects than for
safer projects.
A simple representation of the hurdle rate is as follows:
Hurdle rate = Riskless Rate + Risk Premium
The two basic questions that every risk and return model
in finance tries to answer are:
How do you measure risk?
How do you translate this risk measure into a risk premium?

Aswath Damodaran
70
What is Risk?
71

Risk, in traditional terms, is viewed as a negative.


Websters dictionary, for instance, defines risk as exposing
to danger or hazard. The Chinese symbols for risk,
reproduced below, give a much better description of risk

The first symbol is the symbol for danger, while the second
is the symbol for opportunity, making risk a mix of danger
and opportunity. You cannot have one, without the other.
Risk is therefore neither good nor bad. It is just a fact of life.
The question that businesses have to address is therefore not
whether to avoid risk but how best to incorporate it into their
decision making.
Aswath Damodaran
71
A good risk and return model should
72

1. It should come up with a measure of risk that applies to all assets


and not be asset-specific.
2. It should clearly delineate what types of risk are rewarded and
what are not, and provide a rationale for the delineation.
3. It should come up with standardized risk measures, i.e., an
investor presented with a risk measure for an individual asset
should be able to draw conclusions about whether the asset is
above-average or below-average risk.
4. It should translate the measure of risk into a rate of return that
the investor should demand as compensation for bearing the risk.
5. It should work well not only at explaining past returns, but also in
predicting future expected returns.

Aswath Damodaran
72
The Capital Asset Pricing Model
73

1. Uses variance of actual returns around an expected


return as a measure of risk.
2. Specifies that a portion of variance can be diversified
away, and that is only the non-diversifiable portion that
is rewarded.
3. Measures the non-diversifiable risk with beta, which is
standardized around one.
4. Translates beta into expected return -
Expected Return = Riskfree rate + Beta * Risk Premium
5. Works as well as the next best alternative in most
cases.
Aswath Damodaran
73
1. The Mean-Variance Framework
74

The variance on any investment measures the disparity


between actual and expected returns.
Low Variance Investment

High Variance Investment

Expected Return

Aswath Damodaran
74
How risky is Disney? A look at the past
75

Returns on Disney - 2008-2013


25.00% Average monthly return = 1.65%
Average monthly standard deviation = 7.64%
20.00% Average annual return = 21.70%
Average annual standard deviation = 26.47%
15.00%

10.00%

5.00%

0.00%

-5.00%

-10.00%

-15.00%

-20.00%

-25.00%
Oct-08
Dec-08
Feb-09
Apr-09
Jun-09
Aug-09
Oct-09
Dec-09
Feb-10
Apr-10
Jun-10
Aug-10
Oct-10
Dec-10
Feb-11
Apr-11
Jun-11
Aug-11
Oct-11
Dec-11
Feb-12
Apr-12
Jun-12
Aug-12
Oct-12
Dec-12
Feb-13
Apr-13
Jun-13
Aug-13
Aswath Damodaran
75
Do you live in a mean-variance world?
76

Assume that you had to pick between two investments. They


have the same expected return of 15% and the same
standard deviation of 25%; however, investment A offers a
very small possibility that you could quadruple your money,
while investment Bs highest possible payoff is a 60% return.
Would you
a. be indifferent between the two investments, since they have the
same expected return and standard deviation?
b. prefer investment A, because of the possibility of a high payoff?
b. prefer investment B, because it is safer?
Would your answer change if you were not told that there is a
small possibility that you could lose 100% of your money on
investment A but that your worst case scenario with
investment B is -50%?

Aswath Damodaran
76
The Importance of Diversification: Risk Types
77

Figure 3.5: A Break Down of Risk

Competition
may be stronger
or weaker than Exchange rate
anticipated and Political
risk
Projects may
do better or Interest rate,
worse than Entire Sector Inflation &
may be affected news about
expected by action economy

Firm-specific Market

Actions/Risk that Actions/Risk that


affect only one Affects few Affects many affect all investments
firm firms firms
Firm can Investing in lots Acquiring Diversifying Diversifying Cannot affect
reduce by of projects competitors across sectors across countries

Investors Diversifying across domestic stocks Diversifying globally Diversifying across


can asset classes
mitigate by

Aswath Damodaran
77
Why diversification reduces/eliminates
firm specific risk
78

Firm-specific risk can be reduced, if not eliminated, by


increasing the number of investments in your portfolio
(i.e., by being diversified). Market-wide risk cannot. This
can be justified on either economic or statistical
grounds.
On economic grounds, diversifying and holding a larger
portfolio eliminates firm-specific risk for two reasons-
a. Each investment is a much smaller percentage of the portfolio,
muting the effect (positive or negative) on the overall
portfolio.
b. Firm-specific actions can be either positive or negative. In a
large portfolio, it is argued, these effects will average out to
zero. (For every firm, where something bad happens, there will
be some other firm, where something good happens.)

Aswath Damodaran
78
The Role of the Marginal Investor
79

The marginal investor in a firm is the investor who is


most likely to be the buyer or seller on the next trade
and to influence the stock price.
Generally speaking, the marginal investor in a stock has
to own a lot of stock and also trade that stock on a
regular basis.
Since trading is required, the largest investor may not be
the marginal investor, especially if he or she is a
founder/manager of the firm (Larry Ellison at Oracle,
Mark Zuckerberg at Facebook)
In all risk and return models in finance, we assume that
the marginal investor is well diversified.

Aswath Damodaran
79
Identifying the Marginal Investor in your firm
80

Percent of Stock held Percent of Stock held by Marginal Investor


by Institutions Insiders
High Low Institutional Investor
High High Institutional Investor, with insider influence
Low High (held by Tough to tell; Could be insiders but only if they
founder/manager of firm) trade. If not, it could be individual investors.
Low High (held by wealthy Wealthy individual investor, fairly diversified
individual investor)
Low Low Small individual investor with restricted
diversification

Aswath Damodaran
80
Gauging the marginal investor: Disney in
2013

Aswath Damodaran
81
Extending the assessment of the investor
base
In all five of the publicly traded companies that we
are looking at, institutions are big holders of the
companys stock.

Aswath Damodaran
82
The Limiting Case: The Market Portfolio
83

The big assumptions & the follow up: Assuming diversification costs
nothing (in terms of transactions costs), and that all assets can be
traded, the limit of diversification is to hold a portfolio of every
single asset in the economy (in proportion to market value). This
portfolio is called the market portfolio.
The consequence: Individual investors will adjust for risk, by
adjusting their allocations to this market portfolio and a riskless
asset (such as a T-Bill):
Preferred risk level Allocation decision
No risk 100% in T-Bills
Some risk 50% in T-Bills; 50% in Market Portfolio;
A little more risk 25% in T-Bills; 75% in Market Portfolio
Even more risk 100% in Market Portfolio
A risk hog.. Borrow money; Invest in market portfolio

Aswath Damodaran
83
The Risk of an Individual Asset
84

The essence: The risk of any asset is the risk that it adds to
the market portfolio Statistically, this risk can be measured by
how much an asset moves with the market (called the
covariance)
The measure: Beta is a standardized measure of this
covariance, obtained by dividing the covariance of any asset
with the market by the variance of the market. It is a measure
of the non-diversifiable risk for any asset can be measured by
the covariance of its returns with returns on a market index,
which is defined to be the asset's beta.
The result: The required return on an investment will be a
linear function of its beta:
Expected Return = Riskfree Rate+ Beta * (Expected Return on the
Market Portfolio - Riskfree Rate)

Aswath Damodaran
84
Limitations of the CAPM
85

1. The model makes unrealistic assumptions


2. The parameters of the model cannot be estimated precisely
The market index used can be wrong.
The firm may have changed during the 'estimation' period'
3. The model does not work well
- If the model is right, there should be:
n A linear relationship between returns and betas
n The only variable that should explain returns is betas
- The reality is that
n The relationship between betas and returns is weak
n Other variables (size, price/book value) seem to explain differences
in returns better.

Aswath Damodaran
85
Alternatives to the CAPM
86
Step 1: Defining Risk
The risk in an investment can be measured by the variance in actual returns around an
expected return
Riskless Investment Low Risk Investment High Risk Investment

E(R) E(R) E(R)


Step 2: Differentiating between Rewarded and Unrewarded Risk
Risk that is specific to investment (Firm Specific) Risk that affects all investments (Market Risk)
Can be diversified away in a diversified portfolio Cannot be diversified away since most assets
1. each investment is a small proportion of portfolio are affected by it.
2. risk averages out across investments in portfolio
The marginal investor is assumed to hold a diversified portfolio. Thus, only market risk will
be rewarded and priced.
Step 3: Measuring Market Risk
The CAPM The APM Multi-Factor Models Proxy Models
If there is If there are no Since market risk affects In an efficient market,
1. no private information arbitrage opportunities most or all investments, differences in returns
2. no transactions cost then the market risk of it must come from across long periods must
the optimal diversified any asset must be macro economic factors. be due to market risk
portfolio includes every captured by betas Market Risk = Risk differences. Looking for
traded asset. Everyone relative to factors that exposures of any variables correlated with
will hold thismarket portfolio affect all investments. asset to macro returns should then give
Market Risk = Risk Market Risk = Risk economic factors. us proxies for this risk.
added by any investment exposures of any Market Risk =
to the market portfolio: asset to market Captured by the
factors Proxy Variable(s)
Beta of asset relative to Betas of asset relative Betas of assets relative Equation relating
Market portfolio (from to unspecified market to specified macro returns to proxy
a regression) factors (from a factor economic factors (from variables (from a
analysis) a regression) regression)

Aswath Damodaran
86
Why the CAPM persists
87

The CAPM, notwithstanding its many critics and limitations,


has survived as the default model for risk in equity valuation
and corporate finance. The alternative models that have been
presented as better models (APM, Multifactor model..) have
made inroads in performance evaluation but not in
prospective analysis because:
The alternative models (which are richer) do a much better job than
the CAPM in explaining past return, but their effectiveness drops off
when it comes to estimating expected future returns (because the
models tend to shift and change).
The alternative models are more complicated and require more
information than the CAPM.
For most companies, the expected returns you get with the the
alternative models is not different enough to be worth the extra
trouble of estimating four additional betas.

Aswath Damodaran
87
Application Test: Who is the marginal investor in
your firm?
88

You can get information on insider and institutional


holdings in your firm from:
http://finance.yahoo.com/
Enter your companys symbol and choose profile.

Looking at the breakdown of stockholders in your


firm, consider whether the marginal investor is
An institutional investor
An individual investor

An insider

Aswath Damodaran
88
Aswath Damodaran 89

From Risk & Return Models to Hurdle


Rates:
Estimation Challenges

The price of purity is purists


Anonymous
Inputs required to use the CAPM -
90

The capital asset pricing model yields the following


expected return:
Expected Return = Riskfree Rate+ Beta * (Expected Return
on the Market Portfolio - Riskfree Rate)
To use the model we need three inputs:
a. The current risk-free rate
b. The expected market risk premium, the premium
expected for investing in risky assets, i.e. the market
portfolio, over the riskless asset.
c. The beta of the asset being analyzed.

Aswath Damodaran
90
The Riskfree Rate and Time Horizon
91

On a riskfree asset, the actual return is equal to the


expected return. Therefore, there is no variance around
the expected return.
For an investment to be riskfree, i.e., to have an actual
return be equal to the expected return, two conditions
have to be met
There has to be no default risk, which generally implies that the
security has to be issued by the government. Note, however,
that not all governments can be viewed as default free.
There can be no uncertainty about reinvestment rates, which
implies that it is a zero coupon security with the same maturity
as the cash flow being analyzed.

Aswath Damodaran
91
Riskfree Rate in Practice
92

The riskfree rate is the rate on a zero coupon default-


free bond matching the time horizon of the cash
flow being analyzed.
Theoretically, this translates into using different
riskfree rates for each cash flow - the 1 year zero
coupon rate for the cash flow in year 1, the 2-year
zero coupon rate for the cash flow in year 2 ...
Practically speaking, if there is substantial
uncertainty about expected cash flows, the present
value effect of using time varying riskfree rates is
small enough that it may not be worth it.
Aswath Damodaran
92
The Bottom Line on Riskfree Rates

If the government is default-free, using a long term government rate


(even on a coupon bond) as the risk free rate on all of the cash flows in a
long term analysis will yield a close approximation of the true value. For
short term analysis, it is entirely appropriate to use a short term
government security rate as the riskfree rate.
The riskfree rate that you use in an analysis should be in the same
currency that your cashflows are estimated in.
In other words, if your cashflows are in U.S. dollars, your riskfree rate has to be in
U.S. dollars as well.
If your cash flows are in Euros, your riskfree rate should be a Euro riskfree rate.
The conventional practice of estimating riskfree rates is to use the
government bond rate, with the government being the one that is in
control of issuing that currency. In November 2013, for instance, the rate
on a ten-year US treasury bond (2.75%) is used as the risk free rate in US
dollars.

Aswath Damodaran
93
What is the Euro riskfree rate? An exercise
in November 2013
Rate on 10-year Euro Government Bonds: November 2013

9.00% 8.30%

8.00%

7.00% 6.42%
5.90%
6.00%

5.00%
3.90% 3.95%
4.00% 3.30%

3.00% 2.35%
2.10% 2.15%
1.75%
2.00%

1.00%

0.00%
Germany Austria France Belgium Ireland Italy Spain Portugal Slovenia Greece

Aswath Damodaran
94
When the government is default free: Risk
free rates in November 2013

Aswath Damodaran
95
What if there is no default-free entity?
Risk free rates in November 2013
Adjust the local currency government borrowing rate for default risk to
get a riskless local currency rate.
In November 2013, the Indian government rupee bond rate was 8.82%. the local
currency rating from Moodys was Baa3 and the default spread for a Baa3 rated
country bond was 2.25%.
Riskfree rate in Rupees = 8.82% - 2.25% = 6.57%
In November 2013, the Chinese Renmimbi government bond rate was 4.30% and
the local currency rating was Aa3, with a default spread of 0.8%.
Riskfree rate in Chinese Renmimbi = 4.30% - 0.8% = 3.5%
Do the analysis in an alternate currency, where getting the riskfree rate is
easier. With Vale in 2013, we could chose to do the analysis in US dollars
(rather than estimate a riskfree rate in R$). The riskfree rate is then the
US treasury bond rate.
Do your analysis in real terms, in which case the riskfree rate has to be a
real riskfree rate. The inflation-indexed treasury rate is a measure of a real
riskfree rate.

Aswath Damodaran
96
Three paths to estimating sovereign
default spreads
97

Sovereign dollar or euro denominated bonds: The difference


between the interest rate on a sovereign US $ bond, issued
by the country, and the US treasury bond rate can be used as
the default spread. For example, in November 2013, the 10-
year Brazil US $ bond, denominated in US dollars had a yield
of 4.25% and the US 10-year T.Bond rate traded at 2.75%.
Default spread = 4.25% - 2.75% = 1.50%
CDS spreads: Obtain the default spreads for sovereigns in the
CDS market. The CDS spread for Brazil in November 2013 was
2.50%.
Average spread: If you know the sovereign rating for a
country, you can estimate the default spread based on the
rating. In November 2013, Brazils rating was Baa2, yielding a
default spread of 2%.
Aswath Damodaran
97
Risk free rates in currencies: Sovereigns
with default risk in November 2013
98

Figure 4.2: Risk free rates in Currencies where Governments not Aaa
rated
16.00%

14.00%

12.00%

10.00%

8.00%
Default Spread
6.00%
Risk free rate
4.00%

2.00%

0.00%

Aswath Damodaran
98
99

-5.00%
0.00%
5.00%
10.00%
15.00%
20.00%
25.00%
Japanese Yen
Czech Koruna
Croatian Kuna
Bulgarian Lev
Swiss Franc
Euro

Aswath Damodaran
Danish Krone
Taiwanese $
Pakistani Rupee
Swedish Krona
Hungarian Forint
British Pound
Thai Baht
Vietnamese Dong
Romanian Leu
Israeli Shekel
HK $

Risk free Rate


Korean Won
Norwegian Krone
Canadian $
Chinese Yuan
Phillipine Peso
US $
Singapore $
Polish Zloty
Risk free Rates - January 2017

Australian $
Default Spread based on rating Malyasian Ringgit
NZ $
Chilean Peso
Risk free Rates in January 2017

Iceland Krona
Indian Rupee
Colombian Peso
Peruvian Sol
Indonesian Rupiah
Russian Ruble
Mexican Peso
South African Rand
Venezuelan Bolivar
Brazilian Reai
Turkish Lira
Kenyan Shilling
Nigerian Naira
99
Measurement of the risk premium
100

The risk premium is the premium that investors


demand for investing in an average risk investment,
relative to the riskfree rate.
As a general proposition, this premium should be
greater than zero
increase with the risk aversion of the investors in that
market
increase with the riskiness of the average risk
investment

Aswath Damodaran
100
What is your risk premium?

Assume that stocks are the only risky assets and that you are
offered two investment options:
a riskless investment (say a Government Security), on which you can
make 3%
a mutual fund of all stocks, on which the returns are uncertain
How much of an expected return would you demand to shift
your money from the riskless asset to the mutual fund?
a. Less than 3%
b. Between 3% - 5%
c. Between 5% - 7%
d. Between 7% -9%
e. Between 9%- 11%
f. More than 11%

Aswath Damodaran
101
Risk Aversion and Risk Premiums
102

If this were the entire market, the risk premium


would be a weighted average of the risk premiums
demanded by each and every investor.
The weights will be determined by the wealth that
each investor brings to the market. Thus, Warren
Buffetts risk aversion counts more towards
determining the equilibrium premium than yours
and mine.
As investors become more risk averse, you would
expect the equilibrium premium to increase.

Aswath Damodaran
102
Risk Premiums do change..
103

Go back to the previous example. Assume now that


you are making the same choice but that you are
making it in the aftermath of a stock market crash (it
has dropped 25% in the last month). Would you
change your answer?
a. I would demand a larger premium
b. I would demand a smaller premium
c. I would demand the same premium

Aswath Damodaran
103
Estimating Risk Premiums in Practice
104

Survey investors on their desired risk premiums and


use the average premium from these surveys.
Assume that the actual premium delivered over long
time periods is equal to the expected premium - i.e.,
use historical data
Estimate the implied premium in todays asset
prices.

Aswath Damodaran
104
The Survey Approach
105

Surveying all investors in a market place is impractical.


However, you can survey a few individuals and use these results. In
practice, this translates into surveys of the following:

The limitations of this approach are:


There are no constraints on reasonability (the survey could produce negative risk
premiums or risk premiums of 50%)
The survey results are more reflective of the past than the future.
They tend to be short term; even the longest surveys do not go beyond one year.

Aswath Damodaran
105
The Historical Premium Approach
106

This is the default approach used by most to arrive at the


premium to use in the model
In most cases, this approach does the following
Defines a time period for the estimation (1928-Present, last 50 years...)
Calculates average returns on a stock index during the period
Calculates average returns on a riskless security over the period
Calculates the difference between the two averages and uses it as a
premium looking forward.
The limitations of this approach are:
it assumes that the risk aversion of investors has not changed in a
systematic way across time. (The risk aversion may change from year
to year, but it reverts back to historical averages)
it assumes that the riskiness of the risky portfolio (stock index) has
not changed in a systematic way across time.

Aswath Damodaran
106
ERP: A Historical Snapshot

Arithmetic Average Geometric Average


Stocks - T. Bills Stocks - T. Bonds Stocks - T. Bills Stocks - T. Bonds
1928-2016 7.96% 6.24% 6.11% 4.62% Historical
Std Error 2.13% 2.28% premium for
1967-2016 6.57% 4.37% 5.26% 3.42% the US
Std Error 2.42% 2.74%
2007-2016 7.91% 3.62% 6.15% 2.30%
Std Error 6.06% 8.66%

If you are going to use a historical risk premium, make it


Long term (because of the standard error)
Consistent with your risk free rate
A compounded average
No matter which estimate you use, recognize that it is
backward looking, is noisy and may reflect selection bias.

107
What about historical premiums for other
markets?
108

Historical data for markets outside the United States


is available for much shorter time periods. The
problem is even greater in emerging markets.
The historical premiums that emerge from this data
reflects this data problem and there is much greater
error associated with the estimates of the
premiums.

Aswath Damodaran
108
One solution: Bond default spreads as CRP
November 2013
In November 2013, the historical risk premium for the US was 4.20%
(geometric average, stocks over T.Bonds, 1928-2012)
Arithmetic Average Geometric Average
Stocks - T. Bills Stocks - T. Bonds Stocks - T. Bills Stocks - T. Bonds
1928-2012 7.65% 5.88% 5.74% 4.20%
2.20% 2.33%
Using the default spread on the sovereign bond or based upon the
sovereign rating and adding that spread to the mature market premium
(4.20% for the US) gives you a total ERP for a country.
Country Rating Default Spread (Country Risk Premium) US ERP Total ERP for country
India Baa3 2.25% 4.20% 6.45%
China Aa3 0.80% 4.20% 5.00%
Brazil Baa2 2.00% 4.20% 6.20%

If you prefer CDS spreads:


Country Sovereign CDS Spread US ERP Total ERP for country
India 4.20% 4.20% 8.40%
China 1.20% 4.20% 5.40%
Brazil 2.59% 4.20% 6.79%

Aswath Damodaran
109
Beyond the default spread? Equities are
riskier than bonds
While default risk spreads and equity risk premiums are highly correlated,
one would expect equity spreads to be higher than debt spreads. One
approach to scaling up the premium is to look at the relative volatility of
equities to bonds and to scale up the default spread to reflect this:

Brazil: The annualized standard deviation in the Brazilian equity index


over the previous year is 21 percent, whereas the annualized standard
deviation in the Brazilian C-bond is 14 percent.
! 21% $
Brazil's Total Risk Premium = 4.20% + 2.00%# & = 7.20%
" 14% %

Using the same approach for China and India:


! 24% $
Equity Risk PremiumIndia = 4.20% + 2.25%# & = 7.80%
" 17% %
! 18% $
Equity Risk PremiumChina = 4.20% + 0.80%# & = 5.64%
" 10% %
Aswath Damodaran
110
Implied ERP in November 2013: Watch
what I pay, not what I say..
If you can observe what investors are willing to pay
for stocks, you can back out an expected return from
that price and an implied equity risk premium.
Base year cash flow (last 12 mths)
Dividends (TTM): 33.22 Expected growth in next 5 years
+ Buybacks (TTM): 49.02 Top down analyst estimate of
= Cash to investors (TTM): 82.35 earnings growth for S&P 500 with
Earnings in TTM: stable payout: 5.59%
Beyond year 5
E(Cash to investors) 86.96 91.82 96.95 102.38 108.10 Expected growth rate =
Riskfree rate = 2.55%
S&P 500 on 11/1/13= Expected CF in year 6 =
1756.54 86.96 91.82 96.95 102.38 108.10 110.86 108.1(1.0255)
1756.54 = + + + + +
(1+ r) (1+ r) (1+ r) (1+ r) (1+ r) (r .0255)(1+ r)5
2 3 4 5

r = Implied Expected Return on Stocks = 8.04%


Minus

Risk free rate = T.Bond rate on 1/1/14=2.55%

Equals
Aswath Damodaran Implied Equity Risk Premium (1/1/14) = 8.04% - 2.55% = 5.49%
111
The bottom line on Equity Risk Premiums
in November 2013
Mature Markets: In November 2013, the number that we chose to use as the
equity risk premium for all mature markets was 5.5%. This was set equal to the
implied premium at that point in time and it was much higher than the historical
risk premium of 4.20% prevailing then (1928-2012 period).
Arithmetic Average Geometric Average
Stocks - T. Bills Stocks - T. Bonds Stocks - T. Bills Stocks - T. Bonds
1928-2012 7.65% 5.88% 5.74% 4.20%
2.20% 2.33%
1962-2012 5.93% 3.91% 4.60% 2.93%
2.38% 2.66%
2002-2012 7.06% 3.08% 5.38% 1.71%
5.82% 8.11%
For emerging markets, we will use the melded default spread approach (where
default spreads are scaled up to reflect additional equity risk) to come up with the
additional risk premium that we will add to the mature market premium. Thus,
markets in countries with lower sovereign ratings will have higher risk premiums
that 5.5%.
! $
Emerging Market ERP = 5.5% + Country Default Spread*## Equity
&& !
" Country Bond %

Aswath Damodaran
112
A Composite way of estimating ERP for
countries
Step 1: Estimate an equity risk premium for a mature market. If your
preference is for a forward looking, updated number, you can
estimate an implied equity risk premium for the US (assuming that
you buy into the contention that it is a mature market)
My estimate: In November 2013, my estimate for the implied premium in
the US was 5.5%. That will also be my estimate for a mature market ERP.
Step 2: Come up with a generic and measurable definition of a mature
market.
My estimate: Any AAA rated country is mature.
Step 3: Estimate the additional risk premium that you will charge for
markets that are not mature. You have two choices:
The default spread for the country, estimated based either on sovereign
ratings or the CDS market.
A scaled up default spread, where you adjust the default spread upwards
for the additional risk in equity markets.

Aswath Damodaran
113
Andorra 7.45% 1.95% Liechtenstein 5.50% 0.00%Albania 12.25% 6.75%
ERP : Nov 2013 Austria 5.50% 0.00% Luxembourg 5.50% 0.00%Armenia 10.23% 4.73% Bangladesh 10.90% 5.40%
Belgium 6.70% 1.20% Malta 7.45% 1.95%Azerbaijan 8.88% 3.38% Cambodia 13.75% 8.25%
Cyprus 22.00% 16.50% Netherlands 5.50% 0.00%Belarus 15.63% 10.13% China 6.94% 1.44%
Denmark 5.50% 0.00% Norway 5.50% 0.00%Bosnia 15.63% 10.13% Fiji 12.25% 6.75%
Finland 5.50% 0.00% Portugal 10.90% 5.40%Bulgaria 8.50% 3.00%
Hong Kong 5.95% 0.45%
France 5.95% 0.45% Spain 8.88% 3.38%Croatia 9.63% 4.13%
India 9.10% 3.60%
Germany 5.50% 0.00% Sweden 5.50% 0.00%Czech Republic 6.93% 1.43%
Indonesia 8.88% 3.38%
Estonia 6.93% 1.43%
Greece 15.63% 10.13% Switzerland 5.50% 0.00% Japan 6.70% 1.20%
Georgia 10.90% 5.40%
Iceland 8.88% 3.38% Turkey 8.88% 3.38%Hungary 9.63% 4.13% Korea 6.70% 1.20%
Ireland 9.63% 4.13% United Kingdom 5.95% 0.45%Kazakhstan 8.50% 3.00% Macao 6.70% 1.20%
Italy 8.50% 3.00% Western Europe 6.72% 1.22%Latvia 8.50% 3.00% Malaysia 7.45% 1.95%
Canada 5.50% 0.00% Lithuania 8.05% 2.55% Mauritius 8.05% 2.55%
United States of America 5.50% 0.00% Country TRP CRP Macedonia 10.90% 5.40% Mongolia 12.25% 6.75%
North America 5.50% 0.00% Angola 10.90% 5.40% Moldova 15.63% 10.13% Pakistan 17.50% 12.00%
Argentina 15.63% 10.13% Benin 13.75% 8.25% Montenegro 10.90% 5.40% Papua NG 12.25% 6.75%
Belize 19.75% 14.25% Botswana 7.15% 1.65% Poland 7.15% 1.65% Philippines 9.63% 4.13%
Bolivia 10.90% 5.40% Burkina Faso 13.75% 8.25% Romania 8.88% 3.38%
Singapore 5.50% 0.00%
Brazil 8.50% 3.00% Cameroon 13.75% 8.25% Russia 8.05% 2.55%
Sri Lanka 12.25% 6.75%
Cape Verde 12.25% 6.75% Serbia 10.90% 5.40%
Chile 6.70% 1.20% Taiwan 6.70% 1.20%
Egypt 17.50% 12.00% Slovakia 7.15% 1.65%
Colombia 8.88% 3.38% Thailand 8.05% 2.55%
Slovenia 9.63% 4.13%
Costa Rica 8.88% 3.38% Gabon 10.90% 5.40% Vietnam 13.75% 8.25%
Ukraine 15.63% 10.13%
Ecuador 17.50% 12.00% Ghana 12.25% 6.75% Asia 7.27% 1.77%
E. Europe & Russia 8.60% 3.10%
El Salvador 10.90% 5.40% Kenya 12.25% 6.75%
Guatemala 9.63% 4.13% Morocco 9.63% 4.13% Bahrain 8.05% 2.55%
Mozambique 12.25% 6.75% Israel 6.93% 1.43% Australia 5.50% 0.00%
Honduras 13.75% 8.25%
Namibia 8.88% 3.38% Jordan 12.25% 6.75% Cook Islands 12.25% 6.75%
Mexico 8.05% 2.55%
Nigeria 10.90% 5.40% Kuwait 6.40% 0.90% New Zealand 5.50% 0.00%
Nicaragua 15.63% 10.13%
Rwanda 13.75% 8.25% Lebanon 12.25% 6.75% Australia & NZ 5.50% 0.00%
Panama 8.50% 3.00%
Paraguay 10.90% 5.40% Senegal 12.25% 6.75% Oman 6.93% 1.43%
Peru 8.50% 3.00% South Africa 8.05% 2.55% Qatar 6.40% 0.90%
Suriname 10.90% 5.40% Tunisia 10.23% 4.73% Saudi Arabia 6.70% 1.20%
UruguayAswath Damodaran
8.88% 3.38% Uganda 12.25% 6.75% United Arab Emirates 6.40% 0.90% Black #: Total ERP
Venezuela 12.25% 6.75% Zambia 12.25% 6.75% Middle East 6.88% 1.38% Red #: Country risk premium
Latin America 9.44% 3.94% Africa 11.22% 5.82% AVG: GDP weighted average
Estimating ERP for Disney: November 2013

Incorporation: The conventional practice on equity risk premiums is to


estimate an ERP based upon where a company is incorporated. Thus, the
cost of equity for Disney would be computed based on the US equity risk
premium, because it is a US company, and the Brazilian ERP would be
used for Vale, because it is a Brazilian company.
Operations: The more sensible practice on equity risk premium is to
estimate an ERP based upon where a company operates. For Disney in
2013:
Proportion of Disneys
Region/ Country ERP
Revenues
US& Canada 82.01% 5.50%
Europe 11.64% 6.72%
Asia-Pacific 6.02% 7.27%
Latin America 0.33% 9.44%
Disney 100.00% 5.76%

Aswath Damodaran
115
ERP for Companies: November 2013
Company Region/ Country Weight ERP
Bookscape United States 100% 5.50%
US & Canada 4.90% 5.50%
Brazil 16.90% 8.50%
Rest of Latin
1.70% 10.09%
America
China 37.00% 6.94%
Vale
Japan 10.30% 6.70%
In November 2013, Rest of Asia 8.50% 8.61%
the mature market Europe 17.20% 6.72%
Rest of World 3.50% 10.06%
premium used was Company 100.00% 7.38%
5.5% India 23.90% 9.10%
China 23.60% 6.94%
UK 11.90% 5.95%
Tata Motors United States 10.00% 5.50%
Mainland Europe 11.70% 6.85%
Rest of World 18.90% 6.98%
Company 100.00% 7.19%
Baidu China 100% 6.94%
Germany 35.93% 5.50%
North America 24.72% 5.50%
Rest of Europe 28.67% 7.02%
Deutsche Bank
Asia-Pacific 10.68% 7.27%
South America 0.00% 9.44%
Company 100.00% 6.12%

Aswath Damodaran
116
The Anatomy of a Crisis: Implied ERP from
September 12, 2008 to January 1, 2009
117

Aswath Damodaran
117
An Implied ERP

Aswath Damodaran
118
119

2016
2015
2014
2013
2012
Implied Premiums in the US: 1960-2016

2011
2010
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
Implied Premium for US Equity Market: 1960-2016

2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998
1997
1996
1995
1994
1993
1992
1991
1990
1989
1988
1987
1986
1985
1984
1983
1982
1981
1980
1979
1978
1977
1976
1975
1974
1973
1972
1971
1970
1969
1968
1967
1966

Aswath Damodaran
1965
1964
1963
1962
1961
1960

7.00%

6.00%

5.00%

4.00%

3.00%

2.00%

1.00%

0.00%
Implied Premium
ERP : Jan 2017

Black #: Total ERP


Red #: Country risk premium
AVG: GDP weighted average
Application Test: Estimating a Market Risk
Premium
121

For your company, get the geographical breakdown of revenues in


the most recent year. Based upon this revenue breakdown and the
most recent country risk premiums, estimate the equity risk
premium that you would use for your company.

This computation was based entirely on revenues. With your


company, what concerns would you have about your estimate
being too high or too low?

Aswath Damodaran
121
Estimating Beta
122

The standard procedure for estimating betas is to regress


stock returns (Rj) against market returns (Rm):
Rj = a + b R m
where a is the intercept and b is the slope of the regression.
The slope of the regression corresponds to the beta of
the stock, and measures the riskiness of the stock.
The R squared (R2) of the regression provides an
estimate of the proportion of the risk (variance) of a firm
that can be attributed to market risk. The balance (1 -
R2) can be attributed to firm specific risk.

Aswath Damodaran
122
Estimating Performance
123

The intercept of the regression provides a simple measure of


performance during the period of the regression, relative to
the capital asset pricing model.
Rj = Rf + b (Rm - Rf)
= Rf (1-b) + b Rm ........... Capital Asset Pricing Model
Rj = a + b Rm ........... Regression Equation
If
a > Rf (1-b) .... Stock did better than expected during regression period
a = Rf (1-b) .... Stock did as well as expected during regression period
a < Rf (1-b) .... Stock did worse than expected during regression period
The difference between the intercept and Rf (1-b) is Jensen's
alpha. If it is positive, your stock did perform better than
expected during the period of the regression.

Aswath Damodaran
123
Setting up for the Estimation
124

Decide on an estimation period


Services use periods ranging from 2 to 5 years for the regression
Longer estimation period provides more data, but firms change.
Shorter periods can be affected more easily by significant firm-specific
event that occurred during the period
Decide on a return interval - daily, weekly, monthly
Shorter intervals yield more observations, but suffer from more noise.
Noise is created by stocks not trading and biases all betas towards one.
Estimate returns (including dividends) on stock
Return = (PriceEnd - PriceBeginning + DividendsPeriod)/ PriceBeginning
Included dividends only in ex-dividend month
Choose a market index, and estimate returns (inclusive of
dividends) on the index for each interval for the period.

Aswath Damodaran
124
Choosing the Parameters: Disney

Period used: 5 years


Return Interval = Monthly
Market Index: S&P 500 Index.
For instance, to calculate returns on Disney in December 2009,
Price for Disney at end of November 2009 = $ 30.22
Price for Disney at end of December 2009 = $ 32.25
Dividends during month = $0.35 (It was an ex-dividend month)
Return =($32.25 - $30.22 + $ 0.35)/$30.22= 7.88%
To estimate returns on the index in the same month
Index level at end of November 2009 = 1095.63
Index level at end of December 2009 = 1115.10
Dividends on index in December 2009 = 1.683
Return =(1115.1 1095.63+1.683)/ 1095.63 = 1.78%

Aswath Damodaran
125
Disneys Historical Beta

!
Return on Disney = .0071 + 1.2517 Return on Market R = 0.73386
(0.10)
Analyzing Disneys Performance

Intercept = 0.712%
This is an intercept based on monthly returns. Thus, it has to be
compared to a monthly riskfree rate.
Between 2008 and 2013
n Average Annualized T.Bill rate = 0.50%
n Monthly Riskfree Rate = 0.5%/12 = 0.042%
n Riskfree Rate (1-Beta) = 0.042% (1-1.252) = -.0105%
The Comparison is then between
Intercept versus Riskfree Rate (1 - Beta)
0.712% versus 0.0105%
Jensens Alpha = 0.712% - (-0.0105)% = 0.723%
Disney did 0.723% better than expected, per month, between
October 2008 and September 2013
Annualized, Disneys annual excess return = (1.00723)12 -1= 9.02%

Aswath Damodaran
127
More on Jensens Alpha
128

If you did this analysis on every stock listed on an exchange, what would the
average Jensens alpha be across all stocks?
a. Depend upon whether the market went up or down during the period
b. Should be zero
c. Should be greater than zero, because stocks tend to go up more often than down.
Disney has a positive Jensens alpha of 9.02% a year between 2008 and 2013.
This can be viewed as a sign that management in the firm did a good job,
managing the firm during the period.
a. True
b. False
Disney has had a positive Jensens alpha between 2008 and 2013. If you were an
investor in early 2014, looking at the stock, you would view this as a sign that the
stock will be a:
a. Good investment for the future
b. Bad investment for the future
c. No information about the future

Aswath Damodaran
128
Estimating Disneys Beta

Slope of the Regression of 1.25 is the beta


Regression parameters are always estimated with error.
The error is captured in the standard error of the beta
estimate, which in the case of Disney is 0.10.
Assume that I asked you what Disneys true beta is, after
this regression.
What is your best point estimate?

What range would you give me, with 67% confidence?

What range would you give me, with 95% confidence?

Aswath Damodaran
129
The Dirty Secret of Standard Error

Distribution of Standard Errors: Beta Estimates for U.S. stocks

1600

1400

1200

1000
Number of Firms

800

600

400

200

0
<.10 .10 - .20 .20 - .30 .30 - .40 .40 -.50 .50 - .75 > .75

Standard Error in Beta Estimate

Aswath Damodaran
130
Breaking down Disneys Risk

R Squared = 73%
This implies that
73% of the risk at Disney comes from market sources
27%, therefore, comes from firm-specific sources
The firm-specific risk is diversifiable and will not be
rewarded.
The R-squared for companies, globally, has increased
significantly since 2008. Why might this be happening?

What are the implications for investors?

Aswath Damodaran
131
The Relevance of R Squared
132

You are a diversified investor trying to decide


whether you should invest in Disney or Amgen. They
both have betas of 1.25, but Disney has an R
Squared of 73% while Amgens R squared is only
25%. Which one would you invest in?
Amgen, because it has the lower R squared
Disney, because it has the higher R squared

You would be indifferent

Would your answer be different if you were an


undiversified investor?
Aswath Damodaran
132
Beta Estimation: Using a Service
(Bloomberg)

Aswath Damodaran
133
Estimating Expected Returns for Disney in
November 2013
Inputs to the expected return calculation
Disneys Beta = 1.25
Riskfree Rate = 2.75% (U.S. ten-year T.Bond rate in
November 2013)
Risk Premium = 5.76% (Based on Disneys operating
exposure)
Expected Return = Riskfree Rate + Beta (Risk Premium)
= 2.75% + 1.25 (5.76%) = 9.95%

Aswath Damodaran
134
Use to a Potential Investor in Disney

As a potential investor in Disney, what does this expected


return of 9.95% tell you?
This is the return that I can expect to make in the long term on Disney,
if the stock is correctly priced and the CAPM is the right model for risk,
This is the return that I need to make on Disney in the long term to
break even on my investment in the stock
Both
Assume now that you are an active investor and that your
research suggests that an investment in Disney will yield
12.5% a year for the next 5 years. Based upon the expected
return of 9.95%, you would
Buy the stock
Sell the stock

Aswath Damodaran
135
How managers use this expected return

Managers at Disney
need to make at least 9.95% as a return for their equity
investors to break even.
this is the hurdle rate for projects, when the investment is
analyzed from an equity standpoint
In other words, Disneys cost of equity is 9.95%.
What is the cost of not delivering this cost of equity?

Aswath Damodaran
136
Application Test: Analyzing the Risk Regression
137

Using your Bloomberg risk and return print out, answer the
following questions:
How well or badly did your stock do, relative to the market, during the
period of the regression?
Intercept - (Riskfree Rate/n) (1- Beta) = Jensens Alpha
n where n is the number of return periods in a year (12 if monthly; 52
if weekly)
What proportion of the risk in your stock is attributable to the market?
What proportion is firm-specific?
What is the historical estimate of beta for your stock? What is the
range on this estimate with 67% probability? With 95% probability?
Based upon this beta, what is your estimate of the required return on
this stock?
Riskless Rate + Beta * Risk Premium

Aswath Damodaran
137
A Quick Test
138

You are advising a very risky software firm on the right cost of
equity to use in project analysis. You estimate a beta of 3.0
for the firm and come up with a cost of equity of 20%. The
CFO of the firm is concerned about the high cost of equity
and wants to know whether there is anything he can do to
lower his beta.
How do you bring your beta down?

Should you focus your attention on bringing your beta down?


Yes
No

Aswath Damodaran
138
Regression Diagnostics for Tata Motors

Beta = 1.83
67% range
1.67-1.99

69% market risk


31% firm specific

Jensens a
= 2.28% - 4%/12 (1-1.83) = 2.56% Expected Return (in Rupees)
Annualized = (1+.0256)12-1= 35.42% = Riskfree Rate+ Beta*Risk premium
Average monthly riskfree rate (2008-13) = 4% = 6.57%+ 1.83 (7.19%) = 19.73%
Aswath Damodaran
139
A better beta? Vale

Aswath Damodaran
140
Deutsche Bank and Baidu: Index Effects on
Risk Parameters
For Deutsche Bank, a widely held European stock,
we tried both the DAX (German index) and the FTSE
European index.

For Baidu, a NASDAQ listed stock, we ran regressions


against both the S&P 500 and the NASDAQ.

Aswath Damodaran
141
Beta: Exploring Fundamentals
142

Beta > 2 Bulgari: 2.45

Qwest Communications: 1.85

Beta
between 1 Microsoft: 1.25
and 2
GE: 1.15

Beta <1 Exxon Mobil: 0.70

Altria (Philip Morris): 0.60

Harmony Gold Mining: -0.15


Beta <0

Aswath Damodaran
142
Determinant 1: Product Type
143

Industry Effects: The beta value for a firm depends


upon the sensitivity of the demand for its products
and services and of its costs to macroeconomic
factors that affect the overall market.
Cyclical companies have higher betas than non-cyclical
firms
Firms which sell more discretionary products will have
higher betas than firms that sell less discretionary products

Aswath Damodaran
143
A Simple Test
144

Phone service is close to being non-discretionary in the


United States and Western Europe. However, in much of
Asia and Latin America, there are large segments of the
population for which phone service is a luxury.
Given our discussion of discretionary and non-
discretionary products, which of the following
conclusions would you be willing to draw:
Emerging market telecom companies should have higher betas
than developed market telecom companies.
Developed market telecom companies should have higher betas
than emerging market telecom companies
The two groups of companies should have similar betas

Aswath Damodaran
144
Determinant 2: Operating Leverage Effects
145

Operating leverage refers to the proportion of the


total costs of the firm that are fixed.
Other things remaining equal, higher operating
leverage results in greater earnings variability which
in turn results in higher betas.

Aswath Damodaran
145
Measures of Operating Leverage
146

Fixed Costs Measure = Fixed Costs / Variable Costs


This measures the relationship between fixed and variable
costs. The higher the proportion, the higher the operating
leverage.
EBIT Variability Measure = % Change in EBIT / %
Change in Revenues
This measures how quickly the earnings before interest
and taxes changes as revenue changes. The higher this
number, the greater the operating leverage.

Aswath Damodaran
146
Disneys Operating Leverage: 1987- 2013

Year Net Sales % Change in EBIT % Change in


Sales EBIT
1987 $2,877 $756
1988 $3,438 19.50% $848 12.17%
1989 $4,594 33.62% $1,177 38.80%
1990 $5,844 27.21% $1,368 16.23%
1991 $6,182 5.78% $1,124 -17.84%
1992 $7,504 21.38% $1,287 14.50%
1993 $8,529 13.66% $1,560 21.21% Average across entertainment companies = 1.35
1994 $10,055 17.89% $1,804 15.64%
1995 $12,112 20.46% $2,262 25.39%
1996 $18,739 54.71% $3,024 33.69%
1997 $22,473 19.93% $3,945 30.46%
Given Disneys operating leverage measures (1.01
1998 $22,976 2.24% $3,843 -2.59% or 1.25), would you expect Disney to have a higher
1999 $23,435 2.00% $3,580 -6.84%
2000 $25,418 8.46% $2,525 -29.47% or a lower beta than other entertainment
2001 $25,172 -0.97% $2,832 12.16%
2002 $25,329 0.62% $2,384 -15.82%
companies?
2003 $27,061 6.84% $2,713 13.80% a.Higher
2004 $30,752 13.64% $4,048 49.21%
2005 $31,944 3.88% $4,107 1.46% b.Lower
2006 $33,747 5.64% $5,355 30.39%
2007 $35,510 5.22% $6,829 27.53%
c.No effect
2008 $37,843 6.57% $7,404 8.42%
2009 $36,149 -4.48% $5,697 -23.06%
2010 $38,063 5.29% $6,726 18.06%
2011 $40,893 7.44% $7,781 15.69%
2012 $42,278 3.39% $8,863 13.91%
2013 $45,041 6.54% $9,450 6.62% Operating Leverage
Average:
87-13 11.79% 11.91% 11.91/11.79 =1.01
Average:
96-13 8.16% 10.20% 10.20/8.16 =1.25
Aswath Damodaran
147
Determinant 3: Financial Leverage
148

As firms borrow, they create fixed costs (interest payments) that


make their earnings to equity investors more volatile. This
increased earnings volatility which increases the equity beta.
The beta of equity alone can be written as a function of the
unlevered beta and the debt-equity ratio
bL = bu (1+ ((1-t)D/E))
where
bL = Levered or Equity Beta D/E = Market value Debt to equity ratio
bu = Unlevered or Asset Beta t = Marginal tax rate

Earlier, we estimated the beta for Disney from a regression. Was


that beta a levered or unlevered beta?
a. Levered
b. Unlevered

Aswath Damodaran
148
Effects of leverage on betas: Disney

The regression beta for Disney is 1.25. This beta is a


levered beta (because it is based on stock prices, which
reflect leverage) and the leverage implicit in the beta
estimate is the average market debt equity ratio during
the period of the regression (2008 to 2013)
The average debt equity ratio during this period was
19.44%.
The unlevered beta for Disney can then be estimated
(using a marginal tax rate of 36.1%)
= Current Beta / (1 + (1 - tax rate) (Average Debt/Equity))
= 1.25 / (1 + (1 - 0.361)(0.1944))= 1.1119

Aswath Damodaran
149
Disney : Beta and Financial Leverage

Debt to Capital Debt/Equity Ratio Beta Effect of Leverage


0.00% 0.00% 1.11 0.00
10.00% 11.11% 1.1908 0.08
20.00% 25.00% 1.29 0.18
30.00% 42.86% 1.42 0.30
40.00% 66.67% 1.59 0.47
50.00% 100.00% 1.82 0.71
60.00% 150.00% 2.18 1.07
70.00% 233.33% 2.77 1.66
80.00% 400.00% 3.95 2.84
90.00% 900.00% 7.51 6.39

Aswath Damodaran
150
Betas are weighted Averages
151

The beta of a portfolio is always the market-value


weighted average of the betas of the individual
investments in that portfolio.
Thus,
the beta of a mutual fund is the weighted average of the
betas of the stocks and other investment in that portfolio
the beta of a firm after a merger is the market-value
weighted average of the betas of the companies involved
in the merger.

Aswath Damodaran
151
The Disney/Cap Cities Merger (1996): Pre-
Merger
152

Disney: The Acquirer

Debt = $3,186 million


Equity Beta Market value of equity = $31,100 million
1.15 Debt + Equity = Firm value = $31,100
+ $3186 = $34,286 million
D/E Ratio = 3186/31100 = 0.10

+
Capital Cities: The Target
Debt = $ 615 million
Equity Beta Market value of equity = $18, 500 million
0.95 Debt + Equity = Firm value = $18,500 +
$615 = $19,115 million
D/E Ratio = 615/18500 = 0.03

Aswath Damodaran
152
Disney Cap Cities Beta Estimation: Step 1
153

Calculate the unlevered betas for both firms


Disneys unlevered beta = 1.15/(1+0.64*0.10) = 1.08
Cap Cities unlevered beta = 0.95/(1+0.64*0.03) = 0.93

Calculate the unlevered beta for the combined firm


Unlevered Beta for combined firm
= 1.08 (34286/53401) + 0.93 (19115/53401)
= 1.026
The weights used are the firm values (and not just the
equity values) of the two firms, since these are unlevered
betas and thus reflects the risks of the entire businesses
and not just the equity]

Aswath Damodaran
153
Disney Cap Cities Beta Estimation: Step 2
154

If Disney had used all equity to buy Cap Cities equity, while assuming Cap
Cities debt, the consolidated numbers would have looked as follows:
Debt = $ 3,186+ $615 = $ 3,801 million
Equity = $ 31,100 + $18,500 = $ 49,600 m (Disney issues $18.5 billion in equity)
D/E Ratio = 3,801/49600 = 7.66%
New Beta = 1.026 (1 + 0.64 (.0766)) = 1.08
Since Disney borrowed $ 10 billion to buy Cap Cities/ABC, funded the rest
with new equity and assumed Cap Cities debt:
The market value of Cap Cities equity is $18.5 billion. If $ 10 billion comes from
debt, the balance ($8.5 billion) has to come from new equity.
Debt = $ 3,186 + $615 million + $ 10,000 = $ 13,801 million
Equity = $ 31,100 + $8,500 = $39,600 million
D/E Ratio = 13,801/39600 = 34.82%
New Beta = 1.026 (1 + 0.64 (.3482)) = 1.25

Aswath Damodaran
154
Firm Betas versus divisional Betas
155

Firm Betas as weighted averages: The beta of a firm


is the weighted average of the betas of its individual
projects.
Firm Betas and Business betas: At a broader level of
aggregation, the beta of a firm is the weighted
average of the betas of its individual division.

Aswath Damodaran
155
Bottom-up versus Top-down Beta
156

The top-down beta for a firm comes from a regression


The bottom up beta can be estimated by doing the following:
Find out the businesses that a firm operates in
Find the unlevered betas of other firms in these businesses
Take a weighted (by sales or operating income) average of these
unlevered betas
Lever up using the firms debt/equity ratio
The bottom up beta is a better estimate than the top down
beta for the following reasons
The standard error of the beta estimate will be much lower
The betas can reflect the current (and even expected future) mix of
businesses that the firm is in rather than the historical mix

Aswath Damodaran
156
Disneys businesses: The financial
breakdown (from 2013 annual report)

Aswath Damodaran
157
Unlevered Betas for businesses Unlevered Beta
(1 - Cash/ Firm Value)

Median
Company Cash/ Business
Sample Median Median Median Unlevered Firm Unlevered
Business Comparable firms size Beta D/E Tax rate Beta Value Beta
US firms in
broadcasting
Media Networks business 26 1.43 71.09% 40.00% 1.0024 2.80% 1.0313
Global firms in
amusement park
Parks & Resorts business 20 0.87 46.76% 35.67% 0.6677 4.95% 0.7024
Studio
Entertainment US movie firms 10 1.24 27.06% 40.00% 1.0668 2.96% 1.0993

Global firms in
Consumer toys/games
Products production & retail 44 0.74 29.53% 25.00% 0.6034 10.64% 0.6752
Global computer
Interactive gaming firms 33 1.03 3.26% 34.55% 1.0085 17.25% 1.2187

Aswath Damodaran
158
A closer look at the process
Studio Entertainment Betas
Enterprise Value (EV) = Market Cap + Debt - Cash
Firm value = Market Cap + Total Debt Gross D/E = Total Debt/ Market
Cap

Aswath Damodaran
159
Backing into a pure play beta: Studio
Entertainment
160

The Median Movie Company


Movie Business 97.04 Beta (movies) = 1.0993 Debt 21.30 Beta (debt) = 0

Equity 78.70 Beta (equity) = 1.24


Cash Businesss 2.96 Beta (cash) = 0.0000

Movie Company 100.0 Beta (company) = 1.0668

1. Start with the median regression beta (equity beta) of 1.24


2. Unlever the beta, using the median gross D/E ratio of 27.06%
Gross D/E ratio = 21.30/78.70 = 27.06%
Unlevered beta = 1.24/ (1+ (1-.4) (.2706)) = 1.0668
3. Take out the cash effect, using the median cash/value of 2.96%
(.0296) (0) + (1-.0296) (Beta of movie business) = 1.0668
Beta of movie business = 1.0668/(1-.0296) = 1.0993
Alternatively, you could have used the net debt to equity ratio
Net D/E ratio = (21.30-2.96)/78.70 = 23.30%
Aswath DamodaranUnlevered beta for movies = 1.24/ (1+(1-.4)(.233)) = 1.0879
160
Disneys unlevered beta: Operations &
Entire Company

Value of Proportion of Unlevered


Business Revenues EV/Sales Business Disney beta Value Proportion
Media Networks $20,356 3.27 $66,580 49.27% 1.03 $66,579.81 49.27%
Parks & Resorts $14,087 3.24 $45,683 33.81% 0.70 $45,682.80 33.81%
Studio Entertainment $5,979 3.05 $18,234 13.49% 1.10 $18,234.27 13.49%
Consumer Products $3,555 0.83 $2,952 2.18% 0.68 $2,951.50 2.18%
Interactive $1,064 1.58 $1,684 1.25% 1.22 $1,683.72 1.25%
Disney Operations $45,041 $135,132 100.00% 0.9239 $135,132.11

Disney has $3.93 billion in cash, invested in close to riskless assets (with a beta of zero).
You can compute an unlevered beta for Disney as a company (inclusive of cash):

Aswath Damodaran
161
The levered beta: Disney and its divisions

To estimate the debt ratios for division, we allocate Disneys total debt
($15,961 million) to its divisions based on identifiable assets.

We use the allocated debt to compute D/E ratios and levered betas.
Business Unlevered beta Value of business D/E ratio Levered beta Cost of Equity
Media Networks 1.0313 $66,580 10.03% 1.0975 9.07%
Parks & Resorts 0.7024 $45,683 11.41% 0.7537 7.09%
Studio Entertainment 1.0993 $18,234 20.71% 1.2448 9.92%
Consumer Products 0.6752 $2,952 117.11% 1.1805 9.55%
Interactive 1.2187 $1,684 41.07% 1.5385 11.61%
Disney Operations 0.9239 $135,132 13.10% 1.0012 8.52%
Aswath Damodaran
162
Discussion Issue
163

Assume now that you are the CFO of Disney. The


head of the movie business has come to you with a
new big budget movie that he would like you to
fund. He claims that his analysis of the movie
indicates that it will generate a return on equity of
9.5%. Would you fund it?
Yes. It is higher than the cost of equity for Disney as a
company
No. It is lower than the cost of equity for the movie
business.
What are the broader implications of your choice?

Aswath Damodaran
163
Estimating Bottom Up Betas & Costs of
Equity: Vale
Sample' Unlevered'beta' Peer'Group' Value'of' Proportion'of'
Business' Sample' size' of'business' Revenues' EV/Sales' Business' Vale'

Global'firms'in'metals'&'
Metals'&' mining,'Market'cap>$1'
Mining' billion' 48' 0.86' $9,013' 1.97' $17,739' 16.65%'

Iron'Ore' Global'firms'in'iron'ore' 78' 0.83' $32,717' 2.48' $81,188' 76.20%'

Global'specialty'
Fertilizers' chemical'firms' 693' 0.99' $3,777' 1.52' $5,741' 5.39%'

Global'transportation'
Logistics' firms' 223' 0.75' $1,644' 1.14' $1,874' 1.76%'
Vale'
Operations' '' '' 0.8440' $47,151' '' $106,543' 100.00%'

Aswath Damodaran
164
Vale: Cost of Equity Calculation in
nominal $R
To convert a discount rate in one currency to another, all you need are
expected inflation rates in the two currencies.
(1+ Inflation Rate Brazil )
(1+ $ Cost of Equity) 1
(1+ Inflation Rate US )

From US $ to R$: If we use 2% as the inflation rate in US dollars and 9% as


the inflation ratio in Brazil, we can convert Vales US dollar cost of equity

of 11.23% to a $R cost of equity:

Alternatively, you can compute a cost of equity, starting with the $R


riskfree rate of 10.18%.
Cost of Equity in $R = = 10.18% + 1.15 (7.38%) = 18.67%

Aswath Damodaran
165
Bottom up betas & Costs of Equity: Tata
Motors & Baidu
Tata Motors: We estimated an unlevered beta of 0.8601
across 76 publicly traded automotive companies (globally)
and estimated a levered beta based on Tata Motors D/E ratio
of 41.41% and a marginal tax rate of 32.45% for India:
Levered Beta for Tata Motors = 0.8601 (1 + (1-.3245) (.4141)) = 1.1007
Cost of equity for Tata Motors (Rs) = 6.57% + 1.1007 (7.19%) = 14.49%
Baidu: To estimate its beta, we looked at 42 global companies
that derive all or most of their revenues from online
advertising and estimated an unlevered beta of 1.30 for the
business. Incorporating Baidus current market debt to equity
ratio of 5.23% and the marginal tax rate for China of 25%, we
estimate Baidus current levered beta to be 1.3560.
Levered Beta for Baidu = 1.30 (1 + (1-.25) (.0523)) = 1.356
Cost of Equity for Baidu (Renmimbi) = 3.50% + 1.356 (6.94%) = 12.91%

Aswath Damodaran
166
Bottom up Betas and Costs of Equity:
Deutsche Bank
We break Deutsche Bank down into two businesses commercial and
investment banking.

We do not unlever or relever betas, because estimating debt and equity


for banks is an exercise in futility. Using a riskfree rate of 1.75% (Euro risk
free rate) and Deutsches ERP of 6.12%:

Aswath Damodaran
167
Estimating Betas for Non-Traded Assets
168

The conventional approaches of estimating betas


from regressions do not work for assets that are not
traded. There are no stock prices or historical
returns that can be used to compute regression
betas.
There are two ways in which betas can be estimated
for non-traded assets
Using comparable firms
Using accounting earnings

Aswath Damodaran
168
Using comparable firms to estimate beta
for Bookscape

Unlevered beta for book company = 0.8130/ (1+ (1-.4) (.2141)) = 0.7205
Aswath Damodaran Unlevered beta for book business = 0.7205/(1-.05) = 0.7584 169
Estimating Bookscape Levered Beta and
Cost of Equity
Because the debt/equity ratios used in computing
levered betas are market debt equity ratios, and the only
debt equity ratio we can compute for Bookscape is a
book value debt equity ratio, we have assumed that
Bookscape is close to the book industry median market
debt to equity ratio of 21.41 percent.
Using a marginal tax rate of 40 percent for Bookscape,
we get a levered beta of 0.8558.
Levered beta for Bookscape = 0.7584[1 + (1 0.40) (0.2141)] = 0.8558
Using a riskfree rate of 2.75% (US treasury bond rate)
and an equity risk premium of 5.5%:
Cost of Equity = 2.75%+ 0.8558 (5.5%) = 7.46%

Aswath Damodaran
170
Is Beta an Adequate Measure of Risk for a
Private Firm?
Beta measures the risk added on to a diversified
portfolio. The owners of most private firms are not
diversified. Therefore, using beta to arrive at a cost
of equity for a private firm will
a. Under estimate the cost of equity for the private firm
b. Over estimate the cost of equity for the private firm
c. Could under or over estimate the cost of equity for the
private firm

Aswath Damodaran
171
Total Risk versus Market Risk

Adjust the beta to reflect total risk rather than market risk.
This adjustment is a relatively simple one, since the R squared
of the regression measures the proportion of the risk that is
market risk.
Total Beta = Market Beta / Correlation of the sector with the market
In the Bookscape example, where the market beta is 0.8558
and the median R-squared of the comparable publicly traded
firms is 26.00%; the correlation with the market is 50.99%.
Market Beta 0.8558
= = 1.6783
R squared .5099

Total Cost of Equity = 2.75 + 1.6783 (5.5%) = 11.98%

Aswath Damodaran
172
Application Test: Estimating a Bottom-up Beta
173

Based upon the business or businesses that your


firm is in right now, and its current financial leverage,
estimate the bottom-up unlevered beta for your
firm.

Data Source: You can get a listing of unlevered betas


by industry on my web site by going to updated
data.

Aswath Damodaran
173
From Cost of Equity to Cost of Capital
174

The cost of capital is a composite cost to the firm of


raising financing to fund its projects.
In addition to equity, firms can raise capital from
debt

Aswath Damodaran
174
What is debt?
175

General Rule: Debt generally has the following


characteristics:
Commitment to make fixed payments in the future
The fixed payments are tax deductible
Failure to make the payments can lead to either default or
loss of control of the firm to the party to whom payments
are due.
As a consequence, debt should include
Any interest-bearing liability, whether short term or long
term.
Any lease obligation, whether operating or capital.

Aswath Damodaran
175
Estimating the Cost of Debt
176

If the firm has bonds outstanding, and the bonds are traded,
the yield to maturity on a long-term, straight (no special
features) bond can be used as the interest rate.
If the firm is rated, use the rating and a typical default spread
on bonds with that rating to estimate the cost of debt.
If the firm is not rated,
and it has recently borrowed long term from a bank, use the interest
rate on the borrowing or
estimate a synthetic rating for the company, and use the synthetic
rating to arrive at a default spread and a cost of debt
The cost of debt has to be estimated in the same currency as
the cost of equity and the cash flows in the valuation.

Aswath Damodaran
176
The easy route: Outsourcing the
measurement of default risk
For those firms that have bond ratings from global
ratings agencies, I used those ratings:
Company S&P Rating Risk-Free Rate Default Spread Cost of Debt
Disney A 2.75% (US $) 1.00% 3.75%
Deutsche Bank A 1.75% (Euros) 1.00% 2.75%
Vale A- 2.75% (US $) 1.30% 4.05%

If you want to estimate Vales cost of debt in $R


terms, we can again use the differential inflation
approach we used for the cost of equity:

Aswath Damodaran
177
A more general route: Estimating Synthetic
Ratings
The rating for a firm can be estimated using the
financial characteristics of the firm. In its simplest
form, we can use just the interest coverage ratio:
Interest Coverage Ratio = EBIT / Interest Expenses
For the non-financial service companies, we obtain
the following:
Company Operating income Interest Expense Interest coverage ratio
Disney $10.023 $444 22.57
Vale $15,667 $1,342 11.67
Tata Motors Rs 166,605 Rs 36,972 4.51
Baidu CY 11,193 CY 472 23.72
Bookscape $2,536 $492 5.16

Aswath Damodaran
178
Interest Coverage Ratios, Ratings and
Default Spreads- November 2013

Disney: Large cap, developed 22.57 AAA


Vale: Large cap, emerging 11.67 AA
Tata Motors: Large cap, Emerging 4.51 A-
Baidu: Small cap, Emerging 23.72 AAA
Bookscape: Small cap, private 5.16 A-
Aswath Damodaran
179
Synthetic versus Actual Ratings: Rated
Firms
Disneys synthetic rating is AAA, whereas its actual rating is A.
The difference can be attributed to any of the following:
Synthetic ratings reflect only the interest coverage ratio whereas
actual ratings incorporate all of the other ratios and qualitative factors
Synthetic ratings do not allow for sector-wide biases in ratings
Synthetic rating was based on 2013 operating income whereas actual
rating reflects normalized earnings
Vales synthetic rating is AA, but the actual rating for dollar
debt is A-. The biggest factor behind the difference is the
presence of country risk, since Vale is probably being rated
lower for being a Brazil-based corporation.
Deutsche Bank had an A rating. We will not try to estimate a
synthetic rating for the bank. Defining interest expenses on
debt for a bank is difficult

Aswath Damodaran
180
Estimating Cost of Debt

For Bookscape, we will use the synthetic rating (A-) to estimate the cost of
debt:
Default Spread based upon A- rating = 1.30%
Pre-tax cost of debt = Riskfree Rate + Default Spread = 2.75% + 1.30% = 4.05%
After-tax cost of debt = Pre-tax cost of debt (1- tax rate) = 4.05% (1-.40) = 2.43%
For the three publicly traded firms that are rated in our sample, we will
use the actual bond ratings to estimate the costs of debt.
Company S&P Rating Risk-Free Rate Default Spread Cost of Debt Tax Rate After-Tax Cost of Debt
Disney A 2.75% (US $) 1.00% 3.75% 36.1% 2.40%
Deutsche Bank A 1.75% (Euros) 1.00% 2.75% 29.48% 1.94%
Vale A- 2.75% (US $) 1.30% 4.05% 34% 2.67%

For Tata Motors, we have a rating of AA- from CRISIL, an Indian bond-
rating firm, that measures only company risk. Using that rating:
Cost of debtTMT = Risk free rateRupees + Default spreadIndia + Default spreadTMT
= 6.57% + 2.25% + 0.70% = 9.62%
After-tax cost of debt = 9.62% (1-.3245) = 6.50%

Aswath Damodaran
181
Default Spreads January 2017

Default Spreads for 10-year Corporate Bonds: 2015 thru 2017


25.00%

20.00%

15.00%
Axis Title

10.00%

5.00%

0.00%
Aaa/AA Baa2/BB
Aa2/AA A1/A+ A2/A A3/A- Ba1/BB+ Ba2/BB B1/B+ B2/B B3/B- Caa/CCC Ca2/CC C2/C D2/D
A B
Spread: 2017 0.60% 0.80% 1.00% 1.10% 1.25% 1.60% 2.50% 3.00% 3.75% 4.50% 5.50% 6.50% 8.00% 10.50% 14.00%
Spread: 2016 0.75% 1.00% 1.10% 1.25% 1.75% 2.25% 3.25% 4.25% 5.50% 6.50% 7.50% 9.00% 12.00% 16.00% 20.00%
Spread: 2015 0.40% 0.70% 0.90% 1.00% 1.20% 1.75% 2.75% 3.25% 4.00% 5.00% 6.00% 7.00% 8.00% 10.00% 12.00%

Aswath Damodaran
182
Application Test: Estimating a Cost of Debt
183

Based upon your firms current earnings before


interest and taxes, its interest expenses, estimate
An interest coverage ratio for your firm
A synthetic rating for your firm (use the tables from prior
pages)
A pre-tax cost of debt for your firm

An after-tax cost of debt for your firm

Aswath Damodaran
183
Costs of Hybrids
184

Preferred stock shares some of the characteristics of


debt - the preferred dividend is pre-specified at the time
of the issue and is paid out before common dividend --
and some of the characteristics of equity - the payments
of preferred dividend are not tax deductible. If preferred
stock is viewed as perpetual, the cost of preferred stock
can be written as follows:
kps = Preferred Dividend per share/ Market Price per
preferred share
Convertible debt is part debt (the bond part) and part
equity (the conversion option). It is best to break it up
into its component parts and eliminate it from the mix
altogether.

Aswath Damodaran
184
Weights for Cost of Capital Calculation
185

The weights used in the cost of capital computation should be


market values.
There are three specious arguments used against market
value
Book value is more reliable than market value because it is not as
volatile: While it is true that book value does not change as much as
market value, this is more a reflection of weakness than strength
Using book value rather than market value is a more conservative
approach to estimating debt ratios: For most companies, using book
values will yield a lower cost of capital than using market value
weights.
Since accounting returns are computed based upon book value,
consistency requires the use of book value in computing cost of
capital: While it may seem consistent to use book values for both
accounting return and cost of capital calculations, it does not make
economic sense.

Aswath Damodaran
185
Disney: From book value to market value
for interest bearing debt
In Disneys 2013 financial statements, the debt due over time was footnoted.
Weight
Time due Amount due Weight
*Maturity
0.5 $1,452 11.96% 0.06 The debt in this table does
2 $1,300 10.71% 0.21
not add up to the book value
3 $1,500 12.36% 0.37
of debt, because Disney
4 $2,650 21.83% 0.87
6 $500 4.12% 0.25
does not break down the
8 $1,362 11.22% 0.9 maturity of all of its debt.
9 $1,400 11.53% 1.04
19 $500 4.12% 0.78
26 $25 0.21% 0.05
28 $950 7.83% 2.19
29 $500 4.12% 1.19
$12,139 7.92
Disneys total debt due, in book value terms, on the balance sheet is $14,288
million and the total interest expense for the year was $349 million. Using 3.75%
as the pre-tax cost of debt: " 1 %
$ (1 (1.0375) '
Estimated MV of Disney Debt = 349 $ '+
7.92
14, 288
= $13, 028 million
7.92
$ .0375 ' (1.0375)
$# '&

Aswath Damodaran
186
Operating Leases at Disney

The debt value of operating leases is the present


value of the lease payments, at a rate that reflects
their risk, usually the pre-tax cost of debt.
The pre-tax cost of debt at Disney is 3.75%.
Year Commitment Present Value @3.75%
1 $507.00 $488.67 Disney reported $1,784 million
2 $422.00 $392.05 in commitments after year 5.
3 $342.00 $306.24 Given that their average
4 $272.00 $234.76 commitment over the first 5
5 $217.00 $180.52 years, we assumed 5 years @
6-10 $356.80 $1,330.69 $356.8 million each.
Debt value of leases $2,932.93

Debt outstanding at Disney = $13,028 + $ 2,933= $15,961 million

Aswath Damodaran
187
Application Test: Estimating Market Value
188

Estimate the
Market value of equity at your firm and Book Value of
equity
Market value of debt and book value of debt (If you cannot
find the average maturity of your debt, use 3 years):
Remember to capitalize the value of operating leases and
add them on to both the book value and the market value
of debt.
Estimate the
Weights for equity and debt based upon market value
Weights for equity and debt based upon book value

Aswath Damodaran
188
Current Cost of Capital: Disney

Equity
Cost of Equity = Riskfree rate + Beta * Risk Premium
= 2.75% + 1.0013 (5.76%) = 8.52%
Market Value of Equity = $121,878 million
Equity/(Debt+Equity ) = 88.42%
Debt
After-tax Cost of debt =(Riskfree rate + Default Spread) (1-t)
= (2.75%+1%) (1-.361) = 2.40%
Market Value of Debt = $13,028+ $2933 = $ 15,961 million
Debt/(Debt +Equity) = 11.58%
Cost of Capital = 8.52%(.8842)+ 2.40%(.1158) = 7.81%
Aswath Damodaran
121,878/ (121,878+15,961)
189
Divisional Costs of Capital: Disney and Vale

Disney
Cost!of! Cost!of! Marginal!tax! After6tax!cost!of! Debt! Cost!of!
!! equity! debt! rate! debt! ratio! capital!
Media!Networks! 9.07%! 3.75%! 36.10%! 2.40%! 9.12%! 8.46%!
Parks!&!Resorts! 7.09%! 3.75%! 36.10%! 2.40%! 10.24%! 6.61%!
Studio!
Entertainment! 9.92%! 3.75%! 36.10%! 2.40%! 17.16%! 8.63%!
Consumer!Products! 9.55%! 3.75%! 36.10%! 2.40%! 53.94%! 5.69%!
Interactive! 11.65%! 3.75%! 36.10%! 2.40%! 29.11%! 8.96%!
Disney!Operations! 8.52%! 3.75%! 36.10%! 2.40%! 11.58%! 7.81%!

Vale
Cost of After-tax cost of Debt Cost of capital (in Cost of capital (in
Business equity debt ratio US$) $R)
Metals &
Mining 11.35% 2.67% 35.48% 8.27% 15.70%
Iron Ore 11.13% 2.67% 35.48% 8.13% 15.55%
Fertilizers 12.70% 2.67% 35.48% 9.14% 16.63%
Logistics 10.29% 2.67% 35.48% 7.59% 14.97%
Vale Operations 11.23% 2.67% 35.48% 8.20% 15.62%
Aswath Damodaran
190
Costs of Capital: Tata Motors, Baidu and
Bookscape
To estimate the costs of capital for Tata Motors in Indian
rupees:
Cost of capital= 14.49% (1-.2928) + 6.50% (.2928) = 12.15%
For Baidu, we follow the same path to estimate a cost of
equity in Chinese RMB:
Cost of capital = 12.91% (1-.0523) + 3.45% (.0523) = 12.42%
For Bookscape, the cost of capital is different depending on
whether you look at market or total beta:
Cost of After-tax cost of
equity Pre-tax Cost of debt debt D/(D+E) Cost of capital
Market Beta 7.46% 4.05% 2.43% 17.63% 6.57%
Total Beta 11.98% 4.05% 2.43% 17.63% 10.30%

Aswath Damodaran
191
Application Test: Estimating Cost of Capital
192

Using the bottom-up unlevered beta that you computed for


your firm, and the values of debt and equity you have
estimated for your firm, estimate a bottom-up levered beta
and cost of equity for your firm.

Based upon the costs of equity and debt that you have
estimated, and the weights for each, estimate the cost of
capital for your firm.

How different would your cost of capital have been, if you


used book value weights?
Aswath Damodaran
192
Choosing a Hurdle Rate
193

Either the cost of equity or the cost of capital can be


used as a hurdle rate, depending upon whether the
returns measured are to equity investors or to all
claimholders on the firm (capital)
If returns are measured to equity investors, the
appropriate hurdle rate is the cost of equity.
If returns are measured to capital (or the firm), the
appropriate hurdle rate is the cost of capital.

Aswath Damodaran
193
Back to First Principles
194

Aswath Damodaran
194
Aswath Damodaran 195

MEASURING INVESTMENT RETURNS


I: THE MECHANICS OF INVESTMENT
ANALYSIS

Show me the money


from Jerry Maguire
First Principles
196

Aswath Damodaran
196
Measures of return: earnings versus cash flows
197

Principles Governing Accounting Earnings Measurement


Accrual Accounting: Show revenues when products and services are
sold or provided, not when they are paid for. Show expenses
associated with these revenues rather than cash expenses.
Operating versus Capital Expenditures: Only expenses associated with
creating revenues in the current period should be treated as operating
expenses. Expenses that create benefits over several periods are
written off over multiple periods (as depreciation or amortization)
To get from accounting earnings to cash flows:
you have to add back non-cash expenses (like depreciation)
you have to subtract out cash outflows which are not expensed (such
as capital expenditures)
you have to make accrual revenues and expenses into cash revenues
and expenses (by considering changes in working capital).

Aswath Damodaran
197
Measuring Returns Right: The Basic Principles
198

Use cash flows rather than earnings. You cannot spend


earnings.
Use incremental cash flows relating to the investment
decision, i.e., cashflows that occur as a consequence of
the decision, rather than total cash flows.
Use time weighted returns, i.e., value cash flows that
occur earlier more than cash flows that occur later.
The Return Mantra: Time-weighted, Incremental Cash
Flow Return

Aswath Damodaran
198
Setting the table: What is an
investment/project?
199

An investment/project can range the spectrum from big to


small, money making to cost saving:
Major strategic decisions to enter new areas of business or new
markets.
Acquisitions of other firms are projects as well, notwithstanding
attempts to create separate sets of rules for them.
Decisions on new ventures within existing businesses or markets.
Decisions that may change the way existing ventures and projects are
run.
Decisions on how best to deliver a service that is necessary for the
business to run smoothly.
Put in broader terms, every choice made by a firm can be
framed as an investment.

Aswath Damodaran
199
Here are four examples
200

Rio Disney: We will consider whether Disney should invest in its first
theme parks in South America. These parks, while similar to those that
Disney has in other parts of the world, will require us to consider the
effects of country risk and currency issues in project analysis.
New iron ore mine for Vale: This is an iron ore mine that Vale is
considering in Western Labrador, Canada.
An Online Store for Bookscape: Bookscape is evaluating whether it should
create an online store to sell books. While it is an extension of their basis
business, it will require different investments (and potentially expose
them to different types of risk).
Acquisition of Harman by Tata Motors: A cross-border bid by Tata for
Harman International, a publicly traded US firm that manufactures high-
end audio equipment, with the intent of upgrading the audio upgrades on
Tata Motors automobiles. This investment will allow us to examine
currency and risk issues in such a transaction.

Aswath Damodaran
200
Earnings versus Cash Flows: A Disney Theme
Park
201

The theme parks to be built near Rio, modeled on


Euro Disney in Paris and Disney World in Orlando.
The complex will include a Magic Kingdom to be
constructed, beginning immediately, and becoming
operational at the beginning of the second year, and
a second theme park modeled on Epcot Center at
Orlando to be constructed in the second and third
year and becoming operational at the beginning of
the fourth year.
The earnings and cash flows are estimated in
nominal U.S. Dollars.
Aswath Damodaran
201
Key Assumptions on Start Up and Construction
202

Disney has already spent $0.5 Billion researching the proposal and
getting the necessary licenses for the park; none of this investment
can be recovered if the park is not built. This expenditure has been
capitalized and will be depreciated straight line over ten years to a
salvage value of zero.
Disney will face substantial construction costs, if it chooses to build
the theme parks.
The cost of constructing Magic Kingdom will be $3 billion, with $ 2 billion
to be spent right now, and $1 Billion to be spent one year from now.
The cost of constructing Epcot II will be $ 1.5 billion, with $ 1 billion to be
spent at the end of the second year and $0.5 billion at the end of the third
year.
These investments will be depreciated based upon a depreciation
schedule in the tax code, where depreciation will be different each year.

Aswath Damodaran
202
Key Revenue Assumptions
203

Revenue estimates for the parks and resort properties (in millions)
Year Magic Kingdom Epcot II Resort Properties Total
1 $0 $0 $0 $0
2 $1,000 $0 $250 $1,250
3 $1,400 $0 $350 $1.750
4 $1,700 $300 $500 $2.500
5 $2,000 $500 $625 $3.125
6 $2,200 $550 $688 $3,438
7 $2,420 $605 $756 $3,781
8 $2,662 $666 $832 $4,159
9 $2,928 $732 $915 $4,575
10 $2,987 $747 $933 $4,667

Aswath Damodaran
203
Key Expense Assumptions
204

The operating expenses are assumed to be 60% of


the revenues at the parks, and 75% of revenues at
the resort properties.
Disney will also allocate corporate general and
administrative costs to this project, based upon
revenues; the G&A allocation will be 15% of the
revenues each year. It is worth noting that a recent
analysis of these expenses found that only one-third
of these expenses are variable (and a function of
total revenue) and that two-thirds are fixed.
Aswath Damodaran
204
Depreciation and Capital Maintenance
205

The capital maintenance expenditures are low in the


early years, when the parks are still new but increase as
the parks age.

Aswath Damodaran
205
Other Assumptions
206

Disney will have to maintain non-cash working


capital (primarily consisting of inventory at the
theme parks and the resort properties, netted
against accounts payable) of 5% of revenues, with
the investments being made at the end of each year.
The income from the investment will be taxed at
Disneys marginal tax rate of 36.1%.

Aswath Damodaran
206
Laying the groundwork:
Book Capital, Working Capital and Depreciation
207

12.5% of book
value at end of
prior year
($3,000)

Aswath Damodaran
207
Step 1: Estimate Accounting Earnings on Project
208

Aswath Damodaran
208
And the Accounting View of Return
209

After-tax BV of pre- BV of BV of Average


Operating project fixed Working BV of BV of
Year Income investment assets capital Capital Capital ROC(a) ROC(b)
0 500 2000 0 $2,500
1 -$32 $450 $3,000 $0 $3,450 $2,975 -1.07% -1.28%
2 -$96 $400 $3,813 $63 $4,275 $3,863 -2.48% -2.78%
3 -$54 $350 $4,145 $88 $4,582 $4,429 -1.22% -1.26%
4 $68 $300 $4,027 $125 $4,452 $4,517 1.50% 1.48%
5 $202 $250 $3,962 $156 $4,368 $4,410 4.57% 4.53%
6 $249 $200 $3,931 $172 $4,302 $4,335 5.74% 5.69%
7 $299 $150 $3,931 $189 $4,270 $4,286 6.97% 6.94%
8 $352 $100 $3,946 $208 $4,254 $4,262 8.26% 8.24%
9 $410 $50 $3,978 $229 $4,257 $4,255 9.62% 9.63%
10 $421 $0 $4,010 $233 $4,243 $4,250 9.90% 9.89%
Average 4.18% 4.11%

(a) Based upon average book capital over the year


(b) Based upon book capital at the start of each year
Aswath Damodaran
209
What should this return be compared to?

The computed return on capital on this investment is


about 4.18%. To make a judgment on whether this is
a sufficient return, we need to compare this return
to a hurdle rate. Which of the following is the right
hurdle rate? Why or why not?
a. The riskfree rate of 2.75% (T. Bond rate)
b. The cost of equity for Disney as a company (8.52%)
c. The cost of equity for Disney theme parks (7.09%)
d. The cost of capital for Disney as a company (7.81%)
e. The cost of capital for Disney theme parks (6.61%)
f. None of the above
Aswath Damodaran
210
Should there be a risk premium for foreign
projects?
211

The exchange rate risk should be diversifiable risk (and hence


should not command a premium) if
the company has projects is a large number of countries (or)
the investors in the company are globally diversified.
For Disney, this risk should not affect the cost of capital used.
Consequently, we would not adjust the cost of capital for Disneys
investments in other mature markets (Germany, UK, France)
The same diversification argument can also be applied against
some political risk, which would mean that it too should not affect
the discount rate. However, there are aspects of political risk
especially in emerging markets that will be difficult to diversify and
may affect the cash flows, by reducing the expected life or cash
flows on the project.
For Disney, this is the risk that we are incorporating into the cost of
capital when it invests in Brazil (or any other emerging market)

Aswath Damodaran
211
Should there be a risk premium for foreign
projects?
The exchange rate risk should be diversifiable risk (and hence
should not command a premium) if
the company has projects is a large number of countries (or)
the investors in the company are globally diversified.
For Disney, this risk should not affect the cost of capital used.
Consequently, we would not adjust the cost of capital for Disneys
investments in other mature markets (Germany, UK, France)
The same diversification argument can also be applied against
some political risk, which would mean that it too should not affect
the discount rate. However, there are aspects of political risk
especially in emerging markets that will be difficult to diversify and
may affect the cash flows, by reducing the expected life or cash
flows on the project.
For Disney, this is the risk that we are incorporating into the cost of
capital when it invests in Brazil (or any other emerging market)

Aswath Damodaran
212
Estimating a hurdle rate for Rio Disney

We did estimate a cost of capital of 6.61% for the Disney theme park
business, using a bottom-up levered beta of 0.7537 for the business.
This cost of equity may not adequately reflect the additional risk
associated with the theme park being in an emerging market.
The only concern we would have with using this cost of equity for this
project is that it may not adequately reflect the additional risk associated
with the theme park being in an emerging market (Brazil). We first
computed the Brazil country risk premium (by multiplying the default
spread for Brazil by the relative equity market volatility) and then re-
estimated the cost of equity:
Country risk premium for Brazil = 5.5%+ 3% = 8.5%
Cost of Equity in US$= 2.75% + 0.7537 (8.5%) = 9.16%
Using this estimate of the cost of equity, Disneys theme park debt ratio
of 10.24% and its after-tax cost of debt of 2.40% (see chapter 4), we can
estimate the cost of capital for the project:
Cost of Capital in US$ = 9.16% (0.8976) + 2.40% (0.1024) = 8.46%

Aswath Damodaran
213
Would lead us to conclude that...

Do not invest in this park. The return on capital of


4.18% is lower than the cost of capital for theme
parks of 8.46%; This would suggest that the project
should not be taken.
Given that we have computed the average over an
arbitrary period of 10 years, while the theme park
itself would have a life greater than 10 years, would
you feel comfortable with this conclusion?
Yes
No

Aswath Damodaran
214
A Tangent: From New to Existing
Investments: ROC for the entire firm
Assets Liabilities
Existing Investments Fixed Claim on cash flows
Generate cashflows today Assets in Place Debt Little or No role in management
How good are the Includes long lived (fixed) and Fixed Maturity
short-lived(working Tax Deductible
existing investments capital) assets
of the firm?
Expected Value that will be Growth Assets Equity Residual Claim on cash flows
created by future investments Significant Role in management
Perpetual Lives

Measuring ROC for existing investments..

Aswath Damodaran
215
The return on capital is an accounting number,
though, and that should scare you.

Aswath Damodaran
216
Return Spreads Globally.
217

217
6 Application Test: Assessing Investment
Quality
For the most recent period for which you have data,
compute the after-tax return on capital earned by your
firm, where after-tax return on capital is computed to be
After-tax ROC = EBIT (1-tax rate)/ (BV of debt + BV of
Equity-Cash)previous year
For the most recent period for which you have data,
compute the return spread earned by your firm:
Return Spread = After-tax ROC - Cost of Capital
For the most recent period, compute the EVA earned by
your firm
EVA = Return Spread * ((BV of debt + BV of Equity-
Cash)previous year

Aswath Damodaran
218
The cash flow view of this project..

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
After-tax Operating Income -$32 -$96 -$54 $68 $202 $249 $299 $352 $410 $421
+ Depreciation & Amortization $0 $50 $425 $469 $444 $372 $367 $364 $364 $366 $368
- Capital Expenditures $2,500 $1,000 $1,188 $752 $276 $258 $285 $314 $330 $347 $350
- Change in non-cash Work Capital $0 $63 $25 $38 $31 $16 $17 $19 $21 $5
Cashflow to firm ($2,500) ($982) ($921) ($361) $198 $285 $314 $332 $367 $407 $434

To get from income to cash flow, we


I. added back all non-cash charges such as depreciation. Tax
benefits:
II. subtracted out the capital expenditures
III. subtracted out the change in non-cash working capital

Aswath Damodaran
219
The Depreciation Tax Benefit
220

While depreciation reduces taxable income and taxes, it does not reduce
the cash flows.
The benefit of depreciation is therefore the tax benefit. In general, the tax
benefit from depreciation can be written as:
Tax Benefit = Depreciation * Tax Rate
Disney Theme Park: Depreciation tax savings (Tax rate = 36.1%)

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Depreciation $50 $425 $469 $444 $372 $367 $364 $364 $366 $368
Tax Bendfits from Depreciation $18 $153 $169 $160 $134 $132 $132 $132 $132 $133

Proposition 1: The tax benefit from depreciation and other non-cash


charges is greater, the higher your tax rate.
Proposition 2: Non-cash charges that are not tax deductible (such as
amortization of goodwill) and thus provide no tax benefits have no effect
on cash flows.

Aswath Damodaran
220
Depreciation Methods
221

Broadly categorizing, depreciation methods can be classified


as straight line or accelerated methods. In straight line
depreciation, the capital expense is spread evenly over time,
In accelerated depreciation, the capital expense is
depreciated more in earlier years and less in later years.
Assume that you made a large investment this year, and that
you are choosing between straight line and accelerated
depreciation methods. Which will result in higher net income
this year?
Straight Line Depreciation
Accelerated Depreciation
Which will result in higher cash flows this year?
Straight Line Depreciation
Accelerated Depreciation

Aswath Damodaran
221
The Capital Expenditures Effect
222

Capital expenditures are not treated as accounting expenses


but they do cause cash outflows.
Capital expenditures can generally be categorized into two
groups
New (or Growth) capital expenditures are capital expenditures
designed to create new assets and future growth
Maintenance capital expenditures refer to capital expenditures
designed to keep existing assets.
Both initial and maintenance capital expenditures reduce
cash flows
The need for maintenance capital expenditures will increase
with the life of the project. In other words, a 25-year project
will require more maintenance capital expenditures than a 2-
year project.
Aswath Damodaran
222
To cap ex or not to cap ex?
223

Assume that you run your own software business, and


that you have an expense this year of $ 100 million from
producing and distribution promotional CDs in software
magazines. Your accountant tells you that you can
expense this item or capitalize and depreciate it over
three years. Which will have a more positive effect on
income?
Expense it
Capitalize and Depreciate it
Which will have a more positive effect on cash flows?
Expense it
Capitalize and Depreciate it

Aswath Damodaran
223
The Working Capital Effect
224

Intuitively, money invested in inventory or in accounts receivable cannot


be used elsewhere. It, thus, represents a drain on cash flows
To the degree that some of these investments can be financed using
supplier credit (accounts payable), the cash flow drain is reduced.
Investments in working capital are thus cash outflows
Any increase in working capital reduces cash flows in that year
Any decrease in working capital increases cash flows in that year
To provide closure, working capital investments need to be salvaged at
the end of the project life.
Proposition 1: The failure to consider working capital in a capital
budgeting project will overstate cash flows on that project and make it
look more attractive than it really is.
Proposition 2: Other things held equal, a reduction in working capital
requirements will increase the cash flows on all projects for a firm.

Aswath Damodaran
224
The incremental cash flows on the project

$ 500 million has


already been spent & $
50 million in
2/3rd of allocated G&A is fixed.
depreciation will exist Add back this amount (1-t)
anyway Tax rate = 36.1%

Aswath Damodaran
225
A more direct way of getting to
incremental cash flows
226

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Revenues $0 $1,250 $1,750 $2,500 $3,125 $3,438 $3,781 $4,159 $4,575 $4,667
Direct Expenses $0 $788 $1,103 $1,575 $1,969 $2,166 $2,382 $2,620 $2,882 $2,940
Incremental Depreciation $0 $375 $419 $394 $322 $317 $314 $314 $316 $318
Incremental G&A $0 $63 $88 $125 $156 $172 $189 $208 $229 $233
Incremental Operating Income $0 $25 $141 $406 $678 $783 $896 $1,017 $1,148 $1,175
- Taxes $0 $9 $51 $147 $245 $283 $323 $367 $415 $424
Incremental after-tax Operating income $0 $16 $90 $260 $433 $500 $572 $650 $734 $751
+ Incremental Depreciation $0 $375 $419 $394 $322 $317 $314 $314 $316 $318
- Capital Expenditures $2,000 $1,000 $1,188 $752 $276 $258 $285 $314 $330 $347 $350
- Change in non-cash Working Capital $0 $63 $25 $38 $31 $16 $17 $19 $21 $5
Cashflow to firm ($2,000) ($1,000) ($859) ($267) $340 $466 $516 $555 $615 $681 $715

Aswath Damodaran
226
Sunk Costs
227

What is a sunk cost? Any expenditure that has already


been incurred, and cannot be recovered (even if a
project is rejected) is called a sunk cost. A test market for
a consumer product and R&D expenses for a drug (for a
pharmaceutical company) would be good examples.
The sunk cost rule: When analyzing a project, sunk costs
should not be considered since they are not incremental.
A Behavioral Aside: It is a well established finding in
psychological and behavioral research that managers
find it almost impossible to ignore sunk costs.

Aswath Damodaran
227
Test Marketing and R&D: The Quandary of Sunk
Costs
228

A consumer product company has spent $ 100 million on


test marketing. Looking at only the incremental cash
flows (and ignoring the test marketing), the project looks
like it will create $25 million in value for the company.
Should it take the investment?
Yes
No
Now assume that every investment that this company
has shares the same characteristics (Sunk costs > Value
Added). The firm will clearly not be able to survive. What
is the solution to this problem?

Aswath Damodaran
228
Allocated Costs
229

Firms allocate costs to individual projects from a


centralized pool (such as general and administrative
expenses) based upon some characteristic of the
project (sales is a common choice, as is earnings)
For large firms, these allocated costs can be
significant and result in the rejection of projects
To the degree that these costs are not incremental
(and would exist anyway), this makes the firm worse
off. Thus, it is only the incremental component of
allocated costs that should show up in project
analysis.
Aswath Damodaran
229
Breaking out G&A Costs into fixed and variable
components: A simple example
230

Assume that you have a time series of revenues and


G&A costs for a company.

What percentage of the G&A cost is variable?

Aswath Damodaran
230
To Time-Weighted Cash Flows
231

Incremental cash flows in the earlier years are worth


more than incremental cash flows in later years.
In fact, cash flows across time cannot be added up.
They have to be brought to the same point in time
before aggregation.
This process of moving cash flows through time is
discounting, when future cash flows are brought to the
present
compounding, when present cash flows are taken to the
future
Aswath Damodaran
231
Present Value Mechanics
232

Cash Flow Type Discounting Formula Compounding Formula


1. Simple CF CFn / (1+r)n CF0 (1+r)n

2. Annuity ! 1 $
# 1 -
(1+r)n & " (1 + r) n - 1 %
A$
A# & # r
'
&
# r &
#" &%
!
3. Growing Annuity (1+g)n $
#1 - n &
(1+r)
A(1+g) # &
# r-g &
#" &%

4. Perpetuity A/r
5. Growing Perpetuity Expected Cashflow next year/(r-g)

Aswath Damodaran
232
Discounted cash flow measures of return
233

Net Present Value (NPV): The net present value is the


sum of the present values of all cash flows from the
project (including initial investment).
NPV = Sum of the present values of all cash flows on the project,
including the initial investment, with the cash flows being
discounted at the appropriate hurdle rate (cost of capital, if cash
flow is cash flow to the firm, and cost of equity, if cash flow is to
equity investors)
Decision Rule: Accept if NPV > 0
Internal Rate of Return (IRR): The internal rate of return
is the discount rate that sets the net present value equal
to zero. It is the percentage rate of return, based upon
incremental time-weighted cash flows.
Decision Rule: Accept if IRR > hurdle rate

Aswath Damodaran
233
Closure on Cash Flows

In a project with a finite and short life, you would need to compute
a salvage value, which is the expected proceeds from selling all of
the investment in the project at the end of the project life. It is
usually set equal to book value of fixed assets and working capital
In a project with an infinite or very long life, we compute cash flows
for a reasonable period, and then compute a terminal value for this
project, which is the present value of all cash flows that occur after
the estimation period ends..
Assuming the project lasts forever, and that cash flows after year
10 grow 2% (the inflation rate) forever, the present value at the end
of year 10 of cash flows after that can be written as:
Terminal Value in year 10= CF in year 11/(Cost of Capital - Growth Rate)
=715 (1.02) /(.0846-.02) = $ 11,275 million

Aswath Damodaran
234
Which yields a NPV of..

Discounted at Rio Disney cost


Aswath Damodaran of capital of 8.46% 235
Which makes the argument that..

The project should be accepted. The positive net


present value suggests that the project will add
value to the firm, and earn a return in excess of the
cost of capital.
By taking the project, Disney will increase its value as
a firm by $3,296 million.

Aswath Damodaran
236
The IRR of this project

$5,000.00

$4,000.00

$3,000.00

$2,000.00
Internal Rate of Return=12.60%
NPV

$1,000.00

$0.00
8% 9% 10% 11% 12% 13% 14% 15% 16% 17% 18% 19% 20% 21% 22% 23% 24% 25% 26% 27% 28% 29% 30%

-$1,000.00

-$2,000.00

-$3,000.00
Discount Rate

Aswath Damodaran
237
The IRR suggests..

The project is a good one. Using time-weighted, incremental cash


flows, this project provides a return of 12.60%. This is greater than
the cost of capital of 8.46%.
The IRR and the NPV will yield similar results most of the time,
though there are differences between the two approaches that
may cause project rankings to vary depending upon the approach
used. They can yield different results, especially why comparing
across projects because
A project can have only one NPV, whereas it can have more than one IRR.
The NPV is a dollar surplus value, whereas the IRR is a percentage measure
of return. The NPV is therefore likely to be larger for large scale projects,
while the IRR is higher for small-scale projects.
The NPV assumes that intermediate cash flows get reinvested at the
hurdle rate, which is based upon what you can make on investments of
comparable risk, while the IRR assumes that intermediate cash flows get
reinvested at the IRR.

Aswath Damodaran
238
Does the currency matter?

The analysis was done in dollars. Would the


conclusions have been any different if we had done
the analysis in Brazilian Reais?
a. Yes
b. No

Aswath Damodaran
239
The Consistency Rule for Cash Flows
240

The cash flows on a project and the discount rate


used should be defined in the same terms.
If cash flows are in dollars ($R), the discount rate has to be
a dollar ($R) discount rate
If the cash flows are nominal (real), the discount rate has
to be nominal (real).
If consistency is maintained, the project conclusions
should be identical, no matter what cash flows are
used.

Aswath Damodaran
240
Disney Theme Park: Project Analysis in $R
241

The inflation rates were assumed to be 9% in Brazil and 2% in the


United States. The $R/dollar rate at the time of the analysis was
2.35 $R/dollar.
The expected exchange rate was derived assuming purchasing
power parity.
Expected Exchange Ratet = Exchange Rate today * (1.09/1.02)t
The expected growth rate after year 10 is still expected to be the
inflation rate, but it is the 9% $R inflation rate.
The cost of capital in $R was derived from the cost of capital in
dollars and the differences in inflation rates:
$R Cost of Capital = (1+ Exp InflationBrazil )
(1+ US $ Cost of Capital) 1
(1+ Exp InflationUS )

= (1.0846) (1.09/1.02) 1 = 15.91%



Aswath Damodaran
241
Disney Theme Park: $R NPV
Expected Exchange Ratet Discount at $R cost of capital
= Exchange Rate today * (1.09/1.02)t = (1.0846) (1.09/1.02) 1 = 15.91%

NPV = R$ 7,745/2.35= $ 3,296 Million


Aswath Damodaran
NPV is equal to NPV in dollar terms 242
Uncertainty in Project Analysis: What can we
do?
243

Based on our expected cash flows and the estimated cost of capital, the
proposed theme park looks like a very good investment for Disney. Which
of the following may affect your assessment of value?
Revenues may be over estimated (crowds may be smaller and spend less)
Actual costs may be higher than estimated costs
Tax rates may go up
Interest rates may rise
Risk premiums and default spreads may increase
All of the above
How would you respond to this uncertainty?
Will wait for the uncertainty to be resolved
Will not take the investment
Ask someone else (consultant, boss, colleague) to make the decision
Ignore it.
Other

Aswath Damodaran
243
One simplistic solution: See how quickly
you can get your money back
If your biggest fear is losing the billions that you invested in the project,
one simple measure that you can compute is the number of years it will
take you to get your money back.
Year Cash Flow Cumulated CF PV of Cash Flow Cumulated DCF
0 -$2,000 -$2,000 -$2,000 -$2,000
1 -$1,000 -$3,000 -$922 -$2,922
2 -$859 -$3,859 -$730 -$3,652
3 -$267 -$4,126 -$210 -$3,862
4 $340 -$3,786 $246 -$3,616
5 $466 -$3,320 $311 -$3,305
6 $516 -$2,803 $317 -$2,988
7 $555 -$2,248 $314 -$2,674
8 $615 -$1,633 $321 -$2,353
9 $681 -$952 $328 -$2,025
Payback = 10.3 years
10 $715 -$237 $317 -$1,708
11 $729 $491 $298 -$1,409
12 $743 $1,235 $280 -$1,129
13 $758 $1,993 $264 -$865
14 $773 $2,766 $248 -$617 Discounted Payback
15 $789 $3,555 $233 -$384 = 16.8 years
16 $805 $4,360 $219 -$165
Aswath Damodaran 17 $821 $5,181 $206 $41 244
A slightly more sophisticated approach:
Sensitivity Analysis & What-if Questions
The NPV, IRR and accounting returns for an investment will change
as we change the values that we use for different variables.
One way of analyzing uncertainty is to check to see how sensitive
the decision measure (NPV, IRR..) is to changes in key assumptions.
While this has become easier and easier to do over time, there are
caveats that we would offer.
Caveat 1: When analyzing the effects of changing a variable, we
often hold all else constant. In the real world, variables move
together.
Caveat 2: The objective in sensitivity analysis is that we make
better decisions, not churn out more tables and numbers.
Corollary 1: Less is more. Not everything is worth varying
Corollary 2: A picture is worth a thousand numbers (and tables).

Aswath Damodaran
245
And here is a really good picture

Aswath Damodaran
246
The final step up: Incorporate probabilistic
estimates.. Rather than expected values..
Actual Revenues as % of Forecasted Revenues (Base case = 100%)

Country Risk Premium (Base Case = 3%


(Brazil))

!
Operating Expenses at Parks as % of
Revenues (Base Case = 60%)

Aswath Damodaran
247
The resulting simulation
Average = $3.40 billion
Median = $3.28 billion

!
NPV ranges from -$1 billion to +$8.5 billion. NPV is negative 12% of the
time.

Aswath Damodaran
248
You are the decision maker
249

Assume that you are the person at Disney who is given


the results of the simulation. The average and median
NPV are close to your base case values of $3.29 billion.
However, there is a 10% probability that the project
could have a negative NPV and that the NPV could be a
large negative value? How would you use this
information?
I would accept the investment and print the results of this
simulation and file them away to show that I exercised due
diligence.
I would reject the investment, because it is too risky (there is a
10% chance that it could be a bad project)
Other

Aswath Damodaran
249
Equity Analysis: The Parallels
250

The investment analysis can be done entirely in equity


terms, as well. The returns, cashflows and hurdle rates
will all be defined from the perspective of equity
investors.
If using accounting returns,
Return will be Return on Equity (ROE) = Net Income/BV of Equity
ROE has to be greater than cost of equity
If using discounted cashflow models,
Cashflows will be cashflows after debt payments to equity
investors
Hurdle rate will be cost of equity

Aswath Damodaran
250
A Vale Iron Ore Mine in Canada Investment
Operating Assumptions
251

1. The mine will require an initial investment of $1.25 billion and is expected to have a production
capacity of 8 million tons of iron ore, once established. The initial investment of $1.25 billion will
be depreciated over ten years, using double declining balance depreciation, down to a salvage
value of $250 million at the end of ten years.
2. The mine will start production midway through the next year, producing 4 million tons of iron
ore for year 1, with production increasing to 6 million tons in year 2 and leveling off at 8 million
tons thereafter (until year 10). The price, in US dollars per ton of iron ore is currently $100 and is
expected to keep pace with inflation for the life of the plant.
3. The variable cost of production, including labor, material and operating expenses, is expected to
be $45/ton of iron ore produced and there is a fixed cost of $125 million in year 1. Both costs,
which will grow at the inflation rate of 2% thereafter. The costs will be in Canadian dollars, but
the expected values are converted into US dollars, assuming that the current parity between the
currencies (1 Canadian $ = 1 US dollar) will continue, since interest and inflation rates are similar
in the two currencies.
4. The working capital requirements are estimated to be 20% of total revenues, and the
investments have to be made at the beginning of each year. At the end of the tenth year, it is
anticipated that the entire working capital will be salvaged.
5. Vales corporate tax rate of 34% will apply to this project as well.

Aswath Damodaran
251
Financing Assumptions
252

Vale plans to borrow $0.5 billion at its current cost of debt of 4.05% (based
upon its rating of A-), using a ten-year term loan (where the loan will be paid
off in equal annual increments). The breakdown of the payments each year
into interest and principal are provided below:

Aswath Damodaran
252
The Hurdle Rate
253

The analysis is done US dollar terms and to equity


investors. Thus, the hurdle rate has to be a US $ cost
of equity.
In the earlier section, we estimated costs of equity,
debt and capital in US dollars and $R for Vales iron
ore business.
Cost of After-tax cost of Debt Cost of capital (in Cost of capital (in
Business equity debt ratio US$) $R)
Metals &
Mining 11.35% 2.67% 35.48% 8.27% 15.70%
Iron Ore 11.13% 2.67% 35.48% 8.13% 15.55%
Fertilizers 12.70% 2.67% 35.48% 9.14% 16.63%
Logistics 10.29% 2.67% 35.48% 7.59% 14.97%
Vale Operations 11.23% 2.67% 35.48% 8.20% 15.62%

Aswath Damodaran
253
Net Income: Vale Iron Ore Mine
254

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Production (millions of tons) 4.00 6.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00 8.00
* Price per ton 102 104.04 106.12 108.24 110.41 112.62 114.87 117.17 119.51 121.9
= Revenues (millions US$) $408.00 $624.24 $848.97 $865.95 $883.26 $900.93 $918.95 $937.33 $956.07 $975.20
- Variable Costs $180.00 $275.40 $374.54 $382.03 $389.68 $397.47 $405.42 $413.53 $421.80 $430.23
- Fixed Costs $125.00 $127.50 $130.05 $132.65 $135.30 $138.01 $140.77 $143.59 $146.46 $149.39
- Depreciation $200.00 $160.00 $128.00 $102.40 $81.92 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54
EBIT -$97.00 $61.34 $216.37 $248.86 $276.37 $299.91 $307.22 $314.68 $322.28 $330.04
- Interest Expenses $20.25 $18.57 $16.82 $14.99 $13.10 $11.13 $9.07 $6.94 $4.72 $2.41
Taxable Income -$117.25 $42.77 $199.56 $233.87 $263.27 $288.79 $298.15 $307.74 $317.57 $327.63
- Taxes ($39.87) $14.54 $67.85 $79.51 $89.51 $98.19 $101.37 $104.63 $107.97 $111.40
= Net Income (millions US$) -$77.39 $28.23 $131.71 $154.35 $173.76 $190.60 $196.78 $203.11 $209.59 $216.24
Book Value and Depreciation
Beg. Book Value $1,250.00 $1,050.00 $890.00 $762.00 $659.60 $577.68 $512.14 $446.61 $381.07 $315.54
- Depreciation $200.00 $160.00 $128.00 $102.40 $81.92 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54
+ Capital Exp. $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00
End Book Value $1,050.00 $890.00 $762.00 $659.60 $577.68 $512.14 $446.61 $381.07 $315.54 $250.00
- Debt Outstanding $458.45 $415.22 $370.24 $323.43 $274.73 $224.06 $171.34 $116.48 $59.39 $0.00
End Book Value of Equity $591.55 $474.78 $391.76 $336.17 $302.95 $288.08 $275.27 $264.60 $256.14 $250.00

Aswath Damodaran
254
A ROE Analysis
255

BV of
Beg. BV: Capital Ending BV: Average
Year Net Income Depreciation Working Debt BV: Equity ROE
Assets Expense Assets BV: Equity
Capital
0 $0.00 $0.00 $1,250.00 $1,250.00 $81.60 $500.00 $831.60
1 ($77.39) $1,250.00 $200.00 $0.00 $1,050.00 $124.85 $458.45 $716.40 $774.00 -10.00%
2 $28.23 $1,050.00 $160.00 $0.00 $890.00 $169.79 $415.22 $644.57 $680.49 4.15%
3 $131.71 $890.00 $128.00 $0.00 $762.00 $173.19 $370.24 $564.95 $604.76 21.78%
4 $154.35 $762.00 $102.40 $0.00 $659.60 $176.65 $323.43 $512.82 $538.89 28.64%
5 $173.76 $659.60 $81.92 $0.00 $577.68 $180.19 $274.73 $483.13 $497.98 34.89%
6 $190.60 $577.68 $65.54 $0.00 $512.14 $183.79 $224.06 $471.87 $477.50 39.92%
7 $196.78 $512.14 $65.54 $0.00 $446.61 $187.47 $171.34 $462.74 $467.31 42.11%
8 $203.11 $446.61 $65.54 $0.00 $381.07 $191.21 $116.48 $455.81 $459.27 44.22%
9 $209.59 $381.07 $65.54 $0.00 $315.54 $195.04 $59.39 $451.18 $453.50 46.22%
10 $216.24 $315.54 $65.54 $0.00 $250.00 $0.00 $0.00 $250.00 $350.59 61.68%
Average ROE over the ten-year period = 31.36%

US $ ROE of 31.36% is greater than


Vale Iron Ore US$ Cost of Equity of 11.13%

Aswath Damodaran
255
From Project ROE to Firm ROE
256

As with the earlier analysis, where we used return on capital and cost of
capital to measure the overall quality of projects at firms, we can
compute return on equity and cost of equity to pass judgment on
whether firms are creating value to its equity investors.
Specifically, we can compute the return on equity (net income as a
percentage of book equity) and compare to the cost of equity. The return
spread is then:
Equity Return Spread = Return on Equity Cost of equity
This measure is particularly useful for financial service firms, where
capital, return on capital and cost of capital are difficult measures to nail
down.
For non-financial service firms, it provides a secondary (albeit a more
volatile measure of performance). While it usually provides the same
general result that the excess return computed from return on capital,
there can be cases where the two measures diverge.

Aswath Damodaran
256
An Incremental CF Analysis
257

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Net Income ($77.39) $28.23 $131.71 $154.35 $173.76 $190.60 $196.78 $203.11 $209.59 $216.24
+ Depreciation & Amortization $200.00 $160.00 $128.00 $102.40 $81.92 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54 $65.54
- Capital Expenditures $750.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00
- Change in Working Capital $81.60 $43.25 $44.95 $3.40 $3.46 $3.53 $3.60 $3.68 $3.75 $3.82 ($195.04)
- Principal Repayments $41.55 $43.23 $44.98 $46.80 $48.70 $50.67 $52.72 $54.86 $57.08 $59.39
+ Salvage Value of mine $250.00
Cashflow to Equity ($831.60) $37.82 $100.05 $211.33 $206.48 $203.44 $201.86 $205.91 $210.04 $214.22 $667.42

Aswath Damodaran
257
An Equity NPV
Discounted at US$ cost of
equity of 11.13% for Vales
iron ore business
258

Aswath Damodaran
258
An Equity IRR
259

Aswath Damodaran
259
Real versus Nominal Analysis
260

In computing the NPV of the plant, we estimated US $


cash flows and discounted them at the US $ cost of
equity. We could have estimated the cash flows in real
terms (with no inflation) and discounted them at a real
cost of equity. Would the answer be different?
Yes

No

Explain

Aswath Damodaran
260
Dealing with Macro Uncertainty: The Effect of
Iron Ore Price
261

Like the Disney Theme Park, the Vale Iron Ore Mines actual value will be
buffeted as the variables change. The biggest source of variability is an
external factor the price of iron ore.
Vale Paper Plant: Effect of Changing Iron Ore Prices

$1,500 40.00%

30.00%
$1,000
20.00%
$500
10.00%
NPV

N
$0 0.00%
$50 $60 $70 $80 $90 $100 $110 $120 $130
-10.00%
-$500
-20.00%
-$1,000
-30.00%

-$1,500 Price per ton of iron ore -40.00%


Aswath Damodaran
261
And Exchange Rates
262

Exchange Rate effects on Iron Ore Plant


$700 25.00%

$600

20.00%
$500

Internal Rate of Return


$400
Net Present Value

15.00%

$300
NPV

10.00% IRR
$200

$100
5.00%
$0

-$100 0.00%

Canadian $ versus US $

Aswath Damodaran
262
Should you hedge?
263

The value of this mine is very much a function iron ore prices. There are futures,
forward and option markets iron ore that Vale can use to hedge against price
movements. Should it?
Yes
No
Explain.
The value of the mine is also a function of exchange rates. There are forward,
futures and options markets on currency. Should Vale hedge against exchange rate
risk?
Yes
No
Explain.
On the last question, would your answer have been different if the mine were in
Brazil.
Yes
No

Aswath Damodaran
263
Value Trade Off

What is the cost to the firm of hedging this risk? Cash flow benefits
- Tax benefits
- Better project choices
Negligible High

Survival benefits (truncation risk)


Is there a significant benefit in Is there a significant benefit in - Protect against catastrophic risk
terms of higher cash flows or terms of higher expected cash - Reduce default risk
a lower discount rate? flows or a lower discount rate?
Discount rate benefits
- Hedge "macro" risks (cost of equity)
Yes No Yes No - Reduce default risk (cost of debt or debt ratio)

Hedge this risk. The Indifferent to Can marginal investors Do not hedge this risk.
benefits to the firm will hedging risk hedge this risk cheaper The benefits are small
exceed the costs than the firm can? relative to costs
Pricing Trade
Earnings Multiple Earnings
- Effect on multiple X - Level
Yes No
- Volatility

Will the benefits persist if investors hedge Hedge this risk. The
the risk instead of the firm? benefits to the firm will
exceed the costs
Yes No

Let the risk pass Hedge this risk. The


through to investors benefits to the firm will
and let them hedge exceed the costs
the risk.

264 Aswath Damodaran


Acquisitions and Projects
265

An acquisition is an investment/project like any other and all


of the rules that apply to traditional investments should apply
to acquisitions as well. In other words, for an acquisition to
make sense:
It should have positive NPV. The present value of the expected cash
flows from the acquisition should exceed the price paid on the
acquisition.
The IRR of the cash flows to the firm (equity) from the acquisition >
Cost of capital (equity) on the acquisition
In estimating the cash flows on the acquisition, we should
count in any possible cash flows from synergy.
The discount rate to assess the present value should be based
upon the risk of the investment (target company) and not the
entity considering the investment (acquiring company).

Aswath Damodaran
265
Tata Motors and Harman International
266

Harman International is a publicly traded US firm


that manufactures high end audio equipment. Tata
Motors is an automobile company, based in India.
Tata Motors is considering an acquisition of Harman,
with an eye on using its audio equipment in its
Indian automobiles, as optional upgrades on new
cars.

Aswath Damodaran
266
Estimating the Cost of Capital for the
Acquisition (no synergy)
267

1. Currency: Estimated in US $, since cash flows will be estimated in US $.


2. Beta: Harman International is an electronic company and we use the unlevered beta
(1.17) of electronics companies in the US.
3. Equity Risk Premium: Computed based on Harmans operating exposure:

4. Debt ratio & cost of debt: Tata Motors plans to assume the existing debt of Harman
International and to preserve Harmans existing debt ratio. Harman currently has a debt
(including lease commitments) to capital ratio of 7.39% (translating into a debt to equity
ratio of 7.98%) and faces a pre-tax cost of debt of 4.75% (based on its BBB- rating).
Levered Beta = 1.17 (1+ (1-.40) (.0798)) = 1.226
Cost of Equity= 2.75% + 1.226 (6.13%) = 10.26%
Cost of Capital = 10.26% (1-.0739) + 4.75% (1-.40) (.0739) = 9.67%

Aswath Damodaran
267
Estimating Cashflows- First Steps
268

Operating Income: The firm reported operating income of


$201.25 million on revenues of $4.30 billion for the year.
Adding back non-recurring expenses (restructuring charge of
$83.2 million in 2013) and adjusting income for the
conversion of operating lease commitments to debt, we
estimated an adjusted operating income of $313.2 million.
The firm paid 18.21% of its income as taxes in 2013 and we
will use this as the effective tax rate for the cash flows.
Reinvestment: Depreciation in 2013 amounted to $128.2
million, whereas capital expenditures and acquisitions for the
year were $206.4 million. Non-cash working capital increased
by $272.6 million during 2013 but was 13.54% of revenues in
2013.
Aswath Damodaran
268
Bringing in growth
269

We will assume that Harman International is a mature firm, growing


2.75% in perpetuity.
We assume that revenues, operating income, capital expenditures and
depreciation will all grow 2.75% for the year and that the non-cash
working capital remain 13.54% of revenues in future periods.

Aswath Damodaran
269
Value of Harman International: Before Synergy
270

Earlier, we estimated the cost of capital of 9.67% as the right discount rate to apply in
valuing Harman International and the cash flow to the firm of $166.85 million for 2014 (next
year), assuming a 2.75% growth rate in revenues, operating income, depreciation, capital
expenditures and total non-cash working capital. We also assumed that these cash flows
would continue to grow 2.75% a year in perpetuity.

Adding the cash balance of the firm ($515 million) and subtracting out the existing debt
($313 million, including the debt value of leases) yields the value of equity in the firm:
Value of Equity = Value of Operating Assets + Cash Debt
= $2,476 + $ 515 - $313 million = $2,678 million
The market value of equity in Harman in November 2013 was $5,428 million.
To the extent that Tata Motors pays the market price, it will have to generate benefits from
synergy that exceed $2750 million.

Aswath Damodaran
270
Aswath Damodaran 271

Measuring Investment Returns


II. Investment Interactions, Options
and Remorse
Life is too short for regrets, right?
Independent investments are the exception
272

In all of the examples we have used so far, the


investments that we have analyzed have stood alone.
Thus, our job was a simple one. Assess the expected cash
flows on the investment and discount them at the right
discount rate.
In the real world, most investments are not
independent. Taking an investment can often mean
rejecting another investment at one extreme (mutually
exclusive) to being locked in to take an investment in the
future (pre-requisite).
More generally, accepting an investment can create side
costs for a firms existing investments in some cases and
benefits for others.
Aswath Damodaran
272
I. Mutually Exclusive Investments
273

We have looked at how best to assess a stand-alone


investment and concluded that a good investment will have
positive NPV and generate accounting returns (ROC and ROE)
and IRR that exceed your costs (capital and equity).
In some cases, though, firms may have to choose between
investments because
They are mutually exclusive: Taking one investment makes the other
one redundant because they both serve the same purpose
The firm has limited capital and cannot take every good investment
(i.e., investments with positive NPV or high IRR).
Using the two standard discounted cash flow measures, NPV
and IRR, can yield different choices when choosing between
investments.
Aswath Damodaran
273
Comparing Projects with the same (or similar)
lives..
274

When comparing and choosing between investments


with the same lives, we can
Compute the accounting returns (ROC, ROE) of the investments
and pick the one with the higher returns
Compute the NPV of the investments and pick the one with the
higher NPV
Compute the IRR of the investments and pick the one with the
higher IRR
While it is easy to see why accounting return measures
can give different rankings (and choices) than the
discounted cash flow approaches, you would expect NPV
and IRR to yield consistent results since they are both
time-weighted, incremental cash flow return measures.

Aswath Damodaran
274
Case 1: IRR versus NPV
275

Consider two projects with the following cash flows:


Year Project 1 CF Project 2 CF
0 -1000 -1000
1 800 200
2 1000 300
3 1300 400
4 -2200 500

Aswath Damodaran
275
Projects NPV Profile
276

Aswath Damodaran
276
What do we do now?
277

Project 1 has two internal rates of return. The first is


6.60%, whereas the second is 36.55%. Project 2 has one
internal rate of return, about 12.8%.
Why are there two internal rates of return on project 1?

If your cost of capital is 12%, which investment would


you accept?
a. Project 1
b. Project 2
Explain.

Aswath Damodaran
277
Case 2: NPV versus IRR
278

Project A

Cash Flow $ 350,000 $ 450,000 $ 600,000 $ 750,000

Investment $ 1,000,000

NPV = $467,937
IRR= 33.66%

Project B

Cash Flow $ 3,000,000 $ 3,500,000 $ 4,500,000 $ 5,500,000

Investment $ 10,000,000
NPV = $1,358,664
IRR=20.88%

Aswath Damodaran
278
Which one would you pick?
279

Assume that you can pick only one of these two projects.
Your choice will clearly vary depending upon whether
you look at NPV or IRR. You have enough money
currently on hand to take either. Which one would you
pick?
a. Project A. It gives me the bigger bang for the buck and more
margin for error.
b. Project B. It creates more dollar value in my business.
If you pick A, what would your biggest concern be?

If you pick B, what would your biggest concern be?

Aswath Damodaran
279
Capital Rationing, Uncertainty and Choosing a
Rule
280

If a business has limited access to capital, has a stream of


surplus value projects and faces more uncertainty in its
project cash flows, it is much more likely to use IRR as its
decision rule.
Small, high-growth companies and private businesses are much
more likely to use IRR.
If a business has substantial funds on hand, access to
capital, limited surplus value projects, and more
certainty on its project cash flows, it is much more likely
to use NPV as its decision rule.
As firms go public and grow, they are much more likely
to gain from using NPV.

Aswath Damodaran
280
The sources of capital rationing
281

Cause Number of firms Percent of total


Debt limit imposed by outside agreement 10 10.7
Debt limit placed by management external 3 3.2
to firm
Limit placed on borrowing by internal 65 69.1
management
Restrictive policy imposed on retained 2 2.1
earnings
Maintenance of target EPS or PE ratio 14 14.9

Aswath Damodaran
281
An Alternative to IRR with Capital Rationing
282

The problem with the NPV rule, when there is capital


rationing, is that it is a dollar value. It measures success
in absolute terms.
The NPV can be converted into a relative measure by
dividing by the initial investment. This is called the
profitability index.
Profitability Index (PI) = NPV/Initial Investment
In the example described, the PI of the two projects
would have been:
PI of Project A = $467,937/1,000,000 = 46.79%
PI of Project B = $1,358,664/10,000,000 = 13.59%
Project A would have scored higher.

Aswath Damodaran
282
Case 3: NPV versus IRR
283

Project A

Cash Flow $ 5,000,000 $ 4,000,000 $ 3,200,000 $ 3,000,000

Investment $ 10,000,000

NPV = $1,191,712
IRR=21.41%

Project B

Cash Flow $ 3,000,000 $ 3,500,000 $ 4,500,000 $ 5,500,000

Investment $ 10,000,000
NPV = $1,358,664
IRR=20.88%

Aswath Damodaran
283
Why the difference?
284

These projects are of the same scale. Both the NPV


and IRR use time-weighted cash flows. Yet, the
rankings are different. Why?

Which one would you pick?


a. Project A. It gives me the bigger bang for the buck and
more margin for error.
b. Project B. It creates more dollar value in my business.

Aswath Damodaran
284
NPV, IRR and the Reinvestment Rate
Assumption
285

The NPV rule assumes that intermediate cash flows on


the project get reinvested at the hurdle rate (which is
based upon what projects of comparable risk should
earn).
The IRR rule assumes that intermediate cash flows on
the project get reinvested at the IRR. Implicit is the
assumption that the firm has an infinite stream of
projects yielding similar IRRs.
Conclusion: When the IRR is high (the project is creating
significant surplus value) and the project life is long, the
IRR will overstate the true return on the project.

Aswath Damodaran
285
Solution to Reinvestment Rate Problem
286

Aswath Damodaran
286
Why NPV and IRR may differ.. Even if projects
have the same lives
287

A project can have only one NPV, whereas it can have


more than one IRR.
The NPV is a dollar surplus value, whereas the IRR is a
percentage measure of return. The NPV is therefore
likely to be larger for large scale projects, while the IRR
is higher for small-scale projects.
The NPV assumes that intermediate cash flows get
reinvested at the hurdle rate, which is based upon
what you can make on investments of comparable risk,
while the IRR assumes that intermediate cash flows get
reinvested at the IRR.

Aswath Damodaran
287
Comparing projects with different lives..
288
Project A

$400 $400 $400 $400 $400

-$1000
NPV of Project A = $ 442
IRR of Project A = 28.7%

Project B
$350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350

-$1500 NPV of Project B = $ 478


IRR for Project B = 19.4%
Hurdle Rate for Both Projects = 12%

Aswath Damodaran
288
Why NPVs cannot be compared.. When projects
have different lives.
289

The net present values of mutually exclusive projects


with different lives cannot be compared, since there
is a bias towards longer-life projects. To compare the
NPV, we have to
replicate the projects till they have the same life (or)
convert the net present values into annuities

The IRR is unaffected by project life. We can choose


the project with the higher IRR.

Aswath Damodaran
289
Solution 1: Project Replication
290

Project A: Replicated
$400 $400 $400 $400 $400 $400 $400 $400 $400 $400

-$1000 -$1000 (Replication)


NPV of Project A replicated = $ 693

Project B
$350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350 $350

-$1500
NPV of Project B= $ 478

Aswath Damodaran
290
Solution 2: Equivalent Annuities
291

Equivalent Annuity for 5-year project


= $442 * PV(A,12%,5 years)
= $ 122.62

Equivalent Annuity for 10-year project


= $478 * PV(A,12%,10 years)
= $ 84.60

Aswath Damodaran
291
What would you choose as your investment
tool?
292

Given the advantages/disadvantages outlined for each of


the different decision rules, which one would you choose
to adopt?
a. Return on Investment (ROE, ROC)
b. Payback or Discounted Payback
c. Net Present Value
d. Internal Rate of Return
e. Profitability Index
Do you think your choice has been affected by the
events of the last quarter of 2008? If so, why? If not, why
not?

Aswath Damodaran
292
What firms actually use ..
293

Decision Rule % of Firms using as primary decision rule in


1976 1986 1998
IRR 53.6% 49.0% 42.0%
Accounting Return 25.0% 8.0% 7.0%
NPV 9.8% 21.0% 34.0%
Payback Period 8.9% 19.0% 14.0%
Profitability Index 2.7% 3.0% 3.0%

Aswath Damodaran
293
II. Side Costs and Benefits
294

Most projects considered by any business create side


costs and benefits for that business.
The side costs include the costs created by the use of resources
that the business already owns (opportunity costs) and lost
revenues for other projects that the firm may have.
The benefits that may not be captured in the traditional capital
budgeting analysis include project synergies (where cash flow
benefits may accrue to other projects) and options embedded in
projects (including the options to delay, expand or abandon a
project).
The returns on a project should incorporate these costs
and benefits.

Aswath Damodaran
294
A. Opportunity Cost
295

An opportunity cost arises when a project uses a


resource that may already have been paid for by the
firm.
When a resource that is already owned by a firm is being
considered for use in a project, this resource has to be
priced on its next best alternative use, which may be
a sale of the asset, in which case the opportunity cost is the
expected proceeds from the sale, net of any capital gains taxes
renting or leasing the asset out, in which case the opportunity
cost is the expected present value of the after-tax rental or
lease revenues.
use elsewhere in the business, in which case the opportunity
cost is the cost of replacing it.

Aswath Damodaran
295
Case 1: Foregone Sale?
296

Assume that Disney owns land in Rio already. This land is


undeveloped and was acquired several years ago for $ 5
million for a hotel that was never built. It is anticipated,
if this theme park is built, that this land will be used to
build the offices for Disney Rio. The land currently can be
sold for $ 40 million, though that would create a capital
gain (which will be taxed at 20%). In assessing the theme
park, which of the following would you do:
Ignore the cost of the land, since Disney owns its already
Use the book value of the land, which is $ 5 million
Use the market value of the land, which is $ 40 million
Other:

Aswath Damodaran
296
Case 2: Incremental Cost?
An Online Retailing Venture for Bookscape
297

The initial investment needed to start the service, including the


installation of additional phone lines and computer equipment, will be $1
million. These investments are expected to have a life of four years, at
which point they will have no salvage value. The investments will be
depreciated straight line over the four-year life.
The revenues in the first year are expected to be $1.5 million, growing
20% in year two, and 10% in the two years following. The cost of the
books will be 60% of the revenues in each of the four years.
The salaries and other benefits for the employees are estimated to be
$150,000 in year one, and grow 10% a year for the following three years.
The working capital, which includes the inventory of books needed for the
service and the accounts receivable will be10% of the revenues; the
investments in working capital have to be made at the beginning of each
year. At the end of year 4, the entire working capital is assumed to be
salvaged.
The tax rate on income is expected to be 40%.

Aswath Damodaran
297
Cost of capital for investment
298

We will re-estimate the beta for this online project by looking at


publicly traded online retailers. The unlevered total beta of online
retailers is 3.02, and we assume that this project will be funded
with the same mix of debt and equity (D/E = 21.41%, Debt/Capital
= 17.63%) that Bookscape uses in the rest of the business. We will
assume that Bookscapes tax rate (40%) and pretax cost of debt
(4.05%) apply to this project.
Levered Beta Online Service = 3.02 [1 + (1 0.4) (0.2141)] = 3.41
Cost of Equity Online Service = 2.75% + 3.41 (5.5%) = 21.48%
Cost of CapitalOnline Service= 21.48% (0.8237) + 4.05% (1 0.4) (0.1763) =
18.12%
This is much higher than the cost of capital (10.30%) we computed
for Bookscape earlier, but it reflects the higher risk of the online
retail venture.

Aswath Damodaran
298
Incremental Cash flows on Investment
299

0 1 2 3 4
Revenues $1,500,000 $1,800,000 $1,980,000 $2,178,000

Operating Expenses
Labor $150,000 $165,000 $181,500 $199,650
Materials $900,000 $1,080,000 $1,188,000 $1,306,800
Depreciation $250,000 $250,000 $250,000 $250,000

Operating Income $200,000 $305,000 $360,500 $421,550


Taxes $80,000 $122,000 $144,200 $168,620
After-tax Operating
Income $120,000 $183,000 $216,300 $252,930
+ Depreciation $250,000 $250,000 $250,000 $250,000
- Change in Working
Capital $150,000 $30,000 $18,000 $19,800 -$217,800
+ Salvage Value of
Investment $0
Cash flow after taxes -$1,150,000 $340,000 $415,000 $446,500 $720,730
Present Value -$1,150,000 $287,836 $297,428 $270,908 $370,203

NPV of investment = $76,375


Aswath Damodaran
299
The side costs
300

It is estimated that the additional business associated with


online ordering and the administration of the service itself
will add to the workload for the current general manager of
the bookstore. As a consequence, the salary of the general
manager will be increased from $100,000 to $120,000 next
year; it is expected to grow 5 percent a year after that for the
remaining three years of the online venture. After the online
venture is ended in the fourth year, the managers salary will
revert back to its old levels.
It is also estimated that Bookscape Online will utilize an office
that is currently used to store financial records. The records
will be moved to a bank vault, which will cost $1000 a year to
rent.
Aswath Damodaran
300
NPV with side costs
301

Additional salary costs = PV of $34,352

Office Costs
After-Tax Additional Storage Expenditure per Year = $1,000 (1 0.40) = $600
PV of expenditures = $600 (PV of annuity, 18.12%,4 yrs) = $1,610
NPV with Opportunity Costs = $76,375 $34,352 $1,610= $ 40,413
Opportunity costs aggregated into cash flows
Year Cashflows Opportunity costs Cashflow with opportunity costs Present Value
0 ($1,150,000) ($1,150,000) ($1,150,000)
1 $340,000 $12,600 $327,400 $277,170
2 $415,000 $13,200 $401,800 $287,968
3 $446,500 $13,830 $432,670 $262,517
4 $720,730 $14,492 $706,238 $362,759
Adjusted NPV $40,413
Aswath Damodaran
301
Case 3: Excess Capacity
302

In the Vale example, assume that the firm will use its
existing distribution system to service the
production out of the new iron ore mine. The mine
manager argues that there is no cost associated with
using this system, since it has been paid for already
and cannot be sold or leased to a competitor (and
thus has no competing current use). Do you agree?
a. Yes
b. No

Aswath Damodaran
302
A Framework for Assessing The Cost of Using
Excess Capacity
303

If I do not add the new product, when will I run out


of capacity?
If I add the new product, when will I run out of
capacity?
When I run out of capacity, what will I do?
Cut back on production: cost is PV of after-tax cash flows
from lost sales
Buy new capacity: cost is difference in PV between earlier
& later investment

Aswath Damodaran
303
Product and Project Cannibalization: A Real
Cost?
304

Assume that in the Disney theme park example, 20% of the


revenues at the Rio Disney park are expected to come from
people who would have gone to Disney theme parks in the
US. In doing the analysis of the park, you would
a. Look at only incremental revenues (i.e. 80% of the total revenue)
b. Look at total revenues at the park
c. Choose an intermediate number
Would your answer be different if you were analyzing
whether to introduce a new show on the Disney cable
channel on Saturday mornings that is expected to attract 20%
of its viewers from ABC (which is also owned by Disney)?
a. Yes
b. No

Aswath Damodaran
304
B. Project Synergies
305

A project may provide benefits for other projects within the firm.
Consider, for instance, a typical Disney animated movie. Assume
that it costs $ 50 million to produce and promote. This movie, in
addition to theatrical revenues, also produces revenues from
the sale of merchandise (stuffed toys, plastic figures, clothes ..)
increased attendance at the theme parks
stage shows (see Beauty and the Beast and the Lion King)
television series based upon the movie
In investment analysis, however, these synergies are either left
unquantified and used to justify overriding the results of
investment analysis, i.e,, used as justification for investing in
negative NPV projects.
If synergies exist and they often do, these benefits have to be
valued and shown in the initial project analysis.

Aswath Damodaran
305
Case 1: Adding a Caf to a bookstore: Bookscape
306

Assume that you are considering adding a caf to the bookstore. Assume
also that based upon the expected revenues and expenses, the caf
standing alone is expected to have a net present value of -$87,571.
The cafe will increase revenues at the book store by $500,000 in year 1,
growing at 10% a year for the following 4 years. In addition, assume that
the pre-tax operating margin on these sales is 10%.

1 2 3 4 5
Increased Revenues $500,000 $550,000 $605,000 $665,500 $732,050
Operating Margin 10.00% 10.00% 10.00% 10.00% 10.00%
Operating Income $50,000 $55,000 $60,500 $66,550 $73,205
Operating Income after Taxes $30,000 $33,000 $36,300 $39,930 $43,923
PV of Additional Cash Flows $27,199 $27,126 $27,053 $26,981 $26,908
PV of Synergy Benefits $135,268

The net present value of the added benefits is $135,268. Added to the
NPV of the standalone Caf of -$87,571 yields a net present value of
$47,697.

Aswath Damodaran
306
Case 2: Synergy in a merger..
307

We valued Harman International for an acquisition by Tata Motors and


estimated a value of $ 2,476 million for the operating assets and $ 2,678
million for the equity in the firm, concluding that it would not be a value-
creating acquisition at its current market capitalization of $5,248 million.
In estimating this value, though, we treated Harman International as a
stand-alone firm.
Assume that Tata Motors foresees potential synergies in the combination
of the two firms, primarily from using its using Harmans high-end audio
technology (speakers, tuners) as optional upgrades for customers buying
new Tata Motors cars in India. To value this synergy, let us assume the
following:
It will take Tata Motors approximately 3 years to adapt Harmans products to Tata
Motors cars.
Tata Motors will be able to generate Rs 10 billion in after-tax operating income in
year 4 from selling Harman audio upgrades to its Indian customers, growing at a
rate of 4% a year after that in perpetuity (but only in India).

Aswath Damodaran
307
Estimating the cost of capital to use in valuing
synergy..
308

Business risk: The perceived synergies flow from optional add-ons


in auto sales. We will begin with the levered beta of 1.10, that we
estimated for Tata Motors in chapter 4, in estimating the cost of
equity.
Geographic risk: The second is that the synergies are expected to
come from India; consequently, we will add the country risk
premium of 3.60% for India, estimated in chapter 4 (for Tata
Motors) to the mature market premium of 5.5%.
Debt ratio: Finally, we will assume that the expansion will be
entirely in India, with Tata Motors maintain its existing debt to
capital ratio of 29.28% and its current rupee cost of debt of 9.6%
and its marginal tax rate of 32.45%.
Cost of equity in Rupees = 6.57% + 1.10 (5.5%+3.60%) = 16.59%
Cost of debt in Rupees = 9.6% (1-.3245) = 6.50%
Cost of capital in Rupees = 16.59% (1-.2928) + 6.50% (.2928) = 13.63%

Aswath Damodaran
308
Estimating the value of synergy and what Tata can
pay for Harman
309

Value of synergyYear 3 = Expected Cash Flow Year 4


=
10,000
= Rs 103,814 million
(Cost of Capital - g) (.1363-.04)
Value of Synergy year 3 103,814
Value of synergy today = =
(1+Cost of Capital)3 (1.1363)3
= Rs 70,753 million

Converting the synergy value into dollar terms at the prevailing


exchange rate of Rs 60/$, we can estimate a dollar value for the
synergy from the potential acquisition:
Value of synergy in US $ = Rs 70,753/60 = $ 1,179 million
Adding this value to the intrinsic value of $2,678 million that we
estimated for Harmans equity in chapter 5, we get a total value for
the equity of $3,857 million.
Value of Harman = $2,678 million + $1,179 million = $3,857 million
Since Harmans equity trades at $5,248 million, the acquisition still
does not make sense, even with the synergy incorporated into
value.

Aswath Damodaran
309
III. Project Options
310

One of the limitations of traditional investment analysis


is that it is static and does not do a good job of capturing
the options embedded in investment.
The first of these options is the option to delay taking a project,
when a firm has exclusive rights to it, until a later date.
The second of these options is taking one project may allow us
to take advantage of other opportunities (projects) in the future
The last option that is embedded in projects is the option to
abandon a project, if the cash flows do not measure up.
These options all add value to projects and may make a
bad project (from traditional analysis) into a good one.
Aswath Damodaran
310
The Option to Delay
311

When a firm has exclusive rights to a project or product for a specific


period, it can delay taking this project or product until a later date. A
traditional investment analysis just answers the question of whether the
project is a good one if taken today. The rights to a bad project can
still have value.
PV of Cash Flows

Initial Investment in
Project NPV is positive in this section

Present Value of Expected


Cash Flows on Product

Aswath Damodaran
311
Insights for Investment Analyses
312

Having the exclusive rights to a product or project is


valuable, even if the product or project is not viable
today.
The value of these rights increases with the volatility
of the underlying business.
The cost of acquiring these rights (by buying them or
spending money on development - R&D, for
instance) has to be weighed off against these
benefits.

Aswath Damodaran
312
The Option to Expand/Take Other Projects
313

Taking a project today may allow a firm to consider and take other
valuable projects in the future. Thus, even though a project may have a
negative NPV, it may be a project worth taking if the option it provides the
firm (to take other projects in the future) has a more-than-compensating
value.
PV of Cash Flows
from Expansion

Additional Investment
to Expand

Cash Flows on Expansion


Expansion becomes
Firm will not expand in attractive in this section
this section

Aswath Damodaran
313
The Option to Abandon
314

A firm may sometimes have the option to abandon a project, if the cash
flows do not measure up to expectations.
If abandoning the project allows the firm to save itself from further
losses, this option can make a project more valuable.

PV of Cash Flows
from Project

Cost of Abandonment

Present Value of Expected


Cash Flows on Project

Aswath Damodaran
314
IV. Assessing Existing or Past investments
315

While much of our discussion has been focused on


analyzing new investments, the techniques and
principles enunciated apply just as strongly to
existing investments.
With existing investments, we can try to address one
of two questions:
Post mortem: We can look back at existing investments
and see if they have created value for the firm.
What next? We can also use the tools of investment
analysis to see whether we should keep, expand or
abandon existing investments.

Aswath Damodaran
315
Analyzing an Existing Investment
316

In a post-mortem, you look at the actual cash You can also reassess your expected cash
flows, relative to forecasts. flows, based upon what you have learned,
and decide whether you should expand,
continue or divest (abandon) an investment

Aswath Damodaran
316
a. Post Mortem Analysis
317

The actual cash flows from an investment can be greater than or less than
originally forecast for a number of reasons but all these reasons can be
categorized into two groups:
Chance: The nature of risk is that actual outcomes can be different from
expectations. Even when forecasts are based upon the best of information, they
will invariably be wrong in hindsight because of unexpected shifts in both macro
(inflation, interest rates, economic growth) and micro (competitors, company)
variables.
Bias: If the original forecasts were biased, the actual numbers will be different from
expectations. The evidence on capital budgeting is that managers tend to be over-
optimistic about cash flows and the bias is worse with over-confident managers.
While it is impossible to tell on an individual project whether chance or
bias is to blame, there is a way to tell across projects and across time. If
chance is the culprit, there should be symmetry in the errors actuals
should be about as likely to beat forecasts as they are to come under
forecasts. If bias is the reason, the errors will tend to be in one direction.

Aswath Damodaran
317
b. What should we do next?
318

t =n
NFn ........ Liquidate the project

t =0 (1 + r)
n
<0

t =n
NFn
n
< Salvage Value ........ Terminate the project
t =0 (1 + r)


t =n
NFn ........ Divest the project

t =0 (1 + r)
n
< Divestiture Value

t =n
NFn
n
> 0 > Divestiture Value ........ Continue the project
t =0 (1 + r)

Aswath Damodaran
318

Example: Disney California Adventure


The 2008 judgment call
319

Disney opened the Disney California Adventure (DCA) Park in 2001, at a


cost of $1.5 billion, with a mix of roller coaster rides and movie nostalgia.
Disney expected about 60% of its visitors to Disneyland to come across to
DCA and generate about $ 100 million in annual after-cash flows for the
firm.
By 2008, DCA had not performed up to expectations. Of the 15 million
people who came to Disneyland in 2007, only 6 million visited California
Adventure, and the cash flow averaged out to only $ 50 million between
2001 and 2007.
In early 2008, Disney faced three choices:
Shut down California Adventure and try to recover whatever it can of its initial
investment. It is estimated that the firm recover about $ 500 million of its investment.
Continue with the status quo, recognizing that future cash flows will be closer to the
actual values ($ 50 million) than the original projections.
Invest about $ 600 million to expand and modify the park, with the intent of increasing
the number of attractions for families with children, is expected to increase the
percentage of Disneyland visitors who come to DCA from 40% to 60% and increase the
annual after tax cash flow by 60% (from $ 50 million to $ 80 million) at the park.

Aswath Damodaran
319
DCA: Evaluating the alternatives
320

Continuing Operation: Assuming the current after-tax cash flow of


$ 50 million will continue in perpetuity, growing at the inflation rate
of 2% and discounting back at the theme park cost of capital in
2008 of 6.62% yields a value for continuing with the status quo
Value of DCA = Expected Cash Flow next year
(Cost of capital - g)
=
50(1.02)
(.0662 .02)
= $1.103 billion

Abandonment: Abandoning this investment currently would allow


Disney to recover only $ 500 million of its original investment.

Abandonment value of DCA = $ 500 million
Expansion: The up-front cost of $ 600 million will lead to more
visitors in the park and an increase in the existing cash flows from $
50 to $ 80 million.
Value of CF from expansion = Increase in CF next year = 30(1.02) = $662 million
(Cost of capital - g) (.0662 .02)


Aswath Damodaran
320
First Principles
321

Aswath Damodaran
321

You might also like