Baltazar Parra Policy Analysis
Baltazar Parra Policy Analysis
Baltazar Parra Policy Analysis
26 April 2021
Table of Contents
Background ..................................................................................................................................... 1
1.1 Policy Client: Nayarit’s State Government’s Office of Tourism and Sustainable
Development ................................................................................................................................. 4
Bibliography ................................................................................................................................. 19
Tables ............................................................................................................................................ 22
Table 1. Evaluation criteria for proposed policy alternatives, based on Patton et al.’s (2016, p.
Table 2: Possible Manipulations for Proposed Variables, based on May’s (1981, p. 227)
Table 3: Alternative Policy Strategies, based on May’s (1981, p. 227) Feasible Manipulations
Approach ..................................................................................................................................... 32
Table 4. Goeller’s Scorecard of policy set alternatives and evaluation criteria, based on Patton et
assessment*, based on Patton et al.’s (2016, p. 330) Matrix (Scorecard) Display Systems ....... 44
Table 7. Fact-base indicators and sources for baseline and ongoing measurements, based on
Patton et al.’s (2016) operationalization process for policy monitoring and evaluation ............. 47
Figures........................................................................................................................................... 51
Background
Up until recent years, people in Nayarit coastal towns had low levels of education, high
marginalization, and little access to secondary and tertiary economic sectors, relying primarily on
natural resources and related activities (INEGI 2017); only since the last three decades has the
region started to incorporate tourism as a main income source, and this generation is the first to
access higher education and shift away from agricultural and fishing practices for their
sustenance (INEGI 2017). Given their socioeconomic and cultural context, people in these towns
have been accustomed to using endangered natural resources with no legal restrictions or moral
When fishing and poaching bans were introduced in the early 2000s due to Mexican international
agreements and growing environmental awareness concerns (Micheli 2002), local communities,
having little understanding of the wider implications of ecological imbalances, perceived these
measures as harsh and unwarranted impositions and did not immediately or willingly comply.
Facing such response from the coastal communities, policies in Mexico have implemented
diverse approaches seeking to enforce the bans and to promote conservation over egg extraction.
These approaches have ranged from punitivism to marketing: punitive measures have included
legal punishments for infringing bans (up to nine years in prison plus fines) and use of drone
ecological awareness campaigns such as the 2005 “Sexy” Campaign produced by the
Pronatura Organization to dismantle the widespread myth about egg turtles having aphrodisiac
projects, such as was required for the construction of the touristic Litibú Zone in the state of
While these measures have succeeded in hindering trade and lowering poaching (PROCER 2016,
PROFEPA 2019), poaching and black markets of sea turtle eggs are still active (Ramírez 2018)
and sea turtles, although slightly recovering in population numbers, remain endangered. As of
2018, ecologists estimated that in spite of policy and law regulations prohibiting this trade, 40%
of sea turtle eggs end up in the market as a result of poaching practices (Ceballos 2018), while
other estimations say the percentage is as high as 70% (González-Padilla 2015). In either case,
the percentage represents dozens of thousands of eggs; it is estimated that an individual poacher
takes between 1000 and 2000 eggs, and confiscations of illegal transportation of sea turtle eggs
have reported up to 22,800 eggs per raid (Mendoza 2018). It is further calculated that due to
predators and artificial hazards for young turtles, only 1 in every 1000 hatchlings make it to
adulthood and get to reproduce (IAC 2012, WWF 2014); with these statistical odds, the high
The present situation indicates a policy problem based on underperformance regarding turning
around the endangered status of the species and persistent practices in spite of their illegality.
One underlying cause of this issue is rooted in the role of the communities that are directed
affected by these policies. To this respect, Pacheco, Murillo, and Aguilar (2012, cited in Monroy
et al. 2020) use the example of Nayarit to describe how state development plans in Mexico tend
participation in such decisions being limited to voting and in rare cases presenting citizen
petitions, but not quite getting involved— or being taken into account— to provide input for
objectives, strategies, choices, and monitoring of resources. Hence, we have that the current state
of affairs has not contributed to strengthen community attachment to the goals of conservation
policies even when these communities in the state of Nayarit’s coastal towns are the most
The policy problem at stake is that sea turtle eggs in Nayarit’s coastal towns are being
illegally poached (i.e. extracted from their nests to be sold for human consumption in violation of
official protection dispositions) at a rate such that aggravates the endangered status of sea turtles.
The aimed solution of policy is, thus, to increase the success of incentives for conservation
activities among these coastal communities by turning said communities into interested and
informed stakeholders. Drawing from Clemons and McBeth’s (2020) idea of the policy analyst
as a democratic facilitator contributing to provide access to data for stakeholders, empower the
public to understand analyses, and bringing political issues into serious public discussions (p.
211), the focus on community involvement adopted in this policy analysis offers the additional
While there are precedents of sorts of successful community-based approaches to sea turtle
conservation adopted following sea turtle egg bans and ensuing local financial depletion, such as
in La Escobilla, Oaxaca (Oaxaca Mío 2016), these are usually citizen initiatives or privately
funded projects, not government policy interventions. In this sense, the policy problem at stake
highlights the lack of attention the issue has received at the formal policy level.
The policy problem reveals, furthermore, the present failure to incorporate policy goals into local
culture to ensure not only law compliance, but ongoing policy implementation; in this sense, it
can also be defined in terms of an ineffective punitive focus that absorbs resources that could be
1.1 Policy Client: Nayarit’s State Government’s Office of Tourism and Sustainable Development
The client to whom this policy analysis is addressed is Nayarit’s State Government. The client’s
legal duties and prerogatives include proposing and executing strategic development plans for
the state (Gobierno de Nayarit 2020). Since the issue of sea turtles’ eggs poaching directly
and touristic assets (PRODERETUS 2014)—, the policy analyzed in this document falls under
the responsibility of the client’s Office of Tourism and Sustainable Development (OTSD)
Not only is Nayarit’s state-level OTSD particularly well suited to implement this policy in terms
of its functions, but it has also been identified the most effective government level to address egg
poaching issues and its implications: municipalities across Mexico lack effective administrative
devices to coordinate beyond the local scale for development projects, and the federal level is too
broad to effectively tackle the particular concerns of the specific region of interest (Monroy et al.
2020). In fact, a study by Virgen and Saldaña (2012, cited in Monroy et al. 2020) finds that
planification for touristic development in Mexico is most efficient when implemented by state-
level offices, slightly higher than nation-wide offices, and almost twice as effective as
municipality-level offices.
Nayarit’s state-level OTSD is therefore an adequate client in terms of responsibility for focalized
sustainability policy, as well as in terms of the financial resources and legal capacity to
2. Evaluation Criteria
Following Patton et al. (2016), having defined the problem (see Section 1), evaluation
criteria are necessary to evaluate the potential policy alternatives and identify the most
convenient one to address the policy problem. Considering the objective is to increase the
interest of and information available to local communities in getting involved in sea turtle
sustainability practices and reject poaching both as egg clients and as poaching perpetrators—
and that the wider goal is to improve conservation rates for sea turtles across the state of
Nayarit—, the following relevant criteria were determined to evaluate policy alternatives; refer
to Table 1 for details on each criterion in relation to the policy problem, including proposed
This criterion focuses on the effectiveness of the policy alternative to assess whether or not it
This criterion focuses on change in net worth to assess the impact on communities’ income
This criterion focuses on the acceptability of the policy alternatives from the perspective of
communities as the main affected stakeholders, assessing initial and ongoing support for the
policy from local population, considering whether the communities are receptive to the policy
implementation.
This criterion considers two aspects: institutional commitment, looking at whether organizational
collaboration between Nayarit state staff in charge of policy implementation and communities
where the policy is implemented is sustained and efficient, and budget capability, assessing if
resources allocated, including human, financial, and technical resources are sufficient for optimal
policy implementation.
To propose policy alternatives to the identified policy problem (see Section 1 for
definition), I used May’s (1981, p. 227) Feasible Manipulations Approach to identify variables,
propose manipulations of those variables, and combine them into sets of policy strategies.
Using the Feasible Manipulations Approach to create policy alternatives offers the advantage of
orienting all strategies to what is actually practicable in the area and by the client, without
attempting too much at once (May 1981). On another hand, using the Feasible Manipulations
Approach to create policy alternatives poses the limitation of producing rather rigid sets of
strategies, giving policy design a solid structure at the expense of that structure not being very
flexible to incorporate creative adjustments “on the go”; this may result problematic, for
instance, if the Political Viability (see Section 2.3) is not optimal, if Technical feasibility (see
Section 2.1)
Five variables were chosen for manipulation, considering the capability of the policy client—
Nayarit’s State Government’s OTSD (see Section 1.1). The five variables are described below:
Variable 1 was chosen considering the potential of the Mexican Free Public Textbook system’s
feature of “La Entidad donde Vivo” (“the state where I live”). While these public schoolbooks
follow the same syllabus nation-wide, some subjects are adapted to every state’s resources and
heritage (CONALITEG 2021); the state of Nayarit can use this to incorporate a conservation
Variable 2 draws from the reported effect of awareness documentaries on public perceptions of
environmental urgency and impact on action-oriented commitment (Psihoyos et al. 2015, David
2016, Roosen et al. 2017). This variable can facilitate understanding of sea turtle conservation
implications, foster interest in the issue and lead to higher practical involvement in policy
solutions.
arrangements, and mostly providing a space for community members to directly discuss
problems, needs, and courses of action. This variable contributes to address policy problem by
incorporating horizontal input from affected community members, instead of devising a top-
down strategy that is most likely to fail; this is a relevant asset given the focus on community
involvement (see Section 1) as a means to promote medium and long-term continuation and
Variable 4 seeks to make use of existing informal subdivisions within each town. Catholic
parishes across Nayarit’s coastal towns have established “barrios” (small neighborhoods) in
every town, which are used mainly to assign duties during the many religious holidays’
celebrations. These subdivisions have operated for decades (in the case of the town of Lo de
Marcos, for instance, since the late 1970s; see Figure 1 for an illustration of this town’s church-
neighborhoods) which has strengthened teamwork dynamics within the neighborhoods. Such
social knit and organization can serve as a starting point to facilitate the implementation of the
Variable 4 also seeks to collaborate with and build on the work of local non-profit organizations,
including for instance San Pancho Turtles, Project Tortuga, Grupo Ecológico de la Costa Verde,
and the Entre Amigos Non-Profit Community Center, that are already involved in sea turtle
rescue and preservation and hence have technical experience and camp infrastructure.
Variable 5 addresses the concern of local citizens about mistrust in state institutions handling of
financial and material funds, given as corruption has been rampant regarding resources for
(Pacheco, Murillo & Aguilar 2012, cited in Monroy et al. 2020). This variable seeks to provide a
Four distinct levels of manipulation were considered for each variable: “no intervention”,
“limited”, “moderate”, and “wide”. Table 2 details what each level of manipulation consists of
The proposed variables and their potential manipulation alternatives were combined into
competing sets of policy strategies to respond to the identified policy problem (see Section 1);
Table 3 summarizes these combinations. The following five sets of policy strategy alternatives
were produced:
1. The “Business almost as usual” policy set would not implement would keep only
conservation efforts that are already under way through non-governmental initiatives,
adding only minimal resources to boost meetings and bring the topic to public attention.
2. The “Small steps” policy set focuses on achieving any possible positive changes with as
proposing high impact measures that are not perceived as overwhelming by communities.
4. The “Slow but steady” policy set focuses on long-term results and looks to impose only
5. The “High commitment catalyzers” policy set prioritizes ecologic conservation results
through intensive, very high impact measures aimed to produce prompt and long-lasting
changes.
Overall, these policy strategy sets were put together considering the ultimate objective of
incorporating sea turtle conservation policy goals into local culture. In this way, the policy
manipulations aim to ensure not only law compliance, but ongoing and robust policy
Development Office’s capacities and resources, five sets of policy strategy alternatives (see
Table 3) To distinguish among these alternative policy strategy sets, three approaches were
used— a qualitative assessment, a binary assessment, and a pondered assessment; these three
chosen approaches were selected to provide this analysis with a comparison of the desirability
and feasibility of each policy alternative from different, perspectives, in order to gives a more
realistic and useful decision-making tool for the client. The three approaches are detailed below:
For the qualitative assessment, a Goeller scorecard (see Table 4) , based on Patton et al.’s
(2016, p. 330) Matrix (Scorecard) Display Systems, was used to display the policy alternatives,
assessed using four evaluation criteria (see Table 1): Technical feasibility, Economic and
Goeller’s scorecard does not weigh criteria or establish a ranking of alternatives based on the
assessment, but offers a reasoned, orderly view of how each policy alternative responds to the
evaluation criteria (Patton et al. 2016). This approach allows the client’s work-team to apply
their own judgment based on the explanations provided by the policy analysis, and use it to seek
agreement among the client’s work team on how criteria should be weighted. The scorecard’s
main limitation is not providing a straightforward response to whether each alternative is useful
For the binary assessment, a Brightman’s alternative-consequence matrix (ACM) (see Table
5), based on Patton et al.’s (2016, p. 330) Matrix (Scorecard) Display Systems, was used to show
a simplified assessment of the policy alternatives, evaluating each set as passing or failing for
each criterion. Passing or failing grades were assigned based on the nuances from Goeller’s
Brightman’s ACM works is an absolutist approach that dismisses any alternative not meeting
fundamental criteria, even if that alternative poses other advantages; only those alternatives
adequately complying with all criteria are considered workable (Patton et al. 2016). While ACM
poses limitation regarding the amount of information conveyed compared to Goeller’s Scorecard,
directing focus to the most promising policy sets. The client can, ideally, use ACM and Goeller’s
For the pondered assessment, a Goals-Achievement Matrix (GAM) (see Table 6) , based on
Patton et al.’s (2016, p. 330) Matrix (Scorecard) Display Systems, was used to offer a ranking of
policy sets based on numeric evaluations of the alternatives, pondered by the relative importance
of each criteria to meet the policy goals. Based on Goeller’s Scorecard assessment (see Table 4),
scores were assigned to each alternative-criteria relation (see Table 6). Each criterion was
assigned a weight based over 1: 0.4 for “technical feasibility”, 0.3 for “administrative
operability”, 0.2 for “political viability”, and 0.1 for “economic and financial possibility”. The
weights were assigned considering the contribution of each evaluation criteria (see Table 1) to
the achievement of the general goal and specific objective of the policy (see Section 2), and
Multiplying criteria weight times ranking score, weighted scores were obtained for each
alternative-criteria relation; the weighted scores for each policy set were then added (see Table 6)
to obtain a total GAM score. The five policy alternatives were ranked using total GAM scores.
GAM presents the relative potential of each alternative policy set, calculated quantitatively using
common standards (Patton et al. 2016). The GAM approach strength is objectivity, to the extent
that GAM scores allow for numeric-based comparisons; however, quantifying some aspects of
the evaluation criteria can produce inappropriate indicators that complicate comparative
assessments of policy alternatives if the qualitative insight is not considered. Furthermore, Patton
et al. (2016) highlight numerical weights may not be readily agreed upon when multiple
decision-makers are involved; it must therefore be pointed out that, in the present analysis, GAM
has been manageable because only one policy analyst was in charge of assigning evaluation
criteria weights. On another hand, the criteria weights have the limitation of being based on the
These approaches offer the following results: Goeller’s Scorecard indicates the most suitable
alternative is the “High Commitment Catalyzers” policy set; which obtained “excellent” across
three of four evaluation criteria. GAM’s results confirm this, with the highest score among
alternatives for this set. Brightman’s ACM, instead, indicates “Attractive Convenience” as the
most suitable alternative, being the only set with passing grades for all four criteria. Using the
ACM approach, the “High Commitment Catalyzers” alternative obtains a failing grade for the
The difference between both policy alternatives “frontrunners” (i.e. “High Commitment
Catalyzers” and “Attractive Convenience”) can be interpreted as minimal considering that on one
hand, the only failing grade for the “High Commitment Catalyzers” alternative happens for the
lowest-weighted criteria, and that on the other hand, the GAM score for “Attractive
To evaluate the efficacy of the adopted policy alternative considering the policy problem
definition established in Section 1, two approaches1 based on Patton et al.’s (2016, p. 352) Six
1
Other types of evaluation approaches described in Patton et al.’s (2016, p. 352) Six Basic
Evaluation Processes, such as the experimental and the quasi-experimental mode, may in theory
Basic Evaluation Processes are proposed: the Before-and-After Comparison and the Cost-
In order to produce these evaluation processes, a fact-base must be collected to have baseline
measurements against which to compare ongoing progress measurements. Patton et al.’s (2016)
process to establish policy goals and operationalize them to track their success highlights the
importance of having as broad a fact base as possible. The required indicators for this purpose, as
well as their respective source and suggested frequency of data collection for both baseline
The application of the Before-and-After Comparison and the Cost-oriented (specifically Cost-
A strength of this approach that makes it suitable for the purposes of this policy analysis is it
allows for straightforward identification of whether or not the policy is effective, which is useful
bring useful insights to consider, especially in terms of identifying direct effects of the proposed
policy on the observed outcomes. However, they are not considered suitable to measure policy
concerns the policy alternatives presented in this analysis; this is mainly due to ethical and
practical considerations that arise when assigning populations to control and treatment groups.
in communicating results to relevant stakeholders including the general public. This, in turn, may
be key to determine future improvements to the policy measures (Patton et al. 2016).
exclusively on the adopted policy’s outcomes may forget considerations preceding those
outcomes. In this sense, if this approach is used, it should consider it may minimize relevant
information, such as budgetary implications (for instance, source of funding and the fact that
other policies that may go underfunded as a result), factors of sociopolitical feasibility (for
example, difficulty in generating social responsiveness or support for the policy among the
policy’s target communities), and potential externalities (including unexpected outcomes and
backlash from stakeholders harmed the adopted policy, such as families whose main source of
The “Economic and financial possibility” criteria (see Table 1) can be better addressed by a cost-
benefit approach given it must consider profitability. From the cost-oriented approaches, a cost-
benefit analysis is better suited to this case than a cost-effective analysis, because the objective of
the policy alternatives presented in this analysis is not to propose the ultimate utility
maximization based on available budget constraints;2 rather, the aim of the policy alternatives is
to promote financial benefits that outweigh the financial costs of policy implementation,
2
This may, however, be a relevant adjustment in assessing whether or not it is convenient to
communities.
The main strength of this approach concerns the production of objective numbers to account for
the benefits— or losses— derived from implementing the chosen policy alternative.
Nevertheless, the cost-benefit evaluation approach does pose weaknesses, as Patton et al. (2016)
point out, in that it may underestimate the impact of important positive outcomes of the policy
measured by indicators of success that are not easily quantified in monetary terms— including,
in the context of this policy analysis, restorative ecologic progress, strengthening of community
Considering the analysis presented in this document, both policy alternatives frontrunners
(i.e. “High Commitment Catalyzers” and “Attractive Convenience”, see Section 4.4) are
expected to set adequate results into motion to address the identified policy problem (see Section
1). Therefore, based on this analysis, the client is recommended to base their decision on which
of these policy sets best suits their agenda by considering, at the moment of deciding which
alternative to adopt, its available resources, agreements with other stakeholders, and political
interests.
measurements and ongoing evaluations for as many terms as the adopted policy continues to be
implementation processes, a limitation that will likely be faced in this monitoring and evaluation
stage regarding baseline measurements (as indicated in Section 5) is the limited documentation
of these indicators in the geographical area at stake, i.e. Nayarit coastal towns.3 Obtaining
reliable estimations might require local field work including context assessments and interviews,
surveys, and extended census questionnaires. This data is crucial to develop a mapping strategy
to recognize potential causal explanations in policy results as defined by Stone (2012, Chapter
8); in this sense, these indicators are necessary to evaluate if policy solutions are in fact
producing improvements in terms of community involvement and, ultimately, favoring sea turtle
conservation. Therefore, in spite of the potential difficulty and additional expense, investing
resources to collect data for these estimations prior to policy implementation is highly
recommended.
3
A study by Pacheco, Murillo & Aguilar (2012, cited in Monroy et al. 2020) has noted how the
lack of legal and administrative control of state officers in Nayarit makes it currently impossible
Bibliography
Amorocho, D. (2014). Tortugas Marinas, Guardianas del Océano, World Wildlife Fund
Colombia.
Ceballos, G. (2018). “La Guerra contra la Extinción”, in Boletín UNAM-DGCS, No. 447, 2:2018.
Clemons, R. and M. McBeth. (2020). “Chapter 7. Problem definition, mixed methodologies, and
praxis” in Public Policy Praxis (Clemons and McBeth 2020), Fourth Edition. New York:
México.
David, S. (2016). Eco-Fiction: Bringing Climate Change into the Imagination, University of
Exeter: UK.
Introduction (Dunn 2018), Sixth Edition. New York: Routledge, Taylor and Francis.
Gobierno de Nayarit. (2020). Public Service Offices and Organization, Gobierno del Estado,
Nayarit, Mexico.
Grupo Ecológico de la Costa Verde. (2021). San Pancho Marine Project Newsletter Antology
IAC. (2012). "Amenazas a las Tortugas Marinas y Posibles Soluciones", CIT-IAC, Inter-
May, P. (1981). “Hints for Crafting Policy Alternatives.” Policy Analysis, 7:2:227-244.
Mendoza, G. (2018). "30 años después… ¡México no elimina el consumo de huevo de tortuga!",
Monroy, Y., F. Flores Vilchez, J. Bernal Amaral, and B. García Carmona. (2020). “Políticas
Oaxaca Mío. (2016). “Playa Escobilla”, in Oaxaca Mío Magazine, Oaxaca, Mexico.
Parra Covarrubias, M. C. (2021). División Parroquial en Barrios 1980-2020, San Marcos Church
Historical Archive.
Patton, C., D. Sawicki, and J. Clark. (2016). Basic Methods of Policy Analysis and Planning, Third
PROCER. (2016). Las tortugas marinas en México: Logros y perspectivas para su conservación.
PROFEPA. (2019). Protección de las tortugas marinas en México: Estrategia de la Profepa para
Psihoyos, L., O. Ahnemann, and F. Stevens. (2015). Racing Extinction, Oceanic Preservation
Roosen, L., C. Klöckner, and J. Swim. (2017). “Visual art as a way to communicate climate
doi:10.1080/21500894.2017.1375002
Stone, D. (2012). “Part III: Problems” in Policy Paradox (Stone 2012), Third Edition. New York:
SWOT Scientific Advisory Board. (2011). The State of the World’s Sea Turtles (SWOT) Minimum
Data Standards for Nesting Beach Monitoring, version 1.0. Handbook, 28 pp.
Tables
Table 1. Evaluation criteria for proposed policy alternatives, based on Patton et al.’s (2016, p.
Sub-criterion and
of evaluation criteria
Effectiveness
Estimation of changes (before and
Whether or not policy achieves
after policy implementation)
improvements in sea turtle
for the following indicators:
conservation in Nayarit coastal
trade
poaching
Turtle indicators
Sub-criterion and
of evaluation criteria
beaches to spawn
estimates
Nayarit’s beaches
sustainable destination
Political viability Initial and ongoing support for members regularly involved in
Sub-criterion and
of evaluation criteria
- efficiency of policy
Institutional commitment
Sub-criterion and
of evaluation criteria
implementation, including
resources
Table 2: Possible Manipulations for Proposed Variables, based on May’s (1981, p. 227)
with no Focus on
Implementation
No additional Incentivized Mandatory and
of awareness
incentives for attendance for incentivized
documentaries
attendance given community attendance for
and Q&As
to community members community
members members
Film-making
workshops for
locals and
documentaries
Annual film
to promote local
documentaries
and awareness
community No additional
community
meetings
Profit
Community
Center)
use of funding for sea turtle for sea turtle for sea turtle
Table 3: Alternative Policy Strategies, based on May’s (1981, p. 227) Feasible Manipulations
Approach
Expansion of
conservation No
Limited Wide Wide Moderate
education program intervention
in local schools
Implementation of
No
awareness No
interventi Wide Limited Moderate
documentaries and intervention
on
Q&As
Implementation of
community No
Limited
workshop round Limited interventi Moderate Wide
tables on
(“mesas de trabajo”)
Implementation of
neighborhood No
Limited Moderate Moderate Wide
involvement in sea intervention
turtle camps
Transparency
committees to No
Limited Moderate Wide Wide
monitor Nayarit’s intervention
Table 4. Goeller’s Scorecard of policy set alternatives and evaluation criteria, based on Patton
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
in alternative,
compromise
its popularity.
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
expected to sourced
deplete profits.
natural
resources, The
making constancy
investing in natural
negatively produce
local increases in
economic profitability
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
activities of touristic
primary neurship
sectors. opportunities
across local
economic
sectors.
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
across benefits
expected to sectors.
deplete
natural
resources,
negatively
impacting all
local
economic
activities
based on
tourism and
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
primary
sectors.
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
Business High
Evaluation Attractive Slow but
almost as Small steps commitment
criteria convenience steady
usual catalyzers
those in goal.
charge of
releasing
adminis-
trative
resources.
Evaluation labels hierarchy: Poor < Fair < Sufficient < Good < Excellent
assessment*, based on Patton et al.’s (2016, p. 330) Matrix (Scorecard) Display Systems
Policy Alternatives
Business High
Evaluation Small Attractive Slow but
almost as commitment
criteria steps convenience steady
usual catalyzers
Technical
Fail Fail Pass Pass Pass
feasibility
Economic and
financial Fail Fail Pass Fail Pass
possibility
Political
Fail Pass Pass Pass Pass
viability
Administrative
Pass Pass Pass Pass Fail
operability
*“Poor” and “Fair” scores in Goeller’s scorecard (see Table 4) are considered generally
insufficient and consequently graded as “Fail”; “Sufficient”, “Good”, and “Excellent” scores in
Goeller’s scorecard (see Table 4) are considered generally adequate to fulfill the policy objectives,
and are consequently graded as “Pass”. The overall grade is “Pass” only if the alternative obtains
Economic
and
(1 * 0.1) = (2 * 0.1) = (4 * 0.1) = (2 * 0.1) = (5 * 0.1) =
financial 0.1
0.1 0.2 0.4 0.2 0.5
possibility
total
GAM 1.6 3.1 4.0 3.2 4.1
score
GAM
assessment
Policy
1st
alter- th th nd rd
5 best 4 best 2 best 3 best Best
native
alternative
rank
The total GAM score equals the sum of the corresponding column’s weighted scores.
Table 7. Fact-base indicators and sources for baseline and ongoing measurements,
based on Patton et al.’s (2016) operationalization process for policy monitoring and evaluation
Note: In this table, “Communities” refers to the population of those of Nayarit’s coastal towns to
reports
reports
reports
reports
reports
Number of people INEGI (official Mexican data Data from Data from
community available at
activities
Number of people INEGI (official Mexican data Data from Data from
conservation collection
activities
implemented beginning
implementation reports
conservation
funding
Communities’
public opinion Original survey designed and applied One month - Bi-monthly
implementation reports
Figures