Reducing Forest Emissions in The Amazon Basin

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 26

WORKING PAPER

Reducing forest emissions in the Amazon Basin


A review of drivers of land-use change and how payments for environmental services (PES) schemes can affect them
Sheila Wertz-Kanounnikoff, Metta Kongphan-Apirak and Sven Wunder

CIFOR

Working Paper No. 40

Reducing forest emissions in the Amazon Basin


A review of drivers of land-use change and how payments for environmental services (PES) schemes can affect them

Sheila Wertz-Kanounnikoff, Metta Kongphan-Apirak and Sven Wunder November 2008

2 R E D U C I N G F O R E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E A M A Z O N B A S I N A N D P E S S C H E M E S

Contacts
Sheila Wertz-Kanounnikoff Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR) P.O. Box 0113 BOCBD Bogor 16000 Indonesia Tel: +62 251 8622 622 Fax: +62 251 8622 100 Email: [email protected] Metta Kongphan-Apirak CIFOR consultant Email: [email protected] Sven Wunder Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR) Embrapa, Conv_nio CIFOR Tr. E. Pinheiro s/n CEP 66.095-780 Bel_m-PA Brazil Tel: +55 (91) 4009 2680 Fax: +55 (91) 4009 2651 Email: [email protected]

Acknowledgements
This paper was prepared as one of the background papers for the project Compensation and incentives for the maintenance of ecosystem services: A review of current knowledge and the implications for the Norwegian Climate Forest Initiative, funded by the Royal Norwegian Ministry of Foreign Aairs and conducted jointly by the International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), the World Resources Institute (WRI) and the Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR). We thank DFID for covering printing and dissemination costs through its funding of CIFORs Forests and Climate Initiative. The authors thank Arild Angelsen and Ole Hofstad for comments on an earlier draft, and Mel Kelly, Alana George and Je Walker for editing this paper.

Disclaimers
The views expressed in this publication are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the ocial position or policy of CIFOR, IIED, WRI or the Royal Norwegian Ministry of Foreign Aairs. The maps in this publication are for illustrative purposes and do not imply the expression of any opinion on the part of the authors, CIFOR, or their sponsors concerning the legal status of any country or territory or concerning the delimitation of frontiers or boundaries.

W O r K I N G P a P E r 3

Table of contents
Acronyms and abbreviations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 Executive summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 1 2 3 4 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 Drivers of land-use change and deforestation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 Agricultural expansion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Logging activities. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Infrastructure extension . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 Public policies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

Experience with payments for environmental services (PES) schemes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 Four PES case studies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 Characteristics of case study schemes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 Payment design. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Eectiveness considerations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 Eciency considerations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Equity considerations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

Concluding remarks. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 4.1 4.2 Performance-based incentive schemes based on conditionality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 Governance investments for eective law enforcement. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

4 r E D U C I N G F O r E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E a M a Z O N ba S I N a N D P E S S C H E M E S

Acronyms and abbreviations


AD CIFOR FAO ICDP IIED NK-CAP PES PSA-H REDD WRI Avoided deforestation Center for International Forestry Research (Indonesia) Food and Agriculture Organization Integrated Conservation and Development Project International Institute of Environment and Development (UK) Noel Kemp Mercado Climate Action Project (Bolivia) Payments for environmental services Payments for Hydrological Services (Mexico) Reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation World Resources Institute

CEDERNA Corporation for the Development of Renewable Natural Resources (Ecuador) CONAFOR State Forestry Commission (Mexico)

W O r K I N G P a P E r 5

Executive summary
L and-use change and deforestation in Latin America generally, and in the Amazon Basin specically, are driven primarily by economic protability (agricultural expansion and logging) and governance weaknesses (notably, lenient law enforcement), and only to a much lesser extent by deterministic poverty cycles. Nevertheless, poor forest dwellers (indigenous communities, smallholders, rubber tappers) have the potential to be important stakeholders in stabilising Amazonian land use. Changing incentives for big deforestation actors will likely have indirect eects also on these poor people, to the extent that they might gain or lose from deforesting and degrading activities. Large-scale strategies to reduce emissions from deforestation and degradation will thus require social impact assessments that account for leakage and perverse incentive scenarios. Latin America has been a pioneer in testing and implementing PES schemes in developing countries, and these experiences are of high value to regional REDD policy design. However, ideological resistance against PES/REDD in Amazonia also exists due to fears that such schemes will lead to the loss of land rights or of sovereignty. In these situations, intermediaries whom both service buyers and sellers trust can play an important role in mediating and catalysing initiatives. In addition, a signicant share of deforestation in the Amazon (and in other tropical forest frontiers) happens through private illegal but often tolerated occupation and clearing of government-owned forestlands. This type of deforestation cannot be stopped through landowner payments of the PES type since there are no legitimate landowners available to compensate for their conservation eorts. This paper suggests the following messages: Importance of performance-based incentive schemes with a focus on conditionality Among the variety of elements for enhanced PES adoption that also merit attention with regard to REDD, the conditionality criterion is of particular relevance. Although it is the key feature of performance-based arrangements, PES schemes across Latin America (and elsewhere) have been reluctant to apply hard conditionality in practice. Further experiments with enforced conditionality criteria in dierent local circumstances will aid assessment of their implications, and provide information on appropriate design (e.g., insurance for cases of accidental non-compliance etc.). Need for governance investments with a focus on effective law enforcement REDD schemes will have to rely strongly on functioning government institutions and eective law enforcement. So far, however, forest governance in Amazonia, where most Latin American deforestation occurs, remains weak. A key element for REDD-related investments in governance consists in eective law enforcement. To this end, crucial measures include strengthened institutional capacity for eective control and policing (manpower, vehicles, helicopters, other equipment) and enforcement (including functioning judiciary systems), but also institutional accountability (institutions must be held accountable across sectors for wrongdoings). REDD will likely have to deal with plenty of resistance across various economic sectors not only because of the idea of REDD per se, but because eective law enforcement with respect to land use (closing the agricultural frontier) will become a central requirement.

6 R E D U C I N G F O R E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E A M A Z O N B A S I N A N D P E S S C H E M E S

1. Introduction

ach year during the 1990s, tropical deforestation and forest degradation released 2.2 (+/- 0.6) billion tons of carbon to the atmosphere, of which about 35 per cent was from tropical America (Houghton 2003). Data from the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization, FAO, (2006) reports a total of 55.8 million hectares deforested in the Amazon countries during 1990 and 2005, which corresponds to a release of about 4.8 million tons of carbon (Table 1).

deforestation found in many parts of Africa. Experience with payments for environmental services (PES) schemes can provide further insights into the design of REDD strategies, mainly as regards the institutional set-up and contractual arrangements. This paper reviews current drivers of deforestation and forest degradation in the Amazon Basin and assesses experiences with performance-based schemes, especially PES schemes in the Amazon region. It is

Table 1: Deforestation in Amazon countries, 1990-2005 (Sources: FAO 2006; FAO 2007; IPCC 2006, as cited in Gibbs et al. 2007).
Country
Forest cover 2005 [1000 ha] Average annual change in forest area 1990 2005 absolute [1000 ha] Average annual change in forest area 1990- 2005 relative [%] Forest carbon stock aboveground [MtC] Forest carbon Average annual stock (above- and carbon emissions below-ground) 1990-2005 [MtC] [MtC]

Bolivia Brazil Colombia Ecuador Guyana Peru Suriname Venezuela Total

58,740 477,698 60,728 10,853 15,104 68,742 14,776 47,713 754,354

-270.33 -2,821.80 -47.40 -197.60 0.00 -94.27 0.00 -287.53 -3,718.93

-0.46 -0.59 -0.08 -1.82 0.00 -0.14 0.00 -0.60 -0.49

5,236 49,335 8,062 n/a 1,722 n/a 5,692 n/a 70,047

9,189 82,510 1,222 2,071 3,354 13,241 2,330 7,886 121,803

-24.33 -290.65 -6.30 0.00 0.00 -321.28

Emissions can double during El Nio periods, when severe drought aects large areas of the Amazon forests and augments the incidence of forest res (Alencar et al. 2006). Brazil, which contains 63 per cent of the Amazon biome, is responsible for by far the largest share of deforestation and associated carbon emissions in the Amazon region (see Figure 1) with the bulk occurring in the federal states of Par and Mato Grosso. Nepstad et al. (2007) estimate that if current trends continue, a total of 55 per cent of the forests of the Brazilian Amazon will be cleared, logged, or damaged by drought by the year 2030, releasing 20 (+/-5) billion tons of carbon to the atmosphere. Reducing emissions from tropical deforestation and degradation (REDD) is currently being discussed as an additional strategy to mitigate climate change. Information on the drivers of deforestation and landuse change presents important elements to improved design of local/regional REDD strategies. For example, agricultural expansion due to economic protability as in the case of cattle-ranching in Latin America and oil palm plantations in Southeast Asia requires dierent REDD strategies than the poverty-driven

organised as follows: Section 2 describes the drivers of land-use change and deforestation; Section 3 reviews current PES experiences in the region; and Section 4 comprises concluding remarks. Figure 1: Map of Amazon Basin countries

W O r K I N G P a P E r 7

2. Drivers of land-use change and deforestation


Tropical deforestation occurs mainly because nonforest uses are more protable than forest uses. A recent review of incentives to deforest summarise the following immediate causes (Chomitz et al. 2006): Own assets and access to credit markets (compared to capital-intensive largeholders, a poor household cant aord to clear much forest). High agro-ecological suitability (forestlands with good soils are cleared rst). High protability of farm output. High timber prices (can put pressure on old growth forests, but also induce tree plantations). Low o-farm wages in marginal areas. Roads. The eect of agricultural technology on deforestation is ambiguous: improved technologies reduce the size of land required to produce a certain income, but they can also reinforce incentives to replicate a more protable technology in larger areas (Angelsen and Kaimowitz 2001). For example, increased mechanisation in southern Brazilian agriculture during the 1970s released numerous workers to engage in deforestation at the Amazon frontier. The eect of land titling is also uncertain: safe titles may favour management of the standing forest, but they could also accelerate forest clearing, e.g., if the landowner sees cattle ranching as the long-term most protable land-use option (Chomitz et al. 2006). Agricultural expansion, infrastructure development, and selective logging are among the most frequently cited drivers of Amazon deforestation, while public policies and international market demand are reported as important underlying causes (see Table 2).1 During the early stages of Amazon colonisation in the 1970s1980s, government policies presented important
1 Broadly speaking, the underlying causes determine the eect of the above-mentioned incentives to deforest, which shape the drivers of deforestation.

Table 2: Drivers of land-use change, deforestation and degradation in Amazon countries 1990-2008 (Sources: Armenteras et al. 2006; Fearnside 2005, 2008; Camara et al. 2005; Naughton-Treves 2004; Pacheco 2006; Butler 2006, Kaimowitz and Smith 2001; Kaimowitz et al. 1998; Wunder 2000, 2003)
Country Bolivia Brazil Key drivers Agricultural expansion (cattle ranching, soybean, sorghum, sunflowers, illicit crops). Agricultural expansion (cattle ranching, soybean cultivation). Infrastructure extension. Selective logging. Agricultural expansion (cattle ranching, soybeans, illicit crops). Infrastructure extension (roads to forest frontier). Cattle ranching. Oil exploitation. Logging. Infrastructure extension. Logging. Agricultural expansion (cattle ranching, soybean cultivation shifting cultivation). Logging. Logging. Cattle ranching. Logging. Mining. Oil exploitation. Underlying causes Public policies (the World Banks Structural Adjustment Program Project in the 1990s, fiscal and credit policies). International demand for soybeans. Public policies (credits, roads, resettlement). International demand for soybeans. National, and recently global, beef demand. Institutional factors (weak law enforcement in frontier zones, weak property rights). Public policies (currency devaluation, low export tariffs, easy access to land). International demand for soybeans. Domestic demand for beef. Demographic factors (population pressure). Increased incomes raise demand for meat and dairy products. International demand for oil. Domestic timber demand for construction. International timber demand. Public policies (subsidised tax policies in frontier zones). Institutional factors (land speculation). Public policies (logging concession policies). Domestic demand for beef, timber. Weak governance with respect to private land appropriation

Colombia

Ecuador

Guyana Peru Suriname Venezuela

8 r E D U C I N G F O r E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E a M a Z O N ba S I N a N D P E S S C H E M E S

underlying causes Figure 2 Growth in Brazil beef production (Source: Kaimowitz et al. 2004) of deforestation. But since the 1990s, market factors (international agrarian prices) including renewable energy policies and agricultural health improvements have become more inuential in shaping the drivers of Amazon deforestation (Butler and Laurance, forthcoming). Poverty, although present across Source: United States Department of Agriculture (USDA), Foreign Agricultural Service (FAS), 2004. Amazonia, *CWE = carcass weight equivalence in ,000 of metric tons (p) = preliminary (f) = forcast only marginally contributes to deforestation: in the Brazilian Amazon, (FBOMS 2005, Naughton-Treves 2005, Fearnside small-scale farmers are estimated to account for about 2001). Soybean farming also provides key economic one fth of deforestation (Chomitz et al. 2006). and political impetus for new infrastructure projects, which accelerate deforestation by other actors (Camara et al. 2005). This tendency is likely to increase as the 2.1 Agricultural expansion demand for soy for agro-fuel is also rising. Although Agricultural expansion for large-scale cattlesome countries have started refraining from the ranching activities is the key driver of Amazon promotion and use of bio-fuels (e.g., those of the deforestation and associated emissions.2 Chomitz and European Union), planting bio-fuels (soy, sugar cane, Thomas (2001) estimate that by 1995 almost 90 per oil palm, etc.) continues to be protable, inducing cent of newly deforested Brazilian Amazon land was rapid agricultural expansion, including in the Amazon used for extensive pasture use. Brazil, where Amazonian Basin.3 The recent announcement by the Malaysian cattle ranching is concentrated, has emerged in Government in July 2008 that 100,000 hectares of oil recent years as the largest beef exporter in the world, palm plantations will be established in the Brazilian surpassing the U.S. in 2003 and Australia in 2004 Amazon (Butler 2008) is just one indication that agro(Peel 2008). Domestic beef consumption used to fuels remain on the rise. drive the expansion of Brazils cattle ranching activities between the 1970 and 1990s, but international drivers 2.2 Logging activities have gained far greater importance since 2000 (Figure 2). Kaimowitz et al. (2004) explain the skyrocketing In recent years, logging has emerged as an international demand for Brazilian beef by the additional, though still minor, driver of land cover devaluation of the Brazilian currency and eradication of change in Amazonia. Although rarely directly leading animal diseases such as foot and mouth disease, as well to deforestation, it contributes indirectly by leaving as the outbreaks of mad cow disease (BSE) and the debris that makes it easier for forests to repeatedly catch avian u that negatively aected livestock production in re, and by building roads that enable farmers to move many other parts of the world. into forested areas (Kaimowitz et al. 2004). Logging Soybean cultivation is also growing in the Amazon causes forest degradation (due to collateral damage region. Expanding primarily on degraded pasturelands to remaining trees, sub-canopy vegetation, and soils) (Brando et al. 2005), its share in Amazon clearing at and associated carbon emissions. Asner et al. (2005) least in Brazil is considered low relative to clearings estimated that logged areas in the Brazilian Amazon for new pastureland (Chomitz and Thomas 2001). ranged from 12,075 to 19,823 km2/year (+/- 14 per Nonetheless, soybean production can function as an cent) between 1999 and 2002, equivalent to 60-123 per important indirect driver as it induces land sellers cent of the areas deforested during the same period (see (e.g., cattle ranchers and smallholders) to advance Table 3). The associated regional carbon emissions were further into the Amazon forest to open up new lands estimated up to 0.08 gigatons of carbon (GtC) per year
2 According to estimates from the FAO, the livestock sector alone is responsible for nine per cent of global anthropogenic CO2 emissions, the largest share of this coming from land-use changes especially deforestation (Steinfeld et al. 2006). 3 For example, although the Brazilian president has informed journalists that no sugarcane is being planted in the Amazon region, this is not true at least in the Amazon state of Acre (see: www. amazonia.org.br, 23 June 2008).

W O r K I N G P a P E r 9

for logging, which increases total annual anthropogenic carbon ux from the Amazon forest by up to 25 per cent over carbon emissions from deforestation alone (Asner et al. 2005). Although signicant methodological challenges remain to measure the impact and extent of logging (DeFries et al. 2007; Krug 2008), logging already stands out as a key driver of change in vegetation cover.

2.3 Infrastructure extension


New or improved roads into forested areas tend to strongly promote deforestation (Chomitz et al. 2006). One analysis of 78 case studies from Latin America found that road access was a driver of deforestation in 75.6 per cent of the cases (Geist and Lambin 2002). Road development is often promoted in terms of rural development objectives, e.g., during the early stages of Amazon colonisation with the construction of the TransAmazonian highway, built in the 1970s. Improved accessibility to markets or intermediate processing centres (e.g., slaughterhouses, sawmills) increase landuse protability and tend to induce more deforestation. For example, the immediate realisation of all road projects proposed under Avana Brasil a large-scale Amazon infrastructure development programme of the Brazilian government to be implemented during 19992020 would result in an estimated 28-42 per cent deforestation of the Amazon forest by 2020 (Laurance et al. 2001). In addition, oil and gas development is emerging as a threat of access-provision in the western Amazon, particularly in Colombia, Ecuador, Peru and Bolivia, and to a lesser extent, Brazil. Finer et al. (2008) found that 688,000 km2 of the western Amazon is presently under concession for oil and gas development, partly

inside indigenous reserves and protected areas. Oil and gas development in the western Amazon can potentially have direct and indirect eects on deforestation and forest degradation (Finer et al. 2008). Direct impacts include deforestation for access roads, drilling platforms and pipelines, and are typically minor point impacts that in and of themselves aect relatively small forest areas (see Wunder 2003: ch.7).4 Indirect forest-cover eects arise from the easier access to remote primary forests being provided by new oil roads, facilitating uncontrolled logging, hunting, and squatting. For example, extensive deforestation in the northern Ecuadorian Amazon followed colonisation along the oil access roads (Sierra 2000; Bilsborrow et al. 2004).

2.4 Public policies


Government policies, as an underlying cause of deforestation, were especially inuential in the early phases of Amazon colonisation, from the 1960s to the 1980s. In Brazil, for example, agricultural colonisation both large-scale and small-scale was widely supported by public policies, especially in the form of tax reductions, credit subsidies, and technical assistance. Since the 1990s, however, the underlying cause of deforestation in Amazonia has shifted from public policies to market forces. The demand for beef and soybeans and more recently renewable energy sources has skyrocketed since the 1990s. Whereas public policies therefore provided an important impetus for land colonisation in the early phases, in later stages this trend proved to be largely self-sustained in economic terms (Kaimowitz 2002).
4 Oil operations also cause forest degradation from contamination from oil spills and wastewater discharges, although these do not have a direct inuence on forest cover and carbon stocks.

Table 3: Selective logging rates from 1999-2002 in five major timber-producing states of the Brazilian Amazon, with comparisons to the deforestation rates reported by the Brazilian National Institute for Space Research (INPE) (Source: Asner et al. 2005)
State 19992000 rates (km2 year-1) Logged Acre Mato Grosso* Par Rondnia Roraima Total 64 13,015 5,939 773 32 19,823 Deforested 547 6,176 6,671 2,465 253 16,112 20002001 rates (km2 year-1) Logged 53 7,878 5,343 923 55 14,252 Deforested 419 7,504 5,237 2,673 345 16,178 20002001 rates (km2 year-1) Logged 111 7,207 3,791 946 20 12,075 Deforested 727 6,880 8,697 3,605 54 19,963

Only the northern 58% of Mato Grosso containing forested lands was included in the analysis.

10 r E D U C I N G F O r E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E a M a Z O N ba S I N a N D P E S S C H E M E S

3. Experience with payments for environmental services (PES) schemes


Payments for environmental services (PES) schemes can provide important insights for the design of performance-based REDD arrangements. PES are based on the principle of contractual conservation, with a strong emphasis on conditionality where payments occur only when the requested environmental service (or land use assumed to secure the service) has actually been delivered a requirement that in practice has often remained weakly implemented (Wunder 2007; Wunder et al. 2008).5 The link between PES and REDD occurs at two levels. One is that nations states are likely to receive international PES transfers through REDD independent of how they eventually will spend the money. Second, the modality of landowner compensation PES is one of the ways that governments will be able to spend their money to make sure they achieve reductions in deforestation on the ground. PES can be implemented at local and national level, with the latter corresponding to the likely scale of REDD transactions. National or government-nanced schemes where governments, on behalf of the actual service users, pay for the provision of environmental services are insightful regarding their institutional framework for channelling payment ows from national to local levels. Local schemes can provide information
5 Wunder (2005, p.3) uses a ve-criteria denition, where PES are described as i) voluntary transactions where ii) a well-dened environmental service or land use likely to secure the environmental service is iii) being bought by at least one service buyer from (4) at least one service provider (5) if, and only if, the service provider secures service provision (conditionality).

on conditional payments to providers of environmental services that may be applicable in national schemes. Latin America has been a forerunner in implementing and experimenting with PES. The region supports numerous PES schemes, including the rst national-level scheme implemented in a developing country, initiated in Costa Rica in 1996 (Pagiola 2008). Carbon and watershed protection have been the two dominant services focused on, with biodiversity and recreational services of secondary prevalence. The spatial focus has also been dierentiated. Watershed schemes have emerged in the drier mountainous areas of the Andes and of Central America, where water increasingly becomes a key constraint to development. In the Amazon water is plentiful, but the carbon value of large forested areas with low population densities (and thus relatively low conservation opportunity costs) has favoured the implementation of a series of mitigation and reforestation projects (Southgate and Wunder 2007). The following subsection describes four selected case study PES schemes in Latin America in terms of their eciency, eectiveness and equity outcomes, and lessons for REDD design in the regional context. Distinguished by the number of people involved, these include two small-scale schemes in Bolivia and Ecuador, and two larger-scale schemes in Mexico and Brazil. All these schemes involve payments for forest environmental services, including avoided deforestation. Reasons for the selection of these four schemes are given in Table 4.

Table 4: Selected case studies in Latin America and reasons for their selection
PES scheme 1. Noel Kempff Mercado Climate Action Project (NK-CAP), Bolivia. 2. Bolsa Floresta, Brazil. Justification as case study First scheme paying for avoided deforestation (AD) (= relevant as the pioneer of REDD-type schemes). Government is seller of AD services to international donors (= relevant as it corresponds to one likely design form of the international REDD scheme). State-level scheme paying for REDD services in Amazon forest (= early starter in implementing schemes in view of later connection with international REDD markets). Strong livelihood considerations (= relevant as in many tropical forest areas, forest stewards are smallholders). One of the few PES cases that successfully applies the conditionality criterion (= important for REDD transactions where payments only occur after measurable and verifiable results). National-level scheme paying for forest conservation (= relevant as REDD schemes will likely contain a national implementation level). Individual and collective landowners as service providers (= relevant as in many tropical forest areas, traditional communal land ownership remains important). Poverty considerations explicit (= relevant as in many tropical forest areas, forest stewards are poor).

3. Pimampiro, Ecuador. 4. PSA-H, Mexico.

W O r K I N G P a P E r 11

3.1 Four PES case studies


The Noel Kempff Mercado Climate Action Project in Bolivia (Sources: Brown et al. 2000; Asquith et al. 2002) The Noel Kemp Mercado Climate Action Project (NK-CAP) originally comprised 642,458 ha but was later, as one project objective, extended to 832,000 ha that are now located inside the Noel Kemp National Park in north-eastern Bolivia. It was established in 1997 with the objective of mitigating CO2 emissions from deforestation. This was realised via i) compensations to forest concessionaires for giving up their logging rights on government owned lands to expand the area of the National Park, ii) eective enforcement of the deforestation ban in protected areas within the park by reducing slash-and-burn agricultural and iii) initiating alternative income-generation programmes for surrounding communities to compensate for lost forest access rights and lost salary employment with timber companies. The government is the main provider of the avoided deforestation service, although three local communities also contribute and are being rewarded through benets from integrated conservation and development projects. Co-funded by three American companies, (American Electrical Power System, BPAmoco and Pacic Corp), with two NGOs (The Nature Conservancy and Fundacin Amigos de la Naturaleza) as intermediaries, the project has a total duration of 30 years and is now in its third phase (2007-2010). The NK-CAP has been reported as successful since the start, but it should be remembered that the area has not witnessed strong deforestation pressures. Between 1997 and 2005, 989,622 tons of CO2 emissions were avoided. The Forest Stewardship Program (Bolsa Floresta) in Amazonas State, Brazil (Source: Government of the State of Amazonas 2007) Bolsa Floresta is a public programme of the state of Amazonas, the largest state in the Brazilian Amazon. It has been implemented since September 2007 by the Amazonas Sustainable Foundation and two other Brazilian institutions the public Secretariat for the Environment and Sustainable Development and Bradesco, the largest private bank in Brazil. The key objectives are improved forest conservation (avoided deforestation) and livelihood improvements of traditional and indigenous communities in state protected areas and sustainable use reserves. Specically, the programme rewards indigenous communities and long-term settlers for their commitment to avoid deforestation. Eligible to participate are families, communities or family associations. Families are required to participate in a two-day training course on sustainable land-use management prior to joining the programme. Payments dier depending on participant

type (families, communities or family associations). For example, a family can receive about R$50 (US$30) per month (ideally paid to the wife), while a community association can receive R$4,000 (US$ 2,500) per year. A penalty is applied when participants deforest beyond a maximum limit or render their land uses unsustainable. Presently, the programme covers six reserves/protected areas and 2,102 families in six conservation units of Amazonas state. The objective is to expand to 4,000 families by the end of 2008. It is still too early for an assessment of programme impacts. The PES scheme in Pimampiro, Ecuador (Source: Echavarra et al. 2004; Wunder and Alban 2008) This watershed PES scheme is located in the Andean municipality of Pimampiro in northern Ecuador. It has been implemented since 2000 in the upper watershed of the Palaurco River, which serves the 13,000 inhabitants of the municipality, in order to secure water quality and dry-season quantity through forest conservation and thus avoided deforestation in an uplands community with latent agricultural land colonisation. The establishment of the scheme cost $38,000 and was implemented by CEDERENA (Corporation for the Development of Renewable Natural Resources), a local NGO. The target recipients are 27 households in Nueva Amrica Cooperative, located just above the water intake of the Palaurco watershed. In the beginning, PES contracts lasted for ve years, but since the end of 2005 participants have renewed the contract for an indenite period. The quarterly payments are conditional on contract compliance and vary depending on the type of forest: US$6/year/ha for intervened forest; US$9/year/ha for mature secondary forest; and US$12/year/ha for primary forest. The funds for recurrent PES transfers originate from a 20 per cent water consumption surcharge on the 1,350 families with metered connections in Pimampiro, plus the interest generated by a water fund, which initially held US$15,000. The current challenge for the municipality is to maintain a credible monitoring system under budgetary constraints. The programme shows ample success: deforestation has stopped and the native vegetation cover has regenerated markedly. Payments for Hydrological Services (PSA-H) in Mexico (Source: Muoz-Pia et al. 2008; Southgate and Wunder 2007) PSA-H is a national-level PES scheme that has been operating since 2003, when there were increased water shortages in many parts of the country. To secure water ow and water quality, the programme aims at conserving those natural forests under greatest threat. Funds are managed by CONAFOR (Comisin Nacional Forestal), the State Forestry Commission.

12 r E D U C I N G F O r E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E a M a Z O N ba S I N a N D P E S S C H E M E S

Payment levels were derived from opportunity cost assessments, and dierentiated by forest type (cloud forests received a higher payment than other forest types). The funds for PSA-H increased from US$18 million in 2003 to US$30 million in 2004, derived from charges paid by federal water users. Service providers are both individual landowners and communities (ejidos), contracted for ve years with payment and with limited possibility of contract renewal. One key eligibility criterion consists in eective control over natural forests of good quality. The programme was well-received by landowners, with the number of requests to participate grossly exceeding its existing nancial means. Weaknesses of the programme include likely low additionality due to insucient spatial targeting (insucient funds are allocated to the places with highest deforestation risks), and ineciencies arising from largely undierentiated payment levels, paying probably too much to those who

nanced schemes are fully voluntary for both service buyers and sellers, and focus on one environmental service (e.g., water, carbon); government-nanced schemes are generally only voluntary on the supplier side and often aim at more than one environmental service (Wunder et al. 2008). Of the selected four case studies, the Bolivian and Ecuadorian cases are usernanced schemes; the Brazilian and Mexican cases present government-nanced schemes (see Table 5). All selected case studies evolved over the last 11 years and involve some form of forest protection as a means to secure hydrological functions or abate emissions from deforestation (see Table 5). The obstacles to implementation vary among the selected schemes and indicate the type of diculties REDD may encounter, emphasising in particular the relevance of appropriate payment design. Each scheme has an intermediary between service seller and buyer, but diers in its selection of sellers,

Table 5: Characteristics of PES case studies (adapted from Wunder et al. 2008)
PES scheme Environmental service Who buys? Who sells? Start year Spatial scale Obstacles

User-financed
Reduced emissions from deforestation and degradation (REDD). Pimampiro, Forest conservation/ Ecuador. restoration for hydrological services. Government-financed Bolsa Floresta, REDD. Brazil. NK-CAP, Bolivia. 3 American companies. Bolivian government and local communities. Members (81%) of a cooperative residing in upper target watershed. Forest stewards living in protected areas. Individual landholders and communities. 1997 642,458 ha. Continued logging and deforestation at park boundaries. Monitoring costs, free riders, landuse/service link.

Urban water users with meters.

2000

Palaurco watershed, left side (496 ha).

State of Amazonas + private bank. Water users and state forestry agency.

2007

PSA-H, Mexico.

Avoided logging and deforestation for hydrological services.

2003

Conservation units (CU): 6 reserves (> 2,000 families) in 6 CUs. National, priority areas: 600,000 ha (2005).

Low payment levels, low conditionality. Rent-seeking by communities with timber firms, low conditionality.

would have conserved their forests anyway, and too little to those who face really signicant opportunity costs. The monitoring system has also revealed some weaknesses, so that conditionality does not always apply (i.e., some deforestation has been ignored). An indepth assessment of programme eectiveness is not yet possible, but it seems that deforestation in PES enrolled areas is half the national average (C. Muoz-Pia, pers. comm. Sept. 2008).

3.2 Characteristics of case study schemes


The case studies are grouped into user-nanced and government-nanced schemes to express the nature of the actual service buyer the end user, or a third party (typically the government) on behalf of end users. User-

monitoring, severity of sanctions and degree of conditionality (see Table 6). Intermediaries between buyers and sellers of environmental services generally play an important role in PES schemes, and are often the main drivers of the schemes. Very often nongovernmental organisations play this role, especially in user-nanced schemes. In government-nanced schemes, as in Mexico and Costa Rica, this role is usually taken by government agencies. Seller selection or spatial targeting can improve the cost-eectiveness of PES schemes, for example by targeting high deforestation risk areas (as is done in the Ecuadorian and Mexican schemes). Seller selection and spatial targeting is especially relevant when the scope of the PES/REDD scheme is large and available resources constrained, i.e., where prioritisation is needed. Monitoring is a key requirement for verication

W O r K I N G P a P E r 13

Table 6: Design features of PES case studies (adapted from Wunder et al. 2008)
PES scheme Intermediary Local and international NGOs. Seller selection Macro-level: Bolivian govt. Locally: people using the protected area extension. High threat and strategic service site. Monitoring Remote sensing analysis with ground-truthing. Sanction Not applied. Conditionality Only in the initial government deal: paying for protected area extension.

User-financed
NK-CAP, Bolivia.

Pimampiro, Ecuador.

Local NGO.

Quarterly site inspection, now deteriorating. Remote sensing analysis with ground-truthing. Yearly remote sensing analysis; very few site visits.

Temporary or permanent High, lately some PES exclusion. decline.

Government-financed
Bolsa Floresta, Local NGO and Forest dwellers in Brazil. association. conservation units. PSA-H, Mexico. Several state agencies. 2003: almost random. Since 2005: multicriteria grading. Yellow and red cards (contract withdrawal).* Designed to be high, but with some loopholes.

Designed to be high, but Intentional: cancel with some monitoring current + future payments; unintentional: problems. no payment for affected area.

* Families who have deforested a crop area up to 50% larger than the crop area in 2007 (when the Bolsa Floresta Program was implemented) will receive a yellow card and must explain to the association the reasons for having increased deforestation. Those with a yellow card who continue deforestation in the following year will receive a red card and the payment will be suspended. If the new crop area is extended more than 50% (compared to the 2007 crop area) a red card will be given immediately and payments cease. The families given either two consecutive yellow cards or three in alternate years will be excluded from the programme. (See: www.orestavivaamazonas.org.br/bolsa_ oresta.php).

of land use and contract compliance, and should ultimately decide whether payments are made or not. The method used for monitoring depends on the size of the area to be monitored. For large areas, remote sensing tools are necessary, combined with selective ground-truthing, (e.g., for the Mexican and the State of Amazonas case study areas). In a small scheme like Pimampiro, the investment in remote sensing is not worthwhile. In order to assure genuine conditionality, it is necessary not only to monitor non-compliance, but to sanction it appropriately. Sanctions may dier according to the frequency or severity of the detected infraction (e.g., in Pimampiro and Bolsa Floresta), or according to whether or not the infraction was intentional (e.g., in Mexico PSA-H). No sanction mechanism was applied in the Bolivian case, since the deal with the government was a one-o, while the local communities are receiving non-conditional benets from integrated conservation and development projects. Conditionality is a key criterion for performancebased schemes, i.e., payments are only made if service delivery can be veried. Rigorous implementation of conditionality substantially improves the eciency of PES, although the ethical and public relations consequences of denying and/or retracting payments from poor communities often mean it is not implemented. The success of the Pimampiro scheme, for example, is to a large extent attributed to its high conditionality criterion: various families were temporarily excluded from the scheme when sanctioned for non-compliance, but most rejoined the scheme later

on, having accepted its quid pro quo approach (Wunder and Alban 2008). Conditionality has been a concern also for the Bolsa Floresta scheme (with rules being crafted somewhat loosely) and the Mexican programme (with monitoring and sanctions working imperfectly).

3.3 Payment design


Payments are typically made in cash, but sometimes combined with technical assistance or inkind compensation (see Table 7). The decision on the mode of payment depends on the local circumstances and needs. In the case of Bolsa Floresta scheme, for example, where service providers are smallholders and often poor, cash payments are complemented with capacity-building and technical assistance. An ecient payment scheme would pay an amount only marginally above the individual costs of providing the service faced by each landowner. This corresponds to the opportunity costs and transaction costs involved in shifting from the current land use to a more sustainable one. In addition to politicaleconomic concerns (sellers may feel discriminated against by seeing their rents squeezed to the last cent), the implementation of such ecient payment forms requires more eort, because these spatially varying costs need to be revealed. For the sake of politicaladministrative ease, many implementers opt for uniform per-spatial-unit rates. Payment dierentiation generally increases the cost-eectiveness of PES (Engel et al. 2008). In our case studies, it has been undertaken in Mexico and

14 r E D U C I N G F O r E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E a M a Z O N ba S I N a N D P E S S C H E M E S

Table 7: Payment design features of PES case studies (adapted from Wunder et al. 2008; Porras et al. 2008)
PES scheme Mode of payment Amount [US$] Determination of payment level Timing of payment Differen-tiation Contract duration

User-financed
NK-CAP, Bolivia. Cash, in-kind, and technical assistance. Cash. n/a 1.6 million (total) for concessions; total gross gains for communities: 358,380. 6-12 US$/ha/year. Negotiated. Ex ante. n/a Programme lasts 30 years.

Pimampiro, Ecuador.

Monthly, post monitoring.

Higher for primary vegetation. No.

Initially 5 years, now unlimited.

Government-financed
Bolsa Floresta, Brazil. PSA-H, Mexico. Cash transfer, technical assistance. Cash. Total: US$300 (families); Administrative. US$ 2,000 for community associations. 27-36 US$/ha/year. Administrative. Monthly, (not clear whether ex post or ex ante). Annual, ex post. Not clear.

Higher for cloud forests.

5 years, conditional renewal.

Ecuador, but through payment of a premium for highservice areas, not for higher risk or higher opportunity costs. Potentially, payment dierentiation with respect to each of these factors can optimise the eectiveness and cost eciency of a PES scheme (Wnscher et al. 2008). However, due to equity concerns and for ease of administration, large-scale government-run variants in particular have so far preferred uniform payments (Wunder et al. 2008). In accordance with the principle that applies to performance-based measures, the timing of payments is supposed to be ex post (after verication) and only in cases of actual contract compliance. With the exception of NK-CAP in Bolivia, this applies to the selected case studies. One reason why payments are made ex ante in NK-CAP is that a number of economic activities were completely bought out, thus making it necessary to compensate up front for a series of productive investments. Contract duration among the selected schemes varies between 5 and 30 years with the exception of Pimampiro, where an unlimited timeframe was adopted. The NK-CAP 30 years duration was dened by the duration of the logging concessions that were bought for conservation purposes. Although in theory longer term arrangements allow for better long-term planning, ve year contracts (such as in Mexico and initially in Ecuador) can provide a practical trade-o between security and exibility because conditions, preferences and budgets change over time.

3.4 Effectiveness considerations


Eectiveness refers to whether a certain target in the context of PES, the delivery of environmental services (in REDD, the realisation of avoided

deforestation) has been achieved. Factors aecting the eectiveness of PES schemes include: baselines (reecting the business as usual scenario), payment design, additionality, leakage control, and permanence (see Table 8). Although baselines are important references to measure results against, in most of PES schemes they are not studied in great detail and very often results are based on the implicit assumption of a continuation of current trends (Wunder et al. 2008). Implicit baselines are, for example, used in the cases of Pimampiro and Bolsa Floresta. Additionality is closely related to the overall eectiveness of a programme. It is high where payments make an actual dierence compared to the business as usual scenario. In the cases of NKCAP and Pimampiro, additionality is high because deforestation and forest degradation would likely have continued in the absence of payments, but were in fact halted following the introduction of the schemes. Additionality is less certain in the cases of Bolsa Floresta and PSA-H where for many of the enrolled areas the a priori risk of deforestation was low, which means that deforestation was already unlikely to occur even in the absence of payments. This observation ts with the general perception that user-nanced schemes tend to have higher additionality than government-nanced schemes (Wunder et al. 2008). The degree to which a clear link between a certain land use and the environmental service it provides is established also determines the eectiveness of payments. While there is strong scientic evidence for some links (e.g., between forest conservation and water quality, biodiversity conservation, and carbon storage), it is less clear or highly site-specic for others (e.g., forest conservation and yearly or seasonal run-o and ood control). Eectiveness may be improved through

W O r K I N G P a P E r 15

Table 8: Factors affecting efficiency and effectiveness of PES case studies (adapted from Wunder et al. 2008)
PES scheme Baselines and scenarios Opportunity Additionality costs
Partially studied. Land-use/ service link Leakage Permanence Transaction costs [US$]

User-financed NK-CAP, Studied Bolivia. projection of timber demand.

High (studied) Studied, and High, for land controlled.* use: degradation for forest conservation. would have continued. High, for land use: clear trend change to conservation. Likely low (low deforestation risk). Unknown but evidence that some low-threat areas are offered. Assumed, not proven Zero.

Likely secured by law.

~$9.5 million (total project cost in 2002).

Pimampiro, Implicit likely Not studied. Ecuador. forest decline.

Not secured $38,000 beyond (startup); contract period. $3,600/yr (recurrent). Unclear (depends on governance structures). Not clear, (initial fund counts $20 million).

Government-financed Bolsa Implicit Floresta, current Brazil. deforestation trends. PSA-H, Mexico.

Not studied.

High.

Not studied.

Explicit static Studied. forest-cover baseline, threat area modelling.

Extensive research, but not explicitly modelled.

Not yet evaluated.

Unclear beyond Recurrent: contract period. 4% of payments (defined by law).

* Two types of leakage were assessed: leakage associated with avoided deforestation and leakage associated with averted logging. No leakage from averted deforestation upon project implementation was identied since appropriate leakage prevention measures were undertaken. Leakage from avoided logging, however, was estimated to range between 14-44 per cent (of timber savings), with the more realistic scenario (where export demand is perfectly elastic and prices are insensitive to changes in timber supply due to reduced logging concession areas) being 14 per cent (Winrock 2002). Note that part of these funds were used for payments: US$ 1.6 million was used to indemnify logging concessionaires, another small portion was used to buy out private property owners in the project area, and US$ 1.25 million was used for community development projects in the three communities at the park border and three other small communities (Robertson and Wunder 2005; Asquith et al. 2002).

site-specic assessments to clarify such links. However this can be costly, especially for small-scale schemes, so that in practice payments are often based on assumed links (such as in the case of Pimampiro). Leakage prevention is another important element in securing eectiveness. Because leakage is dicult to measure in practice, especially for avoided deforestation (Wunder et al. 2008), not many schemes conduct indepth assessments. The NK-CAP is one scheme that has invested heavily in leakage prevention measures (Brown et al. 2000). Part of the motivation is probably related to testing methods for measureable, additional emission reductions to be sold in international carbon markets (voluntary markets). Permanence is another key factor in ensuring eectiveness. Very often, permanence is unclear or not secured beyond the contract period (e.g., in the Ecuadorian and Mexican case studies). Permanence may be more likely to be secured in the cases of NK-CAP and Bolsa Floresta as these schemes are implemented within protected areas with de jure protection. However, de facto protection and permanence will largely depend on the strength of public law enforcement, and on ex ante unpredictable changes in the economic environment and in private land-use incentives.

Normally, one cannot expect a forest conservation/ REDD scheme to have generalised protection benets that go beyond the contract/payment period.

3.5 Efficiency considerations


Eciency refers to the costs made to achieve a certain target the lower the costs, the more ecient a scheme is. Information on conservation opportunity costs can help in the design of more cost-eective payments. Yet as mentioned before, analysing opportunity costs can be costly and many schemes, as in the majority of the selected case studies, therefore opt not to do this. Nonetheless, the literature on PES emphasises that payments based on the costs of providing a given environmental service (or land use likely to provide them) can strongly improve the eciency of a scheme. One way to reveal such costs for PES schemes is procurement auctions6, as already used in two PES schemes in the US and Australia (Ferraro 2008). Transaction costs reported here refer to the
6 A PES contract procurement auction is a process through which a buyer of environmental services invites bids (tenders) from suppliers of environmental services for a specied contract and then buys the contracts with the lowest bids (Ferraro 2008).

16 r E D U C I N G F O r E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E a M a Z O N ba S I N a N D P E S S C H E M E S

costs associated with the setting up and running of the scheme, not with the transaction costs borne by service providers (as they are covered in the payments). Generally, and as reected in our case studies, PES programmes face relatively high startup costs and fairly low recurrent costs (Wunder et al. 2008). In government-nanced schemes, such as PSA-H in Mexico, the level of recurrent costs is often conned by law to a percent-share of the annual budget. Comparing the transaction costs of the Bolivian NK-CAP project and the Bolsa Floresta scheme reveals that the xed costs of establishing PES can be very high and at times prohibitive for local schemes while larger-scale schemes can benet from economies of scale eects.

3.6 Equity considerations


Initial experience with PES schemes has occasionally revealed the risk of not reaching out suciently to the poorest land users. Because of certain requirements for participating in PES schemes (e.g., land titles, up front investments to nance licensing of land-use plans or necessary managerial skills), poorer land users can be disadvantaged as was initially the case in Costa Rica for example (Zbinden and Lee 2005). However, eorts are often dedicated to rendering PES pro-poor, helping to ensure that the poor can participate and that they will benet. For example, poverty considerations constituted one key element in the design of the PSA-H scheme in Mexico and an important innovation consisted in allowing contracts with collective service providers (Muoz-Pia et al. 2008). Livelihood considerations also play an important role in the Bolsa Floresta scheme, reected in

the provision of technical assistance and access to health and education services. Generally, additional co-objectives are more frequent in government-nanced schemes than in user-nanced schemes (Wunder et al. 2008), and this is also reected in the selected case studies (see Table 9). In the Latin American PES experiences, typical sideobjectives are: poverty alleviation (Mexican PSA-H) and sustainable regional development (Bolsa Floresta), while biodiversity conservation is sometimes pursued as an implicit co-benet (Mexico, Bolivia). PES schemes can try to limit the trade-o among objectives and render schemes pro-poor or pro-biodiversity, but overloading one scheme with too many side-objectives can ultimately become counter-productive as it basically then reverts to being an integrated conservation and development project (ICDP), and these have been widely criticised for their limited eectiveness.7 However, PES can also have indirect eects on the poor. In the Bolivian case of NK-CAP, for example, the logging ban made many local people lose the jobs they had with logging companies (Asquith et al. 2002). In particular, such welfare eects can occur in activityreducing PES schemes (i.e., payments are made to stop conducting destructive forest uses), where payments are made for pure forest protection without suciently attractive economic alternatives. As was the case for NK-CAP, PES development will need to account and control such indirect eects, and ensure that in these specic contexts, forest conservation does not make the poorest worse o.
7 See for example Wunder (2007) for a comparison of PES and ICDP.

Table 9: Side-objectives and welfare effects of PES case studies (adapted from Wunder et al. 2008)
PES scheme User-financed NK-CAP, Bolivia. Side-objectives Biodiversity conservation. Welfare effects on poor sellers Net gains for community members 1999-2002: per capita gains are estimated to be in the range of US$100250 (Robertson and Wunder 2005). Likely higher income and spending. Income generation, access to services. Income generation (PES can yield up to 10% of their total income).

Pimampiro, Ecuador. Government-financed Bolsa Floresta, Brazil. PSA-H, Mexico.

None. Sustainable livelihoods. Poverty alleviation (explicit). Biodiversity conservation (implicit).

W O r K I N G P a P E r 17

4. Concluding remarks
Land-use change and deforestation in Latin America are driven primarily by economic protability (agricultural expansion and logging), whether for smallholders or corporate interests, and governance weaknesses (notably, lenient law enforcement) and only to a much lesser extent because of deterministic poverty cycles. Although they are less frequently prime Amazon deforesters, poor forest dwellers (indigenous communities, smallholders, rubber tappers) can be important stakeholders in stabilising Amazonian land use. Changing incentives for the big deforestation actors will likely have indirect eects on these poor people, whether they gain or lose from deforesting and degrading activities (see the aforementioned case study from Bolivia). Largescale strategies to reduce emissions from deforestation and degradation will therefore require social impact assessments that account for leakage and perverse incentive scenarios. Latin America has been a pioneer in testing and implementing PES schemes in developing countries, and these experiences are of high value to regional REDD policy design. Experiences from both usernanced schemes and government-nanced schemes exist, and can inform the design of national/subnational REDD schemes, actor constellations and transactions. However, resistance against PES/REDD in Amazonia also exists due to the fear that such schemes represent the rst step toward permanent expropriation of resources (fear of sovereignty loss). In these situations, intermediaries whom both service buyers and sellers trust can play an important role in mediating and catalysing initiatives (Southgate and Wunder 2007). In addition, a signicant share of deforestation in the Amazon (and in other tropical forest frontiers) happens through private illegal but often tolerated occupation and clearing of government-owned forestlands. Note that this type of deforestation cannot be stopped through landowner payments of the PES type: there are no legitimate landowners available to compensate for their conservation eorts (Wunder 2007). Based on these insights, REDD-related investments could focus on the following two domains: rst, on actual performance-based incentive arrangements with a particular focus on eective implementation of the conditionality criterion, and second on improving forest governance by instating eective law enforcement and associated necessary reforms.

4.1 Performance-based incentive schemes based on conditionality


Among the variety of elements for enhanced and widespread PES arrangements that merit further attention, the conditionality criterion is of particular relevance. Although it is the key feature of performance-based arrangements, PES schemes across Latin America (and elsewhere) have been reluctant to apply hard conditionality in practice (Southgate and Wunder 2007). Among the reasons why conditionality receives low popularity are ethical and image reasons. But because it will matter greatly in REDD schemes especially when REDD credits are to be sold on ocial carbon markets further experiments with enforced conditionality criteria in dierent local circumstances will aid assessment of their implications, and provide information on appropriate design (e.g., insurance for cases of accidental non-compliance etc.).

4.2 Governance investments for effective law enforcement


REDD schemes will have to rely strongly on functioning government institutions and eective law enforcement. So far, however, forest governance in Amazonia, where most Latin American deforestation occurs, remains weak. Land-use change and deforestation are, to a considerable degree, associated with insucient enforcement of laws and policies: about 80 per cent of deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon is estimated to be illegal (World Watch Institute 2008). Part of this situation is due to past lenient law enforcement since traditionally the use of natural resources and land was, to all intents and purposes, carried out for free (Southgate and Wunder 2007). This tradition obviously clashes with new policies that seek to put an end to the open frontiers by starting to enforce existing land-use policies or by establishing a price for the use of traditionally abundant natural resources via environmental taxation or PES. Although a change in land-use mentality is underway, inevitably REDD will have to deal with plenty of resistance not only because of the idea of REDD per se (aforementioned fears of sovereignty loss, etc.), but because eective law enforcement with respect to land use will become a central requirement. A key element for REDD-related investments in governance consists of eective law enforcement. To this end, crucial measures include strengthened institutional capacity for eective control and policing (manpower, vehicles, helicopters, other equipment) and

18 r E D U C I N G F O r E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E a M a Z O N ba S I N a N D P E S S C H E M E S

enforcement (including functioning judiciary systems), but also institutional accountability (institutions must be held accountable across sectors for wrongdoings). One innovation for improved environmental law enforcement in very remote areas (such as introduced in Mato Grosso in 19968) is mobile courts, where a judge and police force y by helicopter to areas where there is a dispute to resolve the matter on the spot. Another Brazilian governance innovation is the establishment of
8 See: www.socioambiental.org/website/parabolicas/edicoes/ edicao35/reportag/pg6.html (accessed 30 September 2008).

sectorally independent institutions (e.g., the Brazilian Public Ministry) that monitor public performance and have the power to prosecute the wrongdoings of public servants and government institutions. Although further assessment of the eectiveness of these innovations is needed, they present important steps into the direction of improved forest governance in Amazonia.

W O r K I N G P a P E r 19

References
Alencar, A., D.C. Nepstad and M. del C. Vera Diaz (2006) Forest understory re in the Brazilian Amazon in ENSO and non-ENSO years: Area burned and committed carbon emissions in Earth Interactions 10 (Art. No. 6). Angelsen, A. and D. Kaimowitz (2001) Agricultural Technologies and Tropical Deforestation. CAB International, Wallington, UK. Armenteras, D., G. Rudas, N. Rodriguez, S. Sua and M. Romero (2006) Pattern and causes of deforestation in the Colombia Amazon in Ecological Indicators 6: 353-368. Asner, G.P., D.E. Knapp, E.N. Broadbent, P.J.C. Oliveira, M. Keller and J.N. Silva (2005) Selective Logging in the Brazilian Amazon in Science 310:480482. Asquith, N.M., M.T. Vargas-Ros and J. Smith (2002) Can Forest-Protection Carbon Projects Improve Rural Livelihood? Analysis of the Noel Kemp Mercado Climate Action Project, Bolivia in Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change 7: 323-337. Bilsborrow, R.E., A. Barbieri and W.K. Pan (2004) Changes in population and land use over time in the Ecuadorian Amazon in Acta Amazonica 34: 635647. Block, B. (2008) Deforestation escalates in Brazilian Amazon. Worldwatch Institute, September 5, 2008 (online news). Available online at: http://www. worldwatch.org/node/5877 Brando Pessoa, A., G. Castro de Rezende and R. Wanderley da Costa Marques (2005) Crescimento agrcola no perodo 1999-2004, exploso da rea plantada com soja e meio ambiente no Brasil. Texto para Discusso 1062. Instituto de Pesquisa Econmica Aplicada (IPEA), Rio de Janeiro, Brazil. Brown, S., M. Burnham, M. Delaney, M. Powell, R. Vaca and A. Moreno (2000) Issues and challenges for forest-based carbon-oset projects: a case study of the Noel Kemp Mercado Climate Action Project in Bolivia in Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change 5:99-121. Butler, R.A. (2006) Environmental proles of Surinam, Guyana and Ecuador. Available online at: www.mongabay.com (accessed 05 August 2008). Butler, R.A (2008) Future threats to the Amazon rainforest. Available online at: www.mongabay.com (accessed 17 August 2008). Camara, G., A.P.Dutraaguiar, M.I. Escada, S. Amaral, T. Carneiro, A.M. Viera Monteiro, R. Araujo, I. Viera, B. Beckers, William F. Laurance, Phillip M. Fearnside, Ana K.L.M. Albernaz, Heraldo L. Vasconcelos, and L.V. Ferreira (2005) Amazonian Deforestation Models in Science 307: 1043-1047. Chomitz, K.M., P. Buys, G. di Luca, T.S. Thomas and S. Wertz-Kanounniko (2006) At Loggerheads? Agricultural expansion, poverty reduction and the environment in the tropical forests. World Bank Policy Research Report. Washington D.C., USA. Chomitz, K.M. and T.S. Thomas (2001) Geographic Patterns of Land Use and Land Intensity in the Brazilian Amazon. Development Research Group, World Bank, with contributions by IBGE, University of Washington CAMREX Project, and IMAZON. DeFries, R., F. Achard, S. Brown, M. Herold, D. Murdiyarso, B. Schlamadinger and C. de Souza Jr. (2007) Earth observations to estimate greenhouse gas emissions from deforestation in developing countries in Environmental Science and Policy 10: 385-394. Echavarra, M., J. Vogel, M. Albn and F. Meneses (2004) The impacts of payments for watershed services in Ecuador in Markets for Environmental Services, Vol. 4. IIED, London, UK. Engel, S., S. Pagiola, and S. Wunder (2008) Designing payments for environmental services in theory and practice: an overview of the issues in Ecological Economics 65:4, pp. 663-75. FAO (2005) Global Forest Resources Assessment 2005. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, Italy. Available online at: http://www. fao.org/forestry/site/1191/en/ FAO (2007) State of the Worlds Forests 2007. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Rome. Italy. FBOMS (2005) Relation between expansion of soy plantations and deforestation understanding the Dynamics. Report prepared by the Forest Working Group of the Brazilian Forum of NGOs and Social Movements for Environment and Development (FBOMS). Fearnside, P.M. (2001) Soybean cultivation as a threat to the environment in Brazil in Environmental Conservation 28(1): 23-38. Fearnside, P.M. (2005) Deforestation in Brazil Amazonia: History, Rates, and Consequences in Conservation Biology 19(3): 680-688. Fearnside, P.M. (2008) The Roles and Movement of Actors in the Deforestation of Brazilian Amazonia in Ecology and Society 13(1): 23. Ferraro, P.J. (2008) Asymmetric information and contract design for payments for environmental services in Ecological Economics 65: 810-821. Finer, M., C.N. Jenkins, S.L. Pimm, B. Keane and C. Ross (2008) Oil and Gas Projects in the Western Amazon: Threats to Wilderness, Biodiversity, and Indigenous Peoples in PLOS ONE 3(8): e2932.

20 r E D U C I N G F O r E S T E M I S S I O N S I N T H E a M a Z O N ba S I N a N D P E S S C H E M E S

doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0002932. Geist, H.J. and E.F. Lambin (2002) Proximate Causes and Underlying Driving Forces of Tropical Deforestation in BioScience 52(2): 143-150. Gibbs, H.K., S. Brown, J.O. Niles and J.A. Foley (2007) Monitoring and estimating forest carbon stocks: making REDD a reality. Environmental Resource Letters 2. IOP Publishing Ltd., UK. Available online at: http://www.iop.org/EJ/article/1748-9326/2/4/045023/ erl7_4_045023.html Government of the State of Amazonas (2007) Amazonas Initiative on Climate Change, Forest Conservation and Sustainable Development. Secretariat for Environment and Sustainable Development. Government of the State of Amazonas, Manaus, Brazil. Houghton, R.A. (2003) Revised estimates of the annual net ux of carbon to the atmosphere from changes in land use and land management 1850-2000 in Tellus 55B:378-390. Kaimowitz, D. (2002) Amazon deforestation revisited in Latin. American Research Review, 37: 2, pp. 221-35. Kaimowitz, D., Erwidodo, O. Ndoye, P. Pacheco, and W. D. Sunderlin (1998) Considering the impact of structural adjustment policies on forests in Bolivia, Cameroon, and Indonesia in Unasylva, 49:149, pp. 57-64. Kaimowitz, D., B. Mertens, S. Wunder and P. Pacheco (2004) Hamburger Connection fuels Amazon Destruction. Center for International Forestry Research. Bogor, Indonesia. Available online at: www.cifor.cgiar. org/publications/pdf_les/media/Amazon.pdf Kaimowitz, D. and J. Smith (2001) Soybean technology and loss of natural vegetation in Brazil and Bolivia in Angelsen, A. and D. Kaimowitz (eds) Agricultural technologies and tropical deforestation. CABI International with CIFOR, Wallingford, UK. Pp. 195211. Krug, T. (2008) Detection of selective logging for estimating and monitoring forest degradation: methodologies and experiences in Brazil. Presentation at the UNFCCC Workshop on Methodological Issues relating to Reducing emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation in Developing Countries, Tokyo 25-27 June. Laurance, W.F., A.K.M. Albernaz, G. Schroth, P.M. Fearnside, S. Bergen, E.M. Venticinque and C. Da Costa (2002) Predictors of deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon in Journal of Biogeography 29:737-48. Muoz-Pia, C., A. Guevara, J.M. Torres and J. Braa (2008) Paying for the hydrological services of Mexicos forests: Analysis, negotiations and results in Ecological Economics 65: 725-736. Naughton-Treves, L. (2004) Deforestation and Carbon Emissions at Tropical Frontiers: A Case Study from the Peruvian Amazon in World Development 32(1): 173-190. Nepstad, D., B. Soares-Filho, F. Merry, P.

Moutinho, H. Oliveira-Rodriguez, M. Bowman, S. Schwartzman, O. Almeida and S. Rivero (2007) The costs and benets of reducing carbon emissions from deforestation and forest degradation in the Brazilian Amazon. WHRC-IPAM-UFMG. Pacheco, P. (2006) Agricultural expansion and deforestation in lowland Bolivia: the important substitution versus the structural adjustment in Land Use Policy 23: 205-225. Pagiola, S. (2008) Payments for environmental services in Costa Rica in Ecological Economics 65: 712724. Peel, D.S. (2008) 2008 Cattle Beef and Trade: The U.S. and Major Exporters. Available online at: www. cattlenetwork.com/content.asp?contentid=189831 (accessed 16 August 2008). Porras I., M. Grieg-Gran and N. Neves (2008) All that glitters: A review of payments for watershed services in developing countries. Natural Resource Issues No. 11. International Institute for Environment and Development. London, UK. Robertson, N. and S. Wunder (2005) Fresh tracks in the forest: Assessing incipient payments for environmental services initiatives in Bolivia. CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia. Rogner, H-H., D. Zhou, R. Bradley. P. Crabb, O. Edenhofer, B. Hare (Australia), L. Kuijpers and M. Yamaguchi (2007) Introduction in Metz, B., O.R. Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave and L.A. Meyer (eds) Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA. Sierra, R. (2000) Dynamics and patterns of deforestation in the Western Amazon: The Napo Deforestation Front, 19861996 in Applied Geography 20: 116. Southgate, D. and S. Wunder (2007) Paying for Watershed Services in Latin America: A Review of Current Initiatives. Working Paper 07-07. SNREM CRSP, Oce of International Research, Education, and Development, Virginia Tech., USA. Available online at: http://www.oired.vt.edu/sanremcrsp/documents/PES. Sourcebook.Oct.2007/Sept.2007.PESLatinAmerica.pdf Steinfeld, H., P. Gerber, T. Wassenaar, V. Castel, M. Rosales and C. de Haan (2006) Livestocks long shadow environmental issues and options. Food and Agricultural Organization, Rome, Italy. Available online at: www.virtualcentre.org/en/library/key_pub/longshad/ A0701E00.pdf Stern, N. (2006) The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge University Press. Cambridge, UK. Winrock International (2002) 2001 Analysis of Leakage, Baselines and Carbon Benets for the Noel Kemp Mercado Climate Action Project. Final Report prepared for The Nature Conservancy. Winrock International.

W O r K I N G P a P E r 21

Wunder, S. (2000) The economics of deforestation: the example of Ecuador. Houndmills, Macmillan Press and St. Martins Press, New York, USA. Wunder, S. (2003) Oil wealth and the fate of the forest. A comparative study of eight tropical countries. Routledge, London, UK. Wunder, S. (2005) Payments for environmental services: Some nuts and bolts. Center for International Forestry Research Occasional Paper 42. CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia. Wunder, S. (2007) The Eciency of Payments for Environmental Services in Tropical Conservation in Conservation Biology 21(1): 48-58. Wunder, S. and M. Alban (2008) Decentralized payments for environmental services: The cases of Pinampiro and PROFAFOR in Ecuador in Ecological

Economics 65: 685-698. Wunder S., S. Engel and S. Pagiola (2008) Taking stock: A comparative analysis of payments for environmental service programs in developed and developing countries in Ecological Economics 65: 834852. Wnscher, T., S. Engel, and S. Wunder (2008) Spatial targeting of payments for environmental services: a tool for boosting conservation benets in Ecological Economics, 65:4, pp. 822-33. Zbinden, S. and D.R. Lee (2005) Paying for environmental services: An analysis of participation in Costa Ricas PSA program in World Development 33(2): 255-272.

Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR)


CIFOR advances human wellbeing, environmental conservation, and equity by conducting research to inform policies and practices that affect forests in developing countries. CIFOR is one of 15 centres within the Consultative Group on International Agricultural Research (CGIAR). CIFORs headquarters are in Bogor, Indonesia. It also has offices in Asia, Africa and South America. CIFOR works in over 30 countries worldwide and has links with researchers in 50 international, regional and national organisations. To request a copy of this publication, please contact [email protected]

www.cifor.cgiar.org

CIFOR

International Institute for Environment and Development

You might also like