A Bird in The Hand Consideration and One
A Bird in The Hand Consideration and One
A Bird in The Hand Consideration and One
1. introduction
English contract law has accepted for centuries that a sufcient reason
for enforcing a promise is that it is part of a freely agreed exchange
between two parties. It explains why a promisee is entitled to enforce
the promise and why her remedy should be based on her expecta-
tion (the distinctively contractual measure of enforcement); namely,
because she has paid for it. Formalities and reliance provide excep-
tional reasons for the (sometimes partial) enforcement of promises,
but bargain is overwhelmingly the usual one. Yet the literature on the
consideration doctrine is conspicuous in the intensity and depth of the
hostility it has inspired. It is described as an enormous and shapeless
grab bag; uncertain in scope, and in places overly technical, articial,
internally incoherent, and inconsistent with the parties intentions.1 It
is commonly explained as a historical accident; the result of the tyr-
anny exercised in English law by the mediaeval forms of action. Lord
Goff observed in White v Jones2 that: our law of contract is widely seen
as decient in the sense that it is perceived to be hampered by the
presence of an unnecessary doctrine of consideration.
Abolition has been urged.3 The 1937 Law Revision Committee in its
Sixth Interim Report4 proposed extending the enforceability of prom-
ises in a wide range of circumstances. The Law Commissions report
(implemented by the Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999)
* Reader in Contract Law, University of Oxford, and Tutor in Law, Merton College,
Oxford.
1 See, eg P Atiyah, Consideration: A Restatement in (ed) Essays on Contract (Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1986) 181; EW Paterson, An Apology for Consideration (1958) 58 Columbia
L Rev 929.
2 [1995] 2 AC 207, at 2623.
3 L Wright, Should the Doctrine of Consideration Be Abolished? (1936) 49 Harv L
Rev 1225.
4 Statute of Fraud and the Doctrine of Consideration (1937), Cmnd 5449, paras 26-40, 50.
See similarly the Ontario Law Reform Commission Report on Amendment of the Law of Con-
tract (Report No 85, 1987), ch 2.
5 Law Commission Privity of Contract: Contracts for the Benet of Third Parties (Law
standing the Law of Obligations (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 1998) 197, citing H McGregor, Con-
tract Code Drawn up on Behalf of the English Law Commission, and the Unidroit Statement of
Principles for International Commercial Contracts, art 3.1
7 Stilk v Myrick (1809) 2 Campbell 317.
8 Traceable to Pinnels Case (1602) 5 Co Rep 117a.
9 J Dawson, Gifts and Promises: Continental and American Law Compared (Yale: Yale Univer-
2. consideration
Society (1948) 49; also in A Flew (ed) Logic and LanguageFirst Series (Basil Blackwell, 1952)
145, 173.
12 [1991] 1 QB 1.
13 Ibid, 15-16; followed in Adam Opel GmbH and Renault SA v Mitras Automotive (UK) Ltd
mann (eds), Good Faith and Fault in Contract Law (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995)
12350.
15 Foakes v Beer 9 App Cas 607 at 622 (emphasis added): Lord Blackburn noted his convic-
tion that all men of business, whether merchants or tradesmen, do every day recognise and
act on the ground that prompt payment of a part of their demand may be more benecial to
them than it would be to insist on their rights and enforce payment of the whole. Even where
the debtor is perfectly solvent, and sure to pay at last, this is often so. Where the credit of the
debtor is doubtful it must be more so. And see Collier v Wright [2007] EWCA Civ 1329, [2008]
1 WLR 643 at [3] where Arden LJ notes that Pinnels Case frustrates the parties expectations
and makes it difcult to make modications when this may be commercially benecial for
both parties to do.
16 Ibid, at 20-1, Purchas LJ notes that there were clearly incentives to relieve [Williams]
of his nancial difculties and also to ensure that he was in a position, or alternatively was
willing, to continue with the sub contract works to a reasonable and timely completion.
Businessmen know their own business best even when they appear to grant an indulgence.
See also Russell LJ at 19.
17 B Coote, Consideration and Benet in Fact and in Law (1990) 2 Jl of Contract L 23; FMB
Reynolds and G Treitel, Consideration for the Modication of Contract (1965) 7 Malaya L
Rev 1; J Beatson, Ansons Law of Contract (28th edn, Oxford: Oxford University Press, xx),
125-6; H Kotz and A Flessner, European Contract Law, vol 1 (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
1977), 68-71. In Antons Trawling Co Ltd v Smith [2003] 2 NZLR 23, at [92]: insofar as con-
sideration serves to exclude gratuitous promise, it is of little assistance in the context of
on-going, arms-length, commercial transactions where it is utterly ctional to describe what
has been conceded as a gift, and in which there ought to be a strong presumption that good
commercial considerations underlie any seemingly detrimental modication. See also B
Reiter, Courts, Consideration and Common Sense (1977) 27 University of Toronto L J 439, 507;
and MA Eisenberg, The Principles of Consideration (1982) 67 Cornell L Rev 640, at 644: The
proposition that bargains involving the performance of a pre-existing contractual duty are
often gratuitous is empirically far-fetched.
Myrick and Foakes v Beer take this approach. The eye of the law sees
a contract right as the right to contractual performance and this, in
turn, is equated with the receipt of performance. On this view, the
promisor gets nothing more when she gets her hands on the stipu-
lated bird than she originally had (the right to the bird in the bush).
The problem is that if you start with a legal ction, you are bound to
end up with some odd results. Here, you prevent the promisor from
bargaining for actual performance or part performance because the
promisee knows that the law will not enforce it.
We should be wary of tracking logical deductions beyond com-
mon sense. An analogy can be drawn with the perverse outcomes that
would follow from rigid adherence to the postal acceptance rule. An
offeree who posts her acceptance, then immediately changes her mind
and tells the offeror that she rejects the offer before her letter arrives
would nevertheless be bound if the offeror insists (although the offeror
is not prejudiced and the parties were never in agreement). If the off-
eror had relied on the offerees apparent rejection and sells to another,
he may be in breach if the offeree insists on her postal acceptance. It
is unsurprising that few, if any, judges or writers have been prepared
to follow all these deductions to their logical conclusion.18 Equating a
right to performance with the receipt of performance creates a baseline
against which the value of actual performance over the right to perfor-
mance simply disappears. As Dawson observes, within the limits of
the obligation their agreement had created, the parties had destroyed
their own power to contract. 19 We need an alternative baseline which
is intellectually coherent, yet sufciently open to account for human
and legal realities.
The second, and preferable, baseline is xed by reference to the eyes
of the parties. We bargain for performance, but what we get is a more
fragile right in remedial terms. The unpalatable truth is that there is
no straightforward equivalence between the two. In recognizing the
possibility of gain-based damages for breach of contract in Attorney-
General v Blake, Lord Nicholls20 noted Lionel Smiths argument21 that
contract rights should be protected as strongly from expropriation by
the defendants breach as property rights (which traditionally yield
18 Treitel: The Law of Contract (12th edn, London: Thomson Sweet & Maxwell, 2007) para
2-033.
19 J Dawson, Gifts and Promises: Continental and American Law Compared (Yale: Yale Univer-
22 For example, the rarity of gain-based damages itself; the limited availability of specic
performance; agreed damages clauses are unenforceable if they amount to penalties or indi-
rect specic performance; agreed specic performance will generally be unenforceable; rules
such as remoteness and mitigation cut back the expectation damages to leave the claimants
pecuniary losses inadequately compensated, meanwhile her non-pecuniary losses from the
breach (anxiety, annoyance, and so on) and from seeking legal redress (typically delay, has-
sle, time, and effort) are not normally compensable at all; punitive damages are generally
rejected; and the innocent party may even be prevented from afrming and performing the
contract on the others breach if it would be wholly unreasonable to do so.
23 P Atiyah, Essays on Contract (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986) 190 quoting Corbin on
the claimant has a legitimate interest in preventing the defendant from making or retaining
his prots, and (iii) all the circumstances of the case.
26 Contrast Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Niad Ltd [2001] EWHC 458 (Ch) with AB Corp v CD Co
100% in Attorney-General v Blake; 30-50% in Lane v OBrien Homes Ltd [2004] EWHC 303; the
case was sent back for quantication of the reasonable user in Experience Hendrix LLC v PPX
Enterprises [2003] EWCA Civ 323, (2003) EMLR 25 and for damage to the innocent partys
reputation in WWF World Wide Fund for Nature v World Wrestling Federation Entertainment Inc
[2007] EWCA Civ 286, [2008] 1 WLR 445.
28 B Coote, Consideration and Benet in Fact and in Law (1990) 2 J of Contract L 23, at 28.
29 OW Holmes, The Common Law (1881) 298. See P Atiyah, Holmes and the Theory of Con-
301.
33 As suggested by Holmes and Atiyah, above, n 29.
34 D Friedmann, The Performance Interest in Contract Damages (1995) 111 LQR 628, at
629; C Webb, Performance and Compensation: An Analysis of Contract Damages and Con-
tractual Obligation (2006) 26 Oxford J of Legal Studies 41.
35 D Kimel, Remedial Rights and Substantive Rights in Contract Law (2002) 8 Legal The-
ory 313. Compelling specic behaviour is more oppressive than requiring the payment of
damages, particularly where the former is backed by a nding of contempt of court, poten-
tially punishable by imprisonment. If a money award of a ne were the penalty, courts
may be more prepared to order specic performance as in France or Germany. See H Beale,
A bird in the hand is better than one in the bush. On this view, the
promisor of additional payment is not intending to buy the same right
twice. She is now bargaining for actual performance.37 This describes
a unilateral contract: the promisors offer to pay more (or accept less)
is only accepted if the promisee actually completes the stipulated part
of the promisees pre-existing contractual duty. The bilateral contract
analysis in Williams v Roffey will not do the job. The Court of Appeals
acceptance of the promisees mere repromise to perform her pre-existing
contractual duty provoked Professor Cootes comment that consider-
ation in a bilateral contract is required for the formation of a contract.
Performance, ex hypothesi, comes too late to qualify.38
A complete answer is provided by supplementing the original bilat-
eral contract with a collateral unilateral contract to pay more (or accept
less) if actual performance is rendered. This unilateral contract can
prevail over an inconsistent term in the main written contract.39 But if
the unilateral contract does not eventuate, because the promisee fails
to render the stipulated performance, then the original contract retains
full force. This avoids the absurd and unjust results of a bilateral con-
tract analysis which would leave a promisor of additional payment
A Hartkamp, H Kotz, and D Talon, Ius Commune Casebook for the Common Law of Europe:
Contract Law (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2002) 68081.
36 TE Robison, Enforcing Extorted Contract Modications (1983) Iowa L Rev 699, 751.
37 In Newman Tours Ltd v Ranier Investment Ltd [1992] 2 NZLR 68 at 80, Fisher J applied
Williams v Roffey Bros, saying: the agreement to perform [its] existing contractual obligations,
followed by actual performance in reliance upon that subsequent agreement, can constitute
fresh consideration.
38 Consideration and Benet in Fact and in Law (199091) 3 J of Contract L 23, at 26.
39 See City and Westminster Properties (1934) Ltd v Mudd [1959] Ch 129; Brikom Investments
Ltd v Carr [1979] QB 467; Harling v Eddy [1951] 2 KB 739; Mendelssohn v Normand Ltd [1970]
1 QB 177.
worse off than before because her damages would be reduced by the
original and additional sums she undertook to, but now need not, pay.40
A bilateral contract analysis of relieving promises yields the same per-
verse outcome. If the promisee fails to render the lesser performance,
the promisors claim would be conned to that lesser performance.41
Consistently, the Ontario Law Reform Commission states that where
the promisee of additional payment fails to perform, the appropriate
deduction is the original sum promised, and not the greater modied
sum; it would be an implicit understanding between the parties that
failure to comply with the terms of the new agreement would revive
the old one.42 Likewise, subtracting promises are binding subject to
actual performance by the promisee.43 The promisor has agreed to
accept less on the ground that a bird in the hand is worth two in the
bush. It would be unfair, in such a case, to limit the rights absolutely
to the single bird of the subsequent agreement. The same reasoning
underlies the 1937 Law Revision Committees recommendation on
reversing the effect of Pinnels Case.44 It would be more straightforward
to say that, in both cases, the promisors liability on the additional
promise only crystallizes on the promisees performance on a unilateral
contract analysis.
A unilateral contract analysis avoids another potentially anomalous
result, instanced by Pao On v Lau Yiu Long.45 The parties exchanged
shares in their companies. P also agreed to delay selling 60per cent of
the shares received for at least a year to avoid triggering a fall in their
value; L agreed to buy back those shares at a xed price at or before
the end of the year. When P realized that it would be disadvantaged
if the shares rose above the xed price, he refused to proceed unless
L agreed to a guarantee by way of indemnity (if the shares fell below the
40 For example, X promises to pay Y 5,000 for a job; later X promises another 3,000 (total
8,000), but Y still does not perform and it would cost X 10,000 for substitute perform-
ance. The expectation damages under the original contract is 10,0005,000, while under
the modied contract it would be 10,0008,000.
41 X promises to accept 70 in discharge of Ys debt of 100 in the hope of actually getting
(No 82, 1987) 1213, discussing the promise to accept part performance.
43 Ibid, 10, 1213.
44 Sixth Interim Report on the Statute of Frauds and the Doctrine of Consideration, Cmd 5449,
paras 33-5: It would be possible to enact only that actual payment of the lesser sum should
discharge the obligation to pay the greater, but we consider that it is more logical and more
convenient to recommend that the greater obligation can be discharged either by a promise
to pay a lesser sum or by actual payment of it, but that if the new agreement is not performed
then the original obligation shall revive.
45 [1980] AC 614.
xed price). L agreed in order to avoid the delay and loss of public
condence that legal action against P would attract at a critical time
in their companys restructuring. Moreover, L believed that the risk
entailed in the modication was more apparent than real. When the
share price plummeted, L would neither buy back the shares under the
original contract (alleging this arrangement was ended by the modi-
cation) nor indemnify P under the modied bilateral contract (alleging
that it was voidable for duress). The modication was upheld. How-
ever, the Privy Council opined that, even if duress had been found, it
would not have countenanced the stark injustice of denying P the
safeguard which all were at all times agreed [P] should havethe safe-
guard against fall in value of the shares.46 A unilateral collateral con-
tract analysis of the modication would restrict the vitiating effect of
any duress, leaving the original contract in place.
46 Ibid, at 635.
47 Williams v Roffey Bros [1991] 1 QB 1 at 8-10, 16-17; and 23.
48 Ibid, at 6.
49 This should be 3,800 although the trial judge said 2200 and Glidewell LJ said 2,300.
The error probably occurred because Roffey Brothers made an additional payment of 1500
(3,8001500 = 2,300). However, this was credited twice by being deducted again from
Williams original entitlement of 5,000.
the 1,500 already paid, leaving the nal gure of 3,500. Since Rof-
fey Brothers offer is to pay a specic sum on completion of specied
work, this can be interpreted as 18 separate unilateral offers. One inter-
pretation is that Williams only accepted eight of these by substantial
performance; by ceasing work, it accepted no more.
50 Chitty on Contracts, (30th edn, London: Sweet & Maxwell, 2008) para 2-079.
51 [1952] 1 KB 290.
52 Ibid, at 295.
53 [1978] Ch 231, especially at 239.
54 [2007] EWCA Civ 969, [2008] 2 WLR 834, at [50].
55 [1941] AC 108.
for work done within eight or nine days. The court held that the com-
mon understanding was that estate agents take the risk in the hope of
a substantial remuneration for comparatively small exertion.56
It is tempting to opt for a clear rule prohibiting or permitting revo-
cation of the modifying offer once performance has commenced. How-
ever, the answers never or always will sometimes yield unintended
and unjust results. In Morrison Shipping Co v The Crown57 the Lord
Chancellor doubted: whether a conditional offer in general terms,
whether made to the public (as in the Carbolic Smoke Ball case) or to a
class of persons, is converted into a contract so soon as one of the per-
sons to whom the offer is made takes some step towards performing
the condition. The Federal Court of Australia in Mobil Oil Australia
Ltd v Wellcome International Pty Ltd and Others58 declined to recognize
a universal proposition that an offeror is not at liberty to revoke the
offer once the offeree commences or embarks upon performance of
the sought act of acceptance. The issue is one of construction, but also
of protecting a performing offeree from exploitation by the offeror.59
These features will vary greatly from case to case. Relevant factors
would include:
(i) ConstructionThe parties intention or the prevailing convention
(eg estate agents contracts) as to whether the offeror should be
able to withdraw at any time (ie a locus poenitentiae) which may be
inferable from other relevant factors.
(ii) The length of time over which the offeror would have to keep the
offer open without knowing whether the offeree will complete
the act. Errington v Errington60 involved a lengthy period but was
a family property case where the parties were not considering
future possibilities at arms length.61
(iii) Whether the stipulated performance requires the offerors cooperationif
so, it is less likely that the parties intended to bar revocation (eg
real estate agents contract and by analogy to the test of whether
afrmation is available).
(iv) The extent of performanceThe demands of justice will vary
between an offeree who has completed 1 per cent of the stipu-
lated performance from one who has completed 99 percent.
56 Ibid, at 126.
57 (1924) 20 Ll L Rep 283, at 287.
58 (1998) 153 ALR 196, at 228.
59 This mirrors the concern to protect the promisor from the promisees exploitation via
duress.
60 [1952] 1 KB 290.
61 Ibid, at 293.
Lord Denning opened the way to using the promissory estoppel doc-
trine in Hughes v Metropolitan Railway Co71 to enforce relieving prom-
ises in Central London Property Trust v High Trees House Ltd.72 His
Lordship staked further ground for the equitable doctrine in dicta in
D&C Builders v Rees.73 Namely, that it is in principle, although not on
the facts, applicable to part payment of a debt agreed by the parties
to discharge the whole debt. In Collier v Wright74 the Court of Appeal
applied the dicta in Rees to override the House of Lords decision in
Foakes v Beer.75 Collier and his two former business partners were
jointly indebted to Wright for 46,800, each servicing his share. When
Colliers former partners ceased paying, Collier alleged that Wright
told him to continue his payments and Wright would chase the other
debtors. Over four years later, when Collier had repaid his third of the
debt, Wright demanded the other two-thirds from Collier.
66 Mobil Oil Australia Ltd v Wellcome International Pty Ltd and Others (1998) 153 ALR 196,
at 225.
67 Allied Maples v Simmons & Simmons [1989] 1 WLR 1602; and see Schweppe v Harper [2008]
Neither did the trial judge think that Colliers part payment amounted
to relevant reliance. This is unsurprising since part payment has never
previously, in itself, been sufcient to raise promissory estoppel. Oth-
erwise, one would wonder what all the fuss is about regarding Foakes
v Beer. Nevertheless, Arden LJ held that part performance per se, does
amount to the relevant reliance, and that this, without more, makes it
inequitable for the creditor to resile from the agreement, and com-
pletely extinguishes the creditors right to the balance of the original
debt. This makes the requirement of promisor unconscionability in
resiling redundant and departs from the reliance basis of the doctrine.
It cuts the doctrine adrift from its justication. The analogy with prac-
tical benet is inescapable; Collier v Wright undermines Foakes v Beer in
the same way that Williams v Roffey Brothers undermined Stilk v Myrick.
The same unilateral contract solution can be applied to both.
Longmore LJ conceded that Lord Dennings dicta in Rees seems to
have the effect attributed by Arden LJ,83 but he was distinctly unen-
thusiastic about it. He doubted that Wright had permanently foregone
its original right or that Collier had relied in any meaningful way.
His Lordship recognized that it was arguably inequitable for Wright
to resile, but thought there was much to be said on the other side,
concluding that:84
If, as Arden LJ puts it, the brilliant obiter dictum of Denning J in the High
Trees case [1947] KB 130 did indeed substantially achieve in practical terms
the recommendation of the Law Revision Committee chaired by Lord
Wright MR in 1937, it is perhaps all the more important that agreements
which are said to forgo a creditors rights on a permanent basis should not
be too benevolently construed.
Lord Dennings dicta in D & C Builders Ltd v Rees85 is weak precedent
for Colliers version of promissory estoppel. Lord Denning found his
own formulation inapplicable because Rees bad faith meant that it was
not inequitable for the builders to resile. Thus, Rees part payment did
not, per se, make the builders resiling inequitable, contrary to Arden
LJs formulation.86 The greater part of Lord Dennings judgment sim-
ply applied Foakes v Beer. Danckwerts LJs judgment spent just 14 lines
rejecting promissory estoppel (there was no true accord and no detri-
mental change of position).87 Winn LJ, giving the longest judgment, made
83 Ibid, at [45][47].
84 Ibid, at [48].
85 [1966] 2 QB 617.
86 Arden LJ could explain the outcome of Rees by saying that the builders made no prom-
88 Chitty on Contracts, (30th edn, London: Sweet & Maxwell, 2009) para 22-012. British Rus-
sian Gazette and Trade Outlook Ltd v Associated Newspapers Ltd [1933] 2 KB 616, at 643; Bank of
Credit and Commerce International SA v Ali [1999] ICR 1068, at 1078.
89 Collier v Wright [2007] EWCA Civ 1329, [2008] 1 WLR 643, at [33], [39], and [42].
90 In D&C Builders Ltd v Rees [1966] 2 QB 617, at 625, Lord Denning MR held: Where there
has been a true accord, under which the creditor voluntarily agrees to accept a lesser sum in
satisfaction, and the debtor acts upon that accord by paying the lesser sum and the creditor
accepts it, then it is inequitable for the creditor afterwards to insist on the balance.
91 [2007] EWCA Civ 1329, [2008] 1 WLR 643, at 644. According to the Weekly Law Reports,
Collier v Wright held, inter alia, that Collier had raised a triable issue that there had been an
accord and satisfaction in that he had paid his share of the debt and the company had volun-
tarily agreed to accept the payments on that basis.
92 [1991] 1 QB 1.
93 [1995] 1 WLR 474.
94 [2003] 2 NZLR 23, citing Chen-Wishart The Enforceability of Additional Contractual
When Smith realized the risk that this arrangement entailed when per-
forming exploratory shing, he requested a daily rate as he was enti-
tled to do under the agreement. Antons declined but agreed to give
Smith a 10 per cent share of any additional shing quota allocated by
the government to Antons as a result of Smith proving the existence
of a commercial shery. Antons argued that it was not bound by this
additional promise because Smith was already paid to sh and so gave
no consideration. The court endorsed the practical benet approach95
of Williams v Roffey. However, acknowledging the trenchant criticisms
of the decision, the court held in the alternative that consideration is
unnecessary for the variation of a contract. Baragwanath J said:96
[Denying enforcement] would be inconsistent with the essential principle
underlying the law of contract, that the law will seek to give effect to freely
accepted reciprocal undertakings. Where the parties who have already
made such intention clear by entering legal relations have acted upon an
agreement to a variation, in the absence of policy reasons to the contrary they
should be bound by their agreement.
Although the court did not have to choose between recognizing prac-
tical benet and dispensing with consideration, the two approaches
are conceptually incompatible; one liberalizes consideration, the other
abolishes it, albeit only in adding modications. The latter approach is
objectionable on a number of fronts. First, Baragwanath Js view that
[t]he importance of consideration is as a valuable signal that the parties
intend to be bound by their agreement, rather than an end in itself97
will be contested below.98 Second, if the essential principle underly-
ing the law of contract is the parties intention to be bound, then its
logic should extend to both adding and relieving promises,99 and even
to contract formation. The fact that his Honour connes his abolition
to adding promises where there is already freely accepted reciprocal
undertakings100 shows that reciprocity is not dispensable to contrac-
tual enforcement. Third, the intention to be bound approach cannot
explain why the enforceability of the promise should be conditional
on the promisee actually performance her pre-existing obligations.
General for England and Wales v R [2002] 2 NZLR 91, at 109, which praised the approach as
appropriately paying attention to the practical realities of the parties circumstances rather
than to legal niceties.
96 [2003] 2 NZLR 23, at [93] (emphasis added).
97 Ibid.
98 See text accompanying n 110111.
99 There is no suggestion that the court intended to abrogate the rule in Foakes v Beer.
100 [2003] 2 NZLR 23, at [93] (emphasis added).
101 Ibid, at [59]. This unilateral contract contains additional legal benet for Antons; namely,
the prospect of satisfying the Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries of the existence of a com-
mercial shery in the area. The 10% deal was offered to encourage Smith to redouble his
efforts and to agree to the extensive research programme and record keeping which the
Ministry would require before issuing further quota, at [31][41].
102 [2009] SGCA 31.
103 Ibid, at [92].
104 Ibid, at [94].
105 Ibid, at [92].
106 Ibid, at [113]. Another possible alternative doctrine is promissory estoppel; see [111].
107 Ibid, at [113].
108 Ibid, at [86], citing VK Rajah JC in Chwee Kin Keong v Digilandmall.com Pte Ltd [2004] 2
113 M Cohen, The Basis of Contract (1933) 46 HarvL Rev 553, 572.
114 A Kronman, Paternalism and the Law of Contract (1983) Yale LJ 763.
115 E Weinrib, The Idea of Private Law (Harvard: University Press Harvard, 1995) 13640.
116 P Atiyah, Essays on Contract (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986) 241.
117 S Hedley, Keeping Contract in its Place: Balfour v Balfour and the Enforceability of Infor-
119 530 (1) of the German Civil Code (BGB); Arts 953, 955 of the French Civil Code (Code
civil). This includes, eg, serious misconduct towards the donor or a close relative, indelity
of the donee spouse, ling an unmeritorious petition to declare the donor disabled, and the
donees failure to perform an express condition.
120 519 of the German Civil Code (BGB).
121 See further J Dawson, ibid, 53.
122 320-26 of the German Civil Code (BGB); Art 1102 of the French Civil Code (Code
civil).
123 HLA Hart, The Ascription of Responsibility and Rights in Proceedings of the Aristotelian
Society (1948) 49; also in A Flew (ed.), Logic and LanguageFirst Series (Oxford: Basil Black-
well, 1952) 145, 173.
124 Ibid, 183.
125 Ibid, 145, 174-8 (emphasis in the original). At 180, Hart explains that the logical char-
acter of words like voluntary are anomalous and ill-understood. They are treated in such
denitions as words having positive force, yet, as can be seen from Aristotles discussion
in Book III of the Nicomachean Ethics, the word voluntary in fact serves to exclude a het-
erogeneous range of cases such as physical compulsion, coercion by threats, accidents, the
stakes, etc, and not to designate a mental element or state; nor does involuntary signify the
absence of this mental element or state.
126 Ibid, 174.
127 Universe Tankships Inc of Monrovia v International Transport Workers Federation (The Uni-
Friedmann (eds), Good Faith and Fault in Contract Law (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
1995) 123.
6. conclusion
Evolution, not revolution, has always been the common law way. Lord
Steyns extra-judicial comment is exemplary:131
I have no radical proposals for the wholesale review of the doctrine of
consideration. I am not persuaded that it is necessary. And great legal
change should only be embarked on when they are truly necessary.... [T]
he courts have shown a readiness to hold that the rigidity of the doctrine
of consideration must yield to practical justice and the needs of modern
commerce.
The story of the pre-existing duties problem is partly one of the rich-
ness, ingenuity, and evolutionary capacity of the common law to
overcome obstacles to reaching just and sensible results. Faced with
the perceived obstacle of consideration, Williams v Roffey widened its
scope; Collier v Wright circumvented it, and Antons Trawling and Gay
v Loh abolished it. The three approaches are interconnected; there is
an order of priority in their application. Expansion of consideration
reduces the need to resort to circumvention via promissory estop-
pel. But abolition of consideration makes the expansion of consider-
ation or of promissory estoppel redundant. Consideration bites before
promissory estoppel, but abolition swallows all.
131 Contract Law: Fullling the Reasonable Expectations of Honest Men (1997) 113 LQR
433, 437.