1 s2.0 S0378426614001253 Main PDF
1 s2.0 S0378426614001253 Main PDF
1 s2.0 S0378426614001253 Main PDF
Do investors put their money where their mouth is? Stock market
expectations and investing behavior
Christoph Merkle , Martin Weber
Chair of Finance and Banking, University of Mannheim, Germany
a r t i c l e
i n f o
Article history:
Received 21 February 2013
Accepted 30 March 2014
Available online 24 April 2014
JEL-Classication Codes:
D81
G02
G11
Keywords:
Expectations
Beliefs
Risk
Return
Trading behavior
Portfolio choice
a b s t r a c t
To understand how real investors use their beliefs and preferences in investing decisions, we examine a
panel survey of self-directed online investors at a UK bank. The survey asks for return expectations, risk
expectations, and risk tolerance of these investors in three-month intervals between 2008 and 2010. We
combine the survey data with investors actual trading data and portfolio holdings. We nd that investor
beliefs have little predictive power for immediate trading behavior. The exception is a positive effect of
increases in return expectation on buying activity. Portfolio risk levels and changes are more systematically related to return and risk expectations. In line with nancial theory, risk taking increases with
return expectations and decreases with risk expectations. In response to their expectations, investors also
adjust the riskiness of assets they trade.
2014 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
There is a large gap between what nance models predict for
individual investor behavior and what can be observed in their
actual behavior. Portfolio theory assumes that investors form
expectations about return and risk of securities and select portfolios according to their expectations and risk preferences
(Markowitz, 1952). As a consequence, they should hold broadly
diversied portfolios and trade very little. But instead, private
investors have been shown to hold underdiversied portfolios
(Goetzmann and Kumar, 2008), to trade frequently (Odean, 1999;
Barber and Odean, 2000), to take high idiosyncratic risk (Calvet
et al., 2007), and to gamble in the stock market (Kumar, 2009).
There is also evidence that they use various investment strategies
different from pure meanvariance optimization (Lewellen et al.,
1977; Grinblatt and Keloharju, 2000). Often these deviations have
been explained by specic psychological biases, e.g., excessive
trading by overcondence (Odean, 1998; Glaser and Weber, 2007).
Corresponding author. Address: Lehrstuhl fr ABWL und Finanzwirtschaft,
Universitt Mannheim, 68131 Mannheim, Germany. Tel.: +49 6211811531; fax:
+49 6211811534.
E-mail address: [email protected] (C. Merkle).
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankn.2014.03.042
0378-4266/ 2014 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
However, this way one learns very little about the actual decision making process people go through when they invest. How
do investors use their beliefs and preferences in this process?
Empirically, there is only scarce evidence on this question as the
input parameters are hard to obtain. The economic paradigm of
revealed preferences states that beliefs and preferences can be
inferred from observed actions (Samuelson, 1938). But this already
implies that they are perfectly converted into actions. In order to
reveal whether and where this transfer might fail, direct information on beliefs and preferences is needed.
To this end, we collect return and risk expectations in a
repeated panel survey of self-directed private investors at a large
UK online brokerage provider. These investors are not representative for the overall investor population including institutions,
which imposes some limits on the generality of the results. However, our focus is on individual investors for which our sample is
rather typical. Participants are well informed about nancial markets as, e.g., their responses in a nancial literacy questionnaire
show. They also have on average many years of investment experience and invest non-trivial amounts of money. In three-month
intervals, survey participants are queried for numerical and qualitative expectations and their risk tolerance. We then match expectations of investors to their actual transactions in their online
373
Under the additional assumption that future wealth W 1 is lognormally distributed, expression (1) simplies to (for a detailed derivation cp. Campbell and Viceira, 2002):
1
max ln E0 1 r 0;1 hr20 ;
2
1
1
max ws;0 E0 r s;0;1 r f ;0;1 ws;0 1 ws;0 r20 1 hw2s;0 r20 ;
2
2
ws;0
374
predictive for portfolio volatility. Moreover, younger, selfemployed, less sophisticated, and poorer investors tend to hold
more risky portfolios. Calvet et al. (2007) examine disaggregated
wealth data covering the entire Swedish population and show a
positive impact of wealth, income, and education on risk taking
measured by portfolio volatility.1 They also break down portfolio
risk in its various components and reveal interesting patterns of risk
taking. In a follow-up study, Calvet et al. (2009) present evidence on
rebalancing, suggesting that investors actively control their share of
risky investments and offset changes brought about by passive market variations.
While this literature addresses risk taking behavior of private
investor, it lacks a systematic study of the input variables we are
interested in: individual investor beliefs in form of return and risk
expectations, and investor risk preferences. Closest related to our
study is the work by Amromin and Sharpe (2009), Weber et al.
(2013), Hoffmann et al. (2013), and Guiso et al. (2011). Similar to
us Amromin and Sharpe (2009) use panel data, in their case coming
from the Michigan Survey of Consumer Attitudes. However, they
analyze self-reported portfolio shares of survey participants and
do not have access to their transactions or actual portfolios. They
concentrate on the interrelation of return expectations and risk
expectations, but also provide some evidence of the inuence of
these variables on portfolio composition. Consistent with nancial
theory, higher return expectations and lower risk expectations
increase the share of equity in portfolios of investors. Hoffmann
et al. (2013) study an investor survey in the Netherlands, which
is matched to brokerage account data. Their data spans a time
period from April 2008 to March 2009 and survey rounds are
administered monthly. By eliciting expectations and portfolio
characteristics, Hoffmann et al. (2013) establish a link between
the beliefs of investors and their investing behavior. They nd a
positive impact of risk tolerance, risk perception, and return expectations on trading activity, while risk tolerance is identied as a
main driver for risk taking behavior.
Guiso et al. (2011) concentrate in their analysis on risk aversion
measured by a qualitative and a quantitative approach. They report
a substantial increase of risk aversion in the nancial crisis compared to pre-crisis levels. Ownership of risky assets is negatively
related to risk aversion. Guiso et al. (2011) suggest psychological
factors as drivers of risk aversion, as they are able to rule out alternative explanations such as wealth or background risk.
In a previous analysis of our dataset, Weber et al. (2013) report
a relationship between expectations and investing decisions. They
analyze a survey question which asks participants to split a hypothetical amount of 100,000 between an investment in the UK
stock market and a riskless asset. With this investment task they
are able to show a strong inuence of changes in expectations
and risk attitude on changes in the proportion of risky investment.
This inuence is in the expected direction: increases in expected
returns or risk tolerance lead to an increase in risky investment,
while higher risk expectations render investors more cautious.
We extend this research by relating return and risk expectations
to the actual trades and portfolios of investors. By analyzing various aspects of investing behavior, we present a more complete portrayal of the underlying relationships. We also exploit the full time
series of the survey which was not available to the earlier study by
Weber et al. (2013).
1
The seemingly contradictory results might be explained by the different
composition of the datasets. While Dorn and Huberman (2005) analyze stock
portfolios, where wealth and nancial sophistication usually lead to a better
diversication (and thus less risk), Calvet et al. (2007) use total wealth portfolios
for which wealth and sophistication typically lead to a greater equity share (and thus
more risk).
3. Data
We obtain survey responses and transaction data for a sample
of clients at Barclays Stockbrokers, a UK direct brokerage provider.
Barclays is one of the largest brokers in the UK and attracts a wide
variety of customers (for demographic characteristics of its clients
see below). The accounts are self-directed in the sense that customers can inform themselves on special webpages provided by
the bank but receive no direct investment advice. Most transactions are processed online.
3.1. Survey data
In collaboration with Barclays Wealth, we conduct a repeated
survey taking place every three months, beginning in September
2008 and ending in September 2010. Fig. 1 shows the development
of the UK stock market represented by the FTSE all-share index and
the timing of survey rounds. Our panel consists of nine rounds covering a time period of highly volatile market environment. We thus
expect participants to express changing beliefs about market prospects; in the standard model of Eq. (4) this would in turn lead to
changes in their portfolios.
In the initial survey a stratied sample of the banks client base
was invited via e-mail to participate in the online questionnaire
(for details on the sampling procedure see Weber et al., 2013). In
total 617 clients of the bank participated in the survey, 394 of which
participated multiple times. 189 participants have completed at
least ve rounds, and 52 have participated in all nine rounds. We
have a minimum of 130 observations for each of the nine rounds.
We will discuss potential selection effects in Section 4.4.
Table 1 shows some demographic characteristics of survey participants. Investors are predominantly male, and they are older and
more afuent than the general population (for an explicit
Fig. 1. FTSE all-share index and survey rounds. Development of the FTSE all-share
index (covers 98% of UK market capitalization) between June 2008 and December
2010. Vertical lines represent the timing of the nine survey rounds.
Table 1
Demographics of participants.
Mean
Median
Std.dev.
Min
Max
613
617
614
51.4
0.93
3.49
53
1
4
12.9
0.25
0.68
21
0
0
84
1
4
502
494
4.80
3.88
5
4
2.39
1.80
1
1
9
8
375
How would you rate the returns you expect from an investment in
the UK stock market (FTSE all-share) over the next 3 months?
Over the next 3-months, how risky do you think the UK stock market (FTSE all-share) is?
In the rst question answer alternatives range from extremely
bad to extremely good, in the second question from not risky
at all to extremely risky. We ask equivalent questions for investors own portfolios held with Barclays. In total we thus collect eight
belief items per investor per round.
376
Fig. 3. Risk expectations of investors. Qualitative risk expectations for market and
own portfolio (scale 17, right axis), and numerical risk expectations as implied by
condence intervals (volatilities, left axis). For comparison implied option volatility
(FTSE 100 VIX, left axis).
Compared to the quantitative measure, qualitative risk expectations elicited on a seven-point scale reect more closely implied
market risk expectations represented by the FTSE 100 VIX. While
it is not possible to compare the absolute magnitudes, we nd a
correlation of 0.78 (p < 0:02) between average qualitative risk
expectations and implied option volatilities. Quite intuitively, risk
expectations rise with the peak of the nancial crisis and then fall
afterwards. However, there are two further increases in panelists
risk expectations: one without a corresponding rise in option market expectations (September to December 2009), and another,
which falls together with the onset of the European debt crisis
(June 2010). In general, expectations for own portfolio risk follow
this trend but are on average slightly lower and more stable than
market expectations. It is noteworthy that investors appear to
believe they can earn higher returns bearing less risk (cp. Kempf
et al., 2014).
For investigating trading behavior over time, changes in expectations are particularly important. Table 2 shows average changes
for all expectation variables. We observe a signicant increase in
average return and risk expectations between round one and three
followed by a very mixed pattern from round three to four (further
increase of qualitative return and numerical risk expectations, but
sharp drop of qualitative risk expectations). Changes in expectations are less pronounced for the time after the immediate crisis.
An exception is the very last survey round for which we observe
strongly increasing return expectations and decreasing risk expectations. Similar to Weber et al. (2013), we nd that the correlations
between changes of numeric and qualitative expectations are often
low (return) or insignicant (risk). Stronger correlations exist
between market and portfolio expectations. Average risk tolerance
remains fairly stable over the whole survey period.
3.3. Trading data
Our data also include the trading records of all investors active
in the panel survey. We include three months prior to our rst survey round and three months after our last survey round. In the
resulting period between June 2008 and December 2010 we
observe 49,372 trades with a total trading volume of
258,940,694. Of these trades 37,022 or 75% are in stocks (63% of
trading volume). In some parts of the analysis, we will concentrate
on these equity transactions as they are closest related to the
expectations we elicit among investors. The remaining trades
include bonds, derivatives, mutual funds and ETFs. The average trader in the panel trades 84.1 times within the 2.5 year period (about
three times per month), with an average trading volume of
441,126. However, the distribution is strongly skewed; the median trader trades only 33 times (about once a month), the median
2
Compared to similar studies, portfolio value is high. Glaser and Weber (2007)
report a median portfolio value of 15,630, Barber and Odean (2000) of $16,210,
and Dorn and Huberman (2005) of DM55,000 (about 23,000). On a monthly basis,
median turnover is in the same range as in Barber and Odean (2000) and Dorn and
Huberman (2005) with 6% and 9% respectively.
377
Own portfolio
Round
D risk tolerance
D num. return
D qual. return
D num. risk
D qual. risk
D num. return
D qual. return
D num. risk
D qual. risk
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
0.23
0.10
0.07
0.15
0.14
0.03
0.21
0.22
0.020
0.014
0.010
0.008
0.016
0.004
0.008
0.009
0.12
0.20
0.30
0.01
0.03
0.05
0.27
0.45
0.023
0.001
0.014
0.008
0.011
0.004
0.001
0.015
0.43
0.03
0.77
0.38
0.07
0.22
0.17
0.29
0.026
0.030
0.003
0.019
0.014
0.047
0.010
0.045
0.09
0.20
0.33
0.10
0.17
0.11
0.09
0.35
0.023
0.007
0.018
0.008
0.008
0.017
0.010
0.011
0.28
0.13
0.24
0.02
0.06
0.12
0.13
0.29
(December 08)
(March 09)
(June 09)
(September 09)
(December 09)
(March 10)
(June 10)
(December 10)
Notes: The table states changes in risk tolerance and changes in numerical and qualitative expectations of investors (compared to the previous survey round).
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
378
Table 3
Buying and selling behavior.
Buysell ratio
(1)
Num. return
Num. risk
Qual. return
Qual. risk
Risk tolerance
D
D
D
D
D
0.068
0.059
0.014
0.007
0.010
0.150
0.058
0.010
0.007
0.012
num. return
num. risk
qual. return
qual. risk
risk tolerance
(3)
(4)
(5)
0.275
0.043
0.009
0.018
0.010
0.257
0.029
0.013
0.022
0.010
0.040
0.040
0.014
0.008
0.012
0.293
0.074
0.014
0.016
0.007
0.288
0.070
0.017
0.018
0.007
Age
Gender (male = 1)
Wealth
Income
Fin. literacy
Pseudo-R2
n
(6)
0.186
0.063
0.012
0.010
0.011
(7)
(8)
0.251
0.124
0.011
0.020
0.011
0.234
0.106
0.015
0.024
0.009
0.321
0.115
0.016
0.020
0.005
0.316
0.111
0.019
0.022
0.006
0.002
0.089
0.013
0.034
0.034
0.002
0.108
0.010
0.028
0.034
0.039
0.035
0.049
0.067
0.035
0.035
0.049
0.064
1376
769
769
767
1376
769
769
767
Notes: The table shows results of a panel Tobit regression with random effects and round dummies. Dependent variable is buysell ratio dened over number of trades (# of
buys/# of total trades) for columns 14 and buysell volume ratio dened over trading volume (buying volume/total trading volume) for columns 58. Columns 1 and 5
include levels of expectations and columns 2 and 6 changes of expectations as explanatory variables. Columns 3 and 7 show regressions on both, levels and changes, in
columns 4 and 8 additionally controlled for demographics. Demographic variables include age, gender, wealth, and nancial literacy. The table displays marginal effects,
which are the coefcients of the uncensored dependent variable. The pseudo-R2 is McKelvey and Zavoinas R2 .
3
The correlation between changes in numerical and qualitative expectations is
positive but low (0.26), suggesting that multicollinearity is not an issue. An
explanation for the emergence of the qualitative rating effect is that the used scale
lacks inter-subject comparability, but is a good predictor within subjects (xedeffects model).
4
This is a deliberate analogy to levels and changes in the hypothetical risk taking
task analyzed by Weber et al. (2013). In this task investors had to divide 100,000
between the FTSE all-share and a riskless asset. If we assume a volatility of 0 for the
riskless asset, the volatility of the chosen portfolio is monotonically increasing with
the fraction invested in the FTSE.
379
(1)
clus. SE
(2)
FE
(3)
LAD
(4)
clus. SE
(5)
FE
(6)
LAD
0.199
0.025
0.014
0.017
0.007
0.134
0.090
0.038
0.025
0.023
0.343
0.151
0.008
0.019
0.006
0.173
0.130
0.018
0.021
0.006
0.132
0.106
0.034
0.031
0.022
0.174
0.162
0.011
0.016
0.009
num. return
num. risk
qual. return
qual. risk
risk tolerance
0.230
0.034
0.019
0.013
0.006
0.179
0.006
0.033
0.015
0.005
0.252
0.025
0.026
0.004
0.006
0.276
0.091
0.024
0.019
0.004
0.239
0.127
0.035
0.023
0.006
0.255
0.020
0.028
0.010
0.002
Age
Gender (male = 1)
Wealth
Income
Fin. literacy
0.002
0.088
0.013
0.029
0.029
0.001
0.146
0.006
0.032
0.010
0.002
0.118
0.009
0.022
0.030
R2
n
0.055
0.073
0.047
0.053
0.075
0.043
767
769
767
767
769
767
Num. return
Num. risk
Qual. return
Qual. risk
Risk tolerance
D
D
D
D
D
0.002
0.136
0.012
0.030
0.023
Notes: The table shows results of a panel GLS regression with random effects and standard errors clustered by participant (columns 1 and 4), a panel regression with xed
effects (columns 2 and 5), and a regression using least absolute deviation and bootstrapped standard errors (columns 3 and 6). Dependent variable is buysell ratio dened
over number of trades (# of buys/# of total trades) for columns 13 and buysell volume ratio dened over trading volume (buying volume/total trading volume) for columns
46. Independent variables are as specied in Table 3. For random effects regressions overall R2 is reported, for xed effects regressions within R2 , for LAD-regressions
pseudo-R2 .
Table 5
Correlation of portfolio risk measures.
Levels of portfolio risk
Panel A
Volatility 1y
Volatility 3m
Rel. volatility
Portfolio beta
ACV
Vol 1y
Vol 3m
Rel. Vol
Beta
ACV
1.00
0.76
0.89
0.42
0.64
1.00
0.59
0.28
0.54
1.00
0.43
0.50
1.00
0.23
1.00
Panel B
D Volatility 1y
D Volatility 3m
D Rel. volatility
D Portfolio beta
D ACV
D Vol 1y
D Vol 3m
D Rel. Vol
D Beta
D ACV
1.00
0.60
0.39
0.13
0.60
1.00
0.11
0.05
0.32
1.00
0.40
0.06
1.00
0.05
1.00
Notes: The table shows pairwise Pearson correlations of levels (Panel A) and changes
(Panel B) of portfolio risk measures. All correlations are signicant at 1%-level.
5
We do not nd signicant results for portfolio value / wealth as a measure of
relative importance of investors portfolios for their overall wealth.
6
As a further test we instrument contemporaneous expectations by lagged
expectations. While the results are consistent in direction, signicance is weak.
However, instrumentation is costly in terms of statistical power, as it requires
consecutive observations. Additionally, there are concerns about weak instruments as
correlations between expectations and lagged expectations are only around 0.3
(common tests for weak instruments attain borderline results).
380
Table 6
Portfolio risk and expectations.
Random effects model
ln(Vol 1y)
(1)
ln(Vol 3m)
(2)
Beta
(3)
ln(ACV)
(4)
ln(Vol 1y)
(5)
ln(Vol 3m)
(6)
Beta
(7)
ln(ACV)
(8)
Num. return
Num. risk
Qual. return
Qual. risk
Risk tolerance
0.165
0.131
0.001
0.000
0.001
0.165
0.187
0.000
0.013
0.007
0.070
0.030
0.002
0.003
0.004
0.135
0.086
0.002
0.010
0.011
0.129
0.106
0.003
0.000
0.002
0.102
0.154
0.003
0.012
0.002
0.042
0.006
0.004
0.003
0.003
0.098
0.048
0.001
0.010
0.006
Age
Gender (male = 1)
Income
Wealth
Fin. literacy
0.006
0.085
0.016
0.031
0.066
0.006
0.115
0.014
0.030
0.066
0.002
0.104
0.004
0.016
0.054
0.003
0.059
0.018
0.022
0.059
R2
n
0.368
0.495
0.036
0.290
0.746
0.753
0.089
0.608
1924
1911
1926
1817
1924
1911
1926
1817
Notes: The table shows results of a GLS panel regression with random effects and clustered standard errors (columns 14) and xed effects (columns 58). All regressions
contain round dummies. Dependent variables are portfolio risk measures: the natural logarithm of portfolio volatility calculated over a 1-year and 3-month horizon, portfolio
beta and the log of average component volatility (ACV). Expectation variables and demographics are as dened before. For random effects regressions overall R2 is reported,
for xed effects regressions within R2 .
Table 7
Portfolio risk and lagged expectations.
Random effects model
ln(Vol 1y)
(1)
ln(Vol 3m)
(2)
Beta
(3)
ln(ACV)
(4)
ln(Vol 1y)
(5)
ln(Vol 3m)
(6)
Beta
(7)
ln(ACV)
(8)
0.127
0.116
0.005
0.007
0.006
0.101
0.136
0.006
0.022
0.013
0.060
0.048
0.008
0.001
0.003
0.188
0.147
0.002
0.008
0.014
0.092
0.095
0.007
0.006
0.005
0.012
0.080
0.008
0.020
0.009
0.036
0.034
0.010
0.000
0.002
0.144
0.119
0.002
0.006
0.011
Age
Gender (male = 1)
Income
Wealth
Fin. literacy
0.006
0.080
0.019
0.030
0.058
0.006
0.075
0.025
0.025
0.036
0.002
0.069
0.007
0.016
0.047
0.003
0.078
0.017
0.018
0.059
R2
n
0.400
0.542
0.027
0.297
0.794
0.772
0.134
0.641
1923
1908
1925
1808
1923
1908
1925
1808
Lagged
Lagged
Lagged
Lagged
Lagged
num. return
num. risk
qual. return
qual. risk
risk tolerance
Notes: The table shows results of a GLS panel regression with random effects and clustered standard errors (columns 14) and xed effects (columns 58). All regressions
contain round dummies. Dependent variables are portfolio risk measures: the natural logarithm of portfolio volatility calculated over a 1-year and 3-month horizon, portfolio
beta and the log of average component volatility (ACV). Expectation variables are included as lagged variables. For random effects regressions overall R2 is reported, for xed
effects regressions within R2 .
381
DVol 1y
(1)
DVol 3m
(2)
DRel. Vol
(3)
DBeta
(4)
DACV
(5)
DVol 1y
(6)
DVol 3m
(7)
DRel. Vol
(8)
DBeta
(9)
DACV
(10)
num. return
num. risk
qual. return
qual. risk
risk tolerance
0.062
0.079
0.003
0.001
0.005
0.114
0.128
0.005
0.008
0.008
0.059
0.073
0.000
0.000
0.004
0.000
0.017
0.005
0.002
0.000
0.080
0.020
0.006
0.003
0.004
0.051
0.072
0.007
0.000
0.004
0.107
0.149
0.014
0.010
0.009
0.047
0.069
0.004
0.000
0.002
0.009
0.005
0.001
0.000
0.000
0.083
0.014
0.008
0.005
0.004
Age
Gender (male = 1)
Income
Wealth
Fin. literacy
0.001
0.005
0.003
0.001
0.008
0.001
0.018
0.012
0.008
0.012
0.000
0.012
0.005
0.002
0.003
0.001
0.001
0.002
0.003
0.009
0.000
0.018
0.004
0.001
0.005
R2
n
0.682
0.652
0.246
0.141
0.417
0.733
0.682
0.275
0.170
0.394
1038
1031
1038
1009
1018
1038
1031
1038
1009
1018
D
D
D
D
D
Notes: The table shows results of a GLS panel regression with random effects and clustered standard errors (columns 15) and xed effects (columns 610). All regressions
contain round dummies. Dependent variables are changes in portfolio risk measures: changes in portfolio volatility calculated over a 1-year and 3-month horizon, changes in
relative volatility and portfolio beta, and changes in average component volatility (ACV). Independent variables are demographics and changes in expectations, both as
dened before. For random effects regressions overall R2 is reported, for xed effects regressions within R2 .
Table 9
Volatility of securities traded.
Round
Trade
volatility
Buy
volatility
Buysell
vol. diff.
6.20
6.23
6.02
5.99
6.00
5.96
6.03
5.75
5.86
5.82
6.42
6.37
6.05
5.79
5.88
6.07
6.04
5.60
5.84
5.76
0.33
0.29
0.24
0.39
0.32
0.02
0.06
0.36
0.29
0.23
Notes: The table shows for all survey rounds the average volatility decile of trades
and purchases, and the average volatility differential between purchases and sales.
382
Table 10
Volatility of trades explained by expectations
Random effects model
Trade volatility
(1)
Buy volatility
(2)
Trade volatility
(4)
Buy volatility
(5)
Num. return
Num. risk
Qual. return
Qual. risk
Risk tolerance
0.467
0.042
0.003
0.038
0.045
0.840
0.431
0.002
0.031
0.082
1.374
0.377
0.001
0.049
0.050
0.127
0.201
0.027
0.035
0.015
0.514
0.199
0.038
0.037
0.001
2.367
0.421
0.051
0.089
0.065
Age
Gender (male = 1)
Income
Wealth
Fin. literacy
0.017
0.704
0.047
0.102
0.391
0.017
0.604
0.048
0.116
0.376
0.010
0.077
0.023
0.031
0.005
R2
n
0.085
0.108
0.041
0.010
0.021
0.049
1467
1343
890
1467
1343
890
Notes: The table shows results of panel regression with random effects with clustered standard errors (columns 13) or xed effects (columns 46), all regressions contain
round dummies. Dependent variables are the volatility of trades, the volatility of purchases and the difference between volatility of purchases and sales. For random effects
regressions overall R2 is reported, for xed effects regressions within R2 .
Given the relatively low (but not uncommon8) response rate and
the presence of attrition in our panel, there are two potential channels of selection. Specic investors might be more attracted to participate in the survey, or they leave and rejoin the sample in a
non-random way, both potentially biasing our results. We have only
limited data on non-participants, including age and gender, as well
as some portfolio information (portfolio value, number of positions,
number of transactions).9 We use these items as explanatory variables in a participation regression, results are reported in column 1
of Table 11. We nd that male investors and investors with a higher
number of holdings and transactions are more likely to participate in
the survey. The latter are potentially more active and interested in
nancial markets, which would explain this result.
While this supports the presence of selection on observables in
our sample, it may remain inconsequential for our results. We run
a two-stage Heckmann selection model to test for this possibility.
In columns 2a and 2b, we reproduce the regression of portfolio
value on expectations including the inverse Mills ratio of the rst
stage. The inverse Mills ratio is highly signicant, again suggesting
a selection effect. However, our main result regarding the inuence
of expected return and expected risk on risk taking remains intact.
It is also robust to an inclusion of the set of variables from the participation regression (column 2b). Not surprisingly, portfolio value
and number of positions are strongly negatively related to portfolio
volatility, as they come along with a diversication effect. In contrast, number of transactions has a positive effect on volatility. In
this specication, the signicance of the inverse Mills ratio is much
reduced, as the additional variables capture part of the selection
effect.
We nd similar results for the other levels specications, meaning that despite selection is present in our sample, our results are
mainly unaffected by it. The changes regressions, by making use
of the in-sample variation over time, are per se less vulnerable
against this type of selection.
Next, we analyze the participation in the panel over time to
detect any signs of systematic attrition. To make sure that this type
8
In similar survey studies Graham and Harvey (2001) report a response rate of 9%,
Glaser and Weber (2007) of 7%, Dorn and Sengmueller (2009) of 6%, compared to our
3% for a repeated survey.
9
The remaining demographic variables such as income and wealth were selfreported survey items.
of selection does not bias our main results we again use a Heckman
selection model. We follow Wooldridge (1995) in estimating the
participation equation separately for each round of the panel,
including demographics and lagged survey variables. Instead of
displaying these roundwise rst stage regressions, Table 11 shows
a panel probit version of the participation regression (column 3). It
demonstrates that wealthier investors are more likely to participate, while higher income investors are less likely to participate.
Intuitively, those with higher income might be more time-constraint. More importantly, lagged expectations do not explain subsequent participation, which means that it is not the case that e.g.,
optimistic or more risk tolerant investors are more likely to continue the survey.
We then re-estimate in the second stage the panel regression as
before, including now inverse Mills ratios from the roundwise participation regressions. This time, we nd no signicance for the Mills
ratio, suggesting no strong evidence for selection effects in the sense
of systematic panel attrition. Our main results are unchanged in
both specications, whether using random effects (4a) or xed
effects (4b). We also nd no evidence that the changes regression
of Table 8 is affected by selection. We thus conclude that while selection is present in our sample, it seems to have little inuence on the
effect of expectations and preferences on risk taking behavior.
5. Discussion
A main problem any research in beliefs and expectations
encounters is whether responses in a survey are valid representations of the internal beliefs of participants. The challenge is twofold, questions need to be stated in a way that participants are
able to answer them in a sensible way, and participants need to
be motivated to do so. For the latter we rely on the intrinsic motivation of participants as they completed the survey voluntarily,
and many found it interesting enough to take part multiple times.
As in most large-scale surveys, monetary incentives were not feasible, but we are in this case not aware of any obvious reason to
conceal or distort beliefs in their absence.10 Additionally, we build
10
For a discussion about when monetary incentives are useful see Camerer and
Hogarth (1999). Other surveys that do not incentivize participants include the
Michigan Survey of Consumer Finances, the German Socioeconomic Panel and most
surveys on investing behavior.
383
ln(Vol 1y)
Part.
ln(Vol 1y)
(1)
(2a)
(2b)
(3)
(4a)
(4b)
0.131
0.128
0.005
0.004
0.002
0.136
0.136
0.007
0.002
0.001
0.065
0.315
0.006
0.010
0.002
0.129
0.152
0.003
0.001
0.005
0.106
0.121
0.004
0.000
0.003
0.006
0.219
0.014
0.031
0.040
0.004
0.117
0.015
0.016
0.033
0.004
0.192
0.122
0.115
0.043
0.004
0.098
0.007
0.042
0.022
0.001
0.008
1033
1033
Num. return
Num. risk
Qual. return
Qual. risk
Risk tolerance
Age
Gender (male = 1)
Income
Wealth
Fin. literacy
0.000
0.168
Portfolio value
Portfolio positions
Transactions
0.015
0.062
0.064
Panel attrition
19,609
0.046
0.109
0.044
0.594
0.354
1536
1518
1825
Notes: The table shows two-stage Heckman selection models for participation in the survey and panel attrition. Column 1 displays a probit regression of participation
including age and gender, and portfolio value, portfolio positions, and transactions (all logarithmized). Columns 2a and 2b reproduce results of Table 6 including the inversed
Mills ratio of the rst stage. Column 3 shows a probit regression for participation within survey, columns 4a and 4b the associated second stage estimated with random effects
(4a) and xed effects (4b).
11
Support for this dual-process theories of information processing and decision
making can be found, e.g., in Kahneman (2003).
384
6. Conclusion
We investigate the functional relationship between beliefs and
preferences of investors and their trading behavior. While we are
still far from suggesting a denite functional form in the spirit of
Eq. (4), our ndings are a rst step to improve the understanding
of this complicated but fundamental relationship. We provide evidence that expectations are relevant for risk taking of investors,
and that they are used in a predominantly rational and intuitive way.
Higher return expectations lead to increased risk taking in
terms of portfolio volatility among investors, while higher risk
expectations have the opposite effect. Even more, changes in portfolio risk are predicted by contemporaneous changes in return and
risk expectations. We nd evidence that investors counteract
changes in market volatility by adjusting their portfolio volatility
Appendix A
Description of variables
Variable
Origin
Description
Num. return
Survey
Num. risk
Survey
Qual. return
Survey
Return in % in response to survey question We would like you to make three estimates of the return of the
UK stock market (FTSE all-share) by the end of the next three month. Your best estimate should be your best
guess
Volatility calculated from condence intervals using the methodology of Keefer and Bodily (1983)
using responses to survey question We would like you to make three estimates of the return of the UK
stock market (FTSE all-share) by the end of the next 3 month. Your high estimate should very rarely be lower
than the actual outcome of the FTSE all-share (about once in 20 occasions). Your low estimate should very
rarely be higher than the actual outcome of the FTSE all-share (about once in 20 occasions)
Rating on scale 17 in response to question How would you rate the returns you expect from an
investment in the UK stock market (FTSE all-share) over the next 3 months?
385
Appendix A (continued)
Description of variables
Variable
Origin
Description
Qual. risk
Survey
Risk tolerance
Survey
D num. return
D num. risk
D qual. return
D qual. risk
D risk tolerance
Age
Gender
Wealth
Survey
Survey
Survey
Survey
Survey
Bank data
Bank data
Survey
Income
Survey
Fin. literacy
Survey
Buysell ratio
Buysell
volume ratio
Volatility 1y
Volatility 3m
Rel. Volatility
Portfolio beta
Bank data
Bank data
Rating on scale 17 in response to question Over the next 3-months, how risky do you think the UK stock
market (FTSE all-share) is?
Agreement on Likert scale 17 to statement It is likely I would invest a signicant sum in a high risk
investment
Num. return (t) num. return (t 1)
Num. risk (t) num. risk (t 1)
Qual. return (t) qual. return (t 1)
Qual. risk (t) qual. risk (t 1)
Risk tolerance (t) risk tolerance (t 1)
Age of participants in years
Gender of participants, dummy variable 1 if male, 0 if female
Self-reported wealth using nine categories provided in the survey: 010,000; 10,00150,000;
50,001100,000; 100,001150,000; 150,001250,000; 250,001400,000; 400,001600,000;
600,0011,000,000; >1,000,000. Missing values were imputed
Self-reported income using eight categories provided in the survey: 020,000; 20,00130,000;
30,00150,000; 50,00175,000; 75,001100,000; 100,001150,000; 150,001200,000;
>200,000. Missing values were imputed
Number of correct responses in a 4-item nancial literacy test using questions by van Rooij et al.
(2011)
Number of purchases divided by number of total trades (range 01)
Volume of purchases divided by total trading volume (range 01)
ACV
Bank data
Trade volatility
Bank data
Buy volatility
Bank data
Buysell vol.
diff.
Portfolio value
Bank data
Portfolio
positions
Transactions
Bank
Bank
Bank
Bank
data
data
data
data
Bank data
Bank data
Bank data
References
Amromin, G., Sharpe, S.A., 2009. Expectations of Risk and Return among Household
Investors: Are their Sharpe Ratios Countercyclical? Working Paper.
Barber, B.M., Odean, T., 2000. Trading is hazardous to your wealth: the common
stock investment performance of individual investors. The Journal of Finance 55
(2), 773806.
Barber, B.M., Odean, T., 2001. Boys will be boys: gender, overcondence, and
common stock investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (1), 261292.
Bhattacharya, U., Holden, C.W., Jacobsen, S., 2012. Penny wise, dollar foolish:
buysell imbalances on and around round numbers. Management Science 58 (2),
413431.
Calvet, L.E., Campbell, J.Y., Sodini, P., 2007. Down or out: assessing the welfare costs
of household investment mistakes. Journal of Political Economy 115 (5), 707
747.
Calvet, L.E., Campbell, J.Y., Sodini, P., 2009. Fight or ight? Portfolio rebalancing by
individual investors. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (1), 301348.
Camerer, C.F., Hogarth, R.M., 1999. The effects of nancial incentives in
experiments: a review and capitallaborproduction framework. Journal of
Risk and Uncertainty 19 (13), 742.
Campbell, J.Y., Viceira, L.M., 2002. Portfolio Choice for Long-Term Investors. Oxford
University Press, New York, NY.
Dave, C., Eckel, C.C., Johnson, C.A., Rojas, C., 2010. Eliciting risk preferences: when is
simple better? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 41 (3), 219243.
Dorn, D., Huberman, G., 2005. Talk and action: what individual investors say and
what they do. Review of Finance 9 (4), 437481.
Dorn, D., Huberman, G., 2010. Preferred risk habitat of individual investors. Journal
of Financial Economics 97 (1), 155173.
Dorn, D., Sengmueller, P., 2009. Trading as entertainment? Management Science 55
(4), 591603.
Egan, D., Davies, G.B., Brooks, P., 2010. Comparisons of risk attitudes across
individuals. In: Cochran, J. (Ed.), Wiley Encyclopedia of Operations Research and
Management Science. John Wiley and Sons, Hoboken, NJ.
Ehm, C., Kaufmann, C., Weber, M., 2014. Volatility inadaptability: investors care
about risk, but cant cope with volatility. Review of Finance (in press).
Glaser, M., Langer, T., Weber, M., 2013. True overcondence in interval estimates:
evidence based on a new measure of miscalibration. Journal of Behavioral
Decision Making 26 (5), 405417.
Glaser, M., Weber, M., 2005. September 11 and stock return expectations of
individual investors. Review of Finance 9 (2), 243279.
Glaser, M., Weber, M., 2007. Overcondence and trading volume. The GENEVA Risk
and Insurance Review 32 (1), 136.
Goetzmann, W.N., Kumar, A., 2008. Equity portfolio diversication. Review of
Finance 12 (3), 433463.
386
Graham, J.R., Harvey, C.R., 2001. The theory and practice of corporate nance:
evidence from the eld. Journal of Financial Economics 60 (23), 187243.
Grinblatt, M., Keloharju, M., 2000. The investment behavior and performance of
various investor types: a study of Finlands unique data set. Journal of Financial
Economics 55 (1), 4367.
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., Zingales, L., 2011. Time Varying Risk Aversion. Working
Paper.
Hoffmann, A.O.I., Post, T., Pennings, J.M.E., 2013. Individual investor perceptions and
behavior during the nancial crisis. Journal of Banking and Finance 37 (1), 60
74.
Kahneman, D., 2003. Maps of bounded rationality: a perspective on intuitive
judgement and choice. The American Economic Review 93 (5), 14491475.
Kapteyn, A., Teppa, F., 2011. Subjective measures of risk aversion, xed costs, and
portfolio choice. Journal of Economic Psychology 32 (4), 564580.
Keefer, D.L., Bodily, S.E., 1983. Three-point approximations for continuous random
variables. Management Science 29 (5), 595609.
Kempf, A., Merkle, C., Niessen, A., 2014. Low risk and high return affective
attitudes and stock market expectations. European Financial Management (in
press).
Kuhnen, C.M., Knutson, B., 2011. The inuence of affect on beliefs, preferences, and
nancial decisions. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 46 (3), 605
626.
Kumar, A., 2009. Who gambles in the stock market? The Journal of Finance 64 (4),
18891933.
Lewellen, W.G., Lease, R.C., Schlarbaum, G.G., 1977. Patterns of investment strategy and
behavior among individual investors. The Journal of Business 50 (3), 296333.
Loewenstein, G.F., Hsee, C.K., Weber, E.U., Welch, N., 2001. Risk as feelings.
Psychological Bulletin 127 (2), 267286.
Markowitz, H., 1952. Portfolio selection. The Journal of Finance 7 (1), 7791.
McInish, T.H., 1982. Individual investors and risk-taking. The Journal of Economic
Psychology 2 (2), 125136.
Merkle, C., 2012. Financial Overcondence Over Time Foresight, Hindsight, and
Insight of Investors. Working Paper.
Odean, T., 1998. Volume, volatility, price, and prot when all traders are above
average. The Journal of Finance 53 (6), 18871934.
Odean, T., 1999. Do investors trade too much? The American Economic Review 89
(5), 12791298.
Ritter, J.R., 1988. The buying and selling behavior of individual investors at the turn
of the year. The Journal of Finance 43 (3), 701717.
Samuelson, P.A., 1938. A note on the pure theory of consumers behaviour.
Economica 5 (17), 6171.
Sarin, R.K., Weber, M., 1993. Risk-value models. European Journal of Operational
Research 70 (2), 135149.
Tobin, J., 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. The Review of
Economic Studies 25 (2), 6586.
van Rooij, M., Lusardi, A., Alessie, R., 2011. Financial literacy and stock market
participation. Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2), 449472.
Vissing-Jorgensen, A., 2003. Perspectives on behavioral nance: does irrationality
disappear with wealth? Evidence from expectations and actions. In: Gertler,
Rogoff (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2003, vol. 18. The MIT Press,
Cambridge, MA, pp. 139208.
Weber, M., Weber, E.U., Nosic, A., 2013. Who takes risk and why: determinants of
changes in investor risk taking. Review of Finance 17 (3), 847883.
Windschitl, P.D., Wells, G.L., 1996. Measuring psychological uncertainty: verbal
versus numeric methods. Journal of Experimental Psychology 2 (4), 343364.
Wooldridge, J.M., 1995. Selection corrections for panel data models under
conditional mean independence assumptions. Journal of Econometrics 98 (1),
115132.