SSRN-id3599407 2

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 70

Anticompetitive Effects in EU Competition Law

Pablo Ibáñez Colomo*

Contents
1. Introduction ................................................................................................................................................................ 2
2. What are anticompetitive effects? Making sense of the variables.............................................................................. 6
2.1. The time variable: actual and potential effects .................................................................................................. 6
2.2. The dimensions of competition and of the counterfactual................................................................................. 7
2.3. The meaning of effects ...................................................................................................................................... 9
2.4. The probability of the effects: plausibility, likelihood and certainty ............................................................... 12
3. Anticompetitive effects in the case law: preliminary issues .................................................................................... 14
3.1. Mechanisms through which anticompetitive effects are manifested ............................................................... 14
3.2. The place of anticompetitive effects in the various legal tests ........................................................................ 16
4. The time dimension in the case law: actual and potential effects ............................................................................ 20
4.1. The prospective analysis of potential effects ................................................................................................... 20
4.2. The retrospective analysis of actual effects ..................................................................................................... 22
5. The meaning of competition and the counterfactual in the case law........................................................................ 24
5.1. Competition comprises both the inter-brand and intra-brand dimensions ....................................................... 24
5.2. Competition refers to such lawful competition which would otherwise have existed..................................... 25
5.3. Both the ex ante and ex post dimensions of the counterfactual are considered ............................................... 29
6. The meaning of effects in the case law .................................................................................................................... 31
6.1. Only appreciable effects are relevant under EU competition law ................................................................... 31
6.2. An effect is more than a competitive disadvantage or a limitation of a firm’s freedom of action .................. 34
6.3. As a rule, an anticompetitive effect cannot be equated with harm to consumer welfare................................. 36
6.4. Anticompetitive effects exist where competitive pressure is reduced ............................................................. 38
7. The probability of effects in the case law ................................................................................................................ 45
7.1. Semantic issues: capability and likelihood ...................................................................................................... 45
7.2. The law as applied: plausibility, likelihood and certainty ............................................................................... 47
8. Analysis and discussion ........................................................................................................................................... 52
8.1. Questions addressed in the case law ................................................................................................................ 52
8.2. Open questions ................................................................................................................................................ 57
8.3. Areas of friction in practice ............................................................................................................................. 61
9. Conclusions .............................................................................................................................................................. 67

*
London School of Economics and College of Europe. E-mail: [email protected]. I am grateful to Fernando
Castillo de la Torre, Gianni De Stefano, Andriani Kalintiri and Alfonso Lamadrid de Pablo for their comments on a
previous version. In accordance with the ASCOLA declaration of ethics, I am happy to clarify that I have nothing to
disclose.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


1. Introduction

The ‘effects-based’ approach to EU competition law has been widely discussed for over two decades.1

One would thus be forgiven to assume that the meaning and scope of the notion of anticompetitive

effects in the EU legal order are, and have long been, clear. The opposite, however, is true. Some

elements of the notion have not been fully teased out, and a cloud of uncertainty surrounds the

evaluation of effects in concrete cases. It is true that the Court of Justice (hereinafter, the ‘Court’ or

the ‘ECJ’) has made seminal contributions over the years. For instance, it has consistently held that,

as a general rule, anticompetitive effects must not be equated with a negative impact on consumer

welfare.2 Beyond this point, however, many open issues remain. If, as the case law suggests, effects

amount to more than a mere competitive disadvantage, what are they? How are potential effects

measured? How is the analysis performed when the practice is not price-related? What is the requisite

level of probability? These are just some of the questions – of major practical significance – that play

a prominent role before courts and authorities.

A number of factors help explain the persistent uncertainty. The definition of its

administrative priorities by the European Commission (hereinafter, the ‘Commission’) is one of them.

It is well documented that a growing number of investigations focuses on clear-cut infringements (in

particular, cartel conduct).3 Such practices are prima facie unlawful irrespective of their impact on

1
It would be difficult to summarise the literature dealing with the effects-based approach. Suffice it to mention, inter alia,
Jacques Bourgeois and Denis Waelbroeck (eds), Ten years of effects-based approach in EU competition law: state of play
and perspectives (Bruylant 2012); Luc Peeperkorn and Katja Viertiö, ‘Implementing an effects-based approach to Article
82’ (2009) 1 Competition Policy Newsletter 17; Wouter Wils, ‘The Judgment of the EU General Court in Intel and the
So-Called “More Economic Approach” to Abuse of Dominance’ (2014) 37 World Competition 405; and Anne Witt, ‘The
Enforcement of Article 101 TFEU - What Has Happened to the Effects Analysis?’ (2018) 55 Common Market Law
Review 417.
2
See in particular Opinion of AG Kokott in Case C-95/04 P British Airways plc v Commission, EU:C:2006:133, para 86;
Case T-8/08, T-Mobile Netherlands BV and others v Raad van bestuur van de Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit,
EU:C:2009:343, para 38; Joined Cases C‑501/06 P, C-513/06 P, C-515/06 P and C‑519/06 P GlaxoSmithKline Services
Unlimited v Commission, EU:C:2009:610 (‘Glaxo Spain’), para 63; Case C‑286/13 P Dole Food Company Inc. and Dole
Fresh Fruit Europe v Commission, EU:C:2015:184 (‘Bananas’), para 125; Case T‑216/13, Telefónica, SA v Commission,
EU:T:2016:369, para 270.
3
For a systematic analysis of the enforcement priorities of the Commission, and how cartel conduct has gained in
relevance over the years, see Pablo Ibáñez Colomo and Andriani Kalintiri, ‘The Evolution of EU Antitrust Policy: 1966-
2017’ (2020) 83 Modern Law Review 321.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


competition.4 As a result, the analysis of effects tends to be, if at all, a marginal aspect of such cases.

Second, only a fraction of decisions ever reaches review courts. In the field of merger control, and

given the time-sensitive nature of transactions, the proportion of challenges is small.5 In the context

of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU, the decisions in the very cases that demand a meaningful analysis of

effects are not always subject to judicial review. A substantial proportion of non-cartel cases

examined by the authority have been resolved, in the past decades, by means of commitment

decisions. These decisions do not formally declare whether competition law has been infringed and

are rarely challenged before the EU courts.6 In addition, the use of settlements has progressively

grown over the years and across practices. Firms’ incentives to bring an action are significantly

reduced following an agreement with an authority, and this even when the categorisation of the

practice by the Commission is not wholly uncontroversial.7

It is true that, since the adoption of Regulation 1/2003 – which sought to increase enforcement

at the national level – there has been a steady stream of preliminary references seeking guidance on

the interpretation and application of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU. These judgments provide valuable

indicators about the way in which the analysis of effects is to be conducted and about the specific

meaning of the fundamental underlying concepts. The very nature of preliminary rulings, however,

limits the extent to which they can clarify matters. Where the impact of a practice is assessed, the

analysis cannot be expected to go beyond providing the relevant factors that the national court would

4
Case C-67/13 P, Groupement des cartes bancaires v Commission, EU:C:2014:2204 (‘Cartes Bancaires’), para 51.
5
For a systematic overview of the number of cases reaching the EU courts, see Pablo Ibáñez Colomo, The Shaping of EU
Competition Law (Cambridge University Press, 2018) and the accompanying dataset.
6
See in this sense Article 9 of Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 of 16 December 2002 on the implementation of the
rules on competition laid down in Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty [2003] OJ L1/1. For an exhaustive analysis of their
nature, see Ryan Stones, ‘Commitment Decisions in EU Competition Enforcement: Policy Effectiveness v. the Formal
Rule of Law’ (2019) 38 Yearbook of European Law 361.
7
On the rise of the use of settlements in EU competition law, see Niamh Dunne, ‘From Coercion to Cooperation:
Settlement within EU Competition Law’ (2019) LSE Legal Studies Working Paper, 14, available at
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3481419.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


need to apply to the facts of the case.8 In some instances, the concepts used may not be fully fleshed

out.

As a result of this institutional reality, the aspects of the case law that shed light on the notion

of anticompetitive effects tend to be available in a fragmentary (and sometimes embryonic) manner

– and this, from a variety of disparate sources. The purpose of this paper, against this background, is

to bring together these fragments and present them under a coherent framework. The exercise

suggests that the notion of anticompetitive effects has a concrete meaning in EU competition law.

The case law provides the necessary and sufficient elements to understand how effects are to be

assessed in practice. The conclusion is true of all areas of EU competition law, in the sense that there

are no appreciable differences in the analysis of effects between EU merger control, on the one hand,

and Articles 101 and 102 TFEU, on the other. If there are variations, these relate to the applicable

legal test, not the relevant provision.

Some of the principles underpinning the case law are explicit. To begin with, it does not seem

possible to claim that anticompetitive effects can be equated with a competitive disadvantage, or with

a limitation of a firm’s freedom of action. Something more – namely an impact on efficient firms’

ability and incentive to compete – is required as a matter of law. Similarly, the notions of competition

and the counterfactual have acquired, over the years, a clear and stable meaning. In the EU system,

competition is best understood as actual or potential lawful competition which would have existed in

the absence of the practice (or transaction) under consideration. Finally, the Court has consistently

held that anticompetitive effects can be actual or potential; by the same token, the analysis can be

both prospective and retrospective.

Other principles are implicit or scattered across the relevant judgments. This article seeks to

tease them out from the case law. The requisite level of probability that triggers intervention, for

instance, has never been formulated explicitly. What is more, the Court has occasionally used as

8
Some examples in this sense include Case C-209/10 Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet, EU:C:2012:172 (‘Post
Danmark I’); and Case C-345/14 SIA ‘Maxima Latvija’ v Konkurences padome, EU:C:2015:784.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


synonymous expressions that are suggestive of different thresholds of effects. If one looks at the plain

meaning of the words, there seems to be a difference between showing that a practice is capable of

restricting competition and requiring evidence that it is likely to do so. However, the Court has

sometimes used them as synonymous.9 Against this background, the relevant thresholds need to be

inferred from the analysis as actually conducted. In this sense, this article pays attention not only to

what it is declared in the judgments but also – and mainly – to what the Court does in concrete cases

(that is, how the analysis is performed and, in particular, how penetrating it is).

The abovementioned questions are examined as follows. Section 2 provides the framework

around which the various aspects of the case law can be organised. It identifies the main variables to

consider when giving a concrete meaning to the notion of anticompetitive effects. Thus, it examines

not only the ways in which the key concepts of ‘competition’ and ‘effects’ may be defined but also

the levels of probability, as well as the differences between the evaluation of actual and potential

effects. Sections 3 to 7, in turn, examine how the variables defined in Section 2 have been interpreted

by the Court. In this regard, it considers both the case law on Articles 101 and 102 TFEU and on

merger control. As far as Article 101 TFEU is concerned, it takes into account not only ‘by effect’

conduct (that is, conduct that only gives rise to intervention when effects are established) but also ‘by

object’ behaviour (that is, behaviour that is deemed prima facie unlawful irrespective of its effects).

Finally, Section 8 offers a summary of the main findings and identifies the aspects that are likely to

give rise to frictions in the medium to long term.

9
See for instance Case C-95/04 P British Airways plc v Commission, EU:C:2007:166; Case C-52/09 Konkurrensverket v
TeliaSonera Sverige AB, EU:C:2011:83; and Case C-23/14 Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet, EU:C:2015:651
(‘Post Danmark II’). For a discussion, see Opinion of AG Wahl in Case C-413/14 P Intel Corporation Inc v Commission,
EU:C:2016:788, paras 112-121.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


2. What are anticompetitive effects? Making sense of the variables

The notion of anticompetitive effects can be broken down into various components. Its scope will be

broader or narrower depending on how these components are fleshed out. For instance, it would be

relatively broad if effects were equated with a competitive disadvantage – or with a limitation of a

firm’s freedom of action. In such circumstances, anticompetitive effects would be found to exist in

the vast majority of – if not all – cases. Conversely, the scope would be narrower, and effects

relatively more difficult to establish in practice, if the latter were equated with harm to consumer

welfare. The notion is also sensitive to the requisite threshold of probability. Effects would be

relatively easy to establish if the bar were set at the level of plausibility; and they would be more

difficult to establish if it were necessary to show that an anticompetitive impact is certain, or virtually

certain, to occur. The purpose of this section is to identify these components and provide a template

against which the case law, and its evolution, can be mapped.

2.1. The time variable: actual and potential effects

The evaluation of effects can be based on the actual or potential impact of a practice (or transaction)

on competition. If intervention is based on the latter, intervention need not wait for the impact to be

manifested or to fully display its consequences on the market. The assessment of potential effects is

typically prospective in nature (and is often assumed to be prospective). For instance, action may take

place before a practice or transaction is fully realised. Merger control systems typically evaluate the

compatibility of concentrations prior to their implementation, and this on the basis of their anticipated

effects. The same assessment of potential effects can take place in relation to agreements between

undertakings or unilateral practices by dominant firms (or collectively dominant firms).10 For

10
The remainder of the article will refer to a ‘dominant firm’ as a shorthand for both single and collective dominance.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


instance, an authority may intervene ex ante, before an auction is organised.11 The analysis may also

be prospective where the practice has already been implemented but the effects have not been

manifested to their full extent. This may be the case, for instance, where the practice is ongoing when

intervention takes place.12

A question that might arise in practice is whether the retrospective analysis of the impact of a

practice or transaction can be based on its potential effects alone or must consider its actual effects

instead. The question, in other words, is whether the ex post assessment of effects can focus

exclusively on the conditions that would have potentially prevailed in its absence; or whether the

assessment must take into account the actual context (that is, the subsequent developments that are

contemporaneous with, or that follow, its implementation). Under the first approach (which would

consider potential effects alone), the ex post evaluation would be based on hypotheticals about the

possible evolution of market conditions, irrespective of actual events; under the second, the

assessment would be constrained by the observable evolution of such conditions. The status of this

question in the case law is considered in Section 4 below.

2.2. The dimensions of competition and of the counterfactual

2.2.1. Inter-brand and intra-brand competition

It is commonplace to distinguish between the inter-brand and the intra-brand dimensions of

competition. Inter-brand competition refers, generally speaking, to the competition that exists among

firms at a given level of the value chain, and, in particular, to the rivalry that exists between the

different suppliers of a given product. Intra-brand competition, in turn, is typically defined as the

11
See for instance Joint selling of the media rights to the FA Premier League (Case COMP/C-2/38.173) Commission
Decision of 22 March 2006.
12
Google Search (Shopping) (Case AT.39740) Commission Decision of 27 June 2017 (‘Google Shopping’).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


rivalry that exists among the distributors or retailers of a particular brand of a given product. In any

competition law system, a choice needs to be made, first, about whether both dimensions of

competition are relevant (or whether, instead, only inter-brand competition is) and, second, where the

two are deemed relevant, whether there is a hierarchy between the two dimensions. Since inter-brand

competition is universally understood to be more important, it can be expected to take precedence.

The status of inter-brand and intra-brand competition in the case law is addressed in Section 5.

2.2.2. The ex ante and ex post dimensions of competition

The impact of a practice (or transaction) on competition has to be measured against a benchmark. The

competition that is said to be affected, in other words, needs to be given a concrete meaning. The

most obvious benchmark to establish anticompetitive effects is the counterfactual, that is, the

evaluation of the conditions of competition that would have prevailed had the practice (or transaction)

not been implemented. An analysis of the relevant economic and legal context (including factors such

as the features of the relevant market or the regulatory conditions in which firms operate) sheds light

on this question. The operation of the counterfactual is exemplified by the so-called ‘failing firm

defence’ in merger control.13 A concentration cannot be said to have anticompetitive effects if one of

the parties would have left the market irrespective of it and there would have been no less restrictive

alternatives to dispose of the assets.14 In such circumstances, there would be no causal link between

the anticipated loss of competitive pressure and the completion of the transaction.

The counterfactual has an ex ante and an ex post dimension. When considering the conditions

of competition that would otherwise have prevailed, one should take into account that some practices

and transactions both create and restrict competition; in other words, pro- and anticompetitive effects

13
See Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations
between undertakings [2004] OJ C31/5, paras 89-91.
14
Ibid, para 90.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


may be closely intertwined. For instance, the development of a new technology may create a new

market or intensify rivalry in an existing one. In that regard, it can be said to be pro-competitive. Once

the technology has been developed, however, the firm may decide to keep it for itself to recoup its

investments. Accordingly, it may refuse to share its innovation with would-be rivals. Seen from a

purely ex post perspective, the decision to keep the technology for itself appears to restrict

competition (insofar as would-be rivals would be denied access to the market).

When defining the counterfactual against which effects are evaluated, it is therefore necessary

to decide whether both the ex ante and ex post dimensions are considered, or whether only the latter

is part of the analysis. If, in the example given above, only the ex post dimension were relevant, then

a refusal by the firm to share its technology with rivals would have anticompetitive effects. Seen ex

post, this behaviour necessarily limits the availability of the technology that would otherwise have

existed. This is not necessarily the case, however, when the ex ante dimension is considered. The

investment in the development of a new technology might never have been incurred if the firm had

not had the prospect of recouping it by keeping the innovation for itself. An ex ante approach to the

counterfactual does not merely assume that the pro-competitive gains resulting from a practice (or

transaction) would have existed. Instead, it considers whether they would have been manifested in

the absence of the observable ex post restraints. As explained in Section 5, the EU system considers

both the ex ante and ex post dimensions of the counterfactual.

2.3. The meaning of effects

2.3.1. Between freedom of action and harm to consumers

The assessment of the impact of a practice or transaction on competition is particularly sensitive to

the way the concept of effects itself is defined. As already suggested, anticompetitive effects would

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


be virtually ubiquitous (and straightforward to establish) if the concept were equated with a

competitive disadvantage or with a limitation of a firm’s freedom of action. The opposite would be

true if it were understood to amount to harm to consumer welfare. When considering the possible

meanings that can be attached to the very concept of effects, it is useful to think of such meanings as

discrete points along a spectrum. The two options mentioned above (limitation of a firm’s freedom

of action or competitive disadvantage, on the one hand; and harm to consumer welfare, on the other)

are at the opposite ends of the spectrum.

Virtually any practice that attracts the attention of competition authorities limits the freedom

of action of one or several firms and/or places them at a competitive disadvantage. A distribution

agreement, for instance, may limit the freedom of action of the reseller (and may thus place it at a

competitive advantage relative to rivals) in a variety of ways. The reseller may be prevented from

selling brands competing with those of the supplier,15 or may be precluded from offering the

contractual products via an online marketplace.16 The same can be said of conduct implemented by

dominant firms. For instance, tying places rivals on the market for the tied product at a disadvantage.

In addition, the practice limits the freedom of action of the firm’s customers. At the other edge of the

spectrum, equating anticompetitive effects with harm to consumers (in terms of, inter alia, prices,

output, quality or innovation) would require evidence that the latter are made worse off by the practice

or transaction.17 This is known to be a particularly demanding exercise.

Freedom of Market As efficient Consumer

action* structure competitor welfare

Fig. 1: The meaning of effects


* (or competitive disadvantage)

15
See, for instance, Case C-234/89 Stergios Delimitis v Henninger Bräu AG, EU:C:1991:91.
16
See, for instance, Case C-230/16 Coty Germany GmbH v Parfümerie Akzente GmbH, EU:C:2017:941.
17
For an articulation of what the assessment would involve, see, for instance David Spector, ‘From Harm to Competitors
to Harm to Competition: One More Effort, Please!’ (2006) 2 European Competition Journal 145.

10

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


As seen in Figure 1, it is possible to identify at least two points in the spectrum that are

between these two ends. First, one can define effects as harm to the market structure in which the

practice or transaction is implemented. In such a case, the evaluation would focus on its impact on

other firms on the relevant market. Second, it is possible to further refine the analysis and equate

effects with an impact on equally efficient firms. If the latter definition is embraced, the consequences

on firms that are not as efficient as those implementing the practice or transaction would not amount

to anticompetitive effects. The departure of less efficient rivals would be deemed a natural and

desirable consequence of the operation of the competitive process, not one that would trigger a prima

facie prohibition.

2.3.2. The appreciability of effects

A separate but related question concerns the appreciability of effects. If a threshold of appreciability

is introduced, then it would not be enough to show that a practice or transaction would have a negative

impact on competition (however this is defined). It would be necessary to establish, in addition, that

the impact in question is significant (or appreciable). Suppose that evidence of consumer harm is

required to establish effects. In such a case, the authority would need to show not only that prices

would go up following the practice or transaction, but also that the rise would be appreciable. Suppose

now that harm to the market structure is enough to establish effects. In the context of an exclusive

dealing agreement, for instance, it would be necessary to show not only that access to the market

would be foreclosed to new entrants, but that the agreements concluded by the supplier in question

make an appreciable contribution to rivals’ departure from the relevant market.

Competition law systems can address appreciability in a variety of ways. The approach seems

to depend, at least in part, on the meaning that is attached to the concept of effects. If, for instance, a

negative impact on competition is equated with consumer harm, an appreciable restriction is one that

11

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


leads to a price increase (or equivalent harm to other parameters) above a certain level (for instance

5%).18 An alternative approach to appreciability is one that revolves around the market power – or a

proxy for market power – enjoyed by the firm(s) involved in the practice or transaction. For instance,

one could safely assume that the effects of a practice implemented by a dominant firm (that is, a firm

with substantial market power19) will, if established, be appreciable. Conversely, practices and

transactions implemented by firms with a modest degree of market power, could be assumed (or at

least presumed) not to have appreciable effects. The choices made by the Court in this regard are

explained in Section 6.

2.4. The probability of the effects: plausibility, likelihood and certainty

The probability threshold has already been mentioned as a crucial factor in the definition of

anticompetitive effects. Competition law systems focus on certain practices and transactions that

typically have at least some probability of affecting competition. All the examples mentioned above

– including exclusivity obligations, tying, mergers and acquisitions – can, in certain circumstances,

have negative effects on rivals and/or consumers. Accordingly, if the requisite probability threshold

were set at a sufficiently low level, such practices would be found to have anticompetitive effects in

virtually every instance. For the same reason, the need to show anticompetitive effects would become

a formality and the distinction between practices prohibited ‘by object’ and ‘by effect’ would be

meaningless in practice. Conversely, the threshold of effects may be set at such a high level that it

becomes difficult to meet by an authority or claimant (which would make conduct de facto lawful).

This would be the case, in particular, if the authority or claimant were required to show that the

practice or transaction is certain to have a negative impact on competition.

18
For an example of the articulation of this approach, see US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission,
Horizontal Merger Guidelines (2010).
19
OECD, ‘Evidentiary Issues in Proving Dominance/Monopoly Power’ DAF/COMP(2006)35.

12

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


Certainty

Likelihood

Plausibility

Fig. 2: The probability of effects

The main thresholds of probability are depicted in Figure 2. At the low end of the spectrum,

one can identify a threshold of plausibility. The latter concept is understood to mean that a finding of

anticompetitive effects in the relevant economic and legal context would not be contrary to ‘logic and

experience’.20 Accordingly, this threshold is met as soon as one can identify a credible mechanism

through which the impact on competition can be manifested. At the higher end of the spectrum, one

can identify a threshold of certainty (that is, a 100% probability), or quasi certainty of such effects.

Between the two ends, one can identify a threshold of ‘likelihood’, which would be met where it can

be shown that the impact on competition is more likely than not to occur (that is, a level of probability

right above 50%). All three thresholds are relevant in the EU competition law system, as explained

in Section 6 below.

20
The expression is borrowed from Ioannis Lianos, ‘“Judging” Economists: Economic Expertise in Competition Law
Litigation’ in Ioannis Kokkoris and Ioannis Lianos (eds), The Reform of EC Competition Law: New Challenges (Kluwer
2010).

13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


3. Anticompetitive effects in the case law: preliminary issues

3.1. Mechanisms through which anticompetitive effects are manifested

3.1.1. Collusion or absorption of a source competitive pressure

Anticompetitive effects, irrespective of how they are defined, may be manifested in a variety of ways.

The EU competition law system captures three mechanisms through which such effects may be

displayed. The first mechanism is the one that follows from collusion or the absorption of a source of

competitive pressure. The most straightforward example is that of a horizontal merger, which leads,

by its very nature, to the direct elimination of a rival.21 The negative effects resulting from this first

mechanism may be unilateral (that is, they may result from the increase in market power afforded by

the transaction to one or several market players) or coordinated (that is, they may flow from the

reduced incentive of the remaining market players to compete).22 Practices falling within the scope

of Article 101 TFEU can also display similar effects. An agreement between competitors softens the

competitive pressure faced by each of them; in addition, it may lead to collusive outcomes with other

market players.23 Some vertical arrangements can also lead to collusive outcomes.24

3.1.2. Exclusion of a source of competitive pressure

A second mechanism through which anticompetitive effects may be manifested is exclusion, that is,

the departure of one or several rivals from the market. Exclusionary outcomes may be caught by

21
Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers (n 13) and Case 6/72 Europemballage Corporation and Continental
Can Company Inc. v Commission, EU:C:1973:22.
22
Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers (n 13).
23
See in this sense the Guidelines on the applicability of Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European
Union to horizontal co-operation agreements [2011] OJ C11/1.
24
See in this sense the Guidelines on vertical restraints [2010] OJ C130/1.

14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


Article 101 TFEU, Article 102 TFEU and merger control. Just to mention an example, tying is a

concern insofar as it is a prima facie plausible mechanism through which competitors may be

foreclosed.25 To the extent that tying is implemented by means of an agreement between a supplier

and its customers, it can be caught by Article 101 TFEU; and, where the tie-in is imposed by a

dominant firm, by Article 102 TFEU. In the context of merger control – and, more precisely, where

the transaction gives rise to conglomerate concerns – the entity resulting from the transaction may

have the incentive to engage in tying behaviour, which may in turn have exclusionary effects.26

3.1.3. Exploitation of market power

Finally, anticompetitive effects may result from the exploitation by a dominant firm of its substantial

market power vis-a-vis customers and/or suppliers. As such, exploitative conduct can be caught by

Article 102 TFEU.27 In this case, anticompetitive effects are the consequence of the absence of

effective competitive constraints faced by the dominant firm. The anticompetitive behaviour in these

circumstances can be manifested in two main ways. First, exploitation may lead to the excessive

extraction of rents from operators elsewhere in the value chain. This extraction may be manifested,

for instance, in the dominant firm demanding unfairly high prices to its customers and, conversely,

in offering unfairly low prices to its suppliers.28 It may also result from imposing supplementary

obligations, unrelated to the main transaction, upon them.29

25
See in this sense the Guidance on the Commission’s enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to
abusive exclusionary conduct by dominant undertakings [2009] OJ C45/7.
26
See in this sense the Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the
control of concentrations between undertakings [2008] OJ C265/6.
27
This conclusion is something that directly follows from the letter of the Treaty. See in this sense René Joliet,
Monopolization and Abuse of Dominant Position: A Comparative Study of the American and European Approaches to
the Control of Economic Power (Martinus Nijhoff 1970).
28
Article 102(a) TFEU may consist in ‘directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair
trading conditions’.
29
In accordance with Article 102(d) TFEU, an abuse may also consist in ‘making the conclusion of contracts subject to
acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage,
have no connection with the subject of such contracts’.

15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


Second, exploitation may lead to the distortion of the conditions of competition on the markets

neighbouring the one in which the dominant firm operates. In other words, a dominant player may,

when exercising its substantial market power vis-à-vis customers and/or suppliers, favour some firms

at the expense of others (and thus inflict, at the very least, a competitive disadvantage on the latter).

For instance, a dominant supplier may adopt a policy of rebates that gives more favourable trading

conditions (in the form, for instance, of lower prices) to those customers that choose to deal

exclusively with it.30 In addition to the exclusionary effects that such a practice might display (what

have been termed primary-line effects in the literature), it may distort competition on the relevant

downstream market (secondary-line effects of an exploitative nature).31

3.2. The place of anticompetitive effects in the various legal tests

A practice or transaction that is incapable of having anticompetitive effects is not subject to EU

competition law.32 In that sense, one can claim that the notion is relevant across the board. This fact

does not mean, however, that it is necessary to establish anticompetitive effects, on a case-by-case

basis, in relation to every practice and transaction. Some practices – such as cartels – are deemed

prima facie unlawful irrespective of their impact. Anticompetitive effects are presumed to be an

inherent and inevitable consequence of the implementation of these practices; accordingly, their

impact need not be shown to exist in the economic and legal context of which they are a part.

Conversely, some practices are presumed compatible with Articles 101 and/or Article 102 TFEU;

30
Article 102(c) TFEU expressly provides that an abuse may consist in ‘applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent
transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage’. This is an issue that
complemented the exclusionary concerns in several rebate cases, including Case 322/81 NV Nederlandsche Banden
Industrie Michelin v Commission, EU:C:1983:313 (‘Michelin I’); Case T-203/01 Manufacture française des
pneumatiques Michelin v Commission, EU:T:2003:250 (‘Michelin II’); and British Airways (n 9).
31
For an analysis of the question, see Opinion of AG Wahl in Case C-525/16 MEO – Serviços de Comunicações e
Multimédia SA v Autoridade da Concorrência, EU:C:2017:1020; and Damien Geradin and Nicolas Petit, ‘Price
Discrimination under EC Competition Law: Another Antitrust Doctrine in Search of Limiting Principles?’ (2006) 2
Journal of Competition Law & Economics 479.
32
See in particular T-Mobile (n 2), para 31 and Case C-307/18, Generics (UK) Ltd and others v Competition and Markets
Authority, EU:C:2020:52, para 154.

16

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


thus, they are deemed prima facie lawful without it being necessary to carry out an assessment of

their effects. Finally, there are practices and transactions that only give rise to intervention where

their impact on competition is established in the specific context in which they are implemented. For

instance, mergers scrutinised under Regulation 139/2004 can only be declared to be incompatible

with the internal market following a case-by-case assessment of their effects.

The distinction between practices that are prima facie unlawful irrespective of their impact –

on the one hand – and practices that are only prohibited if they are shown to have such effects – on

the other – is particularly apparent in the context of Article 101(1) TFEU. This provision distinguishes

between agreements that restrict competition by object and by effect. 33 Evidence of the impact on

competition is only required in relation to the latter. Thus, once a restriction by object is established,

it is not necessary to show, in addition, that the agreement in question has anticompetitive effects.34

However, this same divide can be identified in the context of Article 102 TFEU. 35 Some conduct is

prima facie prohibited as abusive without it being necessary to evaluate, on a case-by-case basis, its

impact on competition. This is the case, in particular, of tying,36 of pricing below average variable

costs,37 and of exclusive dealing (as well as loyalty and ‘loyalty-inducing’ target rebates).38 Other

practices, including ‘margin squeeze’ behaviour39 and standardised rebate schemes,40 are only caught

by Article 102 TFEU insofar as they have anticompetitive effects.

33
Article 101(1) TFEU refers to practices that ‘have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of
competition within the internal market’.
34
The consistent line of case law on this point dates back to Joined Cases 56/64 and 58/64 Établissements Consten S.à.R.L.
and Grundig-Verkaufs-GmbH v Commission, EU:C:1966:41.
35
See in this sense Pablo Ibáñez Colomo, ‘Beyond the “more economics-based approach”: a legal perspective on Article
102 TFEU case law’ (2016) 53 Common Market Law Review 709.
36
Case T-30/89 Hilti AG v Commission, EU:T:1991:70; and Case T-83/91 Tetra Pak International SA v Commission,
EU:T:1994:246 (‘Tetra Pak II’).
37
Case C-62/86 AKZO Chemie BV v Commission, EU:C:1991:286, para 71.
38
Case 85/76 Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v Commission, EU:C:1979:36, para 89; confirmed in Case C-413/14 P Intel
Corporation Inc v Commission, EU:C:2017:632, para 137. See also Michelin I (n 30) and British Airways (n 9).
39
Case C-280/08 P Deutsche Telekom AG v Commission, EU:C:2010:603.
40
Post Danmark II (n 9) and TeliaSonera (n 9).

17

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


3.2.1. Anticompetitive effects and prima facie unlawful conduct

When a practice is deemed prima facie unlawful irrespective of its effects (both under Articles 101

and 102 TFEU), it is presumed to be at least ‘capable’ of having such effects.41 In other words, its

negative impact on competition is deemed to exist and need not be established on a case-by-case

basis. The Court has been explicit about the presumption of effects that underpins prima facie

unlawful conduct. In the context of Article 101(1) TFEU, for instance, it has explained that price-

fixing by cartels (which amounts to a ‘by object’ infringement) is known from experience to be a

source of allocative inefficiency.42 The same is true in the context of Article 102 TFEU. Underpinning

the prima facie prohibition of exclusive dealing and loyalty rebates, for instance, there is a

presumption that these practices are capable of restricting competition.43

As far as prima facie unlawful conduct is concerned, arguments about the absence of

anticompetitive effects may be advanced to escape the prohibition. In other words, the underlying

presumption is open to rebuttal by a defendant. Thus, it is possible for the parties to an agreement, or

for a dominant firm, to show that the practice is incapable of having a restrictive impact on

competition in the relevant economic and legal context. That the parties can show that an agreement

is incapable of restricting competition was expressly recognised, in the context of Article 101(1)

TFEU, in Murphy.44 In relation to Article 102 TFEU, this point was made explicit in Intel.45 The two

judgments clarify that defendants may bring arguments pertaining to the nature of the practice and

the relevant economic and legal context. These factors are examined at length below.

41
T-Mobile (n 2), para 31.
42
Cartes Bancaires (n 4) para 51; confirmed in Maxima Latvija (n 8), para 19; and Case C-228/18 Gazdasági
Versenyhivatal v Budapest Bank Nyrt. and others, EU:C:2020:265, para 36.
43
For a discussion on presumptions generally, and on this presumption in particular, see Chapter 6 in Andriani Kalintiri,
Evidence Standards in EU Competition Enforcement (Hart Publishing 2019).
44
Joined Cases C-403/08 and C-429/08 Football Association Premier League Ltd and Others v QC Leisure and Others
and Karen Murphy v Media Protection Services Ltd, EU:C:2011:631 (‘Murphy’), para 140.
45
Intel (n 38), paras 138-140.

18

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


3.2.2. The case-by-case assessment of anticompetitive effects: ‘standard effects’ and ‘enhanced

effects’ tests

The case-by-case assessment of the impact of a practice is the rule in the EU competition law system.

As already pointed out, the compatibility of all mergers within the meaning of Regulation 139/2004

is evaluated on the basis of a case-specific inquiry. In the context of Article 101(1) TFEU, the Court

has held that the ‘by object’ category is to be interpreted restrictively.46 The analysis of effects can

be undertaken in light of two sets of legal tests.47 The default approach is what can be termed the

‘standard effects’ test, which requires an evaluation of the impact of the practice (or transaction) on

competition in the relevant economic and legal context. There are two additional sub-tests, which

depart from the default test and can be termed ‘enhanced effects’ analysis. They apply in exceptional

circumstances. Under them, it is necessary to satisfy additional obligations. At the very least, an

authority or claimant would need to show, first, that an input or platform is indispensable for

competition on a neighbouring market and, second, that lack of access to the said input or platform

would lead to the elimination of all competition on that market.48

3.2.3. Anticompetitive effects and prima facie lawful conduct

Some practices are prima facie lawful in the sense that they are presumed to be compatible with

Article 101(1) and/or 102 TFEU without it being necessary to evaluate, case-by-case, their effects.

For instance, selective distribution agreements are deemed compatible with Article 101(1) TFEU

46
Cartes Bancaires (n 4) para 58; and Budapest Bank (n 42), para 54.
47
For an extensive analysis of the question, see Pablo Ibáñez Colomo, ‘Legal Tests in EU Competition Law: Taxonomy
and Operation’ (2019) 10 Journal of European Competition Law & Practice 424.
48
See in this sense Joined Cases C-241/91 P and C-242/91 P Radio Telefis Eireann (RTE) and Independent Television
Publications Ltd (ITP) v Commission, EU:C:1995:98 (‘Magill’); Case C-7/97 Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co. KG v
Mediaprint Zeitungs- und Zeitschriftenverlag GmbH & Co. KG and others, EU:C:1998:569; and Case C-418/01 IMS
Health GmbH & Co. OHG v NDC Health GmbH & Co. KG, EU:C:2004:257.

19

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


where the conditions set out by the Court in Metro I are fulfilled.49 The same is true of the restraints

found in franchising agreements and which are necessary to preserve the know-how of the franchisor

and the uniformity and reputation of its formula.50 Concerning potentially abusive conduct, above-

cost pricing is prima facie compatible with Article 102 TFEU. Quantity rebates (that is, rebates that

are incremental in nature and transaction-specific) are also prima facie lawful, and this insofar as they

are deemed to reflect the cost savings made by the supplier.51

It is possible for an authority or claimant to rebut the presumption of legality by showing that

prima facie lawful conduct has or would have anticompetitive effects in a given economic and legal

context. For instance, a selective distribution system may have a negative impact on competition

where a network of similar agreements leads to price rigidities, forecloses access to the market and/or

precludes other forms of distribution.52 Similarly, there may be instances, explored in detail below,

where quantity rebates and above-cost prices amount to an abuse of a dominant position. For instance,

an authority or claimant may be able to show that a given rebate scheme does not truly reflect the cost

savings made by the supplier and is designed to foreclose competition.53

4. The time dimension in the case law: actual and potential effects

4.1. The prospective analysis of potential effects

The Court has consistently held that EU competition law is concerned with both actual and potential

effects.54 Accordingly, the fact that an authority or claimant has failed to established the actual impact

49
Case 26/76 Metro SB-Großmärkte GmbH & Co. KG v Commission, EU:C:1977:167 (‘Metro I’).
50
Case 161/84 Pronuptia de Paris GmbH v Pronuptia de Paris Irmgard Schillgallis, EU:C:1986:41.
51
Hoffmann-La Roche (n 38), para 90; and Post Danmark II (n 9), para 28.
52
Case 75/84 Metro SB-Großmärkte GmbH & Co. KG v Commission, EU:C:1986:399 (‘Metro II’), para 40.
53
See for instance Case C-163/99 Portugal v Commission, EU:C:2001:189, paras 52-53.
54
See in particular Joined Cases 142 and 156/84 British-American Tobacco Company Ltd and R. J. Reynolds Industries
Inc. v Commission, EU:C:1987:490, para 39; Case C-7/95, John Deere Ltd v Commission, EU:C:1998:256, para 77;
Joined Cases C-215/96 and C-216/96 Carlo Bagnasco and Others v Banca Popolare di Novara soc. coop. arl. and Cassa

20

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


of a practice does not in itself mean that a restriction has not been established to the requisite legal

standard.55 That potential effects are sufficient to trigger intervention is self-evident in the context of

merger control, which is by definition based on the ex ante evaluation of concentrations. It is also

true in relation to Articles 101 and 102 TFEU. According to the case law, the analysis of potential

effects is relevant where the analysis is prospective in nature. Thus, it may come into play in the two

circumstances identified above: where the practice has not yet been implemented and where the

practice has already been implemented at the time of the adoption of the decision and the analysis

considers the future evolution of the relevant market. These two scenarios were considered by the

Court in British American Tobacco56 and are depicted in Figures 3 and 4.

Adoption of the
decision Court review

Analysis of potential effects

Fig. 3: The analysis of potential effects (I)

Implementation of Adoption of the


the practice Court review
decision

Analysis of actual effects Analysis of potential effects


Fig. 4: The analysis of potential effects (II)

Figures 3 and 4 show, in addition, that there is typically a lag between the adoption of a

decision by a competition authority and the review of its legality by a review court. As a result, by

the time the court reaches its decision, it is possible to assess whether the potential effects identified

by the authority are confirmed by subsequent market developments. These developments may reveal

di Risparmio di Genova e Imperia SpA, EU:C:1999:12, para 34; TeliaSonera (n 9), para 64; and Post Danmark II (n 9),
para 66.
55
John Deere (n 54), para 78.
56
British American Tobacco (n 54).

21

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


that the forecasts made by the authority failed to materialise. For instance, the assessment might have

been based on the premise that the barriers to entry on the relevant market and/or the practices would

have prevented the arrival or growth of rivals,57 and this premise may have been subsequently shown

to be false; alternatively, the assessment may have been based on the premise that network effects

would result in the market ‘tipping’ in favour of the firm involved in the practice.58

The question, in this regard, is whether the evaluation of the legality of the decision (and, in

particular, of whether potential effects have been established to the requisite legal standard) can be

informed by the actual developments that follow its adoption. According to the case law, the legality

of a Commission decision must be assessed on the basis of the evidence that is available when

adopted.59 Thus, the review court would not be able to consider the subsequent evolution of the market

in its assessment. The General Court (hereinafter, the ‘GC’) addressed this point in Microsoft I.60 The

fact that the theories underpinning the analysis of effects did not unfold as predicted by the

Commission was not considered.61 For the same reason, the fact that the anticompetitive effects failed

to materialise is not necessarily conclusive.62 Whether or not anticompetitive effects are established

to the requisite legal standard in such a scenario depends on the relevant probability threshold, which

is discussed below in Section 6.

4.2. The retrospective analysis of actual effects

The EU courts have addressed the question of whether the retrospective analysis can be based on

potential effects alone. The issue, in other words, is whether evidence shedding light on the evolution

of markets following the implementation of the practice (but before the adoption of the decision) can

57
See for instance Michelin II (n 30), paras 235-246.
58
See in this sense Case T-201/04 Microsoft Corp v Commission, EU:T:2007:289 (‘Microsoft I’).
59
Joined Cases 15 and 16/76 France v Commission, EU:C:1979:29..
60
Microsoft I (n 58), para 260.
61
Ibid, para 943.
62
Ibid, paras 560-564.

22

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


be disregarded by a claimant or authority. The issue has been addressed by the Court only indirectly,

and this when enunciating the general principles and when providing guidance to national courts on

the analysis of effects. According to a consistent line of case law, the impact of a practice on

competition is to be assessed in the ‘actual context’ in which it is implemented.63 This principle can

be interpreted as suggesting that the observable market developments at the time of the

implementation of the practice cannot be ignored.

This idea is confirmed when one examines the guidance provided to national courts. In Post

Danmark I, for instance, it explained that, absent evidence of an exclusionary purpose, prices that

cover the bulk of the costs attributable to a good or service are, ‘as a general rule’, not abusive (and

this even when they fall below average total costs).64 In such circumstances, the practice would only

be caught by Article 102 TFEU if it is shown to have anticompetitive effects.65 In its ruling, the Court

engaged in a retrospective analysis of the impact of the conduct and noted that the dominant firm’s

rival had not been driven out of the market and had, in fact, been able to maintain its distribution

network and win two customers back.66 Evidence in this sense was deemed to constitute a strong

indicator that the practice did not display exclusionary effects.

The GC faced the question directly when it considered the legality of the Commission decision

in Servier.67 In its Krka judgment, it held that the retrospective analysis of the anticompetitive effects

of a practice cannot ignore the actual developments that follow its implementation but that precede

the adoption of a decision. Thus, it concluded that the Commission had erred when claiming that,

when examining the impact of an agreement concluded between an actual and a potential competitor,

it can discharge its legal burden merely by considering hypotheticals about the evolution of markets

63
See in particular Case 56/65 Société Technique Minière, EU:C:1966:38, 249; John Deere (n 54), para 76; Case C-
238/05, Asnef-Equifax, Servicios de Información sobre Solvencia y Crédito, SL and Administración del Estado v
Asociación de Usuarios de Servicios Bancarios, EU:C:2006:734, para 49; Generics (n 32), para 116.
64
Post Danmark I (n 8), para 38.
65
Ibid, para 39.
66
Ibid.
67
Perindopril (Servier) (Case AT.39612) Commission Decision of 9 July 2014. See also Case T-691/14 Servier SAS and
others v Commission, EU:T:2018:922; and Case T-684/14 Krka Tovarna Zdravil d.d. v Commission, EU:T:2018:918.

23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


– that is, without considering the actual context in which the agreement in question displayed its

effects.68 In the same vein, it held that the case law discussed in the preceding section – which

concerned the prospective analysis of potential effects – is not applicable to instances in which it is

retrospective.69 The approach embraced in Krka, which is in turn consistent with the case law, reflects

the approaches captured in Figures 3 and 4.

5. The meaning of competition and the counterfactual in the case law

5.1. Competition comprises both the inter-brand and intra-brand dimensions

In Consten-Grundig, the Court unambiguously held that the EU competition law system (and the

‘principle of freedom of competition’) is not only concerned with inter-brand competition, but also

with intra-brand restrictions.70 Accordingly, one cannot rule out, from the outset, that conduct

restraining intra-brand rivalry (such as a distribution agreement providing for territorial protection)

amounts to a breach of Articles 101 and/or 102 TFEU merely because it might increase inter-brand

competition.71 Following Consten-Grundig, there has been a consistent line of enforcement against

practices with the object and/or effect of restricting intra-brand competition alone. Of these, restraints

aimed at limiting cross-border trade represent the largest fraction.72 Other practices include resale

price maintenance73 and selective distribution.74

68
Krka (n 67), paras 317-344.
69
Ibid, paras 345-359.
70
Consten-Grundig (n 34), 342.
71
Ibid.
72
These cases include Glaxo Spain (n 2) and Murphy (n 44).
73
Case 243/83 SA Binon & Cie v SA Agence et messageries de la presse, EU:C:1985:284 and Pronuptia (n 50).
74
Metro I (n 49); Metro II (n 52); and Coty (n 16).

24

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


5.2. Competition refers to such lawful competition which would otherwise have existed

The Court has consistently held, from the early days, that competition, for the purposes of the Treaty,

must be understood as referring to such competition which would have existed in the absence of the

practice or transaction.75 Accordingly, anticompetitive effects need to be established against the

relevant counterfactual, or, as the Court has consistently held, ‘within the actual context in which it

would occur in the absence of the [practice or transaction] in dispute’.76 This is true across the board.

In this sense, the meaning of competition does not change depending on whether the assessment under

Article 101(1) TFEU relates to the object of a practice or to its effects. Similarly, it does not change

depending on whether it is a transaction examined under the Regulation 139/2004 or a practice subject

to Articles 101 and/or 102 TFEU. The need to consider the counterfactual has two main implications.

First, it is necessary to establish a causal link between the practice or transaction and any actual or

potential effects. Second, a practice that is necessary to attain a pro-competitive aim is not restrictive

of competition, whether by object or as a result of its impact on competition. These two implications

are examined in turn.

5.2.1. There must be a causal link between the practice or transaction and any effects

The Court has expressly held that there must be a causal link between a practice or transaction, on

the one hand, and any actual or potential effects, on the other. Accordingly, where the observed or

expected impact (or, more generally, the absence of competition) would have occurred in its absence,

the practice or transaction is not restrictive of competition (whether by object or effect). The need to

establish a causal link was made explicit, in the context of merger control, in Kali & Salz.77 In relation

75
Société Technique Minière (n 63), 250.
76
See above, n 63.
77
Joined cases C-68/94 and C-30/95 France and others v Commission, EU:C:1998:148 (‘Kali & Salz’).

25

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


to Article 102 TFEU, the Court held, in Post Danmark II, that any anticompetitive effects must not

be purely ‘hypothetical’ and must be ‘attributable’ to the dominant firm.78 These judgments are in

line with a consistent line of case law, which under Article 101 TFEU, makes it necessary to establish

the restriction against the relevant counterfactual.79

The evaluation of the causal link between the practice or transaction and its effects is to be

undertaken in light of the economic and legal context of which it is a part. The analysis may reveal

the absence of a causal link, and this for a variety of reasons – including the very nature of the relevant

market and its evolution. Two examples illustrate the idea. To begin with, the absence of competition

may not be attributable to the practice or transaction, but to the regulatory context, which may

preclude any inter-brand and/or intra-brand rivalry. In relation to Article 101(1) TFEU, for instance,

the Court has held that an agreement would not be capable of having anticompetitive effects where

there are ‘insurmountable’ barriers to entry.80 Such insurmountable barriers may exist, for instance,

where there is an intellectual property right.81 They may also exist where the regulatory framework,

taken together, amounts to a de facto monopoly precluding entry.82

A causal link would also fail to exist, in a scenario of exclusion (or exploitation), where the

deterioration of the conditions of competition can be attributed to the inefficiency of the firms that

are or may be driven out of the market. In line with what has been explained above, the Court declared,

in Post Danmark I, that the exclusion of those firms that are ‘less attractive to consumers from the

point of view of, among other things, price, choice, quality or innovation’ does not give rise to

anticompetitive effects under Article 102 TFEU.83 The departure of such firms from the market can

78
Post Danmark II (n 9), para 47 and 65.
79
See in particular Case C‑382/12 P MasterCard Inc. and Others v Commission, EU:C:2014:2201, para 161; Generics (n
32), paras 103-122; and Budapest Bank (n 42), paras 55, 82 and 83.
80
C‑373/14 P Toshiba Corporation v Commission, EU:C:2016:26, paras 31-34; and Generics (n 32), para 45.
81
See for instance Case 262/81 Coditel SA, Compagnie générale pour la diffusion de la télévision, and others v Ciné-Vog
Films SA and others, EU:C:1982:334 (‘Coditel II’); Case C-9/93 IHT Internationale Heiztechnik GmbH and Uwe
Danzinger v Ideal-Standard GmbH and Wabco Standard GmbH, EU:C:1994:261; and Generics (n 32), para 45.
82
Case T-360/09, E.ON Ruhrgas AG and E.ON AG v Commission, para 104. See also Case T-370/09, GDF Suez SA v
Commission, para 97.
83
Post Danmark I (n 8), para 22.

26

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


be expected to occur irrespective of the implementation of the practice.84 For the same reason, above-

cost pricing and quantity rebates (as defined by the Court in Post Danmark II) are deemed prima facie

lawful. It is reasonable to presume that an equally efficient rival would not be excluded as a result of

such practices. In the context of merger control, the Court embraced the same idea by accepting, as a

matter of principle, a variation of the ‘failing firm defence’.85

5.2.2. A practice that is objectively necessary is not restrictive of competition

The evaluation of the counterfactual may reveal not only that a practice does not lead to a deterioration

of the conditions of competition, but that it actually improves them. If the assessment reveals that the

practice in question is objectively necessary to attain a legitimate or pro-competitive aim, it will not

amount to a restriction of competition, whether by object or effect. There is a long line of Article

101(1) TFEU case law expressly addressing this point, starting with Société Technique Minière.86 An

agreement may prove to be objectively necessary for a variety of reasons. It may be the case, for

instance, that a licensee would not have undertaken the necessary investments to produce and market

the contractual goods in the absence of the territorial restraints provided for by virtue of the

agreement.87 It may also be the case that the parties have complementary capabilities that allow them

to engage in a project that they would not have been able to pursue individually.88

A variation of the objective necessity test is the so-called ancillary restraints doctrine, which

has been recognised as such by the Court. Under the doctrine, the question is whether the agreement

would have been concluded in the absence of some clauses. The question, in other words, is whether

84
See in this sense Luc Peeperkorn and Vincent Verouden, ‘The Economics of Competition’, in Jonathan Faull and Ali
Nikpay (eds), The EU Law of Competition (3rd edn, Oxford University Press 2014), 1.43-1.49.
85
Kali & Salz (n 77), para 115.
86
Société Technique Minière (n 63), 250: ‘[...] [I]t may be doubted whether there is an interference with competition if
the said agreement seems really necessary for the penetration of a new area by an undertaking [...]’; Generics (n 32), paras
103-111; and Budapest Bank (n 42), paras 82-83.
87
Case 268/78 L.C. Nungesser KG and Kurt Eisele v Commission, EU:C:1982:211, paras 55-58.
88
Joined Cases T-374/94, T-375/94, T-384/94 and T-388/94 European Night Services Ltd v Commission, EU:T:1998:198,
para 145.

27

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


the clauses are objectively necessary for the agreement to exist in the first place. For instance, a non-

compete obligation may be necessary for the buyer to agree to the acquisition of a business.89 To the

extent that it is, it would not restrict competition, whether by object or effect. Similarly, the Court

explained in Pronuptia that a firm would not be willing to engage in a franchising agreement if it is

unable to preserve its know-how and the uniformity and reputation of its formula.90 Accordingly, the

clauses that are objectively necessary to achieve these aims fall outside the scope of Article 101(1)

TFEU altogether.

The case law addressing objective necessity revolves around the application of Article 101(1)

TFEU. A remaining question, accordingly, is whether the same principles apply in the context of

Article 102 TFEU. If they did, a dominant firm would be able to avoid a prima facie finding of abuse

on objective necessity grounds. Thus, the practice would fall outside the scope of the prohibition since

it would not have anticompetitive effects (the conditions of competition would have improved, not

deteriorated, following the implementation of the practice). The possibility to invoke objective

necessity would be distinct from, and complementary to, the possibility for the dominant firm to

provide an objective justification and/or to show that the efficiencies to which the practice gives rise

outweigh any restrictive effects. Unlike objective necessity, the latter two would only come into play

following the prima facie finding of an abuse.

It would be reasonable to assume that the objective necessity test is also relevant in the context

of Article 102 TFEU. This is so, first, because there are express references to objective necessity in

the case law.91 Second, consistency would demand that the same principles apply across the

competition law system. It would not be obvious to justify why objective necessity would apply only

in relation to Article 101(1) TFEU. Such an approach would amount to attaching different meanings

to the concept of competition depending on the applicable provision, which is not an easily tenable

89
Case 42/84 Remia BV and others v Commission, EU:C:1985:327, para 19.
90
Pronuptia (n 50), paras 16-17.
91
Case 311/84 Centre belge d'études de marché - Télémarketing v SA Compagnie luxembourgeoise de télédiffusion and
Information publicité Benelux, EU:C:1985:394, para 27.

28

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


position. One should consider, in this regard, that there are instances in which the same practice can

be subject to both Articles 101 and 102 TFEU.92 It is difficult to see how the same conduct could be

simultaneously found to be objectively necessary (and thus pro-competitive and incapable of having

restrictive effects) under Article 101(1) TFEU and prima facie abusive (and thus capable of having

restrictive effects) under Article 102 TFEU.

5.3. Both the ex ante and ex post dimensions of the counterfactual are considered

5.3.1. The role of ex ante considerations in the analysis of effects

An important conclusion that follows from the interpretation and application of the counterfactual by

the Court is that both its ex ante and ex post dimensions are considered. The case law shows that the

pro-competitive gains resulting from a practice cannot simply be assumed to have existed. For the

same reasons, any observable ex post restrictions cannot be examined in isolation. There are abundant

examples in the case law showing how ex ante considerations play a role in the analysis. In Nungesser,

the Court deemed justified the concerns expressed by the interveners in the case, who explained that

the relevant technology (and the resulting innovation) was the outcome of ‘years of research and

experimentation’.93 The assessment of any ex post restraints (which in the case gave territorial

protection to the licensee), accordingly, would have to pay due regard to the ‘nature of the product’.94

The cases spelling out the ancillary restraints doctrine further illustrate how the ex ante

dimension of the counterfactual plays a role in the analysis. In Pronuptia, the Court noted that

franchising agreements lead to pro-competitive gains by allowing the franchisor to benefit from its

formula without investing its own capital, on the one hand; and by giving access to franchisees to

92
Joined cases C-395/96 P and C-396/96 P Compagnie Maritime Belge Transports SA v Commission, EU:C:2000:132,
para 33; and Generics (n 32), para 146.
93
Nungesser (n 87), para 56.
94
Ibid, para 58.

29

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


methods they would only have been able to obtain after ‘considerable efforts’ and thus benefit from

the franchisee’s goodwill, on the other.95 Accordingly, some ex post restraints resulting from the

franchising agreement (such as non-compete obligations or limitations relating to the outlets from

which the contractual goods may be sold) are inextricably linked to these ex ante pro-competitive

gains. To the extent that they are, they cannot be dissociated from them.

Beyond the ancillary restraints doctrine, the case law on refusals to deal captures effectively

the role that ex ante considerations play in the analysis. Seen ex post, any refusal by a vertically-

integrated company to deal with a would-be rival has anticompetitive effects. However, the Court has

consistently held that such refusals are only abusive in exceptional circumstances.96 The stringent,

‘enhanced effects’ test laid down in Magill, Bronner and IMS Health can only be understood if the

ex ante dimension of the counterfactual is taken into account. The ex ante factors that confine to

exceptional circumstances the instances in which a refusal amounts to an abuse were discussed by

AG Jacobs in Bronner. The Opinion emphasises that imposing an access obligation too readily would

harm firms’ ex ante incentives to invest and innovate.97 Thus, an exclusive focus on the observable

ex post restraints would disregard the pro-competitive gains resulting from the very same restraints

and lead to less, not more, competition.

5.3.2. How ex ante considerations are incorporated in the analysis

The examples above are useful not only to show how ex ante considerations may lead to the

conclusion that a practice is incapable of having anticompetitive effects, but also the different ways

in which they may be incorporated in the analysis. In some circumstances, ex ante considerations are

evaluated on a case-by-case basis in light of the relevant economic and legal context. Such was the

95
Pronuptia (n 50), para 15.
96
See in this sense Magill (n 48), Bronner (n 48) and IMS Health (n 48).
97
Opinion of AG Jacobs in Case C-7/97 Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co. KG v Mediaprint Zeitungs- und Zeitschriftenverlag
GmbH & Co. KG and others, EU:C:1998:264.

30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


case, for instance, in Nungesser. In these instances, the firm(s) involved in the practice may provide

evidence showing that the effects of any ex post restraints cannot be dissociated from the ex ante

gains resulting from it – and, by the same token, why, by failing to do so, an authority may have erred

in law. For instance, the parties may provide ‘serious indicia’98 showing why, in the specific

circumstances of a case, the benefits resulting from an exclusive distribution agreement would not

have been achieved without the restriction of active and passive sales.99

There are other circumstances where ex ante considerations are incorporated in the legal test

itself. In fact, the ‘enhanced effects’ and prima facie lawfulness tests, described above, are precisely

designed to take into account the ex ante dimension of the counterfactual. These legal tests seek to

capture the presumption that any ex post restraints are inextricably linked to the pro-competitive gains

resulting from the practice. This is obvious, as explained above, in relation to ancillary restraints. By

making them prima facie lawful, the Court acknowledges that the agreements of which they are a part

(and the resulting pro-competitive gains) would not take place without some ex post restraints.

Similarly, the ‘enhanced effects’ test (and, in particular, the indispensability condition) is crafted to

preserve firms’ ex ante incentives to invest and innovate (and, by doing so, the pro-competitive gains

resulting from them).

6. The meaning of effects in the case law

6.1. Only appreciable effects are relevant under EU competition law

Only appreciable effects are relevant in the EU competition law system. As the Court declared in

Völk, practices with an ‘insignificant effect’ on competition (de minimis) fall outside the scope of

98
Budapest Bank (n 42), paras 82-83.
99
Guidelines on vertical restraints (n 24), para 61.

31

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


Article 101 TFEU.100 Appreciability is also enshrined in the merger control regime. In accordance

with Article 2 of Regulation 139/2004, only transactions that would lead to a significant impediment

to effective competition can be declared to be incompatible with the internal market. 101 It seems clear

from Völk that the appreciability of the restrictive effects is assessed by reference to the market power

enjoyed by the firm(s) involved – or, to use the Court’s expression, their weak or strong position on

the relevant market(s) affected by the practice or transaction.

In principle, the assessment of the market power of a firm requires a case-by-case evaluation.

However, both the Court and the Commission have resorted to proxies that dispense from a context-

specific inquiry. In Expedia, the ECJ held that, where an agreement is found to restrict competition

by object, the fact that it is capable of affecting trade between Member States is sufficient to conclude

that its effect on competition is appreciable within the meaning of Völk.102 For practices that are not

prima facie unlawful irrespective of their effects, market shares tend to be used as a proxy. In

accordance with the Preamble to Regulation 139/2004, the fact that the market share of the parties

does not exceed 25%, is an indicator that the transaction is not liable to have significant effects.103 In

the context of Article 101 TFEU, the Commission has published, over the years, several versions of

its De Minimis Notice, which also revolve around market shares.104 This is also the technique used

in the Guidelines on vertical restraints,105 on horizontal co-operation agreements106 and on technology

licensing107 provide, which shed additional light in this regard.

A logical corollary to the above is that the de minimis doctrine has no role to play in abuse of

dominance cases. Given that appreciability depends on the market power enjoyed by the firm(s)

100
Case 5/69 Franz Völk v S.P.R.L. Ets J. Vervaecke, EU:C:1969:35.
101
See Article 2 of Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the control of concentrations between
undertakings [2004] OJ L24/1. See also Case T-399/16 CK Telecoms UK Investments Ltd v Commission, EU:T:2020:217.
102
Case C-226/11 Expedia Inc. v Autorité de la concurrence and others, EU:C:2012:795.
103
Regulation 139/2004 (n 101), Recital 32.
104
Notice on agreements of minor importance which do not appreciably restrict competition under Article 101(1) of the
Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union [2014] OJ C291/1.
105
Guidelines on vertical restraints (n 24).
106
Guidelines on horizontal co-operation agreements (n 23).
107
Guidelines on the application of Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to technology
transfer agreements [2014] OJ C89/3.

32

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


involved in a practice or transaction, and given that a precondition for the application of Article 102

TFEU is a finding of a position of substantial market power, any anticompetitive effects – provided

that they are established to the requisite legal standard – are appreciable by definition. Against this

background, it is only logical that the Court, in Post Danmark II, ruled that it is not appropriate to set

a de minimis or appreciability threshold in abuse cases.108 When implemented by a firm with

substantial market power, ‘any further weakening of the structure of competition may constitute an

abuse of a dominant position’.109 Accordingly, it is not necessary for a claimant or authority to show

that the effects, once shown, are appreciable.

A key question that has not yet been addressed by the Court relates to the requisite level of

appreciability. As the law stands, it is possible to gain an idea of the practices or transactions that are

unlikely to yield appreciable effects. There is no dispute that the effects of a practice implemented by

a dominant firm will, if established, be appreciable. However, the Court has not identified (directly

or by proxy) the degree of market power above which the impact of a practice or transaction on

competition becomes appreciable. It would be reasonable to assume that the threshold of

appreciability is below the level of dominance.110 However, it is unclear where it lies and, by the same

token, how far below dominance it is. There is, in other words, a grey area where effects may or may

not be appreciable depending on the circumstances of the case. Crucially, the EU courts have clarified,

in this regard, that the issue of appreciability is to be assessed on a case-by-case basis. Thus, it would

not be sufficient for an authority or claimant to show that the parties exceed the market share

thresholds as defined in the De Minimis Notice.111

108
Post Danmark II (n 9), para 73.
109
Ibid, para 72.
110
See in this sense the Guidelines on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty [2004] OJ C101/97, para 26.
111
Case T-9/93 Schöller Lebensmittel GmbH & Co. KG v Commission, EU:T:1995:99, para 75. See also Expedia (n 102).

33

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


6.2. An effect is more than a competitive disadvantage or a limitation of a firm’s freedom of

action

From the early days, the Court has held, directly and indirectly, that a limitation of a firm’s freedom

of action does not lead, in and of itself, to anticompetitive effects. Similarly, the fact that one or

several firms are placed at a disadvantage cannot be equated with a negative impact on competition.

These questions were first addressed in relation to the interpretation of Article 101(1) TFEU. 112 The

essence of this consistent line of case law is captured in the rulings dealing with the status of exclusive

dealing. Single-branding restrains, by definition, the freedom of action of the buyer (which is

precluded from selling products competing with the supplier’s); in addition, it would inflict a

competitive disadvantage on the buyer where other outlets are entitled to sell several brands of a

product. In spite of these facts, the Court ruled that exclusive dealing is not restrictive by its very

nature, and that its effects need to be assessed by looking at the impact of the agreement on the

relevant market.113 This position has been held across a broad range of practices that limit a firm’s

freedom of action and/or inflict a competitive disadvantage; including, just to mention some

examples, non-compete obligations,114 non-challenge clauses in a licensing agreement115 or bans on

the use of online marketplaces.116

In the context of merger control, it has never been seriously disputed that limiting a firm’s

freedom of action and/or placing firms at a competitive disadvantage is as such insufficient to

establish anticompetitive effects. This point is exemplified by conglomerate mergers. A conglomerate

transaction involving firms in neighbouring markets typically gives the merged entity a competitive

112
See in particular Case 23/67 SA Brasserie de Haecht v Consorts Wilkin-Janssen, EU:C:1967:54; Delimitis (n 15); Case
C-250/92 Gøttrup-Klim e.a. Grovvareforeninger v Dansk Landbrugs Grovvareselskab AmbA, EU:C:1994:413, paras 28-
34; Case C-309/99 JCJ Wouters, JW Savelbergh and Price Waterhouse Belastingadviseurs BV v Algemene Raad van de
Nederlandse Orde van Advocaten, EU:C:2002:98, para. 97.
113
Delimitis (n 15), paras 10-13.
114
Remia (n 89).
115
Case 65/86 Bayer AG and Maschinenfabrik Hennecke GmbH v Heinz Süllhöfer, EU:C:1988:448.
116
Coty (n 16).

34

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


advantage over rivals operating only on one of the markets. If there is an overlap between the

customers of both products, this competitive advantage would allow the entity to offer a wider

portfolio of products to its customers. The entity may also have the ability and the incentive to engage

in tying and bundling. As confirmed in Tetra Laval, such consequences are, in and of themselves,

insufficient to show that the transaction would have anticompetitive effects.117 These principles are

now encapsulated in the Non-Horizontal Merger Guidelines issued by the Commission.118

The evolution in the interpretation of Article 102 TFEU also leads to the conclusion that the

anticompetitive effects of the practice cannot merely be inferred from a competitive disadvantage

and/or a limitation of a firm’s freedom of action. The Court has consistently held that, in order to

establish anticompetitive effects (and, more precisely, exclusionary effects), it is necessary to

ascertain whether a practice makes entry ‘more difficult, or impossible’.119 The precise meaning of

this expression, which can be interpreted in more ways than one (including in support of the idea that

a competitive disadvantage is enough to trigger intervention) needs to be teased out from an analysis

of individual judgments. The trajectory of the case law since at least Deutsche Telekom120 sheds light

on the nature of the assessment, both in relation to exclusionary and exploitative strategies.

Suffice it to mention some examples. A ‘margin squeeze’, which necessarily places rivals at

a competitive disadvantage by forcing them to sell below cost, is not in itself abusive.121 The

anticompetitive effects of the practice need to be established in light of its impact on the relevant

market.122 The same can be said, more generally, of conduct that amounts to below-cost pricing but

is not predatory within the meaning of AKZO,123 and of standardised rebates.124 In relation to the

117
Case C-12/03 P Commission v Tetra Laval BV, EU:C:2005:87; and Case T-5/02 Tetra Laval BV v Commission,
EU:T:2002:264.
118
Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers (n 26), paras 39, 47-57, 67, 72-77, 103 and 111-118.
119
British Airways (n 9), para 68; Case C-280/08 P Deutsche Telekom (n 39), para 177; TeliaSonera (n 9), para 63 Post
Danmark II (n 9), para 31. This expression has occasionally been used in the context of Article 101 TFEU. See in
particular Maxima Latvija (n 8), para 29.
120
Deutsche Telekom (n 39).
121
Ibid, para 250.
122
Ibid, para 254.
123
Post Danmark I (n 8).
124
Post Danmark II (n 9).

35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


latter, the criteria identified by the Court in cases like Post Danmark II and Intel are the same as those

deemed relevant under Article 101 TFEU in cases like Delimitis.125 Similarly, in Generics, the Court

held that, for the effects of a pay-for-delay agreement to trigger intervention under Article 102 TFEU,

the said effects need to go beyond the mere impact it has on the freedom of action of the generic

producer receiving the payment.126 Concerning, finally, exploitative conduct, the Court declared in

MEO that a competitive disadvantage does not suffice, in and of itself, to show that discriminatory

pricing amounts to a distortion of competition on the relevant market.127

6.3. As a rule, an anticompetitive effect cannot be equated with harm to consumer welfare

In the same way that an analysis of the case law shows that a limitation of a firm’s freedom of action

and/or a competitive disadvantage are insufficient to establish anticompetitive effects, it is clear that,

as a matter of principle, evidence of direct harm to consumers is not necessary to show such effects.

The question of whether anticompetitive effects can be equated with consumer harm has emerged

where the mechanisms through which these effects are manifested are collusion (and more precisely

the absorption of a source of competitive pressure) and exclusion. It has been contended that reduced

competitive pressure is, in and of itself, insufficient to justify intervention. In other words, the

elimination of a source of rivalry (whether through exclusion or collusion) would not amount, from

this perspective, to anticompetitive effects. The argument, according to this interpretation of the

notion, is that it would be necessary to show, in addition, that reduced rivalry makes or would make

consumers worse off.128

125
Delimitis (n 15), paras 15-36. Compare with Post Danmark II (n 9), paras 29-46 and Intel (n 38), paras 139-140.
126
Generics (n 32), paras 161 and 172.
127
Case C-525/16 MEO – Serviços de Comunicações e Multimédia SA v Autoridade da Concorrência, paras 25-26.
128
See for instance Spector (n 17) and Pinar Akman, ‘“Consumer” versus “Customer”: The Devil in the Detail’ (2010)
37 Journal of Law and Society 315.

36

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


The Court has consistently held, in contradiction with the abovementioned view, that the EU

competition law system is concerned not only with the protection of consumers, but also with the

‘structure of the market’ and therefore with ‘competition as such’.129 Accordingly, and as clarified in

British Airways, it would not be necessary to show that an exclusionary strategy would make

consumers worse off for it to be caught by Article 102 TFEU (or at least not in principle).130 Similarly,

the Commission would not need to show that a merger would lead to a price increase for end-users.

For instance, the mere fact that a transaction would eliminate the main source of competitive pressure

faced by the acquiring firm (and that there would be no perspective of new entry replicating such

constraints) would be enough to declare its incompatibility with the internal market.131

An analysis of the case law suggests that there is only one instance in which direct evidence

of consumer harm is required to establish an abuse of a dominant position. In Magill (as confirmed

in IMS Health), the Court held that a refusal to license an intellectual property right amounts to an

abuse of a dominant position where, inter alia, the behaviour prevents the emergence of a new product

for which there is potential consumer demand.132 This condition adds to indispensability and the

elimination of ‘all competition’ conditions, mentioned above. The implication of the ‘new product’

condition is that, for a refusal to license to amount to a violation of Article 102 TFEU, the

anticompetitive effects would need to go beyond those that follow inevitably from the operation of

the intellectual property rights; and that the harm to consumers should be both direct and

substantial.133

129
Glaxo Spain, para 63.
130
British Airways (n 9), paras 103-108.
131
Case T-342/07 Ryanair Holdings plc v Commission, EU:T:2010:280, paras 224, 225 and 445.
132
Magill (n 48), para 54; and IMS Health (n 48), para 38.
133
For a discussion, see Robert O’Donoghue and Jorge Padilla, The Law and Economics of Article 102 TFEU (2nd edn,
Hart Publishing 2013) 559-562.

37

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


6.4. Anticompetitive effects exist where competitive pressure is reduced

In EU competition law, anticompetitive effects exist where a practice (or transaction) harms the

ability and/or incentive to compete of firms that are as efficient as the firm(s) involved in (or

benefitting from) it. More precisely, an analysis of the case law suggests that the relevant question in

this regard is whether the ability and/or incentive to compete are harmed to such an extent that

competitive pressure is reduced. Thus, a disadvantage and/or a limitation of a firm’s freedom of action

would not be problematic in themselves, but only insofar as they can be expected to lead to such an

outcome. In the same vein, no anticompetitive effects would exist where the competitive pressure

faced by the firm(s) involved in (or benefitting from) the practice or transaction is not altered by it.

This principle is expressed in different ways depending on the nature or practice and the mechanism

through which the impact on competition is manifested.

6.4.1. Collusion or absorption of a source of competitive pressure

Turning to the first mechanism identified above – collusion or absorption of a source of competitive

pressure – anticompetitive effects may be manifested in two ways. First, a horizontal agreement or

merger may lead, as already mentioned, to unilateral effects. Unilateral effects arise where, without

coordination, a practice or transaction has a negative impact on one or more firms’ incentive to

compete. In other words, they arise where the reduced competitive pressure faced by one or more

firms leads to an increase in the degree of market power they enjoy. The most straightforward case is

one where a practice or transaction creates or strengthens a position of single dominance, which is

38

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


understood to mean a position of substantial market power.134 As is true of appreciability, market

shares are the most obvious proxy for dominance.135

Unilateral effects may also arise even where a practice or transaction does not create or

strengthen a dominant position. As explained above, the threshold of appreciability seems to be below

that of dominance. According to the GC in CK Telecoms, there are two conditions to establish

unilateral effects, absent dominance, in the context of EU merger control.136 First, the transaction

must lead to an appreciable reduction of the competitive constraints faced by the merging parties prior

to the transaction. Second, it must lead to an appreciable reduction of the competitive constraints

placed upon competitors. In other words, the GC held that the Commission would need to show, to

the requisite legal standard, that the transaction reduces the incentives to compete of all firms on the

relevant market. In addition to market shares,137 an increase in market power can be established by

proxy in light of factors such as firms’ closeness of competition or rivals’ ability to expand capacity

in response to a deterioration of the conditions of competition.138

Second, and as explained above, a practice (or transaction) can also lead to anticompetitive

effects if it eliminates the incentives to compete by means of inter-firm coordination. The

circumstances in which tacit collusion (and thus the emergence of a collective dominant position) is

likely to occur, and become sustainable, were defined by the GC in Airtours.139 Horizontal and non-

horizontal mergers may thus be declared to be incompatible with the internal market if the criteria

defined in that judgment are fulfilled.140 In addition, agreements within the meaning of Article 101

134
For a definition of the notion, see Hoffmann-La Roche (n 38), para 38. See also Guidelines on the assessment of
horizontal mergers (n 13), paras 2 and 17.
135
Hoffmann-La Roche (n 38), para 41 and AKZO (n 37), para 60.
136
CK Telecoms (n 101), para 96.
137
Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers (n 13), paras 14-18 and 27. See, in the same vein, Guidelines on
horizontal co-operation agreements (n 23), paras 44-46.
138
Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers (n 13), paras 28-38 and Guidelines on horizontal co-operation
agreements (n 23), para 34. See also CK Telecoms (n 101), paras 227-250.
139
Case T-342/99 Airtours plc v Commission, EU:T:2002:146, para 62. See also Case C-413/06 Bertelsmann AG and
Sony Corporation of America v Independent Music Publishers and Labels Association, EU:C:2008:392, para 123.
140
Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers (n 13), paras 39-57; and Guidelines on the assessment of non-
horizontal mergers (n 26), paras 79-81.

39

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


TFEU may also be found to have restrictive effects if they create the conditions in which coordination

with other rivals on the market becomes feasible and/or easier to sustain. Some of these scenarios are

explored by the Commission in its Guidelines on horizontal co-operation agreements.141

6.4.2. Exclusion of a source of competitive pressure

Exclusionary concerns arise where actual or potential rivals’ ability and incentive to compete is

affected to such an extent that competitive pressure is reduced. In Delimitis, the Court devised a test

to determine whether access to the market would be foreclosed as a result of a practice (together or

in combination with other practices having the same object and/or effect).142 The question, as

confirmed in Maxima Latvija, would be whether there would be ‘real, concrete possibilities’ for a

new rival to establish itself and exercise a competitive constraint on existing players.143 The same

criteria seem appropriate, mutatis mutandis, to inquire whether existing market players would retain

their ability and incentive to exercise an effective constraint in spite of the practice. These two

judgments are also compatible with the way in which the analysis is actually conducted under Article

102 TFEU and merger control. In abuse of dominance cases, a practice can be said to lead to

‘foreclosure effects’144 where it ‘hinder[s] the ability of competitors’145 to operate on the relevant

market.

As a matter of principle, and in line with what has been explained above, only the exclusion

of equally efficient rivals is relevant in EU competition law.146 This principle is the corollary to the

need to establish a causal link between the practice and any anticompetitive effects. Such a causal

link would be missing where a firm’s departure would be the consequence of its inability to provide

141
Guidelines on horizontal co-operation agreements (n 23), para 77-85; and paras 175-182.
142
Delimitis (n 15), paras 15-36.
143
Maxima Latvija (n 8), para 27.
144
Intel (n 38), paras 138, 142 and 143; and Generics (n 32), para 157.
145
TeliaSonera (n 9), para 67.
146
See above, Section 5.2.1.

40

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


attractive goods and/or services. However, there may be instances in which it the exclusion of less

efficient rivals could give rise to a finding of infringement. This may be the case, the Court explained

in Post Danmark II, where a practice is implemented by a dominant firm that is protected by

regulatory barriers in a partially liberalised industry.147 It is reasonable to assume that, as the law

stands, it would be for the authority or claimant to show, to the requisite legal standard, why the

departure of less efficient rivals is justified in a given case.

The case law provides several illustrations of the principle. It follows from AKZO, Deutsche

Telekom and Post Danmark I that, if a practice does not force rivals to sell below cost, it is deemed

prima facie lawful. An equally efficient rival can be expected to withstand competition that does not

involve below-cost pricing.148 A variation on this filter is the so-called ‘as efficient competitor’ test,

which is relevant when evaluating the lawfulness of conditional rebates. This test is designed to

establish whether a rebate scheme, in the circumstances in which it is implemented, would require an

equally efficient rival to sell at a loss when competing for the contestable part of customers’

demand.149 In Intel, the Court clarified that a dominant firm may rely on the ‘as efficient competitor’

test to show that a loyalty rebate scheme is not capable of having anticompetitive effects.150

Considerations pertaining to the nature of the product, the practice and the actual context in

which the latter is implemented are relevant in the (prospective or retrospective) analysis of

exclusionary effects. First, the Court has had the occasion to explain how the probability of

anticompetitive effects depends, at least in part, on the nature of the practice and its relative potential

to cause harm. This is true of price-based and non-price-based conduct. For instance, the level of a

‘margin squeeze’ has an impact on its exclusionary potential. In particular, the Court held in

TeliaSonera that a negative ‘margin squeeze’ (that is, an instance where the wholesale price charged

by the dominant firm to its downstream rivals is higher than the retail price it charges to its end-users)

147
Post Danmark II (n 9), para 59.
148
AKZO (n 37), para 72.
149
Guidance (n 25), paras 39-44.
150
Intel (n 38), paras 142-143.

41

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


is a probable source of anticompetitive effects.151 Conversely, a pricing practice that allows a rival to

cover the bulk of its costs is unlikely to have such effects.152 The case law on rebates hints at a similar

idea. The exclusionary potential of a scheme depends on the ‘criteria and rules’ for the award of the

rebate.153 Thus, rebates conditional upon exclusivity are more likely to cause harm than standardised

schemes based on the volume supplied (in the same way that retroactive rebates are more likely to

cause harm than incremental schemes). By the same token, an outright refusal to deal has more

exclusionary potential than dealing on less favourable terms and conditions.

Second, factors pertaining to the context in which the practice (or transaction) is implemented

shed light on its impact on rivals’ ability and incentive to compete. One of these factors is the degree

of market power enjoyed by the firm(s) involved. In this sense, the extent of the dominant position

has been frequently mentioned by the Court in Article 102 TFEU cases.154 A second factor is the

coverage of the practice, that is, the fraction of the market subject to it.155 Third, the features of the

relevant market and the nature of the product may also play a prominent role. For instance, the

existence of high barriers to entry characterised by economies of scale may have an impact on rivals’

ability and incentive to compete.156 The same can be said of network effects, which may exacerbate

the foreclosure effects of a practice.157 Where the dominant firm is vertically-integrated, the

indispensable nature of the product may be a factor.158 The regulatory context is another one.159

Where the analysis is retrospective in nature, actual evidence relating to rivals’ ability and

incentive to enter and/or remain on the market is relevant, as already explained above.

Anticompetitive effects would not exist, for instance, where the contemporary evolution of the market

151
TeliaSonera (n 9), para 73.
152
Post Danmark I (n 8), para 38.
153
Post Danmark II (n 9), para 29 and 32.
154
TeliaSonera (n 9), para 81; Post Danmark II (n 9), para 30; and Intel (n 38), para 139.
155
Delimitis (n 15), para 19; Case C-549/10 P Tomra Systems ASA and Others v Commission, EU:C:2012:221, paras 37-
49; Post Danmark II (n 9), para 46; Maxima Latvija (n 8), para 29; and Intel (n 38), para 139.
156
Post Danmark II (n 9), para 39.
157
Microsoft I (n 58), para 562.
158
Deutsche Telekom (n 39), para 255; and TeliaSonera (n 9), paras 69-70.
159
Post Danmark II (n 9), para 39, which makes a reference to the ‘statutory monopoly’ enjoyed by the dominant firm.

42

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


reveals that the practice has not precluded entry.160 The experience acquired over the year yields some

valuable conclusions about the impact of practices in the actual context of which they are a part. It

appears, to begin with, that a competitive advantage (even an unparalleled one) does not necessarily

limit firms’ ability and/or incentive to compete. In Microsoft I, for instance, the Commission noted

that the tying of Windows and Windows Media Player gave the latter product an unparalleled

advantage over rivals.161 In spite of this fact, and even though the remedy failed to work as expected,

the practice did not limit rivals’ ability and incentive to compete.162

Experience also shows that a competitive disadvantage and/or a decrease in terms of market

share (as evidenced, for instance, by the loss of some customers) do not necessarily impact negatively

on rivals’ ability and incentive to compete.163 In and of themselves, the case law shows, these factors

are insufficient to establish exclusionary effects. Decades of enforcement reveal that a competitive

disadvantage may in fact have a positive impact on rivals’ incentives to compete. This point is

acknowledged by the Commission in its Non-Horizontal Merger Guidelines.164 It may spur rivals to

develop counterstrategies or to improve the quality of their products to make up for the disadvantage.

Post Danmark I, in turn, provides a concrete illustration of how a firm may retain its ability and

incentive to compete even after experiencing a decrease in its market share: as observed above, the

dominant firm’s competitor managed to retain its distribution network and win back the two major

customers that were lost following the implementation of the practice. The analysis in Post Danmark

I was retrospective in nature. Where the analysis is prospective, evidence about the features and past

evolution of the market would also be a factor to consider in this regard.165

160
Case C-457/10 P AstraZeneca AB and AstraZeneca plc v Commission, EU:C:2012:770, paras 194-203.
161
Microsoft I (n 58), para 1038.
162
Ibid, paras 1003-1006.
163
See, by analogy, Post Danmark I (n 8), para 39 and Deutsche Telekom (n 39), para 250.
164
Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers (n 26), paras 39, 67 and 103.
165
See in particular British American Tobacco (n 54), John Deere (n 54) and Guidance (n 25), para 20.

43

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


Principle It is for the authority or
Case law
claimant to show why
Only the exclusion of equally departing from the principle
Intel, Post Danmark II
efficient firms is relevant is justified in casu

Relevant factors

Nature of the practice See the contrast between, e.g. Case law
incremental vs retroactive
The exclusionary potential rebates; and negative vs AKZO, TeliaSonera, Post
depends on the practice positive ‘margin squeezes’ Danmark II

Degree of market power Case law

The greater the market power, TeliaSonera, Post Danmark II,


the more likely the effects Intel

Coverage
Case law
The greater the coverage, the
Post Danmark II, Intel
more likely the effects

For instance, effects may be Case law


Other factors include the
more likely in presence of
features of the product and
network effects or large Microsoft I, TeliaSonera, Post
market, regulatory context
economies of scale Danmark II, Intel

Additional considerations

• Experience shows that a competitive advantage (even an unparalleled one) does not necessarily have a
negative impact on firms’ ability and/or incentive to compete (see e.g. Microsoft I, Microsoft/Skype)
• A decrease in market share does not necessarily reduce rivals’ ability and/or incentive to compete (see
e.g. TeliaSonera, Post Danmark I)

Fig. 5: The exclusion of a source of competitive pressure

6.4.3. Exploitation

Cases dealing with exploitative behaviour are relatively scarce. A question that these cases raise is

whether the analysis of exploitative effects differs from that undertaken under the two mechanisms

44

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


discussed above. This question is particularly relevant where the analysis concerns practices that have

as their object or effect the distortion of the conditions of competition on an upstream or downstream

market in which a dominant firm does not operate. The MEO judgment suggests that there are no

fundamental differences in the approach to the analysis of such distortions. As noted above, the Court

held in MEO that a competitive disadvantage does not amount, in and of itself, to a distortion of

competition within the meaning of Article 102(c) TFEU. Accordingly, the impact of the exploitative

practice on a customer’s ability and incentive to compete will have to be established in accordance

with the same criteria defined in cases involving exclusion.166

7. The probability of effects in the case law

7.1. Semantic issues: capability and likelihood

The applicable threshold of effects is not immediately obvious to infer from the case law. It requires

a careful reading, and comparison, of the relevant judgments. Part of the reason behind the absence

of clear and straightforward answers has to do with the vocabulary used when addressing the requisite

probability of anticompetitive effects. The Court has held that the actual or potential anticompetitive

effects must be ‘capable’ of occurring and/or ‘likely’ to occur.167 Other terms, such as ‘liable’ have

also been used.168 It would be reasonable to conclude from the case law, first, that ‘capability’ and

‘likelihood’ have, at least in some judgments, been used as synonymous; and, second, that these two

terms are suggestive of a single relevant threshold of effects. This is the point of view expressed by

AG Wahl in his Opinion in Intel.169

166
MEO (n 125), para 31.
167
See above n 9.
168
Murphy (n 44), para 140. See also Microsoft I (n 58), paras 560-564, where the GC addresses the point and, in
particular, whether the reference to the ‘risk’ of the elimination of all competition sets a threshold identical or similar to
that of likelihood.
169
Opinion of AG Wahl in Intel (n 9).

45

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


Even if this point of view were to be accepted, a number of difficulties remain. The single

most important one is that, while the two terms have been used as synonymous, they convey different

meanings. As a result, the requisite threshold of effects would vary depending on the way they are

interpreted. On the one hand, the literal meaning of the words ‘capable’ and ‘capability’ is indicative

of a low threshold of effects,170 which can be equated with plausibility. Practices and transactions

(including the examples mentioned above, such as tying, exclusive dealing or horizontal and non-

horizontal mergers) attract the attention of competition authorities and give rise to litigation precisely

because they are capable of having anticompetitive effects (or, if one prefers, because it is typically

plausible that they will have a negative impact on competition). If this interpretation were accepted,

the threshold of effects would be presumptively met as soon as it is established that the practice or

transaction has been implemented. Absent other factors pertaining to the economic and legal context,

anticompetitive effects would be deemed to follow, logically and inevitably, from the very

implementation of the practice.

The words ‘likely’ and ‘likelihood’, in turn, are indicative of a higher threshold. The literal

meaning of the words is suggestive of an event that will probably happen or is expected to happen.171

In her Opinion in Post Danmark II, AG Kokott suggested that the applicable threshold is one of

likelihood. In the Advocate General’s view, anticompetitive effects would be established when it is

‘more likely than not’ that they will be manifested.172 AG Kokott’s operational definition of the

concept is not only in line with its plain meaning, but also with the meaning attached to it in Section

2.4. above. This interpretation would, as already mentioned, place the threshold of probability right

170
The Oxford English Dictionary defines ‘capable’ – in its fifth entry – as ‘[h]aving the needful capacity, power, or
fitness for (some specified purpose or activity)’. The Cambridge Dictionary defines that a person is ‘capable’ of something
when she has ‘the ability or qualities to be able to do something’.
171
The Oxford English Dictionary defines ‘likely’ as ‘having a high chance of occurring; probable’. The Cambridge
Dictionary, along the same lines, defines ‘likely’ as ‘expected’ and ‘probably true’.
172
Case C-23/14 Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet, EU:C:2015:343, para 82: ‘According to settled case-law, it is
necessary but also sufficient that the rebates in question can produce an exclusionary effect. This is the case where, on
the basis of an overall assessment of all the relevant circumstances of the individual case, the presence of the exclusionary
effect appears more likely than its absence’. In support of her interpretation of the case law, AG Kokott refers to Post
Danmark I (n 8), paras 42 and 44.

46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


above 50%. At this level, effects would no longer follow presumptively from the implementation of

the practice. For the same reason, it would be easier for the firm(s) involved in the practice or

transaction to rebut a finding of anticompetitive effects.

7.2. The law as applied: plausibility, likelihood and certainty

If one pays attention to the thresholds actually applied by the Court, it becomes possible to discern

the relevant threshold that is relevant for each of the legal tests. When prima facie unlawful practices

are at stake, the applicable threshold is one of plausibility. In other words, it is only in a narrow set

of circumstances that the firm(s) involved are able to rebut the presumption that the behaviour is

capable of having anticompetitive effects. Second, a threshold of likelihood, as defined by AG Kokott

in Post Danmark II, is relevant to evaluate the impact of practices subject to a ‘standard effects’

analysis, as well as concentrations within the meaning of Regulation 139/2004. Finally, the threshold

of certainty, or quasi-certainty appears to be the applicable one where the ‘enhanced effects’ test

defines the conditions against which the legality of conduct is assessed.

7.2.1. A plausibility threshold applies to prima facie unlawful conduct

An overview of the case law reveals that conduct that is prima facie unlawful irrespective of its

effects, such as cartel-like behaviour, is prohibited even when it is not particularly likely to have a

negative impact on competition. In that sense, one can rule out that a threshold of likelihood is

relevant in relation to these practices. It is sufficient to show that harm is a plausible outcome. In T-

Mobile, the referring national court expressed the view that the behaviour at stake in the case – a

single meeting where the reduction of remunerations paid to dealers was discussed among rivals –

could not qualify as an object infringement due to the fact that it was unlikely to have anticompetitive

47

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


effects. More precisely, the referring court was of the view that the ‘by object’ category would be

appropriate ‘where the actual detrimental effects are unmistakable and will occur irrespective of the

characteristic features of the relevant market’.173

The Court dismissed this view and held that the threshold suggested by the national court

(which hinted at certainty or quasi-certainty) is not the applicable one in relation to ‘by object’

conduct. These practices ‘must simply be capable in an individual case, having regard to the specific

legal and economic context’, of having anticompetitive effects.174 In T-Mobile, the Court used the

term ‘capable’ in a manner consistent with its literal meaning, which is consistent, in turn, with a

threshold of plausibility. Bananas confirmed that the requisite threshold of effects would be met in a

‘by object’ case where employees in an industry have bilateral discussions about pre-pricing

information.175 In Toshiba, it sided with the GC and concluded that a cartel-like arrangement

involving a group of potential competitors was capable of having restrictive effects insofar as barriers

to entry were not found to be insurmountable in its economic and legal context.176

Article 102 TFEU case law leads to similar conclusions. In AKZO, the Court held that pricing

below cost is capable of leading to the exclusion of equally efficient competitors.177 As noted in Post

Danmark I, however, below-cost pricing is not necessarily likely to have anticompetitive effects – in

particular where rivals would be able to cover the bulk of their costs. However, where the practice is

an element of a strategy aimed at excluding rivals, it will be deemed abusive even when exclusion is

no more than plausible.178 The case law on rebates leads to similar conclusions. Some rebate schemes

are prima facie abusive irrespective of their effects.179 Underpinning the legal status of these practices

is the idea that they can, or ‘tend to’, restrict competition.180 Finally, tying is also prima facie

173
T-Mobile (n 2), para 20.
174
Ibid, para 31.
175
Bananas (n 2), paras 111-135.
176
Toshiba (n 80), paras 40-48.
177
AKZO (n 37), para 72.
178
Ibid.
179
See above n 38.
180
Hoffmann-La Roche (n 38), para 90.

48

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


prohibited.181 As a result, it is sufficient for a prohibition to be grounded on the conclusion that

anticompetitive effects are at least plausible.182

The case law also gives an idea of what firms would need to show to rebut the presumption

that prima facie unlawful conduct is a plausible source of anticompetitive effects. First, and in line

with Toshiba and Generics, it would be possible for them to show that the behaviour is incapable of

having an impact on competition insofar as there are ‘insurmountable barriers to entry’.183 In such

circumstances, any actual or potential effect would not be attributable to the practice, but to the

regulatory context of which it is a part. Second, it would be possible for firms to argue that the

behaviour is objectively necessary to achieve a pro-competitive aim. They could show, for instance,

that an exclusive distribution agreement limiting both active and passive sales is incapable of having

anticompetitive effects insofar as, in its absence, market entry by the supplier would not occur.184 In

other words, the parties may be able to provide evidence to the effect that the practice can only

produce pro-competitive gains.185 Finally, Intel clarified that it is possible for a dominant firm to

provide evidence pertaining to the nature of the practice, its extent and the features of the relevant

market.186 The Court suggested that a dominant firm may be in a position to show that the exclusion

of an equally efficient competitor is implausible given the nature and scope of the practice in its

economic and legal context. Intel expressly refers to the ‘as efficient competitor’ test as a tool in this

regard. It is reasonable to infer from the judgment that, more generally, a firm would be able to

provide evidence showing that the practice does not deny rivals a minimum efficient scale.187

181
See above n 36.
182
See in this sense Microsoft I (n 58), para 1054.
183
Generics (n 32), para 45.
184
Guidelines on vertical restraints (n 24), para 61, mentioned above.
185
See also, in this same vein, Budapest Bank (n 42), paras 82-83.
186
Intel (n 38), paras 138-142.
187
This conclusion seems consistent with Tomra (n 155). In the latter, the Court held – at para 46, an in line with Intel (n
38), para 137 – that the Commission would not need to apply the ‘minimum viable scale’ test to establish that a loyalty
rebate scheme amounts to an abuse. Intel clarifies that, in spite of the legal status of the practice as prima facie unlawful,
a dominant firm may provide evidence showing that the practice is incapable of excluding equally efficient rivals.

49

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


7.2.2. A threshold of likelihood applies to practices and transactions subject to a ‘standard

effects’ analysis

A threshold of likelihood applies to practices and transactions subject to a ‘standard effects’ test,

which includes mergers examined in accordance with Regulation 139/2004. Post Danmark II comes

across as the most obvious starting point, not only because it illustrates the idea effectively, but

because it is the background against which AG Kokott formalised the requisite threshold of

likelihood. An overview of the facts in Post Danmark II unambiguously shows that the rebate scheme

at stake was, in and of itself, a plausible means to exclude competition. The scheme had indeed been

implemented by an incumbent in a partially liberalised industry with a very large market share; in

addition, the rebates were retroactive, and the relevant reference period was of one year.188 In spite

of these considerations, the Court held that it was necessary to consider the likely impact of the

practice in light of a number of factors pertaining to the relevant economic and legal context. Other

Article 102 TFEU cases where the similar threshold applied include Post Danmark I, Deutsche

Telekom, TeliaSonera and MEO, all discussed above.

In the context of Article 101 TFEU, it seems clear that, once an agreement is found not to be

restrictive by object, showing that anticompetitive effects are plausible (or that there are no

‘insurmountable barriers to competition’) is not enough. In such circumstances, it would be necessary

to establish the likely effect of the practice. Suffice it to come back to Delimitis (and the rulings that

embraced its approach, such as Maxima Latvija) to illustrate the point. The practice at stake in that

case – exclusive dealing – is known to be at least a plausible source of anticompetitive effects. A

network of exclusivity agreements, alone or in combination with others, can lead to the exclusion of

equally efficient suppliers. However, the Court devised a test requiring an authority or claimant to

188
Post Danmark II (n 9), paras 30-46.

50

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


show, in light of an in-depth assessment informed by the features of the market, how the foreclosure

of new entrants would likely result from their implementation in a given economic and legal context.

This same conclusion follows, from an analysis of the way mergers are scrutinised in the EU

regime. That the applicable threshold is one of likelihood was already apparent from Kali & Salz, in

which the Court concluded that the Commission had failed to establish, to the requisite legal standard,

that the transaction was likely to lead to the strengthening of a collective dominant position.189 The

authority had identified several indicators suggesting that such an outcome was at least plausible in

the post-merger scenario. However, the Court found that the joint market share of the parties, or that

the structural links between them, did not point conclusively to the strengthening of a collective

dominant position.190 Other factors, such as the decline in the demand for the product concerned by

the transaction, suggested that an anticompetitive outcome was unlikely.191

The threshold of likelihood was put to the test – and confirmed – when the GC evaluated the

Commission decisions in GE/Honeywell192 and Tetra Laval.193 In the two cases, it did not dispute the

authority’s conclusion that the conglomerate effects of the transactions could lead to the extension of

a dominant position from one market to a neighbouring one. In the economic and legal context of

which the transactions were a part, such an outcome was found to be at least plausible.194 However,

the GC concluded that it was not a likely one. For that reason, it concluded that the Commission had

erred in law in the two cases. In GE/Honeywell, for instance, the GC took the view that the strategy

through which the alleged conglomerate effects would be manifested went against the ‘modus

operandi’ of the sector.195 Thus, an ‘additional commercial effort’ would be required from the merged

entity for exclusion to become a reality.196

189
Kali & Salz (n 77), para 170.
190
Ibid, paras 226-230.
191
Ibid, para 238.
192
Case T-210/01 General Electric Company v Commission, EU:T:2005:456.
193
Case T-5/02 Tetra Laval (n 117).
194
General Electric (n 192), para 404; and Case T-5/02 Tetra Laval (n 117), paras 192-199.
195
General Electric (n 192), para 415.
196
General Electric (n 192), para 423.

51

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


7.2.3. A threshold of certainty (or quasi-certainty) applies to conduct subject to a ‘enhanced

effects’ test

As explained above, a refusal to deal within the meaning of Bronner is abusive if it can be shown to

relate to an input or platform that is indispensable and, in addition, that it would lead to the elimination

of ‘all competition’ on the relevant adjacent market.197 An input or platform is indispensable,

according to the case law, where there are no ‘alternative solutions’ to enter the relevant adjacent

market and where, in addition, duplicating it would be ‘impossible or unreasonably difficult’. These

conditions, which are notoriously demanding in practice, amount in effect to setting a threshold of

certainty for third parties requesting access to the said input or platform. In addition, the condition

that the refusal eliminate ‘all competition’ on the adjacent market implies that no alternative input or

platform is already in place.

8. Analysis and discussion

8.1. Questions addressed in the case law

8.1.1. The notion of anticompetitive effects has clear boundaries

The analysis above suggests that it is possible to discern, from the case law, a specific meaning of the

notion of anticompetitive effects. Starting with competition and the counterfactual, the Court made it

clear, from the outset, that competition comprises both its inter-brand and intra-brand dimensions. In

addition, the case law is consistent in taking into account both the ex ante and the ex post aspects of

the counterfactual. In this sense, the Court does not simply assume that the pro-competitive gains

197
See above n 48.

52

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


resulting from a given practice would have existed independently of any restraints that seemingly

amount, from an ex post perspective, to a restriction. What is more, the system provides for

mechanisms to take the counterfactual into consideration. Not only is it possible for firms to argue

that any ex post restraints are inextricably linked to the pro-competitive aspects of the practice and

thus do not have anticompetitive effects; some legal tests are specifically crafted to incorporate the

ex ante dimension of the counterfactual. The choices made by the Court in this regard are captured in

Figure 6.
Inter- and intra- brand

Inter- and intra-brand

Ex ante and ex post


Dimensions of competition

Inter-brand only

Ex post only Ex ante and ex post +

Dimensions of the counterfactual

Fig. 6: The dimensions of competition and the counterfactual in the case law

It is also possible to discern, from the case law, what effects are. The probability threshold,

which appears to vary depending on the applicable legal test, can also be identified. The different

combinations around two variables are depicted together in Figures 7, 8 and 9. First, only appreciable

effects are relevant in EU competition law. Second, effects amount to more than a mere competitive

disadvantage or a limitation of a firm’s freedom of action but (save a limited exception) to less than

53

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


consumer harm. In addition, it is clear that – at least as a matter of principle – the departure of

inefficient firms is understood to be the natural consequence of the operation of the competitive

process. Against this background, it would appear that effects can be defined as those that impact on

the ability and/or incentive of one or more firms to compete, and this to such an extent that

competitive constraints are reduced as a result.

One can identify three probability thresholds, each corresponding to a particular legal test. To

begin with, a threshold of plausibility applies to conduct that is prima facie unlawful irrespective of

its impact on competition (including ‘by object’ conduct under Article 101(1) TFEU). Second, when

practices and transactions subject to a ‘standard effects’ test are at stake, it is necessary to show that

the practice is ‘more likely than not’ to restrict competition (that is, a threshold of likelihood). Finally,

certainty, or quasi-certainty, is required when the impact of practices subject to an ‘enhanced effects’

test (both under the Bronner and the Magill doctrines) is at stake. The indispensability and the

‘elimination of all competition’ conditions inevitably amount to such a threshold.

Certainty

Likelihood

Plausibility Prima facie


- unlawful conduct

Freedom of Market As efficient Consumer


+
action* structure competitor welfare

Fig. 7: Anticompetitive effects and prima facie unlawful conduct (where effects are presumed)
* (or competitive disadvantage)

54

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


Certainty

‘Standard
Likelihood effects’ test

Capability
-

Freedom of Market As efficient Consumer


+
action* structure competitor welfare

Fig. 8: Anticompetitive effects under the ‘standard effects’ analysis’

‘Enhanced ‘Enhanced
Certainty
effects’ test effects’ test
(Bronner) (Magill)

Likelihood

Capability
-

Freedom of Market As efficient Consumer


+
action* structure competitor welfare

Fig. 9: Anticompetitive effects under the ‘enhanced effects’ analysis

55

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


8.1.2. The approach to the analysis of effects is the same across provisions

A corollary to the conclusions above is that the analysis of effects is the same across the board. When

the ‘standard effects’ test is applicable, the assessment does not seem to vary depending on whether

Article 101 TFEU, 102 TFEU or Regulation 139/2004 is at stake. This conclusion would not have

been obvious to draw during the formative years of the discipline. In particular, it has not always been

clear whether evidence of anticompetitive effects is required to establish an abuse of a dominant

position and whether, if indeed required, the assessment was comparable to that undertaken in the

context of Article 101 TFEU and merger control. The evolution of the case law, in particular

following Deutsche Telekom, TeliaSonera, Post Danmark I and II and Intel, seems to have dissipated

any doubts in this respect. In these judgments, the Court clarified that the practices at stake were only

caught by Article 102 TFEU insofar as they were likely to have anticompetitive effects (other

practices, such as pricing below average variable costs, remain prima facie unlawful). Crucially, the

Court’s assessment is consistent with the framework captured in Figure 8.

From a normative standpoint, the application of a single approach, across the board, to the

analysis of effects seems reasonable and, arguably, inevitable. This is so, first and foremost, because

practices and transactions implemented by a dominant firm can be examined under all provisions

considered. Both Articles 101 and 102 TFEU can simultaneously apply to the same practice, as cases

like Generics and Delimitis/Intel show. Similarly, the likely impact of a leveraging strategy may be

examined under either under Articles 101 or 102 TFEU or, if it results from a conglomerate merger,

under Article 2 of Regulation 139/2004. Just to mention a clear example, similar tying concerns were

considered in Microsoft I (an Article 102 TFEU case) and Microsoft/Skype (a merger case).198 Insofar

as the underlying economic and legal context is essentially the same, it is not obvious to see what

198
Microsoft/Skype (Case COMP/M.6281) Commission Decision of 7 October 2011. See also Case T-79/12 Cisco
Systems, Inc. and Messagenet SpA v Commission, EU:T:2013:635.

56

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


would justify attaching a different meaning to the notion of effects depending on the applicable

provision.

8.2. Open questions

8.2.1. The definition of appreciability

Even though it is clear from the case law that effects must be appreciable, the EU courts have not had

the occasion to clarify how to assess the question on a case-by-case basis. On the one hand, it is clear

from Völk and Expedia that, where the market power of the parties is insignificant, the appreciability

threshold is not met. On the other hand (and as a corollary to the first point), the effects of a practice

implemented by a firm that holds a dominant position (that is, a substantial degree of market power)

will, when established, be appreciable. The difficulty in practice has to do with the identification of

the point at which the degree of market power enjoyed by the firm(s) is significant enough to meet

the appreciability threshold (that is, the boundary between de minimis and appreciable effects). This

practical difficulty has two dimensions. One dimension relates to the problems that are inherent in

establishing market power in the first place. It is an inquiry that involves considering a broad range

of factors, and that is typically assisted by using proxies, in particular market shares. A second

dimension is the identification of the appropriate degree of market power.

In order to address these difficulties, the system relies, at present, upon the various proxies

devised over the years, both in the context of Article 101 TFEU and merger control. At best, these

proxies give an idea of the approximate point at which the degree of market power falls below the

threshold. In other words, these proxies do little more than flesh out, in a more precise way, the

principles defined in Völk. Where the practice or transaction is of a horizontal nature, questions about

appreciability (or rather, its absence) start where the joint market share is below 25%, which is the

57

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


threshold defined in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines.199 Where the practice or transaction is of a

non-horizontal nature, the threshold is set at 30%.200 As can be seen in Figure 10, these instruments

do little more than narrow down, in a tentative way, the ‘grey area’ between Völk and dominance.

The narrowing of this gap is tentative in the sense that nothing prevents a finding of appreciability

below the threshold, but also in the sense that most proxies are derived from a series of soft law

instruments issued by the Commission.

The difficulty that comes with the assessment of appreciability became apparent in CK

Telecoms. This is the first merger case in which the EU courts are confronted with unilateral effects

in the absence of dominance. As explained above, effects in such circumstances are to be established

by reference to factors such as market shares and the closeness of competition between the parties. In

addition, quantitative instruments may be used as a screen to filter out unproblematic

concentrations.201 It is apparent throughout the GC judgment in the case that it may not be easy to

define ex ante the point at which the impediment to effective competition becomes ‘significant’ (and

thus appreciable). It is a context-dependent exercise that requires an evaluation of the degree of

competition between the merging parties prior to the transaction and the features of the relevant

market. In this sense, CK Telecoms suggests that any guidance may only slowly emerge from a

succession of cases addressing the ‘grey area’ between de minimis conduct and transactions, on the

one hand, and those giving rise to dominance, on the other.

‘Grey area’

De minimis Dominance

Fig. 10: The definition of appreciability

199
See for instance Hutchison 3G Austria/Orange Austria (Case COMP/M.6497) Commission Decision of 12 December
2012, in particular paras 90-100.
200
Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers (n 26), para 25; and Guidelines on vertical restraints (n 24).
201
CK Telecoms (n 101), paras 253-259.

58

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


8.2.2. The relative lack of guidance about the assessment of (exclusionary) effects

While the case law gives a sufficiently precise idea of what anticompetitive effects are (as Figures 7,

8 and 9 sought to capture), it remains relatively scant on examples setting out how the ‘standard

effects’ test is to be conducted in practice. This reality leaves several questions unanswered. The

absence of concrete illustrations of the implementation of the applicable framework becomes

particularly apparent when exclusion and exploitation are the mechanisms through which effects are

manifested. To focus on the former, it is true that the Court has already identified a number of factors

to consider in the assessment of anticompetitive effects resulting from exclusion and which comprise,

in particular, the extent of the market power enjoyed, the coverage of the practice, the economic

features of the relevant market and the nature of the product.

However, the Court has not been given sufficient chances to explain, in full, how these factors

are put into operation. As is true of appreciability, the case law is useful to identify the instances in

which anticompetitive effects are in principle implausible, on the one hand, and when they are

particularly likely, on the other. At one end of the spectrum, the Court has confirmed that above-cost

prices are in principle incapable of excluding equally efficient competitors. The same can be said of

prices that would allow rivals to cover the bulk of their costs. The ‘as efficient competitor’ test is an

expression of this same idea. At the other end of the spectrum, the Court has confirmed – in relation

to ‘margin squeeze’ conduct – that anticompetitive effects are at least likely where the relevant input

is indispensable, or where the ‘margin squeeze’ is negative.

Beyond these filters, which are useful to identify instances that safely lie at the two ends of

the spectrum of liability, the case law only sheds limited light on how to establish the likely

anticompetitive effects of a practice or transaction. For instance, while the coverage of the practice is

a relevant (and sometimes a fundamental) factor, there is no indication of the level below which the

59

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


ability and incentive of rivals to compete would be unlikely to be affected. At most, Post Danmark I

suggests that, where there is contemporary evidence showing that rivals were able to remain on the

market in spite of the anticompetitive potential of a practice, this fact can be sufficient to rule out a

finding of anticompetitive effects.

8.2.3. Capability, likelihood, certainty: between semantic and substantive issues

As explained above, there appears to be a gap between the probability thresholds as declared by the

Court and as actually applied by it. The law as declared may not give a clear idea of the requisite level

of probability – the words ‘capable’ and ‘likely’, sometimes used indistinctly, convey different

meanings. The law as applied, on the other hand, gives a more precise idea in this regard. The gap

between the law as declared and the law as applied is a potential source of legal uncertainty, which

may be exploited by stakeholders. It may also be a source of inconsistencies if the confusion trickles

down into the law as applied. Inconsistencies may emerge within provisions – which would arise, for

instance, if both plausibility and likelihood apply to potentially abusive practices subject to a

‘standard effects’ test – and across provisions – which would arise, for instance, if the assessment of

tying practices were assessed differently under Article 102 TFEU, on the one hand; and merger

control, on the other.

It is submitted that the risk of uncertainty and inconsistency could be addressed by bringing

in line the law as declared and the law as applied. The current gap between the two can be explained

by the fact that it has not always been clear which practices were deemed prima facie unlawful

irrespective of their effects and which practices were subject to a ‘standard effects’ analysis. As the

law stands, and following the evolution of the past two decades, it is now possible to tell one group

of practices apart from the other. For the same reason, it would come across as reasonable to define

more clearly and explicitly the respective scopes of the ‘capability’ and ‘likelihood’ thresholds, on

60

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


the one hand, and to use the vocabulary in a consistent way, on the other. The threshold of ‘capability’

seems appropriate, both in form and substance, for behaviour that is prima facie unlawful irrespective

of its effects; ‘likelihood’, in turn, for practices and transactions subject to a ‘standard effects’ test.

8.3. Areas of friction in practice

The open questions described above, together with the relative absence of detail regarding certain

aspects of the assessment, can be expected to give rise to frictions, in the sense that disagreements

about the meaning and/or operation of some concepts are likely to arise before courts and authorities.

One can think of six main areas of friction in practice. The first is the tendency to conflate

appreciability and effects. The second concerns the assessment of effects, and more precisely what

the evaluation entails in practice. Third (and in part as a result of the vocabulary used in the case law),

questions about the role and relevance of the counterfactual in practice are likely to emerge. The

fourth relates to the application of the application of the principle whereby only the exclusion of

equally efficient firms is relevant in the analysis. Fifth, there is a tendency to conflate the legal test

and the standard of proof. Finally, the time dimension and the probability threshold tend to be

confused.

8.3.1. The conflation of appreciability and effects

As explained above, the definition of effects and the question of whether such effects are appreciable

are different questions. The former issue involves making a choice along the continuum that ranges

from a competitive disadvantage (or a limitation of firms’ freedom of action) to harm to consumers.

The second question, in turn, relates to the market power enjoyed by the firm(s) involved in a practice

or transaction. Accordingly, market power can exist without effects. It is not necessarily the case that

61

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


every practice or transaction implemented by a firm with significant market power will have a

restrictive impact on competition. This is, after all, what the Court has consistently held since

Deutsche Telekom. Where effects are an element of the legal test, an actual or potential impact on

competition must be established (and not simply inferred from the market power enjoyed by the firm).

It is not difficult to see, however, why and how the two concepts can be conflated in practice.

The point is easily illustrated by reference to the case law on rebates and exclusivity under Article

102 TFEU. As explained by the Court in Post Danmark II and Intel, the market coverage of the

practice is one of the key factors when evaluating whether such practices have actual or potential

effects. Where the coverage is limited, it is reasonable to expect firms to argue that their schemes are

incapable or unlikely to have a restrictive impact on competition. In such circumstances, the ability

and incentive of equally efficient rivals to enter or remain on the market may be unaffected. However,

an authority or claimant may attempt to counterargue (conflating appreciability and effects in the

process) that there is no appreciability threshold in the context of Article 102 TFEU and therefore

arguments about the limited coverage of the practice are irrelevant.

8.3.2. The tendency to equate every competitive disadvantage with an anticompetitive effect

Experience shows that a competitive advantage – even an unparalleled one – does not necessarily

lead to anticompetitive effects. However, an analysis of the administrative practice suggests that

stakeholders tend to equate the former and the latter. In particular, evidence that rivals are placed at

a disadvantage tends to be used as conclusive proof that a practice has exclusionary effects. This idea

is aptly illustrated in light of the analysis conducted by the Commission in Google Shopping. The

assessment in the decision revolves around the finding that the practice inflicted an competitive

disadvantage on rivals (it decreased traffic from Google’s general search results pages to rivals, and

62

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


increased traffic to Google’s own services202), which cannot be fully offset by other means of

obtaining traffic.203 In this sense, the scenario was not fundamentally different from that at stake in

Microsoft I and Microsoft/Skype. The Android decision also revolves around a similar theme and

displays the same tendency to equate an unparalleled advantage with anticompetitive effects.204

An unparalleled competitive advantage suggests, at most, that the restrictive impact of the

practice is plausible. In and of itself, it is insufficient to conclude that anticompetitive effects are

likely. As discussed above, the experience of cases like Microsoft I (Media Player) and

Microsoft/Skype reveals that even an advantage that rivals cannot match may fail to have a negative

impact on rivals’ ability and incentive to compete. Competitors may be able to exploit their own

strengths, develop counterstrategies or improve their products in response to the practice. In other

words, an unparalleled advantage may spur rivalry (rather than reduce it) and, insofar as it does, firms’

incentives to invest and innovate. In Post Danmark I, for instance, the dominant firm enjoyed unique

advantages as the incumbent operator in a partially liberalised industry. 205 As mentioned above, its

main rival was able to gain back the customers initially lost as a result of the practice.206

8.3.3. The role and assessment of the counterfactual

As explained above, the case law considers both the ex ante and ex post dimensions of the

counterfactual. In practice, however, the ex ante dimension, which accounts for firms’ incentives to

invest and innovate, may be downplayed or disregarded. This is so because ex post restraints are

observable whereas ex ante gains are typically assumed to exist. In other words, the pro-competitive

effects of a practice a practice tend to be taken as a given, without considering that they may be

202
Google Shopping (n 12), paras 452-501.
203
Ibid, paras 542-588.
204
Google Android (Case AT.40099) Commission Decision of 18 July 2018, in particular paras 896-963.
205
Post Danmark I (n 8), paras 3-4.
206
Post Danmark I (n 8), para 39.

63

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


inextricably linked to the observable ex post conduct (and thus that they may not have existed in the

absence of the latter). This tendency is more likely to be displayed where the ex ante dimension is not

enshrined in the legal test – that is, where the practice is deemed prima facie unlawful or where it is

subject to a ‘standard effects’ test. In such circumstances, claimants and authorities, on the one hand,

and defendants, on the other, can be expected to disagree about whether the pro-competitive gains

resulting from the practice would have existed in their absence.

Just to mention an example, frictions might arise about whether an agreement has, as its

object, the restriction of competition. Such agreements are prima facie prohibited irrespective of their

effects. However, the evaluation of the object of the agreement cannot disregard the ex ante dimension

of competition, as explained above. Accordingly, one can expect disagreements to emerge around

whether the practice improves the conditions of competition that would otherwise have existed (and

is therefore not prima facie unlawful). Generics and Budapest Bank make it clear beyond doubt that

defendants in a case can challenge, in light of the counterfactual, claims that an agreement has, as its

object, the restriction of competition. In the coming years, frictions can be expected to arise around

whether such claims meet the requisite legal standard.

8.3.4. Anticompetitive effects and equally efficient firms

As already discussed at length, EU competition law is only concerned with firms that are as efficient

as the firms involved in a practice or transaction – at least so as a matter of principle. The principle

has two main implications, also addressed above. First, a firm’s departure from the relevant market

would not be attributable to a practice or transaction (that is, the requisite causal link would not exist)

if it is the consequence of the firm’s inability to prove attractive with consumers. Second, such an

outcome would be a natural manifestation of competition on the merits and would thus not amount

64

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


to anticompetitive effects. The fact that above-cost prices are prima facie lawful and the ‘as efficient

competitor’ test is used as a filter in rebate cases follow logically from the above.

The practical difficulty that emerges in relation to this principle has to do with its practical

implementation. Filters such as the ‘as efficient competitor’ test are particularly suited for instances

where the price is the relevant parameter of competition. In such instances, evaluating whether an

equally efficient firm would be able to withstand competition is relatively straightforward. The

assessment is likely to be more complex where the practice does not involve prices directly and/or

obviously (suffice it to think of exclusive dealing, tying or an outright refusal to deal). It may also be

more complex where price is not the relevant (or not the most relevant) parameter of competition at

stake. The fact that the filters designed by the Court do not seem relevant or immediately applicable

in such instances does not mean that the fundamental underlying principle, whereby only competition

from equally efficient firms is relevant in the system, does not apply.

Even though the difficulty of implementing the principle is not a reason to depart from it, one

can expect frictions to arise in practice. For instance, a firm may argue – in line with the logic

underpinning the case law – that there is no causal link between a practice and its actual potential

effects, since the potential or likely exclusion of rivals would be attributable to the latter’s inability

to offer attractive goods or services, not to its own conduct. In the same vein, a firm may claim that

anticompetitive effects are implausible (and thus unlikely) insofar as the contentious behaviour is

incapable of denying rivals a minimum efficient scale. On the other hand (and this is the reason why

frictions might arise), the authority (or claimant) may retort that such considerations are irrelevant in

the context of the case, or that they are incapable of calling into question a finding of anticompetitive

effects.

65

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


8.3.5. The confusion between the legal test and the standard of proof

It has become apparent in the past two decades that there is a tendency to conflate the applicable legal

test, discussed in this paper, and the standard of proof.207 Commentators may occasionally fail to

distinguish between the two; or they may refer to one when the substance of the discussion refers to

the other. This confusion is primarily due to the fact that that the two concepts tend to be expressed

in probabilistic terms. This is true, as explained above, of the threshold of anticompetitive effects.

The Court routinely refers to the ‘likely’ or ‘probable’ impact of a practice or transaction. The various

standards of proof are sometimes – at least so in some legal traditions – presented as encapsulating

different probability thresholds (suffice it to think of the expressions ‘balance of probabilities’ and

proof ‘beyond reasonable doubt’).208 In addition, the two questions may arise in the context of the

same case. A challenge against a decision, for instance, may relate both to the appropriate legal test

and about whether the facts have been established to the requisite legal standard.

8.3.6. The confusion between actual effects and the certainty of effects

The concept of actual effects may be interpreted in more ways than one. As explained above, the

Court has consistently used it in contrast with that of potential effect. In this context, it means that the

retrospective analysis of the impact of a practice on competition must consider the actual context in

which it was implemented as well as the contemporary evolution of the market. For instance, the

analysis of actual effects may take into consideration, as in Post Danmark I, that rivals did not lose

their ability and incentive to compete and were in fact able to gain back their main customers. In

practice, however, stakeholders may conflate the time dimension with the probability threshold. More

207
Kalintiri (n 43) 72.
208
For a discussion, see Fernando Castillo de la Torre and Eric Gippini Fournier, Evidence, Proof and Judicial Review in
EU Competition Law (Edward Elgar 2017), 34-36.

66

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


precisely, there may be a tendency to assume that actual effects are only established where the

expected harm to competition (collusion, exclusion or exploitation) has been fully manifested.

According to this view, anticompetitive effects would not be established unless the retrospective

analysis reveals that rivals have departed from the market.

As can be seen, stakeholders may assume that actual effects are synonymous with a certainty

of effects. This tendency may be displayed both by authorities (or claimants) and by defendants in

competition law disputes. On the one hand, defendants may be naturally inclined to equate the time

dimension with the probability threshold so as to escape liability. As suggested above, claims that

rivals were not excluded during the relevant period, or that one or several parameters of competition

were not affected, can be expected from firms facing or challenging a finding of infringement. On the

other hand, authorities and claimants may display a tendency to dismiss any contemporary evidence

contradicting their theory of harm. In this sense, they may argue that conduct may infringe

competition law even when it fails to fully display its impact on competition and, similarly, that

competition law considers both actual and potential effects. The Krka judgment, discussed above,

provides an example in this sense.

9. Conclusions

The impetus behind this article was to study the notion of anticompetitive effects. It does so by

structuring the case law around a framework that considers the relevant variables. The exercise, which

brings together several strands of the case law across all provisions, shows that it is possible to attach

a concrete and consistent meaning to the notion. Some central questions, including the role and

operation of the counterfactual and the threshold of effects have been answered by the Court. In

addition, it has long been clear that anticompetitive effects amount to more than a mere competitive

disadvantage and/or a limitation of a firm’s freedom of action. Something more, namely a reduction

67

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


of competitive pressure resulting from a negative impact on equally efficient firms’ ability and/or

incentive to compete, is required.

At the same time, several open questions remain. Since the number of cases in which the EU

courts have engaged in an in-depth evaluation of the impact or transaction is relatively limited, it is

also likely that additional frictions around the meaning and boundaries of the notion of

anticompetitive effects will emerge. In particular, there is a consistent tendency on the part of

stakeholders to conflate the issue of appreciability with the meaning of effects, to equate every

competitive disadvantage with an anticompetitive effect and to downplay the role of the

counterfactual in the analysis. These same tendencies, observed over the years, are likely to be

displayed before the EU courts. Some pending cases will provide an opportunity to shed additional

light on a notion that is central to the EU competition law system.

68

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


The case law considers both
Time dimension
actual (retrospective analysis)
and potential effects
Actual and/or potential effects
(prospective analysis)

Dimensions of competition
Both the inter-brand and
intra-brand dimensions of
Inter-brand and intra-brand
competition are relevant
competition

Counterfactual Competition means


The counterfactual has an ex
‘competition that would have
ante and an ex post
Benchmark against which existed in the absence of the
dimension
effects are assessed practice or transaction’

The ability and/or incentive


to compete is affected to such
Meaning of effects
an extent that competitive
pressure is reduced

Threshold of effects A threshold of plausibility


A threshold of likelihood
applies to prima facie
applies to conduct subject to
unlawful conduct (‘by
Probability threshold of effects a ‘standard effects’ test
object’)

Fig. 11: The notion of anticompetitive effects – relevant variables

Anticompetitive effects are However, firms may rebut the It is sufficient for firms to
presumed in relation to prima presumption that the practice provide ‘serious indicia’
facie unlawful (‘by object’) is capable of having casting doubts on the
conduct anticompetitive effects capability of effects

The presumption may be


rebutted in three ways

The restriction of competition


would be attributable to the The practice is objectively Anticompetitive effects are
regulatory context, not the necessary to attain a pro- implausible in the relevant
practice competitive aim economic and legal context

Fig. 12: Anticompetitive effects and prima facie unlawful (‘by object’) conduct

69

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407


Identify the mechanism
through which effects would
be manifested: collusion,
exclusion or exploitation

Identify the dimension of


competition affected by the
practice*: inter-brand or intra-
brand

No effects where the practice No effects where there is no


Define the counterfactual:
creates the very competition causal link between the
conditions of competition in
it is said to restrict (objective practice and the effects (no
the absence of the practice
necessity) attributability)

Question 1: will equally


Establish the likely Question 2: will the practice
efficient firms’ ability and/or
anticompetitive effects against reduce competitive pressure
incentive to compete be
the counterfactual** as a result?
affected by the practice?

Once the likely effects


Establish the appreciability of This step is necessary in the
established, appreciability is
the anticompetitive effects context of Article 101 TFEU
assumed in the context of
and merger control
Article 102 TFEU

Fig. 13: Anticompetitive effects under the ‘standard effects’ test


* Practice is used as a shorthand for both practice and transaction
** For a detailed assessment of exclusionary effects, see fig. 5 above

70

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3599407

You might also like