The AIIB in The Liberal International or

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 31

This article was published by Oxford University Press in

The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 12 (2019), Iss. 1, pp. 61–91 (2019/02/26):
https://doi: 10.1093/cjip/poy021

The AIIB in the Liberal International Order


Matthew D. Stephen†,* and David Skidmore‡

Matthew D. Stephen is an Interim Professor of International Relations at Helmut Schmidt University
Hamburg and Senior Research Fellow at the GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies and

David Skidmore is a Professor of Political Science at Drake University, USA.

*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

The rise of China raises fundamental questions about the future of the liberal international order
(LIO) at a time when it is under ever more strain. Although China’s focus for some years was on
joining and participating in existing multilateral institutions, today China is increasingly building
its own. Prominent among them is the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB), launched in
late 2014. Against the background of contending theoretical expectations, this article examines
the extent to which the AIIB either reinforces or challenges the LIO and highlights what this tells
us about China’s broader relationship with the LIO. We provide a definition of the LIO that is
based on its social purpose rather than on its formal characteristics. State-centric approaches
offer insights into China’s decision to engage in new institution building via the AIIB, but we
argue that a focus on social purpose is necessary to assess the AIIB’s broader implications for the
LIO. We find that, while conforming in large measure to existing institutional models, the AIIB
promotes China’s integration into global social networks, strengthens state-led development
pathways, and is associated with the Chinese norm of non-interference. The AIIB, thus,
foreshadows the possibility of an institutionalised international order indifferent to liberalism. In
sum, the AIIB reflects the tensions between the socialising effects of the LIO and China’s growing
externalisation of its own non-liberal, state-led model of political economy.

Introduction

The liberal international order (LIO)—traditionally associated with rules-based multilateralism,


economic openness, and the spread of liberal values and institutions, including representative
democracy and human rights—has lately been buffeted from two directions.1 First, both the
capacity and willingness of the United

1
G. John Ikenberry, ‘Liberal Internationalism 3.0: America and the Dilemmas of Liberal World Order’,
Perspectives on Politics, Vol. 7, No. 1 (2009), pp. 71–87; G. John Ikenberry, ‘The End of Liberal International
Order?’, International Affairs, Vol. 94, No. 1 (2018), pp.7–23.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 61
States to support liberal values and institutions at the global level have diminished.
Secondly, China appears increasingly willing to assert a vision of international order that
departs significantly from certain of the LIO’s key features, albeit while embracing other
aspects of the current order.

The United States has recently withdrawn from the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP),
unilaterally imposed import tariffs,2 repudiated the Paris climate accord,3 exited the United
Nations Human Rights Council,4 and reduced financial support for the United Nations.5 The
Chinese government, meanwhile, has been forthright in its defence of economic
globalisation,6 increased its foreign aid,7 and pledged to ‘uphold the authority and status of
the United Nations, actively fulfil China’s international obligations and duties, remain firmly
committed to China’s pledges to tackle climate change, actively push for the Belt and Road
Initiative, and always be a builder of world peace, contributor of global development and
keeper of international order’.8

A key part of China's new-found commitment to be a ‘keeper of international order’ has


been the construction of new multilateral institutions, including the BRICS New
Development Bank (NDB, created in 2014), the Chiang Mai Initiative Multilateralisation
Agreement (CMIM, signed in 2014), the expansion of the Shanghai Cooperation
Organisation (SCO, founded 2001), and the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership
(RCEP, under negotiation).9

2
‘Trump Trade Tsar Wields Power over WTO Destiny’, Financial Times, 11 December, 2017,
https://www.ft.com/content/b59b4412-dc6f-11e7-a039-c64b1c09b482.
3
Valerie Volcovici, ‘U.S. Submits Formal Notice of Withdrawal from Paris Climate Pact’, 4 August, 2017,
http://www.reuters.com/article/us-un-climate-usa-paris/u-s-submits-formal-notice-of-withdrawal-from-
paris-climate-pact-idUSKBN1AK2FM.
4
Gardiner Harris, ‘Trump Administration Withdraws U.S. from U.N. Human Rights Council’, The New York
Times, 19 June, 2018, http://www.nytimes.com/2018/06/19/us/politics/trump-israel-palestinians-
human-rights.html.
5
Rick Gladstone, ‘Taking Credit for U.N. Budget Cut, Trump’s Envoy Hints at More to Come’, The New York
Times, 25 December, 2017, http://www.nytimes.com/2017/12/25/world/americas/trump-united-
nations-budget.html.
6
‘Keynote Speech by H. E. Xi Jinping, President of the People’s Republic of China’, at the Opening Session
of the World Economic Forum Annual Meeting 2017, 17 January, 2017,
https://www.weforum.org/agenda/2017/01/full-text-of-xi-jinping-keynote-at-the-world-economic-
forum.
7
James Griffiths, ‘Report Exposes Size of China’s Secretive Aid Budget’, 11 October, 2017,
https://edition.cnn.com/2017/10/11/asia/china-overseas-aid/index.html.
8
‘Xi Demonstrates China’s Role as Responsible Country in New Year Address’, 1 January, 2018,
http://www.xinhuanet.com/english/2018-01/01/c_136865307.htm.
9
See, He Kai, ‘Contested Multilateralism 2.0 and Regional Order Transition: Causes and Implications’,
Pacific Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (2018), pp. 1–11; Sebastian Heilmann, Moritz Rudolf, Mikko Huotari, and
Johannes Buckow, ‘China’s Shadow Foreign Policy: Parallel Structures Challenge the Established
International Order’, Chinamonitor, No. 18 (2018), https://www.merics.org/sites/default/files/2018-
01/China_Monitor_18_Shadow_Foreign_Policy_EN.pdf; Matthew D. Stephen, ‘Emerging Powers and
Emerging Trends in Global

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 62
To date, one of the most prominent China-sponsored multilateral initiatives has been the
Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB). Several authors have examined the motivations
prompting China’s decision to sponsor the AIIB.10 Some see it as part of a greater endeavour
to ‘balance’ the United States;11 others have investigated the decisions of other countries to
join the bank.12 There has also been debate over whether the AIIB represents a challenge to
US hegemony or to the existing norms of multilateral development banks (MDBs). Earlier
commentaries anticipated that the AIIB might pose a revisionist challenge to the existing
institutional order,13 but more recent analyses have depicted the AIIB as largely conforming to

Governance’, Global Governance, Vol. 23, No. 3 (2017), pp. 483–502; Ye Min, ‘China and Competing
Cooperation in Asia-Pacific: TPP, RCEP, and the New Silk Road’, Asian Security, Vol. 11, No. 3 (2015), pp. 206–
24; Yan Xuetong, ‘Chinese Values vs. Liberalism: What Ideology Will Shape the International Normative
Order?’, Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 11, No. 1 (2018), pp. 1–22.
10
See, for example: Mike Callaghan and Paul Hubbard, ‘The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank:
Multilateralism on the Silk Road’, China Economic Journal, Vol. 9, No. 2 (2016), pp. 116–39; Chen Zheng and
Liu Yanchuan, ‘Granting Reassurance While Posing Challenge: Explaining China’s Creation of the Asian
Infrastructure Investment Bank’, GEG Working Paper, No. 130 (2017), http://www.geg.ox.ac.uk/granting-
reassurance-while-posing-challenge; Daniel C. K. Chow, ‘Why China Established the Asia Infrastructure
Investment Bank’, Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law, Vol. 49, No. 5 (2016), pp. 1255–98; Jonathan R.
Strand, Eduardo M. Flores, and Michael W. Trevathan, ‘China’s Leadership in Global Economic Governance
and the Creation of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, Rising Powers Quarterly, Vol. 1, No. 1 (2016),
pp. 55–69.; Ren Xiao, ‘China as an Institution-Builder: The Case of the AIIB’, Pacific Review, Vol. 29, No. 3
(2015), pp. 435–42; Yu Hong, ‘Motivation behind China’s “One Belt, One Road” Initiatives and Establishment
of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 26, No. 105 (2017),
pp.353–68.
11
He Kai, ‘Role Conceptions, Order Transition and Institutional Balancing in the Asia-Pacific: A New
Theoretical Framework’, Australian Journal of International Affairs, Vol. 72, No. 2 (2018), pp. 92–109; Yuan
Jing Dong, ‘Beijing’s Institutional-Balancing Strategies: Rationales, Implementation and Efficacy’, Australian
Journal of International Affairs, Vol. 72, No. 2 (2018), pp. 110–28.
12
Tyler Pratt, ‘Angling for Influence: Institutional Proliferation in Development Banking’, paper delivered to
the 10th Annual Conference of the Political Economy of International Organizations, Bern, 12–14 January,
2017, http://wp.peio.me/wp-content/uploads/2016/12/Program%20PEIO10.pdf; Wang Yu, ‘The Political
Economy of Joining the AIIB’, Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 11, No. 2 (2018), pp. 105–30.
13
Chow, ‘Why China Established the Asia Infrastructure Investment Bank’; Heilmann, ‘China’s Shadow
Foreign Policy’; Shintaro Hamanaka, ‘Insights to Great Powers’ Desire to Establish Institutions: Comparison
of ADB, AMF, AMRO and AIIB’, Global Policy, Vol. 7, No. 2 (2016), pp.288–92; Rebecca Liao, ‘Out of the
Bretton Woods: How the AIIB Is Different’, Foreign Affairs, 27 July, 2015,
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/asia/2015-07-27/out-bretton-woods.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 63
standard institutional practices.14 Certain scholars, however, have situated the AIIB within a
broader inter-institutional context, characterised by institutional proliferation and potential
inter-institutional competition.15 De Jonge, meanwhile, emphasises that the AIIB represents
the outcome of a recursive interaction between China’s domestic order and global norms.16

This article goes beyond existing accounts of the AIIB in two ways. First, we argue that in order
to understand the implications of the AIIB for the LIO and how China will relate to the liberal
order in the coming decades, it is essential first to clarify the LIO and what it does. Therefore,
we provide a clear and more targeted definition of the liberal international order as
international institutions that wed the exercise of international power to liberal social purpose
and use this benchmark to guide our empirical study.17

Secondly, a satisfactory assessment of what the AIIB and other new institutions mean for the
LIO requires us to move beyond traditional state-centric theories of international politics to
engage with the societal sources of international behaviour. State-centric approaches to
‘contested multilateralism’,18 rooted in functional and power-oriented types of
institutionalism, offer formal accounts of institutional proliferation and provide useful insights
into China’s decision to sponsor the AIIB.19 From a functionalist perspective, the AIIB arose
partly as a response to the inefficiencies and institutional rigidities of existing multilateral

14
Shahar Hameiri and Lee Jones, ‘China Challenges Global Governance? Chinese International Development
Finance and the AIIB’, International Affairs, Vol. 94, No. 3 (2018), pp. 573–93; Robert J. Hanlon, ‘Thinking
about the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank: Can a China-Led Development Bank Improve Sustainability
in Asia?’, Asia & the Pacific Policy Studies, Vol. 4, No. 3 (2017), pp. 541–54. Gregory Chin came to an
intermediate conclusion, stressing both innovation and continuity. See Gregory T. Chin, ‘Asian Infrastructure
Investment Bank: Governance Innovation and Prospects’, Global Governance, Vol. 22, No. 1 (2016), pp. 11–
26.
15
Nick Bisley, ‘Contested Asia’s “New” Multilateralism and Regional Order’, Pacific Review,
Vol. 78, No. 3 (2018), pp. 1–11; Miles Kellerman, ‘The Proliferation of Multilateral Development Banks’,
Review of International Organizations, 28 February, 2018, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-018-9302-y;
Annalisa Prizzon, Romilly Greenhill, and Shakira Mustapha, ‘An “Age of Choice” for External Development
Finance? Evidence from Country Case Studies’, Development Policy Review, Vol. 35, No. 1 (2018), pp. 29–45.
16
Alice de Jonge, ‘Perspectives on the Emerging Role of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’,
International Affairs, Vol. 93, No. 5 (2017), pp. 1061–84.
17
See also G. John Ikenberry and Darren J. Lim, ‘China’s Emerging Institutional Statecraft’, Brookings
Institution, April 2017, https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/chinas-emerging-
institutional-statecraft.pdf; Yan Xuetong, ‘Chinese Values vs. Liberalism’.
18
Julia C. Morse and Robert O. Keohane, ‘Contested Multilateralism’, Review of International Organizations,
Vol. 9, No. 4 (2014), pp. 385–412.
19
See, for example: Chen and Liu, ‘Granting Reassurance’; Morse and Keohane, ‘Contested Multilateralism’;
Pratt, ‘Angling for Influence’; Johannes Urpelainen and Thijs van de Graaf, ‘Your Place or Mine? Institutional
Capture and the Creation of Overlapping International Institutions’, British Journal of Political Science, Vol.
45, No. 4 (2015), pp. 799–827.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 64
development banks. But as power-oriented theories would suggest, the AIIB also serves
China’s desire to gain clout and status within international development institutions
commensurate with its growing capabilities.

Yet the LIO consists not only of formal institutions such as states and international
organisations but also of an underlying social and normative order that embraces liberal social
purposes.20 Whereas state-centric approaches emphasise the reasons why dissatisfied states
build new institutions, the emphasis of societal approaches is on the substantive reasons for
such state dissatisfaction and its substantive implications for international order and its social
purpose. Seen in this light, we find that, much like China itself, the AIIB stands in a relationship
of partial accommodation and partial challenge to the LIO: On the one hand, the AIIB builds
upon the established structures and practices of existing MDBs and has actively collaborated
with older development banks. The AIIB, thus, reflects China’s partial socialisation to the
norms of the LIO, brought about by ever-deepening integration within a Western-designed
system. On the other hand, the AIIB departs from established norms and objectives in
significant ways, notably by rejecting liberal universalism and creating space for an emergent
‘China model’ of development. In short, the AIIB may presage a potential ‘international order
with Chinese characteristics’ that entwines both liberal and non-liberal features.

We first define the LIO and unpack its component parts to provide a benchmark against which
to assess the AIIB. Secondly, we compare the insights of two sets of theories—state-centric
and societal—on the creation of the AIIB and its likely implications for international order.
Thirdly, we evaluate the explanatory power of each theory, as regards understanding China’s
relationship to the LIO, based on a qualitative analysis of the AIIB’s characteristics, such as its
institutional design, staff composition formal policies, and early operations.

Liberal International Order: Definition and Components

Debates about China’s relationship to the LIO have suffered from a lack of clarity as to exactly
what is meant by LIO. In particular, the LIO must be distinguished from international order per
se. We define the contemporary LIO as constituted by an array of international institutions
that wed the exercise of international power to liberal social purpose. Not all features of the
current international order are liberal in character. Certain elements often associated with the
LIO, such as sovereignty, international trade, and rules-based cooperation, have been present

20
Robert W. Cox, Production, Power and World Order (New York: Columbia University Press, 1987); John W.
Meyer, ‘World Society, Institutional Theories, and the Actor’, Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 36, No. 1
(2010), pp. 1–20; John Gerard Ruggie, ‘Multilateralism: The Anatomy of an Institution’, International
Organization, Vol. 46, No. 3 (1992), pp. 561–98; David Skidmore, Contested Social Orders and International
Politics (Nashville: Vanderbilt University Press, 1997); Matthew D. Stephen, ‘Rising Powers, Global Capitalism
and Liberal Global Governance: A Historical Materialist Account of the BRICs Challenge’, European Journal of
International Relations, Vol. 20, No. 4 (2014), pp. 912–38.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 65
in non-liberal international orders.21 It is the particular way in which the LIO combines power
and purpose that defines its liberal character.

First, the LIO allocates and exercises forms of power. International organisations can exercise
power directly—by allocating or withholding resources, imposing sovereignty costs, or
authoritatively interpreting international norms,22 and indirectly—by reflecting the agendas of
powerful states23 and social forces.24 The United States and its allies continue to enjoy special
rights, privileges, and opt-outs that favour their interests within keystone LIO institutions, such
as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund.25 Changes to the LIO’s decision-
making structures and power relations would alter its power-based and distributional
consequences, but not necessarily the order itself, as defined by its social purpose.

Secondly, liberal international institutions embody distinctively liberal social purposes.26 Social
purpose refers to the substantive normative and policy content that international institutions
represent.27 Many contemporary IOs, according to Michael Barnett and Martha Finnemore,
serve as ‘purveyors of liberal values, including human rights, democracy, and the rule of law’,
as well as ‘liberal economic notions about the virtues of markets and capitalism as the best
(and perhaps the only) means to “progress”’.28 Liberal social purpose is embedded in

21
In fact, it may be more accurate to speak of an international order with liberal features, but we will use
LIO to refer to those liberal features for the sake of brevity.
22
Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, ‘Hard and Soft Law in International Governance’, International
Organization, Vol. 54, No. 3 (2000), pp. 421–56; Michael Barnett and Martha Finnemore, ‘The Politics,
Power, and Pathologies of International’, International Organization, Vol. 53, No. 4 (1999), pp. 699–732.
23
Michael N. Barnett and Raymond Duvall, Power in Global Governance (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2005); Randall W. Stone, Controlling Institutions: International Organizations and the Global Economy
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011).
24
Robert W. Cox, ‘Hegemony and International Relations: An Essay in Method’, Millennium, Vol. 12, No. 2
(1983), pp. 162–75.
25
Ikenberry, ‘Liberal Internationalism 3.0’; Jakob Vestergaard and Robert H. Wade, ‘Protecting Power: How
Western States Retain The Dominant Voice in The World Bank’s Governance’, World Development, Vol. 46
(2013), pp. 153–64; David Skidmore, The Unilateralist Temptation in American Foreign Policy (New York:
Routledge, 2011), pp. 17–42.
26
Barnett and Finnemore, ‘The Politics, Power, and Pathologies of International Institutions’, p. 708;
Ikenberry, ‘Liberal Internationalism 3.0’; John G. Ruggie, ‘International Regimes, Transactions and Change:
Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order’, International Organization, Vol. 36, No. 2 (1982), p.
380.
27
Ruggie, ‘International Regimes, Transactions and Change’, p. 382; Andrew Baker, ‘Macroprudential
Regimes and the Politics of Social Purpose’, Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 25, No. 3 (2018),
pp. 293–316; Bastiaan van Apeldoorn and Sandy
Brian Hager, ‘The Social Purpose of New Governance: Lisbon and the Limits to Legitimacy’, Journal of
International Relations and Development, Vol. 13, No. 3 (2010), pp. 209–38.
28
Michael Barnett and Martha Finnemore, Rules for the World: International Organizations in Global Politics
(Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2004), p. ix.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 66
rules and agreements that favour the market-led allocation of resources, prioritise economic
openness over collective management and public oversight, and foster individualist
conceptions of human rights and procedural notions of democracy. These liberal concepts are
defining features of the LIO because they relate to its normative content. International
institutions that are neutral with regard to certain core issues, such as human rights,
democracy, the rule of law, markets, and capitalism, should not be considered liberal.

The policy field of multilateral development finance is a key component of the LIO. The World
Bank, the largest and only global multilateral development bank, has often served as a major
conduit for the dissemination of liberal economic prescriptions via its research and loan
activities. During the 1990s—a period of US predominance—the average number of
conditions entailed in the bank’s policy-based lending increased considerably29 and, together
with its policy-related research activities, earned it a reputation as a key representative of the
liberal Washington Consensus, characterised by commitments to trade liberalisation, reduced
fiscal deficits, privatisation, and financial liberalisation.30 Today, the Bank’s approach has been
described as a ‘post’ or ‘augmented’ Washington Consensus, wherein the commitment to
economic liberalism is augmented by a greater focus on domestic governance issues.31 This
became visible most recently in fresh debates over the World Bank’s Ease of Doing Business
Report,32 which China has long criticised as having an anti-regulation stance.33

If, then, China is rising in the context of an international order with liberal characteristics,
which features of the LIO will China support and which will it oppose? As China gains the
power to alter the rules of the game, how will an

29
World Bank, Review of World Bank Conditionality (Washington, DC: World Bank, 2005),
https://siteresources.worldbank.org/PROJECTS/Resources/40940-
1114615847489/ConditionalityFinalDCpaperDC9-9-05.pdf.
30
Joseph E. Stiglitz, Globalization and its Discontents (New York: W. W. Norton, 2002); Lance Taylor,
‘Editorial: The Revival of the Liberal Creed—the IMF and the World Bank in a Globalized Economy’, World
Development, Vol. 25, No. 2 (1997), pp. 145–52.
31
Sarah Babb, ‘The Washington Consensus as Transnational Policy Paradigm: Its Origins, Trajectory and
Likely Successor’, Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 20, No. 2 (2013), pp. 268–97; Dani Rodrik
and Roberto Zagha, ‘Goodbye Washington Consensus, Hello Washington Confusion? A Review of the World
Bank’s “Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform”’, Journal of Economic Literature,
Vol. 44, No. 4 (2006), pp. 973–87.
32
Andre´ Broome, Alexandra Homolar, and Matthias Kranke, ‘Bad Science: International Organizations and
the Indirect Power of Global Benchmarking’, European Journal of International Relations, Vol. 24, No. 3
(2018), pp. 514–39; ‘The World Bank’s “Ease of Doing Business” Report Faces Tricky Questions’, The
Economist, 20 January, 2018, https://www.economist.com/news/finance-and-economics/21735076-
embarrassingly-they-are-raised-and-then-answeredby-its-chief-economist-world.
33
Robin Harding, ‘China Seeks to Water Down Key World Bank Report’, Financial Times, 7 May, 2013,
http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/a1ca36d2-b654-11e2-b1e5-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2VMxphHyJ.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 67
international order with Chinese characteristics differ from the status quo in distributional and
social terms?

The Creation of the AIIB and Liberal International Order: Theoretical Approaches

Building on existing theory, we develop a framework to analyse the AIIB’s relationship to the
LIO. Our basic argument is that prevailing state-centric approaches have spoken narrowly to a
single dimension of the LIO related to matters of institutional structure, authority, and power.
A fuller understanding of the LIO requires consideration of its social components, including the
social groups and normative orders it serves.34

State-centric Approaches

China’s launching of the AIIB can be considered, from a rationalist, state-centric perspective,
as a case of institutional creation,35 institutional proliferation,36 creation of an overlapping
institution,37 or contested multilateralism.38 Such approaches build primarily on two types of
rational institutionalism: functionalist (gains-oriented) and distributive (power-based).

Both functionalist institutionalism39 and distributive institutionalism (the former associated


with liberal theory and the latter with realist theory) are concerned primarily with patterns of
international conflict and cooperation, rather than the social orders that such patterns
produce. They treat states as unitary actors whose goals can be described in quantitative
terms (i.e. gains or losses). As Andrew Moravcsik has observed, neither functionalist nor
distributive institutionalism ‘explains the changing substantive goals and purposes over which
states conflict and cooperate; both focus instead on formal causes, such as relative power or
issue density, and formal consequences, such as conflict and cooperation per se’.40

Although these approaches converge in their concern with the distribution of gains and
authority within international institutional arrangements, they differ

34
In this respect, our approach to international order echoes Peter Gourevitch’s distinction between the two
core features of a political system: regime type and coalition pattern. See Peter Gourevitch, ‘The Second
Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic Politics’, International Organization, Vol. 32, No. 4
(1978), p. 883.
35
Joseph Jupille, Walter Mattli, and Duncan Snidal, Institutional Choice and Global Commerce (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2013).
36
Kellerman, ‘The Proliferation of Multilateral Development Banks’; Pratt, ‘Angling for Influence’.
37
Urpelainen and van de Graaf, ‘Your Place or Mine?’.
38
Morse and Keohane, ‘Contested Multilateralism’.
39
Sometimes referred to as liberal institutionalism or regime theory.
40
Andrew Moravcsik, ‘Taking Preferences Seriously: A Liberal Theory of International Politics’, International
Organization, Vol. 51, No. 4 (1997), p. 534.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 68
over which logic predominates: functionalist institutionalism assumes profit-oriented,
absolute gains logic; distributive institutionalism emphasises power-based, relative gains logic.

Functional Institutionalism

For functional institutionalists, international institutions provide efficient solutions to


collective action problems and other impediments to mutually beneficial interstate
cooperation.41 The domestic character and social purposes of the participating states and
dominant social groups, however, lie outside of the scope of the theory and are, hence, largely
ignored.

From a functional institutionalist perspective, China’s creation of the AIIB presents a puzzle.
Given the costs of institutional setup and the uncertainty of success, it is unclear why states
sometimes create new institutions—such as the AIIB—that duplicate the work of already
existing institutions.42 Dysfunction or underperformance on the part of existing institutions
may be one motivation for such institutional innovation. Dissatisfied stakeholders may push
for reform when international organisations become bloated and inefficient. As institutions
age, a number of organisational pathologies may arise.43 The leadership and staff of IOs may
seek expansion of their own power and resources and greater independence from the control
of sponsoring states (i.e. the principal-agent problem).44 Mission creep may lead to an ever
broader and more diffuse agenda that moves the organisation further from its core
competencies, and a lack of market competition, strict oversight, or hard budget caps might
cause its inefficiencies to proliferate.

The functionalist approach proposes that the creation of a new institution may be the result of
bargaining failure, whereby attempts to reform established institutions have been blocked by
internal veto players, or of a failure to successfully signal commitment.45 This suggests that
China’s sponsorship of the AIIB may represent an effort to create a more focused, efficient,
and responsive institution

41
Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, ‘Why States Act through Formal International Organizations’,
Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (1998), pp. 3–32; Robert O. Keohane, After Hegemony:
Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984);
Barbara Koremenos, Charles Lipson, and Duncan Snidal, ‘The Rational Design of International Institutions’,
International Organization, Vol. 55, No. 4 (2001), pp. 761–99.
42
Urpelainen and van de Graaf, ‘Your Place or Mine?’, p. 799; Pratt, ‘Angling for Influence’.
43
Barnett and Finnemore, The Politics, Power, and Pathologies of International Organizations, pp. 699–732;
Tine Hanrieder, International Organization in Time: Fragmentation and Reform (Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 2015).
44
Steffen Eckhard and Jo¨ rn Ege, ‘International Bureaucracies and their Influence on Policymaking: A
Review of Empirical Evidence’, Journal of European Public Policy, Vol. 23, No. 7 (2016), pp. 960–78.
45
Morse and Keohane, ‘Contested Multilateralism’; Urpelainen and van de Graaf, ‘Your Place or Mine?’.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 69
in the field of multilateral development finance. This would likely be the result of previous
failed attempts to reform legacy institutions.

If new institutions are designed with the same purposes in mind as existing ones and seek
merely to improve on their performance or operate with greater efficiency, this would
strongly imply that functional gains-seeking is at play. Therefore, if the AIIB were designed to
do what established institutions do, only better, it would hardly qualify as a challenge to the
LIO.

Power-distributive Institutionalism

Other state-centric approaches stress the role of power in shaping institutional outcomes.
Almost all international institutions raise distributive issues, giving rise to relative gains
dynamics.46 Realists have conceived of international institutions as ‘intervening variables’
between the underlying distribution of power and international outcomes.47 As Steven
Krasner argues, misalignments can arise between underlying power distributions and
institutional governance due to the stickiness of institutional adaptation. International
institutions also often fall prey to the informal control mechanisms that powerful states wield,
which would further disadvantage rising powers.48 It would not be surprising, therefore, if
China, as a rising power, sought to correct the mismatch between its meagre influence within
existing multilateral institutions and its growing capabilities.49

From this perspective, we should expect the Chinese decision to sponsor a new institution (i.e.
the AIIB) to follow close on the heels of China’s failed efforts to gain greater voice within
existing multilateral development institutions. But, in contrast to functional institutionalism,
we would also expect the reigning hegemon, the United States, to resist the creation of new
China-centred institutions that compete with those which it and its allies dominate. In general,
therefore, China’s sponsorship of the AIIB should show evidence of an overriding desire to
maximise China’s power and influence within the international development finance regime.

46
Stephen D. Krasner, ‘Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier’, World
Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (1991), pp. 336–66; Philip Y. Lipscy, Renegotiating the World Order: Institutional
Change in International Relations (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2016); Thomas S. Mowle,
‘Worldviews in Foreign Policy: Realism, Liberalism, and External Conflict’, Political Psychology, Vol. 24, No. 3
(2003), pp. 561–92; Pratt, ‘Angling for Influence’.
47
Stephen D. Krasner, ‘Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables’,
International Organization, Vol. 36, No. 2 (1982), pp. 185–205; Stephen D. Krasner, Structural Conflict: The
Third World Against Global Liberalism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985).
48
Stone, Controlling Institutions; Randall W. Stone, ‘Informal Governance in International Organizations:
Introduction to the Special Issue’, Review of International Organizations, Vol. 8, No. 2 (2013), pp. 121–36.
49
Lipscy, Renegotiating the World Order; Pratt, ‘Your Place or Mine?’.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 70
Societal Approaches

From a state-centric perspective, institutional innovation may be explained as the result of


dissatisfaction with existing institutions, either because of institutional inefficiencies
(functionalist) or due to a mismatch between material and institutional power (distributive).
Although this tells us much about the potential for institutional innovation within the LIO,
both theories are agnostic regarding the substantive norms, principles, and practices of new
institutions. Both ignore international institutions’ social purposes or the role of states or
social forces in pursuing particular social orders or sets of normative values. Rather, each
describes institutional variation in respect of efficiency (functionalist) or of the distribution of
voting power and other aspects of governance (power-based).50

To situate the AIIB in the context of the LIO as a social order, it is necessary to engage societal
theories of international politics. By societal theories, we mean approaches that embed
international politics and institutions in a qualitative social context defined by social groups
and ideas. Societal approaches emphasise the ‘substantive goals and purposes over which
states conflict and cooperate’51 and analyse states ‘as both the products of evolving societies
and as shapers of those societies’.52 Here, we derive expectations about the AIIB from two
societal approaches: ‘World Society’ constructivism (also known as sociological
institutionalism) and second-image ‘social order’ approaches. The former operates according
to an ‘outside-in’ logic, while the latter links states’ conduct to their domestic and
transnational societies (‘inside-out’).53 What unites these approaches is their concern for the
social quality of international orders.

World Society Approach

World society constructivism begins with the observation that the evolution of the global
order over the past several centuries has been dominated by the gradual spread and
increasing elaboration of a set of modern, liberal norms and principles.54 As non-Western
societies have opened—whether by consent or coercion—to the penetration of external ideas
and material exchange, they have become socialised into a set of universalising norms and
institutions. This socialisation process works from the outside-in: a state’s external behaviour
and interaction

50
For example, Phillip Lipscy’s elegant theory of institutional change focuses solely on institutions’
distributive characteristics, while Kellerman’s focus on the proliferation of MDBs’ focuses on distribution and
procedures. See Lipscy, Renegotiating the World Order; Kellerman, ‘The Proliferation of Multilateral
Development Banks’.
51
Moravcsik, ‘Taking Preferences Seriously’.
52
Robert W. Cox, ‘“The International” in Evolution’, Millennium, Vol. 35, No. 3 (2007), p. 514.
53
Harald Mueller and Thomas Risse-Kappen, ‘From the Outside in and From the Inside Out: International
Relations, Domestic Politics and Foreign Policy’, in David Skidmore and Valerie Hudson, eds., The Limits of
State Autonomy: Societal Groups and Foreign Policy Formulation, (Boulder: Westview, 1993), pp. 29–48.
54
Barnett and Finnemore, Rules for the World; Meyer, ‘World Society, Institutional Theories, and the Actor’.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 71
with the outside world conform more quickly than its domestic culture and institutions. From
this perspective, China should remain a rule-taker rather than a rule-maker, even as it
sponsors the creation of new multilateral institutions. We should, hence, expect the AIIB to
import rules, standards, and procedures from already existing development banks, even
where such standards differ markedly from those practiced within China itself. 55 In line with a
logic of appropriateness, therefore, China will emulate existing LIO norms, standards, and
practices in an effort to ensure that Chinese-sponsored institutions are viewed as legitimate.56

While functional institutionalists view ‘institutions as exogenous rule-based, sanction-based


constraints on non-changing agents’,57 constructivists, on the other hand, argue that
engagement with international institutions changes the identity of participating states and
reinforces collective norms of behaviour. From the World Society theory perspective, the
spread of liberal, modern norms and values over the past two centuries has gradually
redefined appropriate state behaviour. International institutions embody universal, liberal
norms and also serve as agents for socialising newly open states into the specifically liberal
rules of the LIO.58 From this perspective, China’s willingness to orient the AIIB towards the
norms, standards, and rule-sets of the pre-existing development finance regime would offer
strong evidence of this socialisation process and a reproduction of LIO.

Social Order Theory

Social order theories argue that great powers seek to structure the international system along
lines compatible with their own political, social, and economic institutions. The basic process
moves from the inside-out: states seek to ‘establish a basic compatibility between domestic
and international policy objectives’.59 Consequently, states leave traces of their domestic
orders in their foreign policies and in international orders.60 From a social order perspective,
therefore, the AIIB should reflect elements of China’s single-party political system and state-
capitalist

55
James Reilly, ‘A Norm-Taker or a Norm-Maker? Chinese Aid in Southeast Asia’, Journal of Contemporary
China, Vol. 21, No. 73 (2012), pp. 71–91.
56
Jeffrey D. Wilson, ‘The Evolution of China’s Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank: From a Revisionist to
Status-seeking Agenda’, International Relations of the Asia-Pacific, Vol. 19, No. 1 (2019), pp. 147–76.
57
Alastair Iain Johnston, Social States: China in International Institutions, 1980–2000 (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 2008), p. xvi.
58
Barnett and Finnemore, Rules for the World.
59
Peter J. Katzenstein, ‘Introduction: Domestic and International Forces and Strategies of Foreign Economic
Policy’, International Organization, Vol. 31, No. 4 (1977), p. 588.
60
Ruggie, ‘Multilateralism’, p. 593. After Waltz, these are known as ‘second image’ approaches. See Kenneth
Waltz, Man, The State and War (New York: Columbia University Press, 1954).

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 72
political economy, which would put it in tension with the LIO of the largely democratic, liberal
capitalist ‘West’.61

Samuel Huntington offered a strong version of a culturalist social order model in his ‘clash of
civilisations’ thesis, which depicts Sinic and Western cultures as bound for conflict.62 Martin
Jaques similarly argues that China has pioneered its distinctive path to modernity and will
externalise the principals of its political and cultural systems.63 Charles Kupchan likewise
asserts that great powers inevitably export their domestic orders, meaning that China will
‘challenge the foundational norms of Pax Americana’ and instead advance its own norms in
keeping with its ideological preferences and material interests.64

If the strong versions of social order theory are correct, we should expect the AIIB to reflect a
fundamental challenge to the basic principles, norms, and rules of the LIO. If China sought to
overturn the LIO, for instance, the AIIB might embody mercantilist principles, strongly favour
state-owned firms, take the form of an exclusive regional economic bloc, or fail to incorporate
protection of human rights, the environment, or honest government.65 A social order model,
therefore, would lead us to expect Western countries to unite in boycotting the AIIB, as
countries might be confronted with a normative clash that forces them to choose between the
World Bank and Asian Development Bank on one hand and the AIIB on the other.

A weaker version of the social order model emerges from comparative capitalism research.
From this perspective, a state’s stance on multilateral economic issues will be influenced by
judgments on whether such initiatives are likely to sustain or to undermine the comparative
institutional advantages of their nation’s economy. Governments should oppose initiatives
that threaten those institutions most crucial to their firms’ competitive advantages.66 From
this perspective, we should expect China to promote different, less liberal forms of economic

61
Charles A. Kupchan, ‘The Normative Foundations of Hegemony and The Coming Challenge to Pax
Americana’, Security Studies, Vol. 23, No. 2 (2014), pp. 219–57; Andreas No¨ lke, ‘Second Image Revisited:
The Domestic Sources of China’s Foreign Economic Policies’, International Politics, Vol. 52, No. 6 (2015), pp.
657–665; Yan Xuetong, ‘Chinese Values vs. Liberalism’.
62
Samuel P. Huntington, The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order (New York: Simon &
Schuster, 1998).
63
Martin Jacques, When China Rules the World: The End of the Western World and the Birth of a New Global
Order, 2nd edition (London: Penguin, 2012).
64
Kupchan, ‘The Normative Foundations of Hegemony’, p. 224.
65
Chow, ‘Why China Established the Asia Infrastructure Investment Bank’; Liao, ‘Out of the Bretton Woods’.
66
Orfeo Fioretos, ‘The Domestic Sources of Multilateral Preferences: Varieties of Capitalism in the European
Community’, in Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of
Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), pp. 213–44; Miles Kahler, International
Institutions and the Political Economy of Integration (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1995).

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 73
regulation commensurate with its state-led form of capitalism.67 China could, hence, use the
AIIB to promote a ‘China model’ of development as an alternative to the ‘Washington
Consensus’ that the World Bank and IMF have promoted, with varying levels of intensity, since
the 1990s. Although the depth of conflict would be more limited than that suggested by
Huntington or Jacques, the AIIB would nevertheless serve as a competitor to rather than as a
collaborator with the legacy development banks and signal a challenge to the LIO at a
normative level. Table 1 summarises these approaches and their observable implications.

The AIIB and Liberal International Order

This framework guides our qualitative analysis of the AIIB. For data, we examine sources that
include the AIIB’s founding documents and institutional design, its staff composition,
statements made by state and bank officials, and analyses of its early operations. First, we
examine to what extent the creation of the AIIB conforms to the observable implications of
functionalist or distributive forms of state-centric theory. Secondly, we use societal
approaches to assess the compatibility of the AIIB with the social purpose of the LIO in the
issue area of development lending.

AIIB Design: Efficiency-seeking Gains or Power Redistribution?

There is significant evidence of a role for functional gains with regard to China’s decision to
initiate the AIIB. Developing countries have long complained about the bureaucratic burdens,
high transaction costs, and lengthy approval processes at existing MDBs.68 Chinese and AIIB
officials have repeatedly promoted the Bank as a ‘lean’ organisation, with a small staff, a non-
resident Board, and low overhead costs.69 Chinese critics describe the World Bank’s
management structure—including a resident Board that costs $70 million per year—as slow,
cumbersome, and expensive.70 These costs represent between 3 and 7% of the

67
Christopher A. McNally, ‘Sino-Capitalism: China’s Reemergence and the International Political Economy’,
World Politics, Vol. 64, No. 4 (2012), pp. 741–76; Ten Brink, ‘The Challenges of China’s Non-Liberal Capitalism
for the Liberal Global Economic Order’, Harvard Asia Quarterly, Vol. 15, No. 2 (2015), pp. 36–44.
68
Richard Carey, Annalisa Prizzon, Xu Jiajun, and Chris Humphrey, ‘Multilateral Development
Banks in the 21st Century Three Perspectives on China and the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’,
Overseas Development Institute Discussion Paper, 2015; Wang Hongying, ‘New Multilateral Development
Banks: Opportunities and Challenges for Global Governance’, Global Policy, Vol. 8, No. 1 (2017), p. 116.
69
Gregory Chin, ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, pp. 15–17.
70
Inclusive Development International, Making Inroads: Chinese Infrastructure Investment in ASEAN and
Beyond (Asheville: Inclusive Development International, 2016), p. 13; Huang Yukon, ‘China has a Role to Play
in Setting the ‘Right’ Standards’, Financial Times, 15 April, 2015, https://www.ft.com/content/b1a49850-
23bb-3f1d-9400-9c96d09cbc60.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 74
institution’s operating budget.71 It takes, on average, seven years for a project to progress
from proposal to approval to completion at the ADB.72 Commenting on this, Chinese Foreign
Minister Lou Jiwei explicitly touted shorter project execution times as one of the bank’s goals.
‘We would not bureaucratize the AIIB. Instead, we need to be efficient and “green”.’73

AIIB officials have stated that although the new Bank will reference existing best practices, it
will also ‘make adjustments to some of the regulations of the established MDBs in order to
raise operating efficiency and improve upon current practices that are overly complicated and
not highly relevant to the actual conditions’.74 One example is that responsibility for project
approval lies

71
Leonardo Martinez-Diaz, ‘Executive Boards in International Organizations’, in Ruben Lamdany and
Leonardo Martinez-Diaz, eds., Studies of IMF Governance: A Compendium (Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund, 2009), pp. 82–126.
72
Jane Perlez, ‘China’s Plan for Regional Development Bank Runs into U.S. Opposition’, International New
York Times, 9 October, 2014, http://www.nytimes.com/2015/12/05/business/international/china-creates-
an-asian-bank-as-the-us-stands-aloof.html.
73
Hua Shengdun, ‘AIIB Looks to be Efficient, “Green”’, China Daily, 20 April, 2018,
http://usa.chinadaily.com.cn/us/2015-04/20/content_20476271.htm.
74
Eiichi Sekine, ‘Aims and Prospects of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank Proposed by China’,
Nomura Journal of Capital Markets, Vol. 6, No. 4 (2015), p. 7.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 75
chiefly with the Bank’s management rather than the Board of Directors.75 Indeed, many of the
design features that differentiate the AIIB from the World Bank stem from recommendations
of the High-Level Commission on Modernisation of World Bank Group Governance chaired by
former President of Mexico Ernesto Zedillo, which criticised the World Bank for bloat and
inefficiency.76

Criticism of the Bretton Woods institutions—the World Bank and the International Monetary
Fund (IMF)—has focused not only on issues of speed and efficiency but also on their poor
performance with regard to preventing and managing regional and global financial crises.77 In
the wake of the Asian financial crisis of the late 90s and the global financial crisis of 2008 and
beyond, many Asian leaders concluded that their countries were overly dependent upon trade
and financial ties with the West and sought to steer their economies towards stronger
regional integration and alternative mechanisms for managing financial risk. The dramatic
declines in investment flows from the World Bank and private capital after 2008 underlined
the urgency of these problems.78

In 2010, therefore, China and the Member States of the Association of Southeast Asian
Nations (ASEAN) launched a $10 billion investment fund. In the same year, ASEAN, together
with China, Japan, and South Korea, announced the Chiang Mai Initiative, which provided a
foreign exchange reserve pool for Member States to tap at times of financial crisis.79 The AIIB’s
creation, thus, followed more than a decade of deliberations among East Asian governments
on institutional innovation to meet regional needs and provide alternatives to the Bretton
Woods institutions.

As often emphasised, the AIIB’s focus on infrastructure reflected the particular needs and
priorities of Asian countries.80 Famously, in 2010, the ADB estimated

75
A group of development NGOs issued a joint statement criticising this arrangement for undermining the
‘chain of accountability’ that ensures Bank accountability to civil society. See Centre for Financial
Accountability, ‘Civil Society Sounds Alarm on AIIB’s Latest “Hands-off” Lending Deal’, 26 June, 2018,
http://www.cenfa.org/media-coverage/civil-society-sounds-alarm-on-aiibs-latest-hands-off-lending-deal/.
76
Leonardo Martinez-Diaz, ‘Toward a Grand Bargain on World Bank Reform’, Brookings, 16 December, 2009,
https://www.brookings.edu/articles/toward-a-grand-bargain-on-world-bank-reform/; David Dollar, ‘The AIIB
and the “One Belt, One Road”’, Brookings Institutions Report (2015),
https://www.brookings.edu/opinions/the-aiib-and-the-one-belt-one-road/.
77
Thomas D. Lairson and David Skidmore, International Political Economy: The Struggle for Power and
Wealth in a Globalizing World (New York: Routledge, 2017), pp. 232–81.
78
Alice D. Ba, ‘In Pursuit of Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank: The Politics and Geopolitics of a Chinese
Bank’, in Steven B. Rothman, Utpal Vyas, Yoichiro Sato, eds., Regional Institutions, Geopolitics and
Economics in the Asia-Pacific (Abingdon: Routledge, 2017), pp. 41–59.
79
Ba, ‘In Pursuit of Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’.
80
Callaghan and Hubbard, ‘The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, pp. 120–22; Ren Xiao, ‘China as an
Institution-builder: The Case of the AIIB’, Pacific Review, Vol. 29, No. 3 (2016), pp. 435–42, p. 2; Wang, ‘New
Multilateral Development Banks’, p. 115.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 76
that Asian countries needed around US $776 billion in annual infrastructure investment.81
From China’s perspective, the AIIB constitutes a vehicle for marshalling and channelling Asia’s
savings glut specifically to meet these infrastructure needs.82 Thus, China had both the
incentive and the capacity to sponsor a competing institution. But the AIIB’s infrastructure
mission was also demand-driven in response to the articulated desires of potential recipient
countries.

The Chinese government also has hopes that the competition the AIIB generates for existing
development banks will force the latter to adapt.83 Indeed, this may already have occurred, as
both the World Bank and the ADB have promised to streamline project approval and reduce
overhead costs.84 Since China’s push to create the AIIB, both institutions have also promised
to allocate greater resources to infrastructure development.85

China’s choice of multilateralism rather than unilateralism can also be explained from a
functionalist perspective. MDBs, in contrast to national development banks, pool the
resources of multiple countries, so spreading political and economic risks and facilitating
coordination among recipient and lending countries on projects with transnational spillovers
and network effects. This accurately describes the AIIB’s ambit.86

Given its particular economic needs and those of its neighbours, China held a strong interest
in expanding infrastructure investment in Asia and had plentiful resources to devote to this
task but found existing development banks poor vehicles for the appropriate channelling of
such resources. From a functional institutionalist perspective, China’s sponsorship of the AIIB
represents an effort to create a more focused, efficient, and responsive institution wherein
China would naturally exercise considerable, although not exclusive, control.

At the same time, there is also evidence that relative-gains considerations played a role in the
AIIB’s creation and that the AIIB will effect a redistribution of authority within the field of
multilateral development financing. Although functional institutionalism can account well for
the creation of the AIIB and its

81
Callaghan and Hubbard, ‘The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, pp. 120–21; Catherine Weaver, ‘The
Rise of China: Continuity or Change in the Global Governance of Development?’, Ethics in International
Affairs, Vol. 29, No. 4 (2015), p. 426.
82
Scott Morris and Tao Lipei, ‘When China Looks at MDBs, It Sees Infrastructure’, Center for Global
Development, 7 June, 2016, https://www.cgdev.org/blog/when-china-looks-mdbs-it-sees-infrastructure.
83
Hua, ‘AIIB Looks to be Efficient, “Green”’.
84
Perlez, ‘China’s Plan for Regional Development Bank Runs into U.S. Opposition’.
85
Asian Development Bank, ‘ADB President Calls for New Infrastructure Investment as Part of ADB’s Long-
Term Strategy’, 6 May, 2017, https://www.adb.org/news/adb-president-calls-new-infrastructure-
investment-part-adbs-long-term-strategy; World Bank, ‘World Bank Group Launches New Global
Infrastructure Facility’, 9 October, 2014, http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-
release/2014/10/09/world-bank-group-launches-new-global-infrastructure-facility.
86
Callaghan and Hubbard, ‘The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, pp. 122–3.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 77
efficiency focus, it is less able to account for the political trade-offs and conflicts underlying its
creation.

In line with a power-distributive approach, the inadequacy of Chinese representation in the


World Bank’s voting share was a key background factor of Chinese dissatisfaction with the
status quo ante.87 China, together with other BRICS countries, had long called for a faster and
greater quota and voice reform at the World Bank,88 but this effort brought only grudging
concessions from the World Bank’s dominant shareholders.89 Although China gained greater
voting power as part of a package of Bank reforms in 2010, it remained far from proportional
to China’s actual weight in the world economy, leaving the United States in a position to veto
key World Bank decisions. The US Congress, moreover, delayed approval of the 2010 Bank
reforms until 2015,90 by which time China was even more under-represented.

First announced in 2013, the AIIB, therefore, could be considered part of a Chinese effort to
enhance its relative power by creating a competitive institution capable of weakening the US-
dominated World Bank and the Japan-dominated ADB’s influence or at least expanding
Chinese influence within existing institutions through demonstrating that it offers a credible
‘exit option’.91 The AIIB’s location in Beijing and the presence of Chinese nationals high in the
bank’s secretariat also enable it to provide scope for Beijing’s exercise, similar to that of the
United States’ within the Bretton Woods institutions, of informal paths of control over the
institution.92

On the other hand, ideas about a China-centred Asian investment bank had been floated as
early as 2007.93 The AIIB was itself originally attached to the much more ambitious Belt and
Road Initiative (BRI) unveiled in 2013. The BRI provides a means for China’s economy to
integrate more closely with those of its neighbours. As China built-out its own domestic
infrastructure, moreover,

87
Chow, ‘Why China Established the Asia Infrastructure Investment Bank’; Helmut Reisen, ‘Will the AIIB and
the NDB Help Reform Multilateral Development Banking?’, Global Policy, Vol. 6, No. 3 (2015), pp. 297–304.
88
BRIC Finance Ministers, BRICs Finance Communiqué, 14 March, 2009,
http://www.brics.utoronto.ca/docs/090314-finance.html.
89
Vestergaard and Wade, ‘Protecting Power’.
90
Tom Miller, China’s Asian Dream: Empire Building along the New Silk Road (London: ZedBooks, 2017), p.
36.
91
Ikenberry and Lim, ‘China’s Emerging Institutional Statecraft’; Chen and Liu, ‘Granting Reassurance while
Posing Challenge’, p. 7.
92
Stone, Controlling Institutions; Stone, ‘Informal Governance in International Organizations’. Evidence that
powerful countries have informal influence over bank lending and policy decisions is presented in
Christopher Kilby, ‘An Empirical Assessment of Informal Influence in the World Bank’, Economic
Development & Cultural Change, Vol. 61, No. 2 (2013), pp. 431–64.
93
Perlez, ‘China Creates a World Bank of its Own, and the U.S. Balks’, International New York Times, 4
December, 2015.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 78
Chinese construction and engineering firms were eager to find new markets for their
capacities through the BRI. The AIIB would provide the financing necessary to exploit such
opportunities in regions stretching from Southeast Asia to Southeast Europe. For this reason,
some argue that, even if reforms at the World Bank and IMF had been more accommodating,
‘China would still have proposed the establishment of an institution like the AIIB.’94

But is the AIIB nevertheless part of a zero-sum power contest between China and the United
States and its allies? If so, it would appear to be more the result of US attempts to undermine
the bank than Chinese attempts to exclude the United States.95 China took steps early on to
assuage American concerns about the AIIB and to smooth the way for the US membership, to
the extent of offering to reduce China’s voting share to below the 25% veto threshold if the
United States and Japan agreed to join as founding members.96 Jin Liqun, later named AIIB’s
first president, visited Washington DC in September 2014 to make a pitch for US participation.
When Evan S. Medeiros, senior China advisor on the National Security Council, remarked, ‘I
am not going to buy the cake you have cooked,’ Jin reportedly replied: ‘you are always
welcome into the kitchen to help with the baking.’97

Despite these Chinese efforts at reassurance, the United States initially criticised the AIIB as an
effort to undermine the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank. American and Japanese
officials also raised questions on whether or not the AIIB would meet the necessarily high
standards of environmental and social protection and anti-corruption. The United States
actively discouraged Australia, South Korea, and European countries from joining the Bank,
although most US allies ignored this advice.98 After the UK announced its plans to join the
Bank, a White House official declared: ‘We are wary about a trend toward constant
accommodation of China.’99 Others worried that the AIIB threatened to fragment and weaken
global economic governance.100

As regards the AIIB’s relationship to pre-existing MDBs, both Chinese and AIIB officials have
gone out of their way to emphasise that the AIIB will closely collaborate with the World Bank
and ADB. In fact, the AIIB’s Articles of

94
Callaghan and Hubbard, ‘The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, p. 125.
95
Ibid.
96
Chin, ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’; Hu Weija, ‘De-Sinicization Can Counter Concerns about AIIB’,
Global Times, 3 December, 2015, http://www.globaltimes.cn/content/956445.shtml.
97
Perlez, ‘China Creates a World Bank of its Own, and the U.S. Balks’.
98
Perlez, ‘China’s Plan for Regional Development Bank Runs into U.S. Opposition’; Perlez, ‘China Creates a
World Bank of its Own, and the U.S. Balks’.
99
Joshua Kurlantzick, ‘Let China Win. It’s Good for America’, Washington Post, 15 January, 2016,
https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/let-china-win-its-good-for-america/2016/01/14/bfec4732-
b9b6-11e5-829c-26ffb874a18d_story.html.
100
Paola Subacchi, ‘The AIIB Is a Threat to Global Economic Governance’, Chatham House Expert Comment, 7
May, 2015, http://www.chathamhouse.org/expert/comment/17391.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 79
Agreement stipulate that it will ‘complement the existing multilateral development banks’.101
The AIIB’s initial loans, moreover, have been made as a junior partner in World Bank- and
Asian Development Bank-led projects.102 The AIIB welcomed World Bank staff as consultants
on the new bank’s design and hired many former World Bank and Asian Development Bank
employees.103 China has, moreover, increased its investment stake in both the World Bank
and the ADB since the AIIB was announced.104 AIIB President Jin Liqun emphasised that, ‘It is
certainly a misconception that the creation of this new bank is meant to create a rivalry
against the Asian Development Bank (ADB) or the World Bank.’105

Although the degree of competition among these institutions could, of course, grow over
time, China has assiduously sought to avoid perceptions that the AIIB represents a direct
challenge to existing MDBs, having actively courted the membership of self-perceived
upholders of the liberal order. In this way, China’s strategy conforms closely to a pattern of
‘strategic restraint’, wherein international institutions are used to reduce fears of China’s rise
and reassure lesser states of China’s commitments.106 Moreover, the AIIB has adopted norms,
rules, and procedures that are much closer to global standards than those China practices in
its bilateral aid programmes. Thus, China both dilutes its potential influence and accepts
deeper constraints by redirecting aid resources through multilateral channels.

The design of the AIIB also suggests that China left potential relative gains on the bargaining
table by accepting conditions less favourable than might be expected in view of its financial
weight in the organisation. Having contributed one-third of the initial capital (33.4%), China’s
voting weight is 28.5%.107

101
Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank, ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank Subscriptions and Voting
Power of Member Countries’, 22 September, 2016, https://www.aiib.org/en/about-aiib/who-we-
are/membership-status/.content/index/_download/20160930035841674.pdf.
102
Sam Fleming, ‘AIIB and World Bank to World on Joint Projects’, Financial Times, 15 April, 2016,
https://www.ft.com/content/3995f790-01b0-11e6-ac98-3c15a1aa2e62; Hameiri and Jones, ‘China
Challenges Global Governance?’.
103
Indeed, former World Bank official Natalie Lichtenstein drafted the AIIB’s Articles of Agreement while
another former World Bank staffer, Stephen Lintner, designed the AIIB’s environmental and social
framework. Tamar Gutner, ‘AIIB: Is the Chinese-led Development Bank a Role Model?’, Council on Foreign
Relations, 25 June, 2018, https://www.cfr.org/blog/aiib-chinese-led-development-bank-role-model.
104
Perlez, ‘China Creates a World Bank of its Own, and the U.S. Balks’.
105
Tabita Diela and Iwan Subarkah, ‘AIIB President Dismisses Accusations of Rivalry with ADB, World Bank’,
Jakarta Globe, 11 May, 2017, https://jakartaglobe.id/economy/aiib-president-dismisses-accusations-rivalry-
adb-world-bank/.
106
Chen and Liu, ‘Granting Reassurance while Posing Challenge’; G. John Ikenberry, After Victory:
Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order after Major Wars (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 2001).
107
Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank, ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank Subscriptions and Voting
Power of Member Countries’.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 80
Although this will initially ensure China’s veto power over key decisions (for which a 75%
supermajority is required), Chinese authorities have intimated their disinclination to maintain
veto power as new Member States gradually dilute China’s voting share.108 Another key
indicator is the greater number of ‘basic’ votes allocated on a one-state, one-vote basis.109 As
with other development banks, AIIB founder members’ votes consist of basic votes, share
votes, and bonus votes. Whereas basic votes make up only 5.55% of World Bank (IBRD) voting
shares, in the AIIB they account for 12%.110 This gives poorer Member States a much bigger
role than in other banks.

Although many observers initially expected loans to be denominated in RMB,111 in keeping


with China’s stated goal to diversify global financial flows, the AIIB will in fact conduct all
transactions in US dollars (although Chinese currency transactions may be introduced over
time).112 Rather than limiting membership to Asian countries, moreover, all World Bank and
ADB members are eligible, and already includes a number of major European powers.113 China
has also stated that the United States and Japan are welcome to join, despite both countries’
initially negative attitudes towards the AIIB’s creation, and the fact that US and/or Japanese
membership would dilute Chinese sway.

Distributive institutionalism is consistent with China’s frustrated efforts to gain greater voting
power within existing MDBs, with its consequent decision to sponsor the AIIB, and with the US
resistance to these moves. Yet China has exercised a degree of restraint patently incompatible
with the assumptions of relative-gains seeking. Indeed, Beijing has sought to balance a
message of growing strength and leadership with steps designed to offer reassurance of
benign intent.114 China’s strategy is not to replace existing institutions but rather to ensure
greater ‘portfolio diversification’ across institutional platforms.115 In contrast to the
predictions of power-based institutionalism, China has made greater

108
Inclusive Development International, Making Inroads, p. 24. Even while China retains voting power in
excess of 25%, AIIB President Jin Liqun has stated that China has no plans to wield its veto power. See
Gutner, ‘AIIB: Is the Chinese-led Development Bank a Role Model?’
109
Marina Larionova and Andrei Vladimirovich Shelepov, ‘Potential Role of the New Development Bank and
Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank in the Global Financial System’, Vestnik RUDN. International Relations,
Vol. 16, No. 4 (2016), p. 706.
110
Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank, ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank Subscriptions and Voting
Power of Member Countries’; World Bank, ‘Allocation of Votes by Organization’ (2018),
http://www.worldbank.org/en/about/leadership/votingpowers.
111
Chow, ‘Why China Established the Asia Infrastructure Investment Bank’, pp. 1295–6.
112
Inclusive Development International, Making Inroads, p. 15.
113
As of this writing, the number of AIIB Member States stands at 87.
114
Miller, China’s Asian Dream, p. 36; Chen and Liu, ‘Granting Reassurance while Posing Challenge’, p. 4.
115
Evan Feigenbaum, ‘Reluctant Stakeholder: Why China’s Highly Strategic Brand of Revisionism is More
Challenging Than Washington Thinks’, 27 April, 2018, https://carne

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 81
accommodations of the pre-existing MDB regime (especially in institutional design and
cooperation with other MDBs) than a purely distributive strategy would suggest.

Functionalist institutionalism and distributive institutionalism each offer useful insights into
China’s decision to sponsor the AIIB, although the latter theory cannot account for the degree
of Chinese restraint as regards seeking relative gains. Nonetheless, neither variant of rational
institutionalism addresses important questions about the qualitative focus off the AIIB and the
type of development it seeks to promote, which is critical to the AIIB’s ultimate impact on the
distinctly liberal elements of international order. To address this broader question, we need to
examine the social purposes underlying Chinese strategic behaviour.

AIIB’s Social Purpose: Reproducing or Challenging Liberalism?

As has been widely recognised, the formal institutional structure of the AIIB closely models
the format of established MDBs.116 AIIB’s tripartite governance structure of President and
staff, Board of Directors, and Board of Governors reflects the typical MDB structure. Although,
in contrast to the World Bank and the ADB, the Board of Directors is non-resident, which some
have suggested would limit management oversight,117 this is not an unprecedented
innovation, the Development Bank of Latin America having adopted it in 1970. The AIIB’s
policy of capping the shares of ‘non-regional’ members is also in line with other regional
development banks.

Despite these clear signs of institutional isomorphism,118 Obama administration officials and
other critics expressed concern that the AIIB would diverge substantively from the
development policies and practices of established MDBs.119 Particular concern surrounded
policy conditionality and transparency and anti-corruption, accountability, and environmental
and labour standards.120 There were concerns that its focus on efficiency might motivate the
AIIB to privilege

gieendowment.org/2018/04/27/reluctant-stakeholder-why-china-s-highly-strategic-brand-of-revisionism-is-
more-challenging-than-washington-thinks-pub-76213.
116
Chin, ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’; Hameiri and Jones, ‘China Challenges Global Governance?’;
Wilson, ‘The Evolution of China’s Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’.
117
Chow, ‘Why China Established the Asia Infrastructure Investment Bank’, p. 1288.
118
Chin, ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’.
119
Nicholas Watt, Paul Lewis, and Tania Branigan, ‘US Anger at Britain Joining Chinese-led Investment Bank
AIIB’, The Guardian, 13 March, 2015, https://www.theguardian.com/usnews/2015/mar/13/white-house-
pointedly-asks-uk-to-use-its-voice-as-part-of-chinese-ledbank.
120
European Political Strategy Centre, ‘The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, EPSC Strategic Notes,
April 2015, https://ec.europa.eu/epsc/publications/strategic-notes/asian-infrastructure-investment-
bank_en; Rohini Kamal and Kevin Gallagher, ‘China Goes Global with Development Banks’, Bretton Woods
Project, April 2016, p. 4; Wang Hongying, ‘New Multilateral Development Banks: Opportunities and
Challenges for Global Governance’, in Miles Kahler, ed., Global Order and the New Regionalism (New York:
Council on Foreign Relations, 2016), p. 49; Weaver, ‘The Rise of China: Continuity or Change’, p. 427; Martin

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 82
quick turnarounds over rigorous safeguards, human rights protection, and promotion of ‘good
governance’,121 which would constitute a significant challenge to the LIO’s established norms
in the area of multilateral development finance.

However, the AIIB has in many respects (so far) conformed to the global norms and practices
of existing MDBs. This fits the overall picture of China’s socialisation into the established LIO.
AIIB staff and Chinese government officials have consistently signalled the commitment to
ensure that the AIIB’s lending practices are in line with global norms.122 At its outset, the bank
drew up a ‘Social and Environmental Framework’, consulted with lender governments and
NGOs, and even hired the World Bank’s former senior technical adviser on safeguard
policies.123 The normative framework within which this Chinese-led institution presents itself
hews remarkably closely to liberal ideas and norms—even though the operation of such
norms is only faintly evident in Chinese domestic society.124

Moreover, having relied heavily on co-financing with established MDBs, the AIIB is bound to
follow the conditions of legacy MDBs.125 It is too early to judge whether this policy framework
will translate into compliant behaviour in the long run. But paper compliance with and
conformity to global models has indeed been secured, in keeping with World Society
expectations. This would imply parallels with China’s broader engagement in global economic
governance. Entry to the World Trade Organisation (WTO) in 2001 compelled China’s revision
of many laws and institutions to meet WTO standards.126 The PRC has imported legal
standards and regulations relating to such areas as disability, environment, and anti-
corruption reforms that drew upon relevant United Nations conventions.127 Indeed, the
Chinese government can reap reputational gains solely to the extent

Weiss, Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB) (Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service, 2017),
p. 4.
121
Chow, ‘Why China Established the Asia Infrastructure Investment Bank’; Joshua Rosenzweig, ‘The AIIB
and Human Rights’, 24 June, 2016, https://thediplomat.com/2016/06/the-aiib-and-human-rights/.
122
AIIB President Jin Liqun pledged that ‘we go by international best standards.’ Quoted in Adva Saldinger,
‘AIIB President Jin Liqun: “We’re Lean, Clean and Green, but Not Mean”’, Devex, 26 April, 2017,
https://www.devex.com/news/aiib-president-jin-liqun-we-re-lean-clean-and-green-but-not-mean-90140.
See also Netherland’s statement at the 2016 AIIB Board of Governors meeting, Netherlands, ‘Statement at
the Annual Meeting of the Board of Governors’, Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank, 25-26 June, 2016, p.
46.https://www.aiib.org/en/about-aiib/governance/board-
governors/.content/index/_download/20160913083104365.pdf.
123
Carey et al. ‘Multilateral Development Banks in the 21st Century’, p. 6.
124
Wilson, ‘The Evolution of China’s Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’.
125
Hameiri and Jones, ‘China Challenges Global Governance?’, pp. 576–8; Weiss, Asian Infrastructure
Investment Bank (AIIB), p. 13.
126
Mingtao Shi, ‘China and International Institutions International Order Beyond Formal Rules?’
International Journal of China Studies, Vol. 4, No. 3 (2017), p. 443.
127
Gregory Chin and Ramesh Thakur, ‘Will China Change the Rules of Global Order?’ The Washington
Quarterly, Vol. 33, No. 4 (2010), pp. 119–38.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 83
whereby AIIB policies resonate with widely held perceptions of appropriateness.128 In line with
the concept of ‘laundering’ activities via independent and impartial international
organisations, this serves an important role in garnering acceptance and legitimacy for
projects that would otherwise be funded through bilateral aid: ‘States may prefer
development assistance from an independent financial institution over direct aid from
another state, especially a former colonial power or one seeking political influence.’129

In addition to institutional legitimacy and prestige, China gains benefits from ensuring that the
AIIB conforms to perceived ‘best practices’ within the global development regime. First, the
AIIB may serve as another lever for the Chinese leadership to push Chinese state-owned
enterprises (SOEs) towards higher standards of environmental quality, transparency, honesty,
and efficiency, as China looks to move up the economic value chain. International
commitments can, thus, be used to promote reforms both at home and in China’s overseas
investments.130 Many of the practices that have evoked the most serious criticism of Chinese
SOEs, with regard to their investments abroad, are neither products of strategic direction nor
efforts to challenge liberal norms, but rather the result of an increasingly fragmented state
authority and growing SOE autonomy in China.131 Chinese authorities may see the AIIB as a
vehicle through which to learn the best practices for setting and bringing into effect high
standards in disciplining overseas aid and investment projects. Yet, as Hameiri and Jones
note,132 the small size of the AIIB portfolio relative to China’s overall foreign aid and
investment may limit its broader impact.

Secondly, the Chinese leadership has recognised the benefits accruing to the United States
through its centrality within inter- and trans-governmental networks and institutions.133 In the
contemporary international system, governmental elites are ever more integrated at an
international level, forming trans-governmental networks and a global bureaucracy wherein
the international-domestic dichotomy has broken down, making them increasingly significant
in the shaping of governance outcomes.134 This internationalisation of state functions has
closely followed the internationalisation of production, consumption,

128
Reilly, ‘A Norm-Taker or a Norm-Maker?’, p. 72.
129
Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, ‘Why States Act through Formal International Organizations’,
Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (1998), pp. 3–32. Miller, China’s Asian Dream, pp. 15, 33;
Hameiri and Jones, ‘China Challenges Global Governance?’.
130
Gu Bin, ‘Chinese Multilateralism in the AIIB’, Journal of International Economic Law, Vol. 20, No. 1 (2017),
pp. 145–6.
131
Hameiri and Jones, ‘China Challenges Global Governance?’.
132
Ibid., p. 593.
133
Pang Xun, Liu Lida, and Stephanie Ma, ‘China’s Network Strategy for Seeking Great Power Status’, Chinese
Journal of International Politics, Vol. 10, No. 1 (2017), pp. 1–29.
134
Stephen Gill and A. Claire Cutler, New Constitutionalism and World Order (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2014); Nico Krisch and Benedict Kingsbury, ‘Introduction: Global Governance and Global
Administrative Law in the International Legal Order’,

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 84
and exchange.135 As Ruban Gonzalez-Vicente emphasises, the internationalisation of the
Chinese state under the leadership of the Communist Party of China has unfolded subsequent
to the process whereby former communist ministries were transformed into SOEs, resulting
not in a liberal market economy but rather in an ‘entrepreneurial state’ that exercises control
over corporations with Fortune 500 rankings and which has deep commitments to
international markets.136

From the Chinese leadership’s perspective, national power relates to the placement of
Chinese elites in influential global social networks. Yet until now, such elites have remained
largely outside such networks.137 Consequently, there is evidence that the Chinese
government seeks to ‘increase its global social power through networking with other
prominent countries’ and building China-centred multilateral institutions.138 The AIIB provides
one vehicle for thickening the connections between relatively insulated state-party-corporate
networks and the broader transnational networks of corporate elites, government officials, IO
staff, and technical experts that will come together through AIIB projects.

Yet these networks are typically organised around sets of shared epistemic and normative
assumptions and knowledge, and tighter connections may serve as mechanisms for further
socialising key Chinese participants.139 Particularly, since Jiang Zemin’s legitimation of the
Chinese business class in 2002, the interaction of the Chinese party-state model with
international standards has resulted in a ‘growing permeability of ideologies in the Chinese
state.’140 This highlights the double-edged nature of the AIIB from China’s perspective:
constructing China-centred institutions not only builds Chinese social and relational power but
also serves to socialise Chinese elites into norms that stand in tension with Chinese domestic
structures.141

European Journal of International Law, Vol. 17, No. 1 (2006), pp. 1–13; Anne-Marie Slaughter, A New World
Order (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2004).
135
Robert W. Cox, ‘Social Forces, States and World Orders: Beyond International Relations Theory’,
Millennium, Vol. 10, No. 2 (1981), pp. 144–9.
136
Ruben Gonzalez-Vicente, ‘The Internationalization of the Chinese State’, Political Geography, Vol. 30, No.
7 (2011), pp. 402–11.
137
William K. Carroll and Colin Carson, The Making of a Transnational Capitalist Class: Corporate Power in
the Twenty-first Century (London and New York: Zed, 2010); Nana´ de Graaff, ‘Oil Elite Networks in a
Transforming Global Oil Market’, International Journal of Comparative Sociology, Vol. 53, No. 4 (2012), pp.
275–97.
138
Pang, Liu and Ma, ‘China’s Network Strategy for Seeking Great Power Status’; Nana´ de Graaff and
Baastian van Apeldoorn, ‘US Elite Power and the Rise of Statist Chinese Elites in Global Markets’,
International Politics, Vol. 54, No. 3 (2017), pp. 338–55; Nana´ de Graaff and Baastian van Apeldoorn, ‘US-
China Relations and the Liberal World Order: Contending Elites, Colliding Visions?’, International Affairs, Vol.
94, No. 1 (2018), pp. 113–31.
139
Stephen, ‘Rising Powers, Global Capitalism and Liberal Global Governance’, p. 920.
140
Gonzalez-Vicente, ‘The Internationalization of the Chinese State’, p. 405.
141
Jonge, ‘Perspectives on the Emerging Role of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 85
Thirdly, there also exist material incentives to conform to the pre-existing norms of the
multilateral development aid regime. Like other MDBs, the AIIB will raise funds by issuing
bonds on commercial markets, and investors will give weight to the ratings that credit rating
agencies place upon these bonds. This means that the AIIB must meet the standards of
governance that are in line with what such agencies define as international best practices, as
they will not otherwise issue favourable ratings.142

In general, China’s behaviour with respect to the AIIB appears relatively consistent with the
idea that China and other states are under strong socialisation pressure to conform to global
norms, especially when they seek buy-in for new international institutions from other states.
Nevertheless, it is unclear exactly how deep such socialisation has gone.143 Despite the striking
institutional isomorphism of the AIIB vis-à-vis established MDBs, our analysis implies that the
AIIB indeed bears certain hallmarks of China’s particular social order, which differentiate it
from the social purpose of the LIO.

First, the AIIB’s Articles of Agreement stipulate that it will take a politically neutral approach.
This at least differentiates the AIIB from explicitly liberal MDBs, such as the European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), which Western and former Soviet-aligned countries
set up in the aftermath of the Cold War and which aligned much more closely to the policy
preferences, beliefs, and resources of legitimacy of Western countries.144 In contrast to the
overtly liberal EBRD, the AIIB’s Articles of Agreement stipulate that, ‘The Bank, its President,
officers and staff shall not interfere in the political affairs of any member, nor shall they be
influenced in their decisions by the political character of the member concerned. Only
economic considerations shall be relevant to their decisions.’145 The Chinese government is
deeply wary of Western attempts to use human rights and limitations on sovereignty as a
political tool and has

142
Ikenberry and Lim, ‘China’s Emerging Institutional Statecraft’, pp. 14–5; Sekine, ‘Aims and Prospects of
the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, p. 11.
143
He Kai and Feng Huiyun, ‘Transcending Rationalism and Constructivism: Chinese Leaders’ Operational
Codes, Socialization Processes, and Multilateralism after the Cold War’, European Political Science Review,
Vol. 7, No. 3 (2015), p. 405; Sekine, ‘Aims and Prospects of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’.
144
Steven Weber, ‘Origins of the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development’, International
Organisation, Vol. 48, No. 1 (1994), p. 1. According to its establishing agreement, the EBRD is ‘Committed to
the fundamental principles of multiparty democracy, the rule of law, respect for human rights and market
economics’, and its Article 1 commits the bank ‘to foster the transition towards open market-oriented
economies and to promote private and entrepreneurial initiatives. . .’. EBRD, Agreement Establishing the
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 29 May, 1990,
http://www.ebrd.com/news/publications/institutional-documents/basic-documents-of-the-ebrd.html.
145
AIIB, Articles of Agreement, www.aiib.org/en/about-aiib/basic-documents/_download/articles-of-
agreement/basic_document_english-bank_articles_of_agreement.pdf.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 86
consequently espoused a broader doctrine of non-interference in the affairs of other
countries.146 As the Information Office of the State Council of China explains:

China has firmly opposed to [sic] any country making use of the issue of human rights to
sell its own values, ideology, political standards and mode of development, and to [sic] any
country interfering in the internal affairs of other countries on the pretext of human rights,
the internal affairs of developing countries in particular, and so hurting the sovereignty
and dignity of many developing countries. […] China has always maintained that human
rights are essentially matters within the domestic jurisdiction of a country. Respect for
each country’s sovereignty and non-interference in internal affairs are universally
recognized principles of international law, which are applicable to all fields of international
relations, and of course applicable to the field of human rights as well.147

By extending Chinese influence through a formal multilateral organisation committed to the


doctrine of non-interference, the AIIB strengthens the Chinese government’s ability to raise
this normative challenge to the LIO. AIIB officials have not only pledged to uphold existing
standards of multilateral development lending but have also suggested a ‘more business-like
approach’, with a lesser focus on poverty reduction and promotion of political and social
change.148 China’s overriding message has been to defend sovereignty, pluralism, and diversity
in political and economic institutions against perceived efforts by the United States to impose
a singular, universal model. In this respect, China presents a challenge to the LIO, not by
championing a ready-made alternative, but by rejecting political and economic uniformity,
and advancing a norm of international diversity. In keeping with this approach, China has also
largely eschewed the attachment of political or economic conditions to its bilateral foreign
assistance.149

Even if the AIIB offers only slightly more lenient terms on its loans than established MDBs, it is
the relative absence of conditions that creates worries in certain quarters that existing
development institutions and donor countries will find insisting upon maintaining their
particular standards difficult when bargaining with recipient countries if a more forgiving
alternative is available.150 By stoking the trend towards institutional proliferation, the creation
of the AIIB ushers in an ‘age of choice’ wherein borrowing countries can pick and choose.151
Indeed, there

146
Peng Zhongzhou and Sow Keat Tok, ‘The AIIB and China’s Normative Power in International Financial
Governance Structure’, Chinese Political Science Review, Vol. 1, No. 4 (2016), pp. 73–53.
147
As cited in Randall Peerenboom, ‘Assessing Human Rights in China: Why the Double Standard?’, Cornell
International Law Journal, Vol. 38, No. 1 (2005), p. 82.
148
Chin, ‘Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’, pp. 20–21; Wang, ‘New Multilateral Development Banks’.
149
A significant exception is that China insists that aid recipients adopt a One-China policy with respect to
Taiwan.
150
Subacchi, ‘The AIIB Is a Threat to Global Economic Governance’.
151
Prizzon, Greenhill and Mustapha, ‘An “Age of Choice” for External Development Finance?’.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 87
is evidence that the governments of many of the least developed countries have chosen more
expensive development finance options that carry fewer conditions.152 Although the AIIB did,
in its early days, co-finance and, therefore, conform to existing standards, a greater
institutional choice would make promoting a particular development model more difficult for
any country in the long run. If this holds, then the AIIB and other new ‘counter-institutional’
initiatives may erode the efficacy of certain levers of liberal influence in the global political
economy.

Secondly, as social order models would expect, the focus on infrastructure is itself reflective of
China’s distinctive political and economic system, implying a more subtle path whereby
China’s internal order is becoming externalised in its interaction with global processes.153
China has leaned heavily upon infrastructure-led development, even by comparison with
other East Asian countries that placed infrastructure at the centre of their economic
development strategies. China has also supported existing multilateral institutions’ greater
focus on infrastructure.154 Infrastructure-led development typically privileges states over
markets. Most infrastructure projects are public-owned, and Chinese SOEs operating in
infrastructural sectors have expanded overseas investment assets to more than $900
billion.155 In short, the spread of infrastructure-led development models provides a
mechanism for strengthening the legitimacy and centrality of China’s own political economy
within the global order, extends Chinese influence,156 and provides opportunities that
strengthen China’s state-owned sector.

152
Ibid.
153
Jonge, ‘Perspectives on the Emerging Role of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank’.
154
Morten Ougaard, ‘The Transnational State and the Infrastructure Push’, New Political Economy, Vol. 23,
No. 1 (2018), pp. 128–44.
155
Chen Aizhuand Matthew Miller, ‘Overseas Assets Held by China’s Centrally Owned Firms Top $900
Billion’, 18 October, 2017, https://www.reuters.com/article/us-china-congress-soes/overseas-assets-held-
by-chinas-centrally-owned-firms-top-900-billion-idUSKBN1CN0UE; Chow, ‘Why China Established the Asia
Infrastructure Investment Bank’, pp. 1292–5. Note that to date only three Chinese SEOs have won major AIIB
contracts (most of which have been associated thus far with projects co-sponsored with the World Bank or
the ADB). Private communications with RWR Advisory Group, https://www.rwradvisory.com.
156
One form of influence arises from debt-dependence. Considering only extreme cases, one study has
identified 10–15 countries that ‘could suffer from debt distress due to future BRI-related financing’. John
Hurley, Scott Morris and Gailyn Portelance, ‘Examining the Debt Implications of the Belt and Road Initiative
from a Policy Perspective’, Center for Global Development Policy Paper, Vol. 121 (2018), p. 11. Through BRI,
China is also gaining control over major infrastructure projects in other countries through ownership, lease
or management arrangements.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 88
Ultimately, this bolsters the control of the ruling Communist Party157 and rewards members of
the governing coalition at the heart of China’s political order.158

It is perhaps no surprise, then, that the AIIB and the BRI may well encourage other countries in
the region to pursue a similar path, led by Chinese finance, expertise, and contracts.159 Chin
and Thakur observe that although China attaches no mandatory conditions, it does advise
recipients to emphasise ‘state support for core industries, foreign exchange management,
(and) central bank direction of capital’.160 In the face of opposition from Western businesses
and certain governments, China has often sought to legitimise the role of SOEs in economic
development, for example, by persuading the BRICS countries to ‘acknowledge the important
role that State Owned Companies (SOCs) play in the economy…’.161 And China has
demonstrated growing confidence that its social model ‘offers a new option for other
countries and nations who want to speed up their development while preserving their
independence’.162 These ideas and practices promote a shift towards greater state control and
a loosening of liberal policy conditionality.

To be sure, the spread of a ‘China model’ and the strengthening of economic networks
centred upon China itself do not signal an intention to undermine or replace the existing LIO.
In the design and early operations of the AIIB, China has, contrary to initial predictions, largely
supported efforts to collaborate with existing development banks and to import most of the
rules, norms, and standards associated with the current aid regime. China is itself heavily
entwined with global markets and relies upon a strong private sector.

Moreover, the very fact that China prefers state-to-state relations and limits its engagements
with the broader civil society indeed impedes the transfer of Chinese norms and knowledge
via aid projects. In contrast, not only do Western aid

157
Huang Yasheng, Capitalism with Chinese Characteristics: Entrepreneurship and the State (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2010).
158
Lin Li-wen and Curtis Milhaupt, ‘We Are the (National) Champions: Understanding the Mechanisms of
State Capitalism in China’, Stanford Law Review, Vol. 65, No.4 (2013), pp. 697–759; Tan Bann-Seng and
Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, ‘Does Chinese Foreign Aid Giving Differ from Other Donor Nations?’, 18 January,
2013, https://www.princeton.edu/politics/about/file-repository/public/Chinese-Foreign-Aid_BdM3_Bueno-
PDF.pdf.
159
Angela Stanzel, Nade`ge Rolland, Jabin Jacob, and Melanie Hart, ‘Grand Designs: Does China Have a
“Grand Strategy”?’, European Council on Foreign Relations, 18 October, 2017,
https://www.ecfr.eu/publications/summary/grands_designs_does_china_have_a_grand_strategy.
160
Chin and Thakur, ‘Will China Change the Rules of Global Order?’, p. 125.
161
BRICS, ‘eThekwini Declaration and Action Plan’, 27 March, 2013,
https://www.brics2017.org/English/Documents/Summit/201701/t20170125_1407.html.
162
Xi Jinping, ‘Secure a Decisive Victory in Building a Moderately Prosperous Society in All Respects and
Strive for the Great Success of Socialism with Chinese Characteristics for a New Era’, delivered at the 19th
National Congress of the Communist Party of China, 18 October, 2017, p. 9,
http://www.xinhuanet.com/english/download/Xi_Jinping’s_report_at_19th_CPC_National_Congress.pdf.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 89
agencies and private firms penetrate recipient societies more deeply, but Western NGOs also
‘train and socialise local NGOs in developing nations … teaching a “Western model” of state-
society relations, whereby NGOs act as a watchdog and are sometimes antagonistic to the
government’.163 As Chinese government-organised NGOs increasingly follow Chinese aid and
investment, however, this asymmetry could change.164

Conclusion

As a key element of China’s new institutional initiatives, the AIIB provides an important
medium for an assessment of the impact of China’s rise on the LIO as the latter faces renewed
challenges from within. The complex forces currently driving international change belie simple
predictions about the future of the LIO. In this article, we have argued that in order to render
judgements about China’s relationship to the LIO, it is necessary not only to analyse the AIIB
using the tools of state-centric IR theory but also to employ societal approaches to understand
its social purpose.

Our empirical findings are two-fold. First, both functional efficiencies and relative power
dynamics appear to have played a role in China’s decision to create the AIIB. The AIIB can
neither be attributed to simple gains-seeking nor to straightforward power politics. It is the
two in combination that generate institutional change. Secondly, we find evidence in the AIIB
of a remarkable level of conformity to existing norms and institutional models, implying a
strong role for socialisation dynamics within the LIO in the issue area of multilateral
development financing. Nonetheless, it is hard to judge how deep or lasting such socialisation
really is, and certain features of the AIIB also reflect the growing global presence of China’s
particular political-economic order.

The AIIB’s focus on infrastructure-led development is itself an externalisation of China’s


domestic political-economic model, much as changes in the US political–economic situation
have shaped the World Bank and UN agencies’ agendas over previous decades.165 This model
favours planning and state-ownership, and sees poverty reduction as a result of development,
rather than the other way around. China’s political order, based upon Leninist principles,
stands in stark contrast to Western liberal democracy, and China’s economy still retains strong
elements of state guidance. Yet China has been profoundly changed over the past four
decades through a process of ever deeper integration into a pre-existing liberal order. As a
result, a hybrid social order has emerged which combines state-led development with
entrepreneurial markets that relate to one another

163
Reza Hasmath, ‘China’s NGOs Go Global’, 23 March, 2016, https://thediplomat.com/2016/03/chinas-
ngos-go-global/.
164
Ibid.
165
Mark Mazower, Governing the World: The History of an Idea (London: Penguin, 2012), pp. 273–99.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 90
‘compensatory, even seemingly contradictory fashion’.166 These internal tensions are mirrored
by the frictions and mutual dependencies that exist between China’s hybrid social order and
the LIO. They also appear to be built into the AIIB itself, so reflecting the somewhat
contradictory influences of the global norms embedded in the LIO, and the structural features
of China’s hybrid social order.

One important caveat about our findings is that, in comparison to other Chinese-led
institutions, the AIIB may qualify as the least likely case of a substantive challenge to the LIO
for two key reasons: membership composition and issue area characteristics. First, China
made important concessions to win the participation of many developed countries. The
Chinese approach to international institution building, therefore, is somewhat diluted with
regard to the AIIB. The bank’s membership composition may, hence, have a constraining
influence on departures from the liberal social purpose when compared to regional
organisations that exclude non-regional members. Secondly, the policy field of development
banking may be one wherein—compared to other policy fields such as internet governance or
human rights—the normative divergence between China and the LIO is less pronounced. This
suggests the need for more research into the social purposes of China’s other multilateral
initiatives and institutions.

The AIIB and China’s new institutional initiatives may not constitute a ‘grand ideological
alternative to a liberal international order’.167 Nor do they—in the words of German Foreign
Minister Sigmar Gabriel—represent an effort ‘to put a Chinese stamp on the world and
impose a Chinese system’.168 But this may be beside the point. The creation of new
institutions may address functional deficiencies of long-established incumbent institutions and
provide a mechanism for China to subvert the US institutional privileges. At the same time, the
LIO’s distinctly liberal features may be eroded more effectively by going around them—either
bilaterally, as in the case of the hub-and-spokes investment patterns that dominate China’s
Belt and Road Initiative, or by adopting new international institutions that are indifferent to
core liberal ideas, as in the case of AIIB. Even without openly challenging the LIO, therefore,
the AIIB lends it Chinese characteristics.

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge helpful comments on earlier versions of this article from Tobias ten
Brink, Sandra Destradi, Nana de Graaff, Inderjeet Parmar, the reviewers from CJIP, and
participants in a research colloquium at the WZB Berlin Social Science Center.

166
McNally, ‘Sino-Capitalism’, p. 754.
167
Ikenberry, ‘The End of Liberal International Order?’, p. 23.
168
Steven Erlanger, ‘Europe Once Saw Xi Jinping as a Hedge Against Trump. Not Anymore’, The New York
Times, 4 March, 2018, https://www.nytimes.com/2018/03/04/world/europe/europe-china-xi-trump-
trade.html.

Originally published in:


The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol 12 (2019), Iss. 1, p. 91

You might also like