Aligning Fiscal Policy With The Circular Economy Roadmap in Finland Extax Sitra GBE IEEP Final Report Final-08-01-19
Aligning Fiscal Policy With The Circular Economy Roadmap in Finland Extax Sitra GBE IEEP Final Report Final-08-01-19
Aligning Fiscal Policy With The Circular Economy Roadmap in Finland Extax Sitra GBE IEEP Final Report Final-08-01-19
January 2019
Page | 1
Ó Authors and Sitra 2018
Authors:
Eero Yrjö-Koskinen and Sarianne Tikkanen, Green Budget Europe
Femke Groothuis and Valérie van de Luitgaarden, The Ex’tax Project
Emma Watkins, Institute for European Environmental Policy
Hector Pollitt, Cambridge Econometrics
Reference:
Green Budget Europe, The Ex’tax Project, Institute for European Environmental Policy,
Cambridge Econometrics (2018): Aligning Fiscal Policy with the Circular Economy Roadmap
in Finland.
Further information:
Eero Yrjö-Koskinen, tel: +358 50 347 8778, email: [email protected]
Page | 2
CONTENT
1. Circular Economy Goals in Finland ............................................................................... 8
1.1. National road map to a circular economy ......................................................................... 8
1.2. Government programme and action plan for a circular economy ................................... 10
1.3. Main goals in the transition towards a carbon-neutral circular economy ........................ 13
6. Conclusions and proposals for next steps to achieve circular economy objectives ... 114
Appendix 1: Environmental and labour taxation and subsidies in Finland....................... 115
Appendix 2: E3ME .......................................................................................................... 127
Page | 4 FOREWORD
This document is the final report on the findings and results of the project Best Practices in the
Promotion of Circular Economy in Finland. The project was funded by the Finnish Innovation
Fund (Sitra) and carried out by Green Budget Europe (GBE) as head of the consortium, in
collaboration with the Institute for European Environmental Policy (IEEP) and the Ex’tax
Project Foundation. The project started in December 2017 and was completed in December
2018.
The main goal of the project was to promote the implementation of the Finnish national road
map to a circular economy by providing policy options and practical instruments on how to
reach circular economy goals in Finland. The project was divided into two parts. Firstly, it
identified tax options and other economic instruments together with best practices to promote
circular economy goals. Secondly, it presented an ambitious scenario for green fiscal reform,
which aligns fiscal policy with carbon-neutral circular economy objectives. In addition, it
assessed through modelling some of the potential economic, environmental and social impacts
of the particular green fiscal reform scenario. Finally, it provided concrete examples of best
practice in other market-based instruments applied in Europe to achieve these goals.
The steering group of the project held two workshops and regular meetings to ensure the timely
development of the scenario and appropriate instruments. It used the services of Cambridge
Econometrics to evaluate the fiscal, macro-economic and environmental impacts of the
proposed tax measures. The project held several meetings with Finnish ministries and industry
groups to consult local experts and interest groups on the possible implications, such as
sectoral competitiveness issues, of the proposed measures. Based on their feedback, some
of the proposed measures were revised before modelling and presenting them in the final
report.
The Finnish Government, together with the public and business sectors, is highly committed
to moving towards a society based on circular economy. However, a major obstacle towards
this transition is that the current regulatory system is in many cases promoting linear economy
and prohibiting the change to circularity. Mainstreaming of the circular economy requires a
regulatory system, which promotes the corresponding business models, such as service-
based business, sustainable consumption patterns, recycling, and the promotion of recycling
and sharing practices.
Taxation, and especially its structure, has a very strong steering impact on the whole society.
The project proposes to use fiscal instruments to promote carbon-neutral circular economy
goals. A green budget reform, which means shifting taxation from labour to resource use and
pollution, could be one of the key drivers in achieving carbon neutrality and circular economy
objectives.
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Page | 5
Many countries are considering new policies to support the transition to a low-carbon circular
economy. This study was initiated to
a) Identify best practices of market-based instruments in EU Member States to enhance
the circular economy;
b) Identify options for phasing out of environmentally harmful subsidies in Finland;
c) Study the potential of environmental fiscal reform (shifting the tax burden from labour
to natural resource use); and
d) Provide an overview of potential measures and economic instruments in the Finnish
context to promote the objectives of a carbon-neutral circular economy.
The study is based on the Finnish roadmap to a circular economy 2016-2025, published by
Sitra in 2016 with relevant ministries and other stakeholders. Following the rationale of the
road map, the following objectives were studied in further detail:
§ Sustainable food systems: using sustainable crop production, organic farming, short
supply chains, and nutrient recycling;
§ Forest-based loops: recycling of the forest industry’s side streams, processed
products other than pulp and paper, wood construction and wooden furniture,
substituting fossil resources and using more wood-based textiles;
§ Technical loops: minimising the need for virgin raw materials by lengthening product
life cycles through redesign, reuse, recycling, repair and maintenance, promoting the
use of secondary materials and remanufacturing by pricing the external costs of virgin
raw materials; and
§ Carbon-neutral transport and logistics: moving beyond fossil-fuels, improving
service-based transport systems, ending fossil fuel use in private cars by 2040,
promoting sustainable biofuels, replacing fossil fuels with renewable and non-fossil
alternatives, optimising transport routes and material flows, and promoting public
transport.
The study provides a series of fiscal and other instruments to promote these carbon-neutral
circular economy objectives. The project also reviewed the Finnish tax system to define
measures to improve resource and energy efficiency, while reducing labour taxes to ensure
fiscal neutrality and boost employment.
Finland has relatively high labour taxation compared with other EU Member States and OECD
countries. When comparing the tax wedge1, Finland occupied the second highest position
among the OECD countries in 2016. The OECD has advised Finland to reduce the tax burden
1
The tax wedge is defined as the ratio between the amount of taxes paid by an average single worker and the
corresponding total labour cost for the employer. The average tax wedge measures the extent to which tax on
labour income discourages employment. (OECD)
on labour, increase environmentally-related taxes and phase out environmentally harmful
Page | 6
subsidies.2 A reduction in labour taxes is crucial to enable labour and knowledge intensive
business models, such as reuse, recycling, repair and maintenance, redesign of supply chains
and products, needed for a circular economy.
The following measures were included in the scenario, which was modelled by Cambridge
Econometrics in the E3ME model:
§ Air pollution: A carbon price floor;
§ Fossil fuels: Removal of the diesel subsidies (transport sector); removal of the light
fuel oil subsidy; removal of the peat tax subsidy; taxation of non-energy use of fossil
fuels (mineral oils and other fossil material used in plastics and other chemical
industry);
§ Energy: Electricity tax increase for bulk users and removal of the subsidy for energy-
intensive industries;
§ Transport related taxes: Air passengers and air freight taxes;
§ Waste related taxes: Incineration of waste and a nuclear waste tax;
§ Natural resource taxes: Water abstraction; extraction of metal ores and extraction of
non-metallic minerals; and
§ Agricultural related taxes: Pesticides tax.
In the scenario, the measures were phased in over the 2019-2025 period, with revenues
amounting to €3.5 billion in 2025. Every year, the revenues were used to lower labour taxes
(personal income tax, social contributions paid by employers and employees, as well as
additional income support for the lowest two income quintiles) and towards investments in
research and development (R&D) and renewables.
Results
The modelling results suggest that the scenario increases GDP and employment by 1.2% in
2025 compared to the business as usual scenario. Similarly, CO2, SO2 and NOx emissions
would be reduced by 6.0%, 8.1% and 6.3% respectively. Exports and imports would be virtually
unaffected, apart from energy imports, which would be reduced by 6.1%.
Graph 1. Overall result: Decoupling (2019-2025, difference from baseline). Source: Cambridge
Econometrics
Overall, the results from the scenario show that the energy and utilities sectors experience the
biggest loss in output, while labour-intensive services sectors experience the largest gains.
Over the course of seven years (2019-2025), compared to baseline, the scenario cumulatively
reduces carbon emissions by 8.4 million tonnes, and saves € 924 million on Finland’s energy
import bill. Over the same period, 115,600 person years of employment are added as well as
€12.9 billion in GDP.
The key message from the results is that it is possible to design policy measures that reduce
final energy consumption and harmful emissions, while at the same time stimulating the
Finnish economy and creating jobs.
This study is meant to provide directions on how fiscal systems can be rationalized in light of the circular
economy goals and describe the potential impacts. The authors hope that the report will be used as a
source of inspiration for further discussion and planning on environmental fiscal reform in Finland and
Europe in general.
More studies will be required on the possibilities of aligning fiscal systems with circular economy goals.
Cooperation among EU countries will be key to ensure a level-playing field.
Page | 8 1. CIRCULAR ECONOMY GOALS IN FINLAND
The Finnish government has a strong commitment to a circular economy. Prime Minister Juha
Sipilä’s government has set a goal to make Finland a global circular economy leader by 2025.
The bioeconomy and clean solutions as a part of a circular economy were some of the focus
areas in the Government Programme approved in 20153. The Finnish Innovation Fund (Sitra)
has played a key role in establishing the circular economy concept in the Finnish society,
particularly by encouraging and implementing it in practice. The business sector has also been
active in identifying opportunities for new circular economy-based business models, and in
maximising the use and reuse of the products, components and materials that already exist in
the economy.
What would the transformation from a linear economy towards a circular economy-based
society require in Finland? The policy goals, measures and actions towards a circular economy
have been defined in several processes and reports. The main report in this field is the national
road map to circular economy prepared by Sitra: Leading the cycle - Finnish road map to a
circular economy 2016–20254. The road map is currently being updated, and a new version,
National roadmap to circular economy 2.0, will be published in early 2019. The main objective
of this exercise is to increase the level of ambition of the circular economy goals, specify the
contents, and to complement new measures and proposals to action.
In addition to the road map, policy goals, measures and actions for transition towards a circular
economy have been defined in the Government Programme of Prime Minister Sipilä (2015), in
the Circular economy action plan (2017)5 prepared by the Finnish Government, and in several
sectoral reports and initiatives. In the next section, we will focus on the main objectives and
policy goals set in the national road map to a circular economy.
The road map defines the steps required for a systemic change in the economy: in the future,
the competitiveness of the Finnish economy and well-being will no longer require
overconsumption of natural resources. Instead, the economy will be based on circularity, and
closing the material and energy loops.
3
Prime Minister’s Office (2015), Finland, a land of solutions. Strategic Programme of Prime Minister Juha Sipilä’s
Government, 29 May 2015. Government Publications 12/2015.
4
Sitra (2016), Leading the cycle. Finnish road map to a circular economy 2016–2025. Sitra Studies 121.
https://media.sitra.fi/2017/02/28142644/Selvityksia121.pdf
5
Ministry of the Environment, Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment
& Sitra (2017), Action Plan for a Circular Economy. 30.11.2017. http://www.ym.fi/en-
US/The_environment/Circular_economy
6
Sitra (2016), Leading the cycle. Finnish road map to a circular economy 2016–2025. Sitra Studies 121.
A circular economy strives to maximise the circulation of products, components and materials,
Page | 9
and the value bound to them. In a circular economy, production and consumption create the
smallest possible amount of material loss and waste. Material efficiency leads to
environmental, economic and social benefits as part of sustainable development. Added value
is often created for products by means of services and digital solutions based on intelligence.
The systemic change towards a circular economy means major changes in both production
manners and consumer behaviour. The driving force for this work is to turn the circular
economy into a driver of growth, investment and exports for Finland.
The national road map for a circular economy contains four focus areas with the following
general description of the aim of the focus area followed by more specific policy actions:
The vision of a sustainable food system emphasises that consumer choices will be more
resource-wise than at present, and that they will be promoted through public food services.
Emissions and resource consumption in food production will decrease and their formation will
be transparent. The policy actions aim to:
Forest-based loops
The vision of circularity in forest-based loops relies on the use of side streams, increasing the
manufacturing and added-value of products and services and other circular economy solutions
derived from forest-based loops. In addition, the second-generation biofuels and the digital
revolution are mentioned, as well as wood construction and wood-based products. The main
objective of the national forest strategy should be to:
§ Maximise the overall added-value of Finnish forest-based products and services rather
than the amount of wood;
§ Encourage through public procurement the selection of wood-based products and
those made from other renewable raw materials when life-cycle analysis demonstrates
that they are more sustainable overall;
§ Provide support to investments aimed at demonstrating bioproducts and bioservices
on a commercial basis; and
§ Create incentives for developing Finnish wood construction and the design of wooden
furniture and interior design sector.
Technical loops
In the technical loops focus area, the principle is sustainable use of non-renewable natural
resources, lengthening the product life cycle via maintenance measures, and determining how
the material at the end of products’ life-cycle can be returned to the loop. According to circular
economy principles, material development and product design play a key role in this work.
Page | 10
Eco-industrial parks are examples to enable side streams from one industry to be used as a
raw material in other industrial processes. In addition, they aim to:
§ Promote the use of secondary raw materials, including waste act interpretation and
streamlining the environmental permit procedure;
§ Make use of the side streams produced during the project, such as surplus spoil. These
should be planned and described in the environmental impact assessment and
environmental processes; and
§ Include eco-design requirements in product design and construction and in the material
development phase.
The vision in the transport and logistics focus area is a systemic change towards a carbon-
neutral and service-based transport system. The idea is to raise the level of logistics capacity
utilisation, replace fossil fuels with renewable and non-fossil alternatives, and optimise
transport routes and material flows. Digitalisation is emphasised as a key enabler as
passenger transport moves towards smart, easy-to-use transport that is based on:
§ Sharing and services (MaaS, Mobility as a Service). This would require the
development of incentives and policy instruments to accelerate a radical change
towards a more service-based transport system; and
§ Developing tax and other steering instruments to support the phase out of fossil fuels
in private cars by 2040 and promote the implementation of sustainable production of
biofuels.
In addition to these substance-related focus areas, the fifth focus area in the road map is
common action. This refers to the notion that legislators, companies, universities and research
institutes, consumers and citizens, and vibrant regions are all needed to achieve systemic
change. Communication and diverse interaction are particularly important when implementing
joint action with different stakeholders. The role of the public sector as a facilitator and
supporter is emphasised together with research, development and innovation activities.
Achieving systemic change requires a wide range of actions and many social changes.
The transition towards a circular economy has an important role in the Government
Programme of Prime Minister Sipilä (2015). Bioeconomy and clean solutions is one of the five
strategic priorities in the Government Programme, and circular economy is treated as a key
project under the title of “Breakthrough to a circular economy and adoption of clean solutions”.
In September 2015, an implementation plan was launched to put the key projects into action.
Page | 11
The Government allocated to the key projects altogether €1 billion, of which €300 million was
earmarked for Bioeconomy and clean technologies. Each circular economy project received
€63 million according to the following topics:
2) Increase of nutrient recycling and promotion of good ecological status of the Baltic
Sea and other water systems;
3) Experimental project for remediation of contaminated land and recycling of soil; and
The objective of these projects was to exploit the growing potential of the circular economy
and clean solutions. Actions to promote a good ecological status of the Baltic Sea were one of
the priorities to be made in cooperation with domestic and international actors. The amount of
nutrients and organic material leaching to the waters would be reduced, while the nutrient and
energy self-sufficiency of agriculture would be enhanced. One of the objectives was that the
circular economy and clean-tech business and exports would grow, and new jobs would be
created.
In the implementation of the Government programme, e.g. the following actions have been
made related to the promotion of a circular economy:
§ An action plan for a circular economy was prepared together with Sitra based on
the national road map to a circular economy.
§ Experimental programme of nutrient recycling has been put into practice.
§ From recycling to a circular economy – The National Waste Plan 2030 was
published in May 2018.
§ A government proposal on amending the Waste Act7 has been submitted to
Parliament in November 2018. One of the amendments is an obligation to create and
develop an information platform for waste and by-products.
§ Experimental projects on recycling municipal waste.
§ New, internationally competitive techniques for reconditioning contaminated soil
have been tested and areas have been reconditioned for use through the Clean Soil
programme of Tekes and the Ministry of the Environment.
§ New investments in bio-economy.
§ Six business ecosystems with international market potential, Tekes’ business
spearheads and ecosystems in the bio-economy programme.
§ In order to encourage sustainable and innovative procurement, a network-based
centre of excellence was to be set up in spring 2018.
§ Preparation of an action plan for sustainable urban development.
7
Hallituksen esitys eduskunnalle laiksi jätelain muuttamisesta (248/2018). Government Proposal on Amending
the Waste Act, 22.11.2018.
§ A green deal model has been piloted. The first Green Deal concerning plastic carrier
Page | 12
bags was concluded in 2016, and has already successfully reduced the use of plastic
bags. The Finnish automotive industry, the Ministry of Transport and Communications
and the Ministry of the Environment concluded the second Green Deal on November
2018. The Green Deal for the benefit of the climate is part of the Finnish Society’s
Commitment to Sustainable Development. The aim is to reduce carbon dioxide
emissions in the transport sector.
Government action plan for a circular economy: experiments, public procurement and service
innovations
In addition to the Government’s key projects and the National road map to a circular economy,
the Government prepared a more concrete action plan on how to promote the realisation of
the circular economy during the rest of the Government term8. The Ministry of Environment -
together with other Ministries9 and Sitra - prepared an Action plan for a circular economy10,
where the objectives, main actions and measures are defined.
The three priorities of the action plan and measures are:
There is a strong emphasis on experiments and pilot projects for testing new ideas for a circular
economy and other policy objectives. Furthermore, public procurement has been raised as a
key measure to promote sustainable solutions and environmentally friendly products,
techniques and methods.
The main objectives of the plan were defined as follows: to generate internationally competitive
solutions to circular economy; create substantial added-value for products; and to share best
practices with other countries. The key aim to circular economy solutions was to make it
possible to cut greenhouse gases and other atmospheric emissions in a decisive way, to
promote the sustainable use of natural resources, and to increase well-being and thereby also
improved competitiveness
8
The next Parliamentary elections will be held in April 2019.
9
The Ministries involved in circular economy are: Ministry of Environment, Ministry of Economic Affairs and
Employment and Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry.
10
Ministry of the Environment, Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment
& Sitra (2017), Action Plan for a Circular Economy. 30.11.2017. http://www.ym.fi/en-
US/The_environment/Circular_economy
1.3. Main goals in the transition towards a carbon-neutral circular Page | 13
economy
Circular economy is a framework for an economy that is restorative and regenerative by
design. According to the Ellen MacArthur Foundation11, circular economy aims to redefine
growth, focusing on positive society-wide benefits. It entails gradually decoupling economic
activity from the consumption of finite resources and designing waste and pollution out of the
system. In addition, a transition to renewable energy sources is an important part of a carbon-
neutral circular economy, which has been emphasised in the Finnish road map.
The system diagram of a circular economy by Ellen MacArthur Foundation illustrates the
continuous flow of technical and biological materials through the “value circle” (Figure 1). The
concept of circular economy is based on three principles12:
1) Regenerate natural systems
2) Keep products and materials in use
3) Design out waste and pollution
11
https://www.ellenmacarthurfoundation.org/circular-economy/concept
12
https://www.ellenmacarthurfoundation.org/circular-economy/concept
Page | 14
In the project, we defined four main goals for the transition towards a carbon-neutral circular
economy in Finland based on these three principles and the content of the Finnish road map
and the Action Plan for a circular economy and other initiatives. These four goals have served
as the general policy objectives of a carbon-neutral circular economy to which the following
economic instruments have been identified:
1) Minimising the use of virgin natural resources
§ Instruments: Natural resource taxes
2) Reducing emissions
§ Pricing of CO2 emissions
§ Incentives for investments in low carbon technology
3) Prolonging the lifetime of products
§ Cutting of labour taxes to boost service-based business models
§ Incentives for research and development
Page | 15
4) Recycling of waste as material
§ Waste related taxes
More detailed presentations on circular economy goals and instruments to promote them are
presented in chapter 3 and its sub chapters.
Page | 16 2. ALIGNING TAX POLICY WITH THE INCLUSIVE CIRCULAR
ECONOMY
As described in Chapter 1, Finland aims to become a global circular economy leader by 2025.
In this chapter we will explore how shifting the tax burden from labour to natural resource use
would align the Finnish tax system with the goals of the carbon-neutral, inclusive and circular
economy.
First, we will briefly explore the difference between linear business models and circular models,
illustrated by examples from the fashion industry.
In the linear, take-make-waste economy, resources are extracted, turned into products and –
after a short lifetime – discarded as waste. Business models in the linear economy revolve
around maximising resource extraction, throughput and product sales. The fashion industry for
example, operates along linear processes. It is one of the most polluting sectors in the world,
using harmful pesticides, dyes, solvents and large amounts of water. The sector emits more
greenhouse gases than all international flights and maritime shipping combined. Less than 1%
of material used to produce clothing is recycled into new clothing and every second, a garbage
truck of textiles is landfilled or incinerated. On a global scale, more than $500 billion of value
is lost every year due to underutilization and the lack of recycling13.
In Finland, around a total of 70 million kg of textiles are used and withdrawn annually which
means 13 kg per person. According to a study on the textiles and textile waste flows in Finland,
in 2012 roughly 20% of discarded textiles were collected separately by charity organisations
and directed mainly towards reuse. Only a few percent of the overall flow was recycled. The
majority of the discarded textiles were collected in municipal solid waste and incinerated with
energy recovery.14 Since 2012, there has been development in the field towards reuse and
recycling and also to sharing of clothes as renting business (eg Vaaterekki and Vaatepuu15).
Compared to linear business models, circular business models are resource-efficient. They
also tend to be more labour and knowledge-intensive. In the circular economy, companies
recollect, repair and disassemble products and provide services with products. Examples of
13
Ellen MacArthur Foundation (2017), A new textiles economy: Redesigning fashion’s future.
http://www.ellenmacarthurfoundation.org/publications
14
Dahlbo, H., Aalto, K., Eskelinen, H. & Salmenperä, H. (2017), Increasing textile circulation—Consequences and
requirements. In Sustainable Production and Consumption
Volume 9, January 2017, Pages 44-57.
15
Vaaterekki and Vaatepuu are companies which rent clothes for customers. More info in Finnish, see
https://www.vaaterekki.com/ and https://vaatepuu.fi/
such new business models are emerging in every sector. In the garment industry, for example,
Page | 17
companies offer lease services and customization (eg Mud Jeans), reselling of products (eg
Patagonia) and sharing/subscription services (eg Ycloset).
Circular business models require a higher service level than simply selling products; they
require handling, sorting, quality monitoring and cleaning. Such business models also require
a redesign of products and supply chains (eg cradle-to-cradle clothing by C&A and reuse of
materials by Ioniqa). Intensive research and development efforts are needed to develop bio-
based materials (such as Earthcolours’ dyes made from agricultural waste) and new processes
(eg Mistra Future Fashion’s ultrasound laser cutting).
Renewable energy
With regard to the carbon-neutrality component of the circular economy, it is important to note
that low-carbon, renewable energy technologies create more jobs than fossil-fuel technologies;
they are more labour-intensive. Solar Photovoltaics, for instance, creates more than twice the
number of jobs per unit of electricity generation compared with coal or natural gas.16 The World
Bank estimates that in the United States, wind and solar create about 13.5 jobs per
million dollars of spending, and that building retrofits (energy efficiency) create 16.7 jobs
per million dollars of spending. This is more than three times the 5.2 jobs per $1 million for
oil and natural gas, and more than twice the 6.9 jobs per $1 million for coal.17
Circular (and low-carbon) business models, compared to linear models, are relatively
resource-efficient but require more human capital.
The next step in our analysis is to look at the role of taxation in the transition to an inclusive
circular economy. EU governments (including Finland) tend to put a high tax burden on labour
(including personal income tax, payroll taxes and social contributions) and low or no taxes on
natural resource-use (‘environmentally related’ taxes, or ‘green’ taxes, which are based for
example on fossil fuel use, carbon emissions and other pollution and water use). Because of
these financial incentives, low-carbon, innovative and labour-intensive circular activities have
a competitive disadvantage compared to linear business models. The societal cost of pollution
and the way tax structures deal with these costs will be further explored in the next sections.
16
UKERC, 2014 in: IRENA (May, 2017), Renewable Energy and Jobs Annual Review 2017.
http://www.irena.org/documentdownloads/publications/irena_re_jobs_annual_review_2017.pdf
17
World Bank (2011), Issues in estimating the employment generated by energy sector activities,
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTENERGY2/Resources/MeasuringEmploymentImpactofEnergySector.pdf
The global welfare losses from pollution have been estimated at $4.6 trillion a year, or 6.2% of
Page | 18
global economic output.18 The long-term negative impacts on the global economy caused by
the CO2 emissions in 2017 alone were $16 trillion.19 Such costs are ‘externalised’, meaning
that they are passed on to society, individuals and future generations, rather than absorbed by
the polluter. The notion of putting a price on externalities has been around since Arthur Pigou
introduced the concept in 1920.20 In recent years, many studies have quantified external costs
(or ‘negative externalities’), in particular related to carbon emissions, with prices ranging from
$30 per tonne to more than $400 per tonne of CO2.21
The OECD applies a minimum social cost of carbon of €30 per tonne, and has included in
2018 a benchmark of €60 per tonne to its analyses to reflect the estimated cost of carbon in
the future.22 The OECD has noted that at the current pace of incremental annual growth in
pricing emissions, carbon prices will reflect the real costs to the climate only in 2095.23
Inconsistent carbon pricing in Finland
In 1990, Finland became the first country to tax CO2 emissions.24 Finland has since developed
a complex system of energy and carbon taxes. In addition to energy taxation, the vehicle
related taxation, both one-off car tax (registration tax) and annual vehicle tax are also based
on CO2 emissions from 2008 onwards. Furthermore, the EU Emission Trading System (EU
ETS) applies to large industrial and energy production plants since 2005.25 Approximately half
of the greenhouse gas emissions in Finland are covered by the ETS.26 Altogether, a large
proportion of the total CO2 emissions in the economy were not effectively taxed.27 Due to
exceptions, rebates and reduced rates, the pricing levels per tonne of CO2 varied significantly
per sector and the type of fuel used. From a climate perspective, there is no difference between
carbon dioxide emitted from an exhaust pipe, a residential heater or a factory chimney; the
impacts and, therefore, the external costs per tonne of carbon are the same. Still, the effective
tax rate in Finland ranges from €0 per tonne of carbon emitted by biomass and waste
18
Lancet, The, Icahn School of Medicine at Mt Sinai and Global Alliance on Health and Pollution (2017), Pollution
is the World’s Largest Environmental Cause of Disease and Premature Death. https://www.thelancet.com/pb-
assets/Lancet/stories/commissions/pollution-2017/Pollution_and_Health_Infographic.pdf
19
Ricke, K., Drouet, L., Caldeira, K. and Tavoni, M. (2018), Country-level Social Cost of Carbon’, Nature Climate
Change, 8: 895–900. https://www.nature.com/articles/s41558-018-0282-y
20
Pigou, A.C. (1920), The Economics of Welfare.
21
ACCA (2018), Tax as a force for good Rebalancing our tax systems to support a global economy fit for the
future. Professional Insight Report by Femke Groothuis, The Ex’tax Project.
https://www.accaglobal.com/gb/en/professional-insights/global-profession/environmental-tax.html
22
OECD (2018), Taxing Energy Use 2018. https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/ taxation/taxing-energy-use-
2018_9789264289635-en#page43
23
OECD (2018), Governments Need to Honour their Climate Pledges as Risks Grow.
http://www.oecd.org/environment/governments-need-to-honour-their-climate-pledges-as-risks-grow.htm
24
World Bank (2018), State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2018
25
In addition, other policy instruments have been in use to tackle greenhouse gas emission. For example,
different kind of subsidies to renewable energy sources, like feed-in-tariff scheme and Energy Aid Programmes
for investment support for renewable energy and energy-saving projects have been used, as well as, regulation
and voluntary schemes to promote energy efficiency and renewables.
26
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment (2018), Emission Trading. https://tem.fi/en/emissions-trading
27
Including taxes and emissions trading systems. OECD (2018), Taxing Energy Use 2018; Companion to the
Taxing Energy Use Database, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264289635-en. Biomass related CO2 emissions
(which do not have a tax) are included in the 58% figure.
combustion in industry to € 300 per tonne of carbon emitted in gasoline used in road transport
Page | 19
(see graph 2).28
Graph 2. Effective tax rates on energy use in EUR per tonne of CO2 in Finland, 201529
28
The effective carbon tax rate is the price of carbon emissions resulting from taxes and emissions trading
systems. Methodology on how the effective tax rate is calculated can be found here: OECD (2018), Taxing
Energy Use 2018; Companion to the Taxing Energy Use Database, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264289635-en
29
Based on OECD (2018), Taxing Energy Use 2018. https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/taxing-energy-use-
2018_9789264289635-en#page2
30
European Commission (2013), Taxation Trends in the European Union, 2013 edition
https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/sites/taxation/files/resources/documents/taxation/gen_info/economic_analy
sis/tax_structures/2013/report.pdf
Governments around the world, including Finland, provide active support to fossil fuel
Page | 20
consumption, and thus to pollution, both through direct budgetary transfers and tax
concessions that in some way provide a benefit or preference for fossil-fuel production or
consumption, relative to alternatives. The IEA estimates the value of global fossil-fuel
consumption subsidies at more than US$ 300 billion in 2017, up from US$ 270 billion in 2016.31
According to OECD data, Finland provided € 1.7 billion in fossil fuel support in 2016 (see table
1).
In 2016, greenhouse gas emissions in Finland were 11.1 tonnes of CO2 equivalent (‘tCO2eq’)
per capita, which was higher than the EU-average of 8.7tCO2eq per capita.32 Two sectors,
manufacturing and electricity, produced 50% of total greenhouse gas emissions in Finland.33
According to a (2016) OECD analysis:
31
IEA (2018), World Energy Outlook 2018. https://www.iea.org/weo/energysubsidies/
32
Eurostat (2018), Greenhouse gas emissions per capita.
https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/tgm/table.do?tab=table&init=1&language=en&pcode=t2020_rd300&plugin=1
33
Eurostat (2018), Greenhouse gas emissions by source sector (source: EEA)
34
Greenhouse gas intensity is defined as greenhouse gas emissions per unit of GDP. OECD (2016), OECD
Economic Surveys FINLAND January 2016 OVERVIEW https://www.oecd.org/eco/surveys/Overview-OECD-
Finland-2016.pdf
“reduce greenhouse gas emissions further, phase out environmentally
Page | 21
harmful subsidies and better align the tax rate on emissions across
sectors.”35
Finland is a member of the Friends of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform (FFFSR), established in
2010, which promotes the gradual phase-out of inefficient fossil fuel subsidies. The other
members of FFFSR are Costa Rica, Denmark, Ethiopia, Norway, Sweden and Switzerland.
The countries are committed to ‘act as first movers, serving as an example and supporting
other countries' participation in efforts to rationalise the use of fossil fuel subsidies36.
Three Scandinavian countries (Sweden, Denmark and Finland) top the 2018 SDG Index, which
ranks 156 countries across the dimensions of the 17 Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs).
This means that Finland is in a good position to meet the SDGs. According to the index, ‘major
challenges’ remain across several indicators including electronic waste generated, net
imported SO2 emissions, non-recycled municipal solid waste, energy-related CO2 emissions,
imported CO2 emissions and the annual change in forest area.37 According to the Ministry of
Environment of Finland:
“It is estimated that Finns consume their own share of the Earth's natural
resources approximately four months earlier than the global average. In
Finland, the national Overshoot Day fell earlier than before, on 11 April. If
everyone in the world consumed as much as the average Finn, 3.6 Earths
would be needed to sustain them.38
Across the EU, in only five countries (Luxembourg, Belgium, Estonia, Sweden and Denmark)
Earth Overshoot Day occurred earlier than in Finland.39
A few additional observations with regard to pollution and resource use in Finland:
Metal ore consumption. In 2016, Finland’s consumption of metal ores was by far the highest
in the EU (5.5 tonnes per capita).40
35
OECD (2016), OECD Economic Surveys FINLAND January 2016 OVERVIEW.
https://www.oecd.org/eco/surveys/Overview-OECD-Finland-2016.pdf
36
Ministry of the Environment (April 2015), Finland calls for phase-out of fossil fuel subsidies, http://www.ym.fi/en-
US/Latest_news/News/Finland_calls_for_phaseout_of_fossil_fue(33271)
37
Sachs, J., Schmidt-Traub, G., Kroll, C., Lafortune, G., Fuller, G. (2018), SDG Index and Dashboards Report
2018. Bertelsmann Stiftung and Sustainable Development Solutions Network (SDSN).
http://sdgindex.org/assets/files/2018/01%20SDGS%20GLOBAL%20EDITION%20WEB%20V9%20180718.pdf;
https://dashboards.sdgindex.org/#/FIN
38
Ministry of Environment Finland (August 1, 2018), Earth Overshoot Day is today. http://www.ym.fi/en-
US/The_environment/Earth_Overshoot_Day_is_today(47420
39
Earth Overshoot Day (accessed 17 December 2018), Country Overshoot Days.
https://www.overshootday.org/newsroom/country-overshoot-days/
40
Eurostat (2018), Material flow accounts and resource productivity
Pesticides used in forestry. Sales of pesticides used in forestry have increased dramatically
Page | 22
over the past 10 years. In 2003, sales of pesticides used in forestry accounted for less than
one percent, while in 2015, they accounted for around 60% of total sales of pesticides.41
Energy import dependency. The consumption of energy in 2016 was 34.6 million tonnes of
oil equivalent, 25.2 million tonnes of oil equivalent (73%) was imported.42 The total value of
imports from Russia in 2016 was € 6.1 billion, 71% of which is energy products.43
Health impacts of air pollution. Estimates of the health impacts attributable to exposure to
air pollution indicate that PM2.5 concentrations in 2015 were responsible for 1,540 premature
deaths in Finland.44
Increasing the tax burden on pollution and resource use would not only benefit the circular
economy but could also help protect the health of the population, reduce energy import
dependency and boost innovation in sustainable products and processes. The OECD has
specifically recommended Finland to increase green taxes and phase out harmful subsidies.
At the same time, the OECD advises to reduce the tax burden on labour.45 The rationale for a
reduction in labour taxes will be further explored below.
§ In 2016, Personal Income Tax was 13% of GDP; the third highest in the EU.48
§ The ‘tax wedge’ (a measure of the tax burden on employment incomes; the difference
between labour costs to the employer and the corresponding net take-home pay of the
employee) is also high in Finland. In 2017, Finland had the fourth highest tax wedge in
the OECD for an average married worker with two children, at 38.4% (compared to an
41
Luke (2018), Use of pesticides. https://www.luke.fi/ruokafakta/en/field-crops/use-of-pesticides/
42
Eurostat (2018), Simplified energy balances - annual data
43
Tulli (2017), Finnish foreign trade 2016, Figures and diagrams.
http://tulli.fi/documents/2912305/3439475/Statistical%20graphics%202016/ce289986-10ef-49e9-b8a5-
30177ca255aa?version=1.8
44
EEA (2018), Air quality in Europe 2018, https://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/air-quality-in-europe-2018
45
OECD (2018), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2018, https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/oecd-
economic-surveys-finland-2018_eco_surveys-fin-2018-en#
46
In the European Union, only in Malta, Romania, Croatia, Bulgaria, Estonia and Cyprus consumption taxes
provide a bigger share of total tax revenues than labour taxes.
47
European Commission (2018), Taxation trends report 2018.
https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/sites/taxation/files/taxation_trends_report_2018.pdf
48
European Commission (2018), Taxation trends report 2018.
https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/sites/taxation/files/taxation_trends_report_2018.pdf
OECD average of 26.1%). The average single worker in Finland faced a tax wedge as
Page | 23
high as 42.9% (compared to an OECD average of 35.9%).49
Other researchers found even stronger correlations. Over the years, institutions such as the
World Bank (World Bank, Bogetic et al. 2015;56 World Bank 2018), the OECD (OECD 2018;
OECD, World Bank and ILO 2015;57 OECD 2011)58, the IMF (2014;59 2015),60 the European
49
OECD (2018), Taxing Wages - Finland, http://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/taxing-wages-finland.pdf
50
Nickell & Layard (1999), cited in Dolenc, Primož, Laporšek, Suzana (2010), Tax wedge on labour and its effect
on employment growth in the European Union.
51
ECB (2008), Labour cost and employment across euro area countries and sectors. Working Paper Series no
912.
52
Vermeend, Willem, van der Ploeg, Rick, Timmer, Jan (2008), Taxes and the Economy. A Survey on the Impact
of Taxes on Growth, Employment, Investment, Consumption and the Environment.
53
Primož Dolenc, Suzana Laporšek (2010), Tax wedge on labour and its effect on employment growth in the
European Union.
54
Brys, Bert (2011), Making Fundamental Tax Reform Happen, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 3.
55
Bassanini & Duval (2006), cited in Primož Dolenc, Suzana Laporšek (2010), Tax wedge on labour and its effect
on employment growth in the European Union.
56
Bogetic, Z., et al. (2015), Fiscal Policy Issues in the Aging Societies. http://documents.worldbank.org/
curated/en/846591468327934918/pdf/95266-REVISED-NWP-PUBLIC- Box391483B-MFM-Discussion-Paper-1-
ZB-May-2015.pdf; World Bank (2018), World Development Report 2019. http://documents.
worldbank.org/curated/en/816281518818814423/pdf/2019-WDR-Report. pdf; OECD (2018), Opportunities for All:
A Framework for Policy Action on Inclusive Growth. https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/opportunities- for-
all_9789264301665-en#page1;
57
OECD, World Bank and ILO (2015), G20 Labour Markets in 2015; Strengthening the Link between Growth and
Employment. https://www.oecd.org/g20/topics/employment-and-social-policy/G20-Labour-Markets-in-2015-
Strengthening-the-Link-between-Growth-and-Employment.pdf
58
OECD (2011), Tax reform can create jobs. http://www.oecd.org/newsroom/taxreformcancreatejobs.htm
59
IMF (2014), The IMF's Advice on Labor Market Issues. https://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/labor.htm
60
IMF (2015), IMF Policy Paper: Fiscal Policy and Long-Term Growth.
https://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2015/042015.pdf
Commission (2013;61 2017)62, the Eurogroup (2014)63 and the European Council (2011)64 have
Page | 24
called for lower labour taxes to reduce unemployment.
From a business perspective, it is clear that a high tax burden on labour incentivises companies
to gain efficiency by reducing payroll costs. ACCA (2018)65 describes a range of strategies for
entrepreneurs to minimise headcount, including:
Such strategies may make business sense, but they contribute directly and indirectly to
unemployment and underemployment as well as informal and temporary employment.
61
European Commission (2013), Tax Reforms in EU Member States 2013. Tax Policy Challenges for Economic
Growth and Fiscal Sustainability. http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/european_economy/2013/pdf/
ee5_en.pdf
62
European Commission (2017), Joint Employment Report 2017.
http://ec.europa.eu/social/BlobServlet?docId=17224&langId=en
63
Eurogroup (2014), Structural Reform Agenda - Thematic Discussions on Growth and Jobs - Reduction of the
Tax Wedge. http://italia2014.eu/media/2066/eurogroup-statement-_12-september-2014.pdf
64
European Council (2011), Conclusions. EUCO 10/1/11 REV 1.
http://register.consilium.europa.eu/doc/srv?l=EN&f=ST%2010%202011%20REV%201
65
ACCA (2018), Tax as a force for good Rebalancing our tax systems to support a global economy fit for the
future. Professional Insight Report by Femke Groothuis, The Ex’tax Project.
https://www.accaglobal.com/gb/en/professional-insights/global-profession/environmental-tax.html
66
Singh, V, (2014), Impact of Labour Cost in Overall Performance of Hotels and Restaurants.
http://www.erpublications.com/ sitepanel/download.php?filename=download/
download_28_10_2014_12_26_27.pdf
67
Wohl, J. (2012), Wal-Mart to Add more Self-checkout Lanes. https://www.reuters.com/article/walmart/update-2-
wal-mart-to- add-more-self-checkout-lanes-idUSL2E8E72FF20120307 .
68
Segran, E. (2017), These Fashion Startups Offer the Prestige of “Made In Italy” without Inflated Prices.
https://www.fastcompany.com/3067010/these-footwear-startups-offer-the-prestige-of-made-in-italy-without-inflat
69
Croxford, Rianna (2018), UN Agency's U-turn after Unpaid Internships Row https://www.bbc.com/news/ world-
45605768; He, H. (2018), Small Chinese Firms Seek “Lessons in Survival” as they Brace for Impact of Social
Welfare Taxes, South China Morning Post, 30 September. https://www.scmp.com/economy/china-
economy/article/2166266/small-chinese-firms-seek-lessons-survival-they-brace-impact
70
Maxim, R. and Muro, M. (2018), Rethinking Worker Benefits for an Economy in Flux
https://www.brookings.edu/blog/the-avenue/2018/03/29/rethinking-worker-benefits-for-an-economy-in-flux/
71
Ghosh, S. (April 2018), Undercover Author Finds Amazon Warehouse Workers in UK “Peed in Bottles” over
Fears of Being Punished for Taking a Break. Business Insider Nederland. https://www.businessinsider.nl/amazon-
warehouse-workers-have-to-pee-into-bottles-2018-4/?international=true&r=US
72
Heath, M. (2015), China is Set to Lose Manufacturing Crown: Manufacturers will be Drawn to Southeast Asia's
Strengths, including the Strategic Location and Cheap Labor of Myanmar, Cambodia and Laos.
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-04-29/china-is-set-to-lose-manufacturing-crown
In 2017, unemployment in the European Union stood at 7.6%73, meaning that 18.8 million
Page | 25
people were unemployed. A closer look at unemployment statistics, however, reveals that the
‘underutilised labour potential’ was more than twice as high, at 38.2 million people.74 This
number takes underemployment into account, including part-time workers who wish to work
more hours, persons seeking work but who are not immediately available and persons
available to work but not actively seeking.
In Finland, the 2017 unemployment rate was 8.6% (higher than the EU average of 7.6%)
implying that 234,000 Finns were unemployed. The underutilised labour potential was more
than twice as high, at 536,000.75 According to the IMF:
§ Finland has the highest social protection costs as a percentage of GDP in the EU28.
In 2016, Finland spent € 55,286 million on social protection, which was 45.8% of total
government expenditure.77
§ Employment in the manufacturing of furniture and other products of wood and
cork (a sector the circular roadmap aims to enhance) has decreased 12.8% and
21.8% respectively in Finland during the 2010-2017 period.78
§ Finland’s employment rate is markedly lower than in the other Nordic countries.79
The combination of different working-age benefits, childcare costs and income taxation
creates complexity, reduces work incentives and holds back employment.80 The
European Commission recommends Finland to ‘improve incentives to accept work’.81
Lowering the tax burden on labour would not only benefit the circular economy, but could also
help to solve unemployment and underemployment in Finland. The rationale to shift the tax
burden from labour to natural resource use will be further explored below.
73
Eurostat (2018), Unemployment by sex and age - annual average[une_rt_a];
74
Eurostat (2018), Supplementary indicators to unemployment - annual data.
75
Eurostat (2018), Unemployment by sex and age - annual average[une_rt_a]; Eurostat (2018), Supplementary
indicators to unemployment - annual data.
76
IMF (2017), Finland; selected issues. https://www.imf.org/~/media/Files/Publications/CR/2017/cr17371.ashx
77
Eurostat (2018), General government expenditure by function (COFOG)[gov_10a_exp]
78
Eurostat (2018), Labour input in industry - annual data[sts_inlb_a]
79
OECD (2018), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2018.
80
Ibid.
81
European Commission (2018), 2018 European Semester: Country Specific Recommendation / Council
Recommendation – Finland. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-
content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:32018H0910(25)&from=EN
Page | 26 2.4. Shifting the tax burden from labour to resource use
Green tax reform has been known under many different names
The proposal to shift taxation from labour to resource use (including pollution and carbon
emissions) has been known as Environmental Tax Reform (ETR), Environmental Fiscal
Reform (EFR), Green Fiscal Reform (GFR), Green Tax Swaps (GTS) and Value Extracted
Tax.82 Throughout this report the term ‘tax shift’ will refer to such reform. The tax shift also
includes the reform of environmentally harmful subsidies. Also, in this perspective, social
benefits are equally important as environmental benefits.
Although budget neutral for governments,85 a tax shift fundamentally changes the margins
within which business, consumers and governments operate. The impacts of a tax shift from
labour to resource-use have been researched extensively, both in theory and in practice.
82
The term Value Extracted Tax (in short: ‘Ex’tax’) was coined in 1994 by the Dutch entrepreneur Eckart Wintzen
in a more integrated approach, focussing on the role of taxes in enabling sustainable prosperity. Wintzen, Eckart
(1994), Re-engineering the Planet. Three Steps to a Sustainable Free Market Economy.
83
ACCA (2018), Tax as a force for good Rebalancing our tax systems to support a global economy fit for the
future. Professional Insight Report by Femke Groothuis, The Ex’tax Project.
https://www.accaglobal.com/gb/en/professional-insights/global-profession/environmental-tax.html
84
Ellen MacArthur Foundation, McKinsey and SUN (2015), Growth Within: A Circular Economy Vision for a
Competitive Europe. https://www.ellenmacarthurfoundation.org/assets/downloads/publications/EllenMacArthur
Foundation_Growth-Within_July15.pdf ; Stegeman, H. (2015), De potentie van de circulaire economie.
https://economie.rabobank.com/publicaties/2015/juli/ de-potentie-van-de-circulaire-economie’; Finnish Innovation
Fund Sitra (2016), Leading the Cycle – Finnish Road Map to a Circular Economy 2016–2025.
https://www.sitra.fi/en/projects/leading-the-cycle-finnish-road-map-to-a-circular-economy-2016-2025/#what-is-it-
about ; Wijkman, A. and Skånberg, K. (2016) The Circular Economy and Benefits for Society
https://www.clubofrome.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/10/The-Circular-Economy-Czech-Republic-and-Poland.pdf ;
Ministry of Environment, Portugal (2017), Leading the Transition (Action Plan for Circular Economy in Portugal:
2017–2020) https://circulareconomy.europa.eu/platform/sites/default/files/strategy_-_portuguese_action_plan_
paec_en_version_3.pdf ; Ministry for the Environment, Land and Sea and Ministry of Economic Development,
Italy (2017), Towards a Model of Circular Economy for Italy – Overview and Strategic Framework.
https://circulareconomy.europa.eu/platform/sites/default/files/strategy_-_towards_a_model_eng_completo.pdf
85
Budget-neutral fiscal reform is defined as changes in the composition of government revenues and expenses,
which are keeping the fiscal budget unchanged.
The UK Green Fiscal Commission modelled an ambitious tax shift in the UK, based largely on
Page | 27
energy taxes and some taxes on water and materials. The impacts included that over the
period 2006 to 2020 an increase of environmental tax revenues from 6% to 15% of total tax
revenues enabled income tax to be cut by 10% and National Insurance Contributions by
around one-third. Other impacts were that carbon dioxide emissions fell by 16% in 2020,
employment was up by around 1.5% (450,000 jobs) and the effect on GDP was negligible, ‘as
the negative effects of the energy price increase were almost completely offset by the positive
effects of the increased employment and reduced labour taxes’.86 This study fits in a long range
of modelling work finding similar impacts.
In 2005, a review looked at 186 model simulations taken from 61 separate studies. On average,
‘all of the different groupings of studies predicted net job creation with significant reductions in
CO2 emissions.87 In 2016, a working group led by The Ex’tax Project presented a tax shift
scenario for 27 EU Member States with positive results. Economic modelling has shown that
switching € 554 billion of taxes from labour to pollution and resource use in the European Union
could add € 842 billion in GDP (2.0% compared to business as usual), enable 6.6 million more
people to be in employment (2.9% compared to business as usual), cut carbon emissions by
8.2% by 2020 and save € 27.7 billion on the EU energy import bill over a five-year period.88
Although the basic principle is simple, rebalancing our tax system is not easy for a number of
reasons. First of all, tax policy is driven by politics, and the relatively short cycles in politics
makes it difficult to develop long-term tax strategies. Secondly, nobody really likes to pay for
something that was previously free of charge. Also, industries with an interest in keeping the
status quo often have a stronger voice than other interest groups such as non-governmental
organisations (NGOs), healthcare organisations or small and medium-sized enterprises that
may have an interest in a transition. Finally, there is the challenge of how to coordinate tax
reform internationally, as shifting financial incentives will change trade patterns. 89
Despite these barriers, the tax shift has been applied in at least nine countries in the past:
Sweden (1990), Denmark (1993), the Netherlands (1996), Finland (1997), Slovenia (1997),
86
Ekins 2015 in ACCA (2018), Tax as a force for good Rebalancing our tax systems to support a global economy
fit for the future. Professional Insight Report by Femke Groothuis, The Ex’tax Project.
https://www.accaglobal.com/gb/en/professional-insights/global-profession/environmental-tax.html
87
Eunomia and IEEP (2014), Study on Environmental Fiscal Reform Potential in 12 EU Member States.
http://knjiznica.sabor.hr/pdf/E_publikacije/Study_on_environmental_fiscal_reform_potential.pdf
88
The Ex’tax Project, Deloitte, EY, KPMG, Meijberg and PwC (2016), New Era. New plan. Europe. A Fiscal
Strategy for an Inclusive, Circular Economy. http://www.neweranewplan.com/
89
ACCA (2018), Tax as a force for good Rebalancing our tax systems to support a global economy fit for the
future. Professional Insight Report by Femke Groothuis, The Ex’tax Project.
https://www.accaglobal.com/gb/en/professional-insights/global-profession/environmental-tax.html
Germany (1999, 2007), UK (1996, 2001),90 British Columbia (Canada) (2008),91 and Colombia
Page | 28
(2012).92
International organisations such as the OECD (2011, 2013, 2015a, 2015b, 2018),93 IMF (2012;
2015; 2016; Heine et al. 2012; Lagarde 2012),94 World Bank (2015),95 European Parliament
(2012; 2013)96 and the ILO have all called for a change from labour-based taxation towards
tax on resource-use and consumption. The ILO has stated, for example:
Business groups such as the World Business Council for Sustainable Development98 and the
Business and Sustainable Development Commission99 have also supported such a tax reform.
90
Andersen, Mikael Skou (et al.) (2007) Competitiveness Effects of Environmental Tax Reforms (COMETR).
Final report to the European Commission.
91
Scientific American (Dec 1, 2015), A Tax on Carbon Pollution Can Benefit Business. Low oil and gas prices
make this the right time to tax fossil fuels.
92
IDB (2015), Fiscal Policy and Management Sector Framework Document.
93
OECD (2011), Towards Green Growth. https://www.oecd.org/greengrowth/48012345.pdf ; OECD (2013), Water
Security for Better Lives. OECD Studies on Water.
https://www.oecd.org/env/resources/Water%20Security%20for%20Better%20Lives-%20brochure.pdf ; OECD
(2015a), Towards Green Growth? Tracking Progress. https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/environment/towards-green-
growth_9789264234437-en#page1 ; OECD (2015b), Environment at a Glance 2015: OECD Indicators. https://
read.oecd-ilibrary.org/environment/environment-at-a-glance- 2015_9789264235199-en#page1; OECD (2018)
Economic Policy Reforms 2018. Going for Growth Interim Report. https://read.oecd-
ilibrary.org/economics/economic-policy-reforms-2018_growth-2018-en#page1
94
IMF (2012) Fiscal Policy to Mitigate Climate Change. A Guide for Policymakers. Editors: Ruud de Mooij, Ian
W.H. Parry, and Michael Keen. http://www.greenfiscalpolicy.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/08/Fiscal_
Policy_to_Mitigate_Climate_Change_IMF2012_Summary.pdf; IMF (2015), Kingdom of the Netherlands: Staff
Concluding Statement of the 2015 Article IV Mission.
https://www.imf.org/en/News/Articles/2015/09/28/04/52/mcs111015a ; IMF (2016), After Paris: Fiscal,
Macroeconomic, and Financial Implications of Climate Change.
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2016/sdn1601.pdf ; Heine, D., Norregaard, J. and Parry, I.W.H. (2012)
Environmental Tax Reform: Principles from Theory and Practice to Date, IMF Working Paper WP/12/180.
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12180.pdf ; Lagarde, C. (2012), Back to Rio—the Road to a
Sustainable Economic Future’, Speech by Christine Lagarde.
https://www.imf.org/en/News/Articles/2015/09/28/04/53/sp061212
95
World Bank (2015), Decarbonizing Development. Three Steps to a Zero-Carbon Future.
https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/21842
96
European Parliament (2012), European Parliament resolution of 24 May 2012 on a Resource-efficient Europe
(2011/2068(INI)). http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=-//EP//TEXT+TA+P7-TA-2012-
0223+0+DOC+XML+V0//EN ; European Parliament (2013), Living Well, within the Limits of our Planet, 7th EAP –
The New General Union Environment Action Programme to 2020.
http://ec.europa.eu/environment/pubs/pdf/factsheets/7eap/en.pdf
97
ILO (2012), Working towards sustainable development. Opportunities for decent work and social inclusion in a
green economy.
98
WBCSD (World Business Council for Sustainable Development) (2010), Vision 2050.
99
BSDC (Business and Sustainable Development Commission) (2017), Better Business, Better World: Executive
Summary. http://report.businesscommission.org/uploads/Executive-Summary.pdf
According to the European Commission, a tax shift from labour to green taxes is ‘a winning
Page | 29
strategy’:
In 2018, OECD recommendations to Finland specifically included the advice to further reduce
the tax burden on labour, increase environmentally-related taxes and phase out
environmentally harmful subsidies.101
Multiple measures – variety in impacts
Shifting the tax burden from labour to natural resource use consists of multiple policies; it is
multi-faceted - and so are the potential impacts. More than a hundred options for ‘green’ taxes
are available to governments for applying the ‘polluter pays’ principle, including putting a price
on air pollution (such as carbon emissions), fossil fuels, waste and water.102
Raising taxes on natural resource-use (such as water, harmful emissions, metals and
minerals) creates both challenges and opportunities for businesses. On one hand, it will be
challenging to reduce water consumption and carbon footprints. On the other hand, when the
price of natural resources goes up, the business case of resource efficient technologies
improves.
In general, when taxes on labour go down, human resources (manpower, craftsmanship and
ingenuity) will become more affordable. Business models can then shift to labour-intensive
business models, repair and maintenance services, remanufacturing of products and R&D. A
lower tax burden on labour also benefits sectors such as healthcare, education and scientific
research. A tax shift has a fundamental impact on consumption patterns too, as pricing of
products and services better reflects the external costs by applying the ‘polluter pays’
principles. Circular business models become more competitive if externalities would be priced
into polluting products and labour costs would go down.
Any potential regressive effect can be balanced out by using (part of) the revenues to lowering
the tax burden (or providing benefits) to low-income groups. As the High-level Commission on
Carbon Prices concludes:
‘Taxing ‘bads’ (pollutants) rather than ‘goods’ (labor, capital) can allow for
a less costly tax system... Revenues can also be used to reduce the social
100
European Commission (2015), Smart Taxation: A Winning Strategy. [video]
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=8kGgpaC6ID8 , accessed 4 November 2018
101
OECD (2018), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2018. https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/oecd-
economic-surveys-finland-2018_eco_surveys-fin-2018-
102
The Ex’tax Project, Deloitte, EY, KPMG, Meijberg and PwC (2016), New Era. New plan. Europe. A Fiscal
Strategy for an Inclusive, Circular Economy. http://www.neweranewplan.com/
charges imposed on labor costs. This may reduce unemployment rates and
Page | 30
help increase real wages. This would also serve to counteract the
potentially regressive effects of higher carbon prices and help poor people
deal with the higher price levels caused by carbon pricing. It also has
positive distributional impacts because of the larger share of wages in the
total income of poor households (higher-income households may have
other sources of income – capital, interest, and rents). Moreover, mitigation
options (eg, energy efficiency, renewables, and agricultural and forestry
low-carbon practices) are generally more labor-intensive than economic
activities based on fossil fuels. Therefore, recycling carbon tax revenues
may generate a double dividend: fostering the transition toward
decarbonization while simultaneously promoting economic growth and
social development.’103
This study explores the potential of a tax shift in Finland. It aims to propose broad-based,
budget-neutral policy measures that incentivise resource-efficiency and employment, while
maintaining overall long-term competitiveness. The next chapter will explain how the research
group developed the scenario under review.
103
CPLC (2017), Report of the High-level Commission on Carbon Prices.
https://www.carbonpricingleadership.org/report-of-the-highlevel- commission-on-carbon-prices/
3. DEVELOPING A CIRCULAR TAX SCENARIO Page | 31
This chapter describes the methodologies used by the GBE, IEEP and Ex’tax research group
to develop a circular tax scenario, which served as input to the modelling.
“The target of the Finnish government and the road map is to make Finland
a global leader in the circular economy by 2025.”105
A circular economy is regenerative, and carbon neutral by design and the policy proposals
should serve the four themes and the goals identified in the roadmap:
Goals: The use of sustainable resources; Sustainable crops production; Short supply chains
(local food); Nutrient recycling and waste management systems.
104
The Ex’tax Project, Deloitte, EY, KPMG, Meijberg and PwC (2016), New Era. New plan. Europe. A Fiscal
Strategy for an Inclusive, Circular Economy. http://www.neweranewplan.com/
105
Sitra (2016), Leading the cycle – Finnish road map to a circular economy 2016–2025.
https://www.sitra.fi/en/publications/leading-cycle/
Theme 2: Forest-based loops
Page | 32
Goals: Recycling of forest industry’s side streams; More refined products than pulp & paper;
Wood construction & wooden furniture; Substituting fossil resources and using more wood-
based textiles.
Goals: All industrial sectors minimise the need for virgin raw materials by lengthening product
life cycles through redesign, reuse, recycling, repair & maintenance, use of secondary
materials and remanufacturing.
Goals: Moving beyond fossil-fuelled transport; More ‘service-based’ transport system; Ending
fossil fuel use in private cars by 2040; Promoting sustainable biofuels; Replacement of fossil
fuels with renewable and non-fossil alternatives; Optimisation of transport routes and material
flows and boost public transport.
Overarching themes are inclusive growth and a fair transition by increasing employment and
wellbeing (including health and social benefits) as well as improving competitiveness of the
Finnish economy through the development of new circular business models. Figure 3 provides
a schematic overview of themes in the circular roadmap.
106
Based on Sitra (2016)
Data limitations were also identified, for example with regard to mining waste per type of
Page | 33
material, recent water data (after 2010) and details of wastewater. Data limitations restrict the
number of policy options that can be modelled.
The ‘Ex’tax Policy Toolkit’ provides an overview of options to shift the tax burden from labour
to natural resource use. Figure 4 shows policy options to lower labour taxes (personal income
tax, social contributions and payroll tax) and more generally to use revenues for the good of
society (e.g. social assistance, environmental protection, and investments). Each category
includes several sub-categories.
Figure 5 provides policy options to apply the ‘polluter pays’ principle and raise revenues based
on natural resource use and consumption (e.g. air pollution, energy, food production inputs,
fossil fuels, metals and minerals). Again, each category includes several sub-categories.
Within the waste category, for example, one of the sub-categories is electronic waste.
In order to create a workable scope, the research group identified a focus group of policy areas
that could help advance the circular roadmap themes by (a) broadening the tax base of
environmental taxes, (b) increasing the rates of environmental taxes, (c) abolishing or reducing
environmentally harmful subsidies (EHS), and (d) lowering labour taxes.
For each theme and goal, the inputs and outputs were assessed (e.g. industrial loops are
linked to inputs such as metals, electricity, water and fossil fuels and outputs such as solid
waste, waste water and air pollution). The focus group of policy areas was chosen based on
criteria such as urgency and (mid- to long-term) attainability. Each policy option is also intended
to be a significant contributor, which means smaller measures are not (yet) included. The
overall goal was a fair transition with progressive impacts on income. The current tax system,
cultural preferences, geographic issues and the climate zone of Finland were also taken into
account to the extent possible.
In building the scenario, there were limitations due to lack of data for some parameters, as well
as limitations to the dimensions in the E3ME model. In sustainable transport, for example, a
Helsinki area congestion charge could not be included, since the model does not allow for
regional assessments. The tax bases this study focuses on are highlighted in pink in Figures
4 and 5. The scenario focuses on tax measures; potential other (non-fiscal) market-based
instruments are discussed in Chapter 5.
Consultations
107
Based on The Ex’tax Project et al. (2016), New era. New plan. Europe. Fiscal reform for an inclusive circular
economy. www.neweranewplan.com
Page | 35
The next section provides a brief overview of the scenario under review.
Revenue-raising measures:
108
Based on The Ex’tax Project et al. (2016), New era. New plan. Europe. www.neweranewplan.com
§ Air pollution taxes
Page | 36 1) CO2 (non-road sectors, bulk users): Carbon Price Floor
§ Fossil fuels
2) Removal of the diesel subsidies (transport sector)
3) Removal of the light fuel oil subsidy
4) Removal of the peat subsidy
5) Non-energy use of fossil fuels (mineral oils and other fossil material used in plastics
and other chemical industry)
§ Energy
6) Electricity (bulk users)
7) Removal of the subsidy for energy-intensive industries
§ Transport related taxes
8) Air passengers
9) Air freight
§ Waste related taxes
10) Incineration of waste
11) Nuclear waste
§ Water
12) Water abstraction
§ Metals and minerals
13) Extraction of metal ores
14) Extraction of non-metallic minerals
§ Agriculture related taxes
15) Pesticides
Figures 6 and 7 provide a brief overview of the tax bases, the measures, pricing level per unit
and the revenues raised and used by each measure.
Page | 37
Figure 6. Estimated use of revenues in the scenario in 2025 in real prices (Cambridge Econometrics
2018).
Page | 38
Figure 7. Estimated revenues of the scenario in 2025 in real prices (Cambridge Econometrics 2018).
Figure 8 shows how the measures contribute to a budget-neutral shift from labour to natural
resource use in 2025. On the right are measures that, compared to the baseline, raise an
additional € 3.5 billion of revenues for the treasuries in Finland (at current prices). On the left
is shown how the costs of labour can potentially be lowered by the same amount.
Page | 39
Figure 8. €3.5 billion tax shift scenario from labour to natural resource-use in Finland (2025)
(Cambridge Econometrics 2018).
Clearly, tax systems are not static; they will evolve with new circumstances. When the updated
system works properly, the tax base can be extended to other categories within the Toolkit, in
order to guarantee a stable government income. Rates and tariffs can also be raised or
lowered; just like the current system of labour taxes, the future system will also be adapted
periodically.
It should be emphasised that the scenario is not a blue print for implementation. It is meant to
provide directions on how the fiscal system can be rationalised in light of the circular economy
roadmap and what the potential impacts are. Any implementation pathway should be
researched and then monitored by the designated Finnish institutions with full access to
national statistics.
In the following sections, the measures are described in terms of the national context in
Finland, the scope of the measures, their rationale, potential revenue, and examples of best
practices in the EU, which may serve as a source of inspiration.
Page | 40 Revenue-raising measures
Carbon Price Floor (non-road sectors, bulk users)
Context
In 1990, Finland became the first country to introduce a carbon tax for fossil fuels. The tax
originally covered fuel oil, natural gas, coal and peat at a rate of € 1.12/tonne of CO2, and has
since undergone several changes. The current excise tax on fossil fuels consists of three
components: an energy content component, a CO2 emissions component (CO2 tax) and a
strategic stockpile fee for certain fuels. The energy and CO2 tax rates have been significantly
increased in the 2000s. At the start of 2018, the carbon tax rate was increased to € 62/tonne
of CO2 emissions109. According to the state budget, energy taxes would accrue total revenues
of around €4.683 billion in 2018, including the revenues from the CO2 tax component110.
In addition to carbon taxation, other economic instruments111 have been used in Finland to
tackle CO2 emissions and to promote low carbon solutions. The main instruments have been
the EU Emission Trading System (EU ETS) and different kind of subsidies to renewable energy
sources, like feed-in-tariff scheme and Energy Aid Programmes for investment support for
renewable energy and energy-saving projects. The EU ETS applies to large industrial and
energy production plants and covers approximately half of the greenhouse gas emissions in
Finland112. For a long time after the start of the ETS in 2005, the allowance price remained low
because of a surplus of emission allowances. Consequently, the incentive to reduce emissions
was not strong. However, it is estimated that in Europe the ETS has had a significant effect on
the emissions of the firms participating in it. In Finland, emissions in the EU ETS sectors have
decreased by 24% between 2005 and 2017.113 Nevertheless, the role of the ETS to the
reduction is uncertain, because at the same time other instruments have been introduced. For
example, the feed-in-tariff scheme for renewable energy has affected the ETS sectors’
emission as well. In 2018, the price of the emission allowance has increased significantly, from
approximately 8 euros in January to 21 euros per tonne of carbon dioxide (CO2 eq.) in August
2018.114
The total Finnish emissions of greenhouse gases in 2017 corresponded to 56.1 million tonnes
of carbon dioxide (CO2 eq.), excluding land use, land-use change and forestry (LULUCF).
109
Finlex (2018), Hallituksen esitys eduskunnalle laeiksi nestemäisten polttoaineiden valmisteverosta sekä
sähkön ja eräiden polttoaineiden valmisteverosta annettujen lakien liitteiden muuttamisesta, HE 138/2017 vp,
(Government Proposal for acts for changing the appendices of the Acts on Excise Duty on Liquid Fuels and Act
on Excise Duty on Electricity and and Certain Fuels). http://www.finlex.fi/fi/esitykset/he/2017/20170138.pdf
110
Ministry of Finance (2017), Talousarvioesitys, Tuloarviot, Verot ja veroluonteiset tulot, Valmisteverot, 07.
Energiaverot, HE 106/2017 vp. (19.9.2017) (Budget Proposal 2018, Tax and tax-like revenues, Excise duties, 07.
Energy taxes.) Only in Finnish.
http://budjetti.vm.fi/indox/download.jsp?lang=fi&file=/2018/aky/YksityiskohtaisetPerustelut/11/08/07/07.pdf
111
In addition to economic instruments, various regulations and voluntary programmes have been used, as well.
112
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment (2018), Emission Trading. https://tem.fi/en/emissions-trading
113
Official Statistics of Finland (OSF). Suomen kasvihuonekaasupäästöt 1990–2017 (Finland's greenhouse gas
emissions in 1990 to 2017).
114
Tamminen S., Haanperä O. and Hietaniemi T. (2018): “Harnessing economic instruments to tackle the climate
crisis − Finland’s experiences with economic instruments applied in climate policy”, Sitra Memorandum 5.10.2018.
Since 1990, Finnish emissions have reduced by one fifth (21%).115 Nevertheless, the full
Page | 41
implementation of a carbon-neutral circular economy needs more effective economic
instruments and other policy tools.
In Finland, like in other European countries, the greenhouse gas emission targets and related
instruments have been divided into two sectors: the emissions trading sector, and the effort
sharing sector. The latter covers the sectors of the economy that fall outside the scope of the
EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS), such as construction, building-specific heating,
housing, agriculture, transport and waste management, and industrial F-gases. These sectors
account for a little more than a half of the EU's greenhouse gas emissions. Emissions in sectors
not covered by the ETS are regulated under the Effort Sharing Decision. 117
In October 2014, EU leaders set a binding economy-wide domestic emission reductions target
for 2021-2030 of at least 40% by 2030 compared to 1990. It was specified that the effort
sharing sector must reduce emissions by 30% by 2030 compared to 2005 as their contribution
to the overall target. The Effort Sharing Regulation translates this commitment into binding
annual greenhouse gas emission targets for each Member State for the period 2021–2030,
based on the principles of fairness, cost-effectiveness and environmental integrity. The
Regulation was adopted on 14 May 2018. Accordingly, Finland's individual target is to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions by 39% compared to 2005 in the effort sharing sector.118
According to World Bank (2018) data, around 40% of all greenhouse gas emissions (including
other than CO2 emissions) in Finland are covered by a carbon tax.119 Taxation is used as a
main instrument in the effort sharing sector. However, it should be kept in mind that about half
of the greenhouse gas emissions in Finland are covered by the ETS.120 If we are looking only
at the carbon taxation, 49 million tonnes of CO2 emissions (incl. biomass & waste) were not
115
Official Statistics of Finland (OSF). Suomen kasvihuonekaasupäästöt 1990–2017 (Finland's greenhouse gas
emissions in 1990 to 2017)
https://www.stat.fi/static/media/uploads/tup/khkinv/yymp_kahup_1990-2017_2018_19735_net.pdf
116
OECD (2016), OECD Economic Surveys Finland. https://www.oecd.org/eco/surveys/Overview-OECD-Finland-
2016.pdf
117
Ministry of the Environment (2018): The European Union's climate policy. http://www.ym.fi/en-
US/The_environment/Climate_and_air/Mitigation_of_climate_change/The_European_Unions_climate_policy
118
European Commission (2018). Effort sharing 2021-2030: targets and flexibilities.
https://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/effort/proposal_en
119
World Bank (2018), State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2018,
https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/29687/9781464812927.pdf
120
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment (2018), Emission Trading. https://tem.fi/en/emissions-trading
under carbon taxation in 2015 (see graph 2 on page 19 for an overview of how the effective
Page | 42
carbon tax rates differ by sector and by energy resource).121
A wide variety of estimates exist of the so-called social cost of carbon (i.e. the damage that
results from emitting one tonne of CO2). The OECD applies a minimum social cost of carbon
of €30 per tonne, and in 2018 added a benchmark of €60 per tonne to their analyses to reflect
the estimated cost of carbon in the future.122 Other estimates do not take into account the
external costs to society, but the price range needed to achieve certain reduction targets. The
High-level Commission on Carbon Pricing, for example, concluded that a $40–$80 range in
2020, rising to $50–$100 by 2030, would be consistent with the core objective of the Paris
Agreement of keeping the average temperature rise below 2 degrees Celsius.123
In Finland, the role of biomass as energy source has increased in recent years. In 2017, wood
fuels reached a new record and became the most important energy source in Finland. They
accounted for 27% of the total energy consumption.124 Biomass in Finland consists mainly of
wood fuels, which are forest industry side-streams and wood residues. In addition, biogas is
produced from organic waste or compostable waste from industrial, municipal or agricultural
waste. Only a very marginal share comes from field biomasses consisting of energy plants or
their parts.
Wood fuels sources and their energy production capacity are divided as follows:
§ solid wood fuels used at power and heating plants accounted for 38 terawatt-hours,
§ the burning of black liquor made up 43 terawatt-hours,
§ the small-scale combustion of wood comprised 17 terawatt-hours, and
§ other wood fuels covered 2 terawatt-hours.125
The consumption of different wood fuels as part of the total energy consumption is shown in
figure 9.
121
OECD (2018), Taxing Energy Use 2018. https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/taxing-energy-use-
2018_9789264289635-en#page2
122
‘The first, EUR 30 is a low-end estimate of the damage that carbon emissions currently cause. Pricing
emissions above EUR 30 does not guarantee that polluters pay for the full damage they cause, or that prices are
sufficiently high to decarbonise economies. A price below EUR 30 does mean, however, that emitters are not
directly confronted with the cost of emissions to society and that incentives for cost effective abatement are too
weak. The second benchmark, EUR 60 per tonne of CO2, is a midpoint estimate of carbon costs in 2020, as well
as a forward-looking low-end estimate of carbon costs in 2030. Rising benchmark values over time for carbon
costs reflect that the marginal damage caused by one tonne of CO2 increases with the accumulation of CO2 in the
atmosphere’ (OECD (2018), Taxing Energy Use 2018. https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/taxing-energy-use-
2018_9789264289635-en#page43.
123
CPLC (2017), Report of the High-level Commission on Carbon Prices.
https://www.carbonpricingleadership.org/report-of-the-highlevel-commission-on-carbon-prices/
124
Natural Resources Institute Finland LUKE (May 24, 2018), The use of wood in energy generation reached a
new record in 2017, https://www.luke.fi/en/news/the-use-of-wood-in-energy-generation-reached-a-new-record-in-
2017/
125
ibid.
Page | 43
Figure 9. Consumption of wood fuels in Finland 2017. Source: Natural Resources Institute Finland LUKE
126
Biomass, which has been defined technically as a renewable energy source, has offered an
alternative for unrenewable fossil fuels. This has been the case in Finland were the use of
biomass has been encouraged by different subsidy schemes such as energy aid and
investment programmes.127 For example, since 2011, Finland has maintained a feed-in tariff
scheme to support the introduction of more renewable energy. Under this scheme, in addition
to wind power, new biogas power plants (gas produced by digestion), new wood-fuelled power
plants (that also produce heat for use) and forest chip power plants have been able to apply
for support. 128
Nevertheless, there is a growing debate on the CO2 emissions of biomass in Finland and
internationally. At the moment, these emissions are not under any kind of pricing mechanism
according to their CO2 content even though they are included in the land-use, land-use change
and forestry sector (LULUCF).
The increasing use of biomass produces CO2 emissions as well. Consequently, a re-evaluation
of the existing approach may be necessary even if the carbon sink is not significantly reduced
by the use of biomass. In Finland, the use of biomass consists mainly of the residues and side
streams produced by the pulp and paper industry, thus trees are not cut to burn as biomass.
In addition, the carbon stock in Finland has been quite stable. However, the role of biomass,
126
https://www.luke.fi/en/news/the-use-of-wood-in-energy-generation-reached-a-new-record-in-2017/
127
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Energy aid. https://tem.fi/en/energy-aid
and Investment aid for key energy projects. https://tem.fi/en/investment-aid-for-key-energy-projects
128
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Feed-in tariff for renewable Energy.
https://tem.fi/en/feed-in-tariff-for-renewable-energy
its emissions and calculation basis should be reconsidered based on open and thorough
Page | 44
reflection.
Internationally, burning wood and wood by-products for electricity generation is the subject of
much debate:
In 2018, more than 800 scientists sent a letter to European policymakers sounding the alarm
about the burning of wood pellets for electricity generation.130
In Finland, CO2 emissions from biomass and waste are currently free of charge, even though
biomass causes 44% of carbon emissions in the country.131 It is important to note that the use
of wood and wood by-products for heat and energy generation is deeply engrained in Finnish
culture and economy.
The measure
The scenario under review includes:
§ A carbon price floor of € 10 per tonne of CO2 emitted from biomass (e.g. wood and
wood by-products);
§ A carbon price floor of € 60 per tonne of CO2 emitted by all other energy resources
used across all industries (e.g. coal, peat, fossil fuels and CHP).
These measures target industrial users (not households). In the modelling, in ETS sectors it
is applied as a mark-up to the ETS price.132 The cost of heat generation in the modelling is
129
Chelsea Harvey, Niina Heikkinen (March 23, 2018), Congress Says Biomass Is Carbon-Neutral, but Scientists
Disagree. Scientific American. https://www.scientificamerican.com/article/congress-says-biomass-is-carbon-neutral-
but-scientists-disagree/ Online article, accessed November 19, 2018.
130
January 11, 2018: letter from scientists to the EU parliament regarding forest biomass.
https://www.euractiv.com/wp-content/uploads/sites/2/2018/01/Letter-of-Scientists-on-Use-of-Forest-Biomass-for-
Bioenergy-January-12-2018.pdf
131
Looking at industrial emissions alone, 74.5 million tonnes of CO2 were emitted in 2015, of which 33 million
tonnes CO2 emissions (44%) were from biomass used as fuel. The combined emissions by industries and
households were 86.4 million tonnes of CO2 in 2015, of which 38.7 million tonnes CO2 emissions (45%) were from
biomass used as fuel. Eurostat (2018), Air emissions accounts by NACE Rev. 2 activity [env_ac_ainah_r2].
Accessed November 19, 2018.
132
The state aid under the ETS remains unchanged. ‘The European Commission has approved a Finnish support
scheme to partially compensate energy-intensive companies in certain sectors for higher electricity prices
resulting from indirect emission costs under the EU Emission Trading Scheme (ETS). This benefits companies in
increased only depending on the type of fuel used. Aviation remains exempt until an EU-wide
Page | 45
approach is found.
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goal of carbon neutrality, industrial loops,
sustainable food, forest loops & sustainable transport by:
§ Putting an effective price on CO2 emissions;
§ Creating a level playing field between fuels with regard to carbon contents (the “polluter
pays” principle);
§ Directing Finland towards an emissions trajectory consistent with the Paris Agreement;
§ Creating fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The revenue of this measure would be € 869 million for the high rate in 2025, and € 284 million
for the low rate, totalling € 1,153 million in 2025 (33% of the revenues raised in the scenario).
Best practices
See the box below. The UK Carbon Price Floor has been highly effective:
'the drop in the European Union (EU) Emissions Trading System (ETS)
emissions (by 2.4 percent in 2016) was primarily driven by the carbon-price
floor introduced in the United Kingdom, where a £18/tCO2 top-up on the
EU ETS price resulted in the coal power plants reducing their emissions by
58 percent in 2016.'133
The UK introduced a carbon price floor in in 2013 to complement the EU ETS. It is administered via
a levy on fossil fuels used to generate electricity, taking into account their average carbon content.
The carbon price floor applies to fossil fuel-based electricity generators, including electricity that is
also subject to the Climate Change Levy regime. The covered fossil fuels are natural gas, liquified
petroleum gas (LPG), coal and other taxable solid fossil fuels, gas oil, fuel oil and other heavy oil134.
specific sectors that are especially exposed to international competition: The state aid aims to avoid an increase
in global greenhouse gas emissions due to shifts of production outside the European Union, where they may face
less environmental regulation. The scheme will cover the period from 2016 to 2020. Finland will grant to relevant
companies compensation of 40% of the eligible costs for the period in 2016-2018 and 37.5% of the eligible costs
for the period 2019-2020. Beneficiaries will still bear part of the ETS costs, so they have an incentive to limit their
electricity consumption. The budget of the scheme is approximately €149 million.’ European Commission (April
2017). http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_MEX-17-864_en.htm
133
CPLC (2017), Report of the High-level Commission on Carbon Prices.
https://www.carbonpricingleadership.org/report-of-the-highlevel-commission-on-carbon-prices/
134
Environmental Defence Fund, CDC Climate Research, Caisse des Dépots Group, IETA Climate Challenges
Market Solutions (2015), United Kingdom. The World’s Carbon Markets: A Case Study Guide to Emissions
Trading. Last Updated: May 2015.
Page | 46
Fossil Fuels
Removal of the diesel subsidy (transport sector)
Context
In Finland, the effective tax rate per tonne of CO2 emitted is significantly lower for diesel (€
190.1 per tonne) than petrol (€ 301.6 per tonne) (see Table 2).135 The difference in pricing
represents an effective subsidy for diesel and increases the demand for diesel and diesel
driven vehicles. The diesel subsidy represented a tax expenditure of € 746 m in 2016.136 Since
the diesel subsidy is targeted towards the transport industry rather than household use of
diesel, the vehicle tax on driving power (€ 388 million 2017) partly offsets the diesel subsidy137.
According to the OECD:
"raising diesel taxation to the level applied on gasoline would spur the
development of alternative fuels and transport modes”.138
Table 2. Duty and effective carbon tax on diesel and petrol for Finland 2018
Diesel Petrol
Duty on fuel (€/1,000 530 703
litres)139
Effective tax rate 190.1 301.6
(€/tonne of CO2)140
The measure
The scenario under review includes the removal of the Reduced Energy Tax Rate on Diesel
Used in Transport minus the driving power vehicle tax.
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goals of sustainable transport, industrial
loops, sustainable food and forest loops by:
§ Phasing out fossil fuel subsidies in line with the Finnish commitment to the Friends of
Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform (FFFSR);
§ Creating a level playing field between fuels (the “polluter pays” principle);
https://www.ieta.org/resources/Resources/Case_Studies_Worlds_Carbon_Markets/2015/uk_case_study_may201
5.pdf
135
This does not consider indirect subsidies for diesel, such as those included in the vehicles taxation system.
136
OECD (2018), Fossil Fuel Support – FIN. https://oecd.stat.org
137
Ministry of Finance (2017), Talousarvioesitys, Tuloarviot, Verot ja veroluonteiset tulot, Valmisteverot, 07.
Energiaverot, HE 106/2017 vp. (19.9.2017) (Budget Proposal 2018, Tax and tax-like revenues, Excise duties, 07.
Energy taxes.) Only in Finnish.
138
OECD (2018), Tax Reform To Support Growth And Employment In Finland.
http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplaydocumentpdf/?cote=ECO/WKP(2018)16&docLanguage=En
139
European Automobile Manufacturers Association. ACEA, Tax guide
https://www.acea.be/uploads/news_documents/ACEA_Tax_Guide_2018.pdf
140
OECD 2018, Taxing energy use – companion to taxing energy use database
§ Aligning tax policy with climate and health goals;
Page | 47
§ Creating fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
The measure is expected to contribute to national goals including 1) ending fossil fuel use in
private cars by 2045; 2) promoting sustainable biofuels; 3) replacing fossil fuels with renewable
& non-fossil alternatives; 4) optimisation of transport routes and material flows.
As the removal of the reduced rate on diesel will have substantial economic impacts on the
transport sector, there should be additional measures to help investments on low-carbon
vehicles and to boost the transition towards carbon-neutral transportation.
Potential revenue
The estimated revenue would be € 461 million in 2025 (13% of the revenues raised in the
scenario).
Best practices
The UK is the only EU Member State to have equalised the “at pump” fuel rates for diesel and petrol,
as of 1994. The rate for both petrol and diesel in the UK was €661 per 1,000 litres of fuel in 2018.
Prior to 1994 diesel was charged a lower rate. The revenues from fuel duties were €31.8 billion for
2017/2018141. Fuel rates overall in the UK have gradually increased between 1993 and 1999 as part
of the “duty escalator” policy. In 1999, the tax on fuel represented 85% of the price, compared to
64% in 2018142. Since then, the escalator concept persists but specific policies have defined rate
increases, including those linking fuel prices to inflation and freezes in prices at various points143.
Other factors have also increased the cost of fuels in the UK, including the increase of the VAT rate
to 20% and the decline in the value of GBP.
The 2018 UK rate is the highest rate applied for diesel in the EU. However, this is not the highest
rate for fuels overall in the EU; several Member States have higher rates for petrol but lower rates
for diesel. For example, the Netherlands charges a higher rate for petrol of € 778 per 1,000 litres,
compared with € 490 for diesel. Other Member States with high rates for fuels include Sweden, Italy
and Denmark.
The UK’s 2017 Autumn Budget statement complemented fuel rates with specific measures on diesel
vehicles. This included increasing the Vehicle Excise Duty (VED) rates for diesel vehicles by one
141
UK Government (2017a) Petrol and diesel prices and duties in April: United Kingdom Fuel consumption tables,
produced by Department for Transport. https://www.gov.uk/government/statistical-data-sets/env01-fuel-
consumption
142
Johnson, P; Leicester, A; Stoye, G. (2012) Fuel for Thought – the what, why and how of motoring taxation.
RAC Foundation. https://www.racfoundation.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/11/fuel_for_thought-johnson_et_al-
150512.pdf
143
Seely, A (2018) Taxation of road fuels – House of Commons Briefing Paper Number 824.
http://researchbriefings.files.parliament.uk/documents/SN00824/SN00824.pdf
Page | 48 band and increasing the company car tax on diesels by 1%144. In 2017, 42% of new cars registered
in the UK were diesels, compared to an EU-15 average of around 45%, just over 30% in Finland
and 17.5% in the Netherlands (the lowest). Historically, UK diesel sales peaked in 2012 at around
51%, having increased steadily prior to this from 6.4% in 1990145. As this is around the same time
the diesel rates were equalised, this implies that the measure was not effective at reducing the
purchase of diesel vehicles and the consumption of diesel overall. This suggests that other factors
than simply closing the diesel gap may help to determine fuel type consumption and the share of
diesel in vehicle fleets.
Evidence based on existing practice suggests that a combination of fiscal and regulatory measures
is most effective in reducing the carbon intensity of vehicle fleets. In the EU, the Netherlands has
the lowest CO2 emissions from new vehicle registrations – 105.9 gCO2 / km in 2016, compared to
an EU-28 average of 118.8 gCO2 / km and 120 gCO2 per km in Finland146. The Netherlands also
has the lowest number of new diesel vehicles as a percentage of new registrations at 19% in 2016.
Likewise, the Netherlands had the highest share of electric chargeable (BEV, PHEV) vehicles in the
EU-28 with 6% and was second only to Norway globally with 29%147.
In the Netherlands, the car registration tax (Belasting Personenauto’s Motorrijwielen, BPM)
increases rapidly with every additional gram of CO2. Under the Dutch system after 175 gCO2/km
and every additional gram costs €478, with an additional surcharge of €86.43 per gram above
67g/km for diesel cars. High-emitting vehicles over 400g gCO2 /km pay up to €120,000.
Previously diesel cars with EURO 6 engines received a rebate in the BPM, however this has since
been removed. On the other hand, plug in hybrids (PHEV) are exempt when they produce zero
emissions and pay lower rates compared to other vehicles; additionally, they do not pay a fixed
€356 surcharge charged to all other vehicle types148. The signal is strengthened by the road tax in
the Netherlands (motorrijtuigenbelasting, MRB). Annual road tax is based on vehicle weight and the
EURO classification of the vehicle, with a surcharge payable for diesel vehicles. Although the
Netherlands does not have an equal fuel rate for diesel and petrol, the system heavily penalises
diesels and high emitting vehicles in general. This gives low emissions vehicles, and particularly
PHEVs, a significant price advantage. The effects of these measures are reflected in purchasing
behaviour in the Dutch car fleet.
144
UK Government (2017b) Oral statement to Parliament. Autumn Budget 2017: Philip Hammond's speech. HM
Treasury and The Rt Hon Philip Hammond MP. https://www.gov.uk/government/speeches/autumn-budget-2017-
philip-hammonds-speech
145
ACEA (2018) Share of Diesel in New Passenger Cars. https://www.acea.be/statistics/article/Share-of-diesel-in-
new-passenger-cars
146
T&E, Forum Ökologisch-Soziale Marktwirtschaft (FÖS) / Green Budget Germany (GBG) (2018 forthcoming) A
comparison of CO2-based car taxation in EU-28, Norway and Switzerland
147
Ibid.
148
ACEA (2018) Share of Diesel in New Passenger Cars. https://www.acea.be/statistics/article/Share-of-diesel-in-
new-passenger-cars
Page | 49
Context
In Finland, a reduced energy tax rate is applied for light fuel oil used in mobile machinery,
meaning off road agricultural, construction, gardening and municipal use149. Light fuel oil is
used also for heating purposes in households. The light fuel oil subsidy represented a tax
expenditure of € 444 million in 2017.150
The measure
The scenario under review includes the removal of the light fuel oil subsidy.
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goals of industrial loops, sustainable food,
forest loops and carbon-neutral transport by:
§ Phasing out fossil fuel subsidies in line with the Finnish commitment to the FFFSR;
thereby applying the “polluter pays” principle;
§ Creating a level playing field between fuels;
§ Driving energy efficiency;
§ Creating fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
The removal of the light fuel oil subsidy will have economic impacts on agriculture, construction
and public sector, as well as, on households. Therefore, additional measures to help
investments on low-carbon machinery and to boost transition towards carbon-neutral heating
should be implemented at the same time. The removal of light fuel oil subsidy should be
implemented as gradually rising and having the biggest increases only in the last years when
actors could have been able to adapt to the forthcoming changes.
Potential revenue
The estimated revenue would be € 442 million in 2025 (13% of the revenues raised in the
scenario).
Context
149
Tax Administration (2018), WWW-pages for Detailed Guidance, Energy Taxation.
https://www.vero.fi/en/detailed-guidance/guidance/56206/energy_taxation/#act-on-excise-duty-on-electricity-and-
certain-fuels
150
Ministry of the Finance (2017), Talousarvioesitys, Tuloarviot, Verot ja veroluonteiset tulot, Valmisteverot, 07.
Energiaverot (Budget Proposal 2018, Tax and tax-like revenues, Excise duties, 07. Energy taxes) Only in Finnish.
http://budjetti.vm.fi/indox/sisalto.jsp?year=2018&lang=fi&maindoc=/2018/tae/hallituksenEsitys/hallituksenEsitys.x
ml&opennode=0:1:133:141:143:163:171:
Peat is the only fossil-like energy material extracted in Finland.151 Finland applies a reduced
Page | 50
carbon tax rate on fuel peat used in heating, which represented a tax expenditure of € 148
million in 2017.152
The measure
The scenario under review includes the removal of the peat subsidy.
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goal of carbon neutrality by levelling the
playing field between fuels with regard to carbon contents (the “polluter pays” principle).
Phasing out fossil fuel subsidies is in line with the Finnish commitment to the FFFSR and
creates fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The revenue of this measure would be € 140 million in 2025 (4% of the revenues raised in the
scenario).
Context
In 2016, non-energy use of fossil fuels in industry in Finland (including petroleum products and
natural gas) was around 65.53 petajoules or 1,565,000 tonnes of oil equivalent (toe).153
According to the Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency (PBL), the external costs of
non-energy use of fossil fuels in the Netherlands are € 9.59 million per PJ. If the same value
per PJ were applied in Finland, the external cost of non-energy use of fossil fuels in Finland
would amount to € 628 million.154
In the case of plastics, production is heavily dependent on fossil fuels, with 90% of the plastics
produced globally derived from fossil fuels.155 Of the 7-8% of global oil production used to
produce plastics, 4% is used as feedstock for plastics, with the remaining 3-4% used to provide
energy for plastics manufacture.156 157
151
Eurostat (2018), Material flow accounts [env_ac_mfa]. Accessed November 19, 2018.
152
Ministry of the Finance (2017), Talousarvioesitys, Tuloarviot, Verot ja veroluonteiset tulot, Valmisteverot, 07.
Energiaverot (Budget Proposal 2018, Tax and tax-like revenues, Excise duties, 07. Energy taxes) Only in Finnish.
http://budjetti.vm.fi/indox/sisalto.jsp?year=2018&lang=fi&maindoc=/2018/tae/hallituksenEsitys/hallituksenEsitys.x
ml&opennode=0:1:133:141:143:163:171:
153
Eurostat (2018), Simplified energy balances - annual data [nrg_100a]. Accessed November 19 2018.
154
Vollebergh, H et al. (2017), Fiscale vergroening: belastingverschuiving van arbeid naar grondstoffen,
materialen en afval, PBL: http://www.pbl.nl/sites/default/files/cms/publicaties/pbl-2017-fiscale-vergroening-deel4-
2853.pdf
155
Bourguignon, D. (2017) Plastics in a circular economy - Opportunities and challenges, Brussels: European
Parliamentary Research Service.
156
Hopewell, J., Dvorak, R. and Kosior, E. (2009) 'Plastics recycling: challenges and opportunities', Philosophical
Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 364, pp. 2115-2126.
157
WEF, EMF and McKinsey&Company (2016) The new plastics economy - rethinking the future of plastics: Ellen
MacArthur Foundation. Available at: http://www.ellenmacarthurfoundation.org/publications
There is currently no tax on the non-energy use of fossil fuels in Finland.
Page | 51
The measure
The scenario under review includes a tax of € 10 per tonnes of oil equivalent (toe) (the
parameter used in the E3ME model) applied to mineral oil and other fossil raw material used
in plastics, rubber, painting and other chemical industries.
Rationale
This measure supports the circular roadmap goal of ‘industrial loops’ by:
§ Internalizing external costs (applying the ‘polluter pays’ principle);
§ Applying a price for the use of finite resources;
§ Driving efficiency, incentivising recycling and substituting fossil-based materials with
recycled materials and renewable resources;
§ Creating fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The revenue of this measure would be € 16 million in 2025 (0.5% of the new revenues in the
scenario).
Best practices
No best practices have been identified.
Energy
Context
Since the energy tax reform of 1997, electricity is taxed at the point of end use, not according
to the fuels used to produce it. Electricity producers in Finland are mostly included in the EU
ETS, which should drive the selection of fuels for electricity production.
According to the IEA, saving energy is one of the keys to achieving the goals of the Paris
Agreement:
The measure
The scenario under review includes the reduction of the tax expenditure on the reduced (II)
rate on electricity by 50%.
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goals of industrial loops, sustainable food,
forest loops by:
§ Driving energy efficiency (regardless of the source of energy);
§ Levelling the playing field between different electricity users;
§ Creating fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The estimated revenue would be € 309 million in 2025 (9% of the revenues raised in the
scenario).
Best practices
158
Veroskatt (2018), Tax rates on electricity and certain fuels, https://www.vero.fi/en/businesses-and-
corporations/about-corporate-
taxes/excise_taxes/valmisteverolajit/sahko_ja_eraat_polttoaineet/s%C3%A4hk%C3%B6n-ja-er%C3%A4iden-
polttoaineiden-verotaulukot/
159
Ministry of Finance (2017), Talousarvioesitys, Tuloarviot, Verot ja veroluonteiset tulot, Valmisteverot, 07.
Energiaverot, HE 106/2017 vp. (19.9.2017) (Budget Proposal 2018, Tax and tax-like revenues, Excise duties, 07.
Energy taxes.) Only in Finnish.
http://budjetti.vm.fi/indox/download.jsp?lang=fi&file=/2018/aky/YksityiskohtaisetPerustelut/11/08/07/07.pdf
160
Eurostat (November 2017) Electricity price statistics. Accessed November 19, 2018. This is the average rate
for industry with annual electricity consumption between 500 and 2 000 MWh.
161
IEA (2018), Perspectives for the Energy Transition: The Role of Energy Efficiency.
http://www.iea.org/publications/freepublications/publication/Perspectives%20for%20the%20Energy%20Transition
%20-%20The%20Role%20of%20Energy%20Efficiency.pdf
Germany currently applies an electricity tax rate of € 0.076/kWh for bulk users, whilst in
Page | 53
Denmark the rate is € 0.023/kWh.162 These rates are higher than the category I rate (the
highest rate) applied to households in Finland.
Context
In 1998, Finland introduced a tax refund system for energy-intensive industry, at the same time
as energy tax reform and a substantial increase of energy tax rates. According to the energy
tax refund system, companies paying energy taxes exceeding 0.5% of the company’s value
added are allowed to apply for a refund of 85% of the amount of the energy taxes paid on the
exceeding amount163.
According to a 2016 study, a change in the calculation basis at the beginning of 2012 resulted
in significant increases in the amount of refunds paid and in the number of firms receiving
them, increasing from 13 companies in 2010 to over 140 in 2014. The amount of energy tax
refunds for energy-intensive industry increased respectively from € 7 million to over € 200
million, with the amount of refunds estimated at € 230 million in 2018. Close to 85% of all
refunds are paid to paper, chemical and forestry companies.164
According to the study, energy tax refunds may distort competition because they only apply to
certain fields of activity and only to the largest companies within these fields. While large
corporations may recoup over 80 per cent of the energy taxes paid, small companies in the
same line of business receive much less or nothing. Close to 85 per cent of all refunds go to
paper, chemical and forestry companies. Many of them are large international corporations.165
Finland is member of the Friends of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform working internationally within
forums such as the G20, APEC, OECD, World Bank, UNFCCC and the UN Sustainable
Development Agenda to convince governments of the benefits of subsidy reform.166
The measure
162
For non-household consumers, for the Band IC: 500 MWh <Consumption <2,000 MWh). Eurostat (2018),
Electricity prices for non-household consumers - bi-annual data (from 2007 onwards) [nrg_pc_205],
163
Tax Administration (2018), WWW-pages for Detailed Guidance, Energy Taxation.
https://www.vero.fi/en/detailed-guidance/guidance/56206/energy_taxation/#act-on-excise-duty-on-electricity-and-
certain-fuels
164
Harju, J., Hokkanen, T., Laukkanen, M., Ollikka, K. & Tamminen, S. 2016. Vuoden 2011
energiaverouudistuksen arviointia (Evaluation of 2011 energy tax reform). Valtioneuvoston selvitys- ja
tutkimustoiminnan julkaisusarja 61/2016. Publications of the Goverment´s analysis, assessment and research
activities. Joulukuu 2016.(In Finnish)
http://tietokayttoon.fi/documents/10616/2009122/61_Vuoden+2011+energiaverouudistuksen+arviointia/73aa9c40-c490-
4b83-bb9a-eb4d3a9f193b?version=1.0
165
Ibid.
166
See website of Friends of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform (FFFSR): http://fffsr.org/about/.
The scenario under review includes the removal of the Energy Tax Refund for Energy Intensive
Page | 54
Enterprises. (Note: the energy tax rebates for certain agricultural fuels (€ 33 m in 2016) remain
unchanged.)167
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap themes of industrial loops, sustainable food,
forest loops and sustainable transport by:
§ Phasing out fossil fuel subsidies in line with the Finnish commitment to the FFFSR;
§ Creating a level playing field between fuels (the “polluter pays” principle);
§ Creating fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The revenue of this measure would be € 201 million in 2025 (6% of the revenues raised in the
scenario).
Context
In Finland, 18.1 million air passengers were transported in 2016, not including transit
passengers (see Table 3).
In general, the environmental impacts of aviation include carbon and air pollutant emissions,
noise pollution and local land use change. There is no VAT on ticket prices and international
agreements and EU law prevent aviation fuel for international flights being taxed. In a bid to
still put a price on the negative impacts of air travel, several countries (including the UK,
Germany and Norway) have introduced a passenger aviation tax, as a proxy for kerosene
use.168
The measure
167
Amounts derived from OECD (2018), Fossil Fuel Support – FIN. https://oecd.stat.org
168
Piera, A. (2015), Why Taxes Are Not an Option in Addressing International Civil Aviation's Carbon Footprint
http://www.greenaironline.com/photos/Alejandro_Piera_Why_Taxes_are_not_an_Option_PDF.pdf
The scenario under review includes a €15 fee per passenger per flight (arrivals and departures,
Page | 55
but excluding transit passengers). The rate is based on the lowest rate applied per passenger
in the UK (see box 4).
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goal of sustainable transport by:
§ Applying the ‘polluter pays’ principle in the absence of (EU-wide) excise duties on
kerosene
§ Creating a level playing field between transport modes in the absence of VAT on plane
tickets;
§ Creating fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The estimated combined revenue of this measure and the air freight tax (see section below)
would be € 274 million in 2025 (8% of the revenues raised in the scenario).
Best practices
The UK air passenger duty (APD) is charged to passengers departing from UK airports. The
measure was introduced in 1994. Planes with a capacity of less than 20 or a maximum take-off
weight (MTOW) of less than 10 tonnes (5.7 tonnes for business jets) are exempt.
Table 4. UK Air passenger duty rates (€) correct from 1 April 2019
The rate charged per passenger is determined by the nature of the aircraft (MTOW, seat pitch and
seating capacity) as well as the distance travelled (capital city to London). In total there are six rates
of duty, between €15 and €583 – see Table 4. A different set of rates are applied in Northern Ireland.
Page | 56
4500
4000
3500
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
Graph 3. Government revenue from the UK air passenger duty (APD) 1997 - 2016 (EUR
millions)169
The revenues from the APD have increased steadily over time, reaching over € 4 billion in 2016.
Although the share is growing, it should be said that the APD is still a small share of total
environmental tax revenues in the UK.
When the APD was introduced it was not initially envisaged as an environmental tax, indeed the
environment was not explicitly referred to in the Budget Speech that launched the measure170. More
recently, the measure has been referred to as an environmental tax, particularly as a measure that
can address aircraft emissions. For example, in the 2006 Pre-Budget report it was estimated that
the measure would deliver carbon emission savings of 0.3 million tonnes of carbon by 2010-2011171.
Currently, the Highlands and Scottish Islands have exemptions from the tax172.
Air freight
Context
Eurostat provides data on all freight and mail on board an aircraft either landing or taking off
from a national airport (see Table 5):
169
Statista (2018) Amount of government revenue from Air Passenger Duty* (APD) in the United Kingdom (UK)
from 1997 to 2016 (in million British pounds). https://www.statista.com/statistics/491760/tax-revenue-from-air-
passenger-duty-united-kingdom-uk/
170
Institute for Fiscal Studies (2008) Aviation Taxes. https://www.ifs.org.uk/budgets/gb2008/08chap9.pdf
171
HM Treasury (2006) Pre-Budget Report. Investing in Britain’s potential: Building our long-term future.
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/272403/6984.p
df
172
Revenue Scotland (2018) Air Departure Tax. https://www.revenue.scot/air-departure-tax
Table 5. Air freight volumes Finland 2016 (tonnes)173
Page | 57
Type of air freight Volume
(tonnes) 2016
National transport 2,864
International intra-EU 68,958
International extra-EU 114,649
TOTAL 186,471
Compared to other means of transporting goods (e.g. rail, road and sea), air freight is
significantly more polluting. Two tonnes of freight carried 1,000 km produces 4,138 kg CO2 by
air, compared to 42 kg by diesel train, 30 kg by container ship. Other externalities of air
transportation are emissions of NOx (causing smog and acid rain), SO2 (deteriorating soil and
water quality) and volatile organic compounds (VOCs),174 and noise pollution.
Air freight fuel (kerosene) is not subject to excise duties with respect to international and EU
law175 and no EU countries currently operate air freight taxes, which represents a significant
effective subsidy to this form of freight compared to other modes of transport.
The measure
The scenario under review includes a flat rate of € 20 per tonne of air freight (excluding
passenger baggage).
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goal of sustainable transport by applying the
‘polluter pays’ principle in the absence of (EU-wide) excise duties on kerosene. Also, the
measure creates fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The estimated combined revenue of this measure and the air passenger tax (see section
above) would be € 274 million in 2025 (8% of the revenues raised in the scenario).
Best practices
The UK tonnage tax, introduced in 2000, is a kind of Corporation Tax specifically designed for the
maritime shipping industry in the UK. The objective of the measure was to support the development
of the UK shipping sector and increase the level of training of personnel working for shipping
173
Eurostat (2018) Main tables. Air transport of goods.
http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/tgm/table.do?tab=table&init=1&language=en&pcode=ttr00011&plugin=1
174
CE Delft (2007), as presented in Ministry of Infrastructure and the Environment (2010), Belastingen en
heffingen in de luchtvaart. KiM Netherlands Institute for Transport Policy Analysis.
175
Ibid
Page | 58 operators. The measure may help to promote the maritime movement of freight, rather than use of
more environmentally polluting or heavily-emitting modes such as air and rail.
The measure allows shippers to pay a tonnage tax on a fixed notional profit based on the tonnage
of their ships, rather than directly on their profits earned. Taxable profits are calculated based on
the net tonnage per vessel and the following guidance:
The rate of the tonnage tax is favourable compared to the general Corporation Tax. In this sense,
the tax can be interpreted as a subsidy to the shipping industry – and has been approved as EU
State Aid177.
Shipping operators must choose whether or not they wish to be part of the tonnage tax scheme and
have to be enrolled for a minimum of 10 years. Entry into the scheme places the following
requirements on ships:
Analysis of the impact of the tonnage tax suggests that in 2015 the measure supported 37,000 jobs,
€463 million in tax contributions, an additional 73% of gross added value (GVA) from the UK
shipping industry, and €4.18 billion in sea-based transport export services178.
Waste
Nuclear waste
Context
176
HMRC (2018) Tonnage Tax Manual. HMRC internal manual. https://www.gov.uk/hmrc-internal-
manuals/tonnage-tax-manual/ttm01300
177
Ibid
178
Cebr (2017) The economic impact of the Tonnage Tax regime on the shipping industry A report for Maritime
UK. https://www.maritimeuk.org/documents/191/Tonnage_Tax.pdf
In 2017, around 33% of total electricity supply in Finland (totalling 21.5 million MWh) was
Page | 59
generated from nuclear energy. In 2017, the largest share of electricity produced by nuclear
energy in the 14 EU Member States that have nuclear facilities to produce electricity were
observed in France (71.5 %), followed by Slovakia (56.6 %), Belgium (49.9 %), Hungary (49.6
%), Sweden (39.6 %), Slovenia (39.1 %), Bulgaria (36.1 %) and Finland (33.2 %).179 Across
OECD countries the average share of nuclear energy is 18.5% of total energy supply.180
Between 1990 and 2016, Finland increased its production of nuclear-generated electricity by
almost 21%.181
There is currently no nuclear waste tax in Finland, but a payment for management of nuclear
waste. An operator holding a licence to run a nuclear facility is responsible for the management
of nuclear waste and all the related costs. To guarantee that outstanding nuclear waste
management interventions can be carried out in all circumstances, licensees under a waste
management obligation make payments to the Nuclear Waste Management Fund.182 The size
of the payments is decided annually by the Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment
based mainly on the amount of waste produced and the overall situation of waste
management. There is currently € 2.6 billion in the nuclear waste management fund. The
payments totalled € 73.1 million in 2017. The production of nuclear energy (electricity) was
22,280 GWh, thus the nuclear waste management payment was about € 3.28/MWh.183
Nuclear waste from energy production can remain dangerous for decades or even up to
millions of years.184 Closing the loop on nuclear waste is not currently possible.
The measure
The scenario under review includes a tax on the production of nuclear waste of € 4 per MWh
of energy generated by nuclear power185 in addition to the payments to the Nuclear Waste
Management Fund. The rate is based on the example in Spain (€ 7/MWh, see box 7), reduced
to € 4/MWh because of the existing Finnish license fee of € 3.28/MWh.
Rationale
179
Eurostat (2018), Nuclear Energy Statistics, http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-
explained/index.php/Nuclear_energy_statistics
180
OECD-NEA (2018), Country profile: Finland, https://www.oecd-nea.org/general/profiles/finland.html
181
Eurostat (2017), Electricity Statistics 2017 (in GWh), http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-
explained/images/7/73/Electricity_Statistics_Files%2C_2017_%28GWh%29-1-update-23-04-2018.xlsx
182
Nuclear waste management web pages by Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment.
https://tem.fi/en/nuclear-energy/nuclear-waste-management
183
Financial statement of NWMF (in Finnish) https://tem.fi/paatos?decisionId=0900908f80593a72
Production of electricity and heat (Statistics Finland) http://www.stat.fi/til/salatuo/2016/salatuo_2016_2017-11-
02_tie_001_en.html
184
Ulrik Kautsky, Peter Saetre, Sten Berglund, et al. (2016), The impact of low and intermediate-level radioactive
waste on humans and the environment over the next one hundred thousand years. Journal of Environmental
Radioactivity, Volume 151, Part 2, January 2016, Pages 395-403. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvrad.2015.06.025;
Harack, B. (September 4, 2010), Does nuclear waste last millions of years?
https://www.visionofearth.org/news/does-nuclear-waste-last-millions-of-years/, Accessed November 19, 2018.
185
At present, the units of electricity produced is used as a proxy due to the structure of the E3ME model.
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goal of industrial loops by applying the ‘polluter
Page | 60
pays’ principle and (indirectly) putting a price on the extraction of non-renewable resources.
Also, the measure creates fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The estimated revenue of this measure would be € 134 million in 2025 (4% of the revenues
raised in the scenario).
Best practices
Germany had in place a tax on nuclear fuel (fissile uranium and plutonium) between 2011 and 2016.
The tax was introduced to make extensions to the lives of nuclear power plants less profitable for
operators in the face of the planned postponement of the phase-out of nuclear power in the country
(i.e. to reduce windfall profits). An additional motivation was to obtain revenue to cover the cost of
decommissioning and decontaminating the Asse II mine, which had been used as a test site for the
long-term storage of radioactive waste. The tax rate was € 145/g of nuclear fuel, which translates
to a tax of approximately € 7.3 to € 15.8 per MWh of electricity generated. The revenues (which
amounted to a total of around € 5.8 billion for the period 2011-2015187) were paid into the general
budget. The tax is no longer in place since 2017.
Spain introduced a tax on nuclear waste generation and storage in 1997. The tax is levied on nuclear
power plant operators. The rate is € 6.60 - € 7.80 per MWh. Revenues accrue to a dedicated fund
to finance decommissioning and nuclear waste storage. In addition, in 2012, Spain introduced two
new nuclear waste taxes, with revenues accruing to general budgets at the federal level.
Incineration
Context
186
Dellinger F. and Schratzenstaller M. (2017) Sustainability-oriented Future EU Funding: A European Nuclear
Power Tax, https://umu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1094210/FULLTEXT01.pdf
187
Fiedler, S. (2016) Kernbrennstoffsteuer nach 2016? Berlin: Forum Ökologisch-soziale Marktwirtschaft,
http://www.foes.de/pdf/2016-09-Kurzanalyse-Kernbrennstoffsteuer-nach-2016.pdf
188
Ibid
Of the total amount of all waste generated in Finland (around 93 million tonnes annually), 4.5
Page | 61
million tonnes are incinerated with energy recovery, and 0.5 million tonnes are incinerated
without energy recovery.189
The EU’s waste hierarchy, as established by the Waste Framework Directive, places
incineration as the second least desirable option, above only landfilling. Incineration with
energy recovery can therefore be seen as downcycling, and incineration without energy
recovery as disposal.
The measure
The scenario under review includes an incineration tax of € 20 per tonne of waste incinerated.
A best practice example of such measure is found in Denmark (see Box 8).
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap goal of industrial loops, sustainable food
and forest loops as incineration is downcycling of materials. Increasing the cost of incineration
increases the value of secondary materials versus virgin materials. This improves the business
case for salvaging and reusing waste streams (such as metals, minerals, biomass from food
waste and wood) that would otherwise be incinerated. Also, the measure creates fiscal space
to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The estimated revenue of this measure would be € 100 million in 2025 (3% of the revenues
raised in the scenario).
Best practices
Denmark introduced landfill and incineration taxes in 1987 and became the first country to
completely ban the landfilling of combustible waste in 1997. When first introduced in 1987, the
incineration tax was set at DKK 40 per tonne (€ 5.4). In 2014, the tax for incineration was DKK 261
per tonne (€ 35) and the tax for landfill DKK 470 per tonne (€ 63) (Legislative Council Secretariat,
2014). The introduction of landfill tax and incineration tax in Denmark has not resulted in a reduction
in the quantity of waste generated. Instead, it has provided a strong economic incentive for
189
Eurostat (2014), Treatment of waste by waste category, hazardousness and waste operations [env_wastrt],
http://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/show.do?dataset=env_wastrt&lang=en
Page | 62 recycling. Private markets for compost products and recycled construction and demolition waste
have been developed as a result190.
Water
Water abstraction
Context
The latest available data in Eurostat on abstraction of fresh surface and ground water is from
2006.191 Salminen et al. (2018) published more recent data, indicating that total abstraction by
Finnish industry was around 1,960 million m3 of fresh water in 2010 for purposes other than
cooling. Around 1,643 million m3 of this came from surface water and around 316 million m3
from ground water. In addition, around 1,891 million m3 of surface water and 3.7 million m3 of
ground water were abstracted for cooling. The amount of brackish water abstracted for various
purposes was around 6,280 million m3 per year.192
Although Finland has the second highest volumes of freshwater resources per inhabitant in
the EU (around 20,000 m3)193, a more efficient and circular use of water is important to improve
the resilience of the system, manage future risks and reduce associated energy use.194
There is currently no Finnish tax on water abstraction (other than locally applied fees).
The measure
The scenario under review includes a water abstraction tax of € 0.04 per m3 of water intake
(including ground water and surface water, excluding sea water). This rate only applies for bulk
users.
Rationale
This measure supports the circular roadmap themes industrial loops and sustainable food
by driving water efficiency and energy efficiency (as energy and water use are interconnected).
A reduction in water use (through efficiency gains, reuse and recycling) could also lessen the
190
Legislative Council Secretariat (2014), INFORMATION NOTE Waste management policy in Denmark,
http://www.legco.gov.hk/yr13-14/english/sec/library/1314in09-e.pdf
191
Eurostat (2018) Water use balance: Eurostat, [Statistics]. Available at:
http://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/show.do?dataset=env_wat_bal&lang=en (Accessed: 20.06.2018)
192
Jani M. Salminen, Pekka J. Veiste, Jari T. Koskiaho, Sarianne Tikkanen (2018), Improving data quality,
applicability and transparency of national water accounts – A case study for Finland,
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.wre.2018.05.001
193
Eurostat (2017) Water statistics - statistics explained: Eurostat. Available at:
http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/pdfscache/1182.pdf (Accessed: 20.06.2018)
194
California’s water conservation between June 2015 and February 2016 simultaneously saved enough
electricity to power 135,000 houses for a year. This energy saving translated into a reduction in greenhouse gas
emissions equivalent of removing 50,000 cars from the road for a year. UC Davis Center for Water-Energy
Efficiency (Accessed June 2016), website.
level of emissions and biochemical oxygen demand (BOD) in wastewater from certain
Page | 63
industries and help reduce pressure on wastewater treatment plants195.
Incentivising water recycling technologies could benefit Finland and its long history of
technological entrepreneurship. Also, the measure creates fiscal space to reduce labour taxes.
Potential revenue
The revenue of this measure would be € 133 million in 2025 (4% of the revenues raised in the
scenario).
Best practices
195
Veolia (2014) Water at the heart of the Circular Economy, Paris: Veolia. Available at:
https://www.veolia.com/leeds/sites/g/files/dvc181/f/assets/documents/2014/12/economy-circular-water.pdf
(Accessed June 20, 2018).
196
EMEPA (2012). Yearly report on the activities of the Enterprise for Management of Environmental Protection
Activities http://pudoos.bg/wp-content/uploads/2013/03/GOD-OT4ET-2012_FINAL.doc
197
EMEPA (2013). Yearly report on the activities of the Enterprise for Management of Environmental Protection
Activities http://pudoos.bg/wp-content/uploads/2014/03/GOD-OT4ET-2013_FINAL.doc
Page | 64 abstraction charges has led to a decrease in water loss as well as to reduced water abstraction
(excluding hydropower production). 198 199 200
A reform of the water allocation regime was undertaken in Luxembourg in 2008 with the 2008 Water
Law, passed by the Government to implement the EU Water Framework Directive and the Floods
Directive. The Water Law includes a charge on surface and groundwater abstraction for all
categories of water users: agriculture, domestic, industrial, energy production (excluding hydro
power), and hydropower. The charge is based on the volume of water drawn and set at € 0.10/m3.
The aim of the tax is to prevent water wastage and to reduce the risk of droughts due to future
climatic changes. In addition to a water abstraction tax, the Water Act sets a pollution tax to ensure
compliance with the EU Water Framework Directive standards for water quality. The revenue
obtained from these taxes goes to the Water Management Fund. 201 202
Context
In Finland, around 27 million tonnes of metal ores were extracted in 2016.203 There is currently
no tax on mining or other extraction of minerals. However, royalties are paid to land owners.
The Mining Act of 2011 requires mining permit holders to pay an annual compensation, an
excavation fee, to the land owners of the mining area. The annual amount of the excavation
fee per property is 50 euros per hectare. In addition, there is an additional compensation fee
differentiated according to metallic mineral mines, and other mining minerals, as follows:
- on metallic mineral mines: 0.15 per cent of the calculated value of metallic mining minerals,
excavated and exploited during the year, considering the average price of the exploited
metals included in the ore during the year, and the average value of other products
exploited from the ore during the year.
198
Ministry of Environment and Water, Environment Executive Agency (2016) National report on the status and
protection of the environment in Bulgaria for 2014 http://eea.government.bg/bg/soer/2014/soer-bg-2014.pdf
199
Sharkov, A. (2016) 'Water abstraction charges in Bulgaria', Capacity building, programmatic development and
communication in the field of environmental taxation and budgetary reform: IEEP.
200
Watkins, E. and et al (2017) Capacity building, programmatic development and communication in the field of
environmental taxation and budgetary reform: Final Report, forthcoming.
201
OECD (2012) OECD Economic Surveys: Luxembourg
202
OECD (2015) Water Resources Allocation - Luxembourg. Available at:
https://www.oecd.org/luxembourg/Water-Resources-Allocation-Luxembourg.pdf (Accessed: 21/06/2018)
203
Eurostat (2018), Material flow accounts [env_ac_mfa]
- on other mining minerals than metallic minerals: reasonable compensation for excavated
Page | 65
and exploited mining mineral, taking into consideration grounds influencing the financial
value of the mining mineral.204
The measure
The scenario under review includes a tax rate of € 2 per tonne of metal ores extracted.
Rationale
This measure supports the circular roadmap theme industrial loops by:
§ Internalising the external environmental costs (e.g. damage to water, biodiversity and
landscapes) caused by metal ore mining.
§ Putting a price on the extraction of non-renewable natural resources, thereby improving
the business case of secondary raw materials versus virgin material;
The measure provides an opportunity to use revenues from resource extraction to the benefit
of Finnish society in general.
Potential revenue
The combined revenue of this measure and the tax on non-metallic minerals (see next section)
would be € 97 million in 2025 (3% of the revenues raised in the scenario).
Best practices
Taxes directly comparable to the measure have not been identified. Nevertheless, the
examples below offer some support to the rationale for applying the instrument in Finland.
In Sweden, for the concession of minerals, 0.15% of the value of minerals extracted is paid to the
landowner, and 0.05% to the Government.
In Norway, for state-owned minerals NOK 100 (around €10.6) is paid to the Government per
hectare per year, with 0.5% of sales value paid to the landowner (0.75% in the county of Finnmark).
In Greenland, a sales royalty of 2.5% of the value of minerals is payable to the Government of
Greenland, rising to 5% for rare earth elements and uranium. An additional 15% surplus royalty is
payable on gross profit exceeding 40%.205
204
Tukes (2018), Mining activity, Compensations paid to landowners pursuant to the Mining Act. Finnish Safety
and Chemicals Agency. https://tukes.fi/en/mining
205
Hojem, P. (2015), Mining in the Nordic Countries, A comparative review of legislation and taxation,
http://norden.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:842595/FULLTEXT01.pdf
Page | 66 Box 12: Examples from outside the EU
In India, a ‘deadrent’ is paid on the land area of a mine at the following rates, whether or not active
extraction is taking place: around €37/ha for copper, around €50/ha for gold and around €12/ha for
iron ore. In addition, royalties are paid at the following rates: 4.2% of the units produced for copper,
2% for gold and 10% for iron ore.
In Ukraine, a tax of around €0.50 is applied per tonne of gold extracted, and around €0.03-€0.35
per tonne of iron ore, depending on the ore quality.
In China, a resource tax is charged at the following rates: €0.64-€0.90 per tonne produced of copper,
€0.19-€0.90 for gold, and €1.29-€3.22 for iron ore. In addition, royalty fees are paid per km2 of mining
area (€12.87 for the first three years, then an additional (€12.87 from the fourth year, with a ceiling
of around €65/km2/year).206
Context
In 2016, a total of around 85 million tonnes of non-metallic minerals were extracted in Finland,
the majority (82%) of which was sand, gravel and clay (70 million tonnes); 13% chemical and
fertiliser minerals (11 million tonnes); 4% stone (such as limestone, gypsum and chalk) (3.3
million tonnes); and other non-metallic minerals (just over 1 million tonnes)207. Total turnover
in 2016 was € 635 million, including these minerals plus the extraction of peat, but not including
mining support service activities.
Discussions on non-metallic minerals in Finland have focussed on sand and gravel, which are
typically extracted in fresh water areas in the south of the country, with associated impacts on
those environments. The turnover for stone, sand and clay was around € 300 million in 2016208.
The measure
The scenario under review includes a tax of € 0.50 per tonne of non-metallic minerals extracted
(including stone, sand, gravel and minerals for chemical and fertiliser use).
206
PWC (2012), Corporate income taxes, mining royalties and other mining taxes: A summary of rates and rules
in selected countries: Global mining industry update June 2012, https://www.pwc.com/gx/en/energy-utilities-
mining/publications/pdf/pwc-gx-miining-taxes-and-royalties.pdf
207
Eurostat (2018), Material flow accounts [env_ac_mfa]
208
Eurostat (2018), Annual detailed enterprise statistics for industry (NACE Rev. 2, B-E) [sbs_na_ind_r2]
209
Ministry of Finance (2012), Maa-ainesvero. Selvitys maa-ainesveron käyttöönoton mahdollisuuksista ja
tarkoituksenmukaisuudesta. (Aggregate tax. Review on possibilities and appropriateness of aggregate tax),
Valtiovarainministeriö / Ministry of Finance, March 2012.
Rationale
Page | 67
This measure supports the circular roadmap theme industrial loops by:
§ Internalizing external costs (e.g. damage to water, biodiversity and landscapes) caused
by the extraction of minerals;
§ Putting price on the extraction of non-renewable natural resources;
§ Promoting recycling of materials (e.g. construction and demolition waste) versus the
use of virgin materials;
§ Encouraging a move towards renewable alternatives, such as wood.
The measure provides an opportunity to use revenues from resource extraction to the benefit
of the Finnish society in general.
Potential revenue
The combined revenue of this measure and the tax on metallic minerals would be € 97 million
in 2025 (3% of the revenues raised in the scenario).
Best practices
Sweden introduced a tax on gravel extraction in 1996. At its introduction, the tax rate was set at
SEK 5 (around € 0.50) per tonne to mirror the price of recycled material and was then gradually
increased to SEK 15 per tonne (around € 1.40). The objectives for the introduction of the tax were
to protect groundwater quality by promoting the recycling of construction materials and the use of
alternatives to virgin gravel, and to internalise in pricing the environmental impacts of gravel
extraction. In addition, there were goals to reduce the use of natural gravel from over 40 million
tonnes to 12 million tonnes per year, and to ensure that recycled material accounted for 15% of all
materials used. These goals were achieved in 2012, and between 1994 and 2014 the use of natural
gravel decreased from almost 44 million tonnes to just under 11 million tonnes per year. The
revenue from the tax amounted to SEK 167 (around € 19 million) in 2013.211
210
Konjunkturinstitutet (2016), Miljö, ekonomi och politik,
https://www.konj.se/download/18.1910291f158b9b08e365eebe/1480941421501/Miljo-ekonomi-politik-2016.pdf
211
European Commission (2015), Taxes in Europe Database,
http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/tedb/taxDetail.html?id=512/1424159356&taxType=Other+indirect+tax
212
Ettlinger, S. (2017), Aggregates Levy in the United Kingdom,
https://ieep.eu/uploads/articles/attachments/5337d500-9960-473f-8a90-
3c59c5c81917/UK%20Aggregates%20Levy%20final.pdf?v=63680923242
213
HMRC (2014), Aggregates Levy Bulletin April 2014, Table 2,
https://www.uktradeinfo.com/statistics/pages/taxanddutybulletins.aspx
Page | 68 An aggregates levy was introduced in the UK in 2002. When introduced, the rate was GBP 1.60,
rising to GBP 2 per tonne (around € 2.25) in 2009. It is applied at the point of commercial exploitation
of sand, gravel and rock. The rationale for the levy was to reduce the negative environmental
impacts of aggregate extraction and to incentivise the recycling of aggregates. Initially, the levy
contributed to a minor tax shift of a 0.1% reduction in employers’ National Insurance (i.e. social
security) contributions. The tax amounts to around 20% of the average price for sand, rock and
gravel214.
The UK has a high recycling rate for aggregates, accounting for almost 25% of the UK aggregates
market; this is the largest recycled market share for any European country. In 2013, revenue from
the tax was around GBP 275 million (€ 324 million), and revenue amounted to GBP 407 million (€
477 million) in 2016-17215. The tax increased the costs of virgin aggregates, incentivising the
construction sector to use recycled aggregates216. Whilst the use of virgin aggregate in the
construction sector has reduced significantly, it is difficult to attribute this solely or specifically to the
levy; the falling trend began prior to the levy’s introduction and has also been linked to the landfill
tax (imposed from 1997 onwards). Nevertheless, a decoupling of the use of aggregates from
construction output can be observed between 1995 and 2010217. From 2002 to 2011, GBP 35 million
(€57 million) per year was ringfenced into the Aggregate Levy Sustainability Fund, to finance
projects to mitigate the local environmental impacts of quarrying.
A tax on raw materials extraction was introduced in Denmark in 1990, together with a waste tax,
with the aim of moving up the waste hierarchy and reducing resource-use. The tax is fixed at DKK
5 (€0.67) for each m3 of raw material extracted: stone, gravel, sand, clay, limestone, chalk, peat,
topsoil and similar deposits. The tax primarily affects the construction and cement production
sectors. The effect of the tax on raw material extraction has been relatively small, as both the
elasticity of demand and the tax rate are low. Revenues are received by the State. In general, the
tax revenue has increased, from EUR 18.2 million in 1995 to EUR 25 million in 1999218. The tax, in
conjunction with the waste tax, has increased the demand for recycled substitutes – from 12% of
construction and demolition waste recycled in 1985 to 94% in 2004219.
214
European Environment Agency (2008) Effectiveness of Environmental Taxes and Charges for Managing
Sand, Gravel and Rock Extraction in Selected EU Countries, June 2008,
www.eea.europa.eu/publications/eea_report_2008_2
215
HMRC (2018), HMRC TAX & NIC RECEIPTS: Monthly and annual historical record, p7,
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/717435/May18
_Receipts_NS_Bulletin_Final.pdf
216
Deloitte UK (2016) Aggregates Levy. Accessed on 26/06/2018. Available at: http://www.ukbudget.com/2016-
measures/aggregates-levy.aspx
217
Fedrigo-Fazio, D., Schweitzer, J-P., ten Brink, P., Mazza, L., Ratliff, A. and Watkins, E. (2016) Evidence of
Absolute Decoupling from Real World Policy Mixes in Europe. Journal of Sustainability. Available at:
https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/5f05/23ff07818336e5b4475ba18f02bd98fb71c4.pdf
218
European Commission, 2011. Taxes on natural resources reduce use of raw materials. Science for
Environment Policy. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/integration/research/newsalert/pdf/262na1_en.pdf
219
European Commission (2011). Ch.11 – Aggregate Taxes, in Study on Environmental Taxes and Charges in
the EU. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/taxation/pdf/ch11_aggregated_taxes.pdf
Food production inputs
Page | 69
Pesticides
Context
In 2016, total sales of plant protection products reached 13,223 tonnes. Sales of plant
protection products for agricultural and horticultural use was 4,335 tonnes, including 1,575
tonnes of active substances. Sales of plant protection products for use in forestry was 8,878
tonnes, including 3,017 tonnes of active substances.220 In 2014-2015, Finland had the greatest
increase in pesticide sales in the EU, compared to 2011-2013 sales.221
The 7th EU Environment Action Programme sets the objective that by 2020, the use of plant
protection products does not have any harmful effects on human health or unacceptable
influence on the environment, and that such products are used sustainably222. A tax on
pesticides may help reduce and/or prevent the use of the most harmful pesticides223.
There is currently no pesticides tax in Finland. A pesticide registration fee was in place
between 1988 and 2006, which applied to the pesticides industry.224 225 Since 2009, there
has been a fee for the approval of new plant protection products if they needed an
evaluation. The fee covers the evaluation cost made by the Finnish Safety and Chemicals
Agency (Tukes).
The measure
The scenario under review includes a tax of € 10 per kg of active ingredients used.
Rationale
This measure ties in with the circular roadmap sustainable food theme by:
§ Internalising the external costs of the use of these substances on society and on the
environment;
§ Incentivising closing the loop on mineral resource-use, thereby reducing pollution. It
may also incentivise the adoption of alternative pest control measures that do not
contribute to further extraction of virgin mineral resources.
Potential revenue
220
Finnish Safety and Chemicals Agency (Tukes) (2018) Plant protection products, sales statistics.
http://www.tukes.fi/en/Branches/Chemicals-biocides-plant-protection-products/Plant-protection-products/Sales-
statisitics/ Accessed 180618
221
[source]
222
Decision No 1386/2013/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council on a General Union Environment
Action Programme to 2020 ‘Living well, within the limits of our planet’. Official Journal of the European Union L
354, pp171-200. 28.12.2013.
223
UNDP (2017) Taxes on Pesticides and Chemical Fertilizers. UNDP.
224
EEA (2018) Pesticide sales. https://www.eea.europa.eu/airs/2017/environment-and-health/pesticides-sales
Accessed 180618
225
Ibid.
The estimated revenue of this measure would be € 43 million in 2025 (1% of the revenues
Page | 70
raised in the scenario).
Best practices
Based on the experience of applying a pesticides tax in other EU Member States, a banded
tax rate according to the potential effects of different active ingredients is considered to be the
most effective. Eunomia (2016) advise a rate of € 10/kg active ingredient.226
Denmark introduced a tax on pesticides in 1996, applying to all types of consumption (including
agriculture). A key aim was to reduce the spraying intensity of pesticides in Danish agriculture (the
Treatment Frequency Index, TFI). A fee had previously been imposed on the agrochemical industry
(since 1986), with the same objective. The initial tax rate was set on retail price (excl. VAT) as
follows: 37% on insecticides and 15% on fungicides, herbicides and growth regulators. In 1998, the
tax rate on insecticides was increased to 54%, and 33% respectively on the other three product
categories227.
The system was reformed in 2013, moving from a consumption-based tax to a tax with rates
differentiated according to the relative environmental and health impacts of individual pesticides.
Average tax rates were also increased. The pesticides with the highest impact are most heavily
taxed to provide the strongest economic incentive to use pesticides with the least negative impact.
This aspect of the tax was positively received by industry228.
In the first ten years of the tax, annual revenues ranged between DKK 235 and 500 million (€31.5-
67.1 million*). This increased to DKK 659 million (€88.5 million) in 2013, or 0.07% of total Danish
tax revenue. Since 2010, farmers were partly compensated for increased expenses by a reduction
in land taxes of DKK 62-72 (€8.3-9.7) per hectare, which also helped to ease resistance from
industry. Part of the revenues are returned to fund agricultural R&D activities, and another part is
used to fund the administration of the Danish Pesticide Action Plan229.
The Danish pesticide tax has had small effects on pesticide use over the years, but more significant
reductions are expected following the reformed tax (it will be evaluated in 2017-18), as the
pesticides with largest environmental load now face substantially higher price levels230.
Finally, the tax has some distributional effects. For instance, as land prices differ across Denmark,
different farmers receive different levels of reimbursements through the reduced land value tax
mechanism231. For example, following the 2013 reform of the tax, strawberry producers could be
226
Eunomia, et al. (2016), Study on Assessing the Environmental Fiscal Reform Potential for the EU28. Final
Report
227
Pedersen, A B, Nielsen, H Ø and Andersen, M S (2015) The Danish Pesticide Tax, in Lago, M, Mysiak, J,
Gómez, C M, Delacámara, G, Maziotis, A (eds), Use of Economic Instruments in Water Policy, pp73-88. Springer
Publishing, Netherlands.
228
The Danish Ecological Council (2014) Fact sheet: Tax on pesticides. The Danish Ecological Council.
229
Ibid
230
Ibid.
231
Ibid
expected to experience decreasing pesticide prices while potato producers might experience Page | 71
increasing prices, due to the differing environmental load of the pesticides used by the respective
types of farmers232.
In 1984, Sweden was the first country in the world to introduce a flat tax on pesticides based on
volume sold. The objective was to reduce pesticide use and thereby its environmental and health
impacts. The initial rate of SEK 4 (€0.39*)/kg active substance has been gradually raised, and since
2015 is SEK 34 (€3.32)/kg. The tax applies to both pesticides produced in Sweden and imported
pesticides233 234.
SEK 122 million (€11.9 million) were raised in revenue from the tax in 2017 (preliminary figures)235.
Until 1995 and Sweden’s accession to the EU, the revenues were used for agri-environmental
programmes aiming to reduce pesticide application and to promote integrated pest management236.
Since then, the revenues have been directly allocated to the national treasury.
Since the introduction of the tax, the sales of active pesticides substances have gone down and the
aggregated environmental risk index calculated for pesticides has remained relatively stable.
However, the pesticide tax cannot be interpreted as the only determinant for these trends237 238.
Updated statistics of pesticide sales in Sweden is expected in mid-2018239.
232
Pedersen, A.B., Nielsen, H.Ø., Andersen, M.S.(2015) The Danish Pesticide Tax, in Use of Economic
Instruments in Water Policy: Insights from International Experience. M. Lago; J. Mysiak; C.M. Gómez, G.
Delacámara; A. Maziotis (eds.). Springer Verlag. (Issues in Water Resources Policy).
233
Böcker, T and Finger, R (2016) European pesticide tax schemes in comparison: an analysis of experiences
and developments. Sustainability No 8 (4), 378.
234
The Swedish Tax Agency (2018) Skatt på bekämpningsmedel [Pesticides tax].
https://www.skatteverket.se/foretagochorganisationer/skatter/punktskatter/bekampningsmedel.4.18e1b10334ebe8
bc80005054.html Accessed 180618
235
Ibid
236
Ecotec Research & Consulting, Centre for Social Science Research on the Environment (CESAM), Centre for
Agriculture and Environment (CLM), University of Gothenburg, University College Dublin (UCD) and Institute for
European Environmental Policy (IEEP) (2001) Study on the economic and environmental implications of the use
of environmental taxes and charges in the European Union and its Member States. Ecotec Research &
Consulting, Brussels.
237
Ibid.
238
Statistics Sweden (SCB) (2012) Sales of pesticides 2012. Statistics Sweden (SCB), Stockholm.
239
Statistics Sweden (SCB) (2018a) Pesticides sales. https://www.scb.se/hitta-statistik/statistik-efter-
amne/miljo/kemikalier-forsaljning-och-anvandning/forsalda-kvantiteter-av-bekampningsmedel/ Accessed 180618
Page | 72 Use of revenues
Personal income tax (PIT) and social security contributions (SSC) reduction
PIT and employee SSC reduction
National context
In Finland, labour taxes raised € 48.8 billion in revenues (or 51% of total tax revenues) in
2016, consisting of:240
The “tax wedge” is a measure of the tax burden on employment incomes. It is the difference
between labour costs to the employer and the corresponding net take-home pay of the
employee. In 2017, Finland had the fourth highest tax wedge (after France, Greece and Italy)
in the OECD for an average married worker with two children, at 38.4% (compared to an OECD
average of 26.1%). The average single worker in Finland faced a tax wedge of 42.9%
(compared to an OECD average of 35.9%)241
As a share of GDP, Personal Income Tax was 13% of total tax revenues in Finland in 2016;
the third highest in the EU (after Denmark and Sweden).242
The measure
In the modelling, 50% of the net increases in government revenues are used to reduce
personal income tax and employee social security contributions.243
In practice, these reductions can take many forms, ranging from benefits and allowances (in
tax credits or cash transfers) to adapting income tax rates to obtain the desired fair distribution.
Specific attention needs to go to the fact that currently, private pensions are deferred wages
and are based on gross income. Lowering income tax rates and social contributions should
not affect pension rights.
240
European Commission (2018), Taxation Trends in the European Union; Data for the EU Member States,
Iceland and Norway; 2018 Edition,
https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/sites/taxation/files/taxation_trends_report_2018.pdf
241
OECD (2018), Taxing Wages - Finland. http://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/taxing-wages-finland.pdf
242
European Commission (2018), Taxation Trends in the European Union; Data for the EU Member States,
Iceland and Norway; 2018 Edition,
https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/sites/taxation/files/taxation_trends_report_2018.pdf
243
The modelling assumption for this measure is that all income tax rates are decreased equally. A separate
income support measure is specifically designed to reduce inequality.
Rationale
Page | 73
The measure supports the circular roadmap goals of inclusive growth and a fair transition.
By lowering personal income tax and employee social contributions, households have more
disposable income. This compensates for an increase in living expenses.
Estimated cost
€ 1,751 million in 2025. This amount represents 4.7% of the combined personal income tax
revenues and employee social contributions in 2016244.
Best practices
Spain reduced the share of the combined personal income tax revenues and employee social
contributions in total tax revenue by 2.9% during the period 2010-2016, the highest reduction
in the EU.245
National context
Employers’ social contributions provided € 18.8 billion, or 20% of total tax revenues in Finland
in 2016. At 8.7% of GDP, these employers’ social contributions are the fourth highest in the
EU (after France, Estonia and Czech Republic). 246
The Finnish employment target for 2020 is 78%; in 2016, the employment rate was 73%. In
2016, 235,600 people were unemployed (8.8% of the labour force). However, according to
Eurostat, the potential additional labour force in 2016 was more than twice as high as the
number of unemployed, at 553,600247, consisting of:
“Raising the employment rate, which is lower than in all the other Nordic
countries, is crucial to address the long-term fiscal challenges posed by
ageing and foster inclusive growth. The Competitiveness Pact which
244
Eurostat (Accessed November 2018), Main national accounts tax aggregates[gov_10a_taxag]
245
Ibid
246
European Commission (2018), Taxation Trends in the European Union; Data for the EU Member States,
Iceland and Norway; 2018 Edition,
https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/sites/taxation/files/taxation_trends_report_2018.pdf
247
Eurostat (Accessed June 2018a), Supplementary indicators to unemployment - annual data
248
An underemployed part-time worker is a person aged 15-74 working part-time who would like to work
additional hours and is available to do so. See also Eurostat (2018), Glossary: Underemployed part-time worker,
https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php?title=Glossary:Underemployed_part-time_worker
entered into force this year is helping contain labour costs and strengthen
Page | 74
demand for labour. Recent measures to enhance work incentives, notably
the cut in the duration of unemployment benefits, will lift labour supply.
However, further reforms to boost employment are needed, as high tax
rates upon return to work and complex benefit rules still undermine work
incentives.” 249
The measure
30% of the net increases in government revenues are used to reduce labour costs for
employers through a reduction in employers’ social contributions. The scenario assumes that
the cost reduction is tied to an effective employment increase. This means that employers only
benefit if they actually increase their workforce structurally.
Rationale
The measure reduces labour costs, which enables a shift towards labour-intensive circular
activities. It ties in with business models for each of the themes of the study: industrial loops,
sustainable foods, forest loops, sustainable transport & logistics.
Through its impact on labour demand, the measure supports the circular roadmap goals of
inclusive growth and a fair transition.
Estimated cost
€1,051 million in 2025.
Best practices
In 2014, Spain adopted a similar measure to promote employment creation and indefinite
hiring. This involved a cut in employers’ social contributions to a flat rate of €100/month for two
years on new permanent contracts, conditional on the upkeep of the labour contract over 3
years.
In March 2014, the Spanish Government adopted the Royal Decree-Law (RDL) 3/2014, on urgent
measures to promote employment creation and indefinite hiring. The Spanish decree contains one
249
OECD (2017), Economic Outlook, Volume 2017 Issue 2 - Preliminary version.
http://www.oecd.org/eco/outlook/economic-forecast-summary-finland-oecd-economic-outlook.pdf
250
OECD Economics Department (March 1, 2018), Finland: growing and reforming, but no time for complacency,
https://oecdecoscope.blog/2018/03/01/finland-growing-and-reforming-but-no-time-for-complacency/
measure: a cut in employers’ social security contributions to a flat rate of €100 per month for two Page | 75
years on all permanent contracts signed until the end of the year. This flat rate is conditional on the
labour contract being maintained over the three following years by the hiring company. The specifics
are as follows251:
§ It applies to either new indefinite contracts or the conversion of temporary into indefinite
contracts.
§ Micro firms may benefit of an additional reduction of 50% of the standard social security
contribution after the end of the first two years of the application of the flat rate.
§ For part-time contracts, the flat rate will be proportional to the working hours.
§ The new regulation does not affect the employer’s or worker's contribution for other
contingencies such as unemployment insurance, professional training, and contribution to
the wage guarantee fund (FOGASA).
§ The job must be maintained for at least three years; otherwise, the amounts saved by the
company shall be recovered, totally or partially (recapturing is 100% if the employment
contract is terminated during the first year, 50% if terminated during the second year and
33% if terminated during the third year).
§ The new measure will have no impact on the benefits to which workers are entitled, which
are calculated applying the full contribution base.
§ According to the Ministry of Labour and Social Security, the scheme will reduce by 75% the
current total social security contributions. Indeed, the flat rate replaces the 23.6%
contribution to social security for common contingencies (basically, related to pensions and
health and safety).
The downside of this scheme is that the flat rate implies that the higher the salary, the higher the
savings on the social security contributions for the company and, consequently, the revenue loss for
the social security system. Still, the advisory commission on this matter states: “While the flat rate
implies a greater subsidy for higher paid workers, the higher labour demand and supply elasticities
could still lead to a bigger impact on low-skilled jobs.”
Another issue may be that the measure could result mainly in a conversion of temporary contracts
into permanent ones, thus meeting one of its stated objectives, while its potential to stimulate
additional employment creation is more uncertain252.
251
European Commission (2014), Spain - Post Programme Surveillance Spring 2014 Report.
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/occasional_paper/2014/pdf/ocp193_en.pdf
252
Ibid
253
European Commission (2018), Taxation Trends in the European Union; Data for the EU Member States,
Iceland and Norway; 2018 Edition,
https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/sites/taxation/files/taxation_trends_report_2018.pdf
The measure
Page | 76
5% of the net increases in government revenues are used to reduce employers’ social security
contributions in general.
Rationale
The measure reduces labour costs, which enables a shift towards labour-intensive circular
activities. It therefore ties in with business models for each of the themes of the study:
industrial loops, sustainable foods, forest loops, sustainable transport & logistics. By
increasing labour demand, the measure supports the circular roadmap goals of inclusive
growth and a fair transition.
Estimated cost
€ 175 million in 2025. To put this into perspective: this amount is comparable to 1.0% of the
employers’ social security revenues in 2016.254
Best practices
Hungary reduced the share of employers’ social contributions in total tax revenue by 5.9%
during the period 2006-2016, which was the highest reduction in the EU in that period.255
National context
Compared to other EU28 member states, Finland has one of the lowest inequality rates and
low at-risk-of-poverty rates in every population category. For employed persons the at-risk-of-
poverty rate is the lowest in the EU28 (3.1%). 37.2% of the unemployed had an income below
the at-risk-of-poverty threshold, which is again below the EU-average of 48.6%. Pensioners
also have a lower than average at-risk-of-poverty rate (at 12%, which is below the 13.8% EU28
average). The 'other inactive' group shows a higher at-risk-of-poverty rate (albeit still lower
than EU average); at 28.8%. Single persons have a higher than EU average risk at 28.6%,
which is also much higher than the rate for two adults at least one aged 65 and older (4%) and
two or more adults (6.4%).256
Finland has a complex system of income support.257 The OECD Economic Survey 2018 notes
the following:
254
Ibid
255
Ibid
256
‘The at-risk-of-poverty rate is the share of people with an equivalised disposable income (after social transfer)
below the at-risk-of-poverty threshold, which is set at 60 % of the national median equivalised disposable income
after social transfers. This indicator does not measure wealth or poverty, but low income in comparison to other
residents in that country, which does not necessarily imply a low standard of living.’ Eurostat (2018), Glossary: At-
risk-of-poverty rate. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Glossary:At-risk-of-poverty_rate
257
Veroskatt (2018), Automatically granted deductions. https://www.vero.fi/en/individuals/tax-cards-and-tax-
returns/income-and-deductions/tax-deductions/automatically_granted_deduction/
“The combination of different working-age benefits, childcare costs and
Page | 77
income taxation creates complexity, reduces work incentives and holds
back employment. Coordinating the tapering of various working-age
benefits against earnings could drastically improve work incentives and
transparency, while preserving the current level of social protection” 258
The measure
5% of the net increases in government revenues in the scenario are used to compensate the
two lowest income quintiles in Finland.
Rationale
The measure supports the circular roadmap goals of inclusive growth and a fair transition
by providing vulnerable households with support to compensate for an increase in living
expenses.
Estimated cost
The estimated cost of the measure is € 175 million in 2025.
Best practices
Due to the complexity and wide range of indicators for the risk of poverty and inequality, no
best practices have been identified.
Investments
R&D subsidy (labour cost reduction)
National context
Finland is a major investor in R&D. Spending on R&D as a percentage of GDP was 2.8% in
2016; higher than the EU average of 2.0% of GDP259. The Finnish 2020 target in this respect
is 4% of GDP, significantly higher than the EU 2020 target of 3% of GDP.260 According to the
OECD:
258
OECD (2018), OECD Economic Surveys Finland. http://www.oecd.org/eco/surveys/Finland-2018-OECD-
economic-survey-overview.pdf
259
Eurostat (Accessed June 2018). Research and development expenditure, by sectors of performance
260
European Commission (Accessed June 2018), 2020 targets: statistics and indicators for Finland.
https://ec.europa.eu/info/business-economy-euro/economic-and-fiscal-policy-coordination/eu-economic-
governance-monitoring-prevention-correction/european-semester/european-semester-your-
country/finland/europe-2020-targets-statistics-and-indicators-finland_en
261
OECD (2018), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2018, https://read.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/oecd-
economic-surveys-finland-2018_eco_surveys-fin-2018-en#.W_LbSpNKj_Q
The measure
Page | 78
5% of the net increases in government revenues in the scenario are used to reduce costs
associated with high-skilled employment in R&D. Such a facility exists in the Netherlands’
Research & Development Promotion Act (WBSO), which is a wage cost reduction for R&D in
general (see Box ). The facility in Finland could potentially be targeted specifically at innovative
circular resource use, including resource efficiency, closing the loop in supply chains and new
(e.g. bio-based) materials. The technical details are to be determined at implementation; the
E3ME model generically treats such measures as a cost reduction that is distributed among
sectors based on their R&D expenditures.
Rationale
Depending on the details of implementation the measure serves the themes industrial loops,
Sustainable foods, Forest loops, Sustainable transport & logistics and carbon neutrality
by:
§ Reducing the tax burden on labour for R&D employers (which enables job creation in
innovative sectors);
§ Promoting sustainable innovation, potentially in each of the themes.
Estimated cost
The estimated cost of the measure is € 175 million in 2025.
Best practices
Box 19: The Research & Development Promotion Act, the Netherlands
In the Netherlands, the Research & Development Promotion Act is a measure of about €0.8 billion
(2014) per year aimed at lowering wage costs for R&D. An evaluation commissioned by the Dutch
Ministry of Economic Affairs, Agriculture and Innovation showed that, thanks to the Act, private
sector wages paid for R&D effectively went up in the period from 2006 to 2010262. In 2014, almost
23,000 Dutch companies, including self-employed entrepreneurs, used the facility263.
National context
In Finland, renewable energy sources represented about 40 per cent of energy end-
consumption in 2017. The aim set in the National Energy and Climate Strategy to 2030 is to
262
EIM (2012) Evaluatie WBSO 2006-2010. Effecten, doelgroepbereik en uitvoering.
https://www.rijksoverheid.nl/binaries/rijksoverheid/documenten/rapporten/2012/04/02/hoofdrapport-evaluatie-
wbso-2006-2010/hoofdrapport-evaluatie-wbso-2006-2010.pdf
263
Dutch Central Planning Bureau (CPB) (2016), Kansrijk innovatiebeleid.
https://www.cpb.nl/sites/default/files/publicaties/download/cpb-boek-20-kansrijk-innovatiebeleid.pdf
increase the share of renewable energy up to more than 50 per cent during the 2020s. The
Page | 79
most important forms of renewable energy used in Finland are bioenergy, fuels from forest
industry side streams and other renewable energy sources, such as hydropower, wind power
and ground heat. Bioenergy is also generated from biodegradable waste and side streams of
agriculture and industrial production and from municipal waste. Solar electricity has a growing
role especially in on-site energy generation.
The main objective in promoting renewable energy is to reduce greenhouse gas emissions
and move away from the energy system that is based on fossil fuels. Another objective is to
improve energy self-sufficiency and employment and support the development of technologies
in the sector.264 Finland has used different policy instruments to achieve the target share of
renewable sources on energy end-consumption. The main drivers for investments and use of
renewables have been a feed-in tariff programme, a biofuel blending requirement for motor
fuels and subsidies for investments for renewable energy production (see appendix 1).
Energy aid and investment aid for key energy projects, managed by the Ministry of Economic
Affairs and Employment has been one of the drivers to promote investments and technology
in renewables. Energy aid can be granted to investment projects and studies that:
§ promote the production or use of renewable energy;
§ promote energy savings or increase the efficiency of energy generation or use; or
§ otherwise promote the transition towards a low-carbon energy system.
Investment Aid for Key Energy Project programme is intended to subsidize investments on
renewable energy and new energy technology. 265 Annually, the subsidies under the Energy
Aid and Investment Aid for Key Energy Projects account around € 60-70 million.266 In addition,
investments in the construction of a national LNG terminals network have been supported with
a total of approximately € 93 million.267
The measure
5% of the net increases in government revenues in the scenario are used to subsidise the
production of solar, wind, biogas and geothermal energy (within the power sectors).
Rationale
Depending on the details of implementation the measure serves the theme of carbon
neutrality by promoting renewable energy use.
264
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Renewable Energy in Finland.
https://tem.fi/en/renewable-energy
265
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Energy aid. https://tem.fi/en/energy-aid
and Investment aid for key energy projects. https://tem.fi/en/investment-aid-for-key-energy-projects
266
Tamminen, S., Haanperä, O. & Hietaniemi, T.(2018) Harnessing economic instruments to tackle the climate
crisis. Finland’s experiences with economic instruments applied in climate policy. Sitra memorandum. 05.10.2018.
Sitra, Finnish Innovation Fund. https://media.sitra.fi/2018/10/04162441/harnessing-economic-instruments-to-
tackle-the-climate-crisis.pdf
267
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Investment Support for LNG Terminals.
https://tem.fi/en/investment-support-for-lng-terminals
Estimated cost
Page | 80
The estimated cost of the measure is € 175 million in 2025.
This chapter provides estimates of macroeconomic impacts of the tax reform policies in Finland
as described in the previous chapter. The analysis is carried out using the E3ME
macroeconomic model, which will be briefly introduced in section 5.1. Section 5.2 explains
some of the assumptions, and 5.3 provides some of the key results. 5.4 provides an overview
of the macro-economic impacts, 5.5 includes impacts per sector. A conclusion is drawn in the
final section.
268
E3ME (Accessed June 2018), www.e3me.com.
269
Pollitt, H (2008), Combining Economic and Material Flows Analysis at the Sectoral level: Development of the
E3ME Model and Application in the MATISSE Case Studies. Deliverable 8.6.1, Work Package 8, MATISSE,
European Commission project No 004059 (GOCE).
270
Ekins, P, Pollitt, H, Summerton, P, Chewpreecha, U (2012), Increasing Carbon and Material Productivity
through Environmental Tax Reform, Energy Policy, 42 (3): 365-376.
271
Pollitt, H, Chewpreecha, U (2011), Macroeconomic modelling of sustainable development and the links
between the economy and the environment. DG Environment, European Commission.
272
European Commission (2014), Study on modelling of the economic and environmental impacts of raw material
consumption.
273
European Commission (Accessed July 2016), 2030 Energy Strategy.
274
Cambridge Econometrics (2013), Modelling Milestones for Achieving Resource Efficiency: Economic Analysis
of Waste Taxes Draft Report for the European Commission (DG Environment).
275
Lee, S, Pollitt, H, Park, S-J (editors) (2016), Low-carbon, Sustainable Future in East Asia: improving energy
systems, taxation and policy cooperation, Routledge Studies in the Modern World Economy.
276
European Commission (2018), Impacts of the Circular Economy on the labour market, see
https://publications.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/fc373862-704d-11e8-9483-
01aa75ed71a1/language-en
277
New Climate Economy (2018), Unlocking the inclusive growth story of the 21st century, see
https://newclimateeconomy.report/2018/wp-content/uploads/sites/6/2018/09/NCE_2018_FULL-REPORT.pdf
278
Mercure, J-F, Pollitt, H, Viñuales, J E, Edwards, N R, Holden, P B, Chewpreecha, U, Salas, P, Sognnaes, I,
Lam, A & Knobloch, F (2018) ‘Macroeconomic impact of stranded fossil fuel assets’, Nature Climate Change,
Volume 8, pp 588–593 (2018).
§ its global coverage (59 regions), while still allowing for analysis at the national level for
Page | 82
large economies and EU Member States
§ the econometric approach, which provides a strong empirical basis for the model and
means it is not reliant on some of the restrictive assumptions common to CGE models
§ the econometric specification of the model, making it suitable for short and medium-
term assessment, as well as longer-term trends.
Appendix 2 includes a description of the model. The main dimensions covered by the model
are listed in the E3ME manual (available online) at http://www.e3me.com. The manual also
explains the theories behind the model as well as econometric specifications for each equation.
A full list of model equations is available in Mercure et al. (2018).279
279
Mercure, J-F, Pollitt, H, Edwards, N R, Holden, P B, Chewpreecha, U, Salas, P, Lam, A, Knobloch, F &
Vinuales, J E (2018) ‘Environmental impact assessment for climate change policy with the simulation-based
integrated assessment model E3ME-FTT-GENIE’, Energy Strategy Reviews, Volume 20, April 2018, Pages 195–
208.
280
See e.g. Lavoie, M (2015) ‘Post-Keynesian Economics: New Foundations’, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton,
MA: Edward Elgar.
281
EU Reference Scenario 2016: Energy, transport and GHG emissions Trends to 2050, European Commission
and The 2015 Ageing Report: Underlying Assumptions and Projection Methodologies, European Commission.
282
Note that in 2016, exports from Finland to the UK accounted for 4.5% and 5.6% of total Finnish exports of
goods and services respectively. Imports from the UK accounted for 3% and 7% of total Finnish imports of goods
and services respectively (source: UN Comtrade for goods, Statistics Finland for services).
Budget-neutrality. Each year, all revenues are used (‘recycled’) in accordance with the
Page | 83
scenario (this means there is no impact on the public deficit).
Price effects. The E3ME model captures price effects and does not include any awareness
or signalling effects from the green taxes. This means that the responses to changes in tax
rates should be attributed to the financial effects, rather than any publicity or virtue-signalling
that accompanies the reforms.
Prices. All euro-values in the results are in 2015 prices, unless specified differently.
The level of disaggregation. Although relatively detailed there are still limitations to E3ME in
terms of sectors, regional breakdown and temporal periods. Probably most important here is
that some sectors (e.g. ‘other mining’) combine things (here aggregates and mineral ores) that
would be useful to have split up.
Modelling the circular economy. E3ME is based around a representation of the national
accounting system which incorporates a detailed ‘input-output’ table that outlines linkages
between sectors. The economic data are linked to physical indicators of energy consumption
and material use. A circular economy is achieved through a reduction in physical consumption
of virgin materials and fossil fuels, which is represented in the economy by changing patterns
of purchases between industry sectors (e.g. less from mining and more from recycling).
283
In general, revenue-neutral means that the revenues from new tax rates introduced are used to offset
something else. Budget neutral means that the overall government budget position is unchanged, which in a
modelling exercise would only be possible if the model covered every source of tax and expenditure.
Page | 84 2%
1%
GDP
0%
2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025
-1%
Employment
-2%
-3%
CO2
-4%
-5%
Final energy
-6% consumption
-7%
Graph 4. Overall result: decoupling (2019–2025, difference from baseline). Source(s): E3ME,
Cambridge Econometrics
Table 8. Key modelling results in 2025, difference from baseline. Source(s): E3ME, Cambridge
Econometrics.
Output
While GDP represents the value added in the economy, output is a gross measure that
includes input material and energy (but not labour) costs.
Although output increases in the scenario, the relative increase is smaller than for GDP. The
reason is that companies become more efficient in their use of material and energy inputs
because of the tax shift. So, the increase in GDP is due to both higher production levels and
greater efficiency.
Investment
There are no measures in the scenario that directly affect investment. However, some of the
measures could lead to investment in new production methods. Furthermore, if the Finnish
economy grows faster there will be higher rates of investment, due to a requirement for
additional production capacity.
Electricity generation
Total electricity generation goes down by 3.1%. This is mainly the result of reduced
consumption by energy-intensive industries.
Out of the different generation technologies, only solar and wind show positive effects; these
are caused by the energy-related measures, notably the subsidy for renewable technologies
(see Table 10).
Table 10. Electricity generation per technology in 2025, difference from baseline
Energy consumption
The total final energy consumption is reduced by 2.6%. This is the result of several of the
measures included in the overall package.284 Table 11 provides the reductions per fuel type.
284
The following measures contribute to the reduction of final energy consumption: Carbon price floor, removal of
the subsidy for energy-intensive industries, removal of the diesel subsidies, removing light fuel oil subsidy,
electricity tax (bulk users) and removing the peat subsidy.
The reduction of the electricity consumption (-2.8%) is driven by a combination of the direct
Page | 88
tax on electricity consumption but also the passing on of costs from the carbon price floor,
water and nuclear waste taxes.285
Energy-related taxes lower energy consumption directly, mostly of road transport and aviation
fuels but also consumption of electricity.
Table 11. Final energy consumption per fuel type (in 2025, difference from baseline)
Final energy
Difference Difference
consumption from baseline from baseline
per fuel type (%) (ktoe)
Material consumption
Because of the taxes on materials extraction, the material consumption is brought down. All
types of materials (construction minerals, industrial minerals, ferrous ores and non-ferrous
ores) show a decline, while economic growth is higher than in the baseline. This demonstrates
an effective decoupling of economic growth and resource use and shows a combination of
improvements in material efficiency and a shift towards production of less material-intensive
goods.
CO2 emissions
In 2025, the policy measures in the scenario reduce CO2 emissions by 6.0% compared to the
baseline, mainly due to a combination of direct taxation on carbon and other measures that
reduce energy consumption. Emissions from biomass are included in this figure. If only
emissions from fossil fuels are included, the reduction in 2025 is 6.3%.
285
Electricity consumption is primary energy consumption, so not included in the final energy consumption to
avoid double counting.
Localised air pollution
Page | 89
Four types of air pollution emissions are included in E3ME: SOx, NOx, PM10 and PM2.5.
Although none of the measures in the scenario directly target air pollution, several of them aim
to reduce the combustion of polluting energy products (e.g. coal or road transport fuels). There
are therefore modest falls in all four types of emissions, compared to the baseline.
Real incomes
Real incomes are determined by a combination of changes in wage rates, taxation and prices
across the economy. Rich and poor households spend their incomes in different ways and
have different effective taxation rates; so the impacts may vary across household groups. Even
without any measures to explicitly address income distribution, the tax shift is slightly
progressive because of these different relative effects. When we account for the measure to
boost incomes in the lowest two quintiles, the effect is more pronounced (see Graph 5).
However, the average household in each group would still see an increase in real incomes of
more than 1%.
2,5
Poorest 2nd
2 quintile
4th 3rd
quintile quintile
1,5 Richest
0,5
Graph 5. Overall result: decoupling (2019–2025, difference from baseline). Source(s): E3ME,
Cambridge Econometrics
Output
The scenario represents a shift from an energy and material-intensive means of economic
production to a more labour-intensive economy. The sectoral results reflect this pattern (see
Table 12 and Graph 6).
The largest increases in output, both in relative and absolute terms, are in services sectors.
These sectors benefit both from lower labour costs and boosts to household expenditure from
lower income tax rates. The main exception is the engineering sector, which plays a role in
developing new infrastructure in the scenario. Some of the manufacturing companies in its
supply chain also benefit. Output falls in the energy and utilities sectors because of reduced
demand for energy products.
Table 12. Output by sector (In 2025, difference from baseline in % and mln €).
* E3ME includes 69 industry sectors based on Eurostat classification (see Appendix 2).
Business Services
Page | 91
Engineering etc.
Basic Manufacturing
Other Services
Wholesale and Retail
Transport and communications
Public Services
Construction
Agriculture
Energy and Utilities
The impacts on the forestry sector are unclear and depend on how the measures in the
scenario are implemented in practice. Although the scenario aims to reduce resource
consumption, including of forestry products, there is an opportunity to use wood in different
ways, for example in replacing mineral-based materials in long-life applications. The modelling
is unable to go into this level of detail and relies largely on the relationships in the sectoral
economic data (input-output tables) to estimate the demand for forestry products. Overall the
scenario shows a change in output that is close to zero for the sector, which reflects a
balancing between a small shift away from forestry products but in a larger economy.
Employment
A feature of the scenario is an increase in employment across almost all sectors (see Table
13 and Graph 7). Employment increases because of both higher levels of production and
reductions in labour costs for employers from the revenues that are raised. The pattern across
sectors broadly mirrors that for output. The largest increases in employment are services
sectors, which are also large employers in absolute terms. However, there are smaller
increases in employment in manufacturing. The only reduction in employment is in the energy
and utilities sector.
Table 13. Employment per sector
2025
Employment per sector 2025
(Employed
(difference from baseline) (%)
persons)
Engineering etc. 2.0% 3,800
Wholesale and Retail 1.9% 5,900
Basic Manufacturing 1.4% 2,200
Other Services 1.3% 5,500
Business Services 1.2% 5,700
Public Services 1.0% 4,800
Page | 92 Construction 0.7% 1,400
Agriculture 0.6% 600
Transport and communications 0.5% 900
Energy and Utilities -0.3% -100
Graph 7. Employment per sector (2025, difference from baseline, number of employed persons)
CO2
All of the measures have impacts on CO2 emissions. Increasing effective carbon tax rates has
a direct impact and changes to tax rates on energy consumption have similar effects. However,
other measures can have indirect effects (either positive or negative) on sectoral emissions.
The impacts on emissions from the different sectors vary according to their fuel mix, existing
fuel prices (including tax rates) and whether they are included in the new measures.
The largest impact on CO2 emissions (both in relative and absolute terms) is in the power
sector. The power sector both faces higher carbon charges and incentives to shift to renewable
technologies. A combination of these measures allows for a substantial reduction in emissions.
The fall in emissions from transport is less. As drivers already pay high fuel prices in Finland,
further increases to liquid fuel prices have a relatively small impact, although it is noted that
higher gasoline and diesel prices help to promote the take-up of non-conventional vehicles.
The transport sector is also excluded from any direct carbon pricing measures.286
286
The carbon price floor is lower than the current effective tax rates in the transport sector, whereby the
proposed measure would have no impact in this sector.
Transport and communications
Page | 93
Construction
Engineering etc.
Basic Manufacturing
Agriculture
All Services
Engineering etc.
Construction
Agriculture
Transport and communications
All Services
Basic Manufacturing
Energy and Utilities
Graph 9. CO2 emissions per sector (2025, absolute difference from baseline in thousand tonnes)
Engineering etc.
Construction
Basic Manufacturing
All Services
Agriculture
Graph 10. Energy consumption per sector (2025, % difference from baseline)
Engineering etc.
Construction
Agriculture
All Services
Basic Manufacturing
Graph 11. Energy consumption per sector (2025, absolute difference from baseline in ktoe)
Conclusion
The modelling exercise has described the potential macroeconomic impacts of a shift in
taxation from labour to resources in Finland. A detailed set of measures was designed and
implemented in the E3ME macroeconomic model.
The results from the model show that it would be possible to implement a set of measures that
reduce resource consumption in Finland while simultaneously boosting economic prospects
and reducing economic inequality.
A key factor in the positive outcomes is a shift from a reliance on imported products (particularly
of energy products) to using domestic labour resources (thereby reducing unemployment).
Such a shift can be achieved through changes to the taxation system and would create a small
stimulus effect that would boost the wider economy in Finland.
As with any taxation shift, the benefits and costs will not be spread evenly. The sectors that
supply energy are likely to lose out from a lower demand, but this effect will be offset by higher
levels of production in labour-intensive sectors. The model results suggest that poor and rich
households alike could benefit, with a slightly higher benefit (in relative terms) for lower income
households.
5. BEST PRACTICES IN THE PROMOTION OF CIRCULAR Page | 95
ECONOMY
In addition to the major tax shifts proposed in the previous chapters of this report, there are
numerous other types of market-based instruments (MBIs) that can be used to promote circular
economy. This chapter outlines some of the key types of MBIs that can contribute to achieving
circular economy objectives, together with illustrative examples from other Member States that
could provide inspiration for the introduction of new MBIs in Finland to complement the
proposed broader tax shifts.
With regards to creating a more sustainable food system, it is particularly important to address
the high level of wastage/lack of efficiency in the system, aiming to close the loops on nutrients
and other materials. This might help reduce the associated negative impacts generated in
production and end-of-life. Meanwhile, there is a need to create stronger incentives for the use
of sustainable resources in food production, which in turn implies a need for more sustainable
agricultural production and shorter supply chains (local food).
For technical loops, it is crucial to ensure that the valuable materials are kept in the economy
and not lost as waste. MBIs can contribute by making the use of secondary raw materials and
recycled materials financially viable in order to achieve market shifts. Waste electrical and
electronic equipment (WEEE) contains many valuable materials, including metals
(aluminum, cobalt, copper, tungsten, silver and cold), rare earth elements and plastics that can
be recycled if products are collected and carefully disassembled. In addition, in many cases
products that consumers no longer want or need, and are therefore seen as waste, can in fact
be reused and resold, thereby extending their useful lifetime and reducing the need for new
products.
Meanwhile, the textiles industry still operates an almost entirely linear system – a traditional
way of doing business, focusing on minimising price and maximising volume. Less than 1% of
the waste is currently recycled into new textile; 87% is landfilled or incinerated. For clothes,
the use per garment has dropped 36% over the last 15 years while overall textile production
has doubled over the same time (Ellen MacArthur Foundation, 2017). Similarly, few existing
policy measures – in Europe or in Finland – go beyond reducing the impacts of the linear
system and address the root causes of the challenge. Overall, the industry therefore offers
significant potential in terms of improving circularity. Greater circularity in the textiles value
chain would imply recyclable products, an available recycling system, and the use of recycled
materials and fibres in the production of new textiles (Dutch Circular Textiles Platform, 2017).
Importantly, in accordance with the waste hierarchy, the main priority should be to reduce
consumption and encourage reuse/ product longevity, e.g. through re-sale/ second-hand and
various new business models and servicing.
A variety of instruments can be used in addition to taxes with the aim of supporting a circular
transition in the transport sector. Instruments can aim to promote more sustainable and
service-based transportation, and to promote a modal shift from conventional transport
towards soft mobility (for instance, cycling, walking and other non-motorised transport), public
transport and low/zero emission vehicles (e.g. electric vehicles). They can also be used to
send financial signals to consumers – either through a monetary reward or reduced cost – to
trigger behavioural change.
Page | 96 5.1. Extended producer responsibility (EPR)
Extended producer responsibility (EPR) is a widely used MBI in the EU, following the
implementation of several EU Directives, which require its introduction to contribute to the
management of specific waste streams (WEEE, batteries, packaging and end-of-life vehicles).
Several EU Member States have also introduced EPR for other waste streams, such as
paper/cardboard, textiles, furniture and agricultural plastics. Typically, within EPR schemes,
producers of products pay a fee based on the amount of product they place on the market (e.g.
per item for EEE, or per tonne for packaging material). These fees are then used to contribute
to, or in some cases completely cover, the cost of collection and environmentally sound
treatment of the products once they become waste.
Some EPR schemes are now going further and introducing fees that vary, or are ’modulated’,
based on specific product features which have environmental impacts, e.g. making products
that are not recyclable or repairable, or contain toxic additives that disrupt recycling processes,
more expensive for producers to place on the market. Such schemes with modulated fees are
particularly promising in promoting greater circularity and therefore sustainability of products.
In France, there are three competing EPR schemes for WEEE (the producer responsibility
organisations (PROs) Eco-systèmes, Ecologic and ERP, plus Recyclum which deals only
with lamps). According to Eurostat, over 650,000 tonnes of WEEE were recovered in France
in 2016, accounting for just over 90% of the amount placed on the market288. Over 591,000
tonnes were recycled/reused (almost 82% of the amount treated)289. Just over 9,000 tonnes
were reused290. The fees paid by producers to French PROs cover 100% of collection,
transport and net treatment costs291. Within the Eco-systèmes scheme, the fees paid by
producers are modulated according to a set of environmental criteria, including reusability,
recyclability, lifetime, presence of hazardous substances, etc292. Examples include293:
287
BIO IS et al (2014) Development of guidance on extended producer responsibility (EPR): Final report
288
Eurostat (2018) Waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) by waste management operations
(env_waselee)
289
Eurostat (2018) Waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) by waste management operations
(env_waselee)
290
Eurostat (2018) Waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) by waste management operations
(env_waselee)
291
BIO IS et al (2014) Development of guidance on extended producer responsibility (EPR): Final report
292
BIO IS et al (2014) Development of guidance on extended producer responsibility (EPR): Final report
293
https://www.eco-
systemes.fr/uploads/documents/1_Réglementation/0_Agrément/0_Cahier%20des%20charges%20agrément%20
DEEE%20ménagers%20pour%20la%20période%202015–2020/CDC-agrement-EO-DEEE-menagers-final.pdf
§ A 100% increase in the fee for tablets and phones for software updates essential Page | 97
to the operation of the device are not provided
§ A 100% increase in the fee for mobile phones which do not use a universal
charger (once an international technical norm is published)
§ A 20% increase in the fee for vacuum cleaners, personal computers and TVs that
include plastic components weighing over 25g that contain brominated flame
retardants
§ A 20% increase in the fee for fridges/freezers, vacuum cleaners, electric
screwdrivers/drills and games consoles that do not have technical documentation
to assist with their repair
§ A 20% increase in the fee for fridges/freezers and vacuum cleaners for which
spare parts essential for the use of the equipment are not available
§ A 20% reduction in the fee for lamps that only use LEDs
§ A 20% reduction in the fee for washing machines, dishwashers,
computers/notebooks and TVs that include at least 10% post-consumer recycled
plastic
In an attempt to assess the cost-effectiveness of schemes, one report found that producers
paid a total of around EUR 181 million of fees for household EEE into EPR schemes in a
year, meaning that the average fees paid by producers in terms of per inhabitant per year
were EUR 2.80294. Waste collection and treatment is subcontracted to professional
operators, and municipalities receive compensation from the PROs295. Stakeholder
dialogue is assured via a consultation committee, which includes all relevant stakeholders
such as producers, retailers, PROs, local authorities, consumers, and environmental
NGOs296.
294
BIO IS et al (2014) Development of guidance on extended producer responsibility (EPR): Final report
295
Ibid
296
Ibid
Page | 98 Box 21: Eco TLC, EPR for textiles (France)
More than 9 kg of textiles per inhabitant are put on the French market each year. Since
2008, France has implemented EPR with take back targets on textiles, domestic linen and
shoes*. The target is to increase selective collection from 30 to 50% of the volumes placed
on the market by 2019, to recycle more than 20% of the collected material and to ensure
more than 95% is valorised (i.e. used for either recycling or energy recovery). Currently,
Eco TLC represents more than 93% of the industry. In 2016, the consultancy EY noted that
the targets for recycling and valorisation had been ‘easily met’, although the target for
collection had not yet been met (Dubois et al., 2016).
Each company pays an equal fee based on the amount of items sold. In order to create a
financial incentive to increase the recycled content in textiles, textiles with over 15%
recycled content receive a fee reduction. However, introducing more than one threshold
might make the incentive more dynamic, allowing those who use more than 15% recycled
content to receive a higher financial incentive (Dubois et al., 2016).
The Eco TLC EPR fees create a fund of €15 million per year. Beyond covering the costs of
waste management, the funds are used for R&D projects, e.g. a study on the use of recycled
post-consumer polyester, and communication campaigns to stimulate collection (Eco TLC,
2018). An example is the development of a national app and website that guide citizens to
nearby textile collection points (Dubois et al., 2016).
In addition to the single threshold for recycled content in the fee modulation, drawbacks with
the French scheme include complicated administration and lack of transparency for citizens
(Dubois et al., 2016).
* Eco TLC was formed following the law of the 21st of December 2006 (Article L-541-10-3
of the Code de l'Environnement; ratified on the 27th June 2008).
In relation to sustainable food, relevant instruments include feed-in tariffs, biogas subsidies,
PES, subsidies for off-grid sewage treatment/waste water, and subsidies for plant-based
foods.
VAT differentiation, such as zero or lower VAT on second-hand products or on the cost of Page | 99
labour for maintenance and repair, can help to reduce waste within technical loops
(including textiles and electronics waste), increase utilisation and encourage service provision
(leasing, sharing, etc.) rather than consumption of new products (ten Wolde, 2018).
Some countries (such as France and Denmark) have wage subsidy mechanisms in place
targeting for instance youth (to tackle youth unemployment) or people who are not able to work
full time due to impairments. In these schemes, businesses can be offered percentage
subsidies of minimum wages or lump-sum payments for hiring a particular group. Similarly,
wage subsidies could be applied to lower the personnel costs for businesses providing
services which encourage circularity, such as repair and reuse (Watson D et al., 2017).
In the transport sector, examples include rebates to return old vehicles, tax reductions or
exemptions for bike commuters, use of low emission company cars, or electric vehicles. These
can in some cases be accompanied by urban spatial planning measures, investments in public
transport, and the provision of charging infrastructure for electric vehicles, all of which aim at
supporting a modal shift from conventional transport towards soft mobility, public transport and
low/zero emission vehicles (e.g. electric vehicles).
Since the mid-1980s, farmers in the Eifel region of North Rhine-Westphalia have been paid
to maintain and extensively cultivate environmentally valuable land. Following the promising
small-scale and privately funded project – initiated by a committed university professor to
protect natural meadows and pastures – the government took over the funding and
expanded the programme, which currently has a budget of about €1.5 million annually. The
scheme has now been in operation for 30 years and is coordinated by the biological stations
in cooperation with the district landscape agencies.
Payments are input-based and the level of payment is based on opportunity and production
costs. In many cases farmers also enjoy a reduced lease payment for the managed area.
The individual farmer can receive up to €600-700 per hectare, which is financially attractive
to many farmers in the region.
The scheme has resulted in a significant increase in biodiversity and populations of rare
species exclusively in the managed areas, and similar schemes have been adopted in other
German states.
Source(s): http://www.civiland-zalf.org/download/PayingforGreen_PESinpractice.pdf
Box 23: Tax incentives for the donation of food surplus (Italy)
To be eligible, both the donating company and the beneficiary need to comply with certain
conditions.
Following the work under the National Food Waste Prevention Plan (PINPAS), including a
review of the efficiency of existing instruments, the Italian Parliament adopted a new law on
food waste prevention in 2016. Unlike the comparable French legislation which in 2016
made it mandatory for large supermarkets to donate their unsold items that are still fit for
consumption, the new Italian law (166/2016) focused on simplifying and clarifying existing
instruments.
Source(s): http://www.eu-fusions.org/phocadownload/country-
report/FUSIONS%20IT%20Country%20Report%2030.06.pdf
To try to remedy the often high upfront costs for start-ups improving textile circularity,
governments can provide access to funding and financing options with generous terms to
allow start-up solutions to reach sufficient scale and finances. In the UK, for instance, the
government set up a two-year Innovation in Waste Prevention Fund (starting in 2014 and
with total value of £800,000) to encourage creative ideas for preventing the waste of certain
priority materials (including textiles). Grants of up to £50,000 were offered to local
businesses, councils, charities and voluntary groups.
France introduced a CO2 based bonus-malus system in 2008. Based on this instrument, the
car buyer is subject to a fee (malus) if the vehicle’s CO2 emissions are above a certain level,
and receives a rebate (bonus) if the emissions are below a certain level.
Until 2017, the French feebate system was based on step functions to set levels of fees and Page | 101
rebates, which allowed manufacturers to take advantage by designing cars with CO2
emissions just below the step function levels during the type-approval test. This initially led
to increases in the rebates paid for small changes in CO2 emissions. In 2017, the French
government moved from this stepwise approach to a continuous function, allowing a
continuous fee rate line to be established for vehicles with CO2 emissions between 126 and
190 g/km. The malus fee for vehicles within that range is reduced for every gram by which
CO2 emissions are reduced (ICCT, 2018)297.
From January 2018, the malus fee is set between €50 (from 120 CO2 g/km) to €10,500 (for
185 CO2 g/km or more). The bonus fee of €6,000 is only applicable to vehicles emitting 20
CO2 g/km or less (ACEA, 2018)298 (Ministère de la Transition, 2017)299.
The aim of this feebate system is to reduce CO2 emissions and fuel consumption, while
increasing vehicles’ efficiency. By providing a monetary advantage, the system incentivises
more eco-friendly cars which emit less CO2 per kilometre.
Since its first introduction, the system has been continuously adjusting and the level of CO2
emissions at which the penalty fees and rebates are applied has decreased. As a result of
the system, vehicle emissions fell significantly in France and the market has transitioned
towards lower CO2 emission vehicles (ICCT, 2018).
The bonus-malus system is expected to change further in 2019. The average penalty fee is
expected to increase from the current €50 to €145 and the CO2 emissions threshold to be
lowered by 3 grams, from 120 g/km to 117 g/km (The Local France, 2018)300.
Belgium introduced a cycling compensation scheme in 1999. Employers may adopt the
scheme on a voluntary basis, as a way to financially reward employees who use a bike for
all or part of their commute between their home and place of work. The scheme grants a
tax-free compensation of €0.23 per kilometre travelled by bike.
The aim of the scheme is to promote eco-friendly transportation while providing alternatives
to the common practice of using company cars. The adoption of the scheme is associated
297
https://www.theicct.org/blog/staff/practical-lessons-vehicle-efficiency-policy-10-year-evolution-frances-co2-
based-bonus
298
https://www.acea.be/uploads/publications/CO2_tax_overview_2018.pdf
299
https://www.ecologique-solidaire.gouv.fr/bonus-malus-ecologique-definitions-et-baremes-2018
300
https://www.thelocal.fr/20180720/france-tightens-grip-on-polluting-cars-with-stricter-eco-tax
Page | 102 with a number of important benefits in terms of public health, air quality, reduction in CO2
emissions and congestion (SPF, 2018)301 (ECF, 2017)302.
Between 2011 and 2015, the number of beneficiaries of the compensation scheme
increased by 30%. In 2015, 406,000 employees (9% of Belgium’s workforce) received the
cycling compensation. Such compensation has a cost of €93 million on Belgium’s public
budget.
In 2018, the Belgian government agreed to the introduction of a mobility allowance or “cash
for car” scheme. The system allows employees to refuse the company car in exchange for
a monetary value calculated as follows:
§ Catalogue value of the company car x 6/7 x 20% (in case no fuel card was available)
§ Catalogue value of the company car x 6/7 x 24% (in case a fuel card was available)
The aim of the system is to reduce the incentives to use company cars and promote
alternative, more sustainable forms of transport.
In addition to this scheme, a “mobility budget” has been proposed which would allow
employees who return their company car to create their own mobility package with the
money received in exchange:
Pillar 1 The company car at the employee’s disposal is exchanged with a more
ecological vehicle.
Pillar 2 The funds obtained following pillar 1 are used for sustainable transportation
options – soft mobility (cycling) or service-based (public transportation, car
sharing systems etc.)
Pillar 3 The remaining funds are made available to the employee in cash
Introducing the mobility budget, if formally accepted, would reduce traffic congestion in
Belgium and promote more eco-friendly/service-based commutes as an alternative to
company cars (EY, 2018)303.
Box 27: Fiscal incentives for vehicles fuelled by alternative energy (Spain)
301
https://finances.belgium.be/fr/particuliers/transport/deduction_frais_de_transport/trajet_domicile_travail/velo#q1
5
302
https://ecf.com/news-and-events/news/tax-breaks-bike-commuters-european-trend
303
https://www.ey.com/be/en/newsroom/news-releases/ey-tax-alert-mobility-allowance-a-k-a-cash-for-car-and-
mobility-budget
Spain introduced the MOVEA plan (Movilidad con Vehículos de Energías Alternativas – Page | 103
Mobility with Alternative Energy Vehicles) in 2012.
The scheme offers €14,260 million in incentives to make the transition towards sustainable
mobility. The grants provided depend on the type of vehicle:
From 2017, the MOVEA plan also includes grants for charging stations: EUR 1,000 for
conventional charging points and €15,000 for fast charge points. These grants are directed
only to natural persons and freelancers, while the rest are available also to private
companies, local and public entities, and autonomous regions.
The aim of the scheme is to promote the shift to more sustainable transportation, favouring
fuel-efficient vehicles from renewable sources and discouraging conventional cars. Thanks
to the benefits associated with the diversification of energy, reduced dependence on
petroleum products and lower CO2 emissions, the scheme provides a way to improve air
quality, diminish noise pollution, and promote renewable energy sources (LiveBarcelona,
2017)304 (Ministerio de Industria, Comercio y Turismo, 2017)305 (Autovista Group, 2017)306.
Between 2012 and 2016, Spain also had the PIVE (Programa de Incentivos al Vehículo
Eficiente – Program to incentivise efficient vehicles) car scrappage programme in place.
The scheme allowed people who scrapped a car that was at least 10 years old to replace it
with a new fuel-efficient vehicle and be entitled to a rebate of up to EUR 2,000.
Over the years, the plan led to the replacement of 890,000 vehicles and an associated
energy saving of 308 million litres of fuel per year (Ministerio de Industria, Comercio y
Tursimo, 2015)307 (Mueller, 2015)308.
304
http://www.livebarcelona.cat/en/convocatoria-movea-2017-ja-no-tens-excuses-per-passar-te-a-la-mobilitat-
sostenible/
305
https://www.mincotur.gob.es/industria/es-es/Servicios/plan-movea/2017/Paginas/ayudas-movea.aspx
306
https://www.autovistagroup.com/news-and-insights/spain-approves-new-incentive-boost-sales-afvs
307
https://www.mincotur.gob.es/es-ES/GabinetePrensa/NotasPrensa/2015/Paginas/20150514-pive.aspx
308
http://europe.autonews.com/article/20150513/ANE/150519953/spain-renews-scrappage-program-for-the-last-
time
Page | 104 Examples include pay-as-you throw (PAYT) schemes for municipal waste, which aim to
change household behaviour, reduce waste generation and encourage recycling. PAYT
schemes with variable rates (based on weight, volume, type or frequency) have been shown
to be more cost-effective than fixed rate schemes. Further, to be effective, PAYT charges need
to be relatively high and combined with supporting policies, such as free separate collection of
recyclable waste (OECD, 2017).
In the transport sector, instruments include road pricing for conventional cars, such as the
implementation of congestion charges to limit private vehicle use, and/or the use of the most
polluting vehicles, in urban areas. In some cases, such instruments may be coupled with
regulatory instruments such as the regulation of CO2 emissions per capita.
The graph shows that the fee is now lower than before the PAYT scheme, despite additional
activities and equipment associated with PAYT implementation.
Page | 105
Graph 12. Evolution of waste fees in Aschaffenburg (1995-2015) (Morlok et al., 2017)
Today, the County has one of the highest rates of recyclables collection in Germany (86%)
and one of the lowest rates of residual waste generation (55 kg/capita/year). Morlok et al
(2017) conservatively estimate that the scheme has led to a 91 kg CO2e/capita/year
reduction in greenhouse gas emissions.
One interesting observation from Aschaffenburg is that – in the case of high-rise buildings
in cities – residents produce significantly less waste if they have smaller individual bins
compared to big communal bins. Another is that socio-economic factors and environmental
awareness appear to be important for PAYT success. PAYT schemes increase the risk of
illegal dumping, but this has generally not occurred in Aschaffenburg. While the PAYT
scheme clearly has contributed to the good results in terms of residual waste reduction, the
case of Aschaffenburg also illustrates the importance of adopting supporting activities,
including awareness raising and investments in better infrastructure for waste sorting and
recycling.
The municipality of Milan introduced a congestion charge in 2012, with the aim of reducing
traffic congestion, discouraging the use of private cars, and reducing pollution by imposing
a cost on access to an area of the city.
The charge covers a Limited Traffic Zone (LTZ) called Cerchia dei Bastioni of 8.2 km2, 4.5%
of the city’s area, located in the centre. Vehicles which enter the area between 7.30am and
Page | 106 7.30pm from Monday to Friday (6pm on Thursday) must buy a daily entrance ticket at the
cost of €5.
Certain types of vehicles are exempt from the charge, including mopeds, motorcycles,
electric cars, vehicles for disabled people, public utility and public transport service vehicles,
taxis. From 2017, hybrid, methane-powered, LPG and biofuel cars have been subject to the
normal entrance fee (C40 cities, 2015)309 (Cleanair Europe, 2015)310. From October 2019,
hybrid vehicles with CO2 emissions greater than 75 g/km will also be subject to the daily
ticket (Comune di Milano, 2018)311.
Within the first week of implementation of the charge, traffic in Area-C fell considerably, from
122,000 to 77,000 cars (Canters, 2014)312.
By 2015, the congestion charge had led to a 28% reduction in road congestion since its first
implementation. The charge has also led to a 6% increase in the share of clean vehicles
and a 49% reduction in polluting vehicles. Such improvements have contributed to a
reduction in several pollutants: total PM10 (-18%); exhaust PM10 (-10%); ammonia (-42%);
nitrogen oxides (-18%); and CO2 (-35%) (C40cities, 2015)313.
In addition, between 2012 and 2015, Area-C witnessed an increase in public transport
usage by 12 and 17% for surface and underground transport respectively. A 26% reduction
in road accidents was also observed in the same period (Amat, 2017)314.
In 2016, the revenue obtained from the Area C congestion charge was approximately €28
million. This amount was reinvested in sustainable mobility projects (Amat, 2017)315:
§ Strengthening of public transport (62%)
§ Development of sustainable mobility projects (22%)
§ IT and software management (16%)
For EEE, upgrades of equipment can result in significant amounts of ’waste’ EEE which could
in many cases, with the correct reconditioning, be reused by other organisations, thereby
extending their lifespan. In the case of food, such measures can promote a reduction in food
waste or promote shifts from meat-based to vegetarian diets. Public procurement guidelines
generally apply to food served in schools, hospitals and public administrations, offering public
309
https://www.c40.org/case_studies/milan-s-area-c-reduces-traffic-pollution-and-transforms-the-city-center
310
http://www.cleanair-europe.org/fileadmin/user_upload/redaktion/downloads/BUND/10_B2_Update_Guideline_-
_Congestion_Charge_IT.pdf
311
http://www.comune.milano.it/wps/portal/ist/it/servizi/mobilita/Area_C/novita_areac
312
http://www.eltis.org/discover/news/congestion-charge-milan-37-less-traffic-first-week-italy-0
313
https://www.c40.org/case_studies/milan-s-area-c-reduces-traffic-pollution-and-transforms-the-city-center
314
https://www.itf-oecd.org/sites/default/files/docs/charging-scheme-other-strategies-milan.pdf
315
https://www.itf-oecd.org/sites/default/files/docs/charging-scheme-other-strategies-milan.pdf
authorities the opportunity to influence the types and quantities of food purchased, for example
promoting zero waste (Schweitzer et al., 2018). Creating a strong enough demand for recycled Page | 107
textile materials is essential to increase circularity for non-wearable items (Ellen MacArthur
Foundation, 2017). The textile industry has expressed that they experience a lack of demand
for circularity in textiles, particularly from public and private procurement, and that
mandatory public procurement criteria can be important to stimulate market demand (ten
Wolde, 2018).
Box 30: Public procurement guidelines to minimise food waste (Italy, Spain,
Germany)
Several European cities have introduced public procurement criteria and guidelines to help
minimise food waste. In 2013, the City of Turin introduced waste reduction criteria in school
catering contracts, supporting for instance separate collection and redistribution of food
waste for social projects (European Commission, 2014a). The same year, Barcelona’s
Municipal Education Institute (IMEB) issued public procurement guidelines for the city’s 49
kindergartens, requiring bidders to train their staff on waste reduction and separate waste
collection (European Commission, 2014b). The City of Hamburg encourages organic, local
and seasonal food produced through green procurement criteria. Further, food packaging
should contain over 45% recycled material or be produced from renewable raw materials,
and food should not be supplied in individual portion packaging. Reusable cutlery,
tableware, glasses and tablecloths must be used. The criteria also includes a ‘negative list’
of products that the administration may no longer purchase or use, including capsule-based
coffee machines, mineral water in non-returnable bottles and disposable dishes (Hamburg,
2016).
Utrecht Provincial Council employs around 800 staff and has been aiming to achieve more
circular procurement for some time. The Council was one of the first to join the Dutch Green
Deal on Circular Procurement and has a target for at least 10% of its total procurement
budget to be spent on circular procurement by 2020. In a pilot starting in 2015, the Council
aimed to purchase laptops for 1,000 workplaces on a circular basis, i.e. by supplying
refurbished ICT hardware for reuse after it reaches the end of its useful life at the Council.
The pilot involved two workshops. The first was with the Dutch waterways, public works and
environment agency Rijkswaterstaat (RWS) and explored the general principles of circular
procurement and the selection and award criteria to achieve it. The second, held with MVO
Netherlands, aimed to identify how to extend the life of aging ICT equipment in Utrecht
Province. In January 2017, an ICT procurement exercise was held and SISO, a Dutch IT
solutions company, was awarded a contract to reuse the laptops within a project to provide
316
http://www.rebus.eu.com/wp-content/uploads/2017/05/REBus-Case-Study-Province-of-Utrecht.pdf
Page | 108 elderly people with lessons in how to use ICT. The ultimate aim is for the Council to award
a single contract for circular services, a model which it hopes to achieve in the coming years.
Whilst the Council anticipates that circular procurement will become the norm over the next
decade, this is not currently the case. Lessons learned through the pilot include the need to
keep track of any changes to procurement rules, to ensure that they are taken into account
in the design of procurement processes. Realism is also needed in terms of the market
opportunities for circular procurement, and how circular purchasing fits or does not fit with
manufacturers' own product distribution models. There are also legal implications of ‘pay-
per-use’ models, notably that the organisation becomes a ‘user’ rather than an ‘owner’ of a
product. In addition, consultation (e.g. with key market players) is critical to the success of
circular procurement. Finally, like any change in approach, shifting towards circular
procurement takes time and requires support and buy-in from those involved, meaning that
barriers such as existing attitudes/mindsets need to be effectively tackled. One way to do
this is to embed change in personal performance targets, to provide a direct incentive for
change.
Box 32: Public procurement guidelines for work wear, Herning Municipality
(Denmark)
For electrical and electronic equipment (EEE), greater circularity can be achieved in various
ways through business models. This includes, for example317:
§ promoting recovery and recycling – to ensure that valuable materials are collected and
reused/recycled at the end of a product’s life;
§ extending product life – for example by ensuring that products are durable, and/or can
be repaired, maintained, upgraded and/or remanufactured during their lifetime;
§ product sharing platforms – to promote shared use of, access to and ownership of
products; and
§ promoting products as a service – offering the use of products as a service (essentially
producers/manufacturers hiring out products to users).
317
Adapted from http://www.kasvuakiertotaloudesta.fi/wp-content/uploads/2018/09/Circular-Economy-Playbook-
for-Manufacturing_v1.pdf
Box 33: Apple – Daisy the disassembling robot Page | 109
In 2018, Apple announced its new robot named ‘Daisy’ which can disassemble nine different
iPhone models at a rate of up to 200 phones per hour, to recover the valuable materials
contained in them. Apple claims that Daisy can recover more materials than ‘traditional
recyclers’, and at a higher quality318. Daisy is currently running in Austin, Texas (US), with
another due to be installed in Europe. Daisy follows in the footsteps of the previous
incarnation named ‘Liam’, launched by Apple in 2016, and was created with some of Liam’s
old parts.
For every 100,000 phones, Daisy could potentially recover: 1,900 kg of aluminium, 770 kg
of cobalt, 710 kg of copper, 93 kg of tungsten, 42 kg of tin, 11 kg of rare earth elements, 7.5
kg of silver, 1.8 kg of tantalum, 0.97 kg of gold and 0.10 kg of palladium319. One recent
report estimates that the total potential value of secondary raw materials in EEE per year is
EUR 55 billion globally, with the value of raw materials in waste mobile phones alone
estimated at EUR 9.4 billion in 2016320.
In addition to these disassembling robots, Apple has announced that it now uses 100%
renewable energy in its supply chain and physical infrastructure, through purchasing green
energy bonds and investing in renewables321.
Argos is the largest high street online retailer in the UK, selling a range of over 50,000
products both online and in its physical shops. In 2014, the company ran a 5-month pilot in
10 stores, supported by WRAP (the Waste and Resources Action Programme, which works
with WRAP works with partners including governments, businesses, local authorities, trade
associations and charities), to explore the potential to incentivise customers to return their
unwanted electrical products by offering them a voucher with monetary value. The aim was
to facilitate end-of-life products’ collection, recycling, refurbishment and reuse. Following
the pilot, in 2015 Argos launched its ‘Gadget Trade-in’ service both online and in almost 800
UK stores, focussing on mobile phones and tablets (but with possible extension in the future
to sat nav systems, cameras and laptops). Customers returning their old products receive
a gift voucher. This business model is deemed to be scalable and commercially viable,
whilst also providing extra environmental credibility to the Argos brand.
The scheme is convenient for customers, avoids the need for shipping/return packaging,
and in 2016 was unique on the UK high street. Once the value of the item being traded in
is determined (prices are regularly checked to remain competitive), a voucher is issued and
can be spent immediately on anything purchased from Argos. All personal data is securely
318
https://www.apple.com/newsroom/2018/04/apple-adds-earth-day-donations-to-trade-in-and-recycling-program/
319
https://www.apple.com/environment/pdf/Apple_Environmental_Responsibility_Report_2018.pdf
320
https://www.itu.int/en/ITU-D/Climate-Change/Documents/GEM%202017/Global-E-
waste%20Monitor%202017%20-%20Chapter%209.pdf
321
https://www.theverge.com/2018/4/19/17258180/apple-daisy-iphone-recycling-robot
322
http://www.rebus.eu.com/wp-content/uploads/2016/12/REBus-Case-Study-Argos.pdf
Page | 110 removed from devices before reuse/resale to another customer. By 2016 Gadget Trade-in
had already prevented thousands of phones and tablets from being sent to landfill and
provided quality second-hand products for resale and reuse.
In terms of functioning of the business model, Argos point out that it is crucial to have cross-
term collaboration within the business for such a model to be successful. The range of
expertise available amongst staff should be drawn upon from an early stage of the business
model development, including sales, marketing, customer engagement and so on.
Argos also provides a take-back service for white consumer goods and packaging for home
delivery.
Major lighting company Philips has developed the ‘Lighting as a Service (LaaS)’ concept,
designed to deliver lighting through an intelligent, energy-saving system developed
specifically for the needs of business clients. Within LaaS, Philips undertakes an
assessment of the existing lighting system and potential savings, proposes a solution, then
delivers, installs and commissions the new lighting system, and disposes of the old
luminaires. Maintenance and repairs are also taken care of throughout the lifetime of the
contract, with a fixed monthly rate charged to the customer. Essentially the concept sees
lighting treated as another utility, such as water, gas or broadband.
Philips claims that the LaaS approach can reduce energy consumption for lighting by up to
80%, through a combination of energy efficient light sources and intelligent control systems
(e.g. collection and use of data on building/room occupancy).
One example is InterAct Office, a connected lighting system provided for principal tenants
OVG Real Estate and Deloitte at The Edge office building in Amsterdam. InterAct Office
uses smart technology, apps and dashboards to provide insights into the use of office space
and energy. Over 3,000 sensors in the connected lighting system receive anonymised data
on lighting performance and space usage. This allows the optimisation of lighting, heating,
ventilation, cooling, cleaning and use of space in the building, reducing energy usage and
associated costs. In terms of hardware, Ethernet cables are used to send both power and
data to the luminaires, which means that separate power cables are not required.
Employees also use an app to tailor the lighting and temperature in their own workspace
(wherever they work within the building).
Compared with previously-occupied offices, it is estimated that the InterAct Office system
has resulted in €3.6m savings in office space and €100,000 reduction in energy costs per
year. Along with desk-sharing, this has contributed to reducing the annual cost of space per
employee by over €1,800.
323
http://www.rebus.eu.com/wp-content/uploads/2017/05/REBus-Case-Study-Province-of-Utrecht.pdf
324
http://images.philips.com/is/content/PhilipsConsumer/PDFDownloads/United%20Kingdom/Case-
Study/CSLI20171222_001_UPD_en_GB_the_Edge.pdf
The Edge has been awarded the highest ever sustainable building score within the Page | 111
BREEAM (Building Research Establishment Environmental Assessment Method)
sustainability assessment method, of 98.36%.
Box 36: Business models in support of a more circular food system (France, UK,
Finland)
The Eqoshère digital platform start-up, created in 2012, connects public and private
sector bodies to reuse food waste. The team also helps customers reduce the generation
of food waste throughout their value chains by auditing waste flows, suggest process
improvements and train staff. In 2017, the start-up helped Leader Price to recycle of 500
tonnes of food, saving 200,000 m3 of water.
Source(s): https://www.livingcircular.veolia.com/en/inspirations/circular-economy-
combined-responsible-food ; http://www.eqosphere.com/
Another similar example is the ‘Too good to go’ app, which allows restaurants to sell any
food they have left at the end of the day to consumers. Consumers place an order via the
app and can pick up their meal an hour before closure, at a reduced rate.
Source: https://toogoodtogo.co.uk/en-gb
Other businesses have innovated the production of food in support of increased circularity,
for instance by producing fertilizers and other soil improvement products from recycled by-
products from conventional agricultural, forestry and bioenergy industry. One example is
the Finnish company Soilfood, established in 2015. Soilfood’s revenue comes from the
acceptance fees paid for industrial by-products as well as products and services sold to
farmers (at a lower rate than synthetic fertilizers). This type of solution reduces the need for
virgin phosphorus, for instance, and can also help reduce the overall energy used to
produce fertilizers.
With regards to textiles, while policy-makers have been moving slowly with regard to
promoting textile circularity, the market has been more active in innovating and closing the
loop on textiles. This is arguably a reflection of the profit opportunities for early movers in
markets where sustainability has been a key trend in recent years. Examples of private sector
innovation in support of a circular textile economy include, for instance, bespoke take-back
Page | 112 schemes or digital solutions providing new ways of accessing quality textiles (such as rental
and subscription-based models, etc.). The Ellen MacArthur Foundation (2015) categorises six
types of action that business (and governments) can take to support a transition towards a
circular economy:
§ Regenerate: shifting to renewable energy and materials;
§ Share: the sharing and recycling economy, and prolonging the life of products;
§ Optimise: increased efficiency, waste minimisation and use of information and
communications technology (ICT);
§ Loop: closing the technical and biological material cycles;
§ Virtualise: direct and indirect dematerialisation; and
§ Exchange: the use of novel materials and technologies.
I:Collect, or I:CO, offers a textiles take-back solution to fashion houses and retailers. I:CO
provides in-store collection bins that can be designed to fit the respective company. It
collects the bins and transports them to the nearest recycling facility, where all items are
sorted by hand into three categories: garments for rewear (sold as second-hand), reuse
(turned into other products) and recycling (turned into textile fibres). At present, the majority
of the latter are made into insulation material for the automotive and construction industries.
More information about I:CO is available on their website: https://www.ico-spirit.com/en/
C&A (The Netherlands) – In 2012, C&A was the first fashion retailer in the Netherlands to
open textile collection points in its stores, in collaboration with I:CO. In exchange for a
voucher of 5% reduction on their next purchase, customers can hand in their old clothes.
Today, all 133 Dutch stores have a collection point and about 250 customers per week hand
in used garments. C&A is now exploring how to expand the scheme beyond the Netherlands
(Dubois et al., 2016).
H&M Group Garment Collection Program (global) – Swedish brand H&M also offers
vouchers towards next purchase in return for customers handing in unwanted textiles.
Claiming to have been the first brand to roll out the concept on a large scale, H&M
introduced the scheme in 2013 for all its stores worldwide. The used textiles are collected,
sorted and distributed by I:CO (H&M, 2018). Since the launch, over 55,000 tonnes of
garments have been collected, and the target is to increase collection to 25,000 tonnes per
year by 2020 (Gould, 2017, Lehmann et al., 2018).
Other companies offering similar services include Levi’s, Nike, Zara and Marks & Spencer,
some of them through I:CO, or via other similar solutions.
While providing an often previously non-existent avenue for disposing of used textiles, it is
important to note that these schemes have been criticised, for example for encouraging a
guilt-free consumption attitude in favour of linear, fast fashion consumption (Gould, 2017).
Box 38: Circular business model initiatives for textiles Page | 113
Example 2 – Digital solutions for material traceability: Reverse Resources have developed
a ‘Software as a Service (SaaS)’ platform to allow fabric and garment factories to map and
measure leftover fabrics and scraps from production, making them traceable throughout
their lifecycles. The aim is to close the loop of spilled fabrics and fibres from garment
production. Although textile manufacturing is a relatively small industry in Finland, solutions
for connecting garment factories with potential buyers of scraps can provide additional
income streams, while providing mechanisms for ensuring high quality streams of scraps
for the benefit of recyclers and secondary raw material markets. Individual brands can trace
the origins of recycled fibres used in production, on which they can base sustainability
claims made to consumers.
Source: http://reverseresources.net/en
Example 3 – Product repair services: Several brands offer repair services of their products
in an attempt to increase product longevity. Customers can for instance bring their damaged
jeans back to Nudie Jeans’ repair shops for free mending. In 2017, Nudie repaired almost
50,000 pairs of jeans, claiming to save an equivalent of 40,000 kg of garments being
disposed of, and saving 345 million litres of water. Patagonia is another example, offering
customers advice on how to best treat their clothes for longevity and how to mend broken
items.
The transport sector has also seen the development of new business models which aim at
promoting service provision instead of product consumption (service over ownership). Models
include introducing car sharing, car clubs and fare sharing deliver a service which is paid based
on the time consumed. Such models aim at reducing car ownership and potentially reduce
CO2 emissions. Evidence shows that the introduction of these circular models has been
successful in several cities (Acea, 2018)325 (OECD, 2002)326.
325
https://www.acea.be/uploads/publications/EV_incentives_overview_2018_v2.pdf
326
http://lnweb90.worldbank.org/ECA/Transport.nsf/ExtECADocByUnid/87A59F75CB89B1EA85256C630069CDD
B/$file/9702151E.pdf
Page | 114
The results indicate that it is possible to design policy measures that reduce final energy
consumption and harmful emissions, while at the same time stimulating the Finnish economy
and creating jobs. Consequently, it would seem appropriate to open national discussions on
the possibilities to introduce similar measures, and to check whether there are some aspects
that may not have been raised during the project. Such incentives could be promoted also at
European level, as Finland will be chairing the European Council during the latter part of 2019.
At the Paris Climate Summit, the European Union together with the other signatory states
pledged to restrict global warming to less than two degrees Celsius and to pursue efforts to
limit it to 1.5 degrees Celsius by the end of this century. Achieving these goals will be difficult
without a major change in fiscal and other policies, whereby the external costs of economic
growth should be internalised in market prices while reducing labour taxation.
The authors of this report hope that Finland would continue its active work in promoting low-
carbon and circular economy objectives by introducing the necessary measures that would
help to materialise these goals. Without the proper incentives, this may be difficult, if not
impossible.
APPENDIX 1: ENVIRONMENTAL AND LABOUR TAXATION Page | 115
Graph 13. The tax burden in Finland and other OECD countries according to OECD Revenue
Statistics Database.
The trend of tax ratio to gross domestic production (GDP) of taxes and compulsory social
security contributions has been growing in long-term (see Graph 15). The ratio was in its
highest in the late 1990 and went down after that period until the recession in 2008 when it
grew again. The accrual of these tax and tax-like payments amounted to €95.2 billion in 2016.
The tax ratio grew from the previous year by 0.2 percentage points to 44.1%.
327
OECD (2018), OECD Economic Surveys - Finland. February 2018. http://www.oecd.org/finland/economic-
survey-finland.htm
Page | 116
Graph 14. Taxes and tax-like payments in Finland in years 1975 – 2016. The tax ratio describes the
ratio of taxes and compulsory social security contributions to gross domestic product (GDP)
Labour Taxation
Finland has high labour taxation, and over half of all tax revenues, to be precise 51.3%, come
from labour taxes in 2016328. Especially the tax wedge329 is high compared to other EU member
states and OECD countries. Finland had the 9th highest tax wedge among the 35 OECD
member countries in 2017. The average single worker in Finland faced a tax wedge of 42.9%
in 2017 compared with the OECD average of 35.9%. In Finland, income tax and employer
social security contributions combine to account for 82% of the total tax wedge, compared with
77% of the total OECD average tax wedge. The tax wedge for a worker with children is slightly
lower than for a worker with the same income without children since benefits to families with
children through cash transfers and preferential tax provisions affect the tax wedge. For an
average married worker with two children, the tax wedge was the 4th highest in the OECD at
38.4% in 2017, which compares with the OECD average of 26.1%. In 2016, the position was
even higher as Finland occupied the 2nd highest position. Child related benefits and tax
provisions tend to reduce the tax wedge for workers with children compared with the average
328
Eurostat data (2018), Shares of environmental and labour taxes in total tax revenues
http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/products-datasets/-/sdg_17_50
329
The tax wedge is a measure of the tax on labour income, which includes the tax paid by both the employee
and the employer.
single worker. In Finland, this reduction (4.5 percentage points) was less than the OECD
Page | 117
average (9.8 percentage points) in 2017330.
Environmental Taxes
In Finland, the share of environmental tax revenues of GDP was 3.1 percent in 2016, which is
higher than the average for EU member states. The share of environmental taxes of entire tax
revenues was over 7%, which is slightly higher than the average for EU member states331(see
Graph 16).
Graph 15. Share of environmental tax revenues of GDP in Finland and other EU member states, 2016
The accrual of the environmental tax revenues was € 6.7 billion in 2016. The revenues from
environmental taxes have increased slowly and stayed nearly the same in the last decade (see
Graph 17). Environmental tax revenues grew in 2016 by 10 per cent in average and taxes paid
by households grew by 14 per cent from the previous year. The households' share of paid
environmental taxes increased to 51 per cent.332 The trend is that the households’ share has
increased every year during the last decade.
330
OECD (2018), Taxing Wages 2018 – Finland. http://www.oecd.org/finland/taxing-wages-finland.pdf
331
Official Statistics of Finland (2018), Environmental and energy taxes [e-publication]. ISSN=2341-796X. 2015.
Helsinki: Statistics Finland [referred: 10.7.2018]. Access method: http://www.stat.fi/til/yev/2015/yev_2015_2017-
09-07_tie_001_en.html
332
Official Statistics of Finland (OSF): Environmental and energy taxes [e-publication].
ISSN=2341-796X. 2016. Helsinki: Statistics Finland [referred: 24.10.2018].
Access method: http://www.stat.fi/til/yev/2016/yev_2016_2018-09-06_tie_001_en.html
Page | 118
Graph 16. Share of environmental tax revenues of total tax and tax-like revenues in EU member
states in 2016
The increase in environmental tax revenues was most significant for transport taxes, which
grew by 14 per cent year-on-year to € 2.1 billion. Transport taxes paid by households increased
by 15 per cent, and represented 73 per cent of all transport taxes. The growth was mostly
caused by the rise in vehicle tax. In addition. energy tax revenues increased by nine per cent
to € 4.5 billion. Energy taxes paid by households and energy supply grew most, by 14 per cent.
Households were the biggest payers of energy taxes, paying 41 per cent of all energy taxes.
Increases in taxes on fuel oil, coal and natural gas contributed to the growth.333
Emission taxes continued their decline in 2016. The falling trend is influenced by the
continuous increase in the incineration of municipal waste that reduces the accrual of waste
tax and by the ending of the temporary increase in oil protection fee that was in force from
2010 to 2015. As a result, emission taxes paid by water and waste management went down
by 34 per cent and those paid by industry by 56 per cent.334
333
Official Statistics of Finland (OSF): Environmental and energy taxes [e-publication].
ISSN=2341-796X. 2016. Helsinki: Statistics Finland [referred: 24.10.2018].
Access method: http://www.stat.fi/til/yev/2016/yev_2016_2018-09-06_tie_001_en.html
334
ibid.
Page | 119
In Finland, environmental taxes include energy taxes, vehicle-related taxes, waste and
packaging taxes, oil spill payments and license fees for hunting and fishing. The majority of
environmental tax revenues accrues from energy taxes on electricity and fuels used in
transportation, heating, industry and in other purposes. In Finland CO2 tax is a part of energy
taxation and included in energy tax revenues, thus its share of environmental taxes is not
shown these statistics. One-third of environmental taxes are vehicle-related taxes, which
comprise car tax, vehicle tax and motor vehicle tax. The car tax and vehicle tax are
differentiated according to carbon dioxide emissions. As the CO2 tax is incorporated into the
energy taxes and vehicle taxes, we do not have specific emission taxes in Finland. In statistics
emission taxes are referred to waste tax, beverage packaging tax and oil spill payments. In
addition, there are no actual natural resource taxes in Finland, apart from license fees for
hunting and fishing.
Graph 19. Environmental taxes by tax payer (industry and households) and tax type in 2015, EUR
million
Since the 2011 energy tax reform, the taxation of heating and transport fuels has been based
mainly on the carbon dioxide emissions from their combustion. The current excise tax on fossil
fuels consists of three components: an energy content component, a carbon dioxide emissions
component (CO2 tax) and a strategic stockpile fee for certain fuels. At the start of 2018, the
335
Official Statistics of Finland (OSF): Environmental and energy taxes [e-publication].
ISSN=2341-796X. 2016. Helsinki: Statistics Finland [referred: 24.10.2018].
Access method: http://www.stat.fi/til/yev/2016/yev_2016_2018-09-06_tie_001_en.html
336
Act on Excise Duty on Electricity and Certain Fuels (1260/1996).
337
Act on Excise Duty on Liquid Fuels (1472/1994).
rate was increased to €62/tonne of CO2 emissions338. According to the state budget, energy
Page | 121
taxes would accrue total revenues of around €4.683 billion in the year 2018, including revenues
from the CO2 tax component339.
There are many tax refund systems incorporated in the Finnish energy taxation. According to
the state budget, the total amount of altogether 11 tax refunds was estimated to cut energy tax
revenues by about €2.3 billion in 2016. The main refund systems and their estimated value in
2017 are:
The excise taxation of electricity has been graded into two categories since 1997. Electricity
used in industry and greenhouse cultivation and in recent years also server rooms and mining,
is subject to the lower (II) tax category. Excise duty of the higher (I) tax category is collected
on electricity used by private households as well as agriculture, forestry, construction, public
administration and service sector. The difference between categories is quite high as the lower
rate is only 0.703 cent/kWh whereas the higher tax rate is 2.253 cent/kWh. According to this
estimate, potential tax revenues of about €614 million are lost because of the lower rate for
category II electricity in 2018.342
In order to compensate the indirect emission costs due to ETS, there is established
compensation measure, which rules are laid down in the Act (138/2017) on aid for indirect
emission costs due to the Emissions Trading System entering into force in June 2017. It is
possible to grant the aid for indirect emission costs under the Emissions Trading Directive, and
338
Finlex (2018), Hallituksen esitys eduskunnalle laeiksi nestemäisten polttoaineiden valmisteverosta sekä
sähkön ja eräiden polttoaineiden valmisteverosta annettujen lakien liitteiden muuttamisesta, HE 138/2017 vp,
(Government Proposal for acts for changing the appendices of the Acts on Excise Duty on Liquid Fuels and Act
on Excise Duty on Electricity and and Certain Fuels)
http://www.finlex.fi/fi/esitykset/he/2017/20170138.pdf
339
Ministry of Finance (2017), State budget for 2018. Talousarvioesitys, Tuloarviot, Verot ja veroluonteiset tulot,
Valmisteverot, 07. Energiaverot, HE 106/2017 vp. (19.9.2017) (Government Proposal of the State budget for
2018, Tax and tax-like revenues, Excise duties, 07. Energy taxes.)
340
This reduced rate for diesel is compensated by an extra tax for private diesel cars. Vehicles that operate with
power or fuel other than motor petrol are subject to the tax on driving power (käyttövoimavero).
341
Ministry of Finance (2017), State budget for 2018.
342
Ministry of Finance (2017), State budget for 2018.
about 10 EU member states or EEA countries have used the aid to compensate operators for
Page | 122
indirect emission costs.
The compensation measure was adopted in Finland in 2017, when it accounted for €43 million.
The amount of compensation is related to the price of allowances, thus the increase in prices
has an impact on the compensation.343 The rates used in the calculation are defined by the
Commission annually. The compensation is calculated individually to all industrial plants
according to the amount of electricity they have used annually. In Finland, the compensation
is only a half of the maximum level allowed.344
The basic tax for passenger cars and vans is based on the levels of carbon dioxide emissions
or on the basis of the total mass of the vehicle. In the case of new vehicles, the tax levied is
based on CO2 data stated by the car's manufacturer in the Vehicular and Driver Data Register.
In case of older vehicles, and if the car does not have emission data, tax is levied on the basis
on the total mass of the vehicle. The annual limits for CO2 and mass are generated in view of
the method for measurement of CO2 emissions that has been standardised at EU level and
the time when the emission data became mandatory for the vehicle's type approval345.
According to state budget estimates the revenues from car tax will amount to €896 million in
2018, and from the motor vehicle tax about to €1.174 billion346. At the moment, the focus in
developing road traffic taxation is on levying taxes on usage not so much on buying a new
vehicle.
343
http://julkaisut.valtioneuvosto.fi/bitstream/handle/10024/79863/TEMrap_22_2017_verkkojulkaisu.pdf
344
The Finnish system for aid for indirect emission costs complies with the obligations laid down in the
Commission Communication on guidelines on certain State aid measures in the context of the emissions trading
system (2012/C 158/04). Source: Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment. https://tem.fi/en/aid-for-indirect-
emission-costs
345
Trafi Finnish Transport Safety Agency (2018), Vehicle tax. Structure and amount of tax.
https://www.trafi.fi/en/road/taxation/vehicle_tax/structure_and_amount_of_tax
346
Ministry of Finance (2017), State budget for 2018.
347
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment. 2017. Virkamiesselvitys yritystuista ja niiden vaikutuksista
(Official Report on Business Subsidies and their Effectiveness). Reports 22/2017 (in Finnish).
business subsidies account for over €4 billion. Of these, direct business subsidies accounts
Page | 123
for €1.1 billion and tax subsidies for around €2.9 billion. However, this estimate does not cover
VAT reduced rates, nor EU financed or partly EU financed subsidies for agriculture348.
According the report by the Ministry, only 11% of the €4 billion of subsidies promote the
development of business sector or companies. Thus, the most part of the subsidies are
supporting the linear economy-based status quo and the existing technology and business
models. It is mainly the research and development tax subsidies and some direct subsidies
that seem to have a positive impact on companies’ innovation activities. According to a study349
by the VATT Institute for Economic Research the effects of research and development
subsidies, for small businesses in particular, are significant. However, most of the subsidy
funds go to large companies. According to the study, correctly targeted subsidies can promote
economic growth effectively. However, many of the subsidies are not effective. On the
contrary, they are detrimental to sustainable development and innovation or even
environmentally harmful while blocking reform and renewal of the business sector.
Consequently, there is a strong case for reforming current practices of business subsidies and
for removing the ineffective and environmentally harmful subsidies. From a point of view of
promoting circular economy, the business subsidies should be reformed as most of them are
environmentally harmful or harmful also for circular economy business models and goals.
Energy sector
The most significant environmentally harmful subsidies in the energy sectors are the same
mentioned in the energy taxation chapter:
348
Ibid.
349
Rauhanen, T., Grönberg, S., Harju, J. & Matikka, T. 2015. Yritystukien arviointi ja vaikuttavuus (The
Assessment and effectiveness of business subsidies). Government’s Analysis, Assessment and Research
Activities8/2015, Prime Minister’s Office.
350
Hyyrynen, M. (2013), Ympäristön kannalta haitalliset tuet. (Environmentally harmful subsidies)
Ympäristöministeriön raportteja (Report of Ministry of Environment) 13/2013.
§ a tax refund system for energy-intensive industry (€230 million in 2019) 351.
Page | 124
Transport sector
The transport sector accounts for approximately 20% of greenhouse gas emissions in Finland,
of which road traffic is responsible for 95 %. Furthermore, road traffic causes other emissions,
such as fine particles (PM10, PM2,5), nitrogen dioxide (NO2) and sulfur dioxide (SO2).352 Even if
these emission have decreased, they still have health impacts especially in the cities. The most
significant subsidies in the transport sector are partly the same than mentioned in the energy
taxation chapter (2014 and estimated values for 2019353):
In addition, company car and parking benefits are significant incentives (administrative
support) for private car use. The estimated amount of the company car benefit is €300 – 800
million in 2014354.
Agriculture sector
In Finland, agriculture is the largest single contributor to nutrient loads on lakes, rivers and the
Baltic Sea. It accounts for approximately 55% of the total nitrogen load and for 65% of the total
phosphorus load on water bodies. In addition, agriculture affects biodiversity. According to the
report by the Ministry of the Environment, the amount of the EHS in the agricultural sector is
more than EUR 1.1 billion in 2014.355 The most significant of these subsidies are:
351
Ministry of Finance (2018), Budget proposal for 2019.
http://budjetti.vm.fi/indox/sisalto.jsp?year=2019&lang=fi&maindoc=/2019/tae/valtiovarainministerionKanta/valtiova
rainministerionKanta.xml&opennode=0:1:3:5:25:33 :
352
LIPASTO - calculation system for traffic exhaust emissions and energy use in Finland,
http://lipasto.vtt.fi/en/index.htm and Liikennejärjestelmä, http://liikennejarjestelma.fi/ymparisto/paastot-
ilmaan/liikenteen-kasvihuonekaasupaastot/
353
. Ministry of Finance (2018), Budget proposal for 2019.
354
Hyyrynen, M. (2013), Ympäristön kannalta haitalliset tuet. (Environmentally harmful subsidies)
Ympäristöministeriön raportteja (Report of Ministry of Environment) 13/2013.
355
The objective of some of these subsidies is to cut emissions from farming and forestry. However, reductions in
CO2 have been modest until now.
356
These figures are now according to the report of Ministry of Environment (Hyyrynen, 2013). They will be
updated and checked the situation and new figures later.
there is a lack of clear commitment, priorities for taking action, no action plan with a schedule
Page | 125
nor a road map.
The main objective in promoting renewable energy is to reduce greenhouse gas emissions
and move away from the energy system that is based on fossil fuels. Another objective is to
improve energy self-sufficiency and employment and support the development of technologies
in the sector.357 Finland has used different policy instruments to achieve the target share of
renewable sources on energy end-consumption. The main drivers for investments and use of
renewables have been a feed-in programme, a biofuel blending requirement for motor fuels
and subsidies for investments for renewable energy production.
Since 2011, a feed-in tariff scheme for electricity has been in use to increase the renewable
energy sources in electricity production. A feed-in tariff is available for 1) new wind power
plants; 2) new biogas power plants (gas produced by digestion); 3) new wood-fuelled power
plants with heat production; and 4) forest chip power plants.358 In the feed-in tariff system, an
electricity producer can receive a production subsidy (feed-in tariff) for a maximum of twelve
years. The subsidy varies on the basis of a three-month electricity market price or the market
price of emission allowances.359 The fiscal effect of the feed-in tariff has varied from around €
11 million in 2011 to € 170 million in 2016.360
Finland has a biofuel blending requirement for motor fuels. This obligation of mixing biofuels
with fossil motor fuels started in 2008 as a small percentage, and has been increased since.
357
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Renewable Energy in Finland.
https://tem.fi/en/renewable-energy
358
Tamminen, S., Haanperä, O. & Hietaniemi, T.(2018) Harnessing economic instruments to tackle the climate
crisis. Finland’s experiences with economic instruments applied in climate policy. Sitra memorandum. 05.10.2018.
Sitra, Finnish Innovation Fund. https://media.sitra.fi/2018/10/04162441/harnessing-economic-instruments-to-
tackle-the-climate-crisis.pdf
359
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Feed-in tariff for renewable Energy.
https://tem.fi/en/feed-in-tariff-for-renewable-energy
360
Tamminen, S., Haanperä, O. & Hietaniemi, T.(2018) Harnessing economic instruments to tackle the climate
crisis. Finland’s experiences with economic instruments applied in climate policy. Sitra memorandum. 05.10.2018.
Sitra, Finnish Innovation Fund. https://media.sitra.fi/2018/10/04162441/harnessing-economic-instruments-to-
tackle-the-climate-crisis.pdf
The latest plans are to extend the biofuel blending requirement gradually to 30% by 2030 for
Page | 126
transport fuels and to 10% for heating and machinery fuels.361
Energy aid and investment aid for key energy projects, managed by the Ministry of Economic
Affairs and Employment, has been one of the drivers to promote investments and technology
in renewables. Energy aid can be granted to investment projects and studies that:
§ promote the production or use of renewable energy;
§ promote energy savings or increase the efficiency of energy generation or use; or
§ otherwise promote the transition towards a low-carbon energy system.
Investment Aid for Key Energy Project programme is intended to subsidy investments on
renewable energy and new energy technology. 362 Annually, the subsidies under the Energy
Aid and Investment Aid for Key Energy Projects amount to around € 60-70 million.363 In
addition, investments in the construction of a national LNG terminals network have been
supported with a total of approximately € 93 million.364
361
ibid.
362
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Energy aid. https://tem.fi/en/energy-aid
and Investment aid for key energy projects. https://tem.fi/en/investment-aid-for-key-energy-projects
363
Tamminen, S., Haanperä, O. & Hietaniemi, T.(2018) Harnessing economic instruments to tackle the climate
crisis. Finland’s experiences with economic instruments applied in climate policy. Sitra memorandum. 05.10.2018.
Sitra, Finnish Innovation Fund. https://media.sitra.fi/2018/10/04162441/harnessing-economic-instruments-to-
tackle-the-climate-crisis.pdf
364
Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment in Finland (2018). Investment Support for LNG Terminals.
https://tem.fi/en/investment-support-for-lng-terminals
APPENDIX 2: E3ME Page | 127
Introduction
E3ME is a computer-based model of the world’s economic and energy systems and the
environment. It was originally developed through the European Commission’s research
framework programmes and is now widely used in Europe and beyond for policy assessment,
for forecasting and for research purposes. Recent applications of E3ME include:
This section provides a short summary of the E3ME model. For further details, the reader is
referred to the full model manual available online from www.e3me.com.
§ 59 countries – all major world economies, the EU28 and candidate countries plus other
countries’ economies grouped
§ 69 industry sectors for European countries, based on the Eurostat classification (the
final page of this Appendix provides a detailed overview)
§ 43 categories of household expenditure
§ 22 different users of 12 different fuel types
§ 14 types of air-borne emission (where data are available) including the six greenhouse
gases monitored under the Kyoto protocol.
E3ME’s historical database covers the period 1970-2016 and the model projects forward on
an annual basis. The main data sources for European countries are the Eurostat national
accounts data365 and the IEA energy balances366. These are supplemented by the OECD’s
Page | 128
STAN database367 and other sources where appropriate. Most of the data provided by Eurostat
are ‘complete’ and do not require further manipulation. Any remaining gaps in the data are
estimated using customised software algorithms.
The econometric techniques used to specify the functional form of the equations are the
concepts of cointegration and error-correction methodology, particularly as promoted by Engle
and Granger (1987)368 and Hendry et al (1984)369. In brief, the process involves two stages.
The first stage is a levels relationship, whereby an attempt is made to identify the existence of
a cointegrating relationship between the chosen variables, selected on the basis of economic
theory and a priori reasoning, e.g. for employment demand the list of variables contains real
output, real wage costs, hours-worked, energy prices and the two measures of technological
progress.
If a cointegrating relationship exists then the second stage regression is known as the error-
correction representation, and involves a dynamic, first-difference, regression of all the
variables from the first stage, along with lags of the dependent variable, lagged differences of
the exogenous variables, and the error-correction term (the lagged residual from the first stage
regression). Due to limitations of data size, however, only one lag of each variable is included
in the second stage.
It is noted that the structure of the Finnish economy has changed considerably over the
historical time period. To test the validity of the econometric parameters over time, we
assessed how key trade price elasticities vary over the period back to 1970, using ‘rolling’
regressions. This analysis found that there were some sectors where elasticities changed, but
the elasticities in the key sectors were generally quite stable.
Figure 10 below shows how the three components (modules) of the model - energy,
environment and economy - fit together. Each component is shown in its own box. Each data
set has been constructed by statistical offices to conform with accounting conventions.
Exogenous factors coming from outside the modelling framework are shown on the outside
edge of the chart as inputs into each component.
For each region’s economy the exogenous factors are economic policies (including tax rates,
growth in government expenditures, interest rates and exchange rates). For the energy
system, the outside factors are the world oil prices and energy policy (including regulation of
the energy industries). The linkages between the components of the model are shown explicitly
by the arrows that indicate which values are transmitted between components. These linkages
are one of the key strengths of the model, as they ensure consistency between each
component.
365
See economy and finance branch at https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/data/database
366
https://www.iea.org/statistics/balances/
367
http://www.oecd.org/industry/ind/stanstructuralanalysisdatabase.htm
368
Engle, R F and C W J Granger (1987), 'Cointegration and error correction: representation, estimation and
testing', Econometrica, 55, 251-76.
369
Hendry, D F, Pagan, A and J D Sargan (1984), ‘Dynamic specification, in Handbook of Econometrics’, Vol II,
Griliches, Z and M D Intriligator (eds), Amsterdam, North Holland.
The economy module provides measures of economic activity and general price levels to the
Page | 129
energy module; the energy module provides measures of emissions of the main air pollutants
to the environment module, which in turn can give measures of damage to health and buildings.
The energy module provides detailed price levels for energy carriers distinguished in the
economy module and the overall price of energy as well as energy use in the economy.
Technological progress plays an important role in the E3ME model, affecting all three Es:
economy, energy and environment. The model’s endogenous technical progress indicators
(TPIs), a function of R&D and gross investment, appear in nine of E3ME’s econometric
equation sets including trade, the labour market and prices. Investment and R&D in new
technologies also appears in the E3ME’s energy and material demand equations to capture
energy/resource savings technologies as well as pollution abatement equipment. In addition,
E3ME also captures low carbon technologies in the power sector through the FTT power sector
model (see below).
An important part of the modelling concerns international trade. E3ME solves for detailed
bilateral trade between regions (similar to a two-tier Armington model). Trade is modelled in
three stages:
§ econometric estimation of regions’ sectoral import demand
§ econometric estimation of regions’ bilateral imports from each partner
§ forming exports from other regions’ import demands
Trade volumes are determined by a combination of economic activity indicators, relative prices
and technology.
Treatment of the labour market is an area that distinguishes E3ME from other macroeconomic
models. E3ME includes econometric equation sets for employment, average working hours,
wage rates and participation rates. The first three of these are disaggregated by economic
sector while participation rates are disaggregated by gender and five-year age band.
The labour force is determined by multiplying labour market participation rates by population.
Unemployment (including both voluntary and involuntary unemployment) is determined by
taking the difference between the labour force and employment. This is typically a key variable
of interest for policy makers.
Page | 130
370
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0301421512005356
371
https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/documents/20160713%20draft_publication_REF2016_v13.pdf
372
http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/european_economy/2014/pdf/ee8_en.pdf
373
https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/population-demography-migration-projections/population-projections-data
In most cases the changes are phased in gradually over the period up to 2025. The rates are
Page | 132
held constant after 2025.
We start with the revenue-raising measures:
§ Carbon Price Floor – implemented as a carbon tax rate (€60/tCO2) for all sectors that
have lower rates in the baseline, such that the total rate paid by the sector is equal to
the value given. A lower rate (€10/tCO2) was applied to the use of bioenergy.
§ A phase-out of the aid scheme for indirect emission trading costs compensation.
§ Removal of the Reduced Energy Tax Rate on Diesel – implemented as an increase in
the cost of diesel for road transport.
§ Removal of the light fuel oil subsidy – as above, implemented as an increase in the
price of light fuel oil. Road and air transport are excluded.
§ Removal of the peat subsidy – peat falls into the category ‘other solid fuel’ in E3ME. It
was verified that the model data for this category represented peat (all cases except
iron and steel, where a weighting was applied). The price of this fuel group was then
increased.
§ Non-energy use of fossil fuels – the tax is applied to the chemicals sector, at a rate
such that the expected revenues are achieved.
§ Electricity (bulk users) – the cost of electricity is increased for the sectors that are
subjected to the lower tax rate (industry, greenhouse cultivation and data centres).
These include sectors covered by the EU ETS (mostly large installations) plus the food
and agriculture sectors.
§ Removal of the subsidy for energy-intensive industries – the cost of energy is increased
for the EU ETS sectors, with the amount determined by the value of the subsidy divided
by energy consumption.
§ Air passengers and air freight – it is not possible to split these two measures, given the
data in the modelling framework. A charge is therefore added to domestic production
(a proxy for number of flights) in the sector.
§ Incineration of waste – the E3ME model does not have a detailed treatment of waste
(mainly due to a lack of data). It was determined that the charge would be passed on
to households that use district heating systems that are powered by incineration. The
cost is therefore passed on to households, on the assumption that they cannot change
their heating system.
§ Nuclear waste – nuclear power is one of the technologies in the FTT:Power model. A
charge per MWh is added to the levelised costs in the model, which help to determine
the choice of future capacity.
§ Water abstraction (bulk users) – a charge was added to industries that self-abstracted
water, based on a €/m3 rate. Gaps in the data make this measure challenging to model
and it was not possible to reconcile the expected revenues with the physical
consumption data.
§ Extraction of metal ores and extraction of non-metallic minerals – a charge is added to
the cost of production of the ‘other mining’ sector in E3ME. It is not possible to
differentiate between metal and non-metal ores here in the economic data.
§ Pesticides – a charge was added to the consumption of ‘other chemicals’ by the
agriculture sector, represented in E3ME by an input-output coefficient. It was assumed
that consumption falls by around 5% as a result, which is broadly in line with other
Page | 133
studies.374
Where sectors face higher costs, it is assumed that, in the long run at least, most of the higher
costs are passed on to consumers. Estimated parameters determine how much of the cost
increase is passed on initially.
The scenario is ‘revenue neutral’, meaning that all tax increases are exactly matched by
reductions in other taxes. How the measures to do this are modelled are described below:
§ Personal income tax and Employee social security tax reduction – both of these
measures are represented as a subtraction of gross wage income. When the rates are
reduced, households therefore have a higher domestic income for expenditure.
§ Employers’ social security tax reduction (for new employment) – this measure is
important for generating new employment. It is assumed that new jobs have the same
wage rates as the existing sectoral average. The number of jobs created is therefore
equal to the revenues available divided by the average wage rate.
§ Employers’ social security tax reduction (general) – a reduction in employers’ labour
taxes reduces the difference between labour costs and wage rates.
§ Income support for specific groups – in the formal modelling, this measure is treated
as a lump-sum payment to households. In a subsequent off-model calculation, the
amount is allocated to low-income households.
§ R&D subsidy (labour cost reduction) – it is assumed that R&D increases by the amount
raised. The share of R&D across sectors matches existing patterns.
§ Subsidy for renewable energy – subsidies are added to renewable technologies in the
FTT:Power model. As a result, there is slightly faster uptake of wind and solar power.
374
The implied elasticity is -0.37. See e.g. Pearce and Koundouri (2003), where they report a value of -0.39.
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWRD/903845-
1112344347411/20424145/31203ARDenoteWRMEIPearceKoundouri.pdf
Page | 134 Conversion of 69 industry sectors to 10 sectors (Eurostat
classification)
1) Agriculture: Crop production, Forestry and Fishing.
2) Energy and Utilities: Coal, Oil and Gas, Manufactured fuels, Electricity, Gas, steam
and Air conditioning, Water supply, Sewerage and waste.
3) Basic Manufacturing: Other mining, Food, drinks and tobacco, Textiles and leather,
wood and wood products, Paper and pulp, Printing, Chemicals, Pharmaceuticals,
Rubber and plastic, Non-metallic mineral products, Basic metals.
4) Engineering etc.: Metal products, Electronics, Electrical equipment, Machinery,
Equipment, Motor vehicles, Other transport equipment, Manufacturing, Repair and
installation.
5) Construction: Construction.
6) Wholesale and retail: Sale of cars, Other wholesale, Other retail.
7) Transport and communications: Land transport, Water transport, Air transport,
Warehousing, Postal and courier activities.
8) Business services: Publishing activities, Broadcasting and movies,
Telecommunications, Computer services, Financial services, Insurance, Auxiliary to
finance, Real estate, Legal, account. etc, Architect & engineer, R&D activities,
Advertising, Other professional, Rental and leasing, Employment activities, Travel
agency, tours, Security and administration.
9) Public services: Public admin, Education, Human health activities.
10) Other services: Hotel & catering, Residential care, Arts and entertainment activities,
Sports activities, Memberships organizations, Repair household goods, Other personal
services, Household employers, Extraterritorial organizations.