ECO1C01
ECO1C01
ECO1C01
STUDY MATERIAL
I SEMESTER
CORE COURSE
MA ECONOMICS
(2019 Admission onwards)
UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT
SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION
CALICUT UNIVERSITY P.O.
MALAPPURAM - 673 635, KERALA
190301
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
2
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
STUDY MATERIAL
FIRST SEMESTER
Prepared by:
Dr. SHIJI O
Assistant Professor on Contract (Economics)
School of Distance Education
University of Calicut
Scrutinized by:
Dr. SITARA V. ATTOKKARAN
Assistant Professor
Department of Economics
Vimala College, Thrissur
3
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
4
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
CONTENTS
5
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
6
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Syllabus
7
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
8
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
MODULE I
CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR UNDER
UNCERTAINTY AND RISK
9
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
10
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
11
In our previous example, if Pg= π= 0:8 and Pb= (1- π) = 0:2
then = 4. In this case the odds in favour of good times
would be stated as “4 to 1”. Fair markets for contingent claims
(such as insurance markets) will also reflect these odds. An
analogy is provided by the “odds” quoted in horse races. These
odds are “fair” when they reflect the true probabilities that
various horses will win.
Risk aversion
We are now in a position to show how risk aversion
is manifested in the state-preference model. Specifically, we
can show that, if contingent claims markets are fair, then a
utility maximizing individual will opt for a situation in
which Wg= Wb ; that is, he or she will arrange matters so
that the wealth ultimately obtained is the same no matter what
state occurs. Maximization of utility subject to a budget
constraint requires that this individual set the MRS of Wg for
Wb equal to the ratio of these “goods” prices:
or Wg= Wb
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
13
5. Sometimes demand for a good is driven partly or entirely
by speculation— people buy the good because they think
its price will rise. We will see how this can lead to a
bubble, where more and more people, convinced that the
price will keep rising, buy the good and push its price up
further—until eventually the bubble bursts and the price
plummets.
In a world of uncertainty, individual behaviour may
sometimes seem unpredictable, even irrational, and perhaps
contrary to the basic assumptions of consumer theory.
Describing Risk
To describe risk quantitatively, we begin by listing all
the possible outcomes of a particular action or event, as well
as the likelihood that each outcome will occur. Suppose, for
example, that you are considering investing in a company that
explores for offshore oil. If the exploration effort is
successful, the company’s stock will increase from Rs.30 to
Rs.40 per share; if not, the price will fall to Rs.20 per
share. Thus there are two possible future outcomes: a
Rs.40-per-share price and a Rs.20-per-share price.
Probability
Probability is the likelihood that a given outcome will
occur. In our example, the probability that the oil exploration
project will be successful might be ¼ and the probability
that it is unsuccessful 3/4. (Note that the probabilities for all
possible events must add up to 1.) Our interpretation of
probability can depend on the nature of the uncertain event, on
the beliefs of the people involved, or both. One objective
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
15
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Expected Value
The expected value associated with an uncertain
situation is a weighted average of the payoffs or values
associated with all possible outcomes. The probabilities of
each outcome are used as weights. Thus the expected value
measures the central tendency—the payoff or value that we
would expect on average.
Our offshore oil exploration example had two possible
outcomes: Success yields a payoff of Rs.40 per share, failure
a payoff of Rs.20 per share. Denoting “probability of” by
Pr, we express the expected value in this case as
Expected value = Pr (success)(Rs.40/share) + Pr (failure)
(Rs.20/share)
= (1/4)(Rs.40/share) + (3/4)(Rs.20/share)
= Rs.25/share
More generally, if there are two possible outcomes
having payoffs X1 and X2 and if the probabilities of each
outcome are given by Pr1 and Pr2, then the expected value is
E(X) = Pr1X1 + Pr2X2
When there are n possible outcomes, the expected
value becomes
E(X) = Pr1X1 + Pr2X2 +........+ PrnXn
Variability
Variability is the extent to which the possible
outcomes of an uncertain situation differ. Now we can discuss
16
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Note that these two jobs have the same expected income. For
Job 1, expected income is 0.5(Rs.2000) + 0.5(Rs.1000) =
Rs.1500; for Job 2, it is 0 .99 (Rs.1510) + 0.01(Rs.510) =
Rs.1500. However, the variability of the possible payoffs is
different. We measure variability by recognizing that large
differences between actual and expected pay offs (whether
17
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Weighted
Out- Devia-
Deviation Out- average Standard
come tion
Squared come 2 Deviation Deviation
1 Squared
Squared
Job 1 2000 250,000 1000 250,000 250,000 500
Job 2 1510 100 510 980,100 9900 99.50
18
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
19
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
denoted Ey.
Let the utility function of the agent be u(c). His
utility when consuming y is: u(y1) with probability p; and
u(y2) with probability 1- p. We assume an agent evaluates the
utility of a random variable y by expected utility; that is,
pu (y1) + (1-p) u (y2)
In other words, we assume that, when facing
uncertainty, agents maximize expected utility. A lot of
experiments document failures of this assumption in various
circumstances. A lot of theoretical work addresses the failure,
postulating different (still optimizing) behavior on the part of
agents. Most economic theory still uses the assumption in
approximation.
The Von Neumann –Morgenstern Theorem
In their book The Theory of Games and Economic
Behaviour, John von Neumann and Oscar Morgenstern
developed mathematical models for examining the economic
behaviour of individuals under conditions of uncertainty. To
understand these interactions, it was necessary first to
investigate the motives of the participants in such “games.”
Because the hypothesis “that individuals make choices in
uncertain situations based on expected utility seemed
intuitively reasonable, the authors set out to show that this
hypothesis could be derived from more basic axioms of
“rational” behaviour. The axioms represent an attempt by the
authors to generalize the foundations of the theory of
individual choice to cover uncertain situations. Although
20
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
21
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
22
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
23
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
24
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
25
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
coin until you get to heads. The number of times it took you
to get to heads is what you put as an exponent to 2 and
receives that in rupees amounts. This game helped to
understand what people were willing to pay versus what
people were expected to gain from this game.
Formula for Expected Utility
When the entity whose value affects a person's utility
takes on one of a set of discrete values, the formula for
expected utility, which is assumed to be maximized, is
E [u(x)] = p1.u(x1) +p2. u (x2)+.....
where the left side is the subjective valuation of the gamble
as a whole, x1 is the ith possible outcome, u(xi) is its
valuation, and pi is its probability. There could be either a
finite set of possible values xi in which case the right side of
this equation has a finite number of terms;
or there could be an infinite set of discrete values, in which
case the right side has an infinite number of terms. When x
can take on any of a continuous range of values, the
expected utility is given by
26
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
27
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
28
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Outcomes = Head 1 2 3 … k
appears in toss
Probability head ½ ¼ 1/8 ..... 1/2k
occurs on given toss
Payoff = 2k 2 4 8 ..... 2k
Therefore,
Expected Payoff = ½ X 2 + ¼ X 4 + 1/8 X 8 + . . . + 1/2k X 2k
+ . . . = 1+ 1+ 1+ 1+ … = ∞
29
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
30
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 1.1
31
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
32
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
33
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
34
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 1.2
35
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
36
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
37
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
38
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 1.3
39
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Income (Rs.1000)
Here the utility associated with a job generating an
income of either Rs.10,000 or Rs.30,000 with equal
probability is 12, as is the utility of receiving a certain
income of Rs.20,000. As you can see from the figure, the
marginal utility of income is constant for a risk-neutral
person. Thus, when people are risk neutral, the income they
40
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Income (Rs.1000)
In this case, the expected utility of an uncertain
income, which will be either Rs.10,000 with probability .5 or
Rs.30,000 with probability .5, is higher than the utility
41
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
42
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
back and the higher the risk, the higher premium an investor
expects over the average return. If an investor has a choice
between a government bond paying 3% interest and a
corporate bond paying 8% interest and he chooses the
government bond, the payoff differential is the certainty
equivalent. The corporation would need to offer this particular
investor a potential return of more than 8% on its bonds to
convince him to buy.
A company seeking investors can use the certainty
equivalent as a basis for determining how much more it needs
to pay to convince investors to consider the riskier option.
The certainty equivalent varies because each investor has a
unique risk tolerance. The term is also used in gambling, to
represent the amount of payoff someone would require to be
indifferent between it and a given gamble. This is called the
gamble's certainty equivalent.
• The certainty equivalent represents the amount of
guaranteed money an investor would accept now instead of
taking a risk of getting more money at a future date
• The certainty equivalent varies between investors based
on their risk tolerance, and a retiree would have a higher
certainty equivalent because he's less willing to risk his
retirement funds
• The certainty equivalent is closely related to the
concept of risk premium or the amount of additional
return an investor requires to choose a risky investment
over a safer investment
43
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
44
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
= (1-p)
= p (W – ) = (1- p) (W + )
= pw - (1- p) W = (1-p) +p
α* = (2p-1) w
Note that when p < 1; α* is negative. In other words, when p
α+ (1-p) (- α) = (2p-1) α
< 0, then the expected value of the stock is negative (p < ).
In that case, the optimal amount of stock purchased would be
negative as well. If the expected value of the stock is zero (p
= ), then the optimal amount of stock purchased is zero. If the
expected value is positive (p > ); then the optimal amount of
stock purchased is positive.
2. Insurance Demand
We assume a utility function over money:
U (W) = Ln W
In one state of the world 1, the consumer is healthy and
has wealth W1. This occurs with probability p. In a second
state of the world, the consumer is sick must spend money for
health services, after which she is left with wealth W2 < W1.
45
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
-p = - (R-1) (1- p)
46
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Bring the exogenous variable to one side and the terms only
involving parameters on the other, we get:
α (1- p) (R- 1) + α p (R- 1)
= (1- p) (R- 1) W1 - pW2
Solving for α*, we finally get:
α*, = =(1-p) W1 -
Certainty Equivalent
In the decision analysis literature, a decision-maker
is called risk-neutral if he (or she) is willing to base his
decisions purely on the criterion of maximizing the expected
value of his monetary income. The criterion of maximizing
expected monetary value is so simple to work with that it is
often used as a convenient guide to decision-making even by
people who are not perfectly risk neutral. But in many
situations, people feel that comparing gambles only on the
basis of expected monetary values would take insufficient
account of their aversion to risks. For example, imagine that
you had a lottery ticket that would pay you either Rs.20,000 or
Rs.0, each with probability 1/2. If you are risk neutral, then
you should be unwilling to sell this ticket for any amount of
money less than its expected value, which is Rs.10,000. But
many risk averse people might be very glad to exchange
this risky lottery for a certain payment of Rs.9000. Given
any such lottery or gamble that promises to pay you an amount
of money that will be drawn randomly from some
probability distribution, a decision-makers certainty
47
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
48
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
49
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
50
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Diversification
Recall the old saying, “Don’t put all your eggs in
one basket.” Ignoring this advice is unnecessarily risky: If
your basket turns out to be a bad bet, all will be lost. Instead,
you can reduce risk through diversification: allocating your
resources to a variety of activities whose outcomes are not
closely related. Suppose, for example, that you plan to take a
part-time job selling appliances on a commission basis. You
can decide to sell only air conditioners or only heaters, or you
can spend half your time selling each. Of course, you can’t be
sure how hot or cold the weather will be next year. Risk can
be minimized by diversification—by allocating your time so
that you sell two or more products (whose sales are not
closely related) rather than a single product. Suppose there is
a 0.5 probability that it will be a relatively hot year, and a 0.5
probability that it will be cold.
Table 1.4
51
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
52
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
utility than would be the case if that person had a high income
when there was no loss and a low income when a loss
occurred.
To clarify this point, let’s suppose a homeowner faces
a 10-percent probability that his house will be burglarized and
he will suffer a Rs.10,000 loss. Let’s assume he has Rs.50,000
worth of property. Note that expected wealth is the same
(Rs.49,000) in both situations. The variability, however, is
quite different. As the table shows, with no insurance the
standard deviation of wealth is Rs.3000; with insurance, it is
0. If there is no burglary, the uninsured homeowner gains
Rs.1000 relative to the insured homeowner. But with a
burglary, the uninsured homeowner loses Rs.9000 relative to
the insured homeowner. Remember: for a risk-averse
individual, losses count more (in terms of changes in utility)
than gains. A risk- averse homeowner, therefore, will enjoy
higher utility by purchasing insurance.
The Value of Information
People often make decisions based on limited
information. If more information were available, one could
make better predictions and reduce risk. Because information
is a valuable commodity, people will pay for it. The value of
complete information is the difference between the expected
value of a choice when there is complete information and the
expected value when information is incomplete. To see how
information can be valuable, suppose you manage a clothing
store and must decide how many suits to order for the fall
season. If you order 100 suits, your cost is Rs.180 per suit. If
53
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
54
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
55
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
56
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
MODULE II
MARKET DEMAND FOR COMMODITIES
Market Demand
A market demand curve shows how much of a good
consumers overall are willing to buy as its price changes. In
this section, we show how market demand curves can be
derived as the sum of the individual demand curves of all
consumers in a particular market.
From Individual to Market Demand
To keep things simple, let’s assume that only three
consumers (A, B, and C) are in the market for coffee. Table
2.1 tabulates several points on each consumer’s demand
curve. The market demand, column (5), is found by adding
columns (2), (3), and (4), representing our three consumers,
to determine the total quantity demanded at every price.
When the price is Rs.3, for example, the total quantity
demanded is 2 + 6 + 10, or 18.
Table 2.1 Determining the Market Demand Curve
Price Individual A Individual B Individual C Market
(Rs.) (units) (units) (units) (units)
1 6 10 16 32
2 4 8 13 25
3 2 6 10 18
4 0 4 7 11
5 0 2 4 6
57
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
58
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
59
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
60
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
62
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
63
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
result, the value of a lift ticket at a ski resort is lower the more
people who bought the tickets. Likewise, for entry to an
amusement park, skating rink, or beach. Another example of a
negative network externality is the snob effect. Snob effect is
the desire to own an exclusive or unique good. The quantity
demanded of a “snob good” is higher the fewer people who
own it. Rare works of art, specially designed sports cars, and
made-to-order clothing are snob goods. The value one gets
from a painting or a sports car is partly the prestige, status,
and exclusivity resulting from the fact that few other people
own one like it.
Figure 2.3
64
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
65
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
fewer skiers on the slopes, the value obtain from a lift ticket at
a ski resort is lower the more people there are who have
bought tickets. Likewise, for entry to an amusement park,
skating rink, or beach. Network externalities have been
crucial drivers for many modern technologies over many
years. Telephones, fax machines, email, Craigslist, Second
Life, and Twitter are just a few examples.
Veblen effect
Veblen Goods are a class of goods that do not strictly
follow the law of demand, which states that there exists an
inverse relationship between the price of a good or service
and the quantity demanded of that good or service. Veblen
goods violate the law of demand after prices have risen
above a certain level. It is named after American economist
and sociologist Thorstein Veblen, who studied the
phenomenon of conspicuous consumption in the late 19th
century.
The Veblen Effect is the positive impact of the price
of a commodity on the quantity demanded of that commodity.
It is abnormal market behaviour where consumers purchase the
higher priced goods whereas similar low priced (but not
identical) substitute are available. It is caused either by the
belief that higher price means higher quality, or by the
desire for conspicuous consumption (to be seen as buying an
expensive, prestige item).
66
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 2.4
67
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
68
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
69
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
70
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
71
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
72
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
73
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
74
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Where, ρ = [1 + (1/β1)].
Linear Demand versus Constant-Elasticity Demand
Linear demand functions and constant-elasticity (log-
linear) demand functions are the simplest classes of demand
functions. Neither is a true representation of real world
demand functions (which are too complicated to work with or
measure exactly), but each is a useful approximation. One
might say that linear functions are too straight and constant
elasticity functions are too curved, with the curvature of
real-world demand functions lying between the two.
A linear demand curve is easy to draw and work
with. Furthermore, it has the property that demand becomes
more elastic moving up the demand curve, which holds in
the real world and is important for certain qualitative
conclusions. One cannot accurately estimate an entire demand
curve of constant-elasticity demand. When we estimate the
linear regression equation log (Q) = log (A) − B log (P), the
75
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
76
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
77
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
78
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
derived as follows.
Demand in any particular period depends on price, on
stocks of the commodity and on the current level of income
Qt = b0+ b1Pt+ b2 St+ b3Yt
where,
St = stocks of durables, if the function refers to such goods
St, = ‘stocks of habits’, if the function refers to non-durables
The sign of the coefficient of S will be negative for
durables: the more we have of furniture, electrical appliances,
etc., the less our demand for such commodities will be. The
sign of the coefficient of S will be positive for non-durables:
the higher our purchases of non-durables the stronger our
habit becomes.
Stocks S, however, cannot be measured: (i) The
stock of durables is composed of heterogeneous items of
various ages- the electrical equipment we have is not of the
same age, some items may be very old and need scrapping
and replacing, some others are new. Their heterogeneity also
makes direct measurement difficult. What we ideally want for
stocks is the sum of depreciated inventories of durables; but
the appropriate depreciation rates are not known. (ii) The
‘stock of habits’ is a psychological variable and cannot be
quantified.
However, we can eliminate algebraically stocks, S,
from the demand function and replace it with other
measurable variables by making some ‘reasonable’
79
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
assumptions.
For durables the elimination process may be outlined as
follows:
(1) The net change in stocks realised in any period (St -
St-1) is equal to our purchases in that period minus the
depreciation of our old possessions:
St - St-1 = Qt -depreciation
(2) Assume that depreciation is equal in all the periods of
the life of the durable, i.e.
Depreciation = δ St
Where, δ is a constant depreciation rate (for example, if
the life of the durable is ten years, we assume that the yearly
depreciation is 10 per cent of the value of the durable). Thus
(St - St-1) = Qt - δ St
(3) From the demand function
Qt = b0+ b1Pt+ b2 St+ b3 Yt
Solving for St we obtain
Substituting this value in the right hand side of the equation (St
- St-1) = Qt - δ St we have
(4) Since the relation Qt = b0+ b1Pt+ b2 St+ b3Yt holds for
period t, the relationship
80
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
81
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
82
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
U=ƩUi
or
U=U(A)+U(B)+U(C)+U(D)+U(E)
Additivity implies that the utilities of the various groups are
independent, that is, there is no possibility of substitution (or
complementarity) between the groups A, B, C, D and E.
In linear expenditure systems the commodities bought
by the consumers are grouped in broad categories, so as to be
compatible with the additivity postulate of the utility function.
Thus each group must include all substitutes, and
complements. In this way substitution between groups is
ruled out, but substitution can occur within each group.
The consumers buy some minimum quantity from
each group, irrespective of prices. The minimum quantities
are called ‘subsistence quantities’ because they are the
minimum requirements for keeping the consumer alive. The
income left (after the expenditure on the minimum quantities
is covered) is allocated among the various groups on the basis
of prices.
The income of the consumer is, therefore, split into
two parts: the ‘subsistence income’, which is spent for the
acquisition of the minimum quantities of the various
commodities, and the ‘supernumerary income’, the income
left after the minimum expenditures are covered.
Characteristic Approach to Demand Function
Characteristics demand theory states that consumers
83
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
derive utility not from the actual contents of the basket but
from the characteristics of the goods in it. This theory was
developed by Kelvin Lancaster in 1966 in his working paper
“A New Approach to Consumer Theory”.
This approach allows us to predict how preferences
will change when we change the options or baskets presented
to consumers by studying how these vary according to the
change in the characteristics that make them up. With
conventional theory, the introduction of a new option meant
that we could not reliably predict how this would slot into the
consumer’s preference map. However, by relying on a study
of the characteristics rather than the goods or service
involved, we can predict how changes will affect a
consumer’s behaviour without needing to start once again
empirically.
This allows us to calculate ‘shadow prices’ for
different attributes without having a price for the good itself
by associating utility to the characteristics that make up the
good rather than the good itself. With these ‘shadow prices’,
we can solve utility maximisation problems for baskets or
options for which we do not have empirical evidence, as
Lancaster demand also lends itself to building utility
functions (based on the amount of each type of characteristic
rather than the amount of each type of good in a particular
basket).
Characteristic demand theory also helps justify the
existence of brands. Luxury brands are able to charge a
surprice for their products by differentiating themselves
from competitors that sell similar goods. In the first diagram
84
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
85
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
86
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
MODULE III
THEORY OF PRODUCTION AND COSTS
Production Function
The production function is a purely technical
relation which connects factor inputs and outputs. It
describes the laws of proportion, that is, the transformation
of factor inputs into products (outputs) at any particular
time period. The production function represents the
technology of a firm of an industry, or of the economy as a
whole. The production function includes all the technically
efficient methods or production.
A method of production (process, activity) is a
combination of factor inputs required for the production of
one unit of output. Usually a commodity may be produced by
various methods of production. The theory of production
describes the laws of production. The choice of any particular
technique (among the set of technically efficient processes)
is an economic one, based on prices, and not a technical one.
We note here that a technically efficient method is not
necessarily economically efficient. There is a difference
between technical and economic efficiency. An isoquant
includes (is the locus of) all the technically efficient methods
(or all the combinations of factors of production) for
producing a given level of output. The production isoquant
may assume various shapes depending on the degree of
substitutability of factors.
87
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
89
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
90
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
91
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
92
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
93
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
94
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
95
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Marginal
Amount of Amount of Total Output Average
Product
Labour (L) Capital (K) (q) Product(q/L)
(MPL)(∆q/∆L)
1 10 10 10 10
2 10 30 15 20
3 10 60 20 30
4 10 80 20 20
5 10 95 19 15
6 10 108 18 13
7 10 112 16 4
96
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Marginal
Amount of Amount of Total Output Average
Product
Labour (L) Capital (K) (q) Product(q/L)
(MPL)(∆q/∆L)
8 10 112 14 0
9 10 108 12 -4
10 10 100 10 -8
97
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
98
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
99
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
100
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
101
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Or
Share of L / share of K = (w/r)/(K/L)
The above equation traces the relationship between
change in / ratio to the relative shares of labour and capital.
Now when < 1, a given percentage change in the / ratio
induces a smaller change in the / ratio. This results an
increase in relative factor share. The = 1 implies that there
will be equal percentage change in / ratio for a given
percentage change of / and consequently the relative factor
share will be unchanged. However, in case of > 1 , the
relative factor share will decline as percentage increase in /
ratio causes relatively smaller percentage increase in / ratio.
It is important to note that there is a two-way causation
between / ratio and / . That is, change in / ratio induces
change in the ratio of factor prices which in turn changes the
shares of factors to output.
Homogeneous Production Function
Specifically, a function f (x1, x2,…, xn) is said to be
homogeneous of degree k if
102
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
103
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
104
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 3.5
105
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 3.6
106
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
108
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
109
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
= = (1 − ) −
= ( − 1)−2 1−
< if <1
110
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
lim →0 = lim →0 =∞
lim →∞ = lim →∞ =0
where = /
= = =
∗ ,
= =1
111
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
112
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
( , , )= A [δ( ) − + (1 − δ) ( ) − ] −1/
− −
= A λ[δ + (1 − δ) ] −1/
=λY.
ii. Positive and Diminishing Returns to Inputs:
The marginal products of the input are
+1
= = (Y/K)
+1
MPL = = (Y/L)
113
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
= (K/L)(1+ )
= =
114
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
115
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Neutral-Technical Progress
Technical progress is neutral if it increases the
marginal product of both factors by the same percentage, so
that the MRSL, K (along any radius) remains constant. The
isoquant shifts downwards parallel to itself. This is shown in
figure 3.11.
116
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 3.11
Cost Function
Cost functions are derived functions. They are
derived from the production function, which describes the
available efficient methods of production at any one time.
Economic theory distinguishes between short-run costs and
long-run costs. Short-run costs are the costs over a period
during which some factors of production (usually capital
equipment and management) are fixed. The long-run costs are
the costs over a period long enough to permit the change of all
factors of production. In the long run all factors become
variable. Both in the short run and in the long run, total cost is
a multi variable function, that is, total cost is determined by
many factors. Symbolically we may write the long-run cost
function as
C = f (X, T, Pf)
and the short-run cost function as
117
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
C = f (X, T, Pf ,K )
Where,
C = total cost
X= output
T = technology
Pf = prices of factors
K = fixed factor(s)
118
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
119
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
121
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
122
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
SC =
123
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
124
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
because the fewer the hours of labour needed, the lower the
marginal and average cost of production.
Figure 3.12
125
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
has taken place. The larger β is, the more important the
learning effect. With β equal to 0.5, for example, the labour
input per unit of output falls proportionately to the square
root of the cumulative output. This degree of learning can
substantially reduce production costs as a firm becomes
more experienced. In this machine tool example, the value
of β is 0.31. For this particular learning curve, every
doubling in cumulative output causes the input requirement
(less the minimum attainable input requirement) to fall by
about 20 percent.
Estimating and Predicting Cost
A business that is expanding or contracting its
operation must predict how costs will change as output
changes. Estimates of future costs can be obtained from a
cost function, which relates the cost of production to the
level of output and other variables that the firm can control.
Suppose we wanted to characterize the short-run cost of
production in the automobile industry. We could obtain data
on the number of automobiles Q produced by each car
company and relate this information to the company’s
variable cost of production VC. The use of variable cost,
rather than total cost, avoids the problem of trying to allocate
the fixed cost of a multiproduct firm’s production process to
the particular product being studied.
126
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 3.13
127
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
128
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
129
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
130
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
131
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
132
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
133
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
c. Cost Elasticity:
On the basis of the relation between MC and AC we
can develop a new concept, viz., the concept of cost
elasticity. It measures the responsiveness of total cost to a
small change in the level of output.
It can be expressed as:
136
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
138
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
139
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
140
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
141
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
LRTC= LRTC/Q
Long-run marginal cost is the extra total cost of producing an
additional unit of output when all inputs are optimally
adjusted:
LRTC= ∆ LRTC /∆Q
It, therefore, measures the change in total cost per unit of
output as the firm moves along the long run total cost curve
(or the expansion path). Figure 3.19 illustrates typical long-
run average and marginal cost curves. They have essentially
the same shape and relation to each other as in the short run.
Long-run average cost first declines, reaches a minimum (at
Q2 in Fig. 14.8), then increases. Long-run marginal cost first
declines, reaches minimum at a lower output than that
associated with minimum average cost (Q1 in Figure 3.19),
and increases thereafter. The marginal cost intersects the
average cost curve at its lowest point (L in Figure 3.19) as in
the short-run. The reason is also the same. The reason has
been aptly summarized by Maurice and Smithson thus:
“When marginal cost is less than average cost, each
additional unit produced adds less than average cost to
total cost; so average cost must decrease. When marginal
cost is greater than average cost, each additional unit of the
good produced adds more than average cost to total cost; so
average cost must be increasing over this range of output.
Thus marginal cost must be equal to average cost when
average cost is at its minimum.
143
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 3.19
144
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
145
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
146
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
148
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Plant I is the best plant for output levels less than 900
units because its AC curve is the lowest to the left of point a.
Plant II is the best plant size for output levels between 900 to
2,000 units, because its AC curve is the lowest between point
a and b. Plant III is the best plant size for output levels
greater than 2,000 units, since its AC curve is the lowest
beyond point b. If these are only three possible plant sizes,
the long run ATC curve will consist of the segments of Plant
I’s AC curve up to point a, the segment of plant II’s AC curve
between points a and b, and the segment of Plant Ill’s AC
curve from point of b and so on. The thick LAC is
composed of the three lowest branches of SACs. This is why
the LAC is called the envelope curve.
Figure 3.22 is the smooth envelope case. Writes
Samuelson: “In the long run, a firm can choose its best plant
sizes and its lower envelope curve.” Since there is an infinite
number of choices, we get LAC as a smooth envelope. And,
as in the short-run, we can derive LMC from LAC, and
LMC emerges from the minimum point of LAC with a
smoother slope than the SMC curve.
Figure 3.22
149
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Differences
The main difference between long run and short run
costs is that there are no fixed factors in the long run; there
are both fixed and variable factors in the short run. In the
long run the general price level, contractual wages, and
expectations adjust fully to the state of the economy. In the
short run these variables do not always adjust due to the
condensed time period. In order to be successful a firm must
set realistic long run cost expectations. How the short run
costs are handled determines whether the firm will meet its
future.
150
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
MODULE IV
THEORY OF IMPERFECT MARKETS
Oligopoly
Oligopoly is a market situation in which there are
a few firms selling homogeneous or differentiated goods.
Though it is very difficult to identify the number of sellers,
but due to few sellers the actions and decisions of one seller
influence the others. Furthermore, under oligopoly market
firms producing homogeneous products are known as pure or
perfect oligopoly and firms selling the differentiated goods
are known as imperfect or differentiated oligopoly. For
instance, pure oligopoly is found among the producers of
industrial goods like aluminum, zinc, copper, cement, steel,
crude oil etc, and imperfect oligopoly is found among the
producers of consumer goods like T.V., automobiles,
typewriters, refrigerators etc.
In some oligopolistic markets, some or all firms earn
substantial profits over the long run because barriers to entry
make it difficult or impossible for new firms to enter.
Oligopoly is a prevalent form of market structure. Managing
an oligopolistic firm is complicated because pricing, output,
advertising, and investment decisions involve important
strategic considerations. Because only a few firms are
competing, each firm must carefully consider how its actions
will affect its rivals, and how its rivals are likely to react.
When making decisions, each firm must weigh its
151
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
152
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
153
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
154
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
155
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
period and despite the fact that the ‘expected’ reaction does
not in fact materialise, the firms continue to assume that the
initial assumption holds. In other words, firms are assumed
never to learn from past experience, which makes their
behaviour at least naive (if not stupid).
Cournot model
The earliest duopoly model was developed in 1838 by
the French economist Augustin Cournot. Actually Cournot
illustrated his model with the example of two firms each
owning a spring of mineral water, which is produced at zero
costs. They sell their output in a market with a straight-line
demand curve. Each firm acts on the assumption that its
competitor will not change its output, and decides its own
output so as to maximise profit. Assume that firm A is the
first to start producing and selling mineral water. It will
produce quantity A, at price P where profits are at a
maximum (figure 4.1), because at this point M C = M R =
0. The elasticity of market demand at this level of output is
equal to unity and the total revenue of the firm is a
maximum. With zero costs, maximum R implies maximum
profits, π. Now firm B assumes that A will keep its output
fixed (at OA), and hence considers that its own demand curve
is CD'. Clearly firm B will produce half the quantity AD',
because (under the Cournot assumption of fixed output of
the rival) at this level (AB) of output (and at price P') its
revenue and profit is at a maximum. B produces half of
the market which has not been supplied by A, that is, B’s
output is of the total market.
156
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 4.1
157
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
period 1:
period 2:
period 3:
period 4:
Product of A in equilibrium=
158
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
period 2:
period 3:
period 3:
period 4:
Product of B in equilibrium=
159
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
price. The larger the number of firms the closer is output and
price to the competitive level.
Bertrand’s Model
Bertrand developed his duopoly model in 1883. His
model differs from Cournot’s in that he assumes that each firm
expects that the rival will keep its price constant, irrespective
of its own decision about pricing. Thus each firm is faced by
the same market demand, and aims at the maximisation of its
own profit on the assumption that the price of the competitor
will remain constant.
The model may be presented with the analytical tools
of the reaction functions of the duopolists. In Bertrand’s model
the reaction curves are derived from isoprofit maps which are
convex to the axes, on which we now measure the prices of the
duopolists. Each isoprofit curve for firm A shows the same
level of profit which would accrue to A from various levels of
prices charged by this firm and its rival. The isoprofit curve for
A is convex to its price axis (P A). This shape shows the fact
that firm A must lower its price up to a certain level (point e in
figure 4.2) to meet the cutting of price of its competitor, in
order to maintain the level of its profits at πA 2. However, after
that price level has been reached and if B continues to cut its
price, firm A will be unable to retain its profits, even if it keeps
its own price unchanged (at PAe). If, for example, firm B cuts
its price at PB , firm A will find itself at a lower isoprofit curve
(πA 1) which shows lower profits. The reduction of profits of A
is due to the fall in price, and the increase in output beyond the
optimal level of utilisation of the plant with the consequent
160
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
161
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
162
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
163
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 4.5
165
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
167
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 4.9
168
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Bertrand’s Model
Bertrand developed his duopoly model in 1883. His
model differs from Cournot’s in that he assumes that each
firm expects that the rival will keep its price constant,
irrespective of its own decision about pricing. Thus each firm
is faced by the same market demand, and aims at the
maximisation of its own profit on the assumption that the
price of the competitor will remain constant.
The model may be presented with the analytical
169
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
170
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
171
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
172
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
rival will keep its price fixed, and they never learn from past
experience which showed that rival did not in fact keep its
price constant. The industry profit could be increased if firms
recognised their past mistakes and abandoned the Bertrand
pattern of behaviour (figure 4.14).
Figure 4.14
173
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
174
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
175
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
price PM. Firm B, under the Cournot assumption that the rival
A will retain his quantity unchanged, considers that its
demand curve is CD and will attempt to maximise its profit
by producing one-half of this demand, that is, quantity XMB
(at which B’s MR = MC = 0). As a consequence the total
industry output is OB and the price falls to P. Now firm A
realises that its rival does in fact react to its actions, and
taking that into account decides to reduce its output to OA
which is one-half of OXM and equal to B’s output. The
industry output is thus OXM and price rises to the monopoly
level OPM. Firm B realises that this is the best for both of
them and so will keep its output the same at XMB = AXM.
Thus, by recognising their interdependence the firms reach
the monopoly solution. Under the assumption of our example
of equal costs (that is, costs = 0) the market will be shared
equally between A and B (clearly OA = AXM) ·
Chamberlin’s model is an advance over the previous
models in that it assumes that the firms are sophisticated
enough to realise their interdependence, and that it leads to a
stable equilibrium, which is the monopoly solution.
However, joint profit maximisation via non-collusive
action implies that firms have a good knowledge of the
market-demand curve and that they soon realise their
mistakes. That is, they somehow acquire knowledge of the
total-supply curve (i.e. of the individual costs of the rivals)
and hence they define the (monopoly) price which is best for
the group as a whole.
176
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
177
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 4.16
178
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
179
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
180
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
181
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
182
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
183
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 4.20
185
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
186
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
187
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
188
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
191
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
192
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
two firms. For this we assume that the MR1 and MR2 is
the demand curve of each firm and MR is its corresponding
MR curve. AC & MC are their identical costs curve where
the MC curve intersects the MR curve so that the profit
maximization output of each firm is OX1 and OX2. So that
OX1 + OX2= OXM, it is equally shared by the 2 firms as per
the quota agreement between them.
Another popular method of sharing the market is the
definition of the region in which each firm is allowed to sell.
In this case of geographical sharing of the market the price as
well as the style of the product may differ. There are many
examples of regional market-sharing cartels, some operating
at international levels. However, even a regional split of the
market is inherently unstable. The regional agreements are
often violated in practice, either by mistake or intentionally,
by the low-cost firms who have always the incentive to
expand their output by selling at a lower price openly
defined, or by secret price concessions, or by reaching
adjacent markets through advertising. It should be obvious
that the cartel models of collusive oligopoly are ‘closed’
models.
If entry is free, the inherent instability of cartels is
intensified: the behaviour of the entrant is not predictable
with certainty. It is not certain that a new firm will join the
cartel. On the contrary, if the profits of the cartel members
are lucrative and attract new firms in the industry, the
newcomer has a strong incentive not to join the cartel,
because in this way his demand curve will be more elastic,
193
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
194
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
The firm with the lowest cost will charge a lower price
(PA) and this price will be followed by the high-cost firm,
although at this price firm B (the follower) does not maximise
its profits. The follower would obtain a higher profit by
producing a lower output (XBe) and selling it at a higher price
(PB). However, it prefers to follow the leader, sacrificing some
of its profits in order to avoid a price war, which would
eliminate it if price fell sufficiently low as not to cover its
LAC. It should be stressed that for the leader to maximise his
profit price must be retained at the level PA and he should
sell XA. This implies that the follower must supply a quantity
195
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Although the price leadership model stresses the fact that the
leader sets the price and the follower adopts it, it is clear that
the firms must also enter a share-of-the-market agreement,
formally or informally, otherwise the follower could adopt the
price of the leader but produce a lower quantity than the level
required to maintain the price (set by the leader) in the
market, and thus push (indirectly, by not producing enough
output) the leader to a non- profit-maximising position. In this
respect the price follower is not completely passive: he may
be coerced to adopt the leader's price, but, unless tied by
a quota-share agreement (formal or informal) he can push the
leader to a non-maximising position.
2. The Dominant Firm Price Leadership Model :
196
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
197
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Figure 4.25
198
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
199
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
200
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
MODULE V
THEORY OF GAMES
Basic concepts
A different approach to the study of the oligopoly
problem is provided by the theory of games. The first
systematic attempt in this field is von Neumann’s and
Morgenstern’s Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour,
published in 1944. Since that time numerous economists
have developed models of oligopolistic behaviour based on the
theory of games.
The firm has various instruments or policy variables
with which it can pursue its goals. The most important are the
price, quantity and style of its products, advertising and other
selling activities, research and development expenditures,
channels for selling the product(s), and changes in the
number of products (discontinuation of an old product or
introduction of new ones).
1. Strategy:
201
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
202
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
B1 B2 B3 B4 B5 B6
A1 G11 G2 G13 G14 G15 G16
A2 G21 G2 G23 G24 G25 G26
A3 G31 G32 G33 G34 G35 G36
A4 G41 G42 G43 G44 G45 G46
A5 G51 G52 G53 G54 G55 G56
4.
203
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
204
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
bidding strategy.
Note that the fundamental difference between
cooperative and non cooperative games lies in the contracting
possibilities. In cooperative games, binding contracts are
possible; in non cooperative games, they are not. We will be
concerned mostly with non cooperative games. Whatever the
game, however, keep in mind the following key point about
strategic decision making: It is essential to understand your
opponent’s point of view and to deduce his or her likely
responses to your actions. This point may seem obvious—of
course, one must understand an opponent’s point of view. Yet
even in simple gaming situations, people often ignore or
misjudge opponents’ positions and the rational responses that
those positions imply.
Two Person Zero Sum Game
A. Certainty Model
The simplest model is a duopoly market in which
each duopolist attempts to maximise his market share. Given
this goal, whatever a firm gains (by increasing its share of
the market) the other firm loses (because of the decrease in its
share). Thus any gain of one rival is offset by the loss of the
other, and the net gain sums up to zero. Hence, the name ‘zero-
sum game’. The assumptions of the model are:
1. The firms have a given, well-defined goal. In our
particular example the goal is maximisation of the market
share.
205
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
206
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
these cells are shares, and the total market is shared between
the two firms. In general, in the two-person zero-sum game
we need not write both payoff matrices because of the nature
of the game: the goals are opposing, and, in our example,
the payoff table of Firm I contains indirectly information
about the payoff of Firm II. Still we start by showing both
tables, and then we show how the equilibrium solution can be
found from only the first payoff matrix.
Choice of strategy by Firm I
Table 5.2: Payoff Matrix of Firm I
B1 B2 B3 B4 B5
A1 0.10 0.20 0.15 0.30 0.25
A2 0.40 0.30 0.50 0.55 0.45
A3 0.35 0.25 0.20 0.40 0.50
A4 0.25 0.15 0.35 0.60 0.20
207
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
208
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
209
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
210
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
B. Uncertainty Model
The assumption that each firm knows with certainty
the exact value of the payoff of each strategy is unrealistic.
The most probable situation in the real business world is that
the firm, by adopting a certain strategy, may expect a range of
results for each counter-strategy of the rival, each result with
an associated probability. Thus the payoff matrix is constructed
so as to include the expected value of each payoff. The
expected value is the sum of the products of the possible
outcomes of a pair of strategies (adopted by the two firms)
each multiplied by its probability:
E(Gij) = g1iP1 + g2iP2 + · · · + gniPn
=
Where, gsi = the sth of the n possible outcomes of strategy i of
Firm I (given that Firm II has chosen strategy j)
Ps = the probability of the sth outcome of strategy i
For example, assume that Firm I chooses strategy A1
and Firm II reacts with strategy B1. This pair of simultaneous
strategies may yield the shares for Firm I each with a certain
probability, shown in the second column of table 5.5. Thus the
expected payoff of the pair of strategies A1 and B1 is
E(G11 ) = (0.00)(0.00) + (0.05)(0.05) + (0.15)(0.05) + · · · +
(0.95)(0.02) + (1)(0)
= 0·458
211
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Table 5.5
212
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
chooses the one with the highest value (the maximum among
the minima).
Firm II adopts the minimax strategy. It finds for each column
the maximum expected payoff, and among these maxima
Firm II chooses the one with the smallest value (the
minimum among the maxima).
Although the uncertainty zero-sum game seems simple, its
assumptions are quite stringent:
1. The firms maximise their expected payoffs.
2. The zero-sum game assumes that both firms assign the
same probability to each pair of payoffs; they make the
same judgement. This implies that the firms must have the
same information and the same objective criteria with which
to evaluate the probabilities of the different payoffs.
Otherwise the probability distribution of the payoffs will not
be objective.
3. The firms maximise their total utility, and the utility of
each payoff is proportional to the value assumed by the
payoff.
The above assumptions are clearly strong and
unrealistic. Furthermore, the basic condition of the zero-sum
game, that the ‘gain’ of one firm is equal to the ‘loss’ of the
other, is rarely met in the real business world. Usually the
‘gains’ are not ‘offset’ by equal ‘losses’. Only in the case of a
share goal, and in the rare case of extinction tactics, do we
have a zero-sum game. In most cases we have a non-zero-sum
game.
213
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Non-Zero-Sum Game
This model is illustrated with a duopolistic market in
which the firms aim at the maximisation of their profit. Their
products are close substitutes so that if their prices differ the
firm with the lower price will supply the largest part of the
market. It is assumed that the firms will use price as their
instrumental variable. For simplicity we assume that each
firm can charge two prices (either Rs. 3 or Rs. 5), that is,
there are two strategies open to each competitor. Each firm
has a different cost structure and the market size is affected
by the rivals’ combined action. Under these conditions the
payoff matrix of each firm is expressed in terms of levels of
profit, and the gains of one rival need not be (and in our
example are not) equal to the losses of the other. The payoff
matrices of the two firms are shown below in tables 5.6 and
5.7, and are subsequently combined in a single table (Table
5.8.).
The behavioural rule is the same for both firms: each
expects the worst from the rival. The choice of Firm I is a
maximin strategy. If Firm I sets the price of Rs.5 the
minimum gain is Rs.50; if it sets P = 3 its minimum profit is
Rs.80. Among these two minima the firm chooses the
maximum, that is, the preferred strategy by Firm I is P = 3.
The choice of Firm II is also a maximin strategy. If Firm II
charges a price of Rs.5 the worst it can expect is a profit of
Rs.60; if it charges a price of Rs.3 the minimum level of
profit is Rs.100. Among these minima the firm will choose the
maximum, that is, Firm II will choose the price of Rs.3.
214
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
P=5 P=3
Firm I’s P=5 ΠA =90 ΠA =50
strategies
P=3 ΠA =150 ΠA =80
PB=5 PB=3
Firm I’s
PA=5 ΠB =90 ΠB =50
strategies
PA=3 ΠB =150 ΠB =80
PB=5 PB=3
215
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
217
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
218
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Firm B
Advertise Don’t advertise
Firm A Advertise 10 5 15 0
Don’t advertise 6 8 10 2
220
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Firm B
Advertise Don’t advertise
Firm A Advertise 10 5 15 0
Don’t advertise 6 8 20 2
222
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
223
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
reveal their coins at the same time. If the coins match (i.e.,
both are heads or both are tails), Player A wins and receives a
dollar from Player B. If the coins do not match, Player B wins
and receives a dollar from Player A. The payoff matrix is
shown in Table 5.12.
Table 5.12: Matching Pennies
Player B
Heads Tails
Player A Heads 10 5 15 0
Tails 6 8 20 2
224
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
225
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Jim
Wrestling Opera
Joa n Wrestling 2 1 0 0
Opera 0 0 1 2
226
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Repeated Games
In oligopolistic markets, firms often find themselves
in a prisoners’ dilemma when making output or pricing
decisions. In the example of prisoners’ dilemma some
prisoners may have only one opportunity in life to confess or
not, most firms set output and price over and over again. In
real life, firms play repeated games: Actions are taken and
payoffs received over and over again. In repeated games,
strategies can become more complex. For example, with each
repetition of the prisoners’ dilemma, each firm can
develop a reputation about its own behaviour and can study
the behaviour of its competitors.
In a repeated game, the prisoners’ dilemma can have a
cooperative outcome. In most markets, the game is in fact
repeated over a long and uncertain length of time, and
managers have doubts about how “perfectly rationally” they
and their competitors operate. As a result, in some
industries, particularly those in which only a few firms
compete over a long period under stable demand and cost
conditions, cooperation prevails, even though no contractual
arrangements are made. In many other industries, however,
there is little or no cooperative behaviour. Sometimes
cooperation breaks down or never begins because there are
too many firms. More often, failure to cooperate is the result of
rapidly shifting demand or cost conditions. Uncertainties
about demand or costs make it difficult for the firms to
reach an implicit understanding of what cooperation should
entail.
227
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Sequential games
In most of the games both players move at the same
time. In the Cournot model of duopoly, for example, both
firms set output at the same time. In sequential games,
players move in turn. The Stackelberg model is an example of
a sequential game; one firm sets output before the other does.
There are many other examples: an advertising decision by
one firm and the response by its competitor; entry-deterring
investment by an incumbent firm and the decision whether to
enter the market by a potential competitor; or a new
government regulatory policy and the investment and output
response of the regulated firms. In a sequential game, the key
is to think through the possible actions and rational reactions of
each player.
As a simple example, let’s return to the product choice
problem. This problem involves two companies facing a
market in which two new variations of breakfast cereal can be
successfully introduced as long as each firm introduces only
one variation. This time, let’s change the payoff matrix
slightly. As Table 5.14 shows, the new sweet cereal will
inevitably be a better seller than the new crispy cereal,
earning a profit of 20 rather than 10 (perhaps because
consumers prefer sweet things to crispy things). Both new
cereals will still be profitable, however, as long as each is
introduced by only one firm.
228
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Firm 2
Crispy Sweet
Firm 1 Crispy -5 -5 10 20
Sweet 20 10 -5 -5
230
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
231
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
232
ECO1C01 - MICROECONOMICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS-I
Table 5.16
Modified Production Choice Problem
Small engines 0 6 0 0
Big engines 1 1 8 3
233