This Motion Relates To:: Plaintiffs
This Motion Relates To:: Plaintiffs
This Motion Relates To:: Plaintiffs
Plaintiffs,
GOOGLE LLC,
Defendant.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
ii
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 3 of 52
TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
Cases Page(s)
Ashcroft v. Iqbal,
556 U.S. 662 (2009) ................................................................................................................ 11
Bogan v. Hodgkins,
166 F.3d 509 (2d Cir. 1999).................................................................................................... 36
iii
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 4 of 52
iv
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 5 of 52
v
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 6 of 52
North Carolina Elec. Membership Corp. v. Carolina Power & Light Co.,
780 F. Supp. 322 (M.D.N.C. 1991) ........................................................................................ 14
vi
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 7 of 52
Smith v. McGinnis,
208 F.3d 13 (2d Cir. 2000)...................................................................................................... 13
vii
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 8 of 52
Statutes
15 U.S.C. § 2 ................................................................................................................................. 11
15 U.S.C. § 26 ............................................................................................................................... 12
Other Authorities
ix
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 10 of 52
TABLE OF ABBREVIATIONS
Term Definition
DA Dynamic Allocation
EB Exchange Bidding
TAC State Plaintiffs’ Third Amended Complaint, MDL ECF No. 195
x
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 11 of 52
Pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6), Defendant Google LLC (“Google”)
moves for an order dismissing the federal antitrust claims (Counts I through IV) of the Third
Amended Complaint (“TAC”) filed by the States of Texas, Alaska, Arkansas, Florida, Idaho,
Indiana, Louisiana, Mississippi, Missouri, Montana, Nevada, North Dakota, South Carolina, South
Dakota, and Utah, and the Commonwealths of Kentucky and Puerto Rico (together, “State
Plaintiffs”). Consistent with the stay of the state law claims (Counts V and VI) ordered at the
September 24, 2021 conference, see MDL ECF No. 142, at 10:13-22, Google does not currently
move to dismiss those claims and reserves all rights with respect to them.
INTRODUCTION
company to “win,” Google, over the past 10-plus years, has clearly been a successful competitor.
Google has achieved that success by developing effective digital display advertising tools (“ad
tech”) that have attracted publishers seeking to monetize their online advertising space and
advertisers seeking the best return on their advertising dollars. U.S. antitrust laws encourage,
reward, and protect that success—success earned through relentless innovation, early and
extensive investment in research and development, vigorous competition, and hard work—even if
Key to Google’s ad tech success has been how it considers the interests of publishers,
advertisers, and internet users. In doing so, Google seeks to generate the highest-quality matches
between publishers and advertisers and to provide the most relevant and safest digital advertising
experience for users. Google has strong incentives to pursue this balanced—and successful—
1
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 12 of 52
mission to organize the world’s information and make it universally accessible and useful, and is
State Plaintiffs respond to Google’s success by seeking to compel Google to share with its
competitors the fruits of its investments and innovation. They criticize Google for not designing
its products to better suit its rivals’ needs and for making improvements to those products that
leave its competitors too far behind. They see the “solution” to Google’s success as holding
Google back, rather than letting market forces urge its competitors forward. But U.S. antitrust law
does not permit State Plaintiffs’ proposed intervention into the free market. Instead, the Supreme
Court has recognized repeatedly that compelling rivals to deal with one another—much less to
share their competitive advantages—is at odds with the purpose of the Sherman Act. The kinds
of compulsory sharing and coerced cooperation sought by the State Plaintiffs undermine our
market economy’s incentives for investment and innovation, force courts to act as central
economic planners, and risk collusion among companies that ought to be left to compete. Given
the fundamentally misguided aim of State Plaintiffs’ complaint, it is not surprising that they are
In their search for a federal antitrust claim, State Plaintiffs reach back as far as 2009. The
TAC admits that much of that conduct is not only out-of-date but, at the time it occurred, was well-
publicized to and well-known by Google’s publisher and advertiser customers and its competitors.
Although these stale allegations consume much of the TAC, any claims based on them are barred
under the doctrine of laches. Moreover, State Plaintiffs admit that some of the alleged conduct
ceased years ago, making the injunction that State Plaintiffs seek unnecessary as a matter of fact
and unavailable as a matter of law. Additionally, the TAC’s allegations concerning conduct that
has not yet occurred are not ripe for adjudication now.
2
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 13 of 52
State Plaintiffs’ makeweight allegations concerning bygone conduct add no heft to their
federal antitrust claims, all of which should be dismissed for independent deficiencies.
The monopolization and attempted monopolization claims (Counts I and II) fail because
State Plaintiffs have not alleged facts plausibly showing that Google has engaged in
anticompetitive conduct. Despite amassing a lengthy collection of grievances, each one comes
down to a plea for Google to share its data or to design its products in ways that would help its
rivals. The Sherman Act requires no such thing. None of the conduct alleged in the TAC falls
into the narrow exception to the general rule that any firm may choose with whom it will deal, and
courts are rightly skeptical of challenges to how a company designs its own products, especially
State Plaintiffs’ claim that Google tied its ad server to its ad exchange (Count III) should
be dismissed because the TAC fails to allege facts showing that Google coerced the publishers that
use Google’s ad exchange to purchase its ad server as well. At its core, the tying claim is just
In Count IV, State Plaintiffs argue that it was unlawful for Google and Facebook to enter
into a Network Bidding Agreement (“NBA”) that enabled Facebook to bid against Google and
other buyers in Google’s auctions. While State Plaintiffs suggest that Facebook agreed not to
support header bidding when it signed the NBA, they have not (and cannot) cite any provision in
the NBA to that effect, and other provisions explicitly preserve Facebook’s freedom to deal with
Google’s competitors. Moreover, the TAC itself describes why it was in Facebook’s independent
self-interest to bid using Google’s tools and why it was in Google’s interest to have Facebook join
its auctions, regardless of whether Facebook also used header bidding. State Plaintiffs also claim
that the “Win Rate” provisions in the NBA were an illegal market allocation agreement. In doing
3
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 14 of 52
so, they mischaracterize the provisions (which do not promise Facebook anything), gloss over how
the NBA increased competition between Facebook and Google, concede that the “Win Rate”
provisions cover less than 7.2 percent of the alleged market (too little to have the requisite effect
on the market as a whole), and fail to allege that Facebook and Google have market power.
State Plaintiffs have tried four times to portray Google’s success, innovation, and
competitiveness as a federal antitrust violation. In this latest effort, rather than “winnow” or
“clarify” their claims, as they promised to do, State Plaintiffs double down on inapt labels, purple
prose, and flawed analogies, increasing the length of their already sprawling complaint by 68 pages
and 220 paragraphs. But merely adding to State Plaintiffs’ collection of grievances cannot disguise
the lack of a plausible cause of action under the Sherman Act. Google’s ad tech products benefit
publishers and advertisers, while helping keep the internet free and open for everyone. State
those rivals, but it also threatens to stifle the dynamism that drives Google and other firms to
deliver the products on which businesses and consumers depend every day.
Accordingly, and for all of the reasons set forth herein, Google respectfully requests that
the Court dismiss Counts I through IV of the TAC in their entirety and with prejudice.
Businesses have long used a variety of types of advertising—including print, radio, and
television—to inform and entice consumers. TAC ¶ 38. The internet revolutionized the
1
For purposes of this motion to dismiss, Google assumes the truth of the well-pleaded allegations in the TAC. Google
expects to contest many of those allegations, including (among many others) the alleged market definitions, should
the case proceed.
4
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 15 of 52
(digital ads presented in response to user queries) and “display advertising” (digital ads shown
elsewhere). Id. ¶¶ 38-39. Publishers of websites use the revenue from selling their display
advertising inventory to offer users free or subsidized content. Id. ¶ 511. In this way, display
advertising helps make the “free and open internet” possible and prevents internet content from
disappearing behind subscription paywalls that many users cannot afford. See id. ¶¶ 9, 511.
This lawsuit focuses primarily on a narrow sliver of display advertising (which is itself
only a part of the broader advertising landscape). Digital display advertising tools, or “ad tech,”
can be used to buy and sell many types of display advertising, including “[i]mage-based ads
presented to a user when a webpage is displayed on the open internet,” “shareable ads on social
media,” and “video ads shown before or during video content.” TAC ¶ 38. But State Plaintiffs
concentrate on image-based display ads for what they call the “open internet” and exclude display
ads sold by Google’s largest competitors (including the social media site Facebook and the e-
commerce site Amazon), the in-app ads that appear in smartphone applications, and other types of
digital advertising. Id.; see also id. ¶¶ 15, 39, 41, 173-77, 191.
State Plaintiffs allege that there are three links in the ad tech chain connecting advertisers
to publishers. At one end of the chain, they allege that advertisers use ad buying tools to purchase
publisher “inventory”—the space on websites where ads are shown. These ad buying tools let
advertisers specify how much they are willing to pay for inventory and the audiences that they
want their ads to reach. TAC ¶ 72. Some ad buying tools are demand-side platforms (“DSPs”)
that “offer robust and complex bidding and trading options” for advertisers. Id. ¶ 73. DSPs include
Google’s DV360, as well as competing offerings from The Trade Desk and Amazon. Id. ¶¶ 71,
73, 76, 204. Other ad buying tools, like Google Ads, provide an “easy to use” interface for
advertisers that do not require all the features of a DSP. Id. ¶¶ 168-69. State Plaintiffs allege that
5
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 16 of 52
some advertisers may use only one buying tool, but they also concede that others “multi-home”—
that is, some advertisers use multiple ad buying tools in parallel. See id. ¶ 192.
At the other end of the chain, State Plaintiffs allege that publishers use ad servers to
“manage and sell their web display inventory” by specifying where advertisers can purchase that
inventory and the minimum prices that publishers will accept for it, among other functions. TAC
¶ 93; see also id. ¶¶ 52, 268. According to the TAC, publisher ad servers manage both the
inventory that publishers sell to advertisers with which they have direct relationships and the
inventory that publishers sell indirectly through “centralized electronic trading venues” that match
them with advertisers. See id. ¶¶ 42-43, 53. Some publishers turn to Google or other ad tech
providers for ad serving functionality, but other publishers have built their own ad servers. Id.
¶¶ 97, 101. Google’s publisher ad server is known as DFP. Id. ¶ 97.2 Competing ad servers
In the middle, State Plaintiffs allege that ad exchanges are the links that typically connect
advertisers’ buying tools and publishers’ ad servers. TAC ¶ 128. Ad exchanges conduct real-time
auctions in which advertisers (through ad buying tools) bid on publisher inventory. Id. ¶ 58.
Google’s ad exchange is known as AdX; rival ad exchanges include Rubicon, Xandr, and Index
Exchange. Id. ¶ 153. Like ad exchanges, ad networks also provide an electronic forum where
With the proliferation of smartphones, specialized tools have emerged to facilitate app
developers’ sale of ad space within their apps (“in-app inventory”). TAC ¶ 15. State Plaintiffs
allege that, like web publishers using ad servers, app developers use in-app mediation tools to
2
State Plaintiffs allege that Google offers publisher ad server functionality as part of a “product” now called “Google
Ad Manager” (“GAM”), TAC ¶ 97, and GAM also includes ad exchange functionality (formerly known as “AdX”).
Because the TAC uses the older names (“DFP” and “AdX”), this motion does the same.
6
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 17 of 52
manage and sell the ads displayed in their mobile apps. Id. ¶¶ 216-17. According to the TAC,
Google offers two mediation tools for app developers—AdMob and GAM. Id. ¶ 217. Developers
can also use mediation tools from competitors like MoPub, AppLovin, ironSource, Unity, and
others, or they may elect not to use any mediation tool. Id. ¶¶ 217, 228. And like ad networks for
web-based ads, in-app networks allegedly act as intermediaries that facilitate sales of in-app
inventory. Id. ¶¶ 232-33. Google’s in-app network is known as the AdMob network. Id. ¶ 232.
Facebook offers its own Facebook Audience Network (“FAN”), and Unity, ironSource, Vungle,
Google’s products interoperate with one another and with products offered by
competitors. For example, Google’s ad buying tools (DV360 and Google Ads) allow advertisers
to submit bids into third-party exchanges as well as Google’s exchange (AdX). TAC ¶¶ 250, 395,
397. Google’s ad server (DFP) allows publishers to connect to third-party exchanges in addition
to AdX. Id. ¶ 366. Likewise, publisher ad servers other than DFP can offer their inventory through
AdX, see id. ¶¶ 246-47, 251, and AdX accepts bids from buyers other than DV360 and Google
The ad tech industry has evolved—and continues to evolve—and Google has evolved
along with it. According to the TAC, before 2009, publisher inventory that did not sell through
directly negotiated deals was generally relegated to a “waterfall” process in which ad servers
contacted (or “called”) ad networks and exchanges one-by-one until the inventory was sold. TAC
¶¶ 268, 270. Because the waterfall made calls in a fixed sequence and “call[ed] each subsequent
exchange only if all prior higher-ranked exchanges failed to clear the impression,” id. ¶ 268, a
buyer could win an impression even if another buyer (later in the sequence) would pay more. As
7
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 18 of 52
a result, the waterfall failed to maximize publisher revenue and to allow advertisers who valued
Google developed programs to reduce these inefficiencies. State Plaintiffs allege that, in
2010, Google introduced Dynamic Allocation, a DFP innovation that allowed the winning bidder
in an AdX auction to compete against winning bidders from other exchanges and ad networks.
TAC ¶ 271. While State Plaintiffs allege that Dynamic Allocation gave Google’s AdX a so-called
“last look” or a “right of first refusal,” they concede that it allowed AdX buyers to win only if they
submitted higher bids than publishers would have received through the waterfall. Id. ¶¶ 271, 377.
When the waterfall generated higher returns, the AdX buyer would lose. By 2014, Google
allegedly expanded this program with Enhanced Dynamic Allocation, adding “high-value
impressions” to the “pool of publishers’ inventory” for which buyers could compete. Id. ¶¶ 282,
284.
For many years, AdX ran as a second-price auction. See TAC ¶ 300. In that type of
auction, the winning bidder does not pay its own bid, but instead pays the higher of either the
second-highest bid or the reserve price (“price floor”), and the auction will not clear unless there
is at least one bid above the price floor. See id. ¶¶ 299, 302. Between 2014 and 2015, Google
developed optimizations that could allow more AdX auctions to clear by adjusting Google’s fees,
see id. ¶ 318 (Dynamic Revenue Share), and that could increase publisher revenues by adjusting
Over time, some publishers began to use “header bidding,” a technology that allowed
them to run real-time auctions among multiple exchanges. TAC ¶ 22. Although DFP was not
designed to support header bidding, publishers could use “‘line items’ . . . an existing feature in
DFP,” id. ¶ 389, to replicate “a live, competitive bid coming in from a header bidding exchange,”
8
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 19 of 52
id. ¶ 390. Google’s competitive response to header bidding’s “wild[] popular[ity]” was Exchange
Bidding, id. ¶¶ 355, 366, a new feature that allowed publishers to “route their inventory to more
than one exchange at a time to mimic the multi-exchange competition fostered by header bidding,”
id. ¶ 366. Exchange Bidding was later renamed Open Bidding when Google improved it to allow
ad networks as well as ad exchanges to compete in real time for publisher inventory. Id. ¶ 425.
In 2018, Facebook and Google entered a Network Bidding Agreement (the “NBA”) that
enabled Facebook’s network, FAN, to compete in Open Bidding against Google and other
exchanges and networks. TAC ¶¶ 425, 436, 446. Although the NBA covered both web and in-
app inventory, id. ¶ 413, Facebook decided to buy only in-app inventory in Open Bidding, id.
¶ 437. FAN is only one of the many participants in Open Bidding, id. ¶ 425, and Open Bidding is
only one of the many places where FAN buys in-app inventory, id. ¶ 446.
As with AdX and DFP, Google also has introduced a number of product improvements
for ad buying tools. For example, Google helped advertisers using Google Ads win more
impressions by optimizing the bids submitted on their behalf into the AdX auction. TAC ¶¶ 303,
306-07 (Project Bernanke). Google protected advertisers using DV360 from “overpaying for an
impression” by adjusting bids made on their behalf into exchanges that were not running true
second-price auctions. Id. ¶ 400 (Project Poirot). And Google helped advertisers avoid bidding
against themselves for the same impression with an optimization that could “identify . . . the same
In 2019, Google’s AdX migrated to a first-price auction, TAC ¶ 346, allegedly matching
the type of auctions used by header bidding exchanges, id. ¶ 402.3 Google made other changes
around the same time, including creating a “unified auction” in which directly-negotiated offers
3
In a first-price auction, the winner “pays the amount of their own winning bid.” TAC ¶ 299.
9
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 20 of 52
from advertisers competed against offers that advertisers submitted through AdX and through the
exchanges and networks that participated in Open Bidding, id. ¶ 379, thus eliminating what State
Plaintiffs call the “last look” “advantage,” id. ¶¶ 381-82. Google also implemented new pricing
rules so that all exchanges and buyers would be treated equally, id. ¶ 460, and retired features
designed for second-price auctions, including Dynamic Revenue Share, see id. heading VII.C.2.
Some changes in the ad tech industry were designed to strengthen protections for user
privacy. TAC ¶¶ 480, 488. According to State Plaintiffs, a “cookie-based user ID[]” was
historically the primary way for ad servers to identify the users visiting a publisher’s site. Id.
¶ 172; see also id. ¶¶ 51, 476. Google’s DFP allegedly began encrypting the cookie-based user
IDs that it shared with publishers as far back as 2009, id. ¶ 257, with Google “publicly tout[ing]”
the change “in terms of protecting user privacy,” id. ¶ 263. Certain browsers, like Apple’s Safari
and browsers on Apple devices, block those cookies altogether. Id. ¶ 433. “As regulatory scrutiny
around Google and other Big Tech firms increased globally,” id. ¶ 473, Google allegedly planned
to do the same in Google’s Chrome browser “in a set of proposals that Google has dubbed ‘Privacy
Sandbox,’” id. ¶ 474; see also id. ¶ 480. Google, however, has deferred implementation of the
proposals as it gathers more input from stakeholders. See id. ¶¶ 470, 474.
In 2019, around when Google was moving to a first-price auction, a group of states led
by Texas Attorney General Ken Paxton began investigating Google’s ad tech business. See MDL
ECF No. 55, at 2. In response to civil investigative demands, Google gave the Texas Office of the
Attorney General (“OAG”) access to hundreds of thousands of internal Google documents, and
the Texas OAG collected additional evidence from dozens of third parties. See id.
On December 16, 2020, Texas and nine other states filed suit in the U.S. District Court
for the Eastern District of Texas. Texas ECF No. 1. Three months later, in March 2021, they filed
10
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 21 of 52
an Amended Complaint that substantially revised their allegations and added four states and Puerto
Rico as plaintiffs. Texas ECF No. 77. On August 10, 2021, the Judicial Panel on Multidistrict
Litigation transferred this case and 18 private cases to this Court for coordinated or consolidated
proceedings. MDL ECF No. 1. Soon thereafter, State Plaintiffs again sought leave to amend their
pleadings, this time to add two more states as plaintiffs and to abandon their damages claims under
federal antitrust law. Texas ECF No. 136. And in November 2021, State Plaintiffs lodged the
fourth iteration of their complaint, a document that has now ballooned to 702 paragraphs, despite
In the TAC, State Plaintiffs seek only injunctive relief for alleged violations of Sections
1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2. TAC ¶ 683. They claim that Google has
monopolized or attempted to monopolize various markets (Counts I and II), tied its ad server to its
ad exchange (Count III), and entered into an unlawful agreement with Facebook (Count IV).
LEGAL STANDARD
To survive a motion to dismiss under Rule 12(b)(6), “a complaint must contain sufficient
factual matter, accepted as true, to ‘state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.’” Ashcroft
v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678 (2009) (quoting Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 570 (2007)).
To do so, the TAC must make factual allegations sufficient to “raise a reasonable expectation that
discovery will reveal evidence,” Twombly, 550 U.S. at 556, that would “allow[] the court to draw
the reasonable inference that the defendant is liable,” Iqbal, 556 U.S. at 678. It is “a plaintiff’s
obligation to provide the ‘grounds’ of his ‘entitle[ment] to relief,’” which “requires more than
labels and conclusions, and a formulaic recitation of the elements of a cause of action will not do.”
Twombly, 550 U.S. at 555 (alteration in original) (citations omitted). The Court should treat the
allegations in the TAC as true, but it is “not required to credit conclusory allegations or legal
conclusions couched as factual allegations.” Rothstein v. UBS AG, 708 F.3d 82, 94 (2d Cir. 2013).
11
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 22 of 52
ARGUMENT
to try to dredge up a claim against Google. Having abandoned claims for damages under federal
law, see Texas ECF No. 136, at 2, State Plaintiffs seek only injunctive relief under Section 16 of
the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 26; see also TAC ¶¶ 31, 33, 683. But the doctrine of laches precludes
entry of an injunction based on much of the conduct described in Counts I, II, and III because that
conduct began more than four years before the filing of State Plaintiffs’ original complaint, in
some cases more than a decade before. In addition, State Plaintiffs concede that some of the
alleged conduct has already ceased and fail to provide any basis for seeking to enjoin completed
conduct. Finally, State Plaintiffs fail to show that their Privacy Sandbox claims are ripe because
their allegations refer only to proposals that are still subject to change. These are not mere
technicalities, but symptoms of even deeper flaws in State Plaintiffs’ case. See infra Parts II-IV.
A. The Doctrine of Laches Bars Claims Based on Conduct That Began Before
December 2016.
“Laches may be decided on the pleadings if unreasonable delay and prejudice are clear on
the face of the complaint.” Madison Square Garden, L.P. v. Nat’l Hockey League, 2008 WL
4547518, at *10 (S.D.N.Y. Oct. 10, 2008). In assessing the unreasonableness of delay in antitrust
cases, courts look to the Clayton Act’s four-year statute of limitation on damages actions as a
guideline for computing the laches period. See, e.g., id.; New York v. Facebook, Inc., 2021 WL
2643724, at *17, *20-22 (D.D.C. June 28, 2021); see also 15 U.S.C. § 15b. And “once the
analogous statute has run, a presumption of laches will apply and plaintiff must show why the
laches defense ought not be applied in the case.” Conopco, Inc. v. Campbell Soup Co., 95 F.3d
187, 191 (2d Cir. 1996). Accordingly, laches presumptively bars claims based on conduct that
12
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 23 of 52
began before December 16, 2016 (i.e., four years before State Plaintiffs filed their original
Much of the conduct identified in Counts I, II, and III allegedly began well before
State Plaintiffs have failed to plead the “‘rare and exceptional circumstances’” required to
apply the doctrine of equitable tolling to any of this conduct. See Levy v. BASF Metals Ltd., 2017
WL 2533501, at *8 (S.D.N.Y. June 9, 2017) (quoting Smith v. McGinnis, 208 F.3d 13, 17 (2d Cir.
2000)), aff’d, 917 F.3d 106 (2d Cir. 2019). Indeed, their own allegations describe practices that
were either publicly announced or of which advertisers and publishers necessarily must have been
aware. See TAC ¶¶ 257-58, 263 (advertisers “unable to receive and utilize . . . raw user IDs” after
2009, with Google “publicly tout[ing]” the change); id. ¶ 246 (only publishers that licensed
Google’s ad server would “receive live, competitive bids from its exchange” from 2010); id. ¶ 291
(Google “coaxed” publishers into leaving Enhanced Dynamic Allocation turned on); id. ¶ 327
(“Google told publishers it was launching” Dynamic Revenue Share in the summer of 2016); id.
¶ 343 (“Google announced it was launching” Reserve Price Optimization in May 2016).
4
Laches applies to State Plaintiffs’ suit under Section 16 of the Clayton Act, just as it does to private plaintiff actions.
See Facebook, 2021 WL 2643724, at *20-22; see also TAC ¶ 31.
13
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 24 of 52
For a “continuing violation” theory to apply, State Plaintiffs would need to plead some
“new and independent act that is not merely a reaffirmation of a previous act” and which “must
inflict new and accumulating injury.” Madison Square Garden, 2008 WL 4547518, at *10; see
also In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 261 F. Supp. 2d 188, 228 (E.D.N.Y. 2003)
(distinguishing independent predicate acts committed during the limitations period from mere
reaffirmations of an initial act). But for each of the practices listed above, the TAC fails to allege
facts showing that Google did anything other than continue to engage in the same conduct that
began more than four years before this case was filed. See Varner v. Peterson Farms, 371 F.3d
1011, 1020 (8th Cir. 2004) (dismissing tying claim where plaintiffs “failed to allege any new overt
acts, other than enforcement of the initial contracts, that would toll the four-year statutes of
limitations”); Vitale v. Marlborough Gallery, 1994 WL 654494, at *5 (S.D.N.Y. July 5, 1994) (“If
an initial refusal to deal with a party is final, the statute of limitations begins to run and does not
restart when the plaintiff makes subsequent unsuccessful efforts to deal with the defendant.”). And
while private plaintiffs seeking to recover overcharge damages may sometimes bring claims more
than four years after the challenged conduct began (for overcharges they paid during the limitations
period), that is only when their cause of action did not “accrue” until they paid the overcharge.
See Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 295-96 (2d Cir. 1979). By contrast,
State Plaintiffs have dropped their federal damages claims, so their cause of action accrued when
5
See also US Airways, Inc. v. Sabre Holdings Corp., 938 F.3d 43, 69 (2d Cir. 2019) (concluding that “each
supracompetitive price charged to US Airways by Sabre pursuant to the 2006 contract was not an overt act of its own,
but a manifestation of the prior overt act of entering into the 2006 contract”); North Carolina Elec. Membership Corp.
v. Carolina Power & Light Co., 780 F. Supp. 322, 330-31 (M.D.N.C. 1991) (distinguishing Berkey Photo because
plaintiffs were rivals alleging “[e]xclusion from [the] market” and were “injured at the time anticompetitive conduct
occur[ed]” (internal quotation marks omitted)).
14
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 25 of 52
In light of State Plaintiffs’ unreasonable delay and the prejudice to Google from allowing
it to invest in continually improving its digital advertising tools over the past decade, only to have
some of the core functionality of those tools challenged now, Counts I and II should be dismissed
to the extent that they are based on the allegations identified above, and Count III should be
To obtain injunctive relief on a federal antitrust claim, State Plaintiffs must “demonstrate
likely to continue or recur.” Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Rsch., Inc., 395 U.S. 100, 130 (1969).
The TAC concedes that Dynamic Allocation and Dynamic Revenue Share ceased in 2019. TAC
heading VII.B.2 (alleging period of 2010 to 2019 for Dynamic Allocation), heading VII.C.2
(alleging period of 2014 to 2019 for Dynamic Revenue Share), ¶¶ 281, 330 (describing programs’
alleged effects in the past tense). And there are no allegations that Google is likely to re-institute
either program. In the absence of any such allegations, all claims based on those programs should
be dismissed. See In re DDAVP Indirect Purchaser Antitrust Litig., 903 F. Supp. 2d 198, 210
(S.D.N.Y. 2012) (“[C]laims for an injunction fail where they do not demonstrate a threat of future
injury”); see also Facebook, 2021 WL 2643724, at *14 (dismissing claim for injunctive relief
where defendant already “discontinued the relevant Platform policies”); New York v. Cedar Park
Concrete Corp., 1997 WL 306909, at *17 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 21, 1997) (no injunctive relief where
“‘violation of the antitrust laws ha[s] terminated’” and “‘the threat to [plaintiff] inherent in the
conduct’ has ceased” (alterations in original)), aff’d in part on other grounds sub nom. New York
15
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 26 of 52
State Plaintiffs’ claims concerning Privacy Sandbox relate not to ongoing conduct, but
instead to alleged “proposals” for the future. See TAC ¶ 474. An Article III court, however,
“cannot entertain a claim which is based upon contingent future events that may not occur as
anticipated, or indeed may not occur at all,” and “when resolution of an issue turns on whether
there are nebulous future events so contingent in nature that there is no certainty they will ever
occur, the case is not ripe for adjudication.” Thomas v. City of New York, 143 F.3d 31, 34 (2d Cir.
1998) (internal quotation marks and citations omitted). The vagueness of State Plaintiffs’
allegations—that Google will offer publishers and advertisers unspecified “new and alternative
tracking mechanisms” that will somehow “exclude competition,” TAC ¶ 474—reflects their
uncertainty about if or how Privacy Sandbox will be implemented. Until those details come into
focus, it will be “difficult to predict” the effects of Privacy Sandbox, and any claims based on that
program should be dismissed. See Volvo N. Am. Corp. v. Men’s Int’l Prof’l Tennis Council, 857
F.2d 55, 64-65 (2d Cir. 1988) (dismissing claims based on certain proposed rules when it was
should be dismissed in their entirety for failing to allege that Google engaged in any
anticompetitive conduct. “To safeguard the incentive to innovate, the possession of monopoly
conduct.” Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407
(2004); see also Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 456 (1993) (requiring showing
16
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 27 of 52
anticompetitive if it occurs “without a legitimate business purpose” and “makes sense only because
it eliminates competition.” In re Adderall XR Antitrust Litig., 754 F.3d 128, 133 (2d Cir. 2014)
(internal quotation marks omitted). Although the TAC describes a variety of practices, all of State
Plaintiffs’ allegations reduce to claims that Google must share data with others or design its
products in ways that help its rivals. The Sherman Act requires neither.
As “a general matter, the Sherman Act ‘does not restrict the long recognized right of [a]
trader or manufacturer engaged in an entirely private business, freely to exercise his own
independent discretion as to parties with whom he will deal.’” Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408 (quoting
United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300, 307 (1919)); see also In re Elevator Antitrust Litig.,
502 F.3d 47, 52 (2d Cir. 2007) (recognizing that “a refusal to deal with competitors does not
typically violate § 2”). The Supreme Court has explained that “[c]ompelling . . . firms to share the
source of their advantage is in some tension with the underlying purpose of antitrust law” because
it “may lessen the incentive for the monopolist, the rival, or both to invest in . . . economically
beneficial facilities”; courts are “ill suited” to act as “central planners” enforcing required dealing;
and compelling cooperation between competitors “may facilitate the supreme evil of antitrust:
collusion.” Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407-08. For all of these reasons, firms generally have no duty to
extend a helping hand to their rivals. See Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 731 F.3d 1064, 1074
(10th Cir. 2013) (Gorsuch, J.) (“Even a monopolist generally has no duty to share (or continue to
share) its intellectual or physical property with a rival.”); Olympia Equip. Leasing Co. v. W. Union
Tel. Co., 797 F.2d 370, 375-76 (7th Cir. 1986) (Posner, J.) (“Today it is clear that a firm with
lawful monopoly power has no general duty to help its competitors” and thus no duty “to extend
a helping hand to new entrants . . . [or] help [rivals] . . . survive or expand.”); see also In re Google
17
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 28 of 52
Digital Advert. Antitrust Litig., 2021 WL 2021990, at *5 (N.D. Cal. May 13, 2021) (expressing
“serious concerns that some . . . allegations rely on a ‘duty to deal’ theory of antitrust”).
Courts have recognized a “limited exception,” grounded in Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen
Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985), where “‘[t]he unilateral termination of a voluntary
(and thus presumably profitable) course of dealing suggest[s] a willingness to forsake short-term
profits to achieve an anticompetitive end.’” In re Elevator Antitrust Litig., 502 F.3d at 53 (quoting
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 409). State Plaintiffs suggest that the Aspen Skiing exception applies to two
ways in which Google allegedly refuses to share data. First, they claim that, since 2009, Google
has encrypted certain user IDs that it previously provided to publishers and advertisers without
encryption. TAC ¶¶ 257-58. Second, they assert that Google redacts certain data from publisher
auction reports and splits the data in ways that make it less useful for publishers. Id. ¶¶ 387-88.
Neither set of allegations fits within the Aspen Skiing exception. The TAC alleges no facts
showing that Google sacrificed profits by encrypting user IDs or redacting auction reports. To the
contrary, the TAC alleges that Google hoped to bring more “spend . . . toward Google’s buying
tools and exchange.” TAC ¶ 266; see In re Adderall XR Antitrust Litig., 754 F.3d at 134-35
(affirming dismissal where plaintiff failed to allege facts suggesting defendant sacrificed short-
term profits); IBM v. Platform Sols., Inc., 658 F. Supp. 2d 603, 613-14 (S.D.N.Y. 2009)
(concluding that refusal to deal did “not constitute anticompetitive conduct” when plaintiff failed
In addition, the allegations concerning encrypted user IDs and redacted reports involve
387, and thus do not present the same situation as Aspen Skiing, a case “at or near the “outer
boundary of § 2 liability.” Trinko, 540 U.S. at 409; see also MiniFrame Ltd. v. Microsoft Corp.,
18
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 29 of 52
551 F. App’x 1, 2 (2d Cir. 2013) (affirming dismissal where defendant allegedly refused to deal
with customers, not competitors); RxUSA Wholesale, Inc. v. Alcon Labs., Inc., 661 F. Supp. 2d
218, 228-29 (E.D.N.Y. 2009) (only prior dealing with rivals can create a duty to deal), aff’d, 391
State Plaintiffs claim that the alleged refusals to deal with customers affect Google’s
competitors because they leave Google with an “information advantage in a manner that adversely
harms less informed parties”—a phenomenon they term “adverse selection.” See TAC ¶ 260; see
also, e.g., id. ¶¶ 276, 281, 316, 344, 464, 514. But the TAC contains no allegations that Google
ever previously shared its supposed “information advantages” with rivals, and “because plaintiffs
do not allege that defendants terminated any prior course of dealing—the sole exception to the
broad right of a firm to refuse to deal with its competitors—the allegations are insufficient to state
a unilateral-monopolization claim.” See In re Elevator Antitrust Litig., 502 F.3d at 52; see also
FTC v. Facebook, Inc., 2021 WL 2643627, at *17 (D.D.C. June 28, 2021) (“Facebook’s general
policy of withholding . . . access from competitors . . . was plainly lawful to the extent it covered
rivals with which it had no previous, voluntary course of dealing.”).6 Moreover, to the extent that
State Plaintiffs challenge Google’s own use of “information . . . to accurately predict the amount
to bid,” TAC ¶ 381, Google’s use of “data collection . . . [to] its competitive advantage does not
*8 (N.D. Cal. Jan. 28, 2019); see also Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263,
276 (2d Cir. 1979) (an integrated business must be allowed “to seek the competitive advantages
6
State Plaintiffs complain that Google shares “Minimum Bid to Win” data with rival exchanges using Exchange
Bidding and assert that rival exchanges using header bidding do not receive the same data. See TAC ¶ 380. But State
Plaintiffs cannot show that limiting the availability of this data is anticompetitive because they do not allege that
Google previously provided it to header bidding exchanges.
19
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 30 of 52
The bulk of the conduct challenged in the TAC concerns ways in which Google designed
its own products, but “any firm, even a monopolist, may generally bring its products to market
whenever and however it chooses.” Berkey Photo, 603 F.2d at 286; see also Allied Orthopedic
Appliances Inc. v. Tyco Health Care Grp. LP, 592 F.3d 991, 999 (9th Cir. 2010) (“[A] monopolist
has ‘the right to redesign its products to make them more attractive to buyers.’” (quoting Foremost
Pro Color, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 703 F.2d 534, 545 (9th Cir. 1983))). That principle reflects
“the undesirability of having courts oversee product design” and is grounded in judicial recognition
that “any dampening of technological innovation would be at cross-purposes with antitrust law.”
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 147 F.3d 935, 948 (D.C. Cir. 1998). Because “product
innovation generally benefits consumers,” courts are “very skeptical about claims that competition
has been harmed by . . . product design changes,” and “neither product withdrawal nor product
improvement alone is anticompetitive.” New York ex rel. Schneiderman v. Actavis PLC, 787 F.3d
638, 652, 653-54 (2d Cir. 2015) (internal quotation marks and citation omitted); see also Berkey
Photo, 603 F.2d at 286 (“The attempt to develop superior products is . . . an essential element of
lawful competition.”).
unless a challenged product design—combined with some other associated conduct—had “the
overall effect of . . . coerc[ing] consumers rather than persuad[ing] them on the merits.” Actavis,
787 F.3d at 654. Product design changes are not coercive as long as alternatives to the redesigned
product remain available and consumers are free to use them. See, e.g., Berkey Photo, 603 F.2d at
287 (no coercion because “Kodak did not remove any other films from the market when it
introduced the new one”); Allied Orthopedic, 592 F.3d at 1002 (no coercion where alternatives
existed and rivals were “effectively competing”); Walgreen Co. v. AstraZeneca Pharms. L.P., 534
20
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 31 of 52
F. Supp. 2d 146, 151-52 (D.D.C. 2008) (no coercion where redesign “added choices” and rivals
remained “free to compete”); Liveuniverse, Inc. v. Myspace, Inc., 2007 WL 6865852, at *14 (C.D.
Cal. June 4, 2007) (no coercion because design change “in no way prevents consumers from
accessing the [rival] site”), aff’d, 304 F. App’x 554 (9th Cir. 2008). Because the TAC fails to
allege that any of the challenged design changes involved the required coercion, the
Dynamic Allocation. State Plaintiffs assail Dynamic Allocation (“DA”), which they claim
to be a 2010 change to DFP that “impart[ed] a substantial new . . . advantage to [Google’s] own
AdX exchange: a right of first refusal,” or what some called a “Last Look.” TAC ¶¶ 271, 377.
But even if the claim were timely, see supra Part I.A-B, the TAC makes clear that DA did not
prevent publishers from transacting with other exchanges. DA allowed AdX to win an impression
Allocation (“EDA”) was “a new decisioning logic that Google incorporated into DFP” in 2014 to
“open[] up a new additional pool of publishers’ inventory to exactly one exchange: AdX.” TAC
¶ 284; see also id. ¶ 282. Any such claim is barred by laches. See supra Part I.A. Even so, the
allegations make clear that Google did not reduce publishers’ options, but instead offered
publishers a new opportunity to allow DFP and AdX to handle more of their inventory. Google
had no obligation to design EDA to help its competitors win more of that business. See Charych
v. Siriusware, Inc., 790 F. App’x 299, 302 (2d Cir. 2019) (refusal to design compatible product
was not anticompetitive); Christy Sports, LLC v. Deer Valley Resort Co., 555 F.3d 1188, 1196
(10th Cir. 2009) (“[I]it is not anticompetitive to refuse to grant access to competitors.”); Bayou
21
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 32 of 52
Bottling, Inc. v. Dr Pepper Co., 725 F.2d 300, 304 (5th Cir. 1984) (concluding that antitrust laws
did not require defendant to stock its vending machines with competitor’s products).
publishers and advertisers to use its products by manipulating auctions with Project Bernanke,
Dynamic Revenue Share (“DRS”), and Reserve Price Optimization (“RPO”), TAC ¶ 297; see also
id. ¶¶ 298-351, State Plaintiffs fail to allege facts that would establish such coercion. For instance,
the TAC does not claim that any of those programs prevented publishers or advertisers from using
rival exchanges or ad buying tools. Rather than coercion, the TAC describes how the programs
● Project Bernanke was intended to help Google Ads advertisers win more auctions,
id. ¶ 308, and sometimes allowed them to pay less for impressions, id. ¶ 304;
● DRS helped publishers make more money in some AdX auctions by “lower[ing]
Google’s exchange fee,” id. ¶ 320; and
● RPO helped publishers achieve “increased price[s]” for their inventory on AdX
auctions, id. ¶ 336.
Even if Google delivered these benefits using “inside information,” see id. ¶¶ 297, 307, 316, 337,
344, the antitrust laws do not require Google to share its competitive advantages with rivals, see
supra Part II.A. In addition, the claims based on DRS and RPO are barred by laches, and no
injunction can address DRS because that program has already concluded. See supra Part I.A-B.
Exchange Bidding. The TAC alleges that Google introduced Exchange Bidding (“EB”)
in April 2016 in response to a “threat from header bidding,” TAC ¶ 366, but introducing new
products generally does not violate antitrust law. See Berkey Photo, 603 F.2d at 286 (explaining
that plaintiff “cannot complain of a product introduction Simpliciter” because “any firm . . . may
generally bring its products to market whenever and however it chooses”). And the TAC does not
allege facts showing that introducing EB coerced publishers to use Google’s products or deprived
22
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 33 of 52
them of any options. To the contrary, it concedes that EB gave publishers an additional way of
transacting on rival exchanges by allowing them to “select which non-Google exchanges to route
their impressions to.” See TAC ¶ 370; see also id. ¶ 366 (EB “permit[ted] non-Google exchanges
Although State Plaintiffs contend that Google should have designed EB to make it even
easier for rivals to compete, antitrust law does not require Google to assist its competitors at all,
much less to help competitors identify Google’s customers, id. ¶ 367, to create a tool that makes it
easier for customers to bypass Google entirely, id. ¶ 370, to forego using information that Google
has lawfully obtained, id. ¶ 371, or to build and maintain systems benefitting competitors free of
charge, id. ¶ 369. See Charych, 790 F. App’x at 302 (“[D]efendants were under no obligation to
develop an interface that was compatible with plaintiffs’ product.”); Novell, 731 F.3d at 1072 (no
duty to “lend smaller rivals a helping hand”); Allied Orthopedic, 592 F.3d at 1002 (“no duty to
help . . . competitors survive or expand when introducing an improved product design”). And once
again, laches bars any claims based on EB in any event. See supra Part I.A.
Capping Line Items. State Plaintiffs allege that Google “capp[ed] publishers[’] use of
‘line items’” in ways that made it more difficult for header bidding “to capture a live, competitive
bid.” TAC ¶¶ 389-90. These allegations fail to allege anticompetitive conduct for two reasons.
First, as just explained, Google had no obligation to design its products in ways that help header
bidding work better. Second, the TAC fails to allege that Google changed its “existing” approach
to line items. Id. ¶ 389. To the contrary, it admits that Google elected to “keep” that approach “in
place,” id. ¶ 391, and fails to allege that Google made any change to coerce publishers to use its
tools rather than header bidding. See Simon & Simon, PC v. Align Tech., Inc., 2020 WL 1975139,
at *7 n.7 (D. Del. Apr. 24, 2020) (“The Complaint does not allege that the design of Align’s iTero
23
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 34 of 52
Element scanner has ever changed. The Court is therefore not confronted with an allegation of
Projects Poirot and Elmo. State Plaintiffs allege that Projects Poirot and Elmo changed
how DV360 bid into rival exchanges. TAC ¶¶ 400, 403. But they fail to allege that those changes
coercively limited advertisers’ choices, and any such allegation would be implausible. The TAC
describes the alleged market as so competitive that Google was at risk of “losing ad spend and
market share to rival DSPs,” id. ¶ 397, and recognizes that it is “unlikely that large advertisers
would continue to use DV360” if Google restricted their options, id. ¶ 395. These dynamics make
clear that any attempts to coerce advertisers would have only “invite[d] a loss of sales and an
Accelerated Mobile Pages. State Plaintiffs describe Accelerated Mobile Pages (“AMP”)
with header bidding,” TAC ¶ 407, and they claim that Google redesigned its Search algorithm so
that publishers’ “pages would be displayed lower in Google Search results” unless they used AMP,
id. ¶ 408. But State Plaintiffs do not allege that AMP prevented publishers from using header
bidding and, indeed, admit that AMP allowed publishers to receive bids from at least “a few
exchanges at a time.” Id. ¶ 407. Because AMP did not preclude publishers from using header
Unified Pricing Rules. According to the TAC, publishers used DFP to “disadvantage”
Google by “[s]etting higher price floors for AdX and Google’s buying tools” than for other
exchanges and buying tools. TAC ¶¶ 453, 456-57. For example, if a publisher set price floors of
7
State Plaintiffs cannot allege actionable coercion with claims that publishers experienced a “40+ percent decrease in
monetization” from the change to Google’s Search algorithm. TAC ¶ 408. Product design changes are not coercive
if consumers retain access to competitive products. See, e.g., Liveuniverse, 2007 WL 6865852 at *14 (dismissing
claim based on blocking access to competitor’s website because consumers had other ways to access it).
24
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 35 of 52
$1.20 for AdX and $1.00 for other exchanges, a buyer could win the impression on another
exchange for $1.01, but would have to pay $1.21 to win the same impression on AdX. State
Plaintiffs allege that, in response to Google’s customers using its own DFP product against it,
Google introduced Unified Pricing Rules (“UPR”) requiring publishers to “set the same price floor
for different exchanges and . . . different buyers.” Id. ¶ 460. They fail to allege, however, that
UPR prevented publishers from using other exchanges or excluded rival buying tools from
participating in AdX auctions. That failure alone suffices to dismiss any claim based on UPR, and
there are other flaws as well. First, State Plaintiffs fault Google for treating all exchanges and
buying tools the “same,” see id., even though equal treatment cannot harm competition. See FTC
v. Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 1002-03 (9th Cir. 2020) (policy that applies regardless of whether
customer deals with defendant or rivals was not anticompetitive because it “by definition does not
distort the ‘area of effective competition’”).8 Second, although State Plaintiffs would require
Google to leave unaltered the parts of DFP that allowed publishers to “disadvantage” Google, see
TAC ¶ 457, firms have no obligation to aid their competitors in perpetuity. Christy Sports, 555
F.3d at 1196 (“[W]e do not see why an initial decision to adopt one business model would lock
the [defendant] into that approach and preclude adoption of [another lawful business model] at a
later time.”); Olympia Equip. Leasing Co., 797 F.2d at 376 (“If a monopolist does extend a helping
hand, though not required to do so, and later withdraws it as happened in this case, does he incur
Privacy Sandbox. State Plaintiffs assail Google’s alleged proposals to modify its Chrome
web browser to “block publishers and advertisers from using the type of cookies they rely on to
8
State Plaintiffs try to cast UPR as imposing a “price disadvantage” on rivals, TAC ¶ 461, but the alleged disadvantage
stems from Google’s fee to participate in EB and thus reduces to a complaint that Google charges too much for EB,
id. ¶ 369. Charging high prices, however, is not illegal. See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407 (“[C]harging of monopoly
prices . . . is not only not unlawful[,] it is an important element of the free-market system.”).
25
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 36 of 52
track users and target ads” and to offer “new and alternative tracking mechanisms” instead. TAC
¶ 474. Notwithstanding their conjecture that Privacy Sandbox will “coerce[] advertisers to shift
spend to Google’s ad buying tools,” id. ¶ 475, State Plaintiffs allege no facts explaining how
Privacy Sandbox would prevent advertisers from using competing products. Nor can they.
According to the TAC, Privacy Sandbox would affect cookie-based targeting only in Chrome. Id.
¶¶ 473-74. And State Plaintiffs do not allege facts showing that Privacy Sandbox would diminish
advertisers’ ability to use cookies to target users of other browsers, that Chrome would support
only Google’s cookie alternative (and not cookie alternatives offered by others), or that Google
would block rival ad buying tools from using its new cookie alternative. Cf. id. ¶ 477 (alleging
that “Chrome is set to disable the primary cookie-tracking technology that almost all non-Google
publishers currently use”) (emphases added). Without such factual allegations, State Plaintiffs’
speculation about the future impact of Privacy Sandbox cannot support a Section 2 claim (even if
“synergistic” effects of the conduct discussed above. TAC ¶¶ 294, 412. Because none was
Ergonomics, Inc. v. Rsch. in Motion Corp., 486 F. App’x 186, 191 (2d Cir. 2012); see City of
Groton v. Conn. Light & Power Co., 662 F.2d 921, 928-29 (2d Cir. 1981) (“[W]e reject the notion
that if there is a fraction of validity to each of the basic claims and the sum of the fractions is one
or more, the plaintiffs have proved a violation of . . . the Sherman Act.”); Valassis Commc’ns, Inc.
v. News Corp., 2019 WL 802093, at *10 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 21, 2019) (Castel, J.) (lawful conduct
“cannot properly be considered an ingredient of a plaintiff’s monopoly broth claim”); New York v.
26
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 37 of 52
Facebook, Inc., 2021 WL 2643724, at *26-28 (D.D.C. June 28, 2021) (excluding lawful refusals
Sherman Act by tying its DFP ad server to its AdX exchange, “thereby coercing publishers to enter
contracts to license its DFP ad server.” TAC ¶¶ 246, 537, 542. In addition to being time barred,
see supra Part I.A, this claim should be dismissed because State Plaintiffs fail to allege facts
establishing a critical element of any tying claim—that “the seller uses actual coercion to force
buyers to purchase the tied product.” See Kaufman v. Time Warner, 836 F.3d 137, 141 (2d Cir.
2016) (describing elements of Section 1 tying claim); E & L Consulting, Ltd. v. Doman Indus. Ltd.,
472 F.3d 23, 27, 31-32 (2d Cir. 2006) (describing elements of Section 2 tying claim).
An actionable tie exists only if the seller “goes beyond persuasion and conditions [the
buyer’s] purchase of one product on the purchase of another product.” Unijax, Inc. v. Champion
Int’l, Inc., 683 F.2d 678, 685 (2d Cir. 1982) (emphasis added). In admitting that Google offered
“exchange-only contracts” until 2018, TAC ¶ 251, State Plaintiffs concede that Google allowed
publishers to contract for its ad exchange without taking its ad server and, thus, that there was no
tie during that period. See In re Time Warner Inc. Set-Top Cable Television Box Antitrust Litig.,
2010 WL 882989, at *5 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 5, 2010) (Castel, J.) (“[W]here the buyer is free to take
either product by itself there is no tying problem.” (internal quotation marks omitted)).
State Plaintiffs likewise fail to allege a tie in the later period. While the TAC alleges that,
in early 2018, Google began “requiring publishers to sign a combined contract that included both
Google’s DFP ad server and Google’s AdX exchange,” TAC ¶ 251, that allegation fails to show
the requisite coercion. The TAC concedes that, even after allegedly insisting on the “combined
contract,” id., Google still does not tie DFP to AdX because it “continues its policy” of allowing
27
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 38 of 52
publishers trading through AdX to “choose[] not to license Google’s ad server,” id. ¶ 250. See
Synergetics USA, Inc. v. Alcon Labs., Inc., 2009 WL 435299, at *4 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 23, 2009)
(“Where . . . the defendant also sells the allegedly tied items separately, general claims that
[defendant] has refused to sell two supposedly tied products individually do not allege actual
coercion of the buyer.”); see also Suburban Propane v. Proctor Gas, Inc., 953 F.2d 780, 788 (2d
Cir. 1992) (finding “no showing of coercion” despite contract covering two products because there
was no indication counterclaimant “was forced to take a product it did not want”).
contract . . . included” both DFP and AdX, TAC ¶ 251 (emphasis added), they do not claim that
the contract actually required publishers to purchase both products. Without such an allegation,
the TAC fails to show that the “combined contract” was anything other than a convenient way of
formalizing the terms governing use of the two products so that publishers would have the option
to purchase both of them when desired. See It’s My Party, Inc. v. Live Nation, Inc., 811 F.3d 676,
684-85 (4th Cir. 2016) (“[M]erely offering two products in a single package, allowing each to
enhance the appeal of the other, is not itself coercive.”); see also Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 142
(recognizing that “consumers often benefit from the bundling of separate products”).
Unable to plead contractual coercion, State Plaintiffs allege that publishers were
economically coerced into using DFP because they would “los[e] 20 to 40 percent” of their revenue
if they chose another ad server that did not have “the ability to receive live, competitive bids” from
AdX. TAC ¶ 247. That allegation underscores the value that publishers receive from Google’s
products and does not support a tying theory based on economic coercion. Such a theory requires
that the defendant’s “pricing structure make[] purchase of the tying and tied products together the
only viable economic option.” Ortho Diagnostic Sys., Inc. v. Abbott Labs., Inc., 920 F. Supp. 455,
28
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 39 of 52
471 (S.D.N.Y. 1996). But State Plaintiffs have failed to plead any facts about how DFP and AdX
are priced together. See Synopsys, Inc. v. ATopTech, Inc., 2015 WL 4719048, at *7-8 (N.D. Cal.
Aug. 7, 2015) (dismissing tying claim for failure to allege facts showing coercive pricing). While
the TAC asserts that publishers would earn 20 to 40 percent less revenue if they used an ad server
other than DFP, TAC ¶ 247, it says nothing about how Google prices its products, and courts have
not found economic coercion whenever products are offered in an attractive package. For example,
the Ninth Circuit rejected a theory of implied coercion where the “economic imperative” allegedly
arose not from how the products were priced, but “simply because [the defendant’s conduct]
ma[de] it less desirable to purchase from the third party.” See Aerotec Int’l, Inc. v. Honeywell
Int’l, Inc., 836 F.3d 1171, 1179-80 (9th Cir. 2016); see also Gen. Motors Corp. v. Gibson Chem.
& Oil Corp., 786 F.2d 105, 110 (2d Cir. 1986) (concluding that risk of voided automobile warranty
The alleged reason why DFP performed so much better than its competitors—it was the
only ad server with “the ability to receive live, competitive bids” from Google’s AdX exchange,
TAC ¶ 247—reveals that, at bottom, State Plaintiffs’ tying claim boils down to an assertion that
Google should be required to give competing ad servers access to live AdX bids. When confronted
with similar attempts to repackage a refusal-to-deal claim as tying, courts have applied the correct
standards. See Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 144-45 (dismissing tying claim and observing that, even
though “plaintiffs frame their claim as a tie-in, the core issue is a cable provider’s right to refuse
to enable cable boxes it does not control to unscramble its coded signal”); Rebotix Repair LLC v.
Intuitive Surgical, Inc., 2021 WL 1227593, at *8 (M.D. Fla. Mar. 8, 2021) (dismissing tying claim
29
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 40 of 52
Applying those standards here, State Plaintiffs have failed to plead that Google was
required to allow AdX to return live bids to rival ad servers because they do not allege that Google
has ever done so previously. See In re Elevator Antitrust Litig., 502 F.3d 47, 52 (2d Cir. 2007)
(“[B]ecause plaintiffs do not allege that defendants terminated any prior course of dealing—the
sole exception to the broad right of a firm to refuse to deal with its competitors—the allegations
are insufficient to state a unilateral-monopolization claim.”); see also Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine
Commc’ns, Inc., 555 U.S. 438, 457 (2009) (“Trinko holds that a defendant with no antitrust duty
to deal with its rivals has no duty to deal under the terms and conditions preferred by those rivals.”);
New York Mercantile Exch., Inc. v. Intercontinental Exch., Inc., 323 F. Supp. 2d 559, 571
(S.D.N.Y. 2004) (dismissing claim premised on alleged failure by exchange to allow rivals to use
real-time bid data for competitive purposes where there was no “history of cooperation” between
the Supreme Court has “long recognized that Congress intended to outlaw only unreasonable
restraints,” see State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997) (emphasis added). According to State
Plaintiffs, the Network Bidding Agreement between Google and Facebook (the “NBA”) is such
an unreasonable agreement for two reasons. First, they suggest that the NBA is an agreement to
9
State Plaintiffs’ Section 2 tying claim suffers from an additional defect: it fails to allege that Google possessed
monopoly power in the alleged market for the tying product (ad exchanges). See Ortho Diagnostic, 920 F. Supp. at
465, 472-73, 472 n.26 (recognizing that Section 2 claims, including a Section 2 tying claim, require proof “that the
defendant possessed monopoly power”—“a higher level of market power than [required for] the Section 1” tying
claim). State Plaintiffs assert that Google’s share of the alleged exchange market was over 60 percent, TAC ¶¶ 151-
153, but market shares below 65 percent cannot support a Section 2 claim. See PepsiCo, Inc. v. Coca-Cola Co., 315
F.3d 101, 109 (2d Cir. 2002) (finding that “a 64 percent market share is insufficient to infer monopoly power”).
30
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 41 of 52
“kill” header bidding. See TAC ¶ 413. Second, they allege that the NBA “established an
agreement for Facebook to win at least 7.2 percent of all in-app impressions sold by developers in
Google run-auctions.” Id. ¶ 438. Because the TAC lacks factual allegations supporting either
A. State Plaintiffs Fail to Allege That Facebook Agreed Not to Support Header
Bidding.
To survive a motion to dismiss, a complaint must provide “enough fact[s] to raise a
reasonable expectation that discovery will reveal evidence of illegal agreement.” Bell Atl. Corp.
v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 556 (2007) (emphasis added). There are two ways to do so. “First, a
plaintiff may, of course, assert direct evidence that the defendants entered into an agreement in
violation of the antitrust laws.” Mayor & Council of Baltimore v. Citigroup, Inc., 709 F.3d 129,
136 (2d Cir. 2013). Second, “a complaint may . . . present circumstantial facts supporting the
inference that a conspiracy existed.” Id. Under either approach, State Plaintiffs have failed to
allege facts showing that Facebook agreed with Google not to support header bidding.
No Direct Allegations. Despite relying on the written NBA, State Plaintiffs do not allege
that the document itself memorialized an agreement that Facebook would not support header
bidding. They cite nothing in the NBA that precludes Facebook from working with header bidding
exchanges or other Google rivals. Nor could they: the NBA explicitly “does not restrict Facebook
from developing or enhancing a product or service that competes with” Google’s products and
id. at -542 (§ 19.10) (“For clarity, this is not an exclusive agreement.”)10; see also Value Drug Co.
10
The Court may consider the NBA, which is quoted and excerpted at length in the TAC, see TAC ¶¶ 425, 434, 449,
because State Plaintiffs “rel[y] heavily upon its terms and effect,” making it “integral” to their complaint. See Int’l
Audiotext Network, Inc. v. AT&T Co., 62 F.3d 69, 72 (2d Cir. 1995); see also DiFolco v. MSNBC Cable LLC, 622
F.3d 104, 111 (2d Cir. 2010) (allowing consideration on motion to dismiss of documents “incorporated by reference
in the complaint” and “integral to the complaint”) (internal quotation marks omitted). After it was originally executed
in September 2018, the NBA has been amended in ways that are not material to or reflected in the claims in the TAC.
31
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 42 of 52
v. Takeda Pharm., U.S.A., Inc., 2021 WL 6200907, at *14 (E.D. Pa. Dec. 29, 2021) (finding no
direct evidence of alleged “overarching” conspiracy to restrict output despite other written
agreements). State Plaintiffs admit that Facebook has taken advantage of that freedom by
Despite asserting that the NBA’s “significant minimum spend requirements running to
hundreds of millions of dollars a year . . . ensured that Facebook would not—and, economically,
could not—return to support header bidding,” TAC ¶ 426, State Plaintiffs allege no facts to support
that conclusory allegation. To the contrary, they allege that Facebook is a digital advertising
“behemoth,” see id. ¶ 436, so it cannot be assumed that the NBA’s spending requirements tie up a
significant enough percentage of Facebook’s total spending to preclude Facebook from using both
header bidding and Open Bidding at the same time. See Tampa Elec. Co. v. Nashville Coal Co.,
365 U.S. 320, 329 (1961) (“mere showing that the contract itself involves a substantial number of
competition); Wellnx Life Scis. Inc. v. Iovate Health Scis. Rsch. Inc., 516 F. Supp. 2d 270, 295 n.8
(S.D.N.Y. 2007) (Castel, J.) (dismissing Section 1 claim that lacked “allegations from which
significant foreclosure could be reasonably inferred”). Indeed, the TAC concedes that Facebook
has agreements with other mediation tools and that the NBA is not the only one to “include dollar-
State Plaintiffs do not cite any other direct evidence that Facebook agreed not to support
header bidding. Despite having years to review mountains of Facebook and Google documents,
see MDL ECF No. 55, at 2 (describing State Plaintiffs’ “expansive, 18-month governmental pre-
suit investigation . . . entailing the production of around three million documents”), State Plaintiffs
quote just a handful of emails allegedly reflecting Facebook’s belief that Google wanted to “kill”
32
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 43 of 52
header bidding and Google’s desire to “protect” its “leadership position,” see TAC ¶ 420. But “a
desire to extinguish one’s rivals is entirely consistent with, often is the motive behind,
competition.” A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc. v. Rose Acre Farms, Inc., 881 F.2d 1396, 1402 (7th Cir.
1989); see also Novell, 731 F.3d at 1078 (“Were intent to harm a competitor alone the marker of
antitrust liability, the law would risk retarding consumer welfare by deterring vigorous
competition.”). Moreover, the TAC’s quotations from emails are silent as to Facebook’s
motivations and thus fail to show that Facebook agreed to help Google realize its supposed goals.
These emails are hardly “smoking gun” evidence that Facebook agreed not to support header
bidding. See Citigroup, 709 F.3d at 136; see also MedioStream, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 869 F.
Supp. 2d 1095, 1105 (N.D. Cal. 2012) (dismissing claim and finding “lack of specificity
particularly troubling” when plaintiff had access to “large volumes of relevant information”).
No Circumstantial Allegations. The TAC also lacks any factual allegations to support an
inference that Facebook agreed not to support header bidding. No inference of collusion arises
when a company’s conduct “made perfect business sense, there are obvious alternative
explanations for the facts alleged, or the alleged facts suggest competition at least as plausibly as
they suggest anticompetitive conspiracy.” In re Interest Rate Antitrust Litig., 261 F. Supp. 3d 430,
Here, the TAC admits that Facebook had its own independent reasons to partner with
Google—namely, to avoid the “huge [engineering] and services investment” and “time and
expense of building a new technology.” TAC ¶ 422 (alteration in original). In addition, the TAC
concedes that Facebook never seriously considered partnering with header bidding exchanges and
that its contrary public announcements were part of a “planned long-term strategy . . . to minimize”
how much it would pay Google to participate in Open Bidding. Id. ¶ 419. The TAC likewise
33
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 44 of 52
explains that Google had its own reasons to encourage Facebook to use Open Bidding, regardless
of whether Facebook committed not to support header bidding. Facebook’s participation in Open
Bidding not only generates fees for Google, id. ¶ 428, it also helps Google attract app developers
by allowing it to “advertise[] the ability to accept Facebook bids as a feature of its mediation tool,”
id. ¶ 448. These “obvious alternative explanation[s]” for why Facebook and Google would enter
the NBA cannot give rise to an inference that Facebook agreed not to support header bidding. See
Cenedella v. Metro. Museum of Art, 348 F. Supp. 3d 346, 358-59 (S.D.N.Y. 2018); see also In re
Inclusive Access Course Materials Antitrust Litig., 2021 WL 2419528, at *9-10 (S.D.N.Y. June
14, 2021) (dismissing Section 1 claim where alleged conduct was “in accordance with [each
defendant’s] own self-interest”); In re Zinc Antitrust Litig., 155 F. Supp. 3d 337, 371 (S.D.N.Y.
2016) (dismissing Section 1 claim where alleged conduct was “equally consistent with rational
State Plaintiffs also contend that Facebook was “induce[d] . . . to shift” its bids from header
bidding to Google’s tools because it received “a number of special advantages” in Open Bidding.
TAC ¶ 427; see also id. ¶¶ 428-34. But State Plaintiffs allege no facts suggesting that Facebook
received the alleged “special advantages” in exchange for a supposed agreement not to support
header bidding. Indeed, the NBA itself refutes this theory because it explicitly allows Facebook
to “develop[] or enhanc[e] a product or service that competes with [Google’s] Program.” Ex. A,
at -526-27 (§ 2.4(e)); see Value Drug, 2021 WL 6200907, at *17 (finding conspiracy implausible
where agreements themselves undermined allegations of parties’ motives). And there is also an
obvious alternative explanation for why Google would give Facebook so-called “special
advantages”: bigger customers often get better terms. See Abbott Labs. v. Adelphia Supply USA,
2017 WL 5992355, at *10 (E.D.N.Y. Aug. 10, 2017) (“[A]llegations of conspiracy will fail on a
34
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 45 of 52
motion to dismiss where there are ‘obvious alternative explanation[s]’ for the facts alleged.”
(quoting Twombly, 550 U.S. at 567)); Cenedella, 348 F. Supp. 3d at 359 (dismissing claim due to
bidding, State Plaintiffs mischaracterize the “Win Rate” provisions in the NBA as “establish[ing]
an agreement for Facebook to win at least 7.2 percent of all in-app impressions sold by developers
in Google run-auctions.” TAC ¶ 438. But the NBA’s actual terms reveal that Google never agreed
to let Facebook win any auction. As properly understood, the “Win Rate” provisions do not violate
State Plaintiffs assert that the “Win Rate” provisions are illegal per se. TAC ¶ 544. But
the categories of activity that qualify for per se treatment are “narrow.” See Texaco Inc. v. Dagher,
547 U.S. 1, 8 (2006); see also E & L Consulting, Ltd. v. Doman Indus. Ltd., 472 F.3d 23, 29 (2d
Cir. 2006) (explaining that per se violations are reserved for “small class of actions”). And there
are several reasons why the “Win Rate” provisions do not fit the bill.
First, the per se rule does not apply to vertical agreements. See United States v. Am.
Express Co., 838 F.3d 179, 194 n.41 (2d Cir. 2016) (“[B]oth vertical price restraints and vertical
non-price restraints are analyzed under the rule of reason.”), aff’d sub nom. Ohio v. Am. Express
11
To the extent that State Plaintiffs contend that the alleged “special advantages” themselves violate Section 1, their
position—that companies should be barred from offering discounts and other favorable terms to important
customers—would impede the very competition on the merits that the antitrust laws are meant to encourage. Cf.
Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986) (“[C]utting prices in order to increase
business often is the very essence of competition.”); Monahan’s Marine, Inc. v. Bos. Whaler, Inc., 866 F.2d 525, 529
(1st Cir. 1989) (noting that many circuits have “found nothing anticompetitive in the simple fact that a seller selectively
cuts its prices, or offers other favorable terms, to some of its dealers, even though such discrimination harms the non-
favored dealers”); Proctor v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 675 F.2d 308, 338 (D.C. Cir. 1982) (“[T]he Sherman
Act was not designed to disallow discounts or other preferential treatment for volume customers.”).
35
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 46 of 52
Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274 (2018). Vertical agreements are “combinations of persons at different levels
of the market structure, e.g., manufacturers and distributors,” Anderson News, LLC v. Am. Media,
Inc., 680 F.3d 162, 182 (2d Cir. 2012) (internal quotation marks omitted), and the NBA is precisely
that. The TAC recognizes that the agreement enabled Facebook to “bid through Google’s tools,”
TAC ¶ 426, and describes Facebook as one of the “bidders” in Google’s “auction house,” id. ¶ 441.
These allegations confirm that the NBA governs the vertical relationship between Facebook as a
Second, State Plaintiffs fail to allege facts showing that the challenged activity “fit[s] into
any of the established per se categories.” Bogan v. Hodgkins, 166 F.3d 509, 514-15 (2d Cir. 1999).
Struggling to allege a per se market allocation agreement, see TAC ¶ 544, State Plaintiffs
mischaracterize the “Win Rate” provisions as an “agreement for Facebook to win at least 7.2
percent of all in-app impressions,” id. ¶ 438, or as one that “pre-determine[d] the outcomes” of
Google’s auctions, id. ¶ 446. In fact, the applicable “Win Rate” provisions require only that
impressions. Ex. A, at -545 (Ex. A § 5).13 As these provisions apply only to Facebook, they do
not require Google to let Facebook win anything, as State Plaintiffs grudgingly concede. See TAC
¶ 450 (“Google and Facebook drafted Jedi Blue to suggest that their agreed bid and win rates were
12
Although State Plaintiffs note that Google and Facebook also “compet[e] directly to purchase in-app impressions
from developers,” TAC ¶ 440, and to “resell impressions to advertisers,” id. ¶ 444, “[a]n allegation that defendants’
conduct was a ‘horizontal conspiracy’ amounting to a per se violation of the Sherman Act ‘is a legal conclusion that
the Court does not accept as true on a motion to dismiss.’” 2238 Victory Corp. v. Fjallraven USA Retail, LLC, 2021
WL 76334, at *3 (S.D.N.Y. Jan. 8, 2021) (Castel, J.). And courts apply the rule of reason to agreements like the NBA
that involve parties with a mixed relationship including both vertical and horizontal elements. See Elecs. Commc’ns
Corp. v. Toshiba Am. Consumer Prod., Inc., 129 F.3d 240, 243-44 (2d Cir. 1997) (collecting cases recognizing that
rule of reason applies to agreements between manufacturers and distributors, even when the manufacturer also
competes at the distribution level); 2238 Victory Corp., 2021 WL 76334, at *5-6 (dismissing per se Section 1 claim
when complaint alleged a mixed horizontal and vertical relationship).
13
For a limited period after the NBA went into effect (Phases 1 and 2), the “Win Rate” provisions obligated Facebook
to “ensure” that it won at least a specified percentage of impressions, Ex. A, at -545 (Ex. A § 5), but Google never
promised not to compete with Facebook for those impressions.
36
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 47 of 52
duties owed by Facebook, not Google.”). And it makes sense that Google would want assurances
that Facebook would actually participate in Open Bidding auctions if Google were going to make
the investment required to expand the program to enable Facebook’s participation. See Ex. A, at
-525 (§ 2.2(c)) (agreement to “build a product solution”). Because Google did not agree to allocate
anything to Facebook, the TAC fails to state a claim for per se illegal market allocation. See In re
Zinc Antitrust Litig., 155 F. Supp. 3d at 375 (dismissing market allocation claim where plaintiffs
“do not directly allege that defendants agreed to allocate the markets”); see also Zenith Radio
Corp. v. Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co., 513 F. Supp. 1100, 1147 (E.D. Pa. 1981) (reasoning that
agreement to charge “‘whatever price was necessary to make the sale’ . . . would merely be an
agreement to compete”), aff’d in part, rev’d in part on other grounds sub nom. In re Japanese
Elec. Prods. Antitrust Litig., 723 F.2d 238 (3d Cir. 1983), rev’d on other grounds sub nom.
Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574 (1986).
Third, courts do not apply the per se rule to novel arrangements with obviously
procompetitive effects. Rather, “it is only after considerable experience with certain business
relationships that courts classify them as per se violations,” and only then if “the practice facially
appears to be one that would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease
output.” Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 9, 19-20 (1979) (internal
alteration and citation omitted); see also Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551
U.S. 877, 886 (2007) (explaining that per se rule applies only to restraints that have “manifestly
anticompetitive effects and lack any redeeming virtue”) (internal quotation marks and citations
omitted). The NBA, however, did not reduce competition; as the TAC concedes, it opened a new
competitive front by enabling Facebook to bid against Google and others in Open Bidding. See
TAC ¶ 436 (explaining that the NBA allowed Facebook “to compete against Google for
37
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 48 of 52
publishers’ and developers’ inventory on equal terms”); Northrop Corp. v. McDonnell Douglas
Corp., 705 F.2d 1030, 1050-54 (9th Cir. 1983) (declining to apply per se rule against market
allocation in a “novel context” and when “there would be no competition but for the agreements”).
The “Win Rate” provisions were particularly procompetitive because they ensured that Facebook
would “bid high enough to win” at least some of the auctions, without stopping Google from
bidding just as aggressively. TAC ¶ 440. Because “there exists a compelling procompetitive
reason” for the NBA, State Plaintiffs’ per se theory should be dismissed. See Flash Elecs., Inc. v.
Universal Music & Video Distrib. Corp., 312 F. Supp. 2d 379, 386 (E.D.N.Y. 2004).
After Google highlighted how State Plaintiffs’ prior pleading challenged the NBA purely
on a per se theory, MDL ECF No. 136, at 4-5, the TAC added the “alternative” theory that the
agreement violates the rule of reason, see TAC ¶ 545. “Under the rule of reason, the plaintiff[s]
must show that defendants’ challenged behavior had an actual adverse effect on competition as a
whole in the relevant market.” Wellnx Life Scis., 516 F. Supp. 2d at 293 (internal quotation marks
omitted). That showing can be made directly (with allegations of effects “such as reduced output”)
or indirectly (with allegations of “market power, plus some other ground for believing that the
challenged behavior could harm competition”). See Tops Mkts., Inc. v. Quality Mkts., Inc., 142
F.3d 90, 96-97 (2d Cir. 1998). But the TAC fails to allege facts showing that the “Win Rate”
Although State Plaintiffs allege that the NBA “depresses prices paid to developers,” their
theory depends on a fundamentally inaccurate premise: that Google and Facebook “agreed to limit
their competitive bidding as between each other.” See TAC ¶ 437. As the text of the NBA reveals,
38
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 49 of 52
the “Win Rate” provisions do not address—much less limit—Google’s bidding, and they do not
prevent Facebook from trying to win even more than the minimum number of auctions for which
it committed to use “commercially reasonable efforts” to win. See Ex. A, at -545 (Ex. A § 5); see
also TAC ¶ 440 (NBA “assure[s] that Facebook will bid high enough to win the minimum percent
quota”). Because State Plaintiffs mischaracterize the NBA’s terms, their allegations about how
those terms affected pricing lack plausibility and should not be credited. See Planetarium Travel,
Inc. v. Altour Int’l, Inc., 97 F. Supp. 3d 424, 432 (S.D.N.Y. 2015) (dismissing Section 1 claim
when the complaint “fail[ed] to offer a plausible theory of anticompetitive harm”), aff’d, 622 F.
App’x 40 (2d Cir. 2015); see also Wellnx Life Scis., 516 F. Supp. 2d at 294-95 (dismissing Section
1 claim when supracompetitive pricing was “not plausibly supported by the factual allegations”).
Even if State Plaintiffs had accurately described the NBA’s terms, their own allegations
demonstrate that the NBA would not affect pricing in the alleged in-app networks market as a
whole.14 The agreement governs only auctions occurring in Google’s in-app mediation tool, and
only about 50 to 60 percent of ad-containing apps allegedly use that tool. TAC ¶¶ 228, 437, 441.
The other half—those using mediation tools offered by competitors like MoPub, ironSource, and
AppLovin, id. ¶ 228—remain untouched by the NBA. In addition, the “Win Rate” provisions
cover just 7.2 percent of in-app impressions sold in Google’s mediation tool, id. ¶ 438, which is
equivalent to at most 4.32 percent (= 7.2% x 60%) of all in-app impressions, id. ¶ 228. With an
effect on less than 5 percent of all in-app impressions, the “Win Rate” provisions cannot harm the
in-app networks market as a whole, so State Plaintiffs have failed to allege the requisite
anticompetitive harm directly. See Wellnx Life Scis., 516 F. Supp. 2d at 293-94 (finding allegations
14
For purposes of Count IV, State Plaintiffs appear to believe that the relevant market is for “in-app networks.” See
TAC ¶ 232 (“In-app networks are the intermediaries that purchase in-app display ad inventory from developers and
resell those impressions to advertisers.”), ¶ 437 (stating that “[a]s operative today,” the NBA “primarily applies to the
auctions Google conducts on behalf of developers to sell their in-app inventory”).
39
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 50 of 52
insufficient to show marketwide effect when agreement affected 40 percent of the market but the
other 60 percent remained “free to compete”); see also PepsiCo, Inc. v. Coca-Cola Co., 315 F.3d
101, 111 (2d Cir. 2002) (affirming summary judgment for inability to show marketwide effect
where defendant had “agreements with only 377 out of more than 2000” customers).
Absent allegations of actual marketwide harm, a plaintiff “must show market power, plus
some other ground for believing that the challenged behavior could harm competition in the
market.” Tops Mkts., 142 F.3d at 97. Although courts sometimes use market shares as a “proxy
for market power,” see Kaufman v. Time Warner, 836 F.3d 137, 143 (2d Cir. 2016), the TAC lacks
any allegations about the market shares of Google or Facebook in the alleged in-app networks
market. To the extent that the TAC discusses market structure at all, it paints a picture of vibrant
competition among Google, Facebook, Unity, ironSource, Vungle, and others. TAC ¶ 232; see
also id. ¶ 89 (recognizing that 25 in-app networks can compete in Google’s mediation tool).
Indeed, State Plaintiffs do not make even a conclusory allegation of market power in the in-app
networks market. See Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 148 (affirming dismissal and rejecting “inference of
market power” where no facts were alleged about defendant’s market share or “how the presence
of . . . competitors affect[ed defendant’s] power over price”). Coupled with the other deficiencies
discussed above, State Plaintiffs’ failure to allege market power in the in-app networks market
CONCLUSION
For the foregoing reasons, Defendant respectfully requests that this Court dismiss Counts
I through IV of State Plaintiffs’ Third Amended Complaint in full and with prejudice.
40
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 51 of 52
Justina Sessions
Jonathan Jacobson
Jessica Lonergan
Mikaela Evans-Aziz (pro hac vice motion
forthcoming)
WILSON SONSINI GOODRICH &
ROSATI
Professional Corporation
One Market Plaza, Spear Tower
Suite 3300
San Francisco, CA 94105
(415) 947-2000
[email protected]
[email protected]
[email protected]
[email protected]
John Harkrider
Daniel Bitton
Bradley Justus (admitted pro hac vice)
Koren Wong-Ervin (pending pro hac vice)
AXINN, VELTROP & HARKRIDER LLP
114 West 47th Street
New York, NY 10036
(212) 728-2200
[email protected]
41
Case 1:21-md-03010-PKC Document 218 Filed 01/21/22 Page 52 of 52
[email protected]
[email protected]
[email protected]
42