Monopoly: I. Why Monopolies Arise
Monopoly: I. Why Monopolies Arise
Monopoly: I. Why Monopolies Arise
Monopoly
I. Why Monopolies Arise
- Monopoly: a firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes
1. Monopoly Resources
- The simplest way for a monopoly to arise is for a single firm to own a key resource.
- The monopolist has much greater market power than any single firm in a
competitive market => Monopolist could command quite a high price => More benefit
2. Government regulation
- In many cases, monopolies arise because the government has given one person or
firm the exclusive right to sell some good or service
- Government-created monopolies
Patent and copyright law: The copyright is a government guarantee that no one
can print and sell the work without the author’s permission.
Ex: The copyright makes the novelist a monopolist in the sale of her novel.
Allowing these monopoly producers to charge higher prices -> earn higher
profits
The laws governing patents and copyrights have benefits and costs. The
benefits of the patent and copyright laws are the increased incentives for
creative activity. These benefits are offset, to some extent, by the costs of
monopoly pricing
- A natural monopoly arises when there are economies of scale over the relevant
range of output.
Ex: To provide water to residents of a town, a firm must build a network of pipes
throughout the town. If two or more firms were to compete in the provision of
this service, each firm would have to pay the fixed cost of building a network.
Thus, the average total cost of water is lowest if a single firm serves the entire
market.
II. How Monopolies Make Production& Pricing Decisions
1. Monopoly versus Competition
- The key difference between a competitive firm and a monopoly is the monopoly’s
ability to influence the price of its output:
A competitive firm: small relative to the market in which it operates => has no
power to influence the price of its output => takes the price as given by market
conditions -> Price taker
Monopoly: the sole producer in its market => can alter the price of its good by
adjusting the quantity it supplies to the market-> Price maker
2. A monopoly’s revenue
- Total revenue = price x quantity (3th column of the table)
- Average revenue = total revenue/ units sold (4th column of the table) <= the
amount of revenue the firm receives per unit sold
Note: Average revenue always equals the price of the good. This is true for monopolists as well
as for competitive firms
- Marginal revenue = the change in total revenue when output increases by 1 unit,
can be negative (last column) <= the amount of revenue that the firm receives for each
additional unit of output
- For example, when the firm is producing 3 gallons of water, it receives total
revenue of $24. Raising production to 4 gallons increases total revenue to $28. Thus,
marginal revenue from the sale of the fourth gallon is $28 minus $24, or $4
=> A monopolist’s marginal revenue is always less than the price of its good: MR < P
- Marginal revenue for monopolies is very different from marginal revenue for
competitive firms. When a monopoly increases the amount it sells, this action has two
effects on total revenue (P × Q):
The output effect: More output is sold, so Q is higher, which tends to increase
total revenue.
The price effect: The price falls, so P is lower, which tends to decrease total
revenue
When a monopoly increases production by 1 unit, it reduce the price it charges for
every unit it sells, and this cut in price reduces revenue on the units it was already
selling
A monopoly’s marginal revenue is less than its price (MR curve is below the D
curve)
3. Profit Maximization
- Suppose:
TH1: The firm produces at a low level of output - Q1.
- Marginal cost < marginal revenue.
- The firm increased production by 1 unit -> the additional revenue would exceed
the additional costs -> profit would rise.
Marginal cost < marginal revenue, the firm can increase profit by producing
more units.
TH2: The firm produce at high levels of output - Q2
- Marginal cost > marginal revenue.
- The firm reduced production by 1 unit -> the costs saved would exceed the
revenue lost.
Marginal cost > marginal revenue, the firm can raise profit by reducing
production
- The firm adjusts its level of production until the quantity reaches Q MAX, at which
marginal revenue equals marginal cost
The monopolist’s profit maximizing quantity of output is determined by the
intersection of the marginal-revenue curve and the marginal-cost curve
(point A figure 4)
4. A Monopoly’s Profit
- Profit = (TR/Q – TC/Q) × Q.
- TR/Q is average revenue, which equals the price, P, and TC/Q is average total
cost, ATC. Therefore:
Profit = (P – ATC) × Q
CASE STUDY: Monopoly Drugs vs Generic Drugs
A firm discovers a new drug, patent laws give the firm a monopoly on the sale of that
drug. But eventually, the firm’s patent runs out, and any company can make and sell the
drug. At that time, the market switches from being monopolistic to being competitive
- During the life of the patent: the monopoly firm maximizes profit by producing
the quantity at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost and charging a price
well above marginal cost.
- When the patent runs out, the profit from making the drug should encourage
new firms to enter the market. As the market becomes more competitive, the
price should fall to equal marginal cost.
- The price of the competitively produced generic drug is well below the price that
the monopolist was charging. The expiration of a patent, however, does not cause
the monopolist to lose all its market power. Some consumers remain loyal to the
brand-name drug, perhaps out of fear that the new generic drugs are not actually
the same as the drug they have been using for years. As a result, the former
monopolist can continue to charge a price above the price charged by its new
competitors.
- Figure 7 analyzes how a benevolent social planner would choose the monopoly’s level
of output.
Demand curve -> the value of the good to consumers, as measured by their
willingness to pay
Marginal-cost curve -> the costs of the monopolist.
The socially efficient quantity is found where the demand curve and the
marginal-cost curve intersect
Below this quantity: the value of an extra unit to consumers > the cost of
providing it -> increasing output would raise the total surplus.
Above this quantity: the cost of producing an extra unit > the value of that unit
to consumers -> decreasing output would raise total surplus.
If the social planner were running the monopoly, the firm could achieve this
efficient outcome by charging the price found at the intersection of the
demand and marginal-cost curves. Thus, like a competitive firm and unlike
a profit-maximizing monopoly, a social planner would charge a price equal
to marginal cost. Because this price would give consumers an accurate
signal about the cost of producing the good, consumers would buy the
efficient quantity.
- Figure 8 shows the comparison of output that the monopolist chooses to the level of
output that a social planner would choose
Monopolist chooses to produce and sell the quantity of output at which the
marginal-revenue and marginal-cost curves intersect
Social planner chooses the quantity at which the demand and marginal-cost
curves intersect
The monopolist produces less than the socially efficient quantity of
output
- The market demand curve describes a negative relationship between the price and
quantity of the good, a quantity that is inefficiently low is equivalent to a price that is
inefficiently high.
- When a monopolist charges a price above marginal cost -> some potential consumers
value the good at more than its marginal cost but less than the monopolist’s price ->
they don’t buy the good because the value they place on the good > the cost of providing
it to them, this result is inefficient.
Monopoly pricing prevents some mutually beneficial trades from taking place.
- The inefficiency of monopoly can be measured with a deadweight loss triangle (figure
8).
Demand curve = the value to consumers
Marginal-cost curve = the costs to the monopoly producer
The area of the deadweight loss triangle between the demand curve and the
marginal-cost curve (= the total surplus lost because of monopoly pricing)
- Figure 9 illustrates producer and consumer surplus with and without price
discrimination
- This figure is drawn assuming constant per unit costs—that is, marginal cost and
average total cost are constant and equal
- (a) without price discrimination:
Some potential customers who value the good at more than marginal cost don’t
buy it at this high price => the monopoly causes a DWL.
- (b) perfectly price discriminate
All mutually beneficial trades take place
No deadweight loss occurs
The entire surplus derived from the market goes to the monopoly producer in
the form of profit.
- Clayton Antitrust Act, 1914: strengthened the government’s powers and authorized
private lawsuits
- The antitrust laws give the government various ways to promote competition. They
allow the government to prevent mergers, such as the assumption of merge between
Coca-Cola and PepsiCo. They also allow the government to break up companies. For
example, in 1984, the government split up AT&T, the large telecommunications
company, into eight smaller companies. Finally, the antitrust laws prevent companies
from coordinating their activities in ways that make markets less competitive.
- Antitrust laws have costs as well as benefits. Sometimes companies merge not to
reduce competition but to lower costs through more efficient joint production.
2. Regulation
- Another way the government deals with the problem of monopoly is by regulating
the behavior of monopolists.
- This solution is common in the case of natural monopolies, such as water and
electric companies. These companies are not allowed to charge any price they want.
Instead, government agencies regulate their prices.
3. Public Ownership
How the ownership of the firm affects the costs of production:
- Private owners
• Incentive to minimize costs