The Increasing Importance of Geoeconomics in Power Rivalries in The Twenty-First Century
The Increasing Importance of Geoeconomics in Power Rivalries in The Twenty-First Century
The Increasing Importance of Geoeconomics in Power Rivalries in The Twenty-First Century
Gyula Csurgai
To cite this article: Gyula Csurgai (2017): The Increasing Importance of Geoeconomics in Power
Rivalries in the Twenty-First Century, Geopolitics, DOI: 10.1080/14650045.2017.1359547
ABSTRACT
Relations between states in the post-Cold War period have been
shaped by an increased economic competition including ‘non-
market’ factors such as intelligence sharing between state agencies
and private businesses, successful economic diplomacy and differ-
Downloaded by [Tufts University] at 11:50 28 October 2017
Introduction
At the end of the Cold War Edward Luttwak, a US expert in strategy, claimed
that ideological rivalries between Western liberal and communist collectivist
models of societies would be replaced by a worldwide economic rivalry, in
which trade, finance, and the mastering of important technologies often
prevail over military power.
1
Indeed, relations between states in the post-Cold War period have been
shaped by an increased economic competition including ‘non-market’ factors
such as intelligence sharing between state agencies and private businesses,
successful economic diplomacy and different techniques to influence and
manipulate non-governmental organisations to weaken an economic adver-
sary, among other things. The considerable influence of these non-market
factors illustrates the limits of the liberal economic theories that emphasise
the dominant role of market forces. Moreover, as Antto Vihma states,2 the
2008 financial crisis, the increasing use of financial means by China to gain
geopolitical influences worldwide, the Russian strategy to use energy as an
instrument in foreign policy, the state-capitalist models of economic devel-
opment and the growing competition for scarce resources necessitate re-
considering the role of the state in economic security.
Geoeconomic analysis questions the validity and usefulness of the main
theories and paradigms of International Relations (IR). Theories, such as,
functionalism, constructivism, post-structuralism, Marxism, liberalism,
among others, have the common feature of constraining the interpretation
of international relations to an oversimplified framework for analysis. These
theories are often based on mono-causality and subsequently interpret poli-
tical and economic phenomena according to a rather limited ideological
Downloaded by [Tufts University] at 11:50 28 October 2017
Geoeconomics
Although the concept of geoeconomics appeared at the end of the Cold War,
thanks mainly to the works of Edward Luttwak, the interrelations between state
power, economy and international trade had been taken into consideration
throughout history.4 Controlling trade routes, gaining access to natural resources
and conquering markets have been important factors in international economic
relations. Venice became gradually a powerful geoeconomic actor from the
eleventh century. In spite of its small geographic configuration, this city state
GEOPOLITICS 3
other. Nonetheless, France, Great Britain, and the United States considered
the rapid rise of German economic and military power as a major challenge.
It is not the type of political regime but the perceptions of the changing
balance of power by Great Britain, France and the US, due to the increasing
international influence of Germany that influenced the transition from peace
to war. Thenceforth, World War I broke out, in which Great Britain, France,
and the United States had the objective of considerably reducing the power
potential of Germany. This objective of the main victorious powers mani-
fested itself as well by the imposition of the humiliating conditions of the
Versailles Treaty on Germany after the end of that war. There is a limitation
of the democratic peace theory to explain wars between contemporary
democracies that are fought by non-military means for geoeconomic supre-
macy. In fact, geoeconomics can be considered as war by other means than
the military ones, as Robert D. Blackwill and Jennfer M. Harris argue11
At present, democracies occasionally wage economic wars on each other.
Similarly, political and military allies can engage in fierce geoeconomic battles to
conquer markets, control technologies, and maintain financial and monetary
domination, as well as other matters. The nature of ‘Ally–Adversary’ relations is
manifested in trans-Atlantic relations. Although European NATO member
states are in a military alliance with the United States, commercial rivalries are
part of the EU–US relations, such as the mutual accusations in the World Trade
Organization related to subsidies given to Boeing and Airbus. A stronger
example is the use of the ECHELON electronic surveillance system, managed
by the United States in collaboration with other English-speaking Western
countries, and PRISM, a clandestine surveillance program under which the
United States National Security Agency (NSA) collects data of internet and
phone communications. The information collected through ECHELON and
PRISM and given to economic actors can be used to promote the economic
6 G. CSURGAI
interests of the United States,12 illustrating the role of the state apparatus in,
ostensibly, intra-firm competition.
Co-operation between state agencies and companies runs counter to the
tenets of neo-liberalism. The neo-liberal ideology advocates a high degree of
deregulation, opening up rapidly the domestic economy to international
exchanges and investments, privatization of most sectors of the economy,
and limitation of the public sector. The neo-liberal model failed in several
countries. One can mention the Argentinian economic depression taking
place between1998 and 2002, or the devastating consequences of the
Russian ‘shock therapy’ in the 1990s. Contrary to the rapid liberalization
and deregulation of the economy, the East Asian states opted for a gradual
opening of their economies combined with a long-term economic develop-
ment approach in which the state played a strategic role.13 One of the most
obvious examples of this approach – also called State Capitalism – is the
Downloaded by [Tufts University] at 11:50 28 October 2017
Economic Intelligence
The mastering of information has been always a key element of power. The
Downloaded by [Tufts University] at 11:50 28 October 2017
Concluding Remarks
The main arguments developed by Edward Luttwak about geoeconomics at
the end of the Cold War have remained not only valid but also gained even
more importance in the examination of power rivalries in contemporary
international relations. Therefore, the article of the Finnish expert Antto
Vihma21 contributes positively to current debates not only about the neces-
sary and more nuanced interpretations of Edward Luttwak’s strategic
approach to the study of international economic relations but also about
the re-consideration of the role of the state in economic policy and in the
enhancement of economic security. Indeed, defending states’ economic inter-
ests in the twenty-first century requires a modified perception of their
security needs in order to develop an efficient geoeconomic coordination
between state agencies and private businesses. Antto Vihma’s study can be
considered as an important contribution to the debates about the limits of
critical geopolitical approach and the problems related to its practical usabil-
ity in applied research and or in practical work in private corporations and
government agencies including diplomacy, intelligence and the military.
Various study programs were established in geoeconomics and economic
intelligence in different European countries to train current and future
decision makers and analysts of both private and public sectors. A consider-
able number of articles and books have been published as well in Europe on
GEOPOLITICS 9
geoeonomics since the end of the Cold War. Somehow, Antto Vihma did not
integrate these developments in his study.
Overall, there are rather few exchanges between the scholars of different
contemporary schools of thought in geopolitics and geoeconomics between con-
tinental Europe and the United States. The journal Geopolitics can contribute to
the increase of exchanges of ideas between these different schools. The discussion
on geoeconomics can be considered as a positive step in this direction.
Notes
1. E. Luttwak, ‘From Geopolitics to Geo-Economics: Logics of Conflict, Grammar of
Commerce’, The National Interest 20 (1990) pp. 17–23.
2. A. Vihma, ‘Geoeconomic Analysis and the Limits of Critical Geopoltics: A New
Engagement with Edward Luttwak’ Geopolitics (2017) pp. 1–21.
Downloaded by [Tufts University] at 11:50 28 October 2017
3. Ibid.
4. A. Laidi, Histoire Mondiale de la Guerre Economique (Paris: Perrin 2016).
5. E. S. Miller, Bankrupting the Enemy: The U.S. Financial Siege of Japan before Pearl
Harbor (Annapolis: United States Naval Institute Press 2007).
6. C. Harbulot, La Machine de Guerre Economique (Paris: Economica 1992) and La main
Invisible des Puissances (Paris: Ellipses 2007); R. D. Blackwill and J. M. Harris, War by
Other Means, Geoeconomics and Statecraft (Cambridge/London: Harvard University
Press 2016).
7. P. Lorot (ed.), Introduction à la géoéconomie (Paris: Economica 1999) p. 15.
8. Vihma (note 3).
9. P. A. Mello, ‘Democratic Peace Theory’, in P. Joseph (ed.), The SAGE Encyclopedia of
War: Social Science Perspectives (Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications 2017).
10. C. Elman, ‘Introduction: History, Theory, and the Democratic Peace’, The International
History Review 23/4 (Abingdon: Routledge 2001).
11. Blackwill and Harris (note 6).
12. L. Gaiser, Economic Intelligence and World Governance, Reinventing States for a New
World Order (Citta di Castello: Il Cerchio 2016) pp. 177–86.
13. E. F. Vogel, The Four Little Dragons: The Spread of Industrialization in East Asia
(Cambridge: Harvard University Press 1993).
14. Y.-I. Chung, South Korea in the Fast Lane: Economic Development and Capital
Formation (Oxford: Oxford University Press 2007).
15. H. Kirsch (ed.), La France en guerre économique, Plaidoyer pour un Etat stratège (Paris:
Vuibert 2008).
16. C. Harbulot, La Machine de Guerre Economique (Paris: Economica 1992); C. Harbulot,
La Main invisible des puissances (Paris: Ellipses 2007); C. Harbulot, Manuel d’intelli-
gence économique (Paris: PUF 2015).
17. C. Harbulot, La Machine de Guerre Economique (Paris: Economica 1992) pp. 29–34.
18. G. Csurgai, ‘Geoeconomic Strategies and Economic Intelligence’, in J. M. Munoz (ed.),
Advances in Geoeconomics (London/New York: Routledge 2017).
19. C. Jean and P. Savona, Intelligence Economica (Soveria Mannelli: Rubettino 2011) p. 21.
20. C. Harbulot (ed.), Manuel d’intelligence économique (Paris: PUF 2015).
21. Vihma (note 3).