2021 Latin American and Caribbean Macroeconomic Report Opportunities For Stronger and Sustainable Postpandemic Growth
2021 Latin American and Caribbean Macroeconomic Report Opportunities For Stronger and Sustainable Postpandemic Growth
2021 Latin American and Caribbean Macroeconomic Report Opportunities For Stronger and Sustainable Postpandemic Growth
Coordinated by
Eduardo Cavallo and Andrew Powell
2021
p. cm.
Includes bibliographic references.
Copyright © 2021 Inter-American Development Bank. This work is licensed under a Creative
Commons IGO 3.0 Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives (CC-IGO BY-NC-ND 3.0 IGO)
license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/igo/legalcode) and may be
reproduced with attribution to the IDB and for any non-commercial purpose. No derivative
work is allowed.
Any dispute related to the use of the works of the IDB that cannot be settled amicably shall
be submitted to arbitration pursuant to the UNCITRAL rules. The use of the IDB’s name
for any purpose other than for attribution, and the use of IDB’s logo shall be subject to a
separate written license agreement between the IDB and the user and is not authorized as
part of this CC-IGO license.
Note that link provided above includes additional terms and conditions of the license.
The opinions expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect the views of the Inter-American Development Bank, its Board of Directors, or the
countries they represent.
Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v
Acknowledgments. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii
Executive Summary. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix
Chapter 1: The Global Economy and Latin America and the Caribbean. . . . 1
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Online Appendices
Appendix A
Appendix B
Appendix C
Appendix D
iii
Preface
T
he COVID-19 shock was a significant and traumatic crisis for Latin America and
the Caribbean. The pandemic dealt the region what I previously described as an
unprecedented triple sudden stop, with major simultaneous disruptions in human
mobility, trade, and capital flows. This was immensely dangerous. As human mobility was
paralyzed by lockdowns and fear of contagion, investments fell, and trade was upended,
the triple sudden stop challenged the region like few things in the past. Undoing the dam-
age it has caused will require astute policymaking, as well as discipline and creativity, in
the months and years ahead. The 2021 edition of the IDB Latin American and Caribbean
Macroeconomic Report identifies opportunities for policymakers to lead their economies
out of this crisis and toward stronger, inclusive, and sustainable growth.
This crisis began to unfold as countries were already facing a complex set of preexisting
conditions, including low levels of productivity and simmering social discontent. Perhaps
a fitting analogy to describe the situation would be that, in 2019, the region was flying
with one broken engine. In 2020, its other engine also took a hit. The challenge we now
face is to fly this aircraft to safety, rescue the passengers, and prepare for the necessary
repairs. Getting the region back off the ground will require greater spending on healthcare,
government transfers to the poor, and loans to struggling firms. Meanwhile, tax revenues
have plummeted due to unemployment and a drop in consumption, and fiscal balances
and public debt have deteriorated considerably since the 2008/09 global financial crisis.
Against this backdrop, public outlays and stimulus will be extremely difficult to achieve.
One lesson from previous crises is that this is not the time to turn inward and erect
barriers. Instead, the region must seek greater integration through stronger trade agree-
ments and the removal of obstacles such as excessive customs controls at borders, which
harm the free flow of goods and services just when it is most needed. It is time to tap
the opportunities provided by a better, smarter integration into global and regional value
chains. It is also time to consider how Latin America and the Caribbean can leverage the
reallocation of resources across sectors to drive productivity growth, promote formal
employment, and achieve a greener future that defies the false dichotomy of economic
growth and environmental sustainability.
Countries will have to become a lot more efficient, making cuts in public spending
and eliminating the inefficiencies that account for an average of more than 4% of GDP
in the region. Further down the road, they will have to find ways to increase resilience
v
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
through wise capital spending that boosts productivity and spurs growth. Governments
must implement policies to make the recovery much more inclusive, which will mean rais-
ing taxes to improve income distribution through social safety nets and better provision
of public services such as education and healthcare. At the same time, many small and
medium-sized enterprises that entered hibernation must be supported so they can join
the recovery and contribute to stronger growth in the aftermath of the pandemic.
This year’s Macroeconomic Report covers more than the standard issues because
the dangers of triple sudden stops make it imperative to act on multiple fronts. We are
going to emerge from this crisis poorer, more indebted, and with economies that will look
very different in terms of their productive structures. Enforcing key health measures is es-
sential to saving lives until vaccines are rolled out to everyone and we can leave the public
health crisis in the rearview mirror. But equally important is getting economies back on
track to ward off crises and their crippling effects. COVID-19 is a wake-up call to reform
and change the status quo so we can arrive not at the old normal, but a new and better
normal. I hope this report will help policymakers in this endeavor.
Eric Parrado
Chief Economist
vi
Acknowledgments
T
his report was prepared by a team of economists from the Research Department,
the Fiscal and Municipal Management Division, and the Vice Presidency of Countries
of the Inter-American Development Bank (IDB).
This document was produced under the direction of Eduardo Cavallo and Andrew
Powell, at the Research Department. They were very efficiently assisted by Laura Acevedo
and Carlos Guevara Kenty.
Eric Parrado, the Chief Economist and General Manager of the Research Department,
provided many useful comments and suggestions.
The principal authors of each chapter are as follows:
vii
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
viii
Executive Summary
W
hile Latin America and the Caribbean has just 8% of the global population, it
accounts for 25% of global deaths from COVID-19. The 7.4% loss of GDP in 2020
was the largest in a single year since 1821. Long overdue reforms are required
to spur recovery and boost medium-term growth. Growth friendly policies will help the
region reduce poverty and ease the fiscal risks brought on by the pandemic.
To slow the spread of the virus, governments were forced to severely restrict mobil-
ity and deliberately shut down large parts of their economies. The region is recovering,
but many external and domestic risks remain.
Growth is expected to be 4.1% for 2021 for the region and then revert to modest
trend growth of about 2.5% per annum. This recovery assumes countries continue to open
up, vaccine rollouts proceed smoothly, and advanced economies achieve widespread
immunity to the virus in the second quarter of 2021, followed by Latin America and the
Caribbean in the second half of the year or early 2023.
However, a negative scenario based on lower growth in the United States and Europe
amidst new outbreaks, a slower vaccine rollout, and new mutations would allow for only
0.8% growth in selected countries in 2021, falling back to -1.1% in 2022 before recovering
to 1.8% in 2023—a W recovery rather than a V or a U.
Labor markets were severely impacted by both external shocks and domestic lock-
downs. An estimated 10% of total jobs were lost between February and October 2020
falling to 7% by February 2021 as economic activity recovered somewhat. That is a loss
of 26 million jobs in 12 countries in the first period in 12 countries.
Given the shock, extreme poverty is projected to increase from 12.1% to 14.6% while
moderate poverty is projected to rise from 11.7% to 14.6%. Only a strong recovery will al-
low these rates to decline significantly.
Country authorities responded with fiscal measures to help households and firms. The
size of fiscal relief packages largely reflected available fiscal space and varied across countries.
The average package was 8.5% of GDP compared to 19% of GDP in advanced economies. But
two-thirds of countries in the region implemented more modest packages of around 3% of GDP.
Fiscal relief included higher transfers to households and reduced taxes for both
families and firms.
Several countries introduced loan guarantee programs and other types of off fiscal
balance sheet support measures, particularly aimed at small and medium-sized enterprises.
ix
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Country authorities encouraged banks to reprogram loans with grace periods and longer
maturities for repayment; some countries mandated loan deferrals.
Overall fiscal deficits rose by 5.3% of GDP, from 3.0% in 2019 to 8.3% in 2020. On
average, public debt is estimated to have increased from 58% in 2019 to 72% of GDP in
2020 and in a central scenario will continue to rise to reach 76% by 2023. But a strong
recovery coupled with reforms would allow debt to stabilize at around 72% and then
begin to fall.
For tourism dependent economies, debt rose to an estimated 80% in 2020 from 63%
of GDP in 2019 and in a central scenario could rise to 87% of GDP by 2023. The unique
position of countries dependent on tourism highlights the international nature of this crisis.
Inflation remained under control in the majority of countries, and inflation expecta-
tions are well anchored. Central banks expanded their balance sheets to provide liquidity,
largely to banks and governments.
Bank balance sheets also expanded with more deposits given the high demand for
liquidity, and credit rose. But current policies hide risks; the full impacts of the pandemic
will be revealed as guarantee programs fade out and deferred loans mature.
Countries with high tax takes and high spending would benefit significantly from greater
efficiency in both taxation and spending. Better targeting of social transfer programs,
matching public wages with private sector ones, and improving government procurement
could yield up to 4.4% of GDP per year on average and more in some countries. Countries
with low tax takes should focus on increasing revenues without sacrificing growth. Higher
revenues and savings should be spent on well-considered projects with high social and
growth benefits.
Given the fiscal challenges and high debt levels, improving fiscal institutions should be
a high priority. Better institutions would enhance credibility and allow for a more gradual
adjustment with lower interest rates to ensure debt sustainability.
Most countries retained access to financial markets; that access will be important
in the months ahead to finance a stronger recovery. Countries will want to rebuild fiscal
buffers, limit dollarization, and ensure ample reserves to reduce capital-flow volatility.
Countries should take advantage of opportunities to reduce interest payments
given low international interest rates. International financial institutions (IFIs) have already
boosted their flows to the region, and further flows can help countries with additional re-
sources or to lower interest payments by replacing more expensive debt. These flows and
IFI expertise can be employed to design reforms and identify projects to boost growth.
Still, some countries may need to restructure commercial debts. Many countries now have
new generation collective action clauses which should make such restructurings easier. If
x
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
this proves to be necessary, it is best to act preemptively and seek a fast and consensual
agreement.
Central banks will have to navigate hazardous and uncharted waters in the months
ahead. With policy rates at historic lows and expanded balance sheets, they have less am-
munition. Assuming a smooth recovery, the demand for liquidity should fall and balance
sheet expansion can be reversed. Rollover risks should be monitored carefully. Policymakers
should respect and maintain central bank independence while central banks resist the
temptation to take on private credit risk or provide persistent monetary deficit financing.
History suggests that will lead to economic uncertainty and high inflation, which is then
costly to reverse.
Policies to smooth the shock in financial sectors are hiding risks, and a disconnect
between balance sheet and market indicators of risk appears to be growing. In the months
ahead, authorities may wish to allow banks to dip into buffers, write off non-viable loans
and establish recovery plans for banks where required. Ensuring balance sheets provide
a true appreciation of risks would build confidence in the financial sector. Maintaining
financial stability is needed for banks to play a constructive role in providing credit to
viable and new firms and for a healthy and sustainable economic recovery.
Recovery in the region will depend critically on the health and behavior of firms.
Leverage has risen and stock markets indicate a substantial reallocation across sectors.
Some firms may not survive, others may need assistance to realize potential opportunities.
Loan guarantee programs have been useful, but new instruments should be considered
to assist viable firms.
The region has not taken full advantage of regional or global value chains. The crisis
has provoked a reevaluation of value chains with potential opportunities for firms in the
region. Regional integration can be deepened through a bottom-up approach, making
current trade agreements consistent, and boosting regional value chains. Other policies
can help firms take advantage of global value chains, particularly small and medium-sized
firms, that find it difficult to participate on a consistent basis.
While economic recovery from COVID-19 may be already underway, previous
crises demonstrate that the pace of recovery may be uneven and biased against high
productivity sectors. Enhancing productivity through innovation and reallocation, and
investing efficiently in quality infrastructure with high spillovers on other economic
sectors, will help the region seize the opportunities for stronger post-pandemic sus-
tainable growth.
The region faces a growing environmental crisis as well as the health crisis. Adopting
ambitious climate goals does not entail any sacrifice in terms of jobs or growth. Countries
should invest for a greener and more sustainable future aimed at zero net carbon emissions
over a reasonable period of time. The right policies can create 15 million jobs by 2030 in
the region, and boost growth by more than 1 percentage point per year.
xi
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
While the months ahead will be challenging, this report details a set of policies that
should help countries realize a stronger recovery. The path out of the health crisis need
not lead back to the low growth rates of the prepandemic period but to higher rates of
growth that will benefit all, with more efficient public policies, higher productivity in the
private sector, and more sustainable economies.
xii
CHAPTER 1
W
hile 2020 started with the expectation that Latin America and the Caribbean
would grow by 1.6%, recovering from almost zero growth in 2019, these hopes
were dashed by the novel Coronavirus. COVID-19 has cost hundreds of thousands
of lives in the region and destroyed livelihoods. GDP fell by an estimated 7.4% in 2020,
the largest loss in output in a single year for the region since at least 1821.1 The crisis has
brought economic crisis to virtually all countries around the globe. The vast majority of
countries in the world recorded higher growth than that estimated for 2020 in about 80%
of all years in a well-known historical dataset. 2 The uniqueness of this crisis is that to slow
the spread of the virus, governments were forced to severely restrict the mobility of their
people and deliberately shut down large parts of their economies. Consequently, trade
collapsed, capital flows dried up, and commodity prices sank. All these factors took a toll
on Latin America and the Caribbean. 3 This chapter reviews the international experience,
focusing largely on selected advanced economies and China, and develops a set of sce-
narios depicting possible recovery paths for the region.
The coronavirus first emerged in Wuhan, a city of 11 million people in China’s central Hubei
province.4 After two phases of mild restrictions on mobility, a third phase that enforced a
strict lockdown brought the outbreak under control. 5 Other countries, such as Singapore
1 Thisstatement is based on an index created from the Maddison Project Database 2020. The loss of GDP in the
period 1930–1932 was larger for the region but no single year reached a loss of 7.4%. In 1914 with the outbreak
of the first world war, the region lost about 6.5% of GDP and the crisis of 1890 resulted in a 6% loss in output.
Data before 1890 become increasingly sparse but there were recessions in 1821 with the wars for independence;
the area defined as Peru at that time is estimated to have lost 17% of GDP in that year.
2 For 90% of the countries in the Maddison sample, growth was above that of 2020 for 79% of the time. See
4 A cluster of pneumonia of unknown origin was reported to the Wuhan office of the World Health Organization
1
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
and South Korea, also succeeded in controlling the spread of the virus with a combination
of lockdowns, large-scale testing, and contact tracing.6
In January 2020, growth for the year in China was projected to be around 6%, but the
estimate was revised down to 1% by June, given a steep fall of GDP in the first quarter follow-
ing mobility restrictions across much of the country. But as the virus was reined in and new
cases fell, cities and provinces were allowed to open. Recovery was stronger than expected
and the year closed with growth of 2.3% (see Figure 1.1). Growth projected for 2021 is 8.1%.
COVID cases grew strongly in most countries across the globe in the first quarter of
2020 and into the second quarter.7 GDP plummeted dramatically in the second quarter in
advanced economies as fear of the virus grew and lockdown policies were implemented.
In general, the lockdowns were successful in slowing the spread of the virus and reducing
the number of new cases. 8 Many advanced economies then started to reopen in the third
quarter and growth recovered. However, as countries opened, new outbreaks emerged,
and some implemented new restrictions to stop the virus from spreading.
The United States was expected to grow at around 2% for 2020 coming into the
year, but with the virus and its associated lockdowns those projections fell dramatically.
In June 2020, the IMF projected growth of –8%. However, the third quarter was stronger
than expected thanks to large fiscal support packages, the Federal Reserve’s expansion-
ary monetary policies, and many states beginning to reopen. Growth in 2020 finally came
in at –3.4% for the year. Good news on vaccines, strong corporate earnings’ reports, the
continued expected backing from the Federal Reserve, and new fiscal support inspired
US stock market indices to soar to record levels.
Growth projections for 2021 were around 2% in February 2020; but as economic
activity plummeted, projections for 2021 started to indicate a strong recovery underlying
the expectation that the COVID crisis would be temporary (see Figure 1.2). The median
of a set of private forecasters suggested growth of about 4.2% for 2021 while IMF projec-
tions are somewhat more optimistic, at 5.1%.
In January 2020, growth was projected to be 1.3% for 2020 for the Eurozone, but
this slid to –10.3% by June, as COVID cases ballooned and restrictions on movement and
economic activity were put in place. Projections then improved thanks to supportive fis-
cal and monetary policy actions and as countries began to reopen. But opening sparked
new outbreaks and some countries in the Euro area reimposed strict restrictions. Growth
for 2020 is estimated at –7.2% (see Figure 1.1).
The Eurozone’s relatively more severe loss in 2020 GDP compared to the United
States was accompanied by a larger expected rebound in 2021 (see Figure 1.2). However,
south-korea-deal-with-coronavirus-quarantine-measures/.
7 See Stein and Valencia (2020).
2
The Global Economy and Latin America and the Caribbean
recently these more favorable expectations have been downgraded, and median private
sector 2021 growth projections converged to those of the United States at around 4.2%—
similar to that of the IMF.
–2
%
–4
–6
–8
–10
–12
US Euro China UK
Source: IDB staff calculations based on IMF (2020c, 2020d, 2020e, 2020f, 2021b).
FIGURE 1.2 2021 Growth Projections for Latin America and the Caribbean and Selected
Trading Partners
7
6
Projected real GDP growth (%)
0
Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec Jan Feb
2020 2021
3
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
The economy of the United Kingdom suffered not only from the COVID shock, but
also from Brexit uncertainties. An initial growth projection of 1.4% fell to –10.2% by June.
The economy started to open but outbreaks provoked new lockdown measures, first in
certain regions but then extended to the entire country. In December 2020, a Brexit deal
was brokered, reducing uncertainties; but while the deal covers goods, it leaves open
questions about services. A new and more contagious strain of the Coronavirus originally
detected in Kent, to the south east of London, spread to other regions and has now been
detected in several other countries. The economy is estimated to have lost 10% of GDP in
2020. Growth is projected to be 4.5% in 2021.
Changes in the 2020 and 2021 growth projections highlight the difficulty of making
forecasts at this time. All growth projections are subject to errors, which may be even
larger when predicting turning points and when the previous year’s growth was nega-
tive. 9 The ongoing health crisis makes projections particularly prone to errors. While a
rebound is expected this year, it is highly dependent on success in fighting the virus.
The economic recovery that has taken place in the United States and Europe occurred
without reducing the number of COVID cases to low levels; in fact, cases, hospitaliza-
tions, and deaths continued to climb.10 As outbreaks and fears over dwindling hospital
capacity grew, policymakers introduced new measures that impacted economic activity.
The new restrictions will impact economic activity and it remains uncertain how long
they will remain in place.
At the same time, vaccines developed in record time have proven to be both safe
and effective in providing immunity against contracting COVID-19 and even more so
against serious disease, if infection does occur. This positive news at the end of 2020
sparked spikes in stock markets around the world and surely upgraded many firms’ in-
vestment plans. But the logistics of vaccinating a large proportion of the population are
daunting, especially as some vaccines require storage at very low temperatures before
use. It will take considerable time to vaccinate enough people for there to be sufficient
immunity to significantly slow the spread of the disease—what is sometimes referred to
as herd immunity. The vaccine rollout in some advanced economies, including the United
States, has been considerably slower than was hoped. With excess demand for vaccines
in most countries, delays to date have been due to whether countries acquired enough
vaccine and the logistics of rollout programs. But as more and more doses become avail-
able, doubts about the safety and efficacy of vaccination in the general population may
become more important issues.
Concern is also growing over mutations of the virus. The Coronavirus has been
around for more than a year and well over 100 million cases have been reported
4
The Global Economy and Latin America and the Caribbean
worldwide. Some individual patients appear to suffer from the disease for months. It
would be surprising indeed if mutations had not occurred, but many countries do not
routinely test for such changes in the virus. Mutations normally create more contagious
virus strains (as they are more contagious, they will tend to dominate in a population)
but not necessarily more deadly (if they kill the host too quickly then they will not
become dominant). The new strain detected in the United Kingdom appears to follow
this pattern. The so-called South African strain also appears to be more contagious;
its virulence is still under debate. Scientists believe a new strain in Brazil is also more
contagious than the original virus.11 A critical question is whether mutations might
render vaccines less effective and if so, whether vaccines can be updated quickly to
restore efficacy. In particular, there is concern that vaccines will be less effective against
the South African strain. As vaccines reduce the spread of existing strains, the fear is
that further mutations may create more contagious strains with greater resistance to
vaccines. If this happens, the result could be more hospitalizations, more deaths, and
a delayed economic recovery. While such negative developments may have adverse
implications for financial markets, they would also likely lead to low interest rates for a
prolonged period of time; in turn, low rates would support equity valuations, particu-
larly for technology and so-called stay at home stocks that have become major parts
of the standard indices.
Still, prospects for China appear to be less uncertain given that country’s success
in taming the Coronavirus. This is good news for the region, in particular for metals and
agricultural producers given China’s demand for these goods. But if China’s exports to
the United States and Europe remain subdued, then gains, particularly for metals, may be
limited as a significant proportion of China’s imports are re-exported.
There are also upside risks to the baseline. For example, the new US government
has made strides to speed up the vaccine rollout and is proposing a new US$1.9 trillion
relief program. Some analysts have even expressed concern regarding overheating and
predicted a significant consumption boom that could reverse the higher savings of con-
sumers that have spent much more time at home than usual.12 This stimulus might create
higher demand than currently expected in the United States and elsewhere, and while
this impetus would be positive for growth, it might also provoke inflationary fears. If so,
central banks may revise current forward guidance on keeping interest rates very low for
a considerable period of time.
Undoubtedly, such a statement would elicit a strong response from financial mar-
kets including rises in market interest rates and declines in equity prices. How far equities
fall may depend on the perceptions of whether current values reflect fundamentals or a
11 See, for example, AAMC (2020) on new strains and whether vaccines will be effective.
12 See, for example, Washington Post, February 4, 2021, https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/2021/02/04/
larry-summers-biden-covid-stimulus/.
5
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
bubble.13 To the extent equity prices are above fair values, then a change in central bank
messaging to indicate that rates could rise over a shorter time horizon, could provoke a
steep fall in prices.
The COVID-19 health crisis and measures to contain the spread of the virus provoked steep
declines in GDP across all countries in the region. While the region lost over 7% of GDP, a
quarter of IDB borrowers lost over 10%. COVID cases, hospitalizations, and deaths grew
steadily from March 2020 and while some countries succeeded in reducing the number
of new cases, many saw new cases rise and then stabilize at high levels. Hundreds of
thousands of lives have been lost due to COVID-19; at the time of writing, deaths were
running more than 2,000 per day and several countries were reporting greater than 60%
occupancy of intensive care beds.14 While the region has just 8% of the global population,
it accounts for 25% of global deaths from COVID-19.
Indeed, a notable positive correlation exists between countries that suffered high
COVID-19 death rates in 2020 and economic growth in that year. Figure 1.3 plots these
two variables focusing on the quadrant in which growth is negative and deaths are high.
Thus, there is no real trade-off between growth and the severity of the health crisis across
countries. Unfortunately, many countries in Latin America and the Caribbean are located
towards the bottom left of this quadrant, implying relatively low growth and a relatively
high rate of deaths. Levels of informality, health system capacity, the effectiveness of
nonpharmaceutical interventions, and limited capacity for telework may be part of the
explanation for the low-growth high-death outcome. However, many other country char-
acteristics may also be at play.
Tourism dependent countries such as The Bahamas, Barbados, and Belize, tend
to lie above the trend line, meaning their 2020 growth is even lower than their death
rates might suggest. On the other hand, Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico,
and Peru had higher death rates than would have been anticipated given their 2020
growth.
Economies were impacted through several different channels. Lockdown poli-
cies to slow the spread of the virus affected employment, the demand for goods and
services, and production. These policies varied in their effectiveness across countries.
The impacts on trading partners reduced the demand for exports and disrupted supply
which recounts increasing anxiety regarding a bubble in stocks. Some argue record volumes in option markets
are fueling the bubble. See New York Times, January 25, 2021, https://www.nytimes.com/2021/01/25/business/
stocks-options-bubble.html.
14 IDB staff calculations based on Johns Hopkins University and national sources.
6
The Global Economy and Latin America and the Caribbean
FIGURE 1.3 COVID-19 Deaths and 2020 Growth Rates Across Countries
Nicaragua China
Botswana Haiti Chad
0
Barbados Sudan Mali SenegalKenya
India Cyprus Uruguay
Finland Ethiopia Egypt
Jamaica Denmark
20 Suriname El Salvador Trinidad & Tobago World
Dominican Republic
Iraq Honduras Israel Guatemala
Paraguay
40 Germany
The Bahamas
Greece
Deaths per 100,000
Costa Rica
Lithuania
60 Netherlands
Belize
Portugal Austria
140
–20 –15 –10 –5 0 5
Source: IMF (2020d, 2021b) and Center for Systems Science and Engineering (CSSE) at Johns Hopkins University.
chains (see Chapter 7). Economies that rely on tourism were particularly hard hit, as
international travel came to a halt. Commodity producers suffered falling prices, but
metals and agricultural export prices came back relatively quickly. For example, cop-
per and soya prices finished the year well above pre-crisis levels (see Figure 1.4). Given
weak demand, particularly from the transport sector, oil prices remain below pre-crisis
levels, prompting producers including Saudi Arabia to announce export limits in an at-
tempt to prop up prices.
Exports fell by more than 10%. In aggregate, this was outstripped by the decline in
imports given reduced demand and supply constraints. Remittances recovered, assisted
by the recovery in advanced economies, particularly the United States, and government
transfers to households, which boosted disposable income; interest payments—held down
by low international interest rates—also cushioned the blow.
Current account balances improved somewhat in aggregate, from a deficit of 1.8%
of GDP in 2019 to a smaller deficit of 0.5% of GDP in 2020. However, performance varied
considerably across countries. Fiscal support packages implied a sharp decline in public
savings, but private savings rose such that total savings were roughly constant. At the same
time, lower investment was compensated by the improvement in net exports. Chapter 3
provides a more detailed analysis of trade and financial flows across the region.
7
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
80
450
Dollars per tonne (soybeans) and
cents per pound (copper)
70
60
350
50
300
40
250
30
200 20
Labor markets were severely impacted by both the external shocks and domestic
lockdowns. An estimated 10% of jobs were lost between February and October 2020, with
that figure falling to 7% by February 2021.15 Informal workers have been particularly hard
hit; about 3.5 informal jobs were lost for each formal one.16 Many countries in the region
do not have a system of unemployment benefits per se, and even in those with coverage,
benefits are limited. In Brazil, a country with one of the most developed systems in the
region, prior to the crisis only about 13% of unemployed workers received this benefit.17
Poverty has also been significantly impacted. Extreme poverty is projected to
increase from 12.1% to 14.6% while moderate poverty is projected to rise from 11.7% to
14.6%.18 The various dimensions of inequality will surely be exacerbated by the economic
crisis.19
Country authorities responded with support that included fiscal, financial, and mon-
etary measures to help households and firms. Fiscal relief included enhanced transfers to
15 This percentage was 26 million jobs lost in the first period, falling to 15 million by February 2021 in 12 coun-
19 See Busso and Messina (2020) and Bottán, Hoffmann, and Vera-Cossío (2020).
8
The Global Economy and Latin America and the Caribbean
households and reduced taxes for both families and firms. On average, the fiscal packages
were around 8.5% of GDP, but that average reflects large packages in a few countries
and smaller packages of 3% or less in many others. In contrast, advanced economies
implemented packages of 19% of GDP on average. Chapter 2 provides a more detailed
analysis of the impacts of the crisis on countries’ fiscal balances.
Several countries introduced loan guarantee programs and other types of support
measures, particularly aimed at small and medium-sized enterprises. On the financial side,
many countries encouraged banks to reprogram loans with grace periods and longer maturi-
ties for repayment, and some countries mandated loan deferrals (see Chapter 5). Currency
depreciations boosted the net worth of central banks that found ways to provide liquidity
to banks and governments. Monetary policy interest rates and reserve requirements were
reduced, allowing banks to withdraw liquidity held at central banks (see Chapter 4). All
these measures helped to soften the shock.
Fiscal deficits are spurring higher public debt ratios. In a central scenario, public
debt will rise from 58% in 2019 to 76% of GDP for the average country in 2023. The future
trajectory will be highly dependent on growth and forthcoming policies. Firms’ leverage
ratios also rose. They issued bonds abroad, but real investment has been limited and
consequently liquidity ratios have risen (see Chapter 6).
Projections for 2021 growth in the region also increased through 2020, but much
more gradually than in the Eurozone or the United States (see Figure 1.2). The baseline
projection for 2021 is a rebound in growth to 4.1%. 20 Growth is then projected to revert
to the long-run trend of around 2.5% per annum. In a statistical model that includes 14
countries in the region, baseline growth is 4.4% for 2021. This scenario assumes countries
around the world and in the region can open and grow in the second half of the year despite
a significant number of new COVID cases in most countries; it also assumes that vaccine
rollout programs advance as planned, bringing widespread immunity by the middle of the
year for most advanced countries and for the majority of emerging economies, including
in Latin America and the Caribbean.
There are significant risks associated with this projection. As countries open, increases
in new cases and hospitalization rates could prompt authorities to return to more restric-
tive measures, thereby impacting economic activity.
The logistics of vaccine rollout programs may prove more complex than anticipated,
delaying the point at which countries reach sufficient levels of immunity to open up even
more beyond the end of 2021. Virus mutations may produce strains that render vaccines
less effective, necessitating new vaccines and requiring continued restrictive measures.
The region, like the rest of the world, is in a race between the spreading virus (including
20 Themedian of private analysts in Bloomberg is about 4.2% while the IMF projects 4.1% for the region or
4.4%, excluding Venezuela from the aggregate.
9
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
FIGURE 1.5 Growth Scenarios for Latin America and the Caribbean
6
0
%
–2
–4
–6
–8
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
new strains and perhaps even new mutations) and the rollout of existing vaccines (and
the race to develop new ones effective against new strains). 21
In a negative scenario, lower growth in important trading partners such as the
Unites States and the Eurozone would hurt Latin America and the Caribbean. Figure 1.5
illustrates baseline growth and two negative scenarios. The first, labelled standard shock,
considers a shock of one standard deviation of the growth rates for the United States and
the Eurozone respectively during 2021. The second, labelled negative scenario is based
on more pessimistic assumptions for the United States and the Eurozone considered in a
negative scenario, as outlined in IMF (2020d).
The loss of GDP relative to the baseline is 4.5% for the standard shock scenario, or
a loss of 1.5% per year for the 3 years, and 8.1% for the negative scenario considering the
period 2021 to 2023, or a loss of 2.7% per year for 3 years (see Table 1.1).
The shock to growth in the United States and the Euro area impacts the entire
region, albeit differently across countries. The shock to the United States is particularly
21 TheBloomberg vaccine tracker claimed countries in Latin America and the Caribbean had contracts for
over 60% of the population as of January 2021. However, this average reflects a small number of countries
with contracts representing doses of more than 100% of populations (most vaccines require two doses) while
several countries have considerably less than the 60% average. See https://www.bloomberg.com/graphics/
covid-vaccine-tracker-global-distribution/contracts-purchasing-agreements.html.
10
The Global Economy and Latin America and the Caribbean
TABLE 1.1 Annual Loss in GDP Relative to Baseline (average 2021–23, in % of GDP)
Standard negative shock Negative scenario
Baseline
growth US Euro Combined US Euro Combined
Latin America and the Caribbean 3.2 –0.8 –0.7 –1.5 –1.3 –1.4 –2.7
Southern Cone except Brazil 3.5 –1.0 –0.8 –1.8 –1.7 –1.6 –3.2
Central America and the Caribbean 2.9 –1.1 –0.7 –1.8 –1.8 –1.4 –3.2
Brazil 2.7 –0.5 –0.5 –0.9 –0.8 –1.0 –1.8
Mexico 2.9 –1.1 –0.7 –1.9 –1.9 –1.5 –3.4
Source: IDB staff calculations.
relevant for Mexico, Central America, and the Caribbean. The Southern Cone is impacted
by the shock to the Euro area as well as to the United States. Brazil is the country least
affected.
Both scenarios imply lower growth in 2021 compared to the baseline, falling back
further in 2022 before recovering to approach trend growth in 2023. In the standard shock
scenario, growth in 2021 is 2.5%, 0.5% in 2022, and then 2.1% in 2023. In the negative sce-
nario, 2021 growth is 0.8%, falls to –1.1% in 2022, and then recovers to 1.8% in 2023. The
recovery is then more of a “W” than a “V” or even a “U.”
As noted above, there is also upward risk. New vaccines are being rolled out and
efforts are now underway to speed up vaccination programs. If the logistical problems are
solved, then immunity may build up faster than anticipated in the baseline assumed for
this report. The simulations illustrated in Figure 1.6A and B include a positive one standard
deviation shock to growth to U.S. and Euro area growth to illustrate the potential impacts
of higher growth in these advanced countries on the region.
However, a positive scenario of this nature also carries the risk that inflation exceeds
targets and that central banks feel forced to adjust their forward guidance to keep interest
rates at very low levels for an extended period of time. Just a statement of this nature,
let alone an actual change in rates, would likely have a substantial impact on equity valu-
ations and bond markets across the world. To illustrate, the impacts of a one standard
deviation fall in equity values and a larger decline calibrated to be an event with a 10%
probability (or approximately 1.64 standard deviations) are incorporated in the positive
scenarios in Table 1.2.
The resulting growth rates for the region are also provided in Table 1.2. In the case
of only a mild financial market correction, growth in the region could be as high as 5.2%
in 2021, falling to 3.9% in 2022, and 2.9% in 2023. In this case, the positive growth shock
outweighs the mild decline in global equities and associated financial market developments.
However, if the financial market correction is more marked, the benefits of the positive
growth shock are reduced. Growth is 4.5% in 2021 (just 0.1% higher than the baseline),
3.3% in 2022, and 2.9% in 2023.
11
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
8 8
6 6
4 4
2 2
0 0
%
–2 –2
–4 –4
–6 –6
–8 –8
–10 –10
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
12
The Global Economy and Latin America and the Caribbean
In the case of the one standard-deviation positive growth shock to the United States
and the Eurozone, the GDP of the region would gain a total of 4.5% over the three years
(2021 to 2023). If the financial shock is relatively mild (a one standard deviation decline
in equity prices or a drop of about 9%), then the resulting net benefit would be some
2.4% of GDP over the three years. Naturally, a deeper correction in financial markets
would reduce these benefits. A correction in equity markets representing a 10% prob-
ability event (a fall of 1.64 standard deviations or a slide of around 14%) would provide
a net benefit of just 1.2% of GDP for the region over the three years. A more dramatic
collapse in financial markets could even turn a positive growth shock into a negative
one for the region.
Again, there are differences across the region. Mexico benefits the most from a posi-
tive growth shock (largely coming from the United States) while Brazil benefits the least.
The Southern Cone, excluding Brazil, also receives relatively strong benefits from the posi-
tive growth shock. However, Mexico and the Southern Cone excluding Brazil are also hit
relatively hard by the financial market correction.
The COVID-19 crisis is unprecedented in recent history for the region, both in terms of the
associated loss of life and the economic crisis it has provoked. This chapter has provided
13
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
a brief and selective introduction, including a review of the international experience and
growth scenarios for the region.
The remainder of this report analyzes specific themes that will impact the economies
of the region and presents policy recommendations to aid in the recovery. Again, the idea
is not to be comprehensive but to provide deeper analysis in certain areas.
In Chapter 2, the fiscal response to the crisis and its impact on fiscal balances and
public debt is analyzed. The chapter also considers how countries may want to reform both
tax and public spending structures, improve institutions, and maintain fiscal sustainability
while providing support during the recovery phase.
Chapter 3 focuses on external accounts, particularly capital flows. The situation is
nuanced and while a minority of countries suffered sudden stops according to the tradi-
tional definitions, others faced a sharp withdrawal of certain types of capital. The chapter
concludes with a policy discussion on how to enhance protection against further impacts
from international markets.
Central banks have been active in the region both in terms of interest rate policy and
more direct monetary policy actions. Chapter 4 details these actions and traces the impacts
on central bank balance sheets, concluding with an assessment of the risks going forward.
The health of financial sectors generally reflects that of underlying economies. Authorities
were swift to act to support firms and families, which allowed for greater access to credit.
At the same time, loan deferral programs may be hiding risks and increase eventual losses.
Chapter 5 reviews bank balance sheets and what can be learned from market indicators of risk.
Recovery in the region will depend critically on the health and behavior of firms, and
whether they are in a position to invest and hire such that employment returns to pre-crisis
levels. An important open question is whether economies will return to their pre-crisis
composition or whether there will be significant reallocation, which in turn would impact
the health of firms. Chapter 6 analyzes firm balance sheets and considers how market valu-
ations can suggest potential reallocation.
Chapter 7 provides further analysis of a rich dataset of firms in the region. The fo-
cus is on trade, the impacts of the crisis on exports, and the participation of firms in the
region in global value chains. The results are used to distill potential policy lessons of how
to boost trade and growth.
Growth and reallocation are also the focus of Chapter 8. The crisis has particularly
impacted labor-intensive sectors due to required social distancing. Firms in Latin America
and the Caribbean tend to use more labor-intensive technologies than in other countries,
perhaps given the desire to remain more flexible in the face of economic volatility. This
chapter draws lessons for policy, given the experience during the COVID crisis compared
to what happened in and after previous crises.
The region faces not only an economic crisis but also a potential environmental one
given the deepening impacts of climate change. An important question is whether investing
14
The Global Economy and Latin America and the Caribbean
in economic recovery means sacrificing climate goals or whether a recovery plan can be
detailed that creates jobs and growth while allowing the region to meet ambitious climate
and environmental goals. This is the central question tackled in Chapter 9.
Chapter 10 draws conclusions of the report, focusing on the policy lessons derived
from each chapter. The region faces unprecedented challenges, but ample space is avail-
able for good policy to make a significant difference to boost recovery and ensure a more
sustainable future.
15
CHAPTER 2
L
atin American and Caribbean countries mobilized sizeable fiscal resources to address
the health crisis and provide economic relief, reversing the gradual fiscal consolida-
tion of prior years. Fiscal packages totaled US$485 billion—greater than the annual
GDP of Colombia, the fourth largest economy in the region.1 The average fiscal package
across countries in the region was 8.5% of GDP (see Figure 2.1, Panel A) but this aver-
age is heavily influenced by a few large packages; packages were larger in countries in
the Andean region and in the Southern Cone (Figure 2.1, Panel B). In contrast, advanced
economies implemented fiscal packages of 19% of GDP on average. 2 Fiscal support in the
region included additional spending and policies that reduced revenues and items that
are off balance sheet, or sometimes referred to as below the line (Figure 2.1). 3
Government current expenditure increased on average from 21% of GDP in 2019 to
24% in 2020, while capital expenditure decreased by 0.2% of GDP over the same period.
At the same time, fiscal revenues declined by 1.9 percentage points (pp) of GDP on aver-
age to roughly 22% in 2020, due to both the economic contraction and policy measures.
The fall in revenues was due to slower growth (an estimated 0.9% of GDP on average)
and actual policy changes (about 1% of GDP).4 As fiscal revenues declined and spending
increased, the region’s average primary balance fell an estimated 4.9 pp of GDP to –5.4%
in 2020 (Figure 2.2, Panels A and B). Over the same period, the overall fiscal balance de-
clined 5.3 pp, from –3.0% to –8.3%. Box 2.1 details the fiscal plans of countries for 2020
and their outcomes.
The increase in fiscal deficits contributed to higher debt levels, which rose from
58% of GDP in 2019 to 72% in 2020 for the average country. However, debt ratios rose
tions of debt.
4 Interestingly, revenues tend to rise faster with GDP in booms (with an elasticity or “tax buoyancy” of 1.3 for
the region) than they fall in busts (with an estimated elasticity of about 0.9).
17
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
10.0
% of GDP
9.3
10 Latin America and the
Caribbean 8.5
% of GDP
8
5.7
6 5.0
0
Andean Countries Southern Cone Caribbean Central America
Source: IDB staff calculations based on IMF-COVID tracker and national data, given data availability.
due to other factors as well. The decline in GDP contributed 4.4 pp of the total 14 pp
rise in the debt-to-GDP ratio of the average country (see Figure 2.3). Real exchange rate
depreciation increased debt by more than 3.2 pp of GDP for the average country, and by
3.6 pp for tourism dependent countries. The rise in interest payments accounted for an
additional 3 pp rise in debt ratios in the average country, and about 3.7 pp for tourism
dependent economies. Inflation acted to reduce debts, but given the relatively low infla-
tion rates (see Chapter 4), only by some 3 pp on average and less than 1 pp among the
tourism dependent countries. Debt ratios increased by less (about 10 pp), in commodity
exporting countries. Among commodity exporters, the increase in debt was driven by
higher primary deficits, (contributing 4.8 pp of GDP), higher interest payments (2.3 pp),
and lower growth (2.1 pp).
18
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
–2 –3.5
–4 –5.4
–1.8
–6 –7.4
–8
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
5
3.3
0
–0.2
–1.9
–5 –4.9
–10
–15
Suriname
Bolivia
Costa Rica
Uruguay
Guatemala
Mexico
Honduras
Guyana
Jamaica
Paraguay
Haiti
Peru
El Salvador
Nicaragua
The Bahamas
Barbados
Belize
Dominican Republic
Panama
Ecuador
Chile
Colombia
Argentina
Source: IBD staff calculations based on IMF (2020d) and national data.
Note: Current expenditure excludes payment of interests.
In general, countries’ fiscal support measures reflected the fiscal space and financing
options available. Many countries issued external debt. In addition, governments drew
down deposits at central banks, or other savings, and issued domestic debt. Central Banks
increased government bond holdings or made emergency loans for fiscal purposes (see
Chapter 4 for a discussion of central bank balance sheets). Multilateral financing comple-
mented commercial financing for many countries.
Interest payments have increased alongside debt ratios, from 10.7% of fiscal revenues
in 2019 to 13.5% in 2020 for the average country (see Figure 2.4, Panel A). This ratio
19
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
The COVID crisis has had a marked impact on countries’ fiscal plans and outcomes. This box analyzes
the explicit plans and outcomes available from national sources for a set of countries in the region.
At the start of 2020, the average country of those analyzed expected a primary deficit of 0.7%. The
deep declines in GDP plus policy measures impacted both spending and revenues.
Revenues ended up as 20.1% of 2020 GDP for this set of countries, but that is only 18.3% of
the GDP that was projected before the pandemic. This implies an effective fall in revenues of 4.4%
of GDP projected for 2020.
On the spending side, the original goal for the average government was to spend 4.3% of
projected GDP on investment, but in the end, this became 3.2% of outturn GDP, which is just 2.9%
of projected GDP, or a fall of 1.4% of projected 2020 GDP. This highlights how spending on invest-
ment, including infrastructure, loses out relative to current spending in times of stress.
Countries benefitted from low interest rates. Interest payments were planned to be 2.7%
of GDP for the average country but ended up at 3.0% of outturn GDP or 2.7% of projected 2020
GDP. Thus, despite rising debt levels, interest payments actually did not increase, and the rise was
largely due to the fall in GDP.
Looking forward, the average country is planning to collect 22.5% of GDP in revenues
and primary spending is planned to be 24.7% for a deficit of 2.2% in 2021. Instead, countries
would need a surplus of 2.7% to keep debt constant, implying a planned rise in the level of
debt. Most governments expect growth of 4.5% in 2021; fiscal outturns will depend on whether
that is realized.
In terms of fiscal institutions, 11 countries with fiscal rules all have an escape clause and ten
of the 11 used that flexibility during the pandemic. The average deviation from the primary deficit
stipulated in the rule was some 3.4% of GDP. Most countries have an explicit target to return to
the fiscal rule in 2021, with a few planning to return in 2022 and later years.
Seven countries with specific programs to reduce debt levels, announced explicit adjustment
programs that reduce the fiscal deficit by 1.4% each year for the following six years. Notably, the
adjustment is planned more on spending (0.9% of GDP per year) than on revenues (0.5% of GDP
per year). Notably, the spending cut is planned entirely in current spending and not in investment
spending. Some 12 countries are considering a significant tax reform to boost revenues.
is higher now than during both the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) and the period of low
commodity prices. For a quarter of IDB borrowing countries, this ratio has increased
to 17% or greater.
Debt service, which includes interest payments and debt amortizations, is expected
to be about 5% of GDP in 2021 for the average country and about 6.5% of GDP for about
a quarter of countries analyzed (see Figure 2.4, Panel B). Considering the amortization
schedule of today, total debt service will be stable in the years ahead for the average
country, but will increase to over 8% of GDP in 2023 for a quarter of countries. 5 Interest
payments represent about 3.2% of GDP per annum for the average country in the years
ahead.
5 These are likely underestimates as the figures reflect the amortization schedules of debt actually issued; this
analysis does not contemplate the roll-over of liabilities within the period.
20
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
10 2.9 3.7
4.8
3.2 3.6
5 2.3
4.4 4.7 0.8
0 2.1
–3.0 –0.9 –0.9
–0.8
–5
Latin America and the Caribbean Tourism dependent Commodity exporter
Source: IDB staff calculations based on IMF (2020d, 2021b) and national data.
Note: Latin America and the Caribbean includes the IDB’s borrowing countries except Venezuela. Commodity exporters
include Guyana, Bolivia, Ecuador, Colombia, Trinidad and Tobago, Peru, Chile, and Mexico. Tourism dependent countries
include The Bahamas, Belize, Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, and Panama.
COVID-19
20
17.0
15.0
15 13.5
10.4 10.4 10.9 10.6 10.7
9.4 9.1 9.1 9.9
10 9.2 8.8 8.7 8.1
5.9
5
0
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
5
5.2
4
3
2
1
0
2021 2022 2023 2024 2025
Source: IDB staff calculations based on IMF (2020d), Bloomberg data, and national sources.
The future trajectory of the debt-to-GDP ratio will hinge on the speed of eco-
nomic recovery, the pace of fiscal adjustment, interest rates, and commodity prices. In
a central scenario, the average ratio of debt to GDP rises from 58% in 2019 to 76% by
21
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
85 76 85 80 85
75 72 75 75 66
% of GDP
65 65 63 65
58 55
55 55 55
47
45 45 45
35 35 35
25 25 25
2007
2009
2011
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
2023
2007
2009
2011
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
2023
2007
2009
2011
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
2023
Expected rank Baseline
2023. This scenario assumes lower growth than the baseline in Chapter 1, but it also
assumes that countries implement fiscal adjustments. 6 If growth rates match those of
the negative scenario in Chapter 1, then debt to GDP would rise further to around 80%
by 2023. The analysis underscores the need for countries to adjust without sacrificing
growth. For example, if the region grows according to the baseline in Chapter 1, and
fiscal adjustment resembles historical patterns, then debt should stabilize at around
72% of GDP.
Debt trajectories vary given different starting positions, growth projections, and
other variables. Tourism dependent economies have higher initial debt levels (80% of
GDP in 2020), and in the central scenario, debt is projected to rise to 87% of GDP. In the
negative scenario, debt could rise to 93% of GDP. Commodity exporters start from lower
initial debt (55% of GDP in 2020), but that is projected to rise rapidly to 66% in the cen-
tral scenario and could reach 70% in the negative scenario. Again, if countries can grow
according to the baseline in Chapter 1 and adjust, then lower debt-to-GDP ratios close
to 80% of GDP can be maintained for tourism dependent countries and 59% of GDP for
commodity exporters.
All projections assume a fiscal adjustment starting in 2021 at a pace consistent with
past behavior. For the average country, the primary fiscal deficit declines to 0.4% of GDP
by 2023, for tourism dependent economies it falls to 0.8%, and for commodity exporters,
which have the most persistent fiscal deficits in the data, primary fiscal deficits shrink to
2.5% of GDP (see Figure 2.6).
6 For further details of the model and assumptions please refer to Appendix A.
22
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
2 2 2
–0.5 –0.4 –0.7 –0.8
0 0 0
% of GDP
–1.2
–2 –2 –2 –2.5
–4 –4 –4
–4.8
–6 –5.3 –6 –6
–6.1
–8 –8 –8
2007
2009
2011
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
2023
2007
2009
2011
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
2023
2007
2009
2011
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
2023
Expected rank Baseline
While the above scenarios assume fiscal adjustment, there may be resistance to paring
back spending. Countercyclical policies were implemented to sustain aggregate demand
during the global financial crisis, but additional social spending proved difficult to revert,
implying persistent increases in deficits, rather than true countercyclicality (Powell, 2012).
Two-thirds of the expansion in spending at that time was to boost salaries and transfers,
and left the region in a weaker fiscal position, even as the COVID crisis began (Izquierdo
and Ardanaz, 2020). This time around, much needed transfers to households have been
expanded and the region will face a persistent increase in the poverty headcount and jobs
lost; therefore, it may be difficult to reverse the measures. Most countries have resisted
increases in public sector wages even though they have fallen in terms of purchasing
power; unions may pressure to increase wages once recovery takes hold.
Enhancing growth would significantly improve fiscal outcomes by boosting revenues.
The timing of these interventions for recovery and growth will be key.7 It will also be criti-
cal to design both expenditure and tax policies that are efficient in terms of growth and
distributional impacts.
Now more than ever, finding the right expenditure strategy is an exercise in optimization
under severe constraints. Seeking greater efficiency should become a mantra for expenditure
7 See Izquierdo et al. (2020) for a discussion of reforms to boost growth and Chapters 7, 8, and 9 of this report
for a more detailed analysis of specific growth strategies.
23
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
policy. Temporary expenditure increases introduced to face the COVID emergency should
be removed as the health crisis dissipates and their rationale fades. The region also needs
to reallocate expenditures from inefficient to more efficient uses, and create fiscal space
to boost growth and seek greater equity.
Identifying significant technical inefficiencies is easier than assessing every expen-
diture item. Three areas likely to offer low hanging fruit are:
• Leakages in social transfers and tax expenditures. The relatively common practice
of reducing value added taxes on some critical items holds the record in terms of
leakages. No less than 84% of these “tax expenditures” end up benefiting others
rather than the poor. Energy subsidies also account for large leakages, with 81%
benefiting the nonpoor. Conditional cash transfers and noncontributory pensions
have leakages in the neighborhood of 43%. On average across IDB countries,
these three types of leakages alone amount to about 1.7% of GDP—resources
that could be put to better use.
• High public sector wages relative to those in the private sector. Accounting for
skills levels and experience, low-skilled public sector workers receive 23% higher
wages than similar workers in the private sector. This amounts to about 1.2% of
GDP of expenditure.
• Waste in government procurement. An estimated 1.4% of GDP is wasted on pro-
curement processes for goods, services, and public investment (see Izquierdo,
Pessino, and Vuletín, 2018).
Overall, savings in these three budget items alone could liberate the equivalent
of almost 4.4% of GDP for pro-growth spending or for more efficient ways to promote
equity. 8
Pension and health spending has also risen steadily, driven by the rapid aging of
the population and exacerbated by the COVID crisis. Reforms to improve efficiency and
ensure a reasonable and affordable health and pension system are badly needed. Taking
into account age distributions, spending on the elderly in Latin America and the Caribbean
even surpassed that of several developed countries (see Pessino and Ter-Minassian, 2021).
Pension systems with defined contributions and guaranteed minimum pensions combined
with the current low interest environment has heightened sustainability risks.
How could savings from more efficient spending help economies? In addition to
freeing up resources for more productive investments, efficiency could help reduce dis-
tortions that hobble growth and welfare:
8 However,the figures are very different across countries: leakages range from 1.8% of GDP in Chile to 7.2%
of GDP in Argentina.
24
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
Chile
Argentina
Panama
Brazil
Barbados
Dominican Rep.
Costa Rica
Guatemala
Peru
Paraguay
Nicaragua
Colombia
Uruguay
Bolivia
Haiti
Honduras
Mexico
Ecuador
Optimizing Taxation
The region suffers from relatively low tax revenues. At 22% of GDP, they are considerably
lower than in developed countries, including the OECD’s 34%. Still, countries vary widely
25
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
with relatively high levels in Argentina, Barbados, Belize, and Uruguay (between 29% and 34%
of GDP) and low levels in the Dominican Republic, Guatemala, Panama, Paraguay, Mexico,
and Peru (between 16% and as low as 12% of GDP).
High taxation countries also tend to be high spending countries; the focus there should
be on improving efficiency in both spending and taxation rather than raising revenues. In low-
taxation countries, assuming a minimum level of efficiency, expanding the tax base could lead
to significant benefits. While increasing overall taxation tends to negatively impact economic
growth, multipliers are low in low-taxation countries.10
Unfortunately, Latin America and the Caribbean continues to suffer from inefficient
tax design and implementation, with considerable avoidance and evasion. The tax effort
(defined as the percentage of effective tax collection as a share of GDP relative to potential
tax collection) is estimated to be about 60%, compared to 77% in advanced economies.11 If
the region could match the tax effort of advanced economies, then revenues would increase
by about 7% of GDP.
Informality is one reason for the low tax effort, but simply increasing tax rates may
induce greater informality and yet greater inefficiencies. Rather, the focus must be on tax and
benefit structures coupled with better enforcement, to reduce the incentives for informality.12
One useful way to deal with informality is through programs that reward formal employment,
particularly for low-income groups, such as the Earned Income Credit (EIC), while phasing
out noncontributory social programs for informal workers (see Box 2.2 for further details).
Although working to increase the tax effort by reducing tax evasion and informality is
key, particularly for high taxation countries, is there any room for raising taxes, and which taxes
should be raised? Twelve countries are planning a tax reform to increase revenues (see Box 2.1).
Increasing value-added-taxes (VAT) tends to damage growth less than raising income taxes.
But increasing VAT is normally considered regressive. Governments frequently exempt specific
goods (e.g., basic food) to lessen the effect on inequality. But as much as 70% of the forgone
revenue in current VAT systems in the region accrues to the nonpoor and is thus a very inef-
ficient way to transfer resources (see Izquierdo, Pessino, and Vuletín, 2018). Applying a unified
VAT tax rate without exemptions and raising more revenues, but then using those resources for
a well-targeted system of transfers to the poor, would be a more efficient policy combination.13
to third parties allowing for higher evasion. Income tax evasion is estimated to be more than 50% for the
self-employed or for those whose income stems from informal sources, while it is less than 5% for dependent
workers. See Slemrod (2019).
13 See Nuguer and Powell (2020a) for further discussion on this point. Note also that a tax credit to low-income
households is a more effective tool for improving the progressivity of consumption taxes than the zero-rating
of basic groceries (Godbout and St-Cerny, 2011; Barreix, Bès, and Roca, 2010). While this compensated VAT is
more progressive in theory, the availability of a good digital system to target beneficiaries accurately is neces-
sary to implement it—a condition not yet met by most countries.
26
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
Addressing informality in Latin America and the Caribbean is urgent. About 58% of workers in the
region have an informal job, compared to less than 20% in advanced economies and about 50% in
some countries in Asia. The region has the second highest average level of informality in the world,
only below Sub-Saharan Africa at 90%. Within Latin America and the Caribbean, 80% of workers
in the poorest decile are informal, and in some cases (Guatemala, Honduras, and Haiti), more than
80% of all workers are informal. In the aftermath of the pandemic crisis, most of the recovery in
employment will likely be in informal jobs, exacerbating already high levels of informality.
Three main reasons explain high informality in Latin America and the Caribbean. First, the
low level and quality of human capital among the poor makes it difficult for the least skilled to
enter formal labor markets. Second, labor taxes averaging 28% discourage formal hiring.b Third, to
overcome the lack of social protection in the informal sector, well-intentioned governments created
a parallel network of social protection for informal workers; these programs included Progresa in
Mexico, and Bolsa Familia in Brazil. These programs reduced poverty and inequality, but acted as
a subsidy on informality, since the benefit is lost when obtaining a formal job.
While it is true that any social program aiming at redistribution creates disincentives to
work, if society agrees to redistribute, schemes such as the negative income tax (NIT) are among
the best in that they are a minimally distorting solution. The great challenge for Latin America
and the Caribbean is to devise a scheme of ¨formal workfare¨ instead of ¨welfare¨ that rewards
those who work formally, gradually replacing subsidies for informality with minimum income
benefits for the poor that are not lost entirely if the individual lands a formal job. The secret to
these “formal workfare” systems is that the total reward for working formally (formal income
plus transfers) is always higher. When individuals start working formally, transfers do not disap-
pear; rather, they gradually decrease so that net income is always higher when working formally,
thereby rewarding formality.
Various systems in use in several countries could be adapted to the Latin American reality.
The Earned Income Credit (EITC) program, introduced in the United States in 1975, has substan-
tially increased formal employment and reduced poverty, reaching around 28 million workers
while spending only 0.3% of GDP. The overwhelming consensus in the literature is that the EITC
has raised labor force participation—particularly for single mothers, which is the group that previ-
ously faced the largest work disincentives.c In 2018, the EITC lifted about 5.6 million people out of
poverty, including about 3 million children, by supplementing the earnings of low-wage workers
and by rewarding work. Moreover, it reduced the participation of men in the informal sector by
between 5.8 and 7.3 percentage points.d Different labor income tax credit programs in at least 18
developed countries, including Canada, New Zealand, United Kingdom, Sweden, and South Korea,
with budgets ranging from 0.3% to 2.1% of GDP, could be adapted to the different realities of Latin
American and Caribbean countries.
a
Based on Pessino, Pineda, and Rasteletti (forthcoming).
b
After the 2012 tax reform, Colombia reduced payroll taxes by almost 50% and managed to increase formal
employment by 18%. See Fernández and Villar (2017).
c
Hoynes and Patel (2018).
d
Gunter (2013).
Among income taxes, there is less scope for raising either the personal income taxes
(PIT) rate or the corporate income tax (CIT) rate. PIT rates are already at levels similar to
advanced economies and, on paper, they are progressive. CIT rates at 27% on average in
27
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Latin America and the Caribbean are higher than in advanced economies (22.6%), although
revenues are similar (3% of GDP) because of smaller bases in the region. Moreover, when
adding other forms of corporate taxation, including labor contributions and other taxes,
the “effective” taxation on profits of firms for compliers can reach close to 60% in Latin
America, while it is 40% in advanced economies, and 30% in emerging Asia (PwC/World
Bank, 2019).14 With CIT statutory tax rates falling across the globe, it would be unwise to
increase them. However, there may be room to lower CIT exemptions. A significant problem
in many countries is that only formal firms pay the relatively high CIT rates, which creates
disincentives for formality.15 Increasing formality, rather than the tax rate, would be more
effective in raising revenues.
Taxation of wealth is receiving much attention in the United States and more recently
in Latin America and the Caribbean (see Saez and Zucman, 2019 and Summers and Sarin,
2019). While wealth taxes have been widely discussed, few countries have implemented
them, perhaps because they are easy to avoid and difficult to enforce. An alternative is
property taxation. Many countries in the region have such taxes but at low rates, and
only about 0.4% of GDP is collected, which is roughly half the amount collected in other
developing countries, and one-sixth that in the OECD (Corbacho, Fretes Cibils, and Lora,
2013). Property taxes appear to impact growth less and are progressive, and could thus
be increased significantly in the region.16
Governments also have new opportunities to tax activities that are detrimental to
health or the environment. Imposing carbon taxes to lower the pervasive effects of cli-
mate change could be beneficial and opportune (see Chapter 9). The region has ample
room to increase fuel taxes (or alternatively, diminish subsidies) in a context of relatively
low oil prices.17
The crisis is prompting both reallocation and innovation. Tax authorities need to
ensure that taxes are applied fairly across sectors. Digital services, for example, have en-
joyed a surge in demand, yet taxation is low for this sector. Only a few countries such as
Argentina, Chile, and Ecuador, already tax digital platforms; taxation should be expanded
throughout the region.
Another revenue-raising possibility is to reduce the relatively high level of tax ex-
penditures, currently about 3.9% of GDP; these are not only distortionary, favoring some
subnational governments, which usually have less capacity and fewer incentives to pursue this source
of tax revenue.
17 For instance, a carbon tax of US$75 per ton—necessary to meet the Paris climate objectives—has
been estimated to generate between 1% and 2% of GDP in the medium term for several countries (de
Mooij et al., 2020).
28
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
activities over others, but they also negatively impact redistribution, due to their generally
regressive nature.18
Finally, the crisis may tempt governments to increase rates on other taxes (or introduce
new taxes) like, for example, on gross receipts, wages (including payroll taxes), exports,
and financial transactions, all of which are easy to collect and, therefore, can be used to
raise revenues quickly. These taxes are, however, highly distortionary and therefore, should
be avoided. Moreover, distortionary taxes should be replaced by less distortionary options
to avoid the perilous effects on much needed investments (see Box 2.3).
Recovery from the crisis will require investment, but high corporate taxes may discourage for-
eign direct investment (FDI).a Hence, governments seek to offer fiscal regimes that appeal to
foreign investors. Tax incentives have been prevalent to attract investment but pose a dilemma
for policymakers. On the one hand, they may boost growth and employment, and attract new
technologies (see OECD, 2018). On the other hand, they negatively impact government revenues
and may introduce distortions, administrative costs, and corruption (see ECLAC/Oxfam, 2020;
World Bank, 2018).
TABLE 2.3.1 Fiscal Cost of Tax Incentives to Invest in Latin America and
the Caribbean (2016–19)
% of GDP % of tax revenue % of social spending
Argentina 1.2 4.4 8.1
Bolivia 0.9 5.0 7.7
Brazil 1.3 6.6 8.4
Chile 2.4 13.8 15.6
Costa Rica 1.9 14 15.3
Dominican Republic 1.5 10.9 19.6
Ecuador 1.4 11.7 16.0
El Salvador 1.8 10.3 19.6
Guatemala 0.7 6.8 13.4
Mexico 0.9 6.5 11.1
Paraguay 0.6 5.7 6.6
Peru 0.9 6.5 10.4
Uruguay 2.5 12.8 15.5
Source: IDB staff calculations based on ECLAC/Oxfam (2020).
Note: Social spending includes central government spending on health, education, and social protection.
18 Tax expenditures are revenues forgone by the state when it grants incentives or benefits that reduce the
tax burden for certain taxpayers in relation to a reference tax system (Pecho, 2014). In Latin America and the
Caribbean, nearly four-fifths of tax expenditure on these items benefit nonpoor households (Izquierdo, Pessino,
and Vuletín, 2018).
29
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
The evidence on the efficacy of incentives for FDI attraction is mixed.b Several studies find
tax incentives have limited effects on investment at the aggregate level. First, taxes are not the
main determinant of investment decisions. Other variables such as political stability and security,
legal and regulatory environment, and domestic market size influence investors more than taxesc
Thus, it is essential to consider these factors when designing fiscal strategies to attract investment.
Second, the efficiency of tax-incentive regimes also plays an important role. Incentives should
target investors whose decision is most likely influenced by these incentives, instead of firms that
would have invested anyway.
Frequently, incentive regimes lack of transparency reduces their efficiency and generates
economic distortions and indirect costs. In the region, tax incentives have continued to play an
important part in the region’s strategy to attract investment. Between 2009 and 2015, the average
corporate tax rate decreased from 29% to 27% and a large proportion of countries increased their
tax incentives, a pattern similar to the one observed in other developing nations.d FDI for countries
in the region remained around 3% of GDP, while tax expenditure from incentives to invest averaged
1.4% of GDP (see OECD, 2019 and ECLAC/Oxfam, 2020).
Chile and Uruguay (2.4% and 2.5% of GDP) had the highest tax expenditures associated
with investment incentives, and Paraguay and Guatemala (0.6% and 0.7% of GDP) had the lowest
(see Table 2.3.1). On average, tax expenditures in the region were almost 9% of total tax revenue
and 13% of social spending.
Preferential tax measures, such as exemptions (including tax holidays), tax rebates, and
reduced rates, remain the most widely used incentives in the region (Figure 2.3.1). These types of
FIGURE 2.3.1 Tax Incentives to Invest in Latin America and the Caribbean, by Type
(2016–19)
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
El Salvador
Guatemala
Paraguay
Costa Rica
Bolivia
Dominican Rep.
Peru
Uruguay
Brazil
Argentina
Ecuador
Mexico
Chile
30
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
measures are profit-based, which implies that they are less effective than others as their use is typi-
cally unrelated to the amount invested.e In general, cost-based measures, such as tax allowances,
tax credits, and tax deferrals (e.g., accelerated depreciation), are preferable, as these instruments
directly lower the cost of investment and, hence, are likely to be more effective. In the region, Chile
employs the most cost-based incentive measures, followed by Mexico, Ecuador, and Argentina.
In summary, fiscal incentives can play an important role, but to be effective they need to be
considered as part of a broader set of measures to attract investment. There is considerable scope
to reform the design of the tax incentive regimes used by countries in the region. These reforms
should focus on shifting tax incentives towards cost-based instruments, while also including mea-
sures to improve their administration and transparency, with the objective of lowering the indirect
cost of tax incentives and enhancing their beneficial impact on investment.
a
See, for example, Abbas and Klemm (2013), Bénassy-Quéré, Fontagne, and Lahrèche-Révil (2005), Desai,
Foley, and Hines (2006), and Djankov et al. (2010).
b
See Van Parys and James (2010), Klemm and Van Parys (2012). Available evidence specifically on Latin America
and the Caribbean is scarce.
c
See the Global Investment Competitiveness Survey in which the share of respondents that considered politi-
cal stability and security (87%), legal and regulatory environment (86%), and domestic market size (80%) as
either critically important or important was significantly larger than for low tax rates (58%) (World Bank, 2018).
d
During this period, 35% of countries in the region increased incentives in at least one sector, whereas 22%
reduced them. This compares to an average of 46% and 24%, respectively, in developing countries (World
Bank, 2018).
e
For instance, a 10-percentage-point decrease in the corporate income tax rate only reduces the likelihood of
firms considering taxes as an obstacle by 3.6%-4%. Additionally, while empirical research shows that tax holidays
also decrease this likelihood (3.3%-6.9%), the link disappears in countries with poor transport or investment
climates (World Bank, 2018).
• A Quality of Spending Unit within the Government. A unit of this type can ensure
that i) all procurement processes are competitive and transparent, and all gov-
ernment purchases, including infrastructure, are bid out; ii) public sector wages
are kept in line with private sector wages, taking skill levels into account; and
iii) transfers and subsidies have good coverage but are also well-targeted to the
poor. Such units can also evaluate the ex-ante and ex-post rates of return of dif-
ferent expenditures, and through cost-benefit analysis help reallocate expenditure
to quality infrastructure and human capital, while providing well-targeted and
efficient transfers to the vulnerable, thereby minimizing their welfare dependence.
• Congressional Budget Office (CBO). An independent fiscal institution serving elected
members of government such as the CBO in the United States and, more recently,
similar offices in Brazil and Argentina can play an important role in providing objec-
tive evaluations of reforms or projects, free of political or interest group pressure.
31
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Several countries have made concerted efforts to improve their spending planning
institutions. In the sphere of infrastructure investment, for example, perhaps the most
important innovation has been the development of national systems of public investment
regulated by an agency that is usually hosted in the finance ministry.19 To enhance the
quality of spending, these institutions regulate the processes of public investment that
guide projects from the early stages of formulation and feasibility to post-completion
evaluation. Improving their efficacy and lengthening the planning horizons would prob-
ably require shielding them from political interference. 20
In addition, smart spending reviews should be conducted regularly to analyze whether
spending is efficient or can be improved, including through reallocation. Well-prioritized
results-based budgeting should help to reassign resources every year to the best programs
while reducing, or even eliminating, those programs that are not performing.
Critically, tax authorities must also work efficiently and closely coordinate with the relevant
ministry or secretary in charge of revenues. Information systems that aggregate the different
sources of income and assets of individuals are key to allocate transfers and subsidies, or to
determine who should be paying taxes and to detect anomalies worthy of further investiga-
tion. Smart digital fiscal systems should be put in place to integrate administrative data from
public and private sources.21 These systems will be necessary to help rapidly formalize the
economy and develop an efficient system of taxes, while controlling and auditing informality.
Given the uncertainty about fiscal sustainability, well-designed fiscal rules can enhance
the credibility of future plans. For countries that already have fiscal rules in place, several
have communicated an explicit path to return to compliance (see Box 2.1). Assuming
those commitments are credible and maintained, this should improve the conditions to
finance the transition.
19 As of 2019, several countries set up National Systems of Public Investment (SNIPs; “Sistemas nacionales de
inversión pública” in Spanish): Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador,
El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, and Uruguay.
20 See Cavallo, Powell, and Serebrisky (2020) and references therein.
21 Pessino (2017) and Izquierdo, Pessino, and Vuletín (2018) explain how to implement these systems with the
example of Argentina, which could cut 1% of GDP in inefficient spending by targeting energy subsidies, while
fueling third-party data to tax administrations to diminish tax evasion.
32
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
5 20
Public investment growth rate (%)
–5 10
–10 5
–15 –0
–20 –5
–25 –10
Source: Ardanaz
0 et1al. (2021).
2 3 4 5 6 0 1 2 3 4 5 6
Note: The figure shows the estimated dynamic effects of a fiscal rule on the growth rate of real public investment, based on a
Years Years
regression model. Year 1 is the year of the start of a fiscal consolidation episode. Dashed lines are the 90 percent confidence
intervals.
A few countries have an explicit target to reduce debt (see Box 2.1) with a gradual
adjustment program. There may be benefits to including explicit debt limits within the
fiscal rules.
Fiscal rules should be evaluated and revised as necessary. In some cases, lax targets on
structural fiscal balances following expansionary policies during a crisis, or over-optimistic
assumptions regarding revenues, including from natural resources, allowed debt ratios to
rise despite abiding by the rule.
Another useful revision would be to ensure rules protect public investment during
downturns. Flexible fiscal rules can significantly safeguard public investment under fiscal
consolidation either directly through investment-friendly provisions (i.e., rules that exclude
capital expenditures from targets imposed on fiscal aggregates) or indirectly through cy-
clically adjusted fiscal targets, or well-defined escape clauses. In countries with either no
fiscal rules or rigid ones, a fiscal consolidation of at least 2% of GDP is associated with an
average 10% reduction in public investment. Instead, in countries with flexible fiscal rules,
the negative effect of fiscal adjustments on public investment vanishes (see Figure 2.8). 22
The COVID-19 crisis has dramatically impacted growth and fiscal outcomes. Countries
face difficult choices and walk a narrow path of maintaining fiscal sustainability while
providing support to economies.
33
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
23 Emergency financing includes the Rapid Financing Instrument and other emergency lines and readjust-
ments; back stops include the Flexible Credit Line, Precautionary Liquidity Line and Extended Fund Facility.
24 See https://www.worldbank.org/en/news/factsheet/2020/04/02/world-bank-response-to-covid-19-coro-
navirus-latin-america-and-caribbean.
25 For example, Reinhart and Rogoff (2020) argue for a debt standstill while Cárdenas and Guzmán Ayala
Uruguay as high income, Haiti and Nicaragua as low income, and the remainder are in the middle-income category.
34
Fiscal Policy for a Sustainable Recovery
new resources from multilaterals would be valuable (Arellano, Bai, and Mihalache, 2020).
The benefits of debt relief on commercial debt depends critically on the assumed costs
of restructuring. If renegotiating existing debt is not too costly, then the benefit of relief,
compared to the alternative of restructuring, declines.
Some research suggests countries face a difficult choice if they need to renegotiate
commercial debts. They may “reprofile,” which means pushing out maturities, but with no
principal haircut and a limited present value haircut on the amounts owed. This reprofiling
may be done relatively quickly, may be voluntary (in the sense of reaching an agreement
with creditors), and buys time, but it may not always solve the underlying problem. If it
doesn’t, then the country may have to reprofile again, or multiple times. Belize and Jamaica
have reprofiled debts several times over the last decade or so. 27 Alternatively, a country
might seek a deeper restructuring, with a larger principal haircut and greater likelihood of
solving the underlying debt overhang. However, that option carries a greater likelihood of
disagreements with some creditors, provoking legal actions in international courts that may
complicate and delay the process. The international financial system had favored “bipolar
debt restructurings,” meaning the distribution of haircuts had twin peaks with most coun-
tries reprofiling and a few seeking deeper restructurings (Powell, 2011). However, recent
innovations in bond contracts known as the new Collective Action Clauses (CACs) may
have provided a more efficient and faster route for countries to restructure. 28 Argentina
and Ecuador have successfully renegotiated debt aided by CACs. 29 Still, it is perhaps too
soon to conclude that the new generation CACs have solved all the underlying issues in
the international financial architecture.
Low-income countries have rightly been a focus of discussion regarding international
support as debt tends to come from official sources—from countries (bilateral debt) and
multilateral institutions. The G20 has agreed on a framework for assistance and countries
have been encouraged to extend debt relief on bilateral debt (World Bank, 2020b). An issue
has arisen with debt owed to countries outside of the usual Paris club of creditor countries.
Some loans are not strictly bilateral, are structured more akin to commercial lending, and
are extended by a variety of institutions in creditor countries. 30 The international commu-
nity has been working towards greater transparency regarding all types of creditors and
encouraging creditor countries to include all types of lending into any relief arrangements.
The 1980s was a lost decade in terms of growth for Latin America and the Caribbean,
in part as a result of a string of sovereign defaults commencing with Mexico in 1982. Given
27 In the case of Jamaica, only domestic debt was reprofiled; in Belize, actions focused on external debt.
28 On the new Collective Action Clauses see IMF (2020b).
29 See Mariscal el al. (2015) and IMF (2020b) on debt restructuring choices. IMF (2020b) argues that preemp-
tive restructurings (which are mostly reprofilings in the data) are less costly.
30 In Latin America and the Caribbean, principally the loans from China’s official banks and other agencies and
those within the context of Petrocaribe (Venezuela) are outside the usual Paris club bilateral debt.
35
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
the growth in debt, there is a natural concern that this could happen again. A relatively
small number of large international banks accounted for much of the external lending
at that time. One theory suggests that renegotiations should have been straightforward
as there were relatively few creditors. But bankers and their regulators were reticent to
recognize the losses on lenders’ balance sheets and dragged the process out. The debt
and the specter of default persisted, affecting investment and growth. In several coun-
tries, sovereign defaults were accompanied by domestic banking crises. Arguably, the
lost decade did not result from the defaults per se, but rather the long delays in resolv-
ing them and complications in the interim (see Cavallo, Fernández-Arias, and Powell,
2014). Countries only escaped the default trap when the debt was converted to bonds
and sold through the so-called Brady deals (see Cavallo, 2020). The policy lesson is, if
restructuring is required, resolving the debt overhang quickly is less costly than delaying
the inevitable. The good news today is that more countries have new generation CACs in
their bond contracts. Therefore, if bad scenarios arise and debt has to be restructured, it
may happen more swiftly. 31
The next few years will be challenging as countries seek to boost growth and bring
debt ratios down. The risks are very real. The war against the virus is not yet won in Latin
America and the Caribbean and a serious second wave in the United States or Europe
could hurt global recovery. Getting the adjustment policies right and maintaining financial
stability will be critical for a healthy recovery.
31 See IMF (2020b) for an updated list of countries that have adopted the new generation CACs.
36
CHAPTER 3
T
he COVID-19 pandemic hit the region directly via supply and demand shocks, and
indirectly through its impact on the rest of the world. When the pandemic struck,
external demand fell and financing conditions tightened, particularly at the peak
of the crisis. But the impacts of the shock on external accounts varied across countries.
This chapter explores how the COVID-19 shock impacted the current and financial
accounts of the balance of payments. The results highlight the importance of fundamen-
tals: countries with better initial conditions including lower fiscal deficits, lower liability
dollarization, and higher levels of international reserves were more resilient.
The pandemic hit the region through many channels including trade and financial links.
Tourism dependent economies, for example, were hurt by the sharp decline in international
travel, and commodity exporters suffered the slump in prices.
Table 3.1 reports the median annual growth rates of goods, services, total exports, and
imports for different country groups. Countries were classified into three groups according
to their export composition. Tourism dependent includes the top third (7 of 22 countries)
employing a Tourism Dependence Index.1 The commodity dependent countries comprise
the top half of the non-tourism countries with the highest share of commodity exports
to total exports. The diversified countries are the remaining 8 economies. 2 By the second
quarter of 2020, exports of goods fell across the board, but countries in the commodities
group experienced larger declines. Tourism dependent countries suffered the greatest
drop in exports of services although other countries also registered significant declines.
Exports of goods and services plus interest earned on external assets plus remittances
1 SeeMooney and Zegarra (2020) for further details on the tourism dependency index.
2 The countries included in this analysis were those with available 2020 external accounts’ data at the time
this chapter was prepared. Guyana was excluded given the large increase in oil production. Appendix B de-
scribes the methodology in detail and presents information for each economy and the classification for 26
Latin American and Caribbean economies.
37
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
TABLE 3.1 Annual Change in Current Account Flows (Second Quarter 2020, %)
Total CA Exports: Exports: Exports: Imports:
credits total goods services total
Tourism groupa –11.83 –14.53 –6.47 –18.25 –13.69
Commodities –10.41 –10.56 –10.33 –16.38 –10.81
groupb
Diversified groupc –3.70 –5.21 –0.23 –14.50 –7.90
25th percentile –11.46 –13.48 –10.85 –20.86 –15.20
Median –9.17 –10.28 –6.95 –16.45 –10.64
75th percentile –3.76 –6.59 –0.57 –12.56 –6.83
Source: IDB staff calculations based on BOPS database (IMF).
Note: Countries for which all variables are available are included. Values for tourism, commodities, and diversified groups are
medians. Total CA credits are the sum of goods and services exports, and the credits of primary and secondary income. Total
exports are the exports of goods and services. Total imports refers to the imports of goods and services. Data for Haiti are for
first quarter 2020. For a more detailed explanation of the construction of the series see Appendix B, Section 1.
a
Tourism group is the top half of non-tourism economies ranked according to the Tourism Dependence Index (from Mooney
and Zegarra, 2020). Includes: The Bahamas, Belize, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Haiti, Jamaica, and Panama.
b
Commodities group contains the top third of economies ranked according to the fraction of commodities in its total
merchandise exports (from UNCTAD, 2019). Includes: Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Paraguay, Peru, and Uruguay.
c
Diversified group includes: Argentina, Brazil, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, and Suriname.
add up to total current account (CA) credits, which fell more than twice as much for the
tourism and commodity dependent countries as for the diversified group.
Imports declined in all countries. The median country suffered a 10.6% drop in im-
ports, outstripping the 9.2% decline in total current account credits. The diversified group
saw a larger fall in imports relative to exports and relative to total current account credits,
and hence watched their current accounts narrow the most. But tourism dependent and
commodity dependent countries underwent larger absolute declines in imports and for
both groups, the drop in imports surpassed the median.
Remittances to the region have proven resilient during the COVID-19 shock. Among the
countries for which annual remittances exceed 5% of GDP, including Belize, the Dominican
Republic, El Salvador, Guatemala, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, and Nicaragua, the annual
growth rate of remittances fell to 4.9% in the first quarter of 2020, down from 7% in 2019
and 8.9% in 2018. However, they recovered to an annualized growth rate of 6.2% in the
second quarter and 7.8% in the third quarter. For the region, remittances slipped by only
0.2% in 2020, which is less than the decline in other regions (World Bank, 2020b) and
better than expected given the severity of the shock (Parrado, Armangué, and Herrera,
2020). The U.S. economy’s better than expected performance (see Chapter 1) as well as
the U.S. government's income support and direct transfers to households may have buoyed
remittances. Currency devaluations and expanded financial inclusion may also have played
a role, not only in Latin America and the Caribbean but across the globe. 3 Irrespective of
the drivers, remittances proved to be a source of strength for external accounts in 2020.
38
The External Sector: Focus on Financial Flows
–2
% of GDP
–4
–6
–8
–10
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
4 Current
Account (CA) balances in the region had been improving since 2013, as shown in Figure 3.1. The
median commodities group economy had the highest overall balance, while the tourism one had the lowest
throughout this period.
39
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
to build savings abroad) precisely when additional financing would allow import levels to
be maintained. The following section explores developments in capital flows and which
countries suffered sudden stops. 5
Most countries were able to borrow from nonresidents during the critical first two
quarters of the pandemic (see Figure 3.2).6 The figure provides a snapshot of financial
flows up to the second quarter of 2020. The convention in this chapter is that a posi-
tive number means an inflow of funds to the economy—either an increase in external
15
10
% of GDP
–5
–10
–15
Suriname
Dominican Republic
Chile
El Salvador
Argentina
Jamaica
Ecuador
Uruguay
Brazil
Mexico
Haiti
Nicaragua
Bolivia
Costa Rica
Guatemala
Colombia
Peru
Paraguay
Belize
Honduras
Panama
The Bahamas
5 SeeCavallo (2019) for a recent review of the literature on capital flow events including sudden stops.
6 Atthe time of writing, data for second quarter 2020 was available for 23 of 26 IDB borrowing member
economies. Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras,
Mexico, Nicaragua, Paraguay, and Suriname also had data available for third quarter. This analysis employed the
IMF’s Balance of Payments’ Statistics (BOPS) database. As standard in the literature, the focus is on financial
account flows excluding reserve related items, as presented in the analytic version of the balance of payments.
More details about the database are in Appendix B..
40
The External Sector: Focus on Financial Flows
liabilities, or a decrease in external assets. Dark blue bars in Figure 3.2 represent the
flows of nonresidents (often referred to as inflows). Since most dark blue bars in the
figure are positive, that means those countries had positive net borrowing with the rest
of the world (i.e., they were able to borrow more than they had to pay back to nonresi-
dents during this period). Light blue bars represent the flows of residents, that is, the
net changes in residents’ foreign asset holdings (often referred to as outflows). Netting
inflows and outflows indicates that 12 countries received net positive flows (i.e., green
dots in Figure 3.2 are positive).
However, most countries in the region were already net borrowers before the pan-
demic hit, meaninig they were receiving net positive financing flows prior to COVID-19.
Countries may have been forced to engineer a current account adjustment even if net
flows remained positive. The question becomes whether financing flows kept up with the
pre-crisis pace.
Sudden stops in net flows (SS) are defined taking into account the existing level of
flows. This chapter draws on Calvo (1998) to define a sudden stop as an event in which
the annual change in net capital flows is more than two standard deviations below the
mean for at least one quarter.7 In terms of timing, the event starts in the quarter when the
yearly change in capital flows falls below one standard deviation, and finishes once the
capital flows are restored back to the one standard deviation threshold.
Perhaps surprisingly, only 7 of 22 countries analyzed suffered a sudden stop dur-
ing the first three quarters of 2020 (see Figure 3.3 and Table 3.2). In Figure 3.3, a green
dot below the line marking the country specific threshold indicates a sudden stop in
that quarter. 8
The episodes are listed in Table 3.2 along with the start date (i.e., when the annual
change in net flows fell below one standard deviation of the mean) and the effective date
(i.e., when the annual change in net flows fell below two standard deviations of the mean).
The final column indicates whether there was a sudden stop in inflows (SSI) or outflows
(SSO), following the taxonomy outlined in Cavallo et al. (2015).
In four of the cases listed in Table 3.2, the sudden stop start date is before 2020,
meaning external financing conditions had already begun to weaken before the pandemic
hit, with some countries in a more vulnerable position than others. In all cases, except
Argentina, the sudden stops became effective when the pandemic hit the economies in
7 The SS threshold for an economy is defined as the mean net flow minus two standard deviations of the
country’s flows. Forbes and Warnock (2012) is used for dating sudden stops.
8 In several countries, residents increased savings abroad from previous levels (i.e., the light blue bars in Figure 3.2
representing annual changes in asset flows are mostly negative). Several countries suffered a reduction in external
liabilities from the previous trend (i.e., some dark blue bars are negative). Suriname is the only country in an SS
in second quarter 2020 where the SS threshold is not breached in that period. It breached the threshold in third
quarter 2020, triggering a sudden stop. The event is then determined to have started in second quarter 2020.
41
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
4.0
1.5
–1.0
% of GDP
–3.5
–6.0
–8.5
–11.0
–13.5
–16.0
Suriname
Bolivia
Dominican Republic
Argentina
Chile
Jamaica
Brazil
Mexico
Haiti
Peru
Colombia
Guatemala
Costa Rica
Belize
Paraguay
The Bahamas
Honduras
Panama
Nicaragua
Uruguay
Ecuador
El Salvador
42
The External Sector: Focus on Financial Flows
full force, in either the first, second, or third quarter of 2020. In the Dominican Republic,
the sudden stop lasted only one quarter because in the third quarter, the government was
able to issue sovereign debt, which resulted in inflows of 3.5% of GDP. 9
In Argentina and Suriname, a sudden reduction in foreign lending (SSI) triggered
the sudden stops in net flows (see Table 3.2, last column). In Bolivia and the Dominican
Republic, the trigger was an outflow from domestic residents (SSO). In Ecuador, SSI and
SSO combined to cause the sudden stop in net flows. And in Chile and Mexico, neither SSI
nor SSO were to blame; less severe fluctuations in foreign lending and residents increasing
foreign asset holdings combined to trigger a sudden stop in net flows.
The literature on the causes of sudden stops identifies specific domestic characteristics
that interact with external conditions to increase the likelihood of sudden stops in net
capital flows. Those features are: the current account and the fiscal deficit—both of which
are proxies for the country’s demand for external financing; and the amount of hard
currency-denominated debt, which affects the country’s ability to undergo real exchange
rate depreciations without triggering private and public bankruptcies. On the flip side,
foreign reserves increase resilience against sudden stops.
Table 3.3 compares these factors in 2007, before the Great Financial Crisis (GFC),
and in 2019, before the COVID-19 pandemic. The comparison is relevant because in the
aftermath of the GFC, the region was able to successfully navigate through the crisis,
avoiding sudden stops in net flows, likely thanks to strong initial conditions. Was this the
case prior to the pandemic? The answer is nuanced. Compared with the pre-GFC period,
by the end of 2019 the region had weaker fiscal balances and lower current account defi-
cits,10 while liability dollarization levels had improved in some countries and were worse
in others.11 International reserves were higher across the board.12
Table 3.4 employs the economic model of Calvo, Izquierdo, and Loo-Kung (2012) to
explore whether the sudden stops that countries experienced were predicted by the initial
conditions in Table 3.3. The table places 14 countries into one of four quadrants: whether a
total debt, was identified by Calvo, Izquierdo, and Mejía (2008) as a key external vulnerability indicator.
A decade of ultra-low interest rates by central banks of advanced economies fueled an increase in this
indicator.
12 Terms of trade were favorable for the commodity group, and several tourism economies benefited from a
43
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
sudden stop was predicted and happened (top left); whether a sudden stop was not predicted,
and it did not happen (bottom right);13 whether a sudden stop was predicted but did not
occur (bottom left); and whether a sudden stop was not predicted but actually happened.
The model predicts the outcomes well: three countries had sudden stops that were
predicted and eight countries that were predicted not to have a sudden stop did not have
one. The exceptions are Costa Rica and Uruguay where the model gives a false positive—it
predicted a sudden stop that did not materialize—and Mexico, which suffered a sudden
stop that was not predicted.14
Most sudden stops that occurred during 2020 could be successfully predicted us-
ing a parsimonious model that relies on a small set of key domestic factors before the
crisis. The conclusion is that initial conditions played a significant role in determining who
suffered a sudden stop and who did not, despite the global nature and the magnitude of
the COVID shock.
13 These14 countries had all the data available to perform this analysis.
14 Themodel calculates the probability of a sudden stop which is then transformed into a prediction applying
a threshold. The threshold that maximized the signal-to-noise ratio was employed.
44
The External Sector: Focus on Financial Flows
About a third of countries experienced a sudden stop in net flows in 2020 (see Table 3.2).
Other countries, however, experienced either a reduction in net lending from foreigners—
what is known as a sudden stop in inflows (SSI)—or a sudden increase in net savings from
residents abroad—also known as a sudden start in outlfows (SSO)—but did not experience
sudden stops in net capital flows. While sudden stops in net flows are likely to be painful
due to the required adjustment in the current account, gross flows sudden stops are not
painless and may cause financial instability.15
Before the global financial crisis, a majority of the sudden stops affecting emerging
countries, including in Latin America and the Caribbean, were triggered by variations in
the flows from foreigners (gross inflows). Since then, gross inflows have remained sig-
nificant, and the importance of external asset flows (gross outflows) has increased.16 As
gross flows become relatively more important in the overall external financing picture,
their behavior during the COVID-19 shock is worth considering.
The algorithm employed to identify sudden stops in net flows can be applied to
identify sudden starts in outflows (SSO) on the asset side, and sudden stops in inflows
(SSI) on the liability side, and their respective start and effective dates.
Table 3.5 shows which countries experienced either an SSO or an SSI during COVID
that were not sudden stops in net capital flows. Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, and
Paraguay twice, had SSOs that did not become sudden stops in net flows because resi-
dents’ capital flight was compensated at least in part by capital inflows from foreigners
(see dark blue bars in Figure 3.3). Conversely, Brazil and Peru experienced SSIs that
did not become sudden stops in net flows, meaning that resident investors repatriated
foreign-held assets and offset the reduction in foreign lending (see light blue bars in
Figure 3.3).
Figure 3.4 shows the annual change in gross outflows (green dot), decomposed according
to specific asset classes, along with the SSO threshold (yellow line) for 22 Latin American
and Caribbean economies. Eleven of the 12 countries with the highest outflow as a percent-
age of GDP (aligned to the left of the figure) experienced either a sudden stop in net flows
(SS), or an SSO, or both at the same time. The other countries presented more nuanced
15 See Cavallo et al. (2015) for discussion on sudden stops in gross and net flows and which ones are most
painful.
16 See Forbes and Warnock (2012) and Broner et al. (2013) for earlier examples of literature on sudden stops
and gross flows and Cavallo (2019) for a more recent literature survey.
45
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
movements in gross outflows. Regarding the asset types driving the fluctuations, “other
investments” (dark blue bars) contributed the most to the fall in asset flows in 9 of the
14 countries where the green dot is below zero. Volatility in other investments, which are
mostly banking flows, are more likely to be tied to financial instability than fluctuations in
other types of flows (Cavallo, et al., 2015).17
At the other end of the spectrum, to the far right of Figure 3.4, Brazil and Peru are
among the countries with the largest increases in asset related flows, meaning there was
capital repatriation on net (i.e., the green dot is above zero).18 Brazil and Peru simultane-
ously experienced a sudden stop in inflows. Therefore, the offsetting repatriation helped
prevent the SSI from becoming a sudden stop in net flows.19 Argentina and Suriname,
on the other hand, also faced SSI during that period. However, those countries had no
capital repatriation on the asset side to prevent the SSI from becoming sudden stops
in net flows.
The factors behind the asymmetric response of outflows amidst SSIs has been the
focus of recent research. Cavallo, Izquierdo, and León-Díaz (2020) argue that sudden
stops in net capital flows are more likely to be prevented in countries with strong and
credible macroeconomic frameworks. Computing the correlation between the exchange
rate regime and gross capital flows during COVID-19 helps determine if that was the case
17 Almost all asset-related outflows are savings from the private sector that are mostly channeled through
financial institutions. A small fraction of Chile and Colombia’s flows are related to sovereign wealth funds
from commodity export proceeds. A small portion of Ecuador’s outflow comes from government cash
deposits.
18 The Bahamas had strong asset inflows, likely due to compensatory flows linked to the offshore banking
industry. The correlation between asset and liability flows in The Bahamas is 0.99, hence the SSO and SSI
thresholds are large.
19 Prevented sudden stops is the term coined by Cavallo, Izquierdo, and León-Díaz (2020) for situations in
46
The External Sector: Focus on Financial Flows
2
% of GDP (– outflow, + inflow)
–2
–4
–6
–8
–10
–12
Chile
Bolivia
Dominican Republic
Uruguay
Suriname
Paraguay
Mexico
Argentina
Costa Rica
Guatemala
Panama
Haiti
Brazil
Colombia
Honduras
Belize
Nicaragua
Peru
Jamaica
The Bahamas
El Salvador
Ecuador
during the COVID crisis. 20 Countries with stronger and more credible macroeconomic
frameworks are more likely to allow the exchange rate to float (Calvo and Reinhart, 2002).
When gross outflows, inflows, and net flows are standardized, a positive rank correlation
(+0.27) emerges between gross outflows and exchange rate flexibility. Moreover, a nega-
tive correlation exists between exchange rate flexibility and gross inflows (–0.15). Together,
the correlation between exchange rate flexibility and net flows is close to zero (–0.08). 21
Thus, countries with greater exchange rate flexibility during COVID were more likely to
see gross inflows and outflows moving in opposite directions, which in turn resulted in
more stable net capital flows.
20 This analysis uses the 2019 Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions AREAER
from the IMF, which classifies the exchange rate regime of each country into one of ten categories, ranging
from the least flexible fully dollarized economies (no separate legal tender) to the most flexible fully floating
exchange rates (free floating).
21 Since AREAER category numbering is meant to be ordinal, the Spearman rank correlation is reported.
47
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
While residents’ external asset flows varied widely during the COVID-19 shock, develop-
ments on the liabilities side were also important.
Figure 3.5 shows the annual change in gross inflows by type of flow. The country
on the far left side of the figure is Jamaica, which suffered a significant drop in inflows;
however, given the volatility of Jamaica’s inflows, the fall did not trigger a sudden stop.
The four countries with the next largest contractions in inflows as a percentage of GDP
1
% of GDP
–4
–9
–14
Jamaica
Brazil
Argentina
Suriname
Peru
Dominican Republic
The Bahamas
Haiti
Mexico
Colombia
Bolivia
Guatemala
Chile
Belize
Nicaragua
Honduras
Costa Rica
Panama
Paraguay
Uruguay
Ecuador
El Salvador
48
The External Sector: Focus on Financial Flows
experienced only a sudden stop in inflows (Brazil and Peru) or sudden stops in inflows
and net flows (Argentina and Suriname).
At the other end of the spectrum, on the right side of the figure, countries experienced
an increase in inflows. In Guatemala, El Salvador, and Paraguay, the surge was enough to
offset a concurrent increase in foreign asset holding by residents that classify as SSOs
(Table 3.5). Guatemala’s liability inflows remained about the same as during the preced-
ing year, which was enough to offset the capital flight on the asset side. In El Salvador
and Paraguay, gross inflows expanded significantly during the crisis which implies these
countries were able to boost foreign borrowing while resident investors were increasing
foreign asset holdings.
The most significant variation on the liability side of the financial account comes
from portfolio and other investment flows (purple and dark blue bars in Figure 3.5). Net
portfolio liability inflows contracted significantly in Brazil and Peru during COVID-19.
Instead, in Chile and Colombia, net portfolio flows remained steady due to large private
debt issuances (see Chapter 6). In smaller countries, the government and the central bank
account for almost all portfolio liability inflows. 22
Other investment liabilities include private flows (i.e., commercial bank loans) and
official lending to countries (bilateral and multilateral). Official lending increased during
COVID-19, especially among the countries with more limited market access. Instead, the
commercial bank loans portion of the other investment liabilities declined and was pro-
cyclical, thereby contributing the largest share of the decline among the countries where
other investment liabilities dropped. The volatility of the private flows component of other
investment liabilities should be monitored because it has been the source of financial
instability in the past (Brunnermeier et. al, 2012).
As the pandemic hit the region, both exports and imports fell and financial conditions
deteriorated, especially during the critical first half of the year. Current account balances
remained broadly stable, but experiences varied widely across the region. On the financing
side, governments that could, borrowed heavily, including from nonresidents, to finance
higher fiscal deficits. Households, facing negative income shocks, also borrowed to smooth
consumption. Firms, facing lower demand, invested less, but some issued bonds abroad,
thereby increasing liquid assets (see Chapter 6). While external financing was available
for some countries, about one-third of all countries analyzed experienced sudden stops
in net flows. Interestingly, most of the sudden stops that materialized were successfully
predicted with a model that considers the state of key macroeconomic factors at the end of
49
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
2019. Thus, while the COVID-19 shock affected all countries, those with weaker pre-existing
conditions, including higher fiscal and current account deficits, higher levels of liability
dollarization, and low international reserve buffers, suffered greater outflows of capital.
Going forward, countries will need to roll over external debt and finance fiscal defi-
cits that may require additional external financing. As economic recovery gathers steam,
investment is likely to increase, leading to greater external financing needs (see Chapters 8
and 9). Countries that lacked buffers before the pandemic, and those that depleted those
buffers during COVID-19, should rebuild them to prevent painful capital flow volatility in
the future as well as to finance the recovery. External financing may become a constraint,
especially if global interest rates start to rise. Official financing from international financial
institutions will likely be in high demand in the coming years.
50
CHAPTER 4
C
entral banks in the region reacted swiftly to the challenges posed by the COVID-19
crisis. They reduced policy interest rates and reserve requirements and provided
liquidity assistance, principally to banks and governments. These policies helped meet
the demands for greater liquidity and assisted families and firms without compromising
monetary and financial stability. Inflation remained low, with expectations well anchored
in the vast majority of countries.
Central bank balance sheets expanded considerably through 2020, and with policy
interest rates at record lows, the space to provide more stimulus going forward is lim-
ited. Moreover, the full impacts of the various policy measures are yet to be fully realized
and uncertainty remains over future demand for liquidity. Further challenges to ensure
consistency between fiscal and monetary policy measures may arise. Central banks will
have to navigate through potentially hazardous and uncharted waters in the aftermath
of the pandemic.
Most central banks in Latin America and the Caribbean maintained low inflation rates
through 2020 (see Figure 4.1). Amidst the COVID crisis and the wide range of policy re-
sponses, the median inflation rate in the region remained stable at around 3% per year.
The countries that are either fully dollarized or adopted a hard peg to the US dollar (fixers
in Figure 4.1) continued to record the lowest inflation, whereas the group of established
inflation targeters (established IT) and those with intermediate regimes converged to
similar, slightly higher rates. Recent inflation targeters (countries that adopted inflation
targeting regimes within the last 15 years) saw inflation drift up above 5% per annum for
the first time since 2014 by the end of 2020, although in January 2021, inflation came
back down to 3.9%. In four other countries (Argentina, Haiti, Suriname, and Venezuela)
inflation exceeded 20% in 2020.1
1 Venezuela remains in a deep economic crisis with a further large loss of output in 2020 and very high inflation.
51
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
15
13
Median annual inflation (%)
11
–1
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
Fixers Intermediate Recent IT Established IT Median
Source: IDB staff calculations based on central banks’ data and Haver Analytics.
Note: This figure depicts median inflation rates for different exchange regimes. Established IT: Brazil, Chile, Colombia,
Mexico, and Peru; Recent IT: Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Guatemala, Jamaica, Paraguay, and Uruguay; Intermediate:
Argentina, Bolivia, Haiti, Honduras, Nicaragua, and Trinidad and Tobago; Fixers: The Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Ecuador,
El Salvador, Guyana, Panama, and Suriname.
The crisis and associated lockdowns provoked a steep fall in demand but also a
set of supply constraints that varied across products. Government support measures
also impacted demand. Still, with lockdowns in many countries, the drop in demand was
most pronounced in the second quarter of 2020, producing record low inflation. Supply
disruptions appeared, particularly for perishable goods such as food. Moreover, some
consumers may have reduced demand for nonessential goods and attempted to purchase
larger quantities of essential items to prepare for possible supply restrictions, and reduce
the number of visits to stores. Government transfers, particularly to poorer families, also
helped buoy the demand for essential goods. The result was that while general inflation
was subdued, inflation for some categories, particularly for food, was higher. 2
Figure 4.2, Panels A and B show that the difference between food inflation and overall
inflation became substantial for some Latin American and Caribbean countries. For the
group of countries in Figure 4.2, Panel A, this difference was temporary and vanished by
the end of the period analyzed. For the group of countries in Panel B, however, the differ-
ence has been persistent and even expanded throughout the year. In Brazil and Guatemala,
for example, food inflation rates were around 9pp and 4pp higher than overall inflation
rates, respectively. In these cases, central banks and governments will need to consider
2 See Nuguer and Powell (2020b), Ebrahimy, Igan, and Martinez Peria (2020), and Lino and Braz (2019).
52
An Array of Monetary Policies to Fight the COVID Crisis
8 8
6 6
4 4
2 2
%
%
0 0
–2 –2
–4 –4
–6 –6
Jan Mar May Jul Sep Nov Jan Jan Mar May Jul Sep Nov Jan
2020 2021 2020 2021
Source: IDB staff calculations based on central banks’ data and National Statistical Agencies.
Note: The figure shows the difference in annual inflation in % from January 2020.
the distributional implications of these divergent inflation rates, because the consumption
basket of poorer households became relatively more expensive.
Persistent and rising inflation in certain product categories and in overall inflation
for a group of countries at the end of 2020 raises the question of whether inflation will
stabilize or continue to rise in 2021. Some of the changes in inflation result from temporary
measures due to the pandemic; they should disappear once the health crisis is over and
economies recover. The effects of lockdown measures, for example, should be temporary.
Some other government policy responses may also fall into this category. For example,
many countries injected substantial liquidity. Unless these injections continue, the impacts
should also be temporary. A danger, however, is that the expansion in the monetary base
persists, especially if central banks become financiers of continuing deficits and the
demand for liquidity from the private sector fades. In that scenario, the region’s history
teaches that inflation could rise, become more persistent, and be costly to bring down. 3
The average output growth of inflation targeters had been below potential since 2016
and that negative gap widened significantly with the pandemic (Figure 4.3, Panel A). By
the end of 2019, the average output gap for the inflation targeters was expected to be
around –1% in 2020, but by October it had reached –5.5%, reflecting the severity of the
3 See Kehoe and Nicolini (2021) and the various chapters on countries in Latin America.
53
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
0.4 2022*
2019 2016
0.2 2020
2013
0.0
2020p
–0.2
–0.4
2018
–0.6
–0.8
–1.0
–6.0 –5.0 –4.0 –3.0 –2.0 –1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0
Output gap (%)
3.5 Uruguay
2.5
Inflation gap (pp)
Jamaica
1.5 Dominican Republic Guatemala
Mexico
0.5 Peru
–2.5
–8.8 –7.8 –6.8 –5.8 –4.8 –3.8 –2.8 –1.8 –0.8 0.2
Output gap (%)
2020 2021*
C. Policy rates
8
7
6
5
4
%
3
2
1
0
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Costa Rica
Dom. Rep.
Guatemala
Honduras
Jamaica
Mexico
Paraguay
Peru
Median
Source: IDB staff calculations based on IMF (2020d) and central banks’ data.
Note: The inflation gap is the deviation of annual inflation from the target in percentage points; the output gap is the deviation
of annual output from its potential level. Paraguay is not included in this chart due to lack of output gap data. (*) denotes
projections from IMF (2020d), and (p) denotes projections from IMF (2019).
54
An Array of Monetary Policies to Fight the COVID Crisis
recession. Figure 4.3, Panel A illustrates the output gap expected in 2020 at the end of
2019 (denoted 2020p in the figure and the outturn inflation rate is labelled 2020). All
countries analyzed saw output gaps rise (Figure 4.3, Panel B).
Given the nature of the shock and the lockdown measures, some widening of output
gaps was unavoidable. Central banks reduced policy rates and injected liquidity to provide
relief to families and firms. Most economies had either negative or small inflation gaps by
the end of 2019 and the recession had a deflationary impact, giving central banks space
to lower their policy rates and inject liquidity into their economies without fueling infla-
tion. By the end of the year, most central banks had overshot their inflation targets, but
most deviations stayed within a 1.5pp range (Figure 4.3, Panel B).
Output gaps are expected to fall in 2021 as economies recover. But recovery is
expected to be gradual, with average projected output gaps for 2021 and 2022 of –2.6%
and –1.2%, respectively. Under this scenario, central banks may be tempted to pursue
further expansionary measures to promote a faster recovery. However, they should
bear in mind that average expected inflation gaps for 2021 and 2022, measured as the
difference between inflation expectations and inflation targets, are already slightly
positive. Thus, the space for further monetary stimulus, without sacrificing inflation
targets, may be limited. The danger is that currently anchored expectations may start
to drift higher.4
The inflation targeters in Latin America and the Caribbean had lowered their policy
rates in preceding years and in 2020 their central banks reduced their policy rates even
further in response to the pandemic (Figure 4.3, Panel C). Jamaica and Peru approached
the zero-lower bound, joining the central banks of many advanced economies. These low
rates were unimaginable not long ago, and these countries will have to rely more on other
policy measures to promote further monetary easing in the future.
By the end of 2020, eleven countries in Latin America and the Caribbean had adopted
inflation targeting regimes and used interest rates as their main policy instrument.
Notwithstanding, the implementation of alternative monetary policy tools in 2020 was the
rule rather than the exception (see Table 4.1). Despite having space to lower interest rates
further, even the more established inflation targeters (Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, and
Peru) used policy instruments other than reducing their policy rates to inject liquidity in
their economies. In fact, Latin America and the Caribbean is well known for using a diverse
set of monetary policy tools in the past and 2020 was no different.
4 SeePowell, Mariscal, and Tavella (2018) on the credibility of inflation targeting regimes in the region and the
potential costs of allowing inflation to exceed targets.
55
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Among the policies listed in Table 4.1, reducing reserve requirements was the most
common tool used by central banks in the region to respond to COVID-19. All inflation
targeters cut reserve requirements in addition to lowering policy rates, which suggests
56
An Array of Monetary Policies to Fight the COVID Crisis
that central banks interpret the two tools as complements rather than substitutes. The
transmission channels for these different policy tools may be quite different. In addition,
some central banks directed the “freed” reserves be used in specific ways, attempt-
ing to provide more and cheaper credit to micro, small, and medium-sized enterprises
and to households in financial distress. The interest rate channel, on the other hand, is
indirect as central banks have little control over how banks and other financial institu-
tions will change their behavior and to what degree lower policy rates will translate
into more/cheaper credit to those targeted firms and households. In countries that are
either fully dollarized or have adopted a hard peg, lowering reserve requirements was
among the few instruments available.
Foreign exchange rate interventions were also common in 2020, as many countries
tried to reduce exchange rate volatility (see Table 4.1). Central banks also used repos to
provide liquidity in foreign currency to banks and firms, especially among established ITs.
Finally, many central banks provided liquidity directly to banks, firms, and government by
purchasing public and private securities.
Table 4.1 presents many central bank policy measures implemented in 2020, but it
is not fully comprehensive. Chapter 5 includes data and discussion on other policy mea-
sures such as the easing of bank loan classifications, imposing grace periods for principal
and interest payments on bank loans, and easing bank provisions. Additional policies to
guarantee that banks remained healthy included loans to banks and creating and/or ex-
panding special credit and liquidity lines.
Purchasing public securities was not the only way in which central banks provided
financing to governments. In some cases, central banks made direct transfers to govern-
ments. For example, Brazil and Colombia used the expansion of their net worth due to
their currency depreciations and the resulting valuation of their foreign reserves to transfer
profits to the government.
To sum up, the wide range of policy measures cited above show that central banks in
the region did not hold back on using their toolkits to face the pandemic. These measures
certainly helped keep businesses afloat, banks healthy and provided greater liquidity to
governments. The consequence was an expansion of central bank balance sheets and the
emergence of several potential risks.
The aforementioned policy measures allowed central banks to address some of the
higher demand for liquidity in 2020. On the one hand, lower policy rates reduced the
opportunity cost for agents to hold liquid assets. On the other hand, amid the eco-
nomic uncertainty surrounding the pandemic, households, firms, and banks sought to
exchange their illiquid assets (e.g., long-term investments) for liquid assets (e.g., cash
57
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
and short-term deposits) to keep these funds safe and make sure they could meet their
financial obligations as needed. All these forces resulted in a pronounced increase in
the stock of liquid assets in Latin America and the Caribbean throughout 2020 (see
Figures 4.4A and B).
6
% of GDP
–1
Feb-20 Mar-20 Apr-20 May-20 Jun-20 Jul-20 Aug-20 Sep-20 Oct-20 Nov-20
B. Currency in circulation
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
% of GDP
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
–0.5
Feb-20 Mar-20 Apr-20 May-20 Jun-20 Jul-20 Aug-20 Sep-20 Oct-20 Nov-20
Source: IDB staff calculations based on IMF and central banks’ data.
Note: The figures plot the estimated residuals in each country from the regression
⎛ Y ⎞⎟
ln⎜⎜⎜ t ⎟⎟⎟ = bt + ∑12 c d + ∈t ,
⎜⎝ GDPt ⎟⎠ i=1 i i
relative to the estimated error in February 2020, where Yt is the dependent variable (M2 in Panel A, currency in circulation in
Panel B), di are monthly dummies. The sample period in each country starts in December 2008.
58
An Array of Monetary Policies to Fight the COVID Crisis
The stock of M2 over GDP increased roughly 3.5 percentage points of GDP on aver-
age by July 2020 (see Figure 4.4A). That monetary aggregate comprises currency outside
banks as well as demand, savings, and some time deposits. Using a narrower definition of
money such as currency in circulation, the pattern is the same (Figure 4.4B). Governments
in the region expanded their transfer programs in response to the crisis, which by itself
increased the demand for currency because poorer households keep a larger fraction of
their assets in the form of cash. 5
The policy measures, together with greater demand for liquidity, not only increased
the stocks of M2 and currency in circulation, they also resulted in additional changes in
the balance sheets of central banks and banking sectors as a whole across the region.
Table 4.2 ranks a group of countries by the cumulative change in their central bank’s
balance sheets in 2020, computed as the cumulative variation in total assets/liabilities in
2020 over 2019 GDP.
Overall, all central banks expanded their balance sheets in 2020. The central banks
of the established inflation targeters (Brazil, Chile, and Peru) recorded the largest ex-
pansion—more than 10% of GDP in each case—while Costa Rica and Mexico recorded
the smallest variation. In both Peru and Chile, the central bank provided liquidity to the
financial system in the form of loans guaranteed by the treasury, financed mostly by
TABLE 4.2 Cumulative Variation in the Balance Sheets of Central Banks in 2020
(% of 2019 GDP)
Assets Liabilities
Net Net Other
credit to Net credit credit to Monetary Sterilization liabilities + Total assets=
foreigners to banks government base liabilities net worth liabilities
Country (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
Peru 11.0 8.0 –2.8 2.8 9.8 3.6 16.1
Chile –0.4 12.3 0.4 6.0 5.6 0.6 12.3
Brazil 6.9 1.1 2.9 1.8 6.2 2.9 10.9
Uruguay 9.4 0.3 –3.0 –1.4 6.6 1.5 6.7
Bolivia –2.2 1.8 5.3 3.4 –0.1 1.6 4.9
Jamaica –0.7 0.0 5.4 2.1 2.7 0.0 4.8
Colombia 4.3 0.5 –0.6 0.5 0.7 3.1 4.3
Paraguay 4.9 0.3 –1.4 0.0 1.3 2.5 3.7
Mexico 3.0 –0.3 –0.2 0.7 0.6 1.1 2.5
Costa Rica 0.1 0.0 0.4 0.6 –0.9 0.8 0.5
Source: IDB staff calculations based on IMF and central banks’ data.
Note: The last observation is October 2020, except for Brazil (November 2020) and Jamaica (September 2020).
5 Álvarezand Argente (2021) suggest that the pandemic itself created incentives for households to hold more
cash so they could make fewer trips to banks and ATMs, thereby reducing the risk of contagion.
59
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
expanding the monetary base and issuing sterilization liabilities (e.g., repos and central
bank debt). Overall, net credit to banks in Peru and Chile increased by 8% and 12.3% of
GDP, respectively.
In Brazil, the dynamics were more complex. The government implemented a sub-
stantial fiscal package to alleviate the effects of the pandemic; one of the main compo-
nents of this package was the expansion of transfers to poorer households (see Chapter
2). To finance this package, the government drew down its deposits at the central bank,
which explains the increase in net credit to the government by 2.9% of GDP in Table 4.2.
However, that was not the total amount financed by the central bank, because it transferred
profits of 4.4% of GDP to the government during 2020 based on the revaluation of the
international reserves. The liquidity injection through the change in government deposits
and the profit transfers would have resulted in a monetary expansion and so the central
bank responded with an increase in sterilization liabilities (e.g., repurchase agreements
or repos). Table 4.2A provides the figures on this sizeable variation on both sides of the
central bank’s balance sheet.
The crisis illustrates that central banks may face limits to the use of monetary policy
in a deep recession. Interest rates are a useful tool but are normally thought to be subject
to a zero or lower bound. Moreover, while a central bank can inject liquidity, in the end
it is banks, firms, and households themselves that decide how much liquidity they are
willing to hold.6
In 2020, central banks in Brazil, Chile, and Peru injected significant liquidity into their
economies, but some of that liquidity then returned to central bank balance sheets in the
form of sterilization liabilities. This contrasts with countries that have a fixed exchange
rate; in these cases, excess liquidity tends to fall by outflows of capital and a reduction
in international reserves. Not surprisingly, Table 4.2 shows that the decline in net foreign
assets was more pronounced in Bolivia (-2.2% of GDP), which holds a peg to the US dollar.
Table 4.3 shows that the expansion of the balance sheet of central banks was ac-
companied by an expansion of the balance sheets of the banking sector.7 In particular, net
credit to firms and households (net credit to the private sector) increased in all countries,
which can be interpreted as a measure of policy success. Again, Brazil, Chile, and Peru
were the countries with the largest variation: 6.1%, 4.6%, and 6.2% of GDP, respectively.
Costa Rica and Mexico again showed the smallest expansion: 0.7% and 1.0% of GDP, re-
spectively. This pattern demonstrates that central banks that followed more expansionary
6 This discussion relates to the idea that at some point monetary policy becomes like “pushing on a piece of
string,” a phrase often ascribed to both Keynes and Federal Reserve Governor Eccles in the 1930s, and to the
continuing discussion regarding the efficacy of quantitative easing. While overall measures of liquidity may
eventually be endogenous, there may be impacts on specific markets and on credit (see for example Kapoor
and Peia, 2021).
7 Banking sector refers to depository institutions other than the central bank.
60
An Array of Monetary Policies to Fight the COVID Crisis
policies provided a larger increase in net credit to the private sector in their economies.
This expansion in net credit by banks was financed largely through short-term liabilities,
which comprise demand deposits as well as other short-term deposits and securities in-
cluded in broader definitions of money.
Conclusions
Central banks in the region took rapid and effective action in response to the COVID crisis
and implemented a wide range of policy measures. As a consequence, interest rates de-
creased, the stock of liquid assets increased, and the balance sheets of both central banks
and banks expanded. The latter boosted credit to governments, firms, and households,
financed mostly through an increase in short-term liabilities, such as deposits. Central
banks saw their reserves rise and lent more to governments and banks. Liabilities also
increased, especially the monetary base and short-term sterilization liabilities, although
many central banks also saw an increase in net worth, in part due to the valuation effects
stemming from depreciations.
While food inflation rose in some countries due to both supply restrictions and
demand effects, in general, inflation has remained low and inflation expectations well-
anchored. Still, central banks have less ammunition now with larger balance sheets and
policy rates at low levels, and inflation expectations have already crept slightly above
61
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
targets in some cases. One risk is that if demand recovers but supply remains constrained,
prices may be pushed higher. If this occurs, it is likely to provoke only a temporary in-
crease in inflation until supply constraints lift. Given economic recovery, fiscal expansion
should be reined in to rebuild fiscal buffers, ensure consistency with monetary policy,
and contain inflation risks.
Perhaps of greater concern is a scenario in which fiscal deficits remain, and a lack
of financing options creates pressure for the monetary financing of fiscal deficits. This
already occurred in 2020 in some cases. Still, as emphasized in Chapter 3, most countries
continue to have access to other sources of financing at reasonable rates. They should be
able to maintain access barring a shock to international capital markets such as a reversal
of current central bank forward guidance towards a tighter monetary stance, or if fiscal
sustainability is considered to be at risk. Given the region’s history, persistent monetary
financing of deficits could create the conditions for higher inflation which is then costly to
bring back down (Esquivel, Kehoe, and Nicolini, 2019). Central bank independence and the
quality of balance sheets going forward are key to avoid these inflationary risks. A further
potential risk is the stock of short-term sterilization liabilities, mostly in local currency, on
the balance sheets of some central banks. Still, those same central banks appear to have
required buffers to back these commitments. But some governments are also faced with
considerable debt service obligations for 2021, and central banks may need to resist sharp
depreciations (which would improve their balance sheets) given inflation objectives and
corporate debts in dollars (see Chapter 6). The dual treasury and central bank roll-over
risks should therefore be closely monitored.
62
CHAPTER 5
Financial Stability:
A Must for a Strong Recovery
T
he region’s financial sectors remain dominated by banks. The banking crises of the
1980s, 1990s, and in some countries the early 2000s, continue to influence regula-
tory and supervisory structures as well as banks’ own risk management decisions.
The subsequent reforms helped the region weather the Global Financial Crisis relatively
unscathed. In addition, supervisors across the region have been adapting local regulations
to ensure compliance with Basel III and other recent reforms.1 Thanks to this history, the
sector came into the current crisis in relatively good shape with improved oversight and
relatively high capital and liquidity.
But COVID-19 is no ordinary shock and as the health of the banking system reflects
that of underlying economies, significant impacts are to be expected. Policy responses have
helped smooth the shock, but they also hide underlying risks. Only in the coming months
may the full impacts be revealed. This chapter first discusses the policy responses to the
crisis and traces the impacts given developments on bank balance sheets. A forward-
looking analysis using market information then estimates the likelihood of banks becoming
capital deficient. Finally, selective policy recommendations are outlined.
In response to the COVID crisis, countries provided support to firms and families (see
Chapter 2). Central banks reduced policy interest rates, lowered reserve requirements,
and provided liquidity to banks in the form of repurchase agreements or collateralized
loans (see Chapter 4). These measures assisted banks and their clients and surely helped
smooth out the impacts of the crisis on the financial sector.
Financial regulatory authorities were also quick to act and in a new database of policy
interventions, no fewer than 467 measures, many relevant to banking sectors, were imple-
mented in the region (see Table 5.1). One hundred and twenty-three measures focused on
support to borrowers, 99 related to providing liquidity, and 77 measures aimed to relax
or seek greater flexibility on prudential norms or reporting standards.
63
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Authorities in most countries acted quickly, introducing incentives for banks to defer
loans to include grace periods and longer maturities for repayment. Motivations included
providing liquidity and allowing banks to continue to report loans as performing and not
requiring additional provisions. In a few countries such programs were mandated. The
details of the programs vary, some allowing for reprogramming up to 12 months and oth-
ers extending the programs. 2
Such policies have the benefit of giving families and firms more time to repay out-
standing loans. But there are also costs: they may eat into bank buffers, and banks and
regulatory authorities lose information on the state of borrowers making it more difficult
to assess risks. Many actors rely on banks’ classification of loans but if they are frozen,
then valuable information on borrower creditworthiness is lost. 3 It is also hard to dis-
criminate between clients in such programs and frequently, deferrals are granted across
the board, or based on only a limited set of criteria; therefore, deferrals may be granted
irrespective of need.
If the underlying problem is strictly temporary and the expectation is that borrowers’
financial health will bounce back relatively quickly to pre-crisis levels, then deferral poli-
cies can be particularly effective. However, the crisis is continuing, the recovery remains
uncertain, and the post-COVID economy may be quite different from the pre-crisis one
(see Chapters 6 and 8). A high degree of reallocation within economies will significantly
impact the ability of borrowers to repay outstanding loans.
A second important policy response has been a set of guarantee programs to back-
stop private banks extending new loans to firms. While such programs have reached sev-
eral points of GDP in some countries, implementation has been mixed.4 Authorities have
64
Financial Stability: A Must for a Strong Recovery
been reticent to provide full guarantees as that would eliminate the incentive of banks to
ensure proper risk assessment and could lead to large fiscal losses. On the other hand,
without close to a full guarantee, banks have been hesitant to lend and therefore, take up
has been low in some cases.
These policies have helped keep credit flowing to firms but again, they carry risks.
Guaranteed loans are a useful instrument when there is confidence in the future viabil-
ity of the borrower and debt is not too high. If a firm’s survival is uncertain or it already
has high debts, then adding more loans (or even replacing existing ones for guaranteed
loans) may not be the best approach. 5 The greater the uncertainty, the more likely these
programs will suffer losses and, the higher the debt levels, then the more likely a debt
overhang problem will emerge (see Chapter 6).
On average, credit to both the private and public sectors has risen during this crisis
(see Chapter 4). Credit to the nonfinancial private sector in real terms grew particu-
larly strongly in 2020 in Brazil and Peru. Credit to firms has been supported by loan
guarantee schemes in some countries; the loan deferral programs imply that credit
maturities have been pushed out. Thus, loans that might have been repaid are kept
on the books, implying that measured credit may be higher than it would have been
otherwise. In some countries, the composition of credit also changed, with credit to
households falling relative to firms. 6
The growth in credit to the private and public sectors is reflected in the growth of
bank assets, which have increased about 9% for the median bank in the region and 15%
for the weighted-average bank from the end of 2019 to September 2020 (see Figure 5.2).
The sharp increase in public sector debt implied a greater demand for financing and, thus,
an increase in credit to the public sector while the guarantee programs have supported
credit to the private sector.
Bank liabilities also grew but perhaps of particular interest was the change in the
structure of bank deposits (see Figure 5.3). Time deposits have fallen as a percentage
of total deposits while demand deposits grew. As detailed in Chapter 4, the demand for
liquidity increased substantially.
The impacts of the crisis are manifest in bank net income, which fell 40% for the
median bank and over 90% for the weighted-average bank from the end of 2019 to
second quarter 2020. For some countries, including Barbados, Chile, and Peru, average
5 Infavor of guarantee schemes see Blanchard, Philippon, and Pisani-Ferry (2020) and for a warning see
Hanson et al. (2020).
6 For example, in Chile credit to households fell from 31% to 28% of total credit and in Mexico it fell from 39%
to 36%, according to BIS data and comparing fourth quarter 2019 to second quarter 2020.
65
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
104
102
100
98
96
94
92
90
Argentina
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Ecuador
El Salvador
Guatemala
Honduras
Mexico
Paraguay
Peru
Uruguay
Jun-20 Dec-20 Dec-19
Source: IDB staff calculations based on data from national central banks.
Note: The figure plots an index of the stock of credit in nominal local currency divided by the consumer price index and with
a base of December 2019 equal to 100 for selected countries. The final data point is December 2020, except for Argentina,
Honduras, and Paraguay where it is November 2020.
net income for the banks in the sample was negative in the second quarter, but recov-
ered in several countries and for the larger banks in the third quarter. Consequently,
the asset-weighted measure rises such that both measures are down by about 35% by
third quarter 2020.
Tier 1 regulatory capital ratios were high coming into this crisis at around 13% at the
end of 2019, and while they fell initially, they have risen since first quarter 2020. A small
115
Index 2019-Q4=100
110
105
100
95
90
2019-Q4 2020-Q1 2020-Q2 2020-Q3
Source: IDB staff calculations based on Standard and Poor’s bank balance sheet data.
Note: Assets are converted from local currency to an index with fourth quarter 2019 = 100. The figure plots the median across
all banks in the dataset and an average of the indices weighted by bank assets.
66
Financial Stability: A Must for a Strong Recovery
sample of banks have data to the end of 2020 and the trend of increasing capital ratios
continues through then. The median bank in the region had higher tier 1 capital to assets
at risk in fourth quarter than in first quarter for this smaller sample.
Interestingly, banks were able to increase capital in nominal terms as dividend pay-
ments declined (in some countries dividend payments were restricted). At the same time,
the average risk weight of assets declined, reflecting a switch in assets towards government
bonds that attract a zero-risk weight in most jurisdictions, thereby pushing regulatory
capital ratios higher. Reflecting the switch to securities, the loans to asset ratios fell from
67% to about 63% for the median bank in third quarter 2020.
Given the depth of the crisis, nonperforming loans have moved relatively little. For
the median bank, nonperforming loans are about 4% of total loans and about 5% for the
weighted-average bank. However, these statistics hide different patterns across countries.
The median bank in Brazil, Chile, Mexico, Panama, and Peru has seen nonperforming loans
rise while in Argentina, Colombia, and Paraguay they have actually fallen through 2020.
These differences likely reflect reporting regulations and the impact and specification
of loan deferral schemes. In countries with rising nonperforming loan ratios in the third
quarter, this trend was extended to the fourth quarter. Nonperforming loans to total loans
for the banks in the sample from Brazil, Chile, Colombia, and Peru were all above 5.0% for
the median bank in fourth quarter. As reprogrammed loans start to mature, nonperforming
loans will inevitably rise in other countries. Interestingly, banks tended to increase provi-
sions against loan losses, which reached 2.7% of total loans for the median bank and 3.1%
of loans for the asset-weighted bank. While banks did not need to set aside provisions
FIGURE 5.3 The Changing Composition of Bank Deposits (time deposits as a % of total
deposits)
44
43
42
41
40
39
%
38
37
36
35
34
2019-Q4 2020-Q1 2020-Q2 2020-Q3
Source: IDB staff calculations based on Standard and Poor’s bank balance sheet data.
Note: The figure plots the median of the variable across all banks in the dataset and an average of the indices weighted by
bank assets.
67
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
100
Index 2019-Q4=100
80
60
40
20
0
2019-Q4 2020-Q1 2020-Q2 2020-Q3
Source: IDB staff calculations based on Standard and Poor’s bank balance sheet data.
Note: Assets are converted from local currency to an index with fourth quarter 2019 = 100. The figure plots the median across
all banks in the dataset and an average of the indices weighted by bank assets.
14.0
13.5
13.0
%
12.5
12.0
11.5
2019-Q4 2020-Q1 2020-Q2 2020-Q3
Source: IDB staff calculations based on Standard and Poor’s bank balance sheet data.
Note: The figure plots the median tier 1 capital ratio across all banks in the dataset and an average of the variable weighted
by bank assets.
against deferred loans, some appear to be anticipating the need for larger buffers in the
months ahead.
The discussion above focuses on the median or average bank according to assets.
But this hides considerable differences across banks. For example, while the median tier 1
ratio was around 13% at the end of 2019, about 20% of banks in the sample had tier 1 ratios
of less than 10%; this remained roughly unchanged through third quarter 2020, despite
the increase in capital ratios noted above. Figure 5.7 illustrates the distribution of tier 1
capital ratios across the banks in the sample.
The distribution of nonperforming loans is particularly interesting. Banks with few
nonperforming loans continued to report low figures, but the number of banks reporting
68
Financial Stability: A Must for a Strong Recovery
5.5
5.0
%
4.5
4.0
3.5
2019-Q4 2020-Q1 2020-Q2 2020-Q3
Source: IDB staff calculations based on Standard and Poor’s bank balance sheet data.
Note: The figure plots the median across all banks in the dataset and an average of the indices weighted by bank assets.
nonperforming loans of around 5% increased (see Figure 5.8). And there was a definite
shift in provisioning against nonperforming loans across banks (see Figure 5.9).
While net income recovered for some banks in third quarter 2020, the distribution
of return on equity showed a clear downward shift (Figure 5.10). In particular, more banks
reported negative returns in third quarter 2020 compared to the end of 2019.
The previous section noted specific changes in bank balance sheets. Figure 5.11 gives a
schematic representation of the composition of the balance sheet of the median bank
0.12
0.10
0.08
Density
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.00
4 9 14 19 24
69
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
and the weighted-average bank (using assets as weights) with all figures expressed as a
percentage of assets.
On the asset side, securities relative to loans have increased notably. This rise was
largely accounted for by an increase in debt issued by the government of the country
where the bank is located, which grew from 14% to 16% of total assets for the weighted-
average bank. Total securities for the weighted-average bank represented as much as
30% of total assets by the end of the third quarter.
0.16
0.12
Density
0.08
0.04
0.00
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
0.25
0.20
Density
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
70
Financial Stability: A Must for a Strong Recovery
FIGURE 5.10 Distribution of the Return on Equity across Banks in the Region
0.06
0.05
0.04
Density
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
–20 –10 0 10 20 30 40 50
2019-Q4 2020-Q3
On the liability side, deposits rose as a percentage of assets and, notably, assets also
grew (see Figure 5.11). Debt fell as a percentage of assets for both the median and the
weighted-average bank. Equity rose in local currency terms, but as assets also increased,
equity as a percentage of assets fell. The composition of capital also shifted with tier 1
71
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
capital declining and lower quality tier 2 capital increasing somewhat as a percentage of
total capital.
The current environment presents several risks. The increase in government bonds
in banks’ assets ties the risks of the banking sector more closely to debt sustainability. In
countries where fiscal adjustment is required to assure sustainability, doubts about this
process may result in concern over bank solvency. Such risks are generally not reflected
in the typical calculation of assets at risk, following Basel recommendations, as the as-
sumption is normally that government bonds issued in the country’s own currency carry
a zero risk-weight.7 However, the risk may be reflected in stock markets, bank ratings,
and funding costs.
A second risk is the expansion in deposits given rising demand for liquidity and less
reliance on longer-term debt. The recent growth in deposits likely reflects uncertainty
rather than greater transaction demand. Some investors may be pursuing a carry trade—
borrowing at very low rates in dollars and investing at higher local interest rates in local
currency. If concerns arise over financial or fiscal risks, or U.S. interest rates rise, then
some deposits may leave quickly. Large corporate deposits are of particular concern as
they tend to be the most at risk of flight. Depending on developments on the asset side,
this could create funding issues for banks that central banks may be forced to address.
A third risk stems from the potential rise in nonperforming loans as growth remains
low, guarantee and deferral programs expire, and delayed loan repayments become due.
Considering the median bank, the loan book is about 63% of assets while total capital plus
provisions amount to about 12%. Many details and parameters must be considered, but
assuming a 50% recovery value, a rough calculation suggests that if 10% of loans become
nonperforming, this would eat up close to a quarter of bank capital (around 3% of assets).
Mitigating this risk, banks may be in a position to continue to build buffers assuming net
income is positive and dividend policy remains conservative. It will be important to closely
monitor these risks in the months ahead.
Balance sheet data can provide a snapshot of the health of a bank at a point in time.
However, changing reporting standards and provisioning decisions means that accounting
ratios may give a misleading account of the risks that banks are facing. Moreover, balance
sheet data is only available with a lag.
Risk indicators can also be generated from market prices. Bank analysts may have
better information and if stock market participants act on their rigorous assessment of risks,
then equity market data may yield a useful complementary and forward-looking vision of
72
Financial Stability: A Must for a Strong Recovery
banking sector risk. While market indicators of risk did not do a great job of predicting
the global financial crisis, arguably that was an unusual period in which significant risks
stemmed from complex, opaque, over-the-counter instruments and banks’ exposures were
not well-known. The main risks facing banks in Latin America and the Caribbean today
are more of a traditional credit variety. Still, these indicators will only be as accurate as
the information available to stock market participants.
Equity-based risk models have become a standard part of the toolkit for risk analysts.
These models draw on option pricing theory and consider the value of the firm (or the bank
in this case) as akin to a call-option on the firm’s assets. 8 A random process is proposed
for the bank’s asset-to-liabilities ratio, and a formula can be derived for the probability
that the value of the bank’s assets as a ratio to liabilities will fall below a threshold level
in a specified period of time.
Following the finance literature, it is then often assumed that this triggers a default.
In what follows, this is referred to as capital deficiency. The probability of such an event
is then the likelihood that the value of a bank’s assets falls below this threshold. Still, bank
management and regulatory authorities will likely react before that point and implement
new policies to rectify the situation. Moreover, public financial support may be provided,
or the bank may seek assistance from a parent or other banks or be the subject of an
acquisition. The estimated probabilities are then best thought of as a market risk indicator
of a potential deficiency in capital that could prompt remedial actions. One way to think
about them is as a type of real-time rating.
The estimated value of the bank and the likelihood of capital deficiency are
functions of a limited set of parameters that can be measured from the data, namely
the current market capitalization of the bank, the liabilities of the bank (assumed to
be fixed), the volatility of the market capitalization, the interest rate (commonly assumed
to be fixed), and the specified time horizon (see Perraudin, Powell, and Yang, forthcoming).
The dataset contains information on 39 banks across six countries. The banks included
are the larger banking institutions in those countries and some foreign subsidiaries and
public banks that are listed on the domestic equity market. Five-year probabilities are
estimated and it is assumed that the trigger value for capital deficiency is when the value
of assets falls below 97% of the value of liabilities. The data employed include the daily
market capitalization of each bank (derived from the sum of all types of shares outstand-
ing) and the liabilities of each bank, which are taken from the bank balance sheet at the
start of the period. The equity series is corrected for dividend payouts. 9
8 See any good finance text such as Hull (2015) for a discussion of option pricing; Merton (1974) is the classic
the MSCI global equity portfolio as the market portfolio. The stochastic processes involved are estimated using
Maximum Likelihood techniques (see Perraudin, Powell, and Yang (forthcoming) for further details).
73
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Estimated probabilities of capital deficiency are illustrated in Figure 5.12 for selected
countries. Average probabilities are calculated for each country weighted by bank liabili-
ties. By comparison, for a sample of banks in Europe, similar probabilities rose to about
7% in March 2020 and then fell back to about 5%. According to these measures, risk
rose significantly as the COVID-19 crisis erupted, especially in Brazil, Chile, and Mexico.
Subsequently, these risk indicators decline as stock markets recovered, but they begin to
rise again later in the sample.
The estimated probabilities depend on bank characteristics. A notable inverse rela-
tionship exists between the size of the bank and the estimated risk. Small banks (less than
US$10 billion in liabilities) have higher estimated risk than medium banks (between US$10
and US$50 billion in liabilities) while medium-sized banks have higher estimated risk than
large banks (liabilities in excess of US$50 billion). The three lines display a similar pattern,
with a sharp rise in the likelihood of capital deficiency in March 2020, followed by a fall
and then a more gradually rising trend towards the end of the sample.
It is unsurprising that these risk indicators rose as the crisis erupted in March given
the declines in stock market valuations. Perhaps of more interest is the subsequent fall in
those probabilities and the gradual rising trend evident towards the end of the period. It is
difficult to assess how accurate these risk measures are as they depend on the information
that stock market participants have and the underlying assumption is that stock markets
reflect fundamentals. Still, given this upward trend, authorities will want to monitor all
indicators of banking sector risk in the months ahead.
0.14
0.12
0.10
Probability
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.00
Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep
74
Financial Stability: A Must for a Strong Recovery
0.20
Probability
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep
Conclusions
The banking system came into the crisis with high capital and liquidity ratios. Supportive
policies have helped smooth the shock but are likely hiding the risks. Bank income has
taken a considerable hit, although conservative dividend policies have allowed some
banks to increase provisioning and capital. Regulatory capital ratios have risen, but this
also reflects the switch to government securities on bank balance sheets and, hence, a
fall in calculated risk weights, despite the high uncertainty generated by the pandemic.
The combination of support policies and regulatory interventions may be creating
a false sense of security with respect to the risks for financial stability. As reviewed in this
chapter, market indicators of bank risk have been increasing in recent months despite
many banks presenting what appear to be strong balance sheets. This apparent discon-
nect between balance sheet indicators and market perceptions is worrisome and may
grow unless policies adapt.
The experience from many previous episodes (including the savings and loan crisis
in the United States, the banking system problems of Japan, as well as previous crises in
the region) was that forbearance policies may help smooth out shocks, but they tend to
increase the eventual losses.10 Recent analyses point to the dangers of these policies in
the current context in Latin America and the Caribbean and elsewhere.11
10 See, for example, Brown and Dinç (2011), Caballero, Hoshi, and Kashyap (2008), and Peek and Rosengren
(2005).
11 See Baer (2020), Cooper et al. (2020), Fitch Ratings (2020), and Powell and Rojas-Suárez (2020).
75
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Nonperforming loans have started to increase in some countries and will likely rise
further as more deferred loans expire. This is to be expected and banks have significant
buffers for such situations. The continuation of forbearance will become less productive
and more dangerous in the months ahead. Where feasible, it will be preferable to move
towards greater transparency and allow losses to be reflected on bank balance sheets. If
communicated in a fashion that indicates a recovery plan is in motion, this will be more
credible and likely less risky than limiting transparency, which may deepen the eventual
problems.
Guarantee programs have helped keep credit flowing but take-up has been mixed;
in the months ahead, new instruments should be considered. Guarantees on loans are
most appropriate where risk is contained and debt levels are not too high.12 Where there
is significant uncertainty or debt levels are already high, alternative instruments should
be considered.13 An equity-like instrument would allow the public sector to enjoy upside
potential and not only backstop downside risk.14 Mechanisms of support that leverage bank
knowledge of clients, but which do not add more debt to firms’ balance sheets, would
be a valuable addition to the policy toolkit. Still, countries should carefully consider the
appropriate institutions and mechanisms to provide the kind of support that can protect
the use of public funds as well as private sector property rights.
Authorities will want to monitor the financial sector risks carefully in the months
ahead. Financial instability would only add to the woes facing the region. Maintaining
financial stability is a necessity for banks to play a constructive role in providing credit to
viable and new firms and for a healthy and sustainable economic recovery.
12 See Blanchard, Philippon, and Pisani-Ferry (2020) for a discussion of guarantee programs as part of the
policy mix.
13 Hanson et al. (2020) make this point in the U.S. context.
76
CHAPTER 6
T
he COVID-19 shock suddenly left many firms with limited or no cash flows to cover
operating costs, repay debt obligations, or continue with investment plans. Their
response was to try to reestablish liquidity by raising cash from available sources
and building a cushion to fend-off a crisis of unknown duration. Relief programs deployed
by central banks and governments helped smooth out sudden liquidity shortages. In ad-
dition to providing much-needed liquidity support, the emergency financing measures
prevented a more damaging wave of debt defaults and bankruptcies among the region’s
corporate sector (see Chapters 4 and 5). However, investment remains subdued and the
health of firms’ balance sheets has deteriorated.
This chapter provides an overview of how the COVID-19 crisis and firms' responses
impacted their balance sheets. The overview is selective because it relies on balance
sheet information available only for firms listed in the local stock markets of Brazil, Chile,
Colombia, Mexico, and Peru. However, these constitute some of the largest and least
financially constrained firms across the region. Therefore, the impacts of the COVID-19
shock on these firms’ balance sheets are probably a lower bound for the effects across
the broader spectrum of firms.
When the COVID-19 shock hit financial markets in full force in March, stock market
valuations in the region plunged. Since then they have recovered, supported by the
low-interest rate environment, and the excellent performance of tech companies. But
the recovery has varied across sectors. The difference in valuations, in turn, is indicative
of the market’s perception of possible sector level reallocations after the pandemic,
with tech companies emerging as clear winners and other sectors, including mining
and capital-intensive manufacturing, expected to perform well in the post-pandemic
environment.
77
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
The supply and demand shocks brought on by forced lockdowns, induced a large decline
in firm-level revenues and profit. Average profit rates across firms declined from 13% in
2018–19 to 10% in first quarter 2020 and 5% in second quarter 2020 before sharply re-
bounding to 15% in third quarter 2020 (see Figure 6.1, Panel A). However, (asset-weighted)
averages are largely driven by Brazilian firms’ relatively better performance. In Chile,
Colombia, Mexico, and Peru, profit rates plummeted to virtually 0% or even slightly nega-
tive in second quarter 2020, while Brazilian firms averaged 7%. On the positive side, the
rebound in the third quarter was strong and common to all five countries analyzed (see
Figure 6.1, Panel B).
The large decline in profits was driven by the larger decline in sales relative to
firms’ variable costs. Arguably, many companies contained some variable costs by lay-
ing off workers, cutting intermediate input expenditures, or refinancing loans. Corporate
revenues (sales) fell by about 10% in real terms in the second quarter—the worst of the
pandemic—which is comparable with the decline during the global financial crisis in 2009
(see Figure 6.2, Panel A).
The impact of the shock on revenues at the firm-level can be illustrated by looking
at the distribution (frequencies) of revenue growth during a long historical period (from
first quarter 2000 to first quarter 2020) compared with the COVID-19 quarters (second
0.20
0.15
0.15
0.10
Rate
Rate
0.10
0.05
0.05
0.00
0.00
–0.05 –0.05
Latin America United States Global Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru
Source: IDB staff calculations based on data from the S&P Capital IQ database.
Note: Firms from Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru are included. The profit rate is defined as the ratio of profits-
to-revenues, where profits are obtained as revenues minus total costs (including cost of goods sold, capital expenditures,
and selling, general and administrative expenses). The figures show the (asset-weighted) profit rates across publicly listed
nonfinancial firms for each country or group.
78
Corporate Balance Sheets and Early Indications of Reallocation
15
50
10
5
0
%
%
0
–5
–50
–10
–15 –100
2005 2007 2010 2012 2015 2017 2020 Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru
Source: IDB staff calculations based on data from the S&P Capital IQ database.
Note: Firms from Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru are included. Firm-level revenue growth (%) is the yearly growth rate
of quarterly total revenues, in real (CPI-deflated) local currency units of 2015. Panel A shows the median and asset-weighted
mean evolution of profit rates, for publicly listed nonfinancial firms. Panel B shows the distribution for yearly growth rates of
quarterly firm revenues in local currency, for publicly listed nonfinancial firms, in each period and country. The box in Panel B
represents the middle 50% of growth rates for each group; the median, shown as the line that divides the box into two parts,
marks the mid-point of the data. Historic period in Panel B includes the period from first quarter 2000 to first quarter 2020,
excluding GFC; GFC includes third quarter 2008 to second quarter 2009; COVID includes second and third quarters 2020.
and third quarter 2020).1 During the historical period, the annual average growth rate
in revenues for five countries was 3.6%; during the COVID-19 quarters, the mean yearly
growth was –10%.
Figure 6.2, Panel B presents analogous results broken down by country. During
COVID-19, in all five countries analyzed, there was a noticeable shift down in the dis-
tribution of revenue growth and an increase in idiosyncratic risk. The sample median
of revenue growth shifted from positive (in normal times) to negative in all five coun-
tries, and the middlebox representing firm observations between the 25th and 75th
percentiles, shifted almost entirely to negative values, except for Brazil. Compared
to normal times, Peru suffered the largest decline in median revenue growth and the
greatest spike in uncertainty, while Brazil performed relatively well. Arguably, the
way in which the five countries performed reflects the different intensities with which
lockdowns were imposed as well as the effectiveness of other health and economic
policies. Compared to the global financial crisis, the median decline in revenue growth
was larger in all countries during the COVID-19 shock, and the distribution of outcomes
1 Firstquarter 2020 is considered in the benchmark period because most countries imposed tight restrictions
after the World Health Organization declared the coronavirus a pandemic in March 2020.
79
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
was more dispersed, except in Colombia, suggesting that firms faced more volatility
than in the previous crisis.
20 Mining and
quarrying
10
COVID period (%)
Manuf.: high-K
Manuf.: high-L
Wholesale andretail trade Other services
Transp., excl. air transp.
0.0
High-contact
services
–0.1
Air transport,
(0.09, –0.36)
–0.20
–0.2 –0.1 0 0.1 0.2
Historic period (rate)
Source: IDB staff calculations based on data from the S&P Capital IQ database.
Note: Firms from Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru are included. The profit rate is defined as the ratio of profits-to-
revenues, where profits are calculated as revenues minus total costs (including cost of goods sold, capital expenditures,
and selling, general and administrative expenses). Panel A shows period (asset-weighted) revenue growth rate pairs by
economic sector. Panel B illustrates period median pairs for firm profit rates by economic sector. Sector classification is based
on the 2-digit US SIC code. Panels A and B include a 45-degree reference line. High-contact services include restaurants,
hotels, cinemas, museums, recreation, and education; Other services includes business, legal and social services; Manuf.:
high-K includes capital-intensive manufactures (chemicals, petroleum, metal, electronics, and transportation equipment);
Manuf.: high-L encompasses labor-intensive manufactures (food, textiles, furniture, paper, and others). Agriculture, forestry,
and fishing are excluded due to the small sample size. Historic corresponds to the period 2000-first quarter 2020; COVID
corresponds to the first two quarters of 2020.
80
Corporate Balance Sheets and Early Indications of Reallocation
The effects of the health crisis vary widely across economic sectors. Figure 6.3 sum-
marizes the (weighted) average of revenue growth and profit rates across firms within
economic sectors, comparing a long historical average (2000-first quarter 2020) against
the COVID quarters. Sectors below the 45-degree line, which includes most sectors,
performed worse during the COVID quarters, with the noticeable exceptions of mining
and quarrying, and manufacturing: high-L. Revenues declined most dramatically in air
transport (–77%) and high-contact services (–27%), which include restaurants, hotels,
cinemas, museums, recreation, and education. In turn, revenues in construction, finance,
and manufacturing: high-K fell 25%, 17%, and 12%, respectively, during the COVID quarters
(see Figure 6.3, Panel A).
However, the picture looks somewhat brighter through the lens of profit rates be-
cause variable costs were also adjusted down. Air transport and high-contact services
are still by far the most affected industries, posting negative profits during second and
third quarter 2020. However, most of the remaining sectors are located on or close to the
45-degree line. Notably, construction and finance managed to maintain profit rates, on
average, which points to the sector’s ability to reduce variable costs vis-a-vis the drop in
revenues (see Figure 6.3, Panel B).
Firms worldwide have raised large amounts of money from public and private sources to
face lockdowns without breaking valuable relationships between workers, firms, suppli-
ers, and consumers. As a consequence, corporate debt measures have risen worldwide.
Prior to the pandemic, leverage measures in Latin American countries were on average
similar to those in the United States. However, during 2020, corporate leverage has
grown significantly more in the Latin American countries than in the rest of the world.
The average debt-to-asset ratio increased from 0.35 to 0.4 in just two quarters (fourth
quarter 2019 to second quarter 2020) while the United States peaked at just 0.32 (see
Figure 6.4, Panel A).
Similarly, the debt-to-EBITDA 2 —an alternative debt ratio normalized by cash flows—
rose even more sharply in Latin America relative to the United States or the Global in-
dex, from 17x in fourth quarter 2019 to an unprecedented 25x in second quarter 2020,
to partially recover to 21x by the end of third quarter 2020 (see Figure 6.4, Panel B).
As a long-run reference, the debt-to-EBITDA in those five countries averaged 14x in the
period 2000–2019, and the peak during the GFC of 2008–09 was 21x. Financial distress,
as measured by the debt-to-EBITDA, rose more in the Latin American countries than in
other regions (see Figure 6.4, Panel B).
81
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
0.35 20
Ratio
Ratio
0.30 15
0.25 10
2018 2019 2020 2018 2019 2020
The rise in leverage is widespread across economic sectors and countries (see
Table 6.1). Air transport is by far the sector that entered the pandemic with the highest
debt-to-assets ratio (average of 0.42) and is also the industry with the largest increase
(50%) between pre-pandemic average and the second and third quarters of 2020.
Other sectors with high initial leverage and large increases in leverage during COVID
include wholesale and retail trade, other transport and high contact services. With some
exceptions, similar sectoral patterns hold for the United States and the Global index in
Table 6.1. Comparing regions, the increase in leverage across sectors is generally larger
in Latin America than in the rest of the world, especially for the more levered sectors.
To cope with liquidity shortages, firms have used both bank credit and debt secu-
rities (bonds). During the last decade, the corporate sector in Latin America has relied
increasingly on bond financing (see Powell, 2014), a tendency that deepened during the
COVID crisis. Bank loans, covered by a leading international source focusing on syndicated
lending, indicated US$37 billion in new funds, down 37% in 2020 compared to 2019 (see
Figure 6.5, Panel A).
3 Consistent credit rating data are available only for a subset of firms in the sample (14%). Among those firms,
roughly one in every four had their credit rating downgraded at least once during the COVID pandemic. Most
of downgrades were concentrated between March and June of 2020.
82
Corporate Balance Sheets and Early Indications of Reallocation
83
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
FIGURE 6.5 Corporate Loan and Bond Issuance and Amortization Schedule
A. Syndicated and other loans by country B. Syndicated and other leans by currency
80 80
US$ billions (12 month moving sum)
60 60
50 50
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Brazil Mexico Chile Colombia Peru Other currencies Hard currencies
160 160
140 140
120 120
100 100
80 80
60 60
40 40
20 20
0 0
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Brazil Mexico Chile Colombia Peru Other currencies Hard currencies
100 100
80 80
60 60
40 40
20 20
0 0
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
2025
2026
2027
2028
2029
2030
2032
2033
2034
2035
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
2025
2026
2027
2028
2029
2030
2032
2033
2034
2035
Source: IDB staff calculations based on data from the Refinitiv Datastream database.
Note: Monthly frequency, last observation available was December 31, 2020. All figures show volumes calculated as the
12-month rolling sum of issued value, by nationality of issuer. Loans include syndicated and other specific types of loans and
facilities. Foreign currencies in Panels B, D, and F include U.S. dollar, Euro, British Pound, Swiss Franc, and Japanese Yen.
Panels E and F assume all amortizations are at bond maturities.
84
Corporate Balance Sheets and Early Indications of Reallocation
0.12
0.10
0.08
Ratio
Ratio
0.010
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.05 0.00
2005 2008 2011 2014 2017 2020 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017 2020
Source: IDB staff calculations based on data from the S&P Capital IQ database.
Note: Panels A and B illustrate the median of firm-level ratios across publicly listed nonfinancial firms in Brazil, Chile, Colombia,
Mexico, and Peru and S&P Global BMI constituents (excluding the five countries in Latin America). Truncated at 0% and 99%
of the distribution. Panel A shows the four-quarter moving average of the investment-to-assets ratio median to smooth out
seasonal variation.
85
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
0.012 0.07
0.010 0.06
Ratio
Ratio
0.008 0.05
0.006 0.04
0.004 0.03
0.002 0.02
Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru
Source: IDB staff calculations based on data from the S&P Capital IQ database.
Note: Panels A and B illustrate the median of firm-level ratios across publicly listed nonfinancial firms in each country (Brazil,
Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru) and the median of all pooled firm-level ratios for the five countries. Truncated at 0% and 99%
of the distribution.
Stock market valuations took an enormous hit in the early stages of the pandemic, and
noticeably rebounded towards the end of 2020. Current asset prices are forward-looking
estimates of expected future dividends at the firm level and are thus indicative of the medi-
um-run prospects during the post-COVID recovery across countries and economic sectors.
Peaking in March 2020, the market capitalization for firms in the region declined
an average 25% relative to January 2020; this compares with a 20% drop in the United
States and 15% in the global index (see Figure 6.8, Panel A). The recovery of market
valuations in Latin America is systematically weaker than in the rest of the world but still
enough to surpass pre-COVID levels by year-end 2020. Within the region, Brazil suf-
fered the greatest peak-to-trough decline (32% from January to March); however, it was
also the country with the most pronounced recovery, reaching 20% above pre-COVID
levels by December. Colombia recorded the second-worst drop (28%) and the weakest
recovery in the group. Stock market valuations have fully recovered in Mexico and Peru,
while Chile and Colombia were still 10% or more below pre-COVID levels by the end of
2020 (see Figure 6.8, Panel B).
Asset prices also suggest potential reallocation forces across sectors in the years
to come. For instance, asset valuations in air transport and high-contact services plum-
meted 52% and 46%, respectively, between January and March of 2020 (see Table 6.2).
86
Corporate Balance Sheets and Early Indications of Reallocation
110 110
100 100
90 90
80 80
70 70
60 60
Jan-19 Jul-19 Jan-20 Jul-20 Jan-19 Jul-19 Jan-20 Jul-20
Source: IDB staff calculations based on data from the S&P Capital IQ database.
Note: Sum of market capitalization in local currency units for publicly listed nonfinancial firms in five countries in Latin America
and S&P Global BMI constituents (excluding the five countries from Latin America).
These sectors also had the weakest recoveries in the group; they remained 18% and 9%
respectively below pre-COVID levels at the end of 2020.
The drop in asset valuations within the finance, insurance, and real estate sectors is
also relatively large across regions, and the recovery by the end of 2020 is also weaker
than in other industries, especially in the Latin American firms. On the other hand, using
asset valuations as forward-looking signals for the shape of the recovery, manufacturing:
high-K industries, which include chemicals, metal-related manufactures, and electron-
ics have emerged as promising sectors across all regions in the post-COVID economy.
Regarding the relative winners among sectors, other services, which include tech-
related and professional services, enjoyed the largest rebound in both Latin America and
worldwide, thus pointing to better prospects for the post-pandemic economy. While some
regional variations exist, other promising sectors in terms of asset price signals globally
are manufacturing sectors and wholesale and retail trade (see columns 4 to 6, Table 6.2).
The leverage of firms has risen in the last decade and reached record levels amid the
COVID-19 pandemic. High levels of corporate debt are a medium-run concern because
they can persistently depress growth through a debt overhang problem in which the debt
87
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
burden is too large for firms to take on additional debt to finance profitable investment
opportunities (see Brunnermeier and Krishnamurthy, 2020). Debt overhang problems tend
to worsen during recessions as bank lending standards tighten and firms’ creditworthiness
stalls (see Blickle and Santos, 2020).
Results of an econometric analysis suggest that firms with debt overhang, defined
as firms with high initial leverage, display significantly lower capital expenditure growth
in subsequent periods. The results are obtained by extending the analysis in Blickle and
Santos (2020) to a sample of listed firms in 64 countries for the quarterly sample from
first quarter 2000 to third quarter 2020.4
Considering the full sample of firms worldwide, an increase in the debt-to-assets ratio
of 10 percentage points is associated with a 3.1 percentage point decline in the growth
rate of capital expenditures. In other words, while a firm with the sample average lever-
age of 25% invests at an annual growth rate of 5.1%, a firm leveraged up to 35% (10 p.p.
above the mean)5 invests at an annual rate of only 2%, which corresponds to the sample
average of 5.1% minus the debt overhang effect of –3.1%.
Estimating the subsample of Latin American countries yields a similar coefficient
(column 2, Table 6.3). However, the debt overhang effect is much worse because the
4 Results
are robust to the inclusion of firm, sector, and year fixed effects, as well as firm-level controls.
5 Since
the standard deviation of leverage is 18% for the full sample, an increase of 10 p.p. corresponds to ap-
proximately half a standard deviation.
88
Corporate Balance Sheets and Early Indications of Reallocation
annual average investment growth rate in the region is only 0.7%. Thus, Latin American
firms with a debt-to-assets ratio of 39% (which is 10 p.p. above the Latin American mean
of 29%) suffered a decline in investment of 2.3%.6
The second and third rows of Table 6.3 show the interaction between firm-level lever-
age and two crisis dummies, one for the GFC and one for COVID. The coefficients mea-
sure the incremental debt overhang effect during bad times. As expected, the signs are
negative, significant, and economically large, especially for the Latin American firms.
During the GFC, a firm levered up to 35% (again 10 p.p. above the sample mean),
invested at an annual rate of –1.3%, which corresponds to the sample mean investment
growth (5.1%) for firms with average leverage (25%), net of the overhang effect from being
levered up to 35% (–3.1%), and minus the incremental effect of the recession (–3.3%) (col-
umn 1). For the Latin American firms (column 2), with debt-to-asset ratios of 39% display
investment growth of –9.6% during the GFC. Similarly, investment growth rates during
the COVID-19 crisis for firms with a 10 p.p. excess leverage are –1.3% for firms worldwide,
and –6.8% for the Latin American firms.7
⎛ capex ⎞⎟
ln⎜⎜⎜ it ⎟ GFC C 19
⎟ = α + β1Leverageit–5 + β2Leverageit–5 ⋅ Dt + β3Leverageit–5 ⋅ Dt + γZ it + ϕsT + εit
⎜⎝ capex it–4 ⎟⎠
where capex it is capital expenditures for firm i in quarter t, Leverageit is the firm’s debt-to-assets ratio, DtGFC is a Global
Financial Crisis dummy equal to 1 in the period third quarter 2008-second quarter 2009, and DtC 19 is a COVID-19 crisis
dummy equal to 1 in second and third quarters 2020. The regressions include firm fixed effects ϕ i , industry-year ϕ sT fixed
effects, and (not-reported) firm controls (Z it ) including lagged liquid (cash and equivalents) assets and lagged size (measured
through total assets). *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Sample: First quarter 2000-third quarter 2020.
6 The number comes from the following calculation: annual average investment growth rate (0.7%) minus β
1
a stable debt overhang pattern across big economic sectors. The crisis dummies at the sector level also reveal
that the COVID-19 crisis hit the air transport and high-contact services sectors especially hard. Notably, air
transport is also the sector worldwide with the largest debt overhang coefficient even in normal times, which
is consistent with the evidence of high debt reported above.
89
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Concluding Remarks
COVID-19 has induced sharp swings in firm cash flows and a deterioration in balance-sheet
indicators. While cash flows plummeted in mid-2020, many firms followed a precaution-
ary wait-and-see strategy, cutting investment and accumulating liquid assets. With some
cross-country variation due to, among other things, different degrees of government
intervention, nonfinancial firms in the region were generally able to raise funds from al-
ternative sources.
As a result, leverage has increased for the firms in the Latin American sample by
more than in other regions, especially in high contact sectors such as transport, restau-
rants, hotels, cinemas, museums, recreation, and education. However, the legacy of the
crisis may last well beyond the pandemic. The main concern going forward is the high
debt level with which the corporate sector will exit the pandemic. High leverage leaves
firms vulnerable to further adverse shocks, such as possible new waves of the virus or
further depreciation of domestic currencies. Moreover, increasing debt levels implies a
more demanding amortization schedule: firms in the five countries considered in the region
already have about US$100 billion coming due within one year, about two-thirds of which
is in foreign currency. High debt levels also correlate with low future investment through
a debt overhang effect, which prevents firms from raising new funds as the interest rate
burden rises. Therefore, while overall risk levels had declined significantly by the second
half of 2020, risks may remain for firms with weaker balance sheets.
As the healing process continues in the post-pandemic period, the financial health
of firms must be monitored and risks contained to avoid setbacks in the recovery. Still, the
COVID-19 shock has meant significant reallocation between economic sectors. Countries
should try to tap the opportunities created in those sectors that have emerged as leading
sectors according to their stock market valuations and consider policies that would allow
labor to move more easily from losers to winners. The latter include tech-related service
sectors and some manufacturing sectors, like chemicals, capital intensive manufactures,
and electronics. The expansion of those sectors can help turn the recovery into stronger
and more sustainable post-pandemic growth.
90
CHAPTER 7
G
lobal value chains (GVCs), or the separation of production into stages across borders,
provide countries with opportunities to diversify trade and boost productivity and
growth by specializing in one stage of the production process. For the most part,
however, the region has not taken full advantage of the growth in GVCs, and Regional
Value Chains (RVCs) within Latin America and the Caribbean have been limited. The
region’s participation in GVCs remains low (18%) compared to Asia (28%) and Europe
(34%).1 In particular, Latin America and the Caribbean lags behind other regions when it
comes to intraregional supply chains, which represent only 24% of total GVC participation,
compared to 56% in Asia, and 74% in Europe (Blyde and Trachtenberg, 2020). Moreover,
GVC participation in Latin America and the Caribbean has had less than half the impact
on productivity than in other regions. 2
The COVID-19 pandemic, plus concerns regarding protectionism and natural disas-
ters, have made countries and companies reassess their positions in global value chains.
The crisis has taken a huge toll on trade, but also provides opportunities to boost regional
integration and value chains within the Americas, sometimes referred to as nearshoring
from the perspective of the United States. Interestingly, despite the crisis, some firms
have performed well, even in those sectors where global demand has fallen, while others
have lost market share.
This chapter analyzes the performance of individual firms, drawing on the study
of rich micro data, to understand their different outcomes. The results are then used to
outline potential policies to assist firms in the region. There is much potential for firms to
more fully participate in both RVCs and GVCs—a prospect that could significantly benefit
the process of recovery from the pandemic. 3
1 GVC participation is measured as the sum of the imported intermediate used in a country’s exports plus the
country’s exports used by another country in the production of its exports, relative to total exports.
2 Cross-country estimates indicate that a 1% increase in GVC participation is associated with a 0.33 percent-
age point increase in the long-run growth of labor productivity. But in Latin America and the Caribbean the
estimate is 0.18 percentage points lower. See Appendix C.
3 The analysis presented in this chapter is based on transaction-level data of imports and exports obtained
91
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
During the COVID-19 pandemic, total exports declined sharply in most countries in the
region and across the majority of sectors and destinations. Figure 7.1 compares export
growth during the first two quarters of 2020 with that in the same quarters of 2019 and
2018, pooling firm level information for six countries in the region: Chile, Colombia, Mexico,
Paraguay, Peru, and Uruguay. The downward shift is clear: more firms suffered lower
export growth and a greater number posted a decline in exports. Figure 7.1 focuses on
continuing exporters; therefore, companies that did not export in the first two quarters
of 2019 or 2020 are excluded.
Exports not only fell, but they did so relative to a measure of global demand, which
is constructed as a weighted average of the growth of US and European imports of the
same products across the world, with weights corresponding to the relative importance
of each product in the region’s export basket (see Figure 7.2).4 The figure also includes
the average export growth in the year before the crisis. Total exports plummeted about
60% between May 2019 and May 2020, while they grew from May 2018 to 2019.
0.010
0.008
Density
0.006
0.004
0.002
0.000
–200 –100 0 100 200
4 Each product refers to a category of the Harmonized Commodity Description and Coding System (HS) at
the six-digit disaggregation level comprising approximately 5,300 products.
92
Global and Regional Value Chains: Risks and Opportunities
10
Export and global demand growth (%)
–10
–20
–30
–40
–50
–60
–70
Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep
Figure 7.2 also plots the export performance in intermediate goods (excluding those
in mining and agriculture), and their corresponding global demand. For the six Latin
American countries analyzed, the decline in intermediate goods exported was larger than
that of total exports. This suggests that participating in value chains may be riskier than
exporting finished goods; still, these exports have recovered since June and have grown
faster than global demand for the same products.
To investigate the role of value chains, this chapter focuses on manufactured interme-
diate goods. 5 These exports are likely to be part of GVCs given their significant backward
and forward linkages.6 At 38% of total exports, they represent a significant fraction of the
export basket for the countries considered.7
5 The analysis focuses on intermediate inputs excluding those in mining and agriculture, following the Broad
Economic Categories (BEC) classification. The conclusions are similar when consumption and capital goods
(excluding mining and agriculture) are also considered in the analysis. See Antràs (2020) for a detailed discus-
sion on the different measures of GVCs using data at the country-industry and firm level.
6 Backward linkages correspond to the value added of imported intermediates used in producing goods to be
exported. Forward linkages represent the domestic value added of intermediate products that are exported
and used in producing trade partner exports. Some countries specialize in upstream natural resource activities,
with limited backward linkages but with strong forward linkages. Mining and agriculture are excluded since
they do not have significant backward linkages.
7 Manufactured intermediate goods are 40% of exports in Mexico, 20% in Colombia, 32% in Peru, 34% in
93
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
During the COVID-19 crisis, US imports from China fell more than 18%, followed by a 17% reduc-
tion from Mexico and 15% from other countries in Latin America and the Caribbean. Imports
from other Asian countries only fell 6% and imports from Europe actually increased 2% (see
Figure 7.3, left panel). Around US$56.5 billion (6.1%) of total US imports switched source
countries during the period. This contrasts with the reallocation observed in normal times; for
example, in 2016–17, the reallocation of US imports was only 2.6 percentage points, less than
half the movement registered during the pandemic.8 This represents a considerable opportu-
nity for the region, which exported just US$26 billion in goods in 2019 to the United States.
For intermediate goods, Europe raised its market share within US imports by 3 per-
centage points or US$5.6 billion, while Latin America and the Caribbean’s share fell by 1
percentage point (see Figure 7.3, Panel B). How can the region emulate Europe or other
Asian countries and take greater advantage of firms’ reassessment of global value chains
in the wake of COVID-19?
Global demand did not fall for all goods. And not all exports from all countries fell.
Impacts depended on the sector and the country. Comparing what happened to demand and
what happened to exports for each country-sector pair helps identify winners and losers.
China China
Mexico Mexico
Canada Canada
Europe Europe
–20 –10 0 10 20 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3
8 In2018–19, largely due to the US-China tariff increases, the United States reallocated 8.1 percentage points
of imports (See Figure C7.5A and C7.5B in Appendix C).
94
Global and Regional Value Chains: Risks and Opportunities
For most sectors in most countries, both global demand and exports from the region
fell. This is the bottom left quadrant of Figure 7.4, Panel A, labelled quadrant III. But even
then, some sectors in some countries did better than others; these are the dots to the
right of the 45-degree line in that quadrant where exports (measured along the horizontal
40
% change in global demand
II I
20
–40
IV
III (b)
–60
–100 –80 –60 –40 –20 0 20 40 60 80 100
% change of exports
Colombia Mexico Peru Chile Paraguay Uruguay 45-degree line
40
% change in global demand
20 Pharma
Chemical products products
Tanning extracts
Albuminoidal
Organic chemicals Cocoa
0
Sugar confect
Plastics articles Machinery
Knitted fabrics
Fertilizers Copper Vehicles
–20 Iron/steel Glass
articles Rubber articles Precious metals
Aluminum
Iron/steel Nuclear reactors
–40
–60
–60 –40 –20 0 20 40 60
% change of exports
95
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
axis) did better than expected given the fall in demand (measured on the vertical axis).
For example, while aluminium and rubber exports from Colombia declined, as did global
demand, Colombian exports in these sectors fell by less than the dip in global demand,
allowing them to gain in export market share (see Figure 7.4, Panel B). 9
Quadrant IV in Figure 7.4 is of particular interest as it contains sectors in which exports
have increased despite falling global demand. Such was the case for vehicles and pre-
cious metals in Colombia, which therefore gained market share for exports in these areas.
Quadrant II contains sectors in countries where exports have fallen even though
global demand has risen; in Colombia, this category includes chemicals, implying consid-
erable market share was lost.
Finally, quadrant I contains sectors in countries where both global demand and exports
rose. In some cases, market share even grew (the sectors to the right of the 45-degree
line). In Colombia, cocoa products fall into this category.
Employing individual firm data provide insight on these cases, the drivers of success
or failure, and the direction of fruitful policies to consider.
While exports fell in some sectors, some individual firms may have actually increased their
exports. In the same way, some firms may have exported less even though exports from
the sector as a whole increased. Exports can rise or fall because firms increase or reduce
their level of exports, stop exporting altogether, or enter the export market. In general,
there are then four ways in which total exports can change, sometimes referred to in
economics as the intensive and the extensive margin (see Box 7.1 for further discussion):10
In quadrants I and IV (where exports rose), interestingly, large firms accounted for the
net trade creation; Figure 7.5 considers each quadrant and graphs the four types of trade
creation and destruction for large and smaller firms. For small and medium-sized firms, net
trade creation was negative in all quadrants. In quadrants II and III, both larger and smaller
firms engaged in net trade destruction. Moreover, large firms tended to adjust by increasing
or reducing their exports—the intensive margin. In sharp contrast, smaller firms adjust more by
stopping exporting altogether, or by starting to export—the extensive margin. Trade destruction
9 Further details and figures for the rest of the countries in the sample can be found in Appendix C.
10 See Alviarez (forthcoming).
96
Global and Regional Value Chains: Risks and Opportunities
TABLE 7.1 Sectors with the Largest Gaps between Exports and Global Demand
Gap = supply
growth-
Supply Demand demand Share of
Country Sector name Quadrant growth growth growth intermediates
Colombia Iron/steel III (a) –0.44 –0.31 –0.13 0.07
Colombia Plastic articles III (a) –0.17 –0.07 –0.09 0.18
Colombia Precious metals IV 0.38 –0.24 0.62 0.29
Mexico Machinery III (a) –0.15 –0.07 –0.08 0.24
Mexico Vehicles III (a) –0.27 –0.23 –0.04 0.17
Mexico Plastic articles III (b) –0.07 –0.07 0.01 0.05
Peru Precious metals III (a) –0.47 –0.24 –0.22 0.46
Peru Zinc articles III (a) –0.40 –0.22 –0.18 0.05
Peru Res. food indus. III (a) –0.26 –0.14 –0.12 0.11
Chile Wood articles III (a) –0.10 –0.06 –0.04 0.09
Chile Pulp of wood III (a) –0.33 –0.30 –0.02 0.09
Chile Inorg/org chem III (b) –0.03 –0.14 0.12 0.08
Paraguay Machinery III (a) –0.53 –0.07 –0.46 0.12
Paraguay Plastic articles III (a) –0.25 –0.07 –0.18 0.05
Paraguay Res. food indus. III (b) –0.05 –0.14 0.09 0.50
Uruguay Raw hides III (a) –0.63 –0.35 –0.28 0.06
Uruguay Animal hair III (a) –0.72 –0.50 –0.23 0.06
Uruguay Plastic articles III (a) –0.16 –0.07 –0.09 0.11
Source: Alviarez (forthcoming).
Note: The table shows per country, the first three sectors (HS2 categories) ordered by the difference between their supply and
demand growth and with export market share equal or above 5%.
when smaller firms completely stop exporting is particularly worrisome as relationships and
links in their trade network may all be destroyed.11 Trade destruction at the extensive margin is
not just limited to those sectors in which exports fell (quadrants II and III) but is even present
among smaller firms in sectors for which exports rose (quadrants I and IV).
The table in the lower panel of Figure 7.5 shows the net trade creation and each margin
but this time weighted by the relative importance of each sector and by firm size. Thus, the
figures for net trade creation are not the same as in the figure that illustrates unweighted
trade creation. As expected, most of the trade destruction occurs in quadrant III where
most sector-country pairs lie. Large firms accounted for most of the trade destruction (as
they export more given their size) but this was largely through an adjustment in exports.
Small and medium-sized firms also accounted for substantial trade destruction, which
was divided equally between an adjustment in exports and halting exports altogether.
11 Thefirm’s export size distribution in each country-sector pair is divided into ventiles (20-quantiles). A firm
is considered large if it belongs to the 20th quartile, and small or medium otherwise. Large firms account on
average for 83% of exports; trade creation and destruction for each group are simple averages.
97
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
In empirical analyses, five firm characteristics appear to play a key role in explaining
export performance during the pandemic: i) Firm size, ii) diversification of export markets,
iii) whether the firm also imports, iv) whether the firm imports intermediate goods from
distant countries such as China, and v) the performance of the firms’ suppliers and customers
40 40
20 20
Change of exports (%)
0 0
–20 –20
–40 –40
–60 –60
–80 –80
–100 –100
I II III IV I II III IV
Quadrants Quadrants
Trade destruction through exit Trade destruction by adjustment of exports
Trade creation through entry Trade creation by adjustment of exports
Net trade creation
Trade
Trade creation destruction by Trade
Net trade by adjustment of Trade creation adjustment of destruction
Quadrant creation exports through entry exports through exit
Large firms (% change)
I 1.1 0.8 0.5 –0.1 –0.1
II –0.4 0.2 0.1 –0.5 –0.2
III –11.1 5.1 1.0 –13.7 –3.5
IV 4.4 5.6 1.1 –0.8 –1.5
Small and medium firms (% change)
I 0.4 1.0 0.6 –0.4 –0.8
II –0.3 0.1 0.1 –0.2 –0.2
III –5.8 2.6 3.8 –6.1 –6.1
IV –0.9 1.0 1.4 –0.6 –2.6
Total –12.7 16.2 8.6 –22.5 –15.0
98
Global and Regional Value Chains: Risks and Opportunities
During the COVID-19 pandemic period, exports declined in most sectors. Nonetheless, within each
sector some exporting firms ‘created trade’ either by increasing their level of exports during the
first three quarters of 2020 relative to 2019 (intensive margin), or because some firms exported in
2020 but did not export during the previous year (extensive margin). Figure 7.1.1 shows the shrink-
ing growth rate of exports (yellow line) across Colombian macro sectors. Overall export growth
within a sector can be broken down into two components: trade creation (TC) represented by light
blue and purple bars, and trade destruction (TD), represented by dark blue and green bars. Trade
creation distinguishes between (i) an increase in exports at expanding firms (light blue bars), and
(ii) exports created by new exporters (purple bars). Similarly, trade destruction (TD) distinguishes
between export losses among shrinking exporters (dark blue bars) and firms exiting from foreign
markets (green bars) (see Alviarez, forthcoming).
The startling fact captured by Figure B7.1.1 is the simultaneous trade creation and destruc-
tion in a given sector, indicating that net trade creation (yellow line) masks big differences among
60
40
20
0
–20
–40
–60
–80
Machinery
Vehicles
Misc. manufactures
Sugar confection
Cocoa
Inorg/org chemicals
Organic chemicals
Pharmaceutical products
Fertilizers
Tanning extr.
Ceramic
Glass
Albuminoidal
Chemical products
Plastic articles
Rubber articles
Paper articles
Man–made filaments
Knitted fabrics
Precious metals
Iron/steel
Iron/steel articles
Copper
Aluminum
Nuclear reactors
firms. For example, in Colombia, although exports of precious metals expanded by a robust 36%
on net, certainly not all firms enjoyed export growth during this period. In fact, substantial trade
destruction (41%) occurred in the sector. In the pharmaceutical products sector, net trade creation
was relatively small (1% in the first three quarters of 2020), but both trade creation and trade
destruction were substantial. Firms that exported in 2020 but not in 2019, or that increased their
99
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
exports over this period, accounted for trade creation of 21.2%. On the other hand, the firms that
stopped exporting in this sector, or that exported less than in the previous year, accounted for
trade destruction of nearly the same magnitude but opposite signed (24.1%). Given the high levels
of trade destruction in some sectors, trade creators have played a crucial role in compensating
the negative effect of trade destruction on aggregate export growth.
Formally, net trade creation (NTC) is given by trade creation (TC) minus trade destruction
(TD), NTCft = TCft –TDft . Trade creation is calculated as the weighted sum of the growth rate cor-
responding to those firms that increase trade, weighted by their relative importance in the economy,
⎛x ⎞
TCft = ∑ gft≥0 ⎜⎜⎜ ft ⎟⎟⎟ gft .
⎜⎝ x st ⎟⎠
Notice that the weights are constructed as the average of firm exports across the two
periods, relative to the country’s average total exports in the two periods. Similarly,
trade destruction is defined as the weighted average of the absolute growth of firms
The export growth rate is calculated using the mid-point method, gft = 2( xft − xft–1 ) / ( xft + xft–1 ) .
This decomposition is inspired by the concepts of labor creation and destruction applied in the
labor literature (Davis and Haltiwanger, 1992).
(the resilience of the firms’ network).12 The importance of these specific factors suggests
how policies might be best designed to help firms participate in global value chains.
i. Firm size. As discussed, large firms appear to adjust exports smoothly while small
firms destroy trade by stopping exports altogether. Adjusting in this manner is
highly inefficient as broken links are likely to be permanent. The lower capacity
of smaller firms to absorb negative shocks may explain this behavior. Although
small firms represent a relatively small share of exports (15–20% on average),
they account for a significant fraction of employment. Finding ways to preserve
the links for small firms that are already exporting would be a valuable policy
objective. Facilitating access to credit may boost a small firm’s capacity to absorb
negative shocks, helping them preserve links.13
ii. Diversification in export markets. Diversification lowers risks or, put another way,
having only a few customers for most of a firm’s exports (a high concentration of
12 See
Alviarez (forthcoming).
13 Dueto their scale, the exports of small firms are often concentrated in just a few clients—often only 1 (see
explanation in the next subsection on diversification).
100
Global and Regional Value Chains: Risks and Opportunities
60 60
40 40
Change of exports (%)
20 20
0 0
–20 –20
–40 –40
–60 –60
–80 –80
I II III IV I II III IV
Quadrants Quadrants
Trade destruction through exit Trade destruction by adjustment of exports
Trade creation through entry Trade creation by adjustment of exports
Net trade creation
customers) is risky. Firms that export to only a few customers create more trade but
also destroy more trade than more diversified ones. In all quadrants, trade destruc-
tion is greater for firms with low customer diversification. In quadrant III (referring
to Figure 7.4), sectors in which global demand and exports fell, trade destruction
was particularly acute for firms with high export concentration.14 In particular, more
firms stopped exporting altogether (See Figure 7.6). As noted, this is an inefficient
way to adjust trade as re-establishing these broken links is costly. And in the case
of quadrant IV (where global demand fell but exports rose), it was also firms with
few customers that created more trade. Interestingly, this trade creation was led
by existing exporters exporting more. One possibility is that these firms took ad-
vantage of problems face by other suppliers. But firms were unable to create trade
if they had to start exporting; only firms that were already exporters could do so.
Perhaps the most relevant finding is that low customer diversification implies
more trade destruction in the event of a negative shock. In fact, the contribution
14 A firm is considered to highly (low) concentrate its exports among their foreign buyers if the Herfindahl
index (HHI) is above (below) the median of the HHI distribution for firms in the same size category (small or
large). This explains why small firms have fewer clients as a result of their scale).
101
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
of exiting exporters in quadrant III was almost twice as larger among concentrated
exporters as it was among exporters with a diversified clientele. Thus, having a
more diversified portfolio of foreign customers can act as an insurance mecha-
nism, especially under adverse demand and supply conditions. From a policy
perspective, the strategy should be to help companies diversify their costumer’s
portfolio, in good times when demand might be increasing, and even in turbulent
times when firms from other countries exit the market, in order to become more
resilient exporters. Policies that help firms preserve their customers in these dif-
ficult times will also make them more resilient for future crises.
iii. The firm’s import status and, iv) whether the firm imports from afar. Exporters
that are also importers tend to benefit from higher quality, cheaper intermediate
products, but appear to be more exposed to external negative shocks and may
not be able to rapidly take advantage of positive shocks. Nonimporting firms ac-
counted for most of the trade creation in quadrants I and IV and importing firms
accounted for most of the trade destruction in quadrants II and III (see Figure 7.7A).
Specifically, in quadrant IV, where global demand fell but exports from the region
rose nonimporters accounted for that net trade creation.
Importing from far afield during the pandemic added further complications.
Importing from China is used to illustrate this point. Firms that imported intermedi-
ate goods from China had lower trade creation in all quadrants compared to firms
that imported from elsewhere (Figure 7.7B). The vast majority of trade creation in
quadrants 1 and 4, where exports rose, was due to firms that imported from else-
where and not from China. Moreover, much of this trade creation came from firms
starting to export. Little trade creation came from firms that started to export if
those firms imported from China.15 There is also more trade destruction from firms
that do not import from China, but net trade creation remains greater. These results
suggest that participating in truly global value chains may reduce the possibility of
taking advantage of new opportunities. One interpretation is that while truly global
value chains may enhance productivity and growth, they may also constrain firms
and are thus less well-positioned to react to shocks and boost exports if there is
an opportunity to do so. Regional value chains may have an advantage in this situ-
ation as they also yield greater productivity and growth but at the same time may
allow firms to take advantage of new export opportunities. The final section of this
chapter outlines policies that would multiply links within the region and allow firms
to source more intermediate inputs from countries in the region which could then
boost exports of finished goods across the region and to advanced economies.16
15 Additional
analysis indicates that this effect is not explained given the size distribution of firms.
16 Given
their comparative advantage, stage of development, and sizable concentration of global production
networks, East Asia is Latin America and the Caribbean’s main competitor exporting to advanced economies.
102
Global and Regional Value Chains: Risks and Opportunities
FIGURE 7.7A Firms that Import Versus Firms that Do Not Import
Exporters that import Exporters that do not import
80 80
60 60
40 40
Change of exports (%)
20 20
0 0
–20 –20
–40 –40
–60 –60
–80 –80
–100 –100
I II III IV I II III IV
Quadrants Quadrants
Trade destruction through exit Trade destruction by adjustment of exports
Trade creation through entry Trade creation by adjustment of exports
Net trade creation
FIGURE 7.7B The Impact of Importing from Afar: China versus Elsewhere
Exporters importing from China Exporters not importing from China
80 80
60 60
40 40
Change of exports (%)
20 20
0 0
–20 –20
–40 –40
–60 –60
–80 –80
–100 –100
I II III IV I II III IV
Quadrants Quadrants
Trade destruction through exit Trade destruction by adjustment of exports
Trade creation through entry Trade creation by adjustment of exports
Net trade creation
103
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
iv. The performance of firms’ suppliers and customers: network resilience. Building
business relationships takes considerable time and effort. This is especially true
in international business, where the transacting parties often do not speak the
same language and conduct business in different time zones. Moreover, relative
to domestic transactions, the time between when orders are placed, customs
are cleared, and products are finally delivered is considerably longer, creating
additional risks that must be managed, and requiring trust between the parties.17
Exporters often rely on imported intermediate inputs tailored to specific
needs, which demands significant investments by both parties. Therefore, when an
exporter loses an existing provider it takes time to search and successfully establish
a relationship with a new partner, which takes a significant toll on output.18 When
facing a large-scale shock such as the COVID-19 pandemic, many businesses are
forced to stop fulfilling their orders, potentially disrupting many relationships.19
The COVID shock has had a serious impact on the foreign suppliers to firms
in the region and also on firms’ customers. Figure 7.8A plots the change in exports
of firms (y-axis) against the fraction of suppliers that the firm lost. 20 Clearly, the
larger the fraction of suppliers that were lost, the more negative is the impact
on firms’ exports. For example, for firms that lost about 20% of their suppliers,
exports fell about 13%. On the other hand, firms that increased their suppliers by
about 20% saw exports grow about 0.1%. A similar exercise considering custom-
ers, rather than suppliers, shows another strong correlation between the change
in exports and the loss in customers. 21 Figure 7.8B plots the export growth of the
firm against the share of customers lost. Firms that exported around a quarter
less lost about a third of their customers.
While the pandemic persists and uncertainty reigns over how the health
and economic crises will proceed, the destruction of the network of firms’ sup-
pliers and customers raises concern. Since it takes time and resources to build
17 To partially overcome the lack of trust, as well as reputational and informational frictions related to inter-
national transactions, the market has developed financial instruments, such as letters of credit, as well as a
complex informational technology system that allows sellers and buyers to share information about themselves
and the products they offer.
18 For a discussion on the relevance of networks on firm performance, see Barrot and Sauvagnat (2016); Martin,
Mejean, and Parenti (2020); Kramarz, Martin, and Mejean (2020); and Bernard et al. (2019).
19 This analysis defines a new relationship as one observed in the current period, but not in the previous one.
Similarly, a disrupted relationship is one observed in the previous period, but not in the current one. Some of
these disrupted relationships could be re-established after the crisis while others may be permanently broken,
especially if buyers connected with new suppliers or sellers found new customers. Therefore, the measure of
network resilience here assesses whether a relationship was disrupted during the pandemic.
20 Firms may add some suppliers and lose others; the analysis is performed on the net change in suppliers for
104
Global and Regional Value Chains: Risks and Opportunities
10
Firms’ export growth (%)
–10
–20
–30
–40
–60 –40 –20 0 20 40 60
10
Firms’ export growth (%)
–10
–20
–30
–40
–40 –30 –20 –10 0 10 20 30 40
relationships, if the network continues to unravel, then the region could experi-
ence a significant loss of exports. On the other hand, the shake-up in global value
chains may represent an opportunity that firms in the region can exploit.
Policy Implications
Increasing participation in global value chains can help countries in the region improve
productivity and growth but may increase vulnerability to shocks. How can policies
105
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
simultaneously enhance participation and reduce risks? Turbulent times like the present
sometimes offer windows of opportunity. These windows may close rapidly, and must be
taken advantage of, since these windows are temporary, but their possible benefits can
be permanent.
Several policies can help firms participate in value chains more generally. Allowing
multinational corporations to operate more freely, fostering trade-facilitation, improving
logistics performance, investing in infrastructure (both physical capital and its governance),
promoting innovation by enhancing intellectual property protection, and investing in educa-
tion and training to improve the technical abilities of workers are all examples of broader,
horizontal policies that can facilitate greater insertion into GVCs. Improving institutions
including trade promotion agencies can also play an important role. 22
Deepening regional value chains that are less developed and less vulnerable to global
shocks would also bring benefits. Removing the barriers to regional integration would go
a long way to promoting greater participation in regional value chains. 23 Unfortunately,
a complicated “spaghetti bowl” of trade agreements across the region lacks consistent
rules. Most trade that does take place could be under preferences (in other words, an
agreement likely exists between the exporting and importing country) but the complexity
of regulations increases the costs of compliance and results in little trade. For example,
rules of origin differ across agreements and do not cumulate between agreements in
many cases. 24 Forming regional value chains involving several countries becomes difficult
indeed. A bottom-up approach ensuring that the rules of origin are consistent between
the many different agreements and removing other trade and nontrade barriers would
provide a significant boost. 25
The analysis in this chapter suggests a set of more specific policies could be beneficial:
22 For a more detailed discussion please refer to Mesquita Moreira and Stein (2019).
23 These barriers affect the gains from trade and multinational production, distorting the levels and the sectoral
allocation of foreign investment (Alviarez, 2019).
24 Some firms do not even bother to ensure that the preferences are applied given the high costs of compliance.
106
Global and Regional Value Chains: Risks and Opportunities
main problems. Policies to help efficient firms weather transitory negative shocks
and thereby prevent their exit from the export market could be highly beneficial.
As reviewed in Chapter 5, governments have attempted to facilitate credit
during the crisis through guarantee programs. Despite concerns regarding the
potential fiscal losses associated with these policies and their support of poten-
tially inefficient firms, their aim is to keep firms operating and their labor force
intact during the health crisis. These programs may be particularly useful for
exporters whose foreign client is also in financial distress and, unable to pay in
advance, must wait to receive payment upon delivery of goods. This policy will
help small and medium exporters to mitigate the high cost associated with re-
lationship disruptions. It also complements Basel III regulations that establish a
lower capital requirement for trade finance instruments and waives the so-called
sovereign floor for confirmed letters of credit, which are particularly important for
low-income countries. 26 Lower regulatory costs for trade finance could increase
the resilience of these countries to external shocks.
• Exporters’ network resilience: Having a robust set of supplier networks enhances
firm export performance, since firm-level idiosyncratic shocks propagate across
their production networks. Evidence from the aftermath of natural disasters, for
example, indicates that affected suppliers impose substantial output losses on their
customers, especially when they produce specific inputs, which is the typical case
in complex GVCs. 27 Diversification at the source country level is also important.
For example, from January to March 2020 some US firms shifted their imports of
particular goods from China to Vietnam and Bangladesh, in response to the initial
stages of the COVID-19 pandemic (Heise, 2020a). This sourcing diversification
strategy was implemented by firms that already imported from the alternative
locations, indicating the importance of pre-existing commercial relationships and
the usefulness of market diversification to build resilience of GVCs. In addition,
diversification of GVCs among foreign suppliers can reduce macroeconomic
volatility by lowering the exposure to any single country. Countries that source
from a variety of locations are better shielded from shocks and experience less
aggregate volatility. Concentration on a single country can increase the risk of a
shock propagating through supply chains and negatively affecting the economy
(Caselli et al., 2020).
Given the importance of maintaining relationships and creating new ones
when facing a significant shock like the COVID-19 pandemic, it is critical to support
business networks on this front. Online networks for businesses are an important
tool provided through the internet for SMEs to connect to international markets.
107
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
The COVID-19 pandemic can become an opportunity for Latin America and the Caribbean.
Foreign markets are restructuring their sourcing strategies and the region may be able to
take advantage of these shifts. Windows of opportunity open during crises but may close
rapidly. Countries that fail to take advantage of them may miss out on lasting benefits. For
example, policies that promote trade credit today may be more effective in allowing firms
to jump on opportunities—including avoiding dropping links to clients and suppliers—than
similar efforts in normal times. Nonetheless, this chapter suggests the need to emphasize
some of these policies on a more consistent basis. Turbulent times may lead to great gains
when earlier and more sustained efforts to help firms participate into GVC are in place. By
grouping firms by their export performance relative to global demand, and by analyzing
which characteristics are most likely to be associated with their capacity to create and de-
stroy trade, this chapter contributes to finding the right mix of policies to help the region
achieve greater and more stable participation in value chains and foster longer-term growth.
108
CHAPTER 8
T
he COVID-19 pandemic hit economic growth in Latin America and the Caribbean
hard (see Chapter 1). But growth has been elusive in the region for decades. Since
1960, the average per capita growth rate of real GDP in the region was 2.4% per
annum—noticeably below that of the rapidly growing Emerging Asian countries (4.9%).
Two factors contributing to mediocre long-run growth have been low investment rates,
resulting in limited capital deepening, and laggard total factor productivity (TFP) growth,
which is the most widely used measure of aggregate economic efficiency.1 Another factor
has been recurrent economic crises. 2 Crises have costs, and not all sectors recover alike.
This asymmetry affects the allocation of economic resources after crises and, therefore,
long-run growth.
COVID-19 has generated more output losses among labor-intensive sectors, which
have been most impacted by changing consumption and production patterns. Despite
the unprecedented nature of the pandemic, the disproportionate impact on labor-inten-
sive sectors is a common feature of crises because those sectors are more “malleable,”
meaning that labor is easier to reallocate than capital. The same feature, compounded
by depressed investment in physical capital after crises, allows labor-intensive sectors
to absorb relatively more resources in the recovery process than capital-intensive sec-
tors. A problem with this bust and recovery cycle is that labor intensive sectors are
also less productive on average and, therefore, resources may be misallocated and hurt
economic efficiency. To reverse that cycle, countries should increase investment in sec-
tors with a greater potential to increase TFP. A case in point is infrastructure: investing
in infrastructure builds up or improves a country’s transport, energy, water and sanita-
tion, and telecommunication assets, with positive spillovers to other sectors. More and
1 Since 1960, growth has been fueled by increased labor participation—amid the demographic bonus—and
higher skills as education expanded to universal coverage (see Cavallo and Powell, 2018).
2 In terms of investment, Latin America and the Caribbean invested less (as a share of GDP) before the pan-
demic than any other region except Sub-Saharan Africa. While investment (net of capital depreciation) has
averaged 12% of GDP since 1960, it was 19% of GDP in Emerging Asia during the same period. The growth
rate of TFP has been close to zero since 1960 in Latin America and the Caribbean, while it was approximately
1 percent per annum on average in Emerging Asia.
109
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
3 Calvo (2005).
4 See, for example, Hausmann and Rodrik (2003).
5 This idea was identified long ago in the Latin American and Caribbean literature as a case of “speculative
production,” in that entrepreneurs, constantly speculating on relative price volatility, pick technologies that
make it easy to switch from one product to the other. See Ocampo Gaviria (1984).
6 LA-KLEMS is the Latin America and the Caribbean chapter of World KLEMS, a global initiative set up to
promote the analysis of growth and productivity patterns around the world. The approach is based on a growth
accounting framework. See: Jorgenson (2012) and LA-KLEMS (2019) databases. The key innovation of the
KLEMS methodology is the building up of databases on output (GDP), inputs (i.e., capital stocks, labor, and
intermediate inputs) and productivity at a detailed economic sector level.
7 The LA-KLEMS database provides data for ten economic sectors at the 1-digit ISIC (rev 3)—agriculture;
construction; electricity, gas and water; financial services (finance and insurance); manufacturing; mining;
transport (transportation, storage, and communication); wholesale, hotels and restaurants; and other personal
services— for eight Latin American economies (Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, El Salvador,
Honduras, Mexico, and Peru), over the period 1990–2017.
110
Growth, Productivity, and Malleability
100 Mining
TFP (index, 100= Max)
80
Agriculture
Other personal services
20
0
–7 –6 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0
Source: IDB staff calculations based on LA-KLEMS (2019) and EU-KLEMS (Van Ark and Jäger, 2017).
Note: Each point is the average of the sector’s TFP and its capital-labor (K/L) ratio, with the average taken over time and
across countries (eight countries from LA-KLEMS, and 12 countries from EU-KLEMS). The TFP for each sector/country is
calculated as a residual using a Cobb-Douglas production function with sector specific coefficients (see Appendix D). Capital
units are in PPP 2010 US dollars, and labor is measured in number of workers.
EU-KLEMS. 8 The figure illustrates that more capital intensity is associated with higher
TFP levels, on average. 9 Given that aggregate TFP is the weighted average of sector-level
TFPs, countries that adopt less capital intensive—more malleable—technologies have lower
aggregate efficiency (TFP). In the case of Latin America and the Caribbean, for example,
the average capital intensity across sectors is about two-thirds that in Europe, while the
average TFP level in the region is 60% lower.10 11
The COVID-19 pandemic is a major shock that is likely to have significant and persistent
impacts on the allocation of resources across sectors.12 The long-run implications of those
8 Appendix D describes how TFP measures are constructed. Suffice it to say that TFP is constructed by a cost
shares approach. A Cobb–Douglas production function in labor and capital is assumed. The production function
is log-linearized and TFP is computed as the accounting difference between output and a linear combination
of the inputs with cost shares varying between sectors but remaining constant across countries.
9 See Cavallo et al. (2013) and Pagés (2010).
10 K/L ratios are lower in Latin America and the Caribbean than in Europe at the aggregate economy level, and
across most economic sectors. At the aggregate economy level, the K/L ratio in Europe is 1.5 times that in the
region. At the sector level, most sectors in the region have lower K/L ratios than their European counterparts.
See Appendix D for details.
11 Lower TFP implies that the average efficiency with which factors of production (i.e., labor and capital) are
employed to produce output is lower, which in turn explains relative income differentials across countries. See
Caselli (2005), and Hsieh and Klenow (2010), and Daude and Fernández-Arias (2010) for an analysis of Latin
America and the Caribbean.
12 See Barrero, Bloom, and Davis (2020).
111
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
changes will depend on which sectors expand and attract more resources in the recovery
phase. The experience of the region coping with crises can be a useful benchmark to assess
the possible implications of COVID-19. In order to make that assessment, this chapter first
ranks sectors’ malleability, employs the resulting classification to study the sector level im-
pacts of the COVID-19 shock, and then draws lessons for the recovery from previous crises.
Malleability is inversely related to the K/L ratio. Figure 8.2 shows the ranking of economic
sectors by their K/L ratio, comparing across sectors in Latin America and the Caribbean
(x-axis) and Europe (y-axis). Sectors with a low rank have more malleable production
technologies, and vice-versa. The ranking across sectors between regions is similar except
for agriculture, which has the lowest K/L ratio in the region, while it ranks six out of ten in
Europe. This suggests that, on average, the technologies used in the region's agricultural
sectors are significantly less capital intensive than in Europe.13
9 Financial services
Low
8 malleability Electricity, gas, and water
7 Mining
+ ← malleability → –
6 Agriculture
Europe
5 Intermediate Transport
malleability
4 Manufacturing
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
13 Theagricultural sector in Latin America and the Caribbean is split between modern (likely more capital in-
tensive) and traditional (likely labor intensive) subsectors that co-exist (see Mesquita Moreira and Stein, 2019).
The low capital intensity of agriculture in Figure 8.3 likely reflects the predominance of the more traditional
sector in this sample.
112
Growth, Productivity, and Malleability
The similar ranking of sectors suggests that the degree of malleability is intrinsic
to the production processes, with some sectors employing more malleable technologies
(i.e., less capital per unit of labor) than others everywhere.14 This implies that, for example,
construction is more malleable than manufacturing, and manufacturing in turn is more
malleable than the electricity, gas, and water sector in both regions. Except for agricul-
ture, the other sectors15 form three malleability clusters: “high malleability” comprises
construction, wholesale, hotels and restaurants, and other personal services; “intermediate
malleability” consists of manufacturing and transport, and; “low malleability” consists of
mining, financial services, and electricity, gas and water.
The relative size of each group in the average economy in Latin America is shown in
Figure 8.3. The intermediate (27%) and higher malleability (39%) groups are bigger than
the low malleability group (25%) and, therefore, weigh more in the aggregate economy.
Agriculture accounts for about 9% of the total. The next section uses this sector level
classification to assess the impact of COVID-19 on sectors.
FIGURE 8.3 Sectoral Share of GDP in Latin America and the Caribbean
Wholesale, hotels,
Agriculture 9%
and restaurants
Mining
%
35
l l.
Ma
Lo w
Hi g h
M a ll .
2 5%
Other personal
services Financial services
Construction
In t
er. Manufacturing
M al l
. 27 %
Transport
14 The assumption that the degree of malleability of sectors is intrinsic to their production processes is akin
to the Rajan and Zingales (1998) assumption that there is a technological reason i(.e., different capital intensi-
ties) why some industries depend more on credit than others and that these technological differences persist
across countries and over time.
15 Housing is dropped from the sample because of lack of data.
113
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
The global pandemic triggered simultaneous supply and demand shocks across sectors.
Lockdowns and other mitigation measures led to the total or partial suspension of pro-
ductive activities, hampering consumption and production. The effect of lockdowns has
been stronger in sectors whose activities involve agglomeration and physical proximity/
contact like, for example, tourism, entertainment, hotels and restaurants, transport, and
personal services, which are labor intensive sectors; it has been milder in sectors consid-
ered essential, for example, food, and some manufacturing activities including cleaning
supplies and disinfectants, pharmaceuticals, and medical supplies.16
As the pandemic crisis hit, real GDP fell by 0.6% year-on-year (yoy) on average during
the first quarter of 2020 across selected countries in the region with available data (see
Table 8.1). The impacts of the lockdowns were felt in full force in second quarter 2020, with
output collapsing by 13.1% yoy, and falling an additional 6.6% yoy on average during the
third quarter.17 The impacts on sector-level output in turn, have been larger among the high
and intermediate malleability groups, than in the low malleability group. The exception is
agriculture, which has withstood the shock better than other malleable sectors, probably
because food, being essential, has benefited from the mitigation policies—including direct
transfers to sustain incomes—that governments implemented in response to the pandemic.
The impacts on output have varied across sectors; what can be expected during the
recovery phase? And what may be the implications for the efficient allocation of resources?
While it is too early to know when the COVID-19 crisis will end, the next section reviews the
pattern of economic recovery from previous crises in search of clues to answer these ques-
tions. The COVID-19 crisis presents both similarities and differences with previous crises.
While the crises that have affected the region since the 1980s usually had either a trade or
a financial shock at their epicenter, during the pandemic international trade was severely
16 SeeECLAC (2020).
17 Similar
sectoral patterns have been observed in other countries. For example, Brinca, Duarte, and
Faria-e-Castro (2020).
114
Growth, Productivity, and Malleability
curtailed by the lockdowns and the global collapse in demand (see Chapters 3 and 7). On
the positive side, to date countries have been spared financial crises thanks to swift policy
responses (see Chapter 5). Despite the differences, the evidence from previous crises may
still shed light on how unique the sector level impacts of COVID-19 (summarized in Table
8.1) have been, and what are the possible implications for growth after the pandemic.
The analysis considers the impact of large economic crises that affected the eight countries
in the LA-KLEMS database since 1990. They are the Tequila Crisis affecting Mexico in 1995,
the aftermath of the Asian and Russian financial crises, which affected Peru in 1998 and
Colombia in 1999, and the Global Financial Crisis of 2008–09 that affected all the countries
in the sample and caused generalized recessions in 2009. The study is of the impacts
of the crises on sector level output and TFP during the crisis and in the recovery phase.
For each of the crises, the crisis year trough (i.e., the year when real GDP bottomed-
out) is presented as T, and the behavior of sector level real GDP and total factor pro-
ductivity (TFP) five years before and four years after the onset of the crisis is studied.
To summarize information across sectors and across crises, the outcome variables of
interest are transformed into indices and then normalized to 100 on T-1, the year prior to
the crisis trough. Then, the simple (unweighted) average of sectors’ indices within each
malleability group for the various crisis episodes in the sample is taken to produce one
synthetic index per group.
Figure 8.4 reports the real GDP indices for the three malleability groups, plus agricul-
ture, which is separated from the other sectors because it has different capital intensities
in Latin America and in Europe, and therefore does not align unequivocally with one of
the malleability groups. Figure 8.4 also reports the index for the economy, which is the
aggregate (weighted average) of all sectors.18
Panel E shows that real GDP losses at the peak of the crisis (on period T) average
5.3% of GDP for the average economy. After the crisis, it takes an average 1.4 years for
GDP to recover from the trough to the pre-crisis counterfactual level (i.e., the level of GDP
that the group would have reached without a crisis if the pre-crisis trend had continued
without interruption).19 Interestingly, the pattern varies across sectors. For high malle-
ability sectors (Panel C), output losses during the crisis are greater than average (6% of
GDP) and it takes 1.5 years for GDP to recover to the pre-crisis level. On this dimension,
18 The total is the aggregate of all economic sectors, which is also the weighted average of sectors, where the
pre-crisis trend. Cerra and Saxena (2008) find that output loss from financial crises and some types of political
crises is highly persistent.
115
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
120 120
Real GDP (Index, 100=T–1)
100 100
90 90
80 80
T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4 T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4
120 120
Real GDP (Index, 100=T–1)
110 110
100 100
90 90
80 80
T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4 T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4
agriculture (Panel D), which in Latin America is the most malleable sector, behaves like the
other high malleability sectors. In the intermediate malleability group (Panel B), output
falls by 5.9% on average, and it takes 1.7 years to recover to pre-crisis levels. Instead, the
low malleability group (Panel A) is the most resilient: on average output falls by 3.9%, and
it takes about a year to recover to pre-crisis levels. 20
20 Theheterogeneity in how sector level output responds to crises is also observed in the behavior of invest-
ment. Aggregate investment falls by 25.3% on average following crises. Investment remains subdued for a
116
Growth, Productivity, and Malleability
A 3.9 0.9
110
B 5.9 1.7
100
C 6 1.5
90 D 5.6 2.3
80 E 5.3 1.4
T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4
This evidence shows that the way in which crises impacted output across economic
sectors was similar to the COVID-19 crisis (Table 8.1), even though previous crises were
less severe in magnitude. It seems then that more malleable sectors typically suffer a
bigger impact during crises. 21
In addition to the impacts on output, the volatility associated with crises usually di-
verts resources away from efficient allocation, especially in developing countries that are
less able to cope with volatility. 22 Resource misallocation then affects economic efficiency
(TFP) during the recovery phase and beyond.
significant period, taking on average 4.6 years to recover to pre-crisis levels. These aggregate effects are driven
by the high malleability and intermediate groups as investment falls 27.2% and 39.2% on average respectively
following crises. Instead, investment dips only 7.9% in the low malleability group and takes about one year to
recover to its pre-crisis level.
21 This is further confirmed in recent work by Ahumada et al. (2021). They find that while Latin American and
Caribbean countries experienced a smaller aggregate shock during the 2008–09 crisis than OECD countries,
the shock was relatively larger for more malleable sectors.
22 See Cavallo et al. (2013).
117
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Figure 8.5 shows the evolution of measured TFP before and after the crisis onset. 23
TFP levels fall uniformly across the three malleability groups; however, interestingly, it takes
longer for the low malleability group to recover its pre-crisis TFP level (5.6 years) than
either the intermediate (1.9 years) or the high malleability group (2.5 years). The combina-
tion of the sector level responses, plus the impacts on agriculture (Panel D), result in an
100 100
95 95
90 90
T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4 T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4
105 105
100 100
95 95
90 90
T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4 T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4
23 Results
using labor productivity (Real GDP/labor) instead of TFP are qualitatively and quantitatively similar
and do not alter the conclusions.
118
Growth, Productivity, and Malleability
105
A 3.3 5.6
B 2.5 1.9
100
C 3.2 2.5
95
D 2.7 2.5
90 E 3.0 2.7
T-5 T-4 T-3 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 T+3 T+4
Source: IDB staff calculations based on LA-KLEMS (2019) and EU-KLEMS (Van Ark and Jäger, 2017).
Note: T is the crisis year trough (i.e., the year when real GDP bottomed-out in each country). To summarize information
across sectors and crises,TFP of each sector is transformed to an index and normalized to 100 on T-1. Each dot is the simple
(unweighted) average across sectors within each malleability group, for each of the five years before, and the four years after
the crisis onset. Averages taken across 11 crisis episodes. Pre- and post-crisis trend lines are included. The TFP loss is the
difference between the counterfactual TFP (computed projecting the pre-crisis trend to T, and plotted as an empty dot on the
vertical line at T) and actual TFP on T (solid dot on the vertical line at T). The time to recovery is the number of years it takes
after the crisis for TFP to reach the pre-crisis counterfactual level. Time to recovery is calculated by projecting horizontally the
empty dot to the post-crisis trend line, and then down to the x-axis.
estimated aggregate TFP loss of 3% (Panel E) for the economy, which takes 2.7 years to
recover to its pre-crisis levels after the crisis trough. 24
The fact that TFP falls in the aftermath of crises has been also documented by Calvo,
Izquierdo, and Talvi (2006). They found that variations in TFP account for the bulk of the
variation in output throughout the collapse-recovery period for a similar sample of crises. 25
That the TFP losses are persistent has been documented as well by Daude and Fernández-
Arias (2010). What is new about these results is that the pace of recovery varies across
sectors, with TFP growth being slower in high capital intensity—low malleability—sectors.
Thus, sectors with the highest average productivity levels usually experience fewer ef-
ficiency gains than other sectors during the recovery and, therefore, contribute less to
aggregate TFP growth.
24 It takes 1.5 years for productivity to recover its pre-crisis level when using labor productivity instead of TFP
as the proxy.
25 Calvo, Izquierdo, and Talvi (2006) find the swings in measured TFP are hard to attribute to technological
factors. An alternative conjecture is that true TFP remains roughly the same throughout the collapse-recovery
process, and that swings in measured TFP stem from a malfunctioning in the financial system.
119
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
The asymmetric responses of sector level output and TFP in the aftermath of crises
suggest that the sector’s malleability has different implications for the crisis impact and
for the recovery phase. Low malleability sectors—which are more productive on average—
seem to be more resilient and sustain lesser output losses when the crisis hits. The same
pattern has prevailed during the COVID shock. However, as resources are misallocated
during crises, especially in developing countries, the higher resilience of low malleability
sectors does not translate into higher efficiency gains in the aftermath of crises. This, in
turn, has implications for long-run growth. Ahumada and Navajas (2019), for example, show
that a productivity slowdown in key low malleability sectors—for example, infrastructure-
related sectors—can have ripple effects on the rest of the economy that are larger than
the impacts of shocks on more malleable sectors. 26
Yet the risk of slower growth can turn into an opportunity if—unlike previous crises—
the region is able to increase investment in economic sectors that can boost productivity
through their interactions with other sectors. 27
The economic sector with the lowest estimated malleability according to the ranking in
Figure 8.2 is electricity, gas, and water and sanitation which, together with transporta-
tion, storage and communications, comprise what is known as “economic” infrastructure.
Investing in infrastructure can support short- and long-term economic growth (Cavallo,
Powell, and Serebrisky, 2020).
In the short run, boosting infrastructure investment can fuel the recovery from the
pandemic because the spending multiplier from an additional dollar in infrastructure can
be as high as two (see Chapter 2), 28 especially in Latin America and the Caribbean, a region
with infrastructure gaps between 2% and 3% of GDP. 29 In the long run, investing in infra-
structure can propel growth by increasing productivity of other economic sectors, especially
those sectors with high growth potential, because infrastructure services are intermediate
26 Similarly, results from a Computable General Equilibrium model in Brichetti et al. (2020), summarized in
Cavallo, Powell, and Serebrisky (2020), Chapter 12, show that productivity gains in infrastructure can produce
significant gains on other sectors.
27 Ahumada and Navajas (2019) find that if countries in Latin America and the Caribbean could increase produc-
tivity levels in infrastructure- related sectors to the levels of OECD countries, then economy wide productivity
growth could increase by 0.6 percentage points per year (i.e., a 75% increase with respect to the historical
average) just through the estimated impact on the low productivity sectors in the region.
28 Spending multipliers of public investment are significantly higher than current expenditures across a broad
set of country estimates. See Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Végh (2013); Abiad, Furceri, and Topalova (2016); Furceri
and Li (2017); and Izquierdo et al., (2019).
29 Infrastructure gap estimates vary widely depending on the data and methodology, but most estimate gaps
around 2.5% of GDP or about US$150 billion per annum. For a recent analysis of infrastructure gaps in the
region, by sector and by country, see Cavallo and Powell (2019), Chapter 6.
120
Growth, Productivity, and Malleability
production inputs of other economic sectors, with varying intensities. Therefore, if electric-
ity provision is intermittent, for example, sectors that use energy intensively have higher
productive costs and, therefore, are less competitive. Increasing investment in infrastructure
by modest amounts can have significant growth impacts due to their interaction with other
economic sectors 30 Ahumada and Navajas (2019) find that if countries in Latin America and
the Caribbean could increase productivity levels in infrastructure-related sectors via targeted
investments to the levels of OECD countries, then economy-wide productivity growth could
increase by 0.6 percentage points per year (i.e., a 75% increase with respect to the historical
average) just through the estimated impact on the low productivity sectors in the region.
Unfortunately, even before the COVID-19 crisis, investment in infrastructure was low
and declining. Investment in the region averaged just 2.8% of GDP between 2008 and
2017, well below the investment to GDP ratio of East Asia and other fast-growing regions,
thereby widening the infrastructure gaps. Taking the median estimate of the infrastructure
investment needs in the region (5% of GDP), closing the infrastructure gap would require
increasing investment by at least 2 p.p. of GDP (approximately US$110 billion) for years. 31
That level of investment will require both private and public financing. While increasing public
investment will be difficult given tight budgets in the post-COVID 19 context, countries can
still reverse the existing bias against public investment in the region’s spending policies.
Distorted political economy incentives bias public expenditures toward consumption and
away from investment over the economic cycle. 32 One way for governments to address
the spending bias is through the design of fiscal institutions, including fiscal rules that
protect public investment from spending cuts during fiscal consolidations (see Chapter 2).
Private investment, which has averaged about 1% of GDP in the region since 2008, must
also play a role boosting aggregate investment. Private investment must take place where
it makes economic sense: that is, in projects with high rates of social return, and where the
private sector can innovate and provide better quality and more efficient services. There
is plenty of room for private investment to grow. Presently, commercial banks account
for two-thirds of the infrastructure financing available in the region. Instead, institutional
investors, which are ideal candidates to finance infrastructure, only account for 1% of total
financing. Commercial banks have played a leading role in financing because they have
the resources and the project finance skills that are particularly important during the con-
struction phase of projects. But the pressure of tighter regulations, and the COVID crisis,
may prevent commercial banks from keeping long-term loans on their balance sheets. New
investors are therefore needed either from the start of the project, or once the construction
phase is complete. By the time that construction phase ends, project risks decline, and the
nature of the risks facing the financier change. At that point, bonds backed by the return of
121
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
the operation of the asset for example, could be an attractive instrument for institutional
investors. Banks could then sell the bonds to institutional investors and free up space in
their balance sheets for additional new investments. If institutional investors were to al-
locate 5% of their assets under management to infrastructure in the region—currently they
allocate negligible amounts— private investment could double to $40 billion annually. 33
Increasing investment is key to enable the region to take advantage of the oppor-
tunities afforded by the digitalization process that is already underway. Digitizing infra-
structure services, which implies increasing the capital intensity of the sector or making
it less malleable, includes using digital technologies to expand supply, improve demand
management, and improve the quality of the services provided. It includes technologies
like smart meters to control and manage residential electricity consumption, smart phone
apps to monitor the consumption of home appliances, remote digital sensors to measure
and control water pressure, and digital screens at bus, train, and metro stations to inform
passengers on the arrival of the next vehicle. The payoffs of increasing digitalization can
be large: on average, countries would experience a 3.5 percentage point increase in growth
rates over a 10-year period following a 5% increase in efficiency in the sector from modest
increases in investment (Brichetti et al., 2020). Extrapolating to Latin America and the
Caribbean, this represents approximately US$200 billion of incremental output over ten
years. These benefits may be as high as 4 and 5 percentage points of incremental growth
in some countries depending on the context and the structure of their economies. 34
A further opportunity comes from the so-called green infrastructure investment
agenda, which combines the need to invest in infrastructure with countries’ environmental
goals and commitments. When planning investment, resources can be directed towards
investments in sustainable infrastructure that, if well-designed, have at least as large an
impact on growth as standard infrastructure. Green building projects, such as refurbish-
ing existing buildings for better heat insulation and/or clean energy infrastructure, may
have high multiplier effects. And critically, they lower the costs of transitioning toward
renewable energies (see Chapter 9).
COVID-19 has dealt a significant blow to the region. While economic recovery may
be already underway in some sectors and countries, previous crises demonstrate that the
pace of recovery may be uneven and biased against high productivity sectors. Seizing
the opportunities for stronger post-pandemic sustainable growth requires boosting the
recovery by investing more in key, low malleability sectors, which have higher average
productivity, and greater potential to generate positive spillovers on other sectors.
122
CHAPTER 9
W
hile governments focus on the health and economic crises, the environmental
and climate crisis deepens. The pandemic has exacerbated social and economic
needs that amplify the region’s vulnerability to current and future climate change
impacts; the aftermath of the November 2020 hurricanes, Iota and Eta, that struck Central
America tragically illustrates this reality.
This chapter presents evidence on how investing for a sustainable recovery consti-
tutes a win-win strategy, adding millions of jobs and increasing economic growth as well
as reducing climate risks. If the right policies are adopted, there is no trade-off between
climate and growth objectives. A set of policies are suggested to leverage synergies
between economic recovery and climate goals. Estimates suggest additional growth of
more than 1% could be attained.
Public spending designed to help firms and households through the pandemic should
prioritize investments in environmentally friendly activities and help relocate workers to sectors
that will benefit from the transition to a net-zero emissions economy. To guarantee sustained
public and private financing, governments should update their fiscal strategies (to rely less on
fossil fuels) and align regulations and prices with environmental goals. The design of ambitious
and comprehensive climate plans can help ensure the consistency of public policy across sec-
tors and help identify which activities to support and which ones to avoid.
Even before the COVID-19 pandemic hit, climate change was having a substantial impact
on the region (Busso and Messina, 2020). For instance, hurricane seasons are becoming
more severe. The 2017 hurricane season resulted in an estimated loss of 800,000 visitors
to the Caribbean who would have generated US$740 million and supported about 11,000
jobs if there had been no hurricane (Saget, Vogt-Schilb, and Luu, 2020). The most affected
are informal and seasonal (lower paid) workers. Now the pandemic has only deepened
the loss of jobs in these industries in tourism dependent economies.
In November 2020, two deadly hurricanes, Iota and Eta, hit Central America two weeks
apart, leaving more than 400 deaths and missing persons in its wake as well as more than
123
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
US$8 billion in damages. In Honduras, the hardest hit country, half of the population was
affected, and economic damages are evaluated at about 8% of GDP.
Iota and Eta were part of the 2020 Atlantic hurricane season, which had no less
than 13 hurricanes—the most active on record. This was the fifth consecutive season with
above-average hurricane intensity; global warming has provoked this trend (Masters, 2021).
Climate change is also provoking more frequent and more intense heat waves.
Considerable evidence shows that high temperatures reduce productivity and growth
(Nuguer and Powell, 2020a). Outdoor workers, such as street vendors and construc-
tion workers, are the most affected. Looking forward, the equivalent of 2.5 million
jobs could be lost due to heat stress in the region by 2030 (Saget, Vogt-Schilb, and
Luu, 2020). Sadly, the same groups hit hardest by the pandemic will be hurt most by
climate change.
Global warming is also making droughts and wildfires increasingly costly. The global
2020 wildfire season was the fifth most damaging on record. In Brazil, the agriculture
sector suffered US$3 billion in losses due to the 2020 drought, the third most expensive
on record. In addition, wildfires destroyed one-third of the Pantanal, the largest tropical
wetland in the world, jeopardizing biodiversity and the health and economy of local com-
munities (Libonati et al., 2020).
Other climate change impacts include altered discharges from rivers, sea level rise,
ocean acidification, coral bleaching, retreats of glaciers, less availability of fresh water,
lower agriculture yields (except in southernmost regions), reduced biodiversity, ecosystem
disruptions, mass extinctions, and fish migrations. Climate change damages infrastructure
and productive capital in the region and increases mortality and morbidity. It can also ag-
gravate conflict, humanitarian crises, and migration (IPCC, 2018). Compounding matters,
poor countries—and poor households within poor countries—tend to be more exposed,
more vulnerable, and less able to cope with the impacts of climate change (Hallegatte
et al., 2015).
Many countries affected by the pandemic were also impacted by these climatic events.
The combination has been particularly acute for poorer and more vulnerable populations.
To manage the impacts of climate change on development, all countries in the world need
to both increase the resilience of their economies to climate change impacts and drasti-
cally reduce greenhouse gas emissions to stabilize climate change itself (Cavallo, Powell,
and Serebrisky, 2020, and Hallegatte et al., 2015).
Stabilizing climate change below 2°C and as close to 1.5°C as possible, the objec-
tive set in the Paris Agreement, requires getting to net-zero carbon emissions globally
by around 2050 (IPCC, 2018). Reaching net-zero carbon emissions, or decarbonizing the
124
Stronger Sustainable Growth
economy, means reducing man-made emissions of carbon due to human activities such
as fossil fuel combustion, and balancing out remaining emissions, for instance by plant-
ing trees at scale.
Latin America and the Caribbean can achieve carbon-free prosperity through im-
mediate and parallel actions around five pillars of decarbonization (Saget, Vogt-Schilb,
and Luu, 2020): (i) phasing out fossil-fuel-based electricity generation by switching to
carbon-free sources such as wind and solar power; (ii) using electricity instead of fossil
fuels for transportation, cooking, and heating; (iii) reducing private transportation, by
increasing public transportation, walking, biking, and telework; (iv) halting and reversing
deforestation, by stabilizing or reducing consumption of animal-based foods to reduce
pressure on forests; and (v) reducing waste in all sectors, recycling materials, and switch-
ing to sustainable construction materials, such as wood or bamboo.
Most countries in the region have either officially embraced the goal of becoming
carbon-neutral, or stated that they are working on it (IDB/DDPLAC, 2019). Done right,
the transition to a net-zero economy can contribute to create jobs and improve economic
growth post-COVID-19.
Governments can simultaneously create jobs, spark economic recovery, and reduce
emissions in a sustainable recovery. The International Energy Agency, in partnership
with the International Monetary Fund, has proposed a global Sustainable Recovery Plan
to help governments boost economic growth, create jobs, and build more resilient and
cleaner energy systems (IEA, 2020a). It focuses on expanding renewable electricity
capacity and electricity grids, expanding electric vehicle production, expanding mass
transit, improving energy efficiency in the residential, commercial, and industrial sec-
tors, among others.
Implementing such a plan would create 9 million jobs a year over the next three
years globally and add 1.1 percentage points to global economic growth each year (IEA,
2020a). In developing countries, growth would increase by around 1.3 percentage points.
Global GDP would be 3.5% higher in 2023 than it would have been otherwise. The plan
envisions 2019 as the definitive peak in global emissions, and then puts them on a path
towards achieving long-term climate neutrality. It would also facilitate attaining sustain-
able development goals such as improving access to electricity, increasing clean cook-
ing solutions, and reducing air pollution. Finally, it would make energy systems more
resilient thanks to investments to expand electricity grids and digitalize grid control
(IEA, 2020a).
125
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
A sustainable recovery for the region entails transformations in more than just the energy
sector. Costa Rica’s National Decarbonization Plan provides an example. It sets the goal of
reaching net-zero greenhouse gas emissions by 2050 by updating agriculture and livestock
practices; using forests and other high-carbon ecosystems as carbon sinks; improving
waste management and recycling; maintaining electricity 100% renewable; electrifying
transportation; reducing reliance on private cars; and implementing efficiency measures
for buildings and industry (Costa Rica, 2019).
Most of the net economic benefits of implementing Costa Rica’s decarbonization
plan would come from updated land use practices in rural areas. There, increased agricul-
tural yields, better livestock productivity, and the value of ecosystem services provided
by forests (such as renewable forestry products, water and soil benefits, and support for
tourism and cultural heritage) would bring US$21 billion in net benefits to the country
(Groves et al., 2020). This figure is net of required investments and the opportunity cost
of land use to reforest.
FIGURE 9.1 Annual Benefits and Costs of the Costa Rica Decarbonization Plan
25
Annual benefits and costs (US$ billions)
20
15 12.9
10.1
10
7.6
5 3.6
1.7
–0.3 0.0
0
–5
–10
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
126
Stronger Sustainable Growth
Many studies stress the social and economic benefits of the transition to a net-zero economy. In
Chile, the productivity and energy efficiency gains associated with a transition to net-zero emissions
by 2050 could add the equivalent of 0.13 percentage points to economic growth (Antosiewicz et
al., 2020).
In the United States, the transition to a net-zero economy will create 0.5 to 1 million net
energy jobs by 2030 (Larson et al., 2020). Similarly, the transition in Europe will produce 2 million
net new jobs by 2030 and 5 million by 2050 (D’Aprile et al., 2020).
Investing in public transit, walking, and cycling creates more jobs than investments in high-
ways, and renewable energy deployment will provide US$97 billion in air pollution and health
benefits 2015–50 (Saha and Jaeger, 2020).
The global commission on the economy and climate found that bold climate action glob-
ally could deliver a direct economic gain of US$26 trillion by 2030, mainly in the form of energy
savings (NCE, 2018).
In Peru, going to net zero emissions by 2050 would bring more than US$150 billion in net
benefits to the country (Quirós-Tortos et al., 2021). The sectoral transformations required for Peru
to reach net-zero emissions are similar to those required in Costa Rica (see main text), with the
addition of transforming the power generation sector to rely on renewable energy rather than
fossil fuels. As a result, the type of costs and benefits that Peru would experience are similar to
those in Costa Rica, with the added benefit of shifting from expensive fossil fuel to cheap renew-
able power generation.
In cities, the economic benefits from energy savings, fewer accidents, time saved
from reduced congestion, and the favorable health effects of less air pollution more than
compensate for the initially higher upfront costs of switching to electric vehicles and
building infrastructure for zero-emissions public transport. Energy savings in buildings,
efficiency gains in industry, and the economic value of recycled materials and treated
water are additional benefits (Figure 9.1). In total, implementing the decarbonization plan
will bring US$41 billion in net benefits to Costa Rica between 2020 and 2050, equivalent
to boosting growth by 0.4 percentage points (Groves et al., 2020).
A sustainable recovery post-COVID could help the region gain new jobs in rural areas
thanks to land use changes. A joint study by the International Labour Organization and
the IDB found that countries can create 15 million additional net new jobs by 2030 if they
advance towards a net zero-emission economy (Saget, Vogt-Schilb, and Luu, 2020). While
all countries can create jobs in the transition, there will be winners and losers within coun-
tries (Figure 9.2). Compared to 2014, employment in plant-based agriculture and renewable
electricity in the region would more than double and employment in forestry would increase
by more than 50%. On the other hand, employment in fossil-fuel electricity and extraction
is bound to decline drastically (by nearly 50% and 30% respectively), while animal-based
food production would also dip slightly (Figure 9.2, right panel).
127
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
7.1
7 156
150
6 124
100
5
Jobs (millions)
Jobs (%)
58
4 50
3
0
2.1 2.1 –4.6
2 1.8
1.6 –32
–50
1 –57
0.4
0 –100
Brazil
Mexico
Andean Countries
Caribbean
Central
America
Rest of Southern
Cone
Agriculture and
plant-based foods
Forestry
Fossil fuel
electricity
Fossil fuel
extraction
Livestock, poultry,
dairy, fish
Renewable
electricity
Source: Saget, Vogt-Schilb, and Luu (2020).
Note: Left panel: net jobs created in a low-carbon scenario with respect to a high-carbon scenario. Right panel: variation of
jobs in 2030 relative to jobs in 2014, selected sectors, Latin America and the Caribbean.
The challenge for governments is to ensure that during and after the pandemic workers
are relocated to (i) sectors that directly contribute to environmental sustainability, such
as renewable energy and grids, sustainable plant-based agriculture, ecosystem restoration
and management, or energy efficient buildings and manufacturing; or (ii) sectors that are
naturally low-carbon such as many service industries. At the same time, workers should
be steered away from industries that go against achieving environmental goals such as
natural gas, oil, or beef production.
More generally, governments should facilitate a just transition of the workforce, which
means ensuring three things (Saget, Vogt-Schilb, and Luu, 2020); (i) workers and communi-
ties affected by the downsizing of fossil fuel must find productive employment in other areas
or be compensated; (ii) the jobs created during the transition must offer decent working
conditions; and (iii) all stakeholders must have a voice and participate in the decision making.
Because of their sheer size, COVID relief packages can impact the transition to net-zero
emissions. By the end of August 2020, global relief packages reached US$12.2 trillion, while
128
Stronger Sustainable Growth
Lessons from the 2008–09 stimulus show that public spending measures can contribute
to a sustainable recovery, as long as governments also ensure a consistent regulatory and
financial environment (IEA, 2020b; IMF, 2020a; Jaeger, Westphal, and Park, 2020). This
section details key recommendations.
Public support to businesses affected by the pandemic and future stimulus spending could
be prioritized for environmentally virtuous businesses (IMF, 2021a).
Public investment could focus on infrastructure that meets sustainability criteria,
such as renewable energy capacity, modern electric grids, public transport, digitalization
(including to build capacity to continue teleworking, remotely engage with the government
and businesses, and teleconferencing), flood protection infrastructure, and resilient trans-
port networks (Cavallo, Powell, and Serebrisky, 2020; IDB and IDB Invest, 2018). Similarly,
public spending on work-for-cash programs could focus on labor-intensive environmental
programs, such as ecosystem restoration or irrigation.
On the other hand, governments should avoid carbon-intensive investments such as
expanding the transport network to remote areas (a key driver of deforestation), or investing
in fossil-fuel infrastructure. In particular, expansions of natural gas production and natural gas
power generation capacity are unlikely to be consistent with the Paris Agreement (Binsted
et al., 2020; Gonzáles-Mahecha et al., 2019). Fossil fuel power plants built today are likely
to become stranded assets, that is, to be retired before the end of their technical lifetime as
governments implement regulations to comply with climate commitments and/or technolo-
gies such as wind and solar outcompete fossil fuels (Delgado, Eguino, and Lopes, 2021).
129
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
130
Stronger Sustainable Growth
Over the last decade, many zero-carbon technologies have become cheaper than fossil
fuel technology. Renewable energy is the cheapest source of energy globally (IEA, 2020c),
and electric transport is bound to follow. But regulations and price signals often work
against attracting private finance to fund the adoption of new technology.
Public transportation in buses, for instance, is provided by the private sector in most
countries of the region. Electric buses can be cheaper to own and operate than diesel
counterparts thanks to lower maintenance and energy costs, but cost much more to buy,
making them more difficult to acquire for small businesses with low financial capacity.
In Chile, a solution was to update market design to let electricity utilities own the buses,
while the operators lease them; previously, bus operators were required to own their fleet
(World Bank, 2020a). In the case of renewable energy, dispatch rules, regulations sur-
rounding connections to high-voltage transmission lines, land-use rights, and net-metering
for households can all be critical to widespread adoption (Energy Sector Management
Assistance Program, 2018).
These examples show that sectoral regulations must accompany any budgetary sup-
port to green activities. Ministries of finance should thus coordinate with line ministries to
ensure financial and regulatory interventions are consistent.
Energy prices kept artificially low by government subsidies can also be an ob-
stacle to the transition to net-zero emissions. In 2017, the region spent US$44 billion on
energy subsidies, including direct subsidies and the cost associated with exemptions
from consumption taxes (Coady et al., 2019). On average, countries spent 1% of GDP
subsidizing energy. Furthermore, putting a price on carbon and other externalities can
improve incentives to adopt low-carbon technology and practices (Stiglitz et al., 2017).
While the context of low oil prices may favor energy price reforms, subsidy re-
moval and environmental taxation can negatively impact the cost of food and public
transport, which affects poor and vulnerable consumers. To make them socially and
politically acceptable, governments should clearly communicate the goals of such
reforms, and provide compensation packages. The cash transfers and social protec-
tion programs that governments have scaled-up to help the population cope with the
pandemic (Chapter 2) are good means of providing compensation (Feng et al., 2018;
Vogt-Schilb et al., 2019).
The crisis has drastically limited fiscal space in the region. Governments should anticipate
the limited capacity of fossil fuels to provide a sustainable tax base when they plan for
future revenues (Delgado, Eguino, and Lópes, 2021).
131
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Before COVID-19, many countries depended on global demand for oil and gas for
their tax revenues. Fossil fuels represented more than 5% of public revenues in Bolivia,
Ecuador, Trinidad and Tobago, and Mexico during the 2013–18 period (Delgado, Eguino,
and Lópes, 2021). Moreover, Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico plan to increase production
and Guyana is beginning exploitation on a transformative scale for its economy. The pan-
demic depressed oil demand, and ongoing global energy transition means that fossil fuel
revenues face an uncertain future.
Indeed, fossil fuel producers’ output aspirations conflict with international climate
targets. Globally, countries aim to produce 120% more fossil fuels by 2030 than would be
consistent with limiting global warming to 1.5°C (SEI et al., 2020). As alternative technolo-
gies become cheaper and measures to address climate change are put in place in most
countries, demand for fossil fuels will drop. IDB projections find that demand for oil from
the region will be down 60% in 2035 compared to pre-COVID-19 levels, and two-thirds of
reserves will remain unused, if the global energy transition proceeds as planned. Compared
to a situation in which global demand continues to grow, cumulative 2020–35 public rev-
enues associated with oil will be about US$2.8 trillion lower (Solano-Rodriguez et al., 2019).
Governments should identify the fiscal risk associated with the energy transi-
tion and develop a strategy to reduce and manage it. Few governments have done
so yet, but South Africa provides a good example of what a comprehensive fiscal risk
identification and management strategy should aim to achieve (Huxham, Anwar, and
Nelson, 2019):
• quantify the financial impact of reduced oil and gas for the country.
• quantify risk distribution along the supply chain (e.g., extractors, refineries, and
consumers), on private vs public actors (depending on contract structure and
market design), at different levels of government (such as municipal or central),
for specific programs (e.g., in cases where royalties finance social programs) and
for different regions.
• identify investments that would increase dependence on fossil fuels, such as
natural gas power plants, in order to delay or avoid them.
• plan to progressively eliminate most carbon-intensive activities. For instance,
Chile announced in 2019 a plan to close all coal power plants before 2040 (Saget,
Vogt-Schilb, and Luu, 2020).
In other countries, gasoline and diesel taxes provide a significant share of public
revenues: e.g., 6% in Uruguay and 11% In Costa Rica (Rodriguez Zúñiga et al., 2021). The
transition to electric vehicles will progressively erode and eventually eliminate that tax
base. In the short term, raising gasoline taxes can be a solution (if distributional impacts
are managed), but in the longer term, countries need a strategy to increasingly replace
132
Stronger Sustainable Growth
the revenue from fossil fuel taxes. Alternative sources of income to consider include
taxes on vehicle purchase or ownership (e.g., acquisition, excise costs, or import taxes);
use charges (e.g., congestion and road charges, ideally linked to the energy efficiency of
vehicles); and distance-based charges. Taxes not linked to transportation might include
electricity taxes or value added taxes (IEA, 2019).
The transition to net-zero emissions requires consistent regulatory and financial environ-
ments across sectors and over time. Decarbonization strategies can help the government
ensure such consistency (Delgado, Eguino, and Lópes, 2021; Fay et al., 2015).
A decarbonization strategy is an aspirational document that: (i) sets a vision of
where the country wants to be in 2050 in terms of decarbonization and development
goals; (ii) anticipates regulatory and financial barriers in the transition; and (iii) enables
the development of policy and investment roadmaps required for the progressive trans-
formation of all sectors (Cavallo, Powell, and Serebrisky, 2020; IDB and DDPLAC, 2019).
Decarbonization strategies should translate the carbon-neutrality goal and socioeco-
nomic aspirations into concrete technical and socioeconomic changes to support these
goals. For instance, Costa Rica’s national decarbonization plan establishes a timeline
for public transport to progressively switch to electric or hydrogen vehicles by 2050,
and identifies immediate regulatory changes needed by 2023 to enable it (Costa Rica,
2019). It includes more than 70 such targets for 35 different government agencies and
line ministries to implement by 2023. During the pandemic, the plan could thus serve as
a guide to focus economic relief policies and financing (Groves et al., 2020).
Finally, to ensure that decarbonization strategies align with domestic develop-
ment goals and to secure a just transition, all relevant stakeholders should be involved
in elaborating decarbonization strategies (Saget, Vogt-Schilb, and Luu, 2020). These
stakeholders include workers’ and employers’ organizations, researchers, indigenous
communities, and civil society groups representing the key sectors of the economy.
In Spain, for instance, a government plan to phase out coal mines designed with trade
unions includes funding to let coal miners retire early or relocate to other sectors (Saget,
Vogt-Schilb, and Luu, 2020).
The Paris Agreement invites countries to design and communicate decarbonization
strategies. Thus, countries have an opportunity to institutionalize the goal to reach a carbon-
free future with a consistent regulatory environment across sectors that brings social and
economic benefits. In this way, a green recovery plan that addresses both environmental
and economic concerns could boost growth by more than an estimated 1% per year.
133
CHAPTER 10
T
he year 2020 will be remembered as one of the most challenging in modern his-
tory. The 7.4% loss in GDP is the largest in Latin America and the Caribbean in a
single year—at least since 1821. The global pandemic spurred a triple sudden stop,
with lockdowns and restrictions on human mobility, a collapse in trade and commodity
prices, and impacts on financial flows.1 Some countries in the region fared particularly
badly in terms of both the health crisis and growth. Tourism dependent economies were
hit particularly hard. 2 Other countries suffered higher COVID-19 cases, hospitalizations,
and deaths than might have been expected, given the level of growth. Potential explana-
tions for the disproportionate impact include high levels of urbanization and population
density, informality, poor health infrastructure, a lack of connectivity to work at home,
patchy enforcement of lockdown policies, and weak fiscal positions coming into the crisis
(that limited resources for support measures). 3 Although the impacts of the shock were
substantial during the first half of 2020, economies started to turn around in the second
half of the year. However, the region was already losing ground in terms of its share in
global GDP, and the pandemic has only reinforced that trend; the region will come out of
the crisis with higher indebtedness, greater poverty, and increased income inequality.4
The region is expected to recover in 2021 with growth expected to be 4.1%, with a
subsequent reversion to trend growth of around 2.5% per annum. Recovery was assisted
by positive growth in China in 2020 and the projected growth of over 8% in 2021 will help
the region to grow. The baseline scenario assumes countries continue to open and are not
forced into new lockdowns, despite a significant number of new COVID-19 cases each day,
and that vaccine roll-out programs advance as planned, bringing widespread immunity
in most countries in the second half of the year.
However, any growth projection is fraught with uncertainty at the present time.
Outbreaks are already forcing new containment measures in some countries, especially
where more contagious strains are gaining ground. Moreover, the concern is that current
1 See, for example, Parrado (2020) on Latin America’s triple sudden stop affecting capital flows, trade, and
mobility.
2 See, for example, Mooney and Zegarra (2020).
3 See, for example, Nuguer and Powell (2020b) on countries’ policy responses to the crisis.
4 See, for example, Cavallo and Powell (2018) on the pre-pandemic growth trajectory, Izquierdo et al. (2020)
on how countries may emerge from the pandemic, and Busso and Messina (2020) on the impacts on inequality.
135
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
vaccines may be less effective against mutations of the virus. In a negative scenario, with
a second wave of the virus in the United States and Europe, combined with delayed and
less-effective vaccines, Latin America and the Caribbean would be severely impacted.
Growth would be considerably lower than in the baseline in 2021 and in 2022 could fall
back further, implying a double-dip scenario or “W”-shaped recovery.
But there is also upside risk. If vaccination programs accelerate and new strains are
contained, then a consumer boom could follow. This would boost growth in the United
States, Europe and the region. But in such a scenario, central banks may have to revise
their current forward guidance on keeping policy interest rates very low for a significant
period of time in order to contain inflationary pressures. At the same time, equity valua-
tions may reflect a bubble rather than fundamentals. The impact could then be a sharp
correction in financial markets. Simulations suggest that if the market correction is severe,
this could nearly wipe out the positive impacts of higher global growth and leave growth
in the region reasonably close to the baseline.
136
The Economy after COVID
spending and to reform tax systems, for example by revising complex systems of exemp-
tions and tax incentives in some countries.
To raise revenue, increasing value-added-taxes (VAT) may negatively impact growth
less than raising income taxes. A concern, however, is that VAT may be regressive, and
countries have responded by introducing reduced rates on basic items. However, these
“subsidies” are very poorly targeted, and leak to more wealthy consumers. It would be
more efficient to have VAT at a common rate and a good system for targeting transfers
to those who need assistance.
Increasing property taxes is progressive and as rates are generally low, may have little
effect on growth. Governments also have opportunities to tax activities that are detrimental
to health or the environment. And the crisis is inducing reallocation and spurring innova-
tion; tax authorities need to keep up to ensure that taxes are applied fairly across sectors.
Corporate tax rates are very high in some countries, but revenues are low. Reducing
rampant informality would be an important step to boost the tax base, while also leveling
the playing field for small and medium enterprises (SMEs) to prosper.
One way to deal with informality is with policies that reward formal employment. Since
as many as 80% of workers are employed in the informal economy, such changes could
have a significant effect. The Earned Income Credit (EIC) could be a useful tool to address
informality while phasing out noncontributory social programs that subsidize informality.
Additional revenues and resources saved from improving efficiency could be chan-
neled to increase productive investments, including sustainable infrastructure. High-quality
public investment has a high growth multiplier of around 2, meaning that for every peso
spent, GDP may grow by up to 2 pesos. In addition, well-designed sustainable infrastruc-
ture can be good for the environment, helping countries achieve Paris Agreement climate
commitments.
Beyond specific spending or tax measures, one of the greatest opportunities to
improve efficiency comes from strengthening fiscal institutions or creating new ones: to
collect taxes more efficiently; to plan spending with long-term horizons; and to build or
strengthen budgeting tools, including multiannual budget planning shielded from politi-
cal pressures.
These may seem like medium-term reforms, but they will help countries deal with
the fiscal problems of today. Public debt as a share of GDP has increased to 72% in 2020,
up from 58% in 2019. Most countries are planning fiscal adjustments to bring debt levels
down over time. While an aggressive adjustment plan means less adjustment will actually
be needed (as debt comes down, interest payments are reduced), it may have a negative
impact on growth. A more gradual adjustment would assist in the recovery from the crisis,
but then more adjustment will be required. Improved fiscal institutions could be particu-
larly beneficial by providing greater credibility, keeping interest rates low, and allowing for
a more gradual adjustment program with less financial cost and less impact on growth.
137
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Exports and imports both collapsed, and the aggregate current account deficit was
reduced narrowly. Nevertheless, several countries were able to finance higher current
account deficits. Tourism dependent countries were particularly hard hit as exports and
economic activity fell in the face of travel restrictions. There was a fear remittance flows
would shrink, but they proved to be resilient, aided by the economic recovery and fiscal
transfers in the United States.
As the COVID-19 shock hit the region and despite the plunge in stock markets around
the world, only about one-third of countries experienced a sudden stop in net capital
flows. In these types of crises, countries must normally narrow current account deficits
swiftly, usually by curtailing imports and thereby provoking a deep recession. This crisis,
however, followed a different pattern, with the fall in demand and supply restrictions taking
center stage. Still, this was no normal demand shock that allowed financing to effectively
smooth consumption. But external financing did help finance government relief packages
and address the private sector’s demand for liquidity.
In addition, some countries saw strong outflows from residents or through some
types of portfolio flows; these were compensated by inflows, which were the product of
tapping bond markets and from official lenders.
Interestingly, the sudden stops that did occur were well predicted by a limited number
of variables capturing countries’ pre-crisis fundamentals. Countries will want to improve
macroeconomic fundamentals to prevent future painful capital flow volatility and maintain
fluid access to international capital markets.
Inflation has been low and stable at around 3% among most countries in the region with
a variety of monetary and exchange rate regimes. Still, food prices have pushed up infla-
tion in some countries. While it is hoped this will be temporary, the impacts on poorer
households should be monitored carefully.
Central banks were active during the crisis, reducing policy interest rates and
reserve requirements, and providing liquidity, particularly to banks and governments.
The demand for liquidity increased substantially and central bank assets (including
reserves) and liabilities (including the monetary base) rose. Central banks mostly
accommodated these changes. In some countries with significant fiscal expansions
and capital inflows, central banks issued large amounts of short-term (sterilization)
liabilities. Exchange rate depreciations in some countries boosted the value of central
banks’ assets (mostly in hard currency) relative to liabilities. In general, central banks
have significant buffers to back their short-term liabilities, but if doubts remain about
138
The Economy after COVID
fiscal sustainability, then the government and central bank roll-over requirements may
provoke risks.
Additional risks would arise If central banks were called upon to provide direct
financing to governments or to take on private sector credit risk. Inflation expectations
remain well-anchored and central banks command considerable credibility. Under a posi-
tive scenario of greater demand, inflation could pick up temporarily, but this may be a
good problem to have. A more dangerous scenario would be the monetary financing of
deficits, a weakening of central bank independence and credibility, and higher inflation
expectations. History suggests that this is the route to more persistent problems, includ-
ing higher inflation, which are then costly to reverse. 5
Banking sectors came into this crisis with high capital ratios and ample liquidity. Banks
have seen deposits rise and the composition of assets has shifted towards holding more
government securities. Policies to support households and firms have helped smooth the
shock. Income fell sharply but appears to have recovered. Many countries have imple-
mented loan guarantee programs and introduced voluntary loan deferral programs; a
few have mandated such policies. In most cases, banks may maintain loans registered
as performing and are not required to set aside additional provisions.6 Such policies
help make bank balance sheets appear healthy, but they hide the risks. Higher govern-
ment bond holdings tie banks closer to fiscal developments, and nonperforming loans
will surely rise as deferred loans mature. Market measures of risk fell after a sharp rise
in March, but they have been increasing once again. History teaches that forbearance
policies are hard to remove once implemented, but the longer they carry on, the greater
will be the eventual losses. It will be important for banks to report the true risk of loans
and provision accordingly, dipping into buffers where required. In some cases, a recovery
plan may be required to allow banks time to regain regulatory ratios. This policy will be
more credible and build confidence.
As the COVID-19 shock hit, firms across the region sought to increase leverage to
restore liquidity and create buffers against a crisis of unknown duration. They were able
to borrow domestically, assisted by loan guarantee programs and central bank support
to banks, and in some cases internationally as well. The increase in firms’ leverage has
been larger in Latin America and the Caribbean than in other regions, which raises the
risk of a debt overhang after the pandemic. A corporate debt overhang could lead to
5 See Powell (2021) on the post-COVID fiscal, monetary, and financial risks and see Kehoe and Nicolini (2021)
on historical experiences of persistent monetary financing of fiscal deficits.
6 See Powell and Rojas-Suárez (2020) for further discussion.
139
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
lower investment or debt restructurings. Guarantees on new loans are not the appropriate
instrument when debt ratios or uncertainty are already high. Authorities should consider
new equity-like instruments to assist firms. The use of public funds and private property
rights should be carefully monitored and protected.
The COVID-19 shock has meant significant reallocation between economic sectors.
Stock markets provide a forward-looking indication of which sectors are expected to
expand and which may contract as a result of the pandemic. The tech-related service
sectors and some manufacturing sectors, including chemicals, oil, metal-related manu-
factures, and electronics have emerged as leading economic sectors according to their
stock market valuations. Countries should seek to tap the opportunities created in those
sectors, facilitating their expansion through smart regulation and taxation that enables
SMEs to invest and grow. These efforts should align with other policy objectives, including
environmental goals, to ensure sustainable and equitable growth.
Firms in the region have also been affected by the disruptions that the COVID-19
shock caused on global trade. Before the crisis, Latin America and the Caribbean had not
been able to take full advantage of the opportunities provided by participation in global
and regional value chains because of deficiencies in logistics, inadequate infrastructure
to access global markets, insufficient information to connect exporters to global suppliers
and foreign demand, and poor harmonization of rules across a diverse set of regional and
bilateral trade agreements. The uncertainty generated by the COVID-19 shock, plus the
disruptions generated by natural disasters and tariff disputes, have forced countries and
companies within countries to reassess their position in global and regional value chains.
The region thus has a unique opportunity to improve its positioning and support growth.
During the COVID crisis, around US$56.5 billion (6.1%) of U.S. total imports switched to
new source countries. This represents a considerable opportunity for the region, which
exported just US$26 billion in 2019 to the United States. Tapping into this opportunity
requires a combination of general policies to help all exporting firms integrate better
with global and regional value chains, like for example providing logistical support, or
overcoming infrastructure gaps through targeted investments, tailoring specific policies
to support small and medium enterprises as exporters, and strengthening the resilience
of exporters’ networks of suppliers and customers. Governments have key roles to play
in supporting smaller exporters that may be able to become large exporters or tap the
openings generated by the reallocation of global supply and demand in a flexible manner.
If exporters in the region can develop a more diversified portfolio of foreign customers,
that would provide an insurance mechanism, especially when the demand and supply
conditions are adverse. From a policy perspective, it is important to help companies di-
versify their customer’s portfolio, in good times when demand might be increasing—and
even in turbulent times when firms from other countries exit the market—to become more
resilient exporters.
140
The Economy after COVID
Building opportunities for higher and sustainable post-pandemic growth will require re-
thinking growth policies. The configuration of economic sectors in the region is the result of
past policies, and of the environment in which those policies are implemented. Two of the
leading factors driving the poor long-run growth performance in the region have been low
investment rates and slow productivity growth. To reverse these trends, the region must
increase productive investments, and ensure the efficient allocation of that investment.
But economic volatility conspires against those goals. In volatile environments, it may be
more convenient for entrepreneurs to choose more malleable production technologies,
meaning that they could be easier to reallocate between sectors. More malleable tech-
nologies are more labor-intensive, but on average they are less productive. Latin America
and the Caribbean have more malleable production technologies than advanced econo-
mies, and malleable sectors account for the largest share of the economies in the region.
The advantage is that sectors may recover quickly from crises like, for example, the one
generated by COVID-19. But while a V-shaped recovery is possible, the recovery will not
foster long-run growth if economic resources are not channeled to productive sectors.
One of the most productive, less malleable sectors is infrastructure. Efficient, qual-
ity investment in infrastructure reduces bottlenecks, which enhances growth prospects.7
Unfortunately, Latin American and Caribbean countries are not investing enough in infra-
structure. Countries should invest between 2% and 3% of GDP more every year in infra-
structure. Achieving that goal requires private and public financing. On the private side,
opportunities arise from incorporating new financiers into the mix, especially institutional
investors that have been constrained by the lack of appropriate projects and investment
instruments. On the public side, opportunities arise from expenditure switching policies,
from current to capital spending, which may be supported through fiscal rules that protect
public investment from cuts during fiscal consolidations.
If investing in infrastructure can support economic growth, investing in sustainable
infrastructure constitutes a win-win strategy, increasing economic growth as well as re-
ducing climate risks. Investing in sustainable infrastructure means focusing on expanding
renewable electricity capacity and electricity grids, expanding electric vehicle production,
expanding mass transit, and improving energy efficiency in the residential, commercial,
and industrial sectors. However, progress toward this has been difficult because of the
erroneous assumption that meeting environmental targets would mean higher energy
costs that impact productivity, competitiveness, and household payment capacity. That is
a false choice. Renewable energy can help reach environmental goals while also fostering
higher growth. Implementing sustainable infrastructure plans could add 1.1 percentage
7 See Cavallo, Powell, and Serebrisky (2020) on the challenges for improving infrastructure in the region.
141
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
points to global economic growth each year and around 1.3 percentage points of incre-
mental growth in the case of developing countries. The technology is advancing, and
costs are falling, but for the benefits to materialize, the regulatory agenda has to be put
in place to facilitate the transition to a power matrix that incorporates a larger share of
nonconventional renewable sources. The Paris Agreement invites countries to design and
communicate decarbonization strategies. Thus, countries have an opportunity to reach
the goals of a carbon-free future with a consistent regulatory environment across sectors
that brings social and economic benefits.
Countries face a hazardous time ahead. Most countries will require some type of fiscal
adjustment to maintain fiscal sustainability and, given the extraordinary circumstances,
some countries may need to consider alternatives to reduce debt overhangs. International
interest rates remain low and opportunities may exist to refinance at improved rates.
International financial institutions (IFIs) have increased disbursements as a result of the
crisis. The IMF has disbursed over US$5.4 billion in emergency financing and approved
more than US$60 billion in backstop and traditional programs for the region. The IDB
group disbursed a record US$18 billion through 2020. The World Bank disbursed more
than US$7 billion between April 2020 and January 2021 for specific COVID-related opera-
tions. Countries should continue to take advantage of the long-maturity and low interest
rate loans from IFIs to substitute more expensive commercial debt.
In some cases, debt restructuring may also be required. Most countries in the region
are middle income countries, and commercial borrowing dwarfs that from the official sec-
tor. A natural concern is whether high debt levels might prompt a repeat of the 1980s,
the so-called Lost Decade. But commercial debt is now more in the form of bonds rather
than bank loans, and many countries have incorporated new generation collective action
clauses (CACs) into debt contracts that should ease any renegotiation with creditors.
Argentina and Ecuador have already restructured debts aided by the existence of such
clauses. The lesson from the 1980s is that it was not the restructurings themselves that
provoked the lost decade, but more the delays in restructuring debt, monetary financing
of fiscal deficits, financial repression, and forbearance type policies. If restructuring of
commercial debts is required, it is better done quickly and preemptively. 8
While the months ahead will be challenging, this report details a set of policies that
should help countries realize a stronger recovery, not just to the low growth rates of the
pre-pandemic period, but to higher rates of growth that will benefit all, with more efficient
public policies, higher productivity in the private sector, and more sustainable economies.
8 See Powell (2021) and Powell and Valencia (2020) for a complementary discussion.
142
References
AAMC (American Association of Medical Colleges). 2021. “The COVID-19 Variants Are Spreading
Rapidly. Here’s What Scientists Know about Them — and Why You Need a Better Mask.”
AAMC. January 21, 2021. https://www.aamc.org/news-insights/covid-19-variants-are-
spreading-rapidly-here-s-what-scientists-know-about-them-and-why-you-need.
Abbas, S. M. Ali, and Alexander Klemm. 2013. “A Partial Race to the Bottom: Corporate
Tax Developments in Emerging and Developing Economies.” International Tax and
Public Finance 20 (4): 596–617. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-013-9286-8.
Abiad, Abdul, Davide Furceri, and Petia Topalova. 2016. “The Macroeconomic Effects of
Public Investment: Evidence from Advanced Economies.” Journal of Macroeconomics
50 (December): 224–40. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2016.07.005.
Acevedo, Ivonne, Francesca Castellani, Iván Flores, Giulia Lotti, and Miguel Székely. 2020.
“Implicaciones Sociales Del Covid-19: Estimaciones y Alternativas Para América
Latina y El Caribe.” IDB Discussion Paper No. 820. Washington, DC: Inter-American
Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002758.
Ahumada, Hildegart, Eduardo A. Cavallo, Santos Espina-Mairal, and Fernando Navajas. 2021.
“Sectoral Productivity Growth, COVID-19 Shocks and Infrastructure.” Mimeograph.
Ahumada, Hildegart, and Fernando Navajas. 2019. “Productivity Growth and Infrastructure
Related Sectors.” Unpublished.
Alaimo, Verónica, Mariano Bosch, David S. Kaplan, Carmen Pages, and Laura Ripani. 2015.
Empleos Para Crecer. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://
doi.org/10.18235/0000139.
Álvarez, Fernando, and David Argente. 2021. “Cash-Management in Times of Covid-19.”
Covid Economics, no. 68 (February): 139–71. https://cepr.org/sites/default/files/
CovidEconomics68.pdf.
Alviarez, Vanessa. Forthcoming. “Firm Networks and Margins of Trade Creation in Global
Value Chains.” Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
———. 2019. “Multinational Production and Comparative Advantage.” Journal of International
Economics 119 (July): 1–54. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2019.03.004.
An, Zidong, João Tovar Jalles, and Prakash Loungani. 2018. “How Well Do Economists
Forecast Recessions?” International Finance 21 (2): 100–121. https://doi.org/10.1111/
infi.12130.
Andrijevic, Marina, Carl-Friedrich Schleussner, Matthew J. Gidden, David L. McCollum,
and Joeri Rogelj. 2020. “COVID-19 Recovery Funds Dwarf Clean Energy Investment
Needs.” Science 370 (6514): 298–300. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.abc9697.
143
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Antosiewicz, Mareck, Luis E. Gonzáles Carrasco, Piotr Lewandowski, and Nicolás de la Maza
Greene. 2020. Green Growth Opportunities for the Decarbonization Goal for Chile:
Report on the Macroeconomic Effects of Implementing Climate Change Mitigation
Policies in Chile 2020. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Antràs, Pol. 2020. “Conceptual Aspects of Global Value Chains.” Policy Research
Working Paper No. 9114. Washington, DC: World Bank. https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-
9450-9114.
Ardanaz, Martín, Eduardo Cavallo, Alejandro Izquierdo, and Jorge Puig. 2021. “Growth-
Friendly Fiscal Rules? Safeguarding Public Investment from Budget Cuts through
Fiscal Rule Design.” Journal of International Money and Finance 111 (March): 102319.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2020.102319.
Arellano, Cristina, Yan Bai, and Gabriel P. Mihalache. 2020. “Deadly Debt Crises: COVID-19
in Emerging Markets.” NBER Working Paper, no. 27275 (May). https://ideas.repec.
org/p/nbr/nberwo/27275.html.
Aslam, Aqib, Natalija Novta, and Fabiano Rodrigues-Bastos. 2017. “Calculating Trade in Value
Added.” IMF Working Paper 17/178, July. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781484311493.001.
Baer, Greg. 2020. “Forbearance during Coronavirus a Double-Edged Sword.”
American Banker, June 25, 2020. https://www.americanbanker.com/opinion/
forbearance-during-coronavirus-a-double-edged-sword.
Barreix, A., M. Bès, and J. Roca. 2010. “El IVA personalizado: Aumentando la recaudación
y compensando a los más pobres.” Report. Washington, DC: Inter-American
Development Bank.
Barrero, Jose Maria, Nicholas Bloom, and Steven J. Davis. 2020. “Covid-19 Is Also a
Reallocation Shock.” NBER Working Paper, no. 27137.
Barrot, Jean-Noel, and Julien Sauvagnat. 2016. “Input Specificity and the Propagation of
Idiosyncratic Shocks in Production Networks.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics
131(3): 1543–92.
Beck, Thorsten, and Liliana Rojas-Suárez. 2019. “Making Basel III Work for Emerging
Markets and Developing Economies: A CGD Task Force Report.” SSRN Electronic
Journal. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3391886.
Bénassy-Quéré, Agnès, Lionel Fontagné, and Amina Lahrèche-Révil. 2005. “How Does FDI
React to Corporate Taxation?” International Tax and Public Finance 12 (5): 583–603.
Bernard, Andrew, Emmanuel Dhyne, Glenn Magerman, Kalina Manova, and Andreas Moxnes.
2019. “The Origins of Firm Heterogeneity: A Production Network Approach.” NBER
Working Paper, no. 25441 (January). https://doi.org/10.3386/w25441.
Binsted, Matthew, Gokul Iyer, James Edmonds, Adrien Vogt-Schilb, Ricardo Arguello,
Angela Cadena, Ricardo Delgado, et al. 2020. “Stranded Asset Implications of the
Paris Agreement in Latin America and the Caribbean.” Environmental Research
Letters 15 (4): 044026. https://doi.org/10.1088/1748–9326/ab506d.
144
REFERENCES
Blanchard, Olivier J., Thomas Philippon, and Jean Pisani-Ferry. 2020. “A New Policy Toolkit
Is Needed as Countries Exit COVID-19 Lockdowns.” Policy Brief PB20-8. Washington,
DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Blickle, Kristian, and João A. C. Santos. 2020. “The Costs of Corporate Debt Overhang.”
SSRN Electronic Journal, October. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3708502.
Blyde, Juan, and Danielle Trachtenberg. 2020. “Global Value Chains and Latin America:
A Technical Note.” IDB Technical Note No. 1853. Washington, DC: Inter-American
Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002155.
Bottán, Nicolás, Bridget Hoffmann, and Diego Vera-Cossío. 2020. The Unequal Burden of
the Pandemic: Why the Fallout of Covid-19 Hits the Poor the Hardest. Washington,
DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002834.
Brichetti, Juan Pablo, Eduardo Cavallo, Omar O. Chisari, Leonardo Mastronardi, Tomás
Serebrisky, and Juan Pablo Vila Martínez. 2020. “El efecto de la infraestructura en
el desempeño de seis economías de América Latina: Una evaluación con modelos
de Equilibrio General Computado.” IDB Technical Note No. 1855. Washington, DC:
Inter-American Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002290.
Brinca, Pedro, Joao B. Duarte, and Miguel Faria-e-Castro. 2020. “Measuring Sectoral
Supply and Demand Shocks during COVID-19.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Working Paper, no. 2020–011.
Broner, Fernando, Tatiana Didier, Aitor Erce, and Sergio L. Schmukler. 2013. “Gross Capital
Flows: Dynamics and Crises.” Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (1): 113–33. https://
doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2012.12.004.
Brown, Craig O., and I. Serdar Dinç. 2011. “Too Many to Fail? Evidence of Regulatory
Forbearance When the Banking Sector Is Weak.” Review of Financial Studies 24 (4):
1378–1405. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhp039.
Brunnermeier, Markus, José De Gregorio, Barry Eichengreen, Mohamed El-Erian, Arminio
Fraga, T. Ito, P. Lane, J. Pisani-Ferry, E. Prasad, and R. Rajan. 2012. “Banks and Cross-
Border Capital Flows: Policy Challenges and Regulatory Responses.” Committee on
International Economic Policy and Reform. https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/
uploads/2016/06/09-ciepr-banking-capital-flows.pdf.
Brunnermeier, Markus, and Arvind Krishnamurthy. 2020. “Corporate Debt Overhang and
Credit Policy.” Brooking Papers of Economic Activity, BPEA Conference Drafts, June
2020. https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2020/06/Brunnermeier-
Krishnamurthy-conference-draft.pdf.
Bruno, Valentina, and Hyun Song Shin. 2017. “Global Dollar Credit and Carry Trades: A
Firm-Level Analysis.” The Review of Financial Studies 30 (3): 703–49. https://doi.
org/10.1093/rfs/hhw099.
Business Insider. 2020. “Prime Minister Announces Additional Support for Businesses to
Help Save Canadian Jobs,” May 11, 2020. https://markets.businessinsider.com/news/
145
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
stocks/prime-minister-announces-additional-support-for-businesses-to-help-save-
canadian-jobs-1029187813.
Busso, Matías, and Julián Messina. 2020. “The Inequality Crisis: Latin America and the
Caribbean at the Crossroads.” Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
https://publications.iadb.org/publications/english/document/The-Inequality-Crisis-
Latin-America-and-the-Caribbean-at-the-Crossroads. pdf.
Caballero, Julian, Ugo Panizza, and Andrew Powell. 2014. “Balance Sheets and Credit
Growth.” In Global Recovery and Monetary Normalization: Escaping a Chronicle
Foretold, edited by Andrew Powell, 21–35. Washington, DC: Inter-American
Development Bank. https://publications.iadb.org/publications/english/document/
Global-Recovery-and-Monetary-Normalization-Escaping-a-Chronicle-Foretold.pdf.
Caballero, Julián, Ugo Panizza, and Andrew Powell. 2016. “The Second Wave of Global
Liquidity: Why Are Firms Acting Like Financial Intermediaries?” IDB Working Paper
No. 641. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://publications.
iadb.org/publications/english/document/The-Second-Wave-of-Global-Liquidity-
Why-Are-Firms-Acting-Like-Financial-Intermediaries.pdf.
Caballero, Ricardo J., Takeo Hoshi, and Anil K. Kashyap. 2008. “Zombie Lending and
Depressed Restructuring in Japan.” American Economic Review 98 (5): 1943–77.
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.98.5.1943.
Calvo, Guillermo A. 1998. “Capital Flows and Capital-Market Crises: The Simple Economics
of Sudden Stops.” Journal of Applied Economics 1 (1): 35–54. https://doi.org/10.10
80/15140326.1998.12040516.
———. 2005. “Volatility as an Innovation Deterrent: Adam Smith in Stormy Weather.” College
Park, United States: University of Maryland. Mimeographed Document.
Calvo, Guillermo A., Alejandro Izquierdo, and Luis-Fernando Mejía. 2008. “Systemic Sudden
Stops: The Relevance of Balance-Sheet Effects and Financial Integration.” NBER
Working Paper, no. 14026 (May). https://doi.org/10.3386/w14026.
Calvo, Guillermo A., Alejandro Izquierdo, and Rudy Loo-Kung. 2012. “Optimal Holdings of
International Reserves: Self-Insurance against Sudden Stop.” NBER Working Paper,
no. 18219 (July). https://doi.org/10.3386/w18219.
Calvo, Guillermo A., Alejandro Izquierdo, and Ernesto Talvi. 2006. “Sudden Stops and
Phoenix Miracles in Emerging Markets.” American Economic Review 96 (2): 405–10.
https://doi.org/10.1257/000282806777211856.
Calvo, Guillermo A., and Carmen M. Reinhart. 2002. “Fear of Floating.” The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 117 (2): 379–408.
Cárdenas, Mauricio. 2020. “Emerging Economies Need New Finance, Not Moratoriums.”
Project Syndicate, May 13, 2020. https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/
emerging- economies-need-new-finance -not-moratoriums-by-mauricio -
cardenas-2020–05.
146
REFERENCES
Cárdenas, Mauricio, and Juan José Guzmán Ayala. 2020. “Planning a Sustainable Post-
Pandemic Recovery in Latin America and the Caribbean.” UNDP LAC COVID-19
Policy Documents Series 21. New York: UNDP. https://www.latinamerica.undp.org/
content/rblac/en/home/library/crisis_prevention_and_recovery/planeando-una-
recuperacion-sostenible-para-la-pospandemia-en-ame.html.
Casella, Bruno, Richard Bolwijn, Daniel Moran, and Keiichiro Kanemoto. 2019. “Improving
the Analysis of Global Value Chains: The UNCTAD-Eora Database.” Transnational
Corporations 26 (3): 115–42. https://doi.org/10.18356/3aad0f6a-en.
Caselli, Francesco. 2005. “Chapter 9 Accounting for Cross-Country Income Differences.”
In Handbook of Economic Growth, 1:679–741. Amsterdam: Elsevier. https://doi.
org/10.1016/S1574–0684(05)01009–9.
Caselli, Francesco, Miklós Koren, Milan Lisicky, and Silvana Tenreyro. 2020. “Diversification
through Trade.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 135(1): 449–502. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w21498.
Castellani, Francesca, Marcelo Olarreaga, Ugo Panizza, and Yue Zhou. 2019. “Investment
Gaps in Latin America and the Caribbean.” International Development Policy, no. 11.1
(March). https://doi.org/10.4000/poldev.2894.
Cavallo, Eduardo. 2019. “International Capital Flow Reversals.” IDB Working Paper
No. 1040. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. http://dx.doi.
org/10.18235/0001809.
———. 2020. “Baker or Brady: Lessons of Past Financial Crises for the Pandemic Recovery.”
Ideas Matter (blog). July 9, 2020. https://blogs.iadb.org/ideas-matter/en/
baker-or-brady-lessons-of-past-financial-crises-for-the-pandemic-recovery/.
Cavallo, Eduardo A., Eduardo Fernández-Arias, and Andrew Powell. 2014. “Is the Euro-Zone
on the Mend? Latin American Examples to Analyze the Euro Question.” Journal of
Banking & Finance 47 (October): 243–57. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.07.010.
Cavallo, Eduardo A., Arturo Galindo, Alejandro Izquierdo, and John Jairo León. 2013. “The
Role of Relative Price Volatility in the Efficiency of Investment Allocation.” Journal
of International Money and Finance 33: 1–18.
Cavallo, Eduardo A., Alejandro Izquierdo, and John J. León-Díaz. 2020. “Preventing
Sudden Stops in Net Capital Flows.” IDB Working Paper No. 1132. Washington, DC:
Inter-American Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002561.
Cavallo, Eduardo A., and Andrew Powell, eds. 2018. A Mandate to Grow. 2018 Latin American
and Caribbean Macroeconomic Report. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development
Bank. https://publications.iadb.org/publications/english/document/2018-Latin-
American-and-Caribbean-Macroeconomic-Report-A-Mandate-to-Grow.pdf.
———, eds. 2019. Building Opportunities to Grow in a Challenging World. 2019 Latin American
and Caribbean Macroeconomic Report. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development
Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0001633.
147
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Cavallo, Eduardo A., Andrew Powell, Mathieu Pedemonte, and Pilar Tavella. 2015. “A
New Taxonomy of Sudden Stops: Which Sudden Stops Should Countries Be Most
Concerned About?” Journal of International Money and Finance 51 (March): 47–70.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2014.10.001.
Cavallo, Eduardo A., Andrew Powell, and Tomás Serebrisky, eds. 2020. From Structures
to Services: The Path to Better Infrastructure in Latin America and the Caribbean.
Development in the Americas Series. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development
Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002506.
Cerra, Valerie, and Sweta Chaman Saxena. 2008. “Growth Dynamics: The Myth of Economic
Recovery.” American Economic Review 98 (1): 439–57. https://doi.org/10.1257/
aer.98.1.439.
CFMCA (Coalition of Finance Ministers for Climate Action). 2020. “Better Recovery, Better
World: Resetting Climate Action in the Aftermath of the COVID-19 Pandemic.” CFMCA.
https://www.financeministersforclimate.org/sites/cape/files/inline-files/Better%20
Recovery%2C%20Better%20World%20FINAL.pdf.
Coady, David, Ian Parry, Nghia-Piotr Le, and Baoping Shang. 2019. “Global Fossil Fuel
Subsidies Remain Large: An Update Based on Country-Level Estimates.” IMF Working
Paper 19/89. http://cc-lesbecquets.info/pdf/WPIEA2019089.pdf.
Cooper, Cheryl R., Darryl E. Getter, Raj Gnanarajah, David W. Perkins, and Andrew P. Scott.
2020. “COVID-19: Consumer Loan Forbearance and Other Relief Options.” CRS
Report. Congressional Research Service. https://fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/R46356.pdf.
Corbacho, Ana, Vicente Fretes Cibils, and Eduardo Lora, eds. 2013. More than Revenue:
Taxation as a Development Tool. New York: Palgrave Macmillan US. https://doi.
org/10.1057/9781137315977.
Costa Rica. 2019. “National Decarbonization Plan Costa Rica.” New York: United Nations.
https://unfccc.int/sites/default/files/resource/NationalDecarbonizationPlan.pdf.
D’Aprile, Paolo, Hauke Engel, Godart van Gendt, Stefan Helmcke, Solveigh Hieronimus, Tomas
Nauclér, Dickon Pinner, Daan Walter, and Maaike Witteveen. 2020. “Net-Zero Europe:
Decarbonization Pathways and Socioeconomic Implications.” McKinsey & Company.
http://artfuelsforum.eu/wp-content/uploads/2020/12/Net-zero-Europe.pdf.
Daude, Christian, and Eduardo Fernández-Arias. 2010. “On the Role of Productivity and
Factor Accumulation in Economic Development in Latin America and the Caribbean.”
IDB Working Paper No. 155. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
Davis, Steve, and John Haltiwanger. 1992. “Gross Job Creation, Gross Job Destruction
and Employment Reallocation.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(3): 819–63.
https://doi.org/10.3386/w3728.
De Mooij, Ruud, Ricardo Fenochietto, Shafik Hebous, Sébastien Leduc, and Carolina
Osorio-Buitron. 2020. “Tax Policy for Inclusive Growth after the Pandemic.” Special
Series on COVID-19. International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/-/media/
148
REFERENCES
Files/Publications/covid19-special-notes/en-special-series-on-covid-19-tax-policy-
for-inclusive-growth-after-the-pandemic.ashx.
Delgado, R., H. Eguino, and A. Lópes. 2021. “Política fiscal y cambio climático.” Washington,
DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
Dellas, Harris, Dimitris Malliaropulos, Dimitris Papageorgiou, and Evangelia Vourvachaki. 2017.
“Fiscal Multipliers with an Informal Sector.” Bank of Greece Working Paper 2017235.
Desai, Mihir A., C. Fritz Foley, and James R. Hines Jr. 2006. “Taxation and Multinational
Activity: New Evidence, New Interpretations.” Survey of Current Business 86 (2):
16–22.
Djankov, Simeon, Tim Ganser, Caralee McLiesh, Rita Ramalho, and Andrei Shleifer. 2010.
“The Effect of Corporate Taxes on Investment and Entrepreneurship.” American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (3): 31–64. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.2.3.31.
Ebrahimy, E., D. Igan, and S. Martinez Peria. 2020. “The Impact of COVID-19 on Inflation:
Potential Drivers and Dynamics.” Special Series on COVID-19. International Monetary
Fund.
ECLAC (Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean). 2020. “Sectores y
empresas frente al COVID-19: emergencia y reactivación.” https://repositorio.cepal.
org/bitstream/handle/11362/45734/4/S2000438_es.pdf.
ECLAC (Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean), and Oxfam. 2020.
“Tax Incentives for Businesses in Latin America and the Caribbean. Summary.” Project
Documents. Santiago: ECLAC and Oxfam. https://repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/
handle/11362/45204/1/S1901195_en.pdf.
Energy Sector Management Assistance Program. 2018. Policy Matters: Regulatory Indicators
for Sustainable Energy. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Esquivel, Carlos, Timothy J. Kehoe, and Juan Pablo Nicolini. 2019. “Lessons from the
Monetary and Fiscal History of Latin America.” Becker Friedman Institute for Economics
Working Paper 2019–47.
Fang, Hanming, Long Wang, and Yang Yang. 2020. “Human Mobility Restrictions and the
Spread of the Novel Coronavirus (2019-NCoV) in China.” NBER Working Paper, no.
26906 (March). https://doi.org/10.3386/w26906.
Fay, Marianne, Stephane Hallegatte, Adrien Vogt-Schilb, Julie Rozenberg, Ulf Narloch, and
Tom Kerr. 2015. Decarbonizing Development: Three Steps to a Zero-Carbon Future.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Feng, Kuishuang, Klaus Hubacek, Yu Liu, Estefanía Marchán, and Adrien Vogt-Schilb. 2018.
“Managing the Distributional Effects of Energy Taxes and Subsidy Removal in Latin
America and the Caribbean.” Applied Energy 225 (September): 424–36. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2018.04.116.
Fenochietto, Ricardo, and Carola Pessino. 2013. “Understanding Countries’ Tax Effort.” IMF
Working Paper 13/224. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2013/wp13244.pdf.
149
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Fernández, Cristina, and Leonardo Villar. 2017. “The Impact of Lowering the Payroll Tax on
Informality in Colombia.” Economía Journal Volume 18 Number 1 (Fall 2017): 125–55.
https://ideas.repec.org/a/col/000425/015830.html.
Fitch Ratings. 2020. “Forbearance Programs Will Camouflage Weakening Bank
Asset Quality.” Fitch Ratings. https://www.fitchratings.com/research/banks/
forbearance-programs-will-camouflage-weakening-bank-asset-quality-21-05-2020.
Forbes, Kristin J., and Francis E. Warnock. 2012. “Capital Flow Waves: Surges, Stops, Flight,
and Retrenchment.” Journal of International Economics 88 (2): 235–51. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2012.03.006.
Foster, Lucia, John C. Haltiwanger, and Cornell John Krizan. 2001. “Aggregate Productivity
Growth: Lessons from Microeconomic Evidence.” In New Developments in Productivity
Analysis, 303–372. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Furceri, Davide, and Bin Grace Li. 2017. “The Macroeconomic (and Distributional) Effects
of Public Investment in Developing Economies.” IMF Working Paper 17/217.
Godbout, Luc, and Suzie St-Cerny. 2011. “Are Consumption Taxes Regressive in Quebec?”
Canadian Tax Journal 59 (3): 463. https://www.ctf.ca/ctfweb/CMDownload.
aspx?ContentKey=eccf6a21-de59-4ff6-8833-068f87018401&ContentItemKey=03a
626bd-c8a0-4179-a505-1ecdf3f2b285.
Gonzáles-Mahecha, Esperanza, Oskar Lecuyer, Michelle Hallack, Morgan Bazilian, and Adrien
Vogt-Schilb. 2019. “Committed Emissions and the Risk of Stranded Assets from Power
Plants in Latin America and the Caribbean.” IDB Discussion Paper No. 708. Washington,
DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0001827.
Granja, Joao, and Christian Leuz. 2017. “The Death of a Regulator: Strict Supervision, Bank
Lending and Business Activity.” NBER Working Paper, no. 24168. https://www.nber.
org/system/files/working_papers/w24168/w24168.pdf.
Gropp, Reint, Steven Ongena, Jörg Rocholl, and Vahid Saadi. 2020. “The Cleansing Effect
of Banking Crises.” CEPR Discussion Paper 15025.
Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman. 2020. “When Tariffs Disturb Global Supply Chains.”
NBER Working Paper, no. 27722 (August). https://doi.org/10.3386/w27722.
Groves, David G., James Syme, Edmundo Molina-Perez, Carlos Calvo, Luis Víctor-Gallardo,
Guido Godinez-Zamora, Jairo Quirós-Tortos, et al. 2020. The Benefits and Costs of
Decarbonizing Costa Rica’s Economy: Informing the Implementation of Costa Rica’s
National Decarbonization Plan under Uncertainty. Washington, DC: Inter-American
Development Bank. https://publications.iadb.org/en/node/29378.
Gunter, Samara. 2013. “State Earned Income Tax Credits and Participation in Regular and
Informal Work.” National Tax Journal 66 (1): 33–62. https://doi.org/10.17310/ntj.2013.1.02.
Gunter, Samara, Daniel Riera-Crichton, Carlos Végh, and Guillermo Vuletín. 2019. “Non-
Linear Effects of Tax Changes on Output: The Role of the Initial Level of Taxation.”
NBER Working Paper, no. 26570 (December). https://doi.org/10.3386/w26570.
150
REFERENCES
Hallegatte, Stephane, Mook Bangalore, Laura Bonzanigo, Marianne Fay, Tamaro Kane, Ulf
Narloch, Julie Rozenberg, David Treguer, and Adrien Vogt-Schilb. 2015. Shock Waves:
Managing the Impacts of Climate Change on Poverty. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Hanson, Samuel H., Jeremy C. Stein, Adi Sunderman, and Eric Zwick. 2020. “Business
Credit Programs in the Pandemic Era.” Brooking Papers of Economic Activity, BPEA
Conference Drafts, September 2020.
Hausmann, Ricardo, and Dani Rodrik. 2003. “Economic Development as Self-Discovery.”
Journal of Development Economics 72 (2): 603–33. https://doi.org/10.1016/
S0304-3878(03)00124-X.
Heise, Sebastian. 2020a. “Firm-to-Firm Relationships and the Pass-Through of Shocks:
Theory and Evidence.” FRB of New York Staff Report. https://www.ssrn.com/
abstract=3437861.
———. 2020b. “How Did China’s COVID-19 Shutdown Affect US Supply Chains?” Federal
Reserve Bank of New York. Liberty Street Economics (blog). 2020. https://
libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2020/05/how-did-chinas-covid-19-
shutdown-affect-us-supply-chains.html.
Hoynes, Hilary W., and Ankur J. Patel. 2018. “Effective Policy for Reducing Poverty and
Inequality?: The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Distribution of Income.” Journal
of Human Resources 53 (4): 859–90. https://doi.org/10.3368/jhr.53.4.1115.7494R1.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2010. “Development Accounting.” American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (1): 207–23. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.2.1.207.
Hull, John. 2015. Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives. Ninth edition. Boston: Pearson.
Huxham, Matthew, Muhammed Anwar, and David Nelson. 2019. “Understanding the Impact
of a Low Carbon Transition on South Africa.” Climate Policy Initiative. http://www.
indiaenvironmentportal.org.in/files/file/Understanding%20the%20impact%20of%20
a%20low%20carbon%20transition%20on%20South%20Africa.pdf.
IDB (Inter-American Development Bank). 2020. “Summary of the Main Economic, Monetary
and Financial Policy Measures Taken in the Face of the Global COVID-19 Pandemic.”
Inter-American Development Bank.
IDB (Inter-American Development Bank), and DDPLAC (Deep Decarbonization
Pathways in Latin America and the Caribbean). 2019. “Getting to Net-Zero
Emissions: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean.” Washington,
DC: Inter-American Development Bank and Deep Decarbonization Pathways
in L atin America and the C aribbean . ht tps://publications .iadb.org/en/
getting-net-zero-emissions-lessons-latin-america-and-caribbean.
IDB (Inter-American Development Bank), and IDB Invest. 2018. “What Is Sustainable
Infrastructure? A Framework to Guide Sustainability Across the Project Cycle.” IDB
Technical Note No. 1388. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://
publications.iadb.org/handle/11319/8798.
151
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
IEA (International Energy Agency). 2019. “Government Revenue from Taxation.” In Global
EV Outlook 2019. Paris: International Energy Agency.
———. 2020a. “Green Stimulus after the 2008 Crisis: Learning from Successes and Failures.”
World Energy Outlook Special Report. Paris: International Energy Agency.
———. 2020b. “Sustainable Recovery.” World Energy Outlook Special Report. Paris:
International Energy Agency.
———. 2020c. World Energy Outlook 2020. Paris: International Energy Agency.
Ilzetzki, Ethan, Enrique G. Mendoza, and Carlos Végh. 2013. “How Big (Small?) Are Fiscal
Multipliers?” Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2): 239–54. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jmoneco.2012.10.011.
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2019. World Economic Outlook: Global Manufacturing
Downturn, Rising Trade Barriers. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
———. 2020a. “Greening the Recovery.” Special Series on COVID-19. Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/~/media/Files/Publications/
covid19-special-notes/en-special-series-on-covid-19-greening-the-recovery.ashx.
———. 2020b. “The International Architecture for Resolving Sovereign Debt Involving
Private-Sector Creditors—Recent Developments, Challenges, And Reform Options.”
Policy Papers 20 (043). https://doi.org/10.5089/9781513557472.007.
———. 2020c. World Economic Outlook: A Crisis Like No Other, An Uncertain Recovery.
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
———. 2020d. World Economic Outlook: A Long and Difficult Ascent. Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund.
———. 2020e. World Economic Outlook: Tentative Stabilization, Sluggish Recovery?
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
———. 2020f. World Economic Outlook: The Great Lockdown. Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund.
———. 2021a. “Policy Responses to COVID19.” Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
https://www.imf.org/en/Topics/imf-and-covid19/Policy-Responses-to-COVID-19.
———. 2021b. World Economic Outlook: Policy Support and Vaccines Expected to Lift
Activity. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change). 2018. “Summary for Policymakers.”
In IPCC, 2018: Global Warming of 1.5°C. An IPCC Special Report on the Impacts of
Global Warming of 1.5°C above Pre-Industrial Levels and Related Global Greenhouse
Gas Emission Pathways, in the Context of Strengthening the Global Response to
the Threat of Climate Change, Sustainable Development, and Efforts to Eradicate
Poverty. Cambridge & New York: IPCC. https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/
sites/2/2019/06/SR15_Full_Report_High_Res.pdf.
Izquierdo, Alejandro, and Martín Ardanaz. 2020. “Can Latin America Afford to Fight
COVID-19?” Project Syndicate, April 7, 2020. https://www.project-syndicate.org/
152
REFERENCES
commentary/coronavirus-latin-america-economy-by-alejandro-izquierdo-2-and-
martin-ardanaz-2020-04.
Izquierdo, Alejandro, Philip Keefer, Allen Blackman, Matías Busso, Eduardo A. Cavallo,
Gregory Elacqua, Ana María Ibáñez, et al. 2020. Emerging from the Pandemic Tunnel
with Faster Growth and Greater Equity: A Strategy for a New Social Compact in Latin
America and the Caribbean. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
https://doi.org/10.18235/0002473.
Izquierdo, Alejandro, Ruy E. Lama, Juan Pablo Medina, Jorge P. Puig, Daniel Riera-
Crichton, Carlos Végh, and Guillermo Vuletín. 2019. “Is the Public Investment
Multiplier Higher in Developing Countries? An Empirical Investigation.” NBER Working
Paper, no. 26478.
Izquierdo, Alejandro, Carola Pessino, and Guillermo Vuletín, eds. 2018. Better Spending for
Better Lives: How Latin America and the Caribbean Can Do More with Less. Vol. 10.
Development in the Americas Series. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development
Bank. https://flagships.iadb.org/en/node/17354.
Jaeger, Joel, Michael Westphal, and Corey Park. 2020. “Lessons Learned on Green
Stimulus: Case Studies from the Global Financial Crisis.” Washington, DC: World
Resources Institute. https://www.wri.org/publication/lessons-learned-on-green-
stimulus-case-studies-from-the-global-financial-crisis.
Johnson, Robert C. 2018. “Measuring Global Value Chains.” Annual Review of Economics
10 (1): 207–36. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-080217-053600.
Jorgenson, Dale W. 2012. “The World KLEMS Initiative.” International Productivity Monitor
24: 5–19. https://ideas.repec.org/a/sls/ipmsls/v24y20121.html.
Kapoor, Supriya, and Oana Peia. 2021. “The Impact of Quantitative Easing on Liquidity
Creation.” Journal of Banking & Finance 122 (January): 105998. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2020.105998.
Kehoe, Timothy Jerome, and Juan Pablo Nicolini, eds. 2021. A Monetary and Fiscal History
of Latin America, 1960–2017. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Klemm, Alexander, and Stefan Van Parys. 2012. “Empirical Evidence on the Effects of
Tax Incentives.” International Tax and Public Finance 19 (3): 393–423. https://doi.
org/10.1007/s10797-011-9194-8.
Kramarz, Francis, Julien Martin, and Isabelle Mejean. 2020. “Volatility in the Small and in
the Large: The Lack of Diversification in International Trade.” Journal of International
Economics 122 (January): 103276. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2019.103276.
LA-KLEMS. 2019. LA-KLEMS: Crecimiento económico y productividad en América Latina.
Database. http://www.laklems.net/.
Larson, Eric, Chris Greig, Jesse Jesse, Erin Mayfield, Andrew Pascale, Chuan Zhang,
Joshua Drossman, et al. 2020. “Net-Zero America: Potential Pathways, Infrastructure
and Impacts.” Interim report. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University. https://
153
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
environmenthalfcentury.princeton.edu/sites/g/files/toruqf331/files/2020-12/
Princeton_NZA_Interim_Report_15_Dec_2020_FINAL.pdf.
Libonati, Renata, Carlos C. DaCamara, Leonardo F. Peres, de Lino A. Sander Carvalho,
and Letícia C. Garcia. 2020. “Rescue Brazil’s Burning Pantanal Wetlands.” Nature
588 (7837): 217–19. https://doi.org/10.1038/d41586–020–03464–1.
Lino, Igor dos Reis, and André Furtado Braz. 2019. “Cesta de Consumo e Inflação Das
Famílias de Baixa Renda: Um Panorama Da Última Década.” Caderno de Estudos 34.
Mariscal, Rodrigo, Andrew Powell, Guido Sandleris, and Pilar Tavella. 2015. “Sovereign
Defaults: Has the Current System Resulted in Lasting (Re)Solutions?” Business School
Working Paper. Universidad Torcuato Di Tella. https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/
udtwpbsdt/2015–03.htm.
Martin, Julien, Isabelle Mejean, and Mathieu Parenti. 2020. “Relationship Stickiness and
Economic Uncertainty.” Mimeo.
Masters, Jeff. 2021. “Reviewing the Horrid Global 2020 Wildfire Season » Yale Climate
Connections.” Yale Climate Connections. https://yaleclimateconnections.org/2021/01/
reviewing-the-horrid-global-2020-wildfire-season/.
Merton, Robert C. 1974. “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest
Rates.” The Journal of Finance 29 (2): 449. https://doi.org/10.2307/2978814.
Mesquita Moreira, Mauricio, and Ernesto H. Stein, eds. 2019. Trading Promises for Results:
What Global Integration Can Do for Latin America and the Caribbean. Development
in the Americas Series. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://
doi.org/10.18235/0001886.
Mooney, Henry, and María Alejandra Zegarra. 2020. “Extreme Outlier: The Pandemic’s
Unprecedented Shock to Tourism in Latin America and the Caribbean.” IDB Policy Brief No.
339. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://publications.iadb.org/en/
extreme-outlier-pandemics-unprecedented-shock-tourism-latin-america-and-caribbean.
NCE (New Climate Economy). 2018. Unlocking the Inclusive Growth Story of the 21st Century:
Accelerating Climate Action in Urgent Times. Washington, DC: New Climate Economy.
https://newclimateeconomy.report/2018/wp-content/uploads/sites/6/2018/09/
NCE_2018_FULL-REPORT.pdf.
Neumeyer, Pablo Andrés, Paulina Restrepo-Echevarría, and Lucas Belmudes. 2020. “The
COVID-19 Recession in Historical Perspective.” St. Louis Fed on the Economy Blog
(blog). November 12, 2020. https://www.stlouisfed.org/on-the-economy/2020/
november/covid19-recession-historical-perspective.
Nuguer, Victoria, and Andrew Powell, eds. 2020a. Inclusion in Times of Covid-19. Washington,
DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002529.
Nuguer, Victoria, and Andrew Powell, eds. 2020b. Policies to Fight the Pandemic. 2020 Latin
American and Caribbean Macroeconomic Report. Washington, DC: Inter-American
Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002284.
154
REFERENCES
Ocampo Gaviria, José Antonio. 1984. Colombia y la economía mundial: 1830–1910. 1a ed.
Economía y Demografía. México, D.F: Siglo Veintiuno Editores.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2018. “Tax Effects on
Foreign Direct Investment.” OECD Policy Brief. OECD.
———. 2019. “FDI in Figures - Latin America.” OECD. https://www.oecd.org/investment/
FDI-in-Figures-April-2019-Latin-America-English.pdf.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development), CIAT (Inter-American
Center of Tax Administrations), ECLAC (United Nations Economic Commission
for Latin America and the Caribbean), and IDB (Inter-American Development
Bank). 2020. Tax Revenue Statistics in Latin America and the Caribbean 2020.
Revenue Statistics in Latin America and the Caribbean. Paris: OECD. https://doi.
org/10.1787/68739b9b-en-es.
Pagés, Carmen. 2010. “The Age of Productivity.” In The Age of Productivity, edited by Carmen
Pagés, 1–21. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230107618_1.
Pagés, Carmen, Andrés Rodríguez Clare, and Ernesto H. Stein. Forthcoming. “Covid-19
y Empleo Formal: ¿Qué puede aprender América Latina y El Caribe del debate en
países desarrollados?” Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
Parrado, Eric. 2020. “Latin America’s Triple Sudden Stop.” Project Syndicate, August 12,
2020. https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/latin-america-triple-sudden-
stop-lockdowns-by-eric-parrado-2020–08?barrier=accesspaylog.
Parrado, Eric, Tristany Armangué, and Nicolás Herrera. 2020. “How the Fall in
Remittances During the Pandemic Threatens Regional Wellbeing.” Ideas
M at te r (blog). J un e 17, 2020. ht tps: // blogs . ia db.org/ ideas- mat te r/e n/
how-the-fall-in-remittances-during-the-pandemic-threatens-regional-wellbeing/.
Paul, Mark, Carla Santos Skandier, and Rory Renzy. 2020. “Out of Time: The Case for
Nationalizing the Fossil Fuel Industry.” People’s Policy Project and The Next System
Project. https://thenextsystem.org/sites/default/files/2020–06/OutofTime-Report_
Final%282%29pages.pdf.
Pecho, Miguel. 2014. “Tax Expenditures in Latin America: 2008–2012.” Tax Studies and
Research Directorate Working Paper, no. 2–2014.
Peek, Joe, and Eric S Rosengren. 2005. “Unnatural Selection: Perverse Incentives and
the Misallocation of Credit in Japan.” American Economic Review 95 (4): 1144–66.
https://doi.org/10.1257/0002828054825691.
Perraudin, William, Andrew Powell, and Peng Yang. Forthcoming. “Estimating Bank Default
Probabilities through the Covid-19 Crisis.” IDB Working Paper. Washington, DC: Inter-
American Development Bank.
Pessino, Carola. 2017. “Utilizando Big Data para construir un sistema de inteligencia fiscal
para los gobiernos.” Gestión Fiscal (blog). June 13, 2017. https://blogs.iadb.org/
gestion-fiscal/es/inteligencia-fiscal-para-los-gobiernos/.
155
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Pessino, Carola, Emilio Pineda, and Alejandro Rasteletti. Forthcoming. “Fiscal Policy
and Management to Increase Formalization.” Washington, DC: Inter-American
Development Bank.
Pessino, Carola, and Teresa Ter-Minassian. 2021. “Addressing the Fiscal Costs of Aging in
Latin America and the Caribbean with Lessons from Advanced Countries.” Washington,
DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
Powell, Andrew. 2011. “Bipolar Debt Restructuring: Lessons from LAC.” VOX LACEA (blog).
February 24, 2011. https://vox.lacea.org/?q=debt-lessons-LAC.
——— , ed. 2012. The World of Forking Paths. 2012 Latin American and Caribbean
Macroeconomic Report. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://
publications.iadb.org/en/world-forking-paths-latin-america-and-caribbean-facing-
global-economic-risks.
———, ed. 2014. Global Recovery and Monetary Normalization: Escaping a Chronicle Foretold?
2014 Latin American and Caribbean Macroeconomic Report. Washington, DC: Inter-
American Development Bank. https://publications.iadb.org/en/publication/16835/
global-recovery-and-monetary-normalization-escaping-chronicle-foretold.
———, ed. 2017. Routes to Growth in a New Trade World. 2017 Latin American and Caribbean
Macroeconomic Report. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://
doi.org/10.18235/0000653.
———. 2021. “On the Macroeconomics of Covid-19 and the Risks That Will Be Left in Its
Wake.” Ideas Matter (blog). January 6, 2021. https://blogs.iadb.org/ideas-matter/
en/on-the-macroeconomics-of-covid-19-and-the-risks-that-will-be-left-in-its-wake/.
Powell, Andrew, Rodrigo Mariscal, and Pilar Tavella. 2018. “On the Credibility of Inflation-
Targeting Regimes in Latin America.” Economía Journal Volume 18 Number 2 (Spring
2018): 1–24. https://ideas.repec.org/a/col/000425/016330.html.
Powell, Andrew, and Liliana Rojas-Suárez. 2020. Sound Banks for Healthy Economies:
Challenges for Policymakers in Latin America and the Caribbean in Times of
Coronavirus. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development and Inter-American
Development Bank. https://doi.org/10.18235/0002636.
Powell, Andrew, and Oscar Valencia. 2020. “Avoiding a New Lost Decade for Latin America
and the Caribbean.” Ideas Matter (blog). October 15, 2020. https://blogs.iadb.org/
ideas-matter/en/another-lost-decade-for-latin-america-and-the-caribbean/.
PwC (PricewaterhouseCoopers), and World Bank. 2019. “Paying Taxes 2020: What Can
We Learn from Tax Regimes in 190 Economies around the World.” Washington, DC:
PricewaterhouseCoopers and World Bank. https://www.pwc.com/gx/en/paying-
taxes/pdf/pwc-paying-taxes-2020.pdf.
Quirós-Tortos, Jairo, Guido Godínez-Samora, D. De La Torre Ugarte, C. Heros, J. Lazo Lazo,
E. Ruiz, B. Quispe, et al. 2021. “Costos y beneficios de la carbono-neutralidad en el
156
REFERENCES
157
OPPORTUNITIES FOR STRONGER AND SUSTAINABLE POSTPANDEMIC GROWTH
Fiscal Revenues in Latin America and the Caribbean.” IDB Discussion Paper No. 701.
Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. https://publications.iadb.org/
en/implications-climate-targets-oil-production-and-fiscal-revenues-latin-america-
and-caribbean.
Stein, Ernesto H., and Camila Valencia. 2020. “The Spread of the Novel Coronavirus Outside
China.” Ideas Matter (blog). March 30, 2020. https://blogs.iadb.org/ideas-matter/
en/the-spread-of-the-novel-coronavirus-outside-china/.
Stiglitz, Joseph E., Nicholas Stern, Maosheng Duan, Ottmar Edenhofer, Gaël Giraud,
Geoffrey M. Heal, Emilio Lèbre La Rovere, Adele Morris, Elisabeth Moyer, and Mari
Pangestu. 2017. “Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices.” High-Level
Commission on Carbon Prices. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Summers, Lawrence H., and Natasha Sarin. 2019. “A ‘Wealth Tax’ Presents a Revenue
Estimation Puzzle.” Washington Post, 2019. https://www.washingtonpost.com/
opinions/2019/04/04/wealth-tax-presents-revenue-estimation-puzzle/.
TCFD (Task Force on Climate-related Financial Disclosures). 2017. “Recommendations of
the Task Force on Climate-Related Financial Disclosures.” Switzerland: TCFD. https://
assets.bbhub.io/company/sites/60/2020/10/FINAL-2017-TCFD-Report-11052018.
pdf.
UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). 2019. The
State of Commodity Dependence. New York: United Nations Conference on
Trade and Development. https://unctad.org/system/files/official-document/
ditccom2019d1_en.pdf.
Valencia, Oscar, and Matilde Angarita. 2020. “Assessing the Fiscal Impact of COVID-19 in
LAC.” IDB Manuscript. Washington, DC.
Van Ark, Bart, and Kirsten Jäger. 2017. “Recent Trends in Europe’s Output and Productivity
Growth Performance at the Sector Level, 2002–2015.” International Productivity
Monitor 33: 8–23. https://ideas.repec.org/a/sls/ipmsls/v33y20171.html.
Van Parys, Stefan, and Sebastian James. 2010. “The Effectiveness of Tax Incentives in
Attracting Investment: Panel Data Evidence from the CFA Franc Zone.” International
Tax and Public Finance 17 (4): 400–429. https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/
s10797–010–9140–1.
Vogt-Schilb, Adrien, Brian Walsh, Kuishuang Feng, Laura Di Capua, Yu Liu, Daniela Zuluaga,
Marcos Robles, and Klaus Hubaceck. 2019. “Cash Transfers for Pro-Poor Carbon Taxes
in Latin America and the Caribbean.” Nature Sustainability 2 (10): 941–48. https://
doi.org/10.1038/s41893–019–0385–0.
Wang, Zhi, Shang-Jin Wei, Xinding Yu, and Kunfu Zhu. 2017. “Measures of Participation in
Global Value Chains and Global Business Cycles.” NBER Working Paper, no. 23222.
https://doi.org/10.3386/w23222.
158
REFERENCES
World Bank. 2018. Global Investment Competitiveness Report 2017/2018: Foreign Investor
Perspectives and Policy Implications. Washington, DC: World Bank. https://doi.
org/10.1596/978–1-4648–1175–3.
———. 2020a. “Lessons from Chile’s Experience with E-Mobility: The Integration of E-Buses
in Santiago.” Washington, DC: World Bank.
———. 2020b. World Development Report 2020: Trading for Development in the Age of Global
Value Chains. Washington, DC: World Bank. https://doi.org/10.1596/978–1-4648–1457–0.
Yazmín López, Carolina, María Eugenia Sosa, David Carlin, Remco Fischer, Mauricio
Velásquez, Jessica Palomeque, Rodrigo García, Sofía Burford, and Hugo Mendizábal.
2020. Cómo los bancos incorporan el cambio climático en su gestión de riesgos.
Caracas: CAF - Banco de Desarrollo de América Latina. https://scioteca.caf.com/
handle/123456789/1626.
159