Krugman - The Myth of Asia

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

The Myth of Asia’s Miracle

Paul Krugman
Foreign Affairs; Nov/Dec 1994; Vol.73, Iss. 6; pg. 62, 17 pgs

The Myth of Asia’s Miracle


Paul Krugman

A CAUTIONARY FABLE

Once upon a time, Western opinion leaders found themselves both impressed and frightened by the
extraordinary growth rates achieved by a set of Eastern economies. Although those economies were
still substantially poorer and smaller than those of the West, the speed with which they had
transformed themselves from peasant societies into industrial powerhouses, their continuing ability to
achieve growth rates several times higher than the advanced nations, and their increasing ability to
challenge or even surpass American and European technology in certain areas seemed to call into
question the dominance not only of Western power but of Western ideology. The leaders of those
nations did not share our faith in free markets or unlimited civil liberties. They asserted with
increasing self-confidence that their system was superior: societies that accepted strong, even
authoritarian governments and were willing to limit individual liberties in the interest of the common
good, take charge of their economies, and sacrifice short-run consumer interests for the sake of
long-run growth would eventually outperform the increasingly chaotic societies of the West. And a
growing minority of Western intellectuals agreed.

The gap between Western and Eastern economic performance eventually became a political issue. The
Democrats recaptured the White House under the leadership of a young, energetic new president who
pledged to "get the country moving again--a pledge that, to him and his closest advisers, meant
accelerating America's economic growth to meet the Eastern challenge.

The time, of course, was the early 1960s. The dynamic young president was John F. Kennedy. The
technological feats that so alarmed the West were the launch of Sputnik and the early Soviet lead in
space. And the rapidly growing Eastern economies were those of the Soviet Union and its satellite
nations.

While the growth of communist economies was the subject of innumerable alarmist books and
polemical articles in the 1950s, some economists who looked seriously at the roots of that growth
were putting together a picture that differed substantially from most popular assumptions. Communist
growth rates were certainly impressive, but not magical. The rapid growth in output could be fully
explained by rapid growth in inputs: expansion of employment, increases in education levels, and,
above all, massive investment in physical capital. Once those inputs were taken into account, the
growth in output was unsurprising--or, to put it differently, the big surprise about Soviet growth was
that when closely examined it posed no mystery.

This economic analysis had two crucial implications. First, most of the speculation about the
superiority of the communist system--including the popular view that Western economies could
painlessly accelerate their own growth by borrowing some aspects of that system--was off base. Rapid
Soviet economic growth was based entirely on one attribute: the willingness to save, to sacrifice
current consumption for the sake of future production. The communist example offered no hint of a
free lunch.

Second, the economic analysis of communist countries' growth implied some future limits to their
industrial expansion--in other words, implied that a naive projection of their past growth rates into the
future was likely to greatly overstate their real prospects. Economic growth that is based on expansion
of inputs, rather than on growth in output per unit of input, is inevitable subject to diminishing returns.
It was simply not possible for the Soviet economies to sustain the rates of growth of labor force
participation, average education levels, and above all the physical capital stock that had prevailed in
previous years. Communist growth would predictably slow down, perhaps drastically.

Can there really be any parallel between the growth of Warsaw Pact nations in the 1950s and the
spectacular Asian growth that now preoccupies policy intellectuals? At some levels, of course, the
parallel is far-fetched: Singapore in the 1990s does not look much like the Soviet Union in the 1950s,
and Singapore's Lee Kuan Yew bears little resemblance to the U.S.S.R.'s Nikita Khrushchev and less
to Joseph Stalin. Yet the results of recent economic research into the sources of Pacific Rim growth
give the few people who recall the great debate over Soviet growth a strong sense of deja vu. Now, as
then, the contrast between popular hype and realistic prospects, between conventional wisdom and
hard numbers, remains so great that sensible economic analysis is not only widely ignored, but when it
does get aired, it is usually dismissed as grossly implausible.

Popular enthusiasm about Asia's boom deserves to have some cold water thrown on it. Rapid Asian
growth is less of a model for the West than many writers claim, and the future prospects for that
growth are more limited than almost anyone now imagines. Any such assault on almost universally
held beliefs must, of course, overcome a barrier of incredulity. This article began with a disguised
account of the Soviet growth debate of 30 years ago to try to gain a hearing for the proposition that we
may be revisiting an old error. We have been here before The problem with this literary device,
however, is that so few people now remember how impressive and terrifying the Soviet empire's
economic performance once seemed. Before turning to Asian growth, then, it may be useful to review
an important but largely forgotten piece of economic history.

"WE WILL BURY YOU"

Living in a world strewn with the wreckage of the Soviet empire, it is hard for most people to realize
that there was a time when the Soviet economy, far from being a byword for the failure of socialism,
was one of the wonders of the world--that when Khrushchev pounded his shoe on the U. N. podium
and declared, "We will bury you," it was an economic rather than a military boast. It is therefore a
shock to browse through, say, issues of Foreign Affairs from the mid-1950s through the early 1960s
and discover that at least one article a year dealt with the implications of growing Soviet industrial
might.

Illustrative of the tone of discussion was a 1957 article by Calvin B. Hoover.(1) Like many Western
economists, Hoover criticized official Soviet statistics, arguing that they exaggerated the true growth
rate. Nonetheless, he concluded that Soviet claims of astonishing achievement were fully justified:
their economy was achieving a rate of growth "twice as high as that attained by any important
capitalistic country over any considerable number of years [and] three times as high as the average
annual rate of increase in the United States." He concluded that it was probable that "a collectivist,
authoritarian state" was inherently better at achieving economic growth than free-market democracies
and projected that the Soviet economy might outstrip that of the United States by the early 1970s.

These views were not considered outlandish at the time. On the contrary, the general image of Soviet
central planning was that it might be brutal, and might not do a very good job of providing consumer
goods, but that it was very effective at promoting industrial growth. In 1960 Wassily Leontief
described the Soviet economy as being "directed with determined ruthless skill"--and did so without
supporting argument, confident he was expressing a view shared by his readers.

Yet many economists studying Soviet growth were gradually coming to a very different conclusion.
Although they did not dispute the fact of past Soviet growth, they offered a new interpretation of the
nature of that growth, one that implied a reconsideration of future Soviet prospects. To understand this
reinterpretation, it is necessary to make a brief detour into economic theory to discuss a seemingly
abstruse, but in fact intensely practical, concept: growth accounting.

ACCOUNTING FOR THE SOVIET SLOWDOWN

It is a tautology that economic expansion represents the sum of two sources of growth. On one side are
increases in "inputs": growth in employment, in the education level of workers, and in the stock of
physical capital (machines, buildings, roads, and so on). On the other side are increases in the output
per unit of input; such increases may result from better management or better economic policy, but in
the long run are primarily due to increases in knowledge.

The basic idea of growth accounting is to give life to this formula by calculating explicit measures of
both. The accounting can then tell us how much of growth is due to each input--say, capital as
opposed to labor--and how much is due to increased efficiency.

We all do a primitive form of growth accounting every time we talk about labor productivity; in so
doing we are implicitly distinguishing between the part of overall national growth due to the growth in
the supply of labor and the part due to an increase in the value of goods produced by the average
worker. Increases in labor productivity, however, are not always caused by the increased efficiency of
workers. Labor is only one of a number of inputs; workers may produce more, not because they are
better managed or have more technological knowledge, but simply because they have better
machinery. A man with a bulldozer can dig a ditch faster than one with only a shovel, but he is not
more efficient; he just has more capital to work with. The aim of growth accounting is to produce an
index that combines all measurable inputs and to measure the rate of growth of national income
relative to that index to estimate what is known as "total factor productivity."(2)

So far this may seem like a purely academic exercise. As soon as one starts to think in terms of growth
accounting, however, one arrives at a crucial insight about the process of economic growth: sustained
growth in a nation's per capita income can only occur if there is a rise in output per unit of input.(3)

Mere increases in inputs, without an increase in the efficiency with which those inputs are
used--investing in more machinery and infrastructure--must run into diminishing returns; input-driven
growth is inevitably limited.

How, then, have today's advanced nations been able to achieve sustained growth in per capita income
over the past 150 years? The answer is that technological advances have led to a continual increase in
total factor productivity--a continual rise in national income for each unit of input. In a famous
estimate, MIT Professor Robert Solow concluded that technological progress has accounted for 80
percent of the long-term rise in U.S. per capita income, with increased investment in capital
explaining only the remaining 20 percent.

When economists began to study the growth of the Soviet economy, they did so using the tools of
growth accounting. Of course, Soviet data posed some problems. Not only was it hard to piece
together usable estimates of output and input (Raymond Powell, a Yale professor, wrote that the job
"in many ways resembled an archaeological dig"), but there were philosophical difficulties as well. In
a socialist economy one could hardly measure capital input using market returns, so researchers were
forced to impute returns based on those in market economies at similar levels of development. Still,
when the efforts began, researchers were pretty sure about what: they would find. Just as capitalist
growth had been based on growth in both inputs and efficiency, with efficiency the main source of
rising per capita income, they expected to find that rapid Soviet growth reflected both rapid input
growth and rapid growth in efficiency.

But what they actually found was that Soviet growth was based on rapid--growth in inputs--end of
story. The rate of efficiency growth was not only unspectacular, it was well below the rates achieved
in Western economies. Indeed, by some estimates, it was virtually nonexistent.(4)

The immense Soviet efforts to mobilize economic resources were hardly news. Stalinist planners had
moved millions of workers from farms to cities, pushed millions of women into the labor force and
millions of men into longer hours, pursued massive programs of education, and above all plowed an
ever-growing proportion of the country's industrial output back into the construction of new factories.
Still, the big surprise was that once one had taken the effects of these more or less measurable inputs
into account, there was nothing left to explain. The most shocking thing about Soviet growth was its
comprehensibility.

This comprehensibility implied two crucial conclusions. First, claims about the superiority of planned
over market economies turned out to .be based on a misapprehension. If the Soviet economy had a
special strength, it was its ability to mobilize resources, not its ability to use them efficiently. It was
obvious to everyone that the Soviet Union in 1960 was much less efficient than the United States. The
surprise was that it showed no signs of closing the gap.

Second, because input-driven growth is an inherently limited process, Soviet growth was virtually
certain to slow down. Long before the slowing of Soviet growth became obvious, it was predicted on
the basis of growth accounting. (Economists did not predict the implosion of the Soviet economy a
generation later, but that is a whole different problem.)

It's an interesting story and a useful cautionary tale about the dangers of naive extrapolation of past
trends. But is it relevant to the modern world?

PAPER TIGERS

At first, it is hard to see anything in common between the Asian success stories of recent years and the
Soviet Union of three decades ago. Indeed, it is safe to say that the typical business traveler to, say,
Singapore, ensconced in one of that city's gleaming hotels, never even thinks of any parallel to its
roach-infested counterparts in Moscow. How can the slick exuberance of the Asian boom be
compared with the Soviet Union's grim drive to industrialize?

And yet there are surprising similarities. The newly industrializing countries of Asia, like the Soviet
Union of the 1950s, have achieved rapid growth in large part through an astonishing mobilization of
resources. Once one accounts for the role of rapidly growing inputs in these countries' growth, one
finds little left to explain. Asian growth, like that of the Soviet Union in its high-growth era, seems to
be driven by extraordinary growth in inputs like labor and capital rather than by gains in efficiency.(5)

Consider, in particular, the case of Singapore. Between 1966 and 1990, the Singaporean economy
grew a remarkable 8.5 percent per annum, three times as fast as the United States; per capita income
grew at a 6.6 percent rate, roughly doubling every decade. This achievement seems to be a kind of
economic miracle. But the miracle turns out to have been based on perspiration rather than inspiration:
Singapore grew through a mobilization of resources that would have done Stalin proud. The employed
share of the population surged from 27 to 51 percent. The educational standards of that work force
were dramatically upgraded: while in 1966 more than half the workers had no formal education at all,
by 1990 two-thirds had completed secondary education. Above all, the country had made an awesome
investment in physical capital: investment as a share of output rose from 11 to more than 40
percent.(6)
Even without going through the formal exercise of growth accounting, these numbers should make it
obvious that Singapore's growth has been based largely on one-time changes in behavior that cannot
be repeated. Over the past generation the percentage of people employed has almost doubled; it cannot
double again. A half-educated work force has been replaced by one in which the bulk of workers has
high school diplomas; it is unlikely that a generation from now most Singaporeans will have Ph.D.s.
And an investment share of 40 percent is amazingly high by any standard; a share of 70 percent would
be ridiculous. So one can immediately conclude that Singapore is unlikely to achieve future growth
rates comparable to those of the past.

But it is only when one actually does the quantitative accounting that the astonishing result emerges:
all of Singapore's growth can be explained by increases in measured inputs. There is no sign at all of
increased efficiency. In this sense, the growth of Lee Kuan Yew's Singapore is an economic twin of
the growth of Stalin's Soviet Union--growth achieved purely through mobilization of resources. Of
course, Singapore today is far more prosperous than the U.S.S.R. ever was--even at its peak in the
Brezhnev years--because Singapore is closer to, though still below, the efficiency of Western
economies. The point, however, is that Singapore's economy has always been relatively efficient; it
just used to be starved of capital and educated workers.

Singapore's case is admittedly the most extreme. Other rapidly growing East Asian economies have
not increased their labor force participation as much, made such dramatic improvements in
educational levels, or raised investment rates quite as far. Nonetheless, the basic conclusion is the
same: there is startlingly little evidence of improvements in efficiency. Kim and Lau conclude of the
four Asian "tigers" that "the hypothesis that there has been no technical progress during the postwar
period cannot be rejected for the four East Asian newly industrialized countries." Young, more
poetically, notes that once one allows for their rapid growth of inputs, the productivity performance of
the "tigers" falls "from the heights of Olympus to the plains of Thessaly."

This conclusion runs so counter to conventional wisdom that it is extremely difficult for the
economists who have reached it to get a hearing. As early as 1982 a Harvard graduate student, Yuan
Tsao, found little evidence of efficiency growth in her dissertation on Singapore, but her work was, as
Young puts it, "ignored or dismissed as unbelievable." When Kim and Lau presented their work at a
1992 conference in Taipei, it received a more respectful hearing, but had little immediate impact But
when Young tried to make the case for input-driven Asian growth at the 1993 meetings of the
European Economic Association, he was met with a stone wall of disbelief.

In Young's most recent paper there is an evident tone of exasperation with this insistence on clinging
to the conventional wisdom in the teeth of the evidence. He titles the paper "The Tyranny of
Numbers"--by which he means that you may not want to believe this, buster, but there's just no way
around the data. He begins with an ironic introduction, written in a deadpan, Sergeant Friday, "Just the
facts, ma'am style: "This is a fairly boring and tedious paper, and is intentionally so. This paper
provides no new interpretations of the East Asian experience to interest the historian, derives no new
theoretical implications of the forces behind the East Asian growth process to motivate the theorist,
and draws no new policy implications from the subtleties of East Asian government intervention to
excite the policy activist. Instead, this paper concentrates its energies on providing a careful analysis
of the historical patterns of output growth, factor accumulation, and productivity growth in the newly
industrializing countries of East Asia."

Of course, he is being disingenuous. His conclusion undermines most of the conventional wisdom
about the future role of Asian nations in the world economy and, as a consequence, in international
politics. But readers will have noticed that the statistical analysis that puts such a different
interpretation on Asian growth focuses on the "tigers," the relatively small countries to whom the
name "newly industrializing countries" was first applied. But what about the large countries? What
about Japan and China?

THE GREAT JAPANESE GROWTH SLOWDOWN

Many people who are committed to the view that the destiny of the world economy lies with the
Pacific Rim are likely to counter skepticism about East Asian growth prospects with the example of
Japan. Here, after all, is a country that started out poor and has now become the second-largest
industrial power. Why doubt that other Asian nations can do the same?

There are two answers to that question. First, while many authors have written of an "Asian
system"--a common denominator that underlies all of the Asian success stories--the statistical
evidence tells a different story. Japan's growth in the 1950s and 1960s does not resemble Singapore's
growth in the 1970s and 1980s. Japan, unlike the East Asian "tigers," seems to have grown both
through high rates of input growth and through high rates of efficiency growth. Today's fast-growth
economies are nowhere near converging on U. S. efficiency levels, but Japan is staging an
unmistakable technological catch-up.

Second, while Japan's historical performance has indeed been remarkable, the era of miraculous
Japanese growth now lies well in the past. Most years Japan still manages to grow faster than the other
advanced nations, but that gap in growth rates is now far smaller than it used to be, and is shrinking.

The story of the great Japanese growth slowdown has been oddly absent from the vast polemical
literature on Japan and its role in the world economy. Much of that literature seems stuck in a time
warp, with authors writing as if Japan were still the miracle growth economy of the 1960s and early
1970s. Granted, the severe recession that has gripped Japan since 1991 will end soon if it has not done
so already, and the Japanese economy will probably stage a vigorous short-term recovery. The point,
however, is that even a full recovery will only reach a level that is far below what many sensible
observers predicted 20 years ago.

It may be useful to compare Japan's growth prospects as they appeared 20 years ago and as they
appear now. In 1973 Japan was still a substantially smaller and poorer economy than the United States.
Its per capita GDP was only 55 percent of America's, while its overall GDP was only 27 percent as
large. But the rapid growth of the Japanese economy clearly portended a dramatic change. Over the
previous decade Japan's real GDP had grown at a torrid 8.9 percent annually, with per capita output
growing at a 7.7 percent rate. Although American growth had been high by its own historical
standards, at 3.9 percent (2.7 percent per capita) it was not in the same league. Clearly, the Japanese
were rapidly gaining on us.

In fact, a straightforward projection of these trends implied that a major reversal of positions lay not
far in the future. At the growth rate of 1963-73, Japan would overtake the United States in real per
capita income by 1985, and total Japanese output would exceed that of the United States by 1998! At
the time, people took such trend projections very seriously indeed. One need only look at the titles of
such influential books as Herman Kahn's The Emerging Japanese Superstate or Ezra Vogel's Japan as
Number One to remember that Japan appeared, to many observers, to be well on its way to global
economic dominance.

Well, it has not happened, at least not so far. Japan has indeed continued to rise in the economic
rankings, but at a far more modest pace than those projections suggested. In 1992 Japan's per capita
income was still only 83 percent of the United States', and its overall output was only 42 percent of the
American level. The reason was that growth from 1973 to 1992 was far slower than in the
high-growth years: GDP grew only 3.7 percent annually, and GDP per capita grew only 3 percent per
year. The United States also experienced a growth slowdown after 1973, but it was not nearly as
drastic.

If one projects those post-1973 growth rates into the future, one still sees a relative Japanese rise, but a
far less dramatic one. Following 1973-92 trends, Japan's per capita income will outstrip that of the
United States in 2002; its overall output does not exceed America's until the year 2047. Even this
probably overestimates Japanese prospects. Japanese economists generally believe that their country's
rate of growth of potential output, the rate that it will be able to sustain once it has taken up the slack
left by the recession, is now no more than three percent. And that rate is achieved only through a very
high rate of investment, nearly twice as high a share of GDP as in the United States. When one takes
into account the growing evidence for at least a modest acceleration of U.S. productivity growth in the
last few years, one ends up with the probable conclusion that Japanese efficiency is gaining on that of
the United States at a snail's pace, if at all, and there is the distinct possibility that per capita income in
Japan may never overtake that in America. In other words, Japan is not quite as overwhelming an
example of economic prowess as is sometimes thought, and in any case Japan's experience has much
less in common with that of other Asian nations than is generally imagined.

THE CHINA SYNDROME

For the skeptic, the case of China poses much greater difficulties about Asian destiny than that of
Japan. Although China is still a very poor country, its population is so huge that it will become a
major economic power if it achieves even a fraction of Western productivity levels. And China, unlike
Japan, has in recent years posted truly impressive rates of economic growth. What about its future
prospects?

Accounting for China's boom is difficult for both practical and philosophical reasons. The practical
problem is that while we know that China is growing very rapidly, the quality of the numbers is
extremely poor. It was recently revealed that official Chinese statistics on foreign investment have
been overstated by as much as a factor of six. The reason was that the government offers tax and
regulatory incentives to foreign investors, providing an incentive for domestic entrepreneurs to invent
fictitious foreign partners or to work through foreign fronts. This episode hardly inspires confidence in
any other statistic that emanates from that dynamic but awesomely corrupt society.

The philosophical problem is that it is unclear what year to use as a baseline. If one measures Chinese
growth from the point at which it made a decisive turn toward the market, say 1978, there is little
question that there has been dramatic improvement in efficiency as well as rapid growth in inputs. But
it is hardly surprising that a major recovery in economic efficiency occurred as the country emerged
from the chaos of Mao Zedong's later years. If one instead measures growth from before the Cultural
Revolution, say 1964, the picture looks more like the East Asian "tigers": only modest growth in
efficiency, with most growth driven by inputs. This calculation, however, also seems unfair: one is
weighing down the buoyant performance of Chinese capitalism with the leaden performance of
Chinese socialism. Perhaps we should simply split the difference: guess that some, but not all, of the
efficiency gains since the turn toward the market represent a one-time recovery, while the rest
represent a sustainable trend.

Even a modest slowing in China's growth will change the geopolitical outlook substantially. The
World Bank estimates that the Chinese economy is currently about 40 percent as large as that of the
United States. Suppose that the U. S. economy continues to grow at 2.5 percent each year. If China
can continue to grow at 10 percent annually. by the year 2010 its economy will be a third larger than
ours. But if Chinese growth is only a more realistic 7 percent, its GDP will be only 82 percent of that
of the United States. There will still be a substantial shift of the world's economic center of gravity,
but it will be far less drastic than many people now imagine.

THE MYSTERY THAT WASN'T

The extraordinary record of economic growth in the newly industrializing countries of East Asia has
powerfully influenced the conventional wisdom about both economic policy and geopolitics. Many,
perhaps most, writers on the global economy now take it for granted that the success of these
economies demonstrates three propositions. First, there is a major diffusion of world technology in
progress, and Western nations are losing their traditional advantage. Second, the world's economic
center of gravity will inevitably shift to the Asian nations of the western Pacific. Third, in what is
perhaps a minority view, Asian successes demonstrate the superiority of economies with fewer civil
liberties and more planning than we in the West have been willing to accept.
All three conclusions are called into question by the simple observation that the remarkable record of
East Asian growth has been matched by input growth so rapid that Asian economic growth, incredibly,
ceases to be a mystery.

Consider first the assertion that the advanced countries are losing their technological advantage. A
heavy majority of recent tracts on the world economy have taken it as self-evident that technology
now increasingly flows across borders, and that newly industrializing nations are increasingly able to
match the productivity of more established economies. Many writers warn that this diffusion of
technology will place huge strains on Western society as capital flows to the Third World and imports
from those nations undermine the West's industrial base.

There are severe conceptual problems with this scenario even if its initial premise is right.(7) But in
any case, while technology may have diffused within particular industries, the available evidence
provides absolutely no justification for the view that overall world technological gaps are vanishing.
On the contrary, Kim and Lau find "no apparent convergence between the technologies" of the newly
industrialized nations and the established industrial powers; Young finds that the rates in the growth of
efficiency in the East Asian "tigers" are no higher than those in many advanced nations.

The absence of any dramatic convergence in technology helps explain what would otherwise be a
puzzle: in spite of a great deal of rhetoric about North-South capital movement, actual capital flows to
developing countries in the 1990s have so far been very small--and they have primarily gone to Latin
America, not East Asia. Indeed, several of the East Asian "tigers" have recently become significant
exporters of capital. This behavior would be extremely odd if these economies, which still pay wages
well below advanced-country levels, were rapidly achieving advanced-country productivity. It is,
however, perfectly reasonable if growth in East Asia has been primarily input-driven, and if the capital
piling up there is beginning to yield diminishing returns.

If growth in East Asia is indeed running into diminishing returns, however, the conventional wisdom
about an Asian-centered world economy needs some rethinking. It would be a mistake to overstate
this case: barring a catastrophic political upheaval, it is likely that growth in East Asia will continue to
outpace growth in the West for the next decade and beyond. But it will not do so at the pace of recent
years. From the perspective of the year 2010, current projections of Asian supremacy extrapolated
from recent trends may well look almost as silly as 1960s-vintage forecasts of Soviet industrial
supremacy did from the perspective of the Brezhnev years.

Finally, the realities of East Asian growth suggest that we may have to unlearn some popular lessons.
It has become common to assert that East Asian economic success demonstrates the fallacy of our
traditional laissez-faire approach to economic policy and that the growth of these economies shows
the effectiveness of sophisticated industrial policies and selective protectionism. Authors such as
James Fallows have asserted that the nations of that region have evolved a common "Asian system,"
whose lessons we ignore at our peril. The extremely diverse institutions and policies of the various
newly industrialized Asian countries, let alone Japan, cannot really be called a common system. But in
any case, if Asian success reflects the benefits of strategic trade and industrial policies, those benefits
should surely be manifested in an unusual and impressive rate of growth in the efficiency of the
economy. And there is no sign of such exceptional efficiency growth.

The newly industrializing countries of the Pacific Rim have received a reward for their extraordinary
mobilization of resources that is no more than what the most boringly conventional economic theory
would lead us to expect. If there is a secret to Asian growth, it is simply deferred gratification, the
willingness to sacrifice current satisfaction for future gain.

That's a hard answer to accept, especially for those American policy intellectuals who recoil from the
dreary task of reducing deficits and raising the national savings rate. But economics is not a dismal
science because the economists like it that way; it is because in the end we must submit to the tyranny
not just of the numbers, but of the logic they express.

1 Hoover's tone--critical of Soviet data but nonetheless accepting the fact of extraordinary
achievement--was typical of much of the commentary of the time (see, for example, a series of articles
in The Atlantic Monthly by Edward Crankshaw, beginning with "Soviet Industry" in the November
1955 issue). Anxiety about the political implications of Soviet growth reached its high-water mark in
1959, the year Khrushchev visited America. Newsweek took Khrushchev's boasts seriously enough to
warn that the Soviet Union might well be "on the high road to economic domination of the world."
And in hearings held by the Joint Economic Committee late that year, CIA Director Allen Dulles
warned, "If the Soviet industrial growth rate persists at eight or nine percent per annum over the next
decade, as is forecast, the gap between our two economies...will be dangerously narrowed."

2 At first, creating an index of all inputs may seem like comparing apples and oranges, that is, trying
to add together noncomparable items like the hours a worker puts in and the cost of the new machine
he uses. How does one determine the weights for the different components? The economists' answer is
to use market returns. If the average worker earns $15 an hour, give each person-hour in the index a
weight of $15; if a machine that costs $100,000 On average earns $10,000 in profits each year (a 10
percent rate of return), then give each such machine a weight of 10,000; and so on.

3 To see why, let's consider a hypothetical example. To keep matters simple, let's assume that the
country has a stationary population and labor force, so that all increases in the investment in
machinery, etc., raise the amount of capital per worker in the country. Let us finally make up some
arbitrary numbers. Specifically, let us assume that initially each worker is equipped with $10,000
worth of equipment; that each worker produces goods and services worth $10,000; and that capital
initially earns a 40 percent rate of return, that is, each $10,000 of machinery earns annual profits of
$4,000.

Suppose, now, that this country consistently invests 20 percent of its output, that is, uses 20 percent of
its income to add to its capital stock. How rapidly will the economy grow?
Initially, very fast indeed. In the first year, the capital stock per worker will rise by 20 percent of
$10,000, that is, by $2,000. At a 40 percent rate of return, that will increase output by $800: an 8
percent rate of growth.

But this high rate of growth will not be sustainable. Consider the situation of the economy by the time
that capital per worker has doubled to $20,000. First, output per worker will not have increased in the
same proportion, because capital stock is only one input. Even with the additions to capital stock up to
that point achieving a 40 percent rate of return, output per worker will have increased only to $14,000.
And the rate of return is also certain to decline--say to 30 or even 25 percent. (One bulldozer added to
a construction project can make a huge difference to productivity. By the time a dozen are on-site, one
more may not make that much difference.) The combination of those factors means that if the
investment share of output is the same, the growth rate will sharply decline. Taking 20 percent of
$14,000 gives us $2,800; at a 30 percent rate of return, this will raise output by only $840, that is,
generate a growth rate of only 6 percent; at a 25 percent rate of return it will generate a growth rate of
only 5 percent. As capital continues to accumulate, the rate of return and hence the rate of growth will
continue to decline.

4 This work was summarized by Raymond Powell, "Economic Growth in the U.S.S.R.," Scientific
American, December 1968.

5 There have been a number of recent efforts to quantify the sources of rapid growth in the Pacific
Rim. Key readings include two papers by Professor Lawrence Lau of Stanford University and his
associate Jong-Il Kim, "The Sources of Growth of the East Asian Newly Industrialized Countries,"
Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 1994, and "The Role of Human Capital in the
Economic Growth of the East Asian Newly Industrialized Countries," mimeo, Stanford University,
1993; and three papers by Professor Alwyn Young, a rising star in growth economics, "A Tale of Two
Cities: Factor Accumulation and Technical Change in Hong Kong and Singapore," NBER
Macroeconomics Annual 1992, MIT Press; "Lessons from the East Asian NICS: A Contrarian View,"
European Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, May 1984; and "The Tyranny of Numbers:
Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth Experience," NBER Working Paper No.
4680, March 1994.

6 These figures are taken from Young, ibid. Although foreign corporations have played an important
role in Singapore's economy, the great bulk of investment in Singapore, as in all of the newly
industrialized East Asian economies, has been financed out of domestic savings.

7 See Paul Krugman, "Does Third World Growth Hurt First World Prosperity?" Harvard Business
Review, July 1984.

Paul Krugman is Professor of Economics at Stanford University. His most recent book is Peddling
Prosperity: Economic Sense and Nonsense in the Age of Diminished Expectations.

You might also like