Week 11 Options4
Week 11 Options4
Week 11 Options4
Guanglian Hu
S1, 2020
Risk management
The state of art measure of option implied volatility exploits the fact
that implied volatility can be inferred from option prices in an
model-free way.
The VIX is a widely watched volatility index that measures the market’s
expectation of 30-day forward volatility implied from options market.
In 1993, the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) developed the
first-ever volatility index, which then was based on the average implied
volatility from at-the-money S&P 100 index options (VXO). The CBOE
provides a historical record of the VXO dating back to 1986.
In 2003, the CBOE changed the methodology used to construct the
volatility index and started publishing a new VIX index, which is calculated
as the weighted average of OTM S&P 500 option prices (VIX). The CBOE
provides a historical record of the VIX dating back to 1990.
Despite the difference in methodology, the two volatility indexes are very
similar (have a correlation about 0.99).
160
VXO
140 VIX
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
1987 1990 1992 1995 1997 2000 2002 2005 2007 2010 2012 2015
150
100
50
-50
-100
1992 1995 1997 2000 2002 2005 2007 2010 2012 2015
Researchers soon realized that not only volatility, but other higher
moments (e.g., skewness and kurtosis) could be extracted from the
options market.
In fact, the entire risk neutral distribution can be inferred from option
prices.
1
0
0
.
.
.
0
Let ws be today’s price of such claim. Basic arbitrage arguments dictate
that 0 < ws < 1. The prices of AD securities [w1 , w2 , w3 ,...,wS ] are also
referred to as state prices.
Guanglian Hu S1 2020 S1 2020 12 / 22
Risk Neutral Probabilities and State Prices
Once we know the prices of Arrow Debreu securities, we will be able to price
any risky asset with a random payoff Y :
y1
y2
.
Y =
.
yS
. + y2 . + ..... + yS .
y1
. . .
. . .
0 0 1
Guanglian Hu S1 2020 S1 2020 13 / 22
Risk Neutral Probabilities and State Prices
We can also use AD securities to infer the price of a risk-less bond (B) that
pay off $1 regardless of which state occurs.
S
X
B= ws
1
Let
ws
π̃s = (2)
B
Note that π̃s have all of the properties of probabilities: 0 < π̃s < 1 and
S
1 π̃s = 1.
P
Observe from equation (2) and equation (1) on the previous slide, we can
rewrite the price of Y as
S S
X ws X
p=B ys = B π̃s ys
B
1 1
Lastly, using B = 1
1 + rf , we have
S
1 X
p= π̃s ys
1 + rf
1
Note that
S
1 X
p 6= πs ys
1 + rf
1
In this set-up, we can break the payoffs or cash flows of any risky
asset down ’state-by-state’, and then pricing it as a bundle of AD
securities.
State prices can be inferred from prices of call options with different strikes.
Denote the vector of payoffs of a European call option on the market with a
strike price of X as C(X); its price today will be denoted as c(X)
1 0 1
1 1 0
1 1 0
. − . = .
. . .
. . .
1 1 0
Suppose the prices of calls are c(0) = $1.7, c (1) = $0.8, and c (2) =
$0.1
Also, the price of a riskless discount bond paying $1.00 would be $0.2
+ $0.6 + $0.1 = $0.9
Just like other derivatives, options can be used to lock in future price
today and therefore they can be used to reduce the ”risk” or
”uncertainty”.
For example, an airline company can buy a call option on jet fuel to
hedge price fluctuations in jet fuel.