Limit of A Function
Limit of A Function
Limit of A Function
Limit of a function
3.1. Introduction
Value expected of a function by looking its values at nearby points.
3.1.1 Examples:
1
(i) f (x) = , x 6= 1 What do you think could be a suitable value for
x−1
x − 1? On the right of 1, x − 1 0 and as you approach 1, x − 1 becomes
smaller and smaller,so the graph comes closer to the line x − 1.
figure 32
53
54 3. Limit of a function
3.3.2 Examples:
(i) All constant functions are continuous.
(ii) All linear functions are continuous.
(iii) All polynomial functions are continuous.
3.3.3 Discontinuities of a function: Geometrically,discontinuity at a point
means there is a break in the graph of the function.The type of discontinuities
of function can have are the following:
(i) Essential discontinuity:
(ii) Jump discontinuity:
(iii) Removable discontinuity:
56 3. Limit of a function
cumulative sales for all except the last day of the month
A 2, 60, 000/ =
B 1, 85, 000/ =
C 60, 000/ =
What do you think the three will be doing on the last day. For A, since he
has already crossed the mark of 20, 00, 000, and got the bonus, additional work
for last day will not make a significant change in his earnings for that month. So
he may not work on the last day. Similarly, for C, he possibly cannot expect to
make sales for Rs.1, 40, 000/ = in a day to claim bonus. So he may also decide
not to work. Only for B, it is close to the critical figure of 2, 00, 000/ = and
hence he will (possible) try to work in the last day.
Example 3(Salary with commission and bonus):
Consider the earnings of a sales executive of a firm: He gets a fixed pay of Rs.
3.3. Continuous functions 57
8, 000/ = per month and commission of 10% of the sales, plus an additional
bonus of Rs.500/ = if he does sales more than or equal to Rs.2, 00, 000/ =.Then
his total take home earnings (p), as a function of sales(s) is given by
10
8000 + 100 s if s < 2, 00, 000/ =
p(s) = 10
8000 + 100 s + 500 if s ≥ 2, 00, 000/ = .
figure 33
Executive Sales
A 2, 60, 000/ =
B 1, 80, 000/ =
C 60, 000/ =
What do you think they will be doing on the last day of the month? Most
probably A and C will not work for different reasons. Only B may work to meet
the target of 2, 00, 000/ = .
Marginal of a function: The concept of marginal of a function plays an
important role in analyzing the decision making problems in the short run when
it is possible to alter an input. Marginal of a function y = f (x) is defined as the
result on the output y for an additional unit of the input x. The idea is that for
an increase in unit input, the output change is small(marginal). The marginal
of a function is again a function (of x). For example, consider the input-output
function given by
y = 2x.
When x is say the labor employed. The above suggests that if we increase the
labor input by unit, then the output will double. Thus the marginal of the out-
put function is the constant function, M p(x) = 2, for every x. However notice
that more output is generated even for large inputs of labor. This seems con-
tradictory(if all other input remain fixed.) In fact, one would expect that larger
inputs of labor should reduce output and may become zero or even negative.
This suggest that marginal should not be modelled as continuous function.
Example 4(Income support programme):In a social security setup the gov-
ernment decides to give a non-employment allowance of Rs.700/ = per month
to all unemployed adults. However, the allowance is stopped if the person starts
58 3. Limit of a function
earning. Let us suppose an individual can earn Rs.20/ = per hour. Then the
earnings is given by
700 if x = 0.
E(x) =
20x if x > 0.
figure 34
Thus to earn Rs.700/ = he has to work for 35 hours. Why he should work
at all??
Modification: The Government takes 50% of his earnings and the person is
allowed to keep 50% of his earnings in addition to the allowance of 700/ = till
he has paid back 700/ = . Suppose he earns Rs. 20/ = per hour. To pay back
700/ = he has to work for
0.5 × 20 × x = 700.
700
x = × 2 = 70.
20
figure 35
3.3. Continuous functions 59
figure 36
figure 37
Next, suppose that the company makes a profit of Rs.1000/ = per cycle(not
including labor costs.) The wage per worker is Rs.30/ = per hour for any
weekday shift and Rs.60/ = per hour for weekend shift. The company decides
to have weekend shifts only in case it wants to produce more cycles per week
than it can using weekday shifts only. Let Π(y) denote the profit earned per
week as a function of y, the number of cycles produced per week.
This function Π(y) can be found as follows: First from the given data the
number of cycles produced by one worker per hour is given by:
No. of cycles produced per hour
Total number of workers
100 1
= = car per hour.
2000 20
Thus, a worker has to work for 20 hours to produce a car. If the worker
works on weekdays i.e., at the rate of Rs. 30/ = per hour, the cost of producing
a cycle is 20 × 30 = Rs.600/ = . Thus, the net profit per car is
1000 − 600 = Rs.400/ = per car.
So,
Π(y) = 400y, y being the cycles produced per week.
3.4. Special properties of continuous functions 61
If the company decides to work on weekends also, then profit will be as follows:
The labor cost for producing a cycle (in 20 hours), on weekends will be
Rs.60 × 20 = 1200/ = .
Thus the profit to such cars i.e., for y > 12000, will be (1000 − 1200)(y − 12000).
Further, the maximum capacity of the plant is 24 × 7 × 100 = 16, 800/ = . Thus,
the net profit function is:
400y for 0 < y ≤ 12, 000.
Π(y) =
400y + (1000 − 1200)(y − 12000) for 12000 < y < 16800.
i.e. 200y + 24000.
figure 38
figure 39
3.4.3 Example: Let the demand and supply functions of a commodity be given
by (as a function of price):
D(p) = 100 − 2p
S(p) = 3p.
Then the price p0 where demand equals supply is called the equilibrium
price pe of the commodity. In this case, solve the above equations to get:
D(pe ) = S(pe ),
i.e.,100 − 2pe = 3pe ,
i.e.,pe = 20.
figure 40
Note at pe ,
D(pe ) = 100 − 40 = 60.
S(pe ) = 3 × 20 = 60.
Another way of solving above is to look at
f (p) = D(p) − S(p) = 100 − 5p,
and observing 0 = f (pe ) gives pe = 20. In general, it may not be that easy,as
D(p), S(p) may not be linear. However the equilibrium price is that value pe for
which
f (pe ) = D(pe ) − S(pe ) = 0.
Thus, how to ensure that there is at least one value of p for which f (p) =
D(pe ) − S(pe ) = 0. This will be so if f is continuous, f (p1 ) > 0 for some p1 and
f (p2 ) < 0 for some p2 .
3.4. Special properties of continuous functions 63
figure 41
(9.5) For the following functions, show that the indicated limit does not exist
(i)
|x|
lim
x→0 x
(ii)
3
lim
x→0 x − 4
(iii)
1
x − 4 if x ≤ 4
lim
x→0 1
if x > 4
x
(9.6) Consider a production function of a product with input L :
Q(L) = bL, L > 0.
Let w be the unit input price. Write the cost function and the profit function.
Discuss their continuity properties.
(9.7) A sales person earns a basic monthly salary of Rs.800/ =, plus commission
at the rate of 15% of his monthly sales and bonus of Rs1000/ = if his sales
exceeds by Rs.10, 000/ = in that month. He is also given a super bonus of
Rs.2, 500/ = if his monthly sales exceeds Rs.15, 000/ = . Write the income
function of sales and analyze its continuity.
Chapter 4
Differentiation
4.1. Introduction
In economics,most of the time one is concerned with analyzing say, how change
in price affect its production, or how the change in supply of a commodity affect
its price, or the change in price affects the revenue of a company and so on. We
saw earlier that when a variable y is related to x by a linear relation: y = mx+c,
the rate of change at any point x = x0 , is same and is given by m, the slop of the
linear relation. In general, given y = f (x), we want to know what measures the
change in y with respect to change in x at a point x = x0 . Intuitively, if x changes
from x0 to x0 + ∆x and y changes from y0 = f (x0 ) to y0 + ∆y = f (x0 + ∆x),
then proportion of this change is represented by
f (x0 + ∆x) − f (x0 ) ∆y
= .
(x0 + ∆x) − x0 ∆x
To find the rate of change at x0 let ∆x → 0. This motivates our next definition.
4.1.1 Definition:
Let f : (a, b) → R be a function and c ∈ (a, b). The function f is said to be
differentiable at c if
f (c + h) − f (c)
limh→0
h
exists. In that case the above limit is denoted by
df (c)
f ′ (c) or
dx
and is called the derivative of f at x = c.
4.1.2 Note:
(i) For c ∈ (a, b), there exists some δ > 0 such that c ∈ (c−δ, c+δ) ⊆ (a, b).
Then for 0 < |h| < δ,
(c + h) − f (c)
φ(h) :=
h
65
66 4. Differentiation
4.1.3 Examples:
f (x + h) − f (x) (x + h)2 − x2
=
h h
x2 + 2hx + h2 − x2
=
h
= 2x + h
Thus,
f (x + c) − f (x)
limh→0 = limh→0 (2x + h)
h
= 2x.
Hence,
d 2
(x ) = 2x ∀x.
dx
To compute derivatives of more functions the following results are useful.
4.1.4 Theorem: Let f, g : (a, b) → R and c ∈ (a, b). Let f and g be differentiable
at x = c. Then,the following holds:
(i) Let φ(x) = 3x2 +5x+2. Then, using the above theorem,φ′ (x) = 6x+5.
4.1. Introduction 67
x3
(ii) Let φ(x) = 2x2 +5 . Then by quotient rule,
2x2 + 5)(3x2 ) − x3 (4x + 5)
φ′ (x) =
(2x2 + 5)2 .
6x4 + 15x2 − 4x4 − 5x3
=
(2x2 + 5)2 .
2x4 − 5x3 + 15x2
=
(2x2 + 5)2 .
(iii) Consider the power function
f (x) = xn for any n ∈ Z
Then, f (x) is differentiable ∀x if n ∈ N and f ′ (x) = nxn−1 .
For n = 0, f (x) ≡ 1 and hence is differentiable with f ′ (x) = 0∀x.
For n < 0, f (x) is differentiable for x 6= 0 with f ′ (x) = nxn−1 .
(i) Recall, we had defined the exponential function with natural base: x →
exp(x), x ∈ R. This function is unique:
d
(exp(x)) = exp(x)∀x.
d(x)
(ii) Derivative of inverse function: If f is one-one onto and is differ-
entiable at a point x = c with f ′ (c) 6= 0, then the inverse function f − 1
is differentiable at d = f (c) with derivative: (f − 1)(d) = f ′1(c) . As an
application of this theorem, the function ln (x), being the inverse of the
exponential function, is differentiable at every d = exp(c) > 0, with
1 1 1
(ln )′ (d) = d = = .
dx (exp(x) x=c exp(c) d
Thus,(ln )′ (x) = x1 ∀x > 0.
(iii) Since the exponential function ax , a > 0, a 6= 1, can be written as
ax = exp(xln a),
by chain rule, it is differentiable with
d n
(a ) = exp(xln a) × ln (a) = ln (a)ax .
dx
(iv) Finally, the function loga (x) being the inverse of the function ax , for
d = ac ,
d 1
(loga (x)) x=d = d y y=c .
dx dy (a )
1
=
ln (a)ay y = c
ac
= .
ln (a)
(v) For the function a ∈ R fixed, the function y = xa , x > 0, is called the
1 dy a
power function.Since ln (y) = aln (x) we have · = .
y dx x
dy ay axa
Thus, = = = axa−1 .
dx x x
figure 42
Thus,
f (x0 + h) − f (x0 ) = hf ′ (x0 ) − P C.
Note that P C → 0 as h → 0. Thus, we can say that
f (x0 + h) − f (x0 ) ∼
= hf ′ (x0 ).
i.e.,
f (x0 + h) ∼
= f (x0 ) + hf ′ (x0 ).
This is called the linear approximation to f (x0 +h). Another way to represent
this is
f (x0 + h) − f (x) ∼ ′
= f (x0 ).
h
In particular, for h = 1 unit change in input, the change in output is approxi-
mately given by f ′ (x0 ). This motivates the next definition.
Find a relation between his tax T and his pre-tax income (x). Find the mar-
ginal tax-rate? Find the average tax-rate of an individual with pre-tax earn-
ings (i)1000, (ii) 2000.
(10.3) Let the post tax-earning y and pre tax earnings be related by
y = a + bx.
Find the marginal tax-rate. Under what conditions, the marginal tax rate will
be equal to average tax-rate for all values of x ?
(10.4) Let a firm’s total cost C be a function of Q, the quantity produced, and
be given by
C(Q) = Q3 − 4Q2 + 12Q.
Find the average cost and the marginal cost. When is AC = M C? If the cost
function changes to
C(Q) = Q3 − 4Q2 + 12Q + 10,
what effect it has on AC, M C ?
(10.5) If the average cost is a function f (Q) of the total quantity produced, write
relation for the total cost and compute the marginal cost. Find the conditions
when the average cost will be same as marginal cost.
(10.6) The demand function of a certain product is such that the total amount
received in sales is always same, regardless of the quantity sold. Write the
functional relation between demand and the price and calculate the elasticity
of demand for this.
(10.7) Find the income elasticity of Q, the demand Q for the following functions
relating demand to income y, by:
(i) Q = 4y − 1.
(ii) Q = ay + b.
(iii) Q = ay b .
Analyze the behavior of elasticity as income changes in the above.
(10.8) Let demand (Q) and price (P ) be related by P = 60 − 0.5Q.
(i) Express ǫd purely in terms of P and then in terms of Q.
(ii) Calculate ǫd when Q = 100
(iii) Calculate the demand when ǫd = −1.5 and p = 200.
(10.9) Compute the derivative function for the following:
(i) f (x) = 9x − 6.
(ii) f (x) = 6x4 .
(iii) f (x) = x8 + 8x3 + 2.
(iv) f (x) = −2x−4 .
(10.10) Compute derivatives of the following:
(i) f (x) = (2x5 + 6)(x3 − 3).
2
(ii) f (x) = 5x +2
x2 +1 .
(iii) f (x) = (7x3 + 1)5 .
(10.11) Show that the function f (x) = |x| is not differentiable at x = 0. Is it
differentiable at x = 1?
Chapter 5
Optimization
for some δ > 0. Similarly, a point c ∈ (a, b) is called a point of local minimum
if
f (c) ≤ f (x)∀x ∈ (c − δ, c + δ)for someδ > 0.
5.1.2 Example:
Thus,
f ′ (x) ≥ 0 if (x + 2) ≥ 0 and (x − 1) ≥ 0,
i.e., x ≥ −2 and x ≥ 1.
Hence, f ′ (x) ≥ 0 if x ≥ 1.
Similarly,
71
72 5. Optimization
figure 43
f ′ (x) ≥ 0 if (x + 2) ≤ 0 and (x − 1) ≤ 0,
i.e., x ≤ −2 and x ≤ 1.
Hence, f ′ (x) ≥ 0 if x ≤ −2.
Thus,the regions where f ′ (x) ≥ 0 are (−∞, −2) ∪ (1, ∞). These are the
regions where f (x) is increasing. Similarly, f ′ (x) ≤ 0, if either (x + 2) ≥ 0
and (x − 1) ≤ 0 or (x + 2) ≤ 0. Thus, f ′ (x) ≤ 0 if x ≥ −2 and x ≤ 1 i.e.,
the interval (−2, 1) and if x ≤ −2 and x ≥ 1, which is not possible.Hence,
f ′ (x) ≤ 0∀x ∈ (−2, 1), i.e.,this is interval where f is decreasing.
Note, f ′ (x) = 0, if x = −2 or x = 1. The point x = −2 is a point of local
maxima and x = 1 is a point of local minima.
figure 44
5.2. Marginal propensities 73
5.2.1 Definition:
The relationship between consumption and income: C = f (y), y is called the
consumption function.
5.2.2 Definition:
The rate of change of C with respect to y is called the marginal of consump-
tion (or marginal propensity to consume) and is given by
dC
M P C(y) = .
dy
Using the approximation given by the derivative,
△C
M P C(y) ∼
= .
△y
This is interpreted as saying that the marginal propensity to consume is ap-
proximately the change in consumption due to unit increase in income. Suppose
the income is used up in consumption and savings:
y = C(y) + S(y).
Then, differentiating, we get
dC dS
1= + = M P C + M P S, (∗)
dS dy
where M P S = dSdy is called the marginal propensity to save. Once again, using
linear approximations
△S dS
≃ = M P S.
△y dy
The relation (*) can be used to find MPC or MPS if either is known.
5.2.3 Example:
Let the consumption as a function of income be given by
C = 0.005y 2 + 0.3y + 20
Then,
dC
MPC = = 2 × 0.005 × y + 0.3
dy
74 5. Optimization
figure 45
5.2.8 Example: (a) Given a perfectly competitive firm with P = 20, find the
marginal and average revenues ? Ans: MR = AR = P = 20. (b)In a monopolist
firm, with P = 50 − 2Q. Find the marginal and average revenues ? Ans: TR =
PQ =(500 − 2Q)Q = 50Q − 2Q2 . MR = d(T R)
dQ = 50 − 2 × 2Q = 50 − 4Q. AR =
P = 50 − 2Q.
TC
5.2.9 Relation between average cost and marginal cost: AC = Q ⇒
T C = AC × Q. Thus,
d AC
MC = (AC × Q) = Qd + AC.
dQ dQ
30
5.2.10 Example: Let AC = 2Q + 5 + Q. Then, TC = 2Q2 + 5Q + 30. MC =
2 × 2Q + 5 = 4Q + 5.
Exercise :Optimization)
(11.1) Find the local max./min. and global max./min. if any of the following
functions:
(i) f (x) = x3 − 3.
(ii) f (x) = x2 + 2x + 1.
3x
(iii) f (x) = 2 .
x +1
1
(iv) f (x) = x + .
x
76 5. Optimization
Thus,
abP b
dQ P P
ǫd (P ) = = (abP b−1 )( )= = b.
dP Q Q aP b
5.3.3 Note: For such a product, total revenue as a function of price is given by
T R(Total revenue) = P Q = aP b+1
Thus, marginal of revenue as a function of price is given by
d(T R)
MR = = a(b + 1)P b .
dP
Conclusions:
1
5.3.5 Note: Since P > 0, M R > 0 iff 1 + > 0. i.e.,
ǫd
1 ǫd < −1 if ǫd < 0.
> −1 i.e.,
ǫd or ǫd > 0
Thus, revenue will rise if ǫd < −1 or ǫd > 0.
1 d2 Q M PL − APL
1
= 2
− − 2 (M PL − APL ).
L dL L L
Thus, at L = L0 , M PL = APL implies
d2 (APL ) 1 d2 Q
= .
dL L dL2
5.4.5 Example (Relation between marginal revenue and marginal cost):
The total cost of a product is a function of Q, the quantity produced and is
given by
T C(Q) = F C + V C(Q)Q.
d(T C)
The marginal cost is M C = . Π(Q) Profit(Q) = TR(Q)-TC(Q). Thus,
dQ
marginal of profit is
dΠ(Q) d(T R) d(T C)
M P (Q) = = (Q) − (Q).
dQ dQ dQ
d(Π)
If Π(Q) is maximum at Q = Q0 , then (Q) = 0. i.e., at Q0 , the point of
dQ
maximum profit
d(T R) d(T C)
0 = M R(Q0 ) = (Q0 ) = (Q0 ).
dQ dQ
Some relations at points of maximum/minimum:
(1) Total profit Π = T R − T C. Then,
d(Π) d(T R)
= − d(T C)dQ = M R − M C.
dQ dQ
(a) If at point Q0 , Π is maximum, then,
d(Π)
MR − MC = = 0 ⇒ M R − M C.
dQ
(b) If M R > M C ⇒ Π ↑, M R < M C ⇒ Π ↓
d(AC) d(T C
(2) TC= AC
Q AC=Q.TC dQ =Q dQ +TC.
MAC=MTC
5.4.6 Example: The cost of building x floors in an office block requires the
following:
• The cost of the land Rs.18, 00, 000/ = .
• The cost per floor Rs.2, 00, 000/ = .
• The cost rise per floor Rs.20, 000x.
How many floors should be constructed so that the average cost per floor is
minimum ?