A Handbook of Environmental Management PDF
A Handbook of Environmental Management PDF
A Handbook of Environmental Management PDF
MANAGEMENT
A Handbook of
Environmental Management
Edited by
Jon C. Lovett
Professor of Sustainable Development in a North South
Perspective, University of Twente, The Netherlands and
former Director, Centre for Ecology, Law and Policy,
University of York, UK
David G. Ockwell
Lecturer in Geography and Fellow, Sussex Energy Group and
Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research, University of
Sussex, UK
Edward Elgar
Cheltenham, UK • Northampton, MA, USA
© Jon C. Lovett and David G. Ockwell 2010
Published by
Edward Elgar Publishing Limited
The Lypiatts
15 Lansdown Road
Cheltenham
Glos GL50 2JA
UK
1 Introduction 1
Jon C. Lovett and David G. Ockwell
2 Global biodiversity conservation priorities: an expanded review 8
Thomas M. Brooks, Russell A. Mittermeier, Gustavo A.B. da
Fonseca, Justin Gerlach, Mike Hoffmann, John F. Lamoreux,
Cristina G. Mittermeier, John D. Pilgrim and Ana S.L. Rodrigues
3 Integrated conservation and development projects: a positive
role for forest conservation in tropical Africa? 30
Neil Burgess, David Thomas, Shakim Mhagama,
Thomas Lehmberg, Jenny Springer and Jonathan Barnard
4 Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 75
Tom M. van Rensburg and Greig A. Mill
5 How do institutions affect the management of environmental
resources? 119
Bhim Adhikari
6 Analysing dominant policy perspectives – the role of discourse
analysis 168
David G. Ockwell and Yvonne Rydin
7 Theoretical perspectives on international environmental
regime effectiveness: a case study of the Mediterranean Action
Plan 198
Sofia Frantzi
8 The price of fish and the value of seagrass beds:
socioeconomic aspects of the seagrass fishery on Quirimba
Island, Mozambique 241
Fiona R. Gell
9 The link between ecological and social paradigms and the
sustainability of environmental management: a case study
of semi-arid Tanzania 282
Claire H. Quinn and David G. Ockwell
10 Exploring game theory as a tool for mapping strategic
interactions in common pool resource scenarios 309
Vanessa Pérez-Cirera
v
vi A handbook of environmental management
Index 431
Contributors
vii
viii A handbook of environmental management
1
2 A handbook of environmental management
References
Hardin, G. (1968), ‘The tragedy of the commons’, Science, 162(3859), 1243–8.
Leach, M. and R. Mearns (1996), The Lie of the Land. Challenging Received Wisdom on the
African Environment, Oxford, UK: James Currey.
Ockwell, D.G. (2008), ‘“Opening up” policy to reflexive appraisal: a role for Q Methodology?
A case study of fire management in Cape York, Australia’, Policy Sciences, 41(4), 263–92.
Ockwell, D. and Y. Rydin (2006), ‘Conflicting discourses of knowledge: understanding the
policy adoption of pro-burning knowledge claims in Cape York Peninsula, Australia’,
Environmental Politics, 15(3), 379–98.
Snow, C.P. (1998), The Two Cultures, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
2. Global biodiversity conservation
priorities: an expanded review1
Thomas M. Brooks, Russell A. Mittermeier,
Gustavo A.B. da Fonseca, Justin Gerlach,
Mike Hoffmann, John F. Lamoreux,
Cristina G. Mittermeier, John D. Pilgrim and
Ana S.L. Rodrigues2
8
Global biodiversity conservation priorities 9
Note: For each proposal, we note primary references, definitions paraphrased from the
primary references, maps from the primary references except for Global 200 ecoregions
(Olson and Dinerstein, 2002) and biodiversity hotspots (Mittermeier et al., 2004) for which
more recent maps are available, and secondary references in square brackets. The Global
200 ecoregions also include 53 freshwater and 43 marine ecoregions, not mapped.
800
CE BH EBA
700
CPD MC G200
600
Number of citations
HBWA FF LW
500
400
300
200
100
0
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Year
Note: Codes as in Figure 2.1. Growth measured by number of citations (in parentheses)
of the primary (most cited) reference for each global conservation prioritization recorded
in the Web of Science (accessed 23 December 2009, searching comprehensively using ‘Cited
Reference Search’).
EBA, CPD
Irreplaceability
Irreplaceability
BH MC, G200
HBWA
FF CE
LW
Vulnerability Vulnerability
Note: Codes as in Figure 2.1. (A) Purely reactive (prioritizing high vulnerability) and
purely proactive (prioritizing low vulnerability) approaches. (B) Approaches that do not
incorporate vulnerability as a criterion (all prioritize high irreplaceability).
Measures of irreplaceability
Six of the nine templates of global conservation priority incorporate irre-
placeability – measures of spatial conservation options (Margules and
Pressey 2000; Pressey and Taffs, 2001). The most common measure of irre-
placeability is plant (WWF and IUCN, 1994–97; Mittermeier et al., 1997,
12 A handbook of environmental management
2003b; Myers et al., 2000) or bird (Stattersfield et al., 1998) endemism, often
supported by terrestrial vertebrate endemism overall (Mittermeier et al.,
1997, 2003b; Myers et al., 2000). The logic for this is that the more endem-
ics a region holds, the more biodiversity is lost if that region is lost (even
if anywhere holding even one endemic is irreplaceable in a strict sense). In
addition to numbers of endemic species, other aspects of irreplaceability
have been proposed including taxonomic uniqueness, unusual phenomena
and global rarity of major habitat types (Olson and Dinerstein, 1998), but
these remain difficult to quantify. Despite the fact that species richness
within a given area is sometimes assumed to be important in prioritization
(Prendergast et al., 1993), none of the approaches rely on species richness
alone. This is because species richness is driven by common, widespread
species, thus strategies focused on species richness tend to miss exactly
those biodiversity features most in need of conservation (Orme et al., 2005;
Possingham and Wilson, 2005; Lamoreux et al., 2006). Three approaches
do not incorporate irreplaceability (Bryant et al., 1997; Sanderson et al.,
2002; Hoekstra et al., 2005).
The choice of measures of irreplaceability is to some degree subjective,
in that data limitations currently preclude the measurement of biodiver-
sity wholesale. Further, these same data constraints have meant that, with
the exception of endemic bird areas (Stattersfield et al., 1998), the meas-
ures of irreplaceability used in global conservation prioritization have
necessarily been derived from specialist opinion. Subsequent tests of plant
endemism estimates (Krupnick and Kress, 2003) have proven this expert
opinion to be quite accurate. However, reliance on specialist opinion
means that results cannot be replicated, raising questions concerning the
transparency of the approaches (Humphries, 2000; Mace et al., 2000). It
also prevents formal measurement of irreplaceability, which requires the
identities of individual biodiversity features, such as species names, rather
than just estimates of their magnitude expressed as a number (Balmford,
et al., 2000; Humphries, 2000; Mace et al., 2000; Brummitt and Lughadha,
2003).
Measures of vulnerability
Five of the templates of global conservation priority incorporate
vulnerability – measures of temporal conservation options (Margules and
Pressey, 2000; Pressey and Taffs, 2001). A recent classification of vulner-
ability (Wilson et al., 2005) recognizes four types of measures based on:
environmental and spatial variables; land tenure; threatened species; and
expert opinion. Of these, environmental and spatial variables have been
used most frequently in global conservation prioritization, measured as
proportionate habitat loss (Myers et al., 2000; Sanderson et al., 2002;
Global biodiversity conservation priorities 13
Spatial units
The spatial units most commonly used in systematic conservation planning
are equal-area grids. However, data limitations have precluded their use
in the development of actual templates of global biodiversity conservation
priority to date. Instead, all proposals, with the exception of megadiver-
sity countries (Mittermeier et al., 1997), are based on biogeographic units.
Typically, these units are defined a priori by specialist perception of the
distribution of biodiversity. For example, ‘ecoregions’, one of the most
commonly used such classifications, are ‘relatively large units of land
containing a distinct assemblage of natural communities and species’
14 A handbook of environmental management
(Olson et al., 2001, p. 933). Only in the endemic bird areas approach are
biogeographic units defined a posteriori by the distributions of the species
concerned (Stattersfield et al., 1998). Relative to equal-area grids, biogeo-
graphic units bring advantages of ecological relevance, while megadiver-
sity countries (Mittermeier et al., 1997) bring political relevance.
However, reliance on biogeographic spatial units raises several compli-
cations. Various competing bioregional classifications are in use (Jepson
and Whittaker, 2002), with the choice of system having considerable
repercussions for resulting conservation priorities (Pressey and Logan,
1994). Further, when unequally sized units are employed, priority may be
biased towards large areas as a consequence of species–area relationships.
Assessment of global conservation priorities should, therefore, factor out
area, either by taking residuals about a best-fit line to a plot of species
against area (Balmford and Long, 1995; Brooks et al., 2002; Werner and
Buszko, 2005; Lamoreux et al., 2006) or by rescaling numbers of endemics
using a power function directly (Veech, 2000; Brummitt and Lughadha,
2003; Hobohm, 2003; Ovadia, 2003). Nevertheless, use of a priori bio-
regional units for global conservation prioritization will be essential until
data of sufficient resolution become available to enable the use of grids.
Spatial patterns
In Figure 2.4, we map the overlay of the global biodiversity conservation
priority systems into geographic space from the conceptual framework
of Figure 2.3. Figure 2.4A illustrates the large degree of overlap between
templates that prioritize highly vulnerable regions of high irreplace-
ability: tropical islands and mountains (including montane Mesoamerica,
the Andes, the Brazilian Atlantic forest, Madagascar, montane Africa,
the Western Ghats of India, Malaysia, Indonesia, the Philippines and
Hawaii), Mediterranean-type systems (including California, central Chile,
coastal South Africa, south-west Australia and the Mediterranean itself),
and a few temperate forests (the Caucasus, the central Asian mountains,
the Himalaya and south-west China). Highly vulnerable regions of lower
irreplaceability (generally, the rest of the northern temperate regions)
are prioritized by fewer approaches. Figure 2.4B shows a large amount
of overlap between templates for regions of low vulnerability but high
irreplaceability, in particular the three major tropical rainforests of
Amazonia, the Congo and New Guinea. Regions of simultaneously lower
vulnerability and irreplaceability, such as the boreal forests of Canada and
Russia, and the deserts of western USA and central Asia are prioritized
less often.
Two general observations are apparent. First, most land (79 per
cent) is highlighted by at least one of the prioritization systems. Second,
Global biodiversity conservation priorities 15
Note: (A) Reactive approaches, corresponding to the right-hand side of Figure 2.3A,
that prioritize regions of high threat and those that do not incorporate vulnerability as a
criterion (Figure 2.3B); the latter are only mapped where they overlap with the former. (B)
Proactive approaches, corresponding to the left-hand side of Figure 2.3A, that prioritize
regions of low threat and those that do not incorporate vulnerability as a criterion (Figure
2.3B); again, the latter are only mapped where they overlap with the former. Shading
denotes number of global biodiversity conservation prioritization templates, in both cases.
Crisis ecoregions
Biodiversity
hotspots
Endemic bird
areas
Centres of plant
diversity
Megadiversity
countries
Global 200
ecoregions
High-biodiversity
wilderness areas
Frontier forests
Last of the wild
% land area 30 16 10 9 35 37 8 9 24
§ §
Crisis ecoregions 33* 14 10 44 36 2 1 4§
18
High
ability
vulner-
Biodiversity hotspots 61* 33* 21* 46* 78* 0§ 5 6§
Endemic bird areas 43* 50* 24* 68* 70* 7 11 11§
Centres of plant diversity 34 40* 28* 48* 66* 18* 14 21
Megadiversity countries 38 21 19* 12 53* 18* 11 24
Global 200 ecoregions 28 33* 19* 15* 49* 16* 16* 28
High irreplaceability
High-biodiversity wilderness areas 6§ 0§ 15 19* 79* 72* 41* 53*
§ §
Frontier forests 4 8 11 13 39 64* 35* 73*
Low
§ §
Last of the wild 5 4 4 7 34 43 17* 28*
vulnerability
Note: Cells show the percentage overlap of the approach in a given row by the approach in the corresponding column. The three blocks of cells
outlined in bold correspond to overlaps between approaches within three categories, indicated in the bars on the left: reactive approaches, those
prioritizing high irreplaceability and proactive approaches. Significance was tested against overlap expected based on the percentage of the land
area covered by each approach, using a chi-squared test (P = 0.05; * significantly greater overlap than expected; § significantly less overlap than
expected). There are many significant overlaps between approaches within each of the three categories: those prioritizing highly vulnerable regions
19
(2/2 overlaps significantly more than expected), those prioritizing irreplaceable regions (24/30), and those prioritizing regions of low vulnerability
(6/6). The opposite is true when comparing approaches prioritizing vulnerable regions with those prioritizing regions of low vulnerability (11/12
overlaps significantly less than expected). The approaches that incorporate irreplaceability almost all show significantly more overlap than
expected with and by at least four other systems. In contrast, those that do not incorporate irreplaceability only overlap significantly more than
expected with or by three other approaches at the most.
20 A handbook of environmental management
Note: Global conservation prioritization templates have been based almost exclusively
on bioregional classification and specialist opinion, rather than primary biodiversity data.
Such primary datasets have recently started to become available under the umbrella of the
IUCN Species Survival Commission (Baillie et al., 2004), and they allow progressive testing
and refinement of templates. (A) Global gap analysis of coverage of 11 633 mammal, bird,
turtle and amphibian species (~40% of terrestrial vertebrates) in protected areas (Rodrigues
et al., 2004b). It shows unprotected half-degree grid cells characterized simultaneously by
irreplaceability values of at least 0.9 on a scale of 0–1, and of the top 5% of values of an
extinction risk indicator based on the presence of globally threatened species (Rodrigues
et al., 2004a). (B) Priorities for the conservation of 6269 African plant species (~2% of
vascular plants) across a 1-degree grid (Küper et al., 2004). These are the 125 grid cells with
the highest product of range-size rarity (a surrogate for irreplaceability) of plant species
distributions and mean human footprint (Sanderson et al., 2002). Comparison of these two
maps, and between them and Figure 2.4, reveals a striking similarity among conservation
priorities identified using independent datasets. The difference in taxonomic and geographic
coverage between A and B also highlights the challenge facing the botanical community
to compile comprehensive primary data on plant conservation in order to inform global
conservation prioritization (Callmander et al., 2005). Rectifying this is part of the Global
Strategy for Plant Conservation of the Convention on Biological Diversity.
Notes
1. This chapter is an expanded version of Brooks et al. (2006), ‘Global biodiversity conser-
vation priorities’, Science, 313(5783), 58–61, originally published by AAAS.
2. We thank G. Fabregas, D. Knox, T. Lacher, P. Langhammer, N. Myers, A. Sugden and
W. Turner for help with the manuscript, anonymous peer reviewers for comments, the
Gordon and Betty Moore Foundation for funding, D. Ockwell and J. Lovett for the invi-
tation for this contribution and for editorial help, and AAAS for permission to reprint
this expanded version of our original review paper.
References
Araújo, M.B. (2002), ‘Biodiversity hotspots and zones of ecological transition’, Conservation
Biology, 16(6), 1662–3.
Baillie, J.E.M., L.A. Bennun, T.M. Brooks, S.H.M. Butchart, J.S. Chanson, Z. Cokeliss, C.
Hilton-Taylor, M. Hoffmann, G.M. Mace, S.A. Mainka, C.M. Pollock, A.S.L. Rodrigues,
A.J. Stattersfield and S.N. Stuart (2004), A Global Species Assessment, Gland, Switzerland:
IUCN – International Union for Conservation of Nature.
Balmford, A. and A. Long (1994), ‘Avian endemism and forest loss’, Nature, 372(6507), 623–4.
Balmford, A. and A. Long (1995), ‘Across-country analyses of biodiversity congruence and
current conservation effort in the tropics’, Conservation Biology, 9(16), 1539–47.
24 A handbook of environmental management
Balmford, A. and T. Whitten (2003), ‘Who should pay for tropical conservation, and how
could the costs be met?’, Oryx, 37(2), 238–50.
Balmford, A., K.J. Gaston, A.S.L. Rodrigues and A. James (2000), ‘Integrating costs of con-
servation into international priority setting’, Conservation Biology, 14(3), 597–605.
Balmford, A., J. Moore, T. Brooks, N. Burgess, L.A. Hansen, P. Williams and C. Rahbek
(2001), ‘Conservation conflicts across Africa’, Science, 291(5513), 2616–19.
Balmford, A., G.J. Gaston, S. Blyth, A. James and V. Kapos (2003), ‘Global variation in
conservation costs, conservation benefits, and unmet conservation needs’, Proceedings of
the National Academy of Sciences of the U.S.A., 100(3), 1046–50.
Balmford, A., L. Bennun, B. ten Brink, D. Cooper, I. Côté, P. Crane, A. Dobson, N.
Dudley, I. Dutton, R.E. Green, R.D. Gregory, J. Harrison, E.T. Kennedy, C. Kremen,
N. Leader-Williams, T.E. Lovejoy, G. Mace, R. May, P. Mayaux, P. Morling, J. Phillips,
K. Redford, T.H. Ricketts, J.P. Rodriguez, M. Sanjayan, P.J. Schei, A.S. van Jaarsveld
and B.A. Walther (2005), ‘The Convention on Biological Diversity’s 2010 target’, Science,
307(5707), 212–13.
BirdLife International (2004), State of the World’s Birds 2004, Cambridge, UK: BirdLife
International.
Briggs, J.C. (2002), ‘Coral reef biodiversity and conservation’, Science, 296(5570), 1027.
Brooks, T.M., R.A. Mittermeier, C.G. Mittermeier, G.A.B. da Fonseca, A.B. Rylands,
W.R. Konstant, P. Flick, J. Pilgrim, S. Oldfield, G. Magin and C. Hilton-Taylor (2002),
‘Habitat loss and extinction in the hotspots of biodiversity’, Conservation Biology, 16(4),
909–23.
Brooks, T.M., J.D. Pilgrim, A.S.L. Rodrigues and G.A.B. da Fonseca (2005), ‘Conservation
status and geographic distribution of avian evolutionary history’, in A. Purvis, J.L.
Gittleman and T.M. Brooks (eds), Phylogeny and Conservation, Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press, pp. 267–94.
Brooks, T.M., R.A. Mittermeier, G.A.B. da Fonseca, J. Gerlach, M. Hoffmann, J.F.
Lamoreux, C.G. Mittermeier, J.D. Pilgrim and A.S.L. Rodrigues (2006), ‘Global biodi-
versity conservation priorities’, Science, 313(5783), 58–61.
Brummitt, N. and E.N. Lughadha (2003), ‘Biodiversity: where’s hot and where’s not?’,
Conservation Biology, 17(5), 1442–8.
Bryant, D., D. Nielsen and L. Tangley (1997), Last Frontier Forests: Ecosystems and
Economies on the Edge, Washington DC: World Resources Institute.
Burgess, N.D., C. Rahbek, F.W. Larsen, P. Williams and A. Balmford (2002), ‘How much
of the vertebrate diversity of sub-Saharan Africa is catered for by recent conservation
proposals?’, Biological Conservation, 107(33), 327–39.
Callmander, M.W., G.E. Schatz and P.P. Lowry II (2005), ‘IUCN Red List assessment and
the Global Strategy for Plant Conservation: taxonomists must act now’, Taxon, 54(4),
1047–50.
Cardillo, M., G.M. Mace, J.L. Gittleman and A. Purvis (2006), ‘Latent extinction risk and
the future battlegrounds of mammal conservation’, Proceedings of the National Academy
of Sciences of the U.S.A., 103(11), 4157–61.
Ceballos, G., P.R. Ehrlich, J. Soberón, I. Salazar and J.P. Fay (2005), ‘Global mammal con-
servation: what must we manage?’, Science, 309(5734), 603–7.
Cincotta, R.P., J. Wisnewski and R. Engelman (2000), ‘Human population in the biodiver-
sity hotspots’, Nature, 404(6781), 990–92.
Cowling, R.M., R.L. Pressey, M. Rouget and A.T. Lombard (2003), ‘A conservation plan
for a global biodiversity hotspot – the Cape Floristic Region, South Africa’, Biological
Conservation, 112(1–2), 191–216.
Crosby, M.J. (1994), ‘Mapping the distributions of restricted-range birds to identify global
conservation priorities’, in R.I. Miller (ed.), Mapping the Diversity of Nature, London:
Chapman and Hall, pp. 145–54.
Dalton, R. (2000), ‘Biodiversity cash aimed at hotspots’, Nature, 406(6798), 818.
Darwall, W., K. Smith, T. Lowe and J.-C. Vié (2005), The Status and Distribution of
Freshwater Biodiversity in Eastern Africa, Gland, Switzerland: IUCN.
Global biodiversity conservation priorities 25
Kelly, C.K. and T.R.E. Southwood (1999), ‘Species richness and resource availability: a phy-
logenetic analysis of insects associated with trees’, Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences of the U.S.A., 96(14), 8013–16.
Krupnick, G.A. and W.J. Kress (2003), ‘Hotspots and ecoregions: a test of conservation
priorities using taxonomic data’, Biodiversity and Conservation, 12(11), 2237–53.
Kunich, J.C. (2001), ‘Preserving the womb of the unknown species with hotspots legislation’,
Hastings Law Journal, 52(16), 1149–1253.
Küper, W., J.H. Sommer, J.C. Lovett, J. Mutke, H.P. Linder, H.J. Beentje, R.S.A.R. Van
Rompaey, C. Chatelain, M. Sosef and W. Barthlott (2004), ‘Africa’s hotspots of biodiver-
sity redefined’, Annals of the Missouri Botanical Garden, 91(4), 525–35.
Lamoreux, J.F., J.C. Morrison, T.H. Ricketts, D.M. Olson, E. Dinerstein, M.W. McKnight
and H.H. Shugart (2006), ‘Global tests of biodiversity concordance and the importance of
endemism’, Nature, 440(7082), 212–14.
Liu, J., D.C. Daily, P.R. Ehrlich and G.W. Luck (2003), ‘Effects of household dynamics on
resource consumption and biodiversity’, Nature, 421(6922), 530–33.
Long, A.J., M.J. Crosby, A.J. Stattersfield and D.C. Wege (1996), ‘Towards a global map
of biodiversity: patterns in the distribution of restricted-range birds’, Global Ecology and
Biogeography Letters, 5(4–5), 281–304.
Loreau, M., S. Naeem, P. Inchausti, J. Bengtsson, J.P. Grime, A. Hector, D.U. Hooper, M.A.
Huston, D. Raffaelli, B. Schmid, D. Tilman and D.A. Wardle (2001), ‘Biodiversity and eco-
system functioning: current knowledge and future challenges’, Science, 294(5543), 804–8.
Mace, G.M., A. Balmford, L. Boitani, G. Cowlishaw, A.P. Dobson, D.P. Faith, K.J.
Gaston, C.J. Humphries, R.I. Vane-Wright, P.H. Williams, J.H. Lawton, C.R. Margules,
R.M. May, A.O. Nicholls, H.P. Possingham, C. Rahbek and A.S. van Jaarsveld (2000),
‘It’s time to work together and stop duplicating conservation efforts. . .’, Nature,
405(6785), 393.
Margules, C.R. and R.L. Pressey (2000), ‘Systematic conservation planning’, Nature,
405(6783), 243–53.
McAllister, D.E., A.L. Hamilton and B. Harvey (1997), ‘Global freshwater biodiversity:
striving for the integrity of freshwater ecosystems’, Sea Wind, 11(2), 1–106.
McClean, C.J., N. Doswald, W. Küper, J.H. Sommer, P. Barnard and J.C. Lovett (2006),
‘Potential impacts of climate change on sub-Saharan Africa plant priority area selection’,
Diversity and Distributions, 12(16), 645–55.
Midgley, G.F., L. Hannah, R. Roberts, D.J. MacDonald and J. Allsopp (2001), ‘Have
Pleistocene climatic cycles influenced species richness patterns in the Greater Cape
Mediterranean Region?’, Journal of Mediterranean Ecology, 2(2), 137–44.
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005), Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Biodiversity
Synthesis, Washington DC: World Resources Institute.
Mittermeier, R.A. (1988), ‘Primate diversity and the tropical forest’, in E.O. Wilson (ed.),
BioDiversity, Washington DC: National Academy Press, pp. 145–54.
Mittermeier, R.A., P. Robles Gil and C.G. Mittermeier (1997), Megadiversity, Mexico:
CEMEX.
Mittermeier, R.A., N. Myers, J.B. Thomsen, G.A.B. da Fonseca and S. Olivieri (1998),
‘Biodiversity hotspots and major tropical wilderness areas: approaches to setting conserva-
tion priorities’, Conservation Biology, 12(3), 516–20.
Mittermeier, R.A., N. Myers, P. Robles Gil and C.G. Mittermeier (1999), Hotspots, Mexico:
CEMEX.
Mittermeier, R.A., C.G. Mittermeier, P. Robles Gil, J.D. Pilgrim, W.R. Konstant, G.A.B.
da Fonseca and T.M. Brooks (2002), Wilderness: Earth’s Last Wild Places, Mexico:
CEMEX.
Mittermeier, R.A., G.A.B. da Fonseca, T. Brooks, J. Pilgrim and A. Rodrigues (2003a),
‘Hotspots and coldspots’, American Scientist, 91(5), 384.
Mittermeier, R.A., C.G. Mittermeier, T.M. Brooks, J.D. Pilgrim, W.R. Konstant, G.A.B. da
Fonseca and C. Kormos (2003b), ‘Wilderness and biodiversity conservation’, Proceedings
of the National Academy of Sciences of the U.S.A., 100(18), 10309–10313.
Global biodiversity conservation priorities 27
Price, A.R.G. (2002), ‘Simultaneous “hotspots” and “coldspots” of marine biodiversity and
implications for global conservation’, Marine Ecology Progress Series, 241, 23–7.
Redford, K.H., P. Coppolillo, E.W. Sanderson, G.A.B. da Fonseca, E. Dinerstein,
C. Groves, G. Mace, S. Maginnis, R.A. Mittermeier, R. Noss, D. Olson, J.G. Robinson,
A. Vedder and M. Wright (2003), ‘Mapping the conservation landscape’, Conservation
Biology, 17(1), 116–31.
Reid, W.V. (1998), ‘Biodiversity hotspots’, Trends in Ecology and Evolution, 13(7), 275–80.
Ricketts, T.H., E. Dinerstein, T. Boucher, T.M. Brooks, S.H.M. Butchart, M. Hoffmann,
J.F. Lamoreux, J. Morrison, M. Parr, J.D. Pilgrim, A.S.L. Rodrigues, W. Sechrest, G.E.
Wallace, K. Berlin, J. Bielby, N.D. Burgess, D.R. Church, N. Cox, D. Knox, C. Loucks,
G.W. Luck, L.L. Master, R. Moore, R. Naidoo, R. Ridgely, G.E. Schatz, G. Shire, H.
Strand, W. Wettengel and E. Wikramanayake (2005), ‘Pinpointing and preventing immi-
nent extinctions’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the U.S.A., 102(51),
18497–18501.
Roberts, C.M., C.J. McClean, J.E.N. Veron, J.P. Hawkins, G.R. Allen, D.E. McAllister,
C.G. Mittermeier, F.W. Schueler, M. Spalding, F. Wells, C. Vynne and T.B. Werner
(2002), ‘Marine biodiversity hotspots and conservation priorities for tropical reefs’,
Science, 295(5558), 1280–84.
Rodrigues, A.S.L., H.R. Akçakaya, S.J. Andelman, M.I. Bakarr, L. Boitani, T.M. Brooks,
J.S. Chanson, L.D.C. Fishpool, G.A.B. da Fonseca, K.J. Gaston, M. Hoffmann, P.A.
Marquet, J.D. Pilgrim, R.L. Pressey, J. Schipper, W. Sechrest, S.N. Stuart, L.G. Underhill,
R.W. Waller, M.E.J. Watts and X. Yan (2004a), ‘Global gap analysis – priority regions for
expanding the global protected area network’, BioScience, 54(12), 1092–1100.
Rodrigues, A.S.L., S.J. Andelman, M.I. Bakarr, L. Boitani, T.M. Brooks, R.M. Cowling,
L.D.C. Fishpool, G.A.B. da Fonseca, K.J. Gaston, M. Hoffmann, J.S. Long, P.A.
Marquet, J.D. Pilgrim, R.L. Pressey, J. Schipper, W. Sechrest, S.N. Stuart, L.G. Underhill,
R.W. Waller, M.E.J. Watts and X. Yan (2004b), ‘Effectiveness of the global protected area
network in representing species diversity’, Nature, 428(6983), 640–43.
Sanderson, E.W., M. Jaiteh, M.A. Levy, K.H. Redford, A.V. Wannebo and G. Woolmer
(2002), ‘The human footprint and the last of the wild’, BioScience, 52, 891–904.
Sarkar, S. (1999), ‘Wilderness preservation and biodiversity conservation – keeping divergent
goals distinct’, BioScience, 49(5), 405–12.
Schmidt, K. (1996), ‘Rare habitats vie for protection’, Science, 274(5289), 916–18.
Sechrest, W., T.M. Brooks, G.A.B. da Fonseca, W.R. Konstant, R.A. Mittermeier, A. Purvis,
A.B. Rylands and J.L. Gittleman (2002), ‘Hotspots and the conservation of evolutionary
history’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the U.S.A., 99(4), 2067–71.
Shi, H., A. Singh, S. Kant, Z. Zhu and E. Waller (2005), ‘Integrating habitat status, human
population pressure, and protection status into biodiversity conservation priority setting’,
Conservation Biology, 19(4), 1273–85.
Sisk, T.D., A.E. Launer, K.R. Switky and P.R. Ehrlich (1994), ‘Identifying extinction
threats’, BioScience, 44(9), 592–604.
Smith, R.J., R.D.J. Muir, M.J. Walpole, A. Balmford and N. Leader-Williams (2003),
‘Governance and the loss of biodiversity’, Nature, 426(6962), 67–70.
Smith, T.B., R.K. Wayne, D.J. Girman and M.W. Bruford (1997), ‘A role for ecotones in
generating rainforest biodiversity’, Science, 276(5320), 1855–7.
Smith, T.B., S. Kark, C.J. Schneider, R.K. Wayne and C. Moritz (2001), ‘Biodiversity
hotspots and beyond: the need for preserving environmental transitions’, Trends in
Ecology and Evolution, 16(8), 431.
Spector, S. (2002), ‘Biogeographic crossroads as priority areas for biodiversity conservation’,
Conservation Biology, 16(6), 1480–87.
Stattersfield, A.J., M.J. Crosby, A.J. Long and D.C. Wege (1998), Endemic Bird Areas of the
World: Priorities for Biodiversity Conservation, Cambridge, UK: BirdLife International.
Stuart, S.N., J.S. Chanson, N.A. Cox, B.E. Young, A.S.L. Rodrigues, D.L. Fischman and
R.W. Waller (2004), ‘Status and trends of amphibian declines and extinctions worldwide’,
Science, 306(5695), 1783–6.
Global biodiversity conservation priorities 29
Supriatna, J. (2001), ‘All sectors of society must work together to save biodiversity’, Nature,
410(6824), 14.
Thomas, C.D., A. Cameron, R.E. Green, M. Bakkenes, L.J. Beaumont, Y.C. Collingham,
B.F.N. Erasmus, M. Ferreira de Siqueira, A. Grainger, L. Hannah, B. Huntley, A.S. van
Jaarsveld, G.F. Midgley, L. Miles, M.A. Ortega-Huerta, A.T. Peterson, O.L. Phillips and
S.E. Williams (2004), ‘Extinction risk from climate change’, Nature, 427(6970), 145–8.
Veech, J.A. (2000), ‘Choice of species–area function affects identification of hotspots’,
Conservation Biology, 14(1), 140–47.
Veech, J.A. (2003), ‘Incorporating socioeconomic factors into the analysis of biodiversity
hotspots’, Applied Geography, 23(1), 73–88.
Werner, U. and J. Buszko (2005), ‘Detecting hotspots using species–area and endemics–area
relationships: the case of butterflies’, Biodiversity and Conservation, 14(8), 1977–88.
Whittaker, R.J., M.B. Araújo, P. Jepson, R.J. Ladle, J.E.M. Watson and K.J. Willis (2005),
‘Conservation biogeography: assessment and prospect’, Diversity and Distributions, 11(1),
3–23.
Wilson, K.A., R.L. Pressey, A. Newton, M. Burgman, H. Possingham and C. Weston (2005),
‘Measuring and incorporating vulnerability into conservation planning’, Environmental
Management, 35(5), 527–34.
Wilson, K.A., M. McBride, M. Bode and H.P. Possingham (2006), ‘Prioritizing global con-
servation efforts’, Nature, 440(7082), 337–340.
WWF and IUCN (1994–97), Centres of Plant Diversity: A Guide and Strategy for their
Conservation, Gland, Switzerland: WWF and IUCN.
3. Integrated conservation and development
projects: a positive role for forest
conservation in tropical Africa?1
Neil Burgess, David Thomas,
Shakim Mhagama, Thomas Lehmberg,
Jenny Springer and Jonathan Barnard
Background
A debate has been going on for a number of years on the best ways to
achieve conservation in Africa (and elsewhere). Two elements of the
debate involve those espousing ‘fortress conservation’ and those promot-
ing ‘people-focused conservation’. In some circles this debate has become
highly polarized, with a considerable divide on the best ways to achieve
conservation opening between biologists (Spinage, 1996, 1998; Kramer et
al., 1997; Oates, 1999; Attwell and Cotterill, 2000; Bruner et al., 2000) and
social scientists (Grove, 1995; Neumann, 1996, 1998; Borrini-Feyerabend
and Buchan, 1997; Ghimire and Pimbert, 1997; Hackel, 1999; Leach et
al., 2002). However, for those involved with implementing conservation
projects on the ground in the developing world, the polarized views often
represent impractical extremes. Moreover, for the people living in the
rural areas of developing countries, the divide between ‘development’
and ‘conservation’ is often quite artificial. The third element of the debate
involves attempts to merge human development and wildlife conservation
issues within a single integrated programme, ideally where all sides benefit,
the basis of Integrated Conservation and Development Projects (ICDPs).
These kinds of projects can be considered to fall between ‘fortress conser-
vation’ and ‘sustainable resource use for rural development’. The ICDP
has become one of the dominant approaches to field implementation
of conservation in the developing world over the past 30 years. In this
chapter we look at where ICDPs have come from, what their successes and
failures have been and where they are heading.
30
Integrated conservation and development projects 31
CATEGORIES OF INTERVENTION
Scale is appropriate
Recent discussion has focused on whether the ICDP model only applies
to small sites of isolated habitat, or whether it can be used as a model
Integrated conservation and development projects 35
Activity Benefit
Tree planting Reduces dependence on extraction
from natural forest
Community management Empowers local populations to protect
forest (generally outside reserves)
Agricultural improvement Reduces shifting cultivation, con-
trols soil erosion and reduces loss of
natural forest
Ecotourism Provides a value to the natural forest
resource
Sustainable extraction Provides a value to the natural forest
resource
Small animal husbandry Can reduce hunting pressure in
natural forest (but care has to be
taken to maintain these links)
Alternative incomes Can take pressure from forest (but
care has to be taken to maintain the
beneficial links between the utilization
of the resource and the conservation
of the habitat and species of concern
What is an SDSS?
A decision support software (DSS) can be generally defined as
an interactive computer-based software to help decision-makers
utilize data and models to solve problems. For our purposes, we
further define a DSS to include a spatial (mappable) component,
commonly provided through a GIS. Therefore a spatial decision
support system (SDSS) is a software program that uses a variety
of spatial data and analytical and statistical modelling capabilities
to answer problems in a map or graphic display. Most SDSSs can
be adapted to meet decision-makers’ needs to solve problems,
formulate alternative displays, interpret and select appropriate
implementation options and modify or include new data.
Note: The dark line denotes the boundaries of the river basin that are linked to the
Eastern Arc.
own smaller patches of forest, often for traditional spiritual purposes, and
50 of these villages touch the forest margins (Figure 3.2b). Population
density is somewhat variable, but typically there are high densities of
people up to the borders of the Forest Reserves and in some parts of the
area human populations increase at higher altitudes where the farming
Integrated conservation and development projects 47
Morogoro town
Uluguru North
Forest Reserve
North
20 km
North
Forest
reserves
Village Uluguru South
boundaries Forest Reserve Boundaries between
villages
Ward Roads and tracks
a) boundaries b)
Forest outside the
reserves in this area
has been extensively
converted to banana
plantation
Pitsawing
Fire wood
collection
Commercial
agriculture
Mining for
rubies
c) Roads d)
potential is better (Figure 3.2c). Most people living on the mountains are
poor (Hartley and Kaare, 2001). For an outsider it is quite a daunting
region and a car can only reach a few higher regions of the mountain.
However, for the people of the Ulugurus, paths link nearby villages and
there are paths crossing the mountains to facilitate longer-distance travel-
ling. It is often quicker to walk (or run) over the mountain than it is to
drive around it. Distances are measured in hours of walking.
48 A handbook of environmental management
The focal area for intervention by these projects is the region of highest
forest biodiversity and greatest threats to the forests. Until 2002, this
caused project actions to concentrate in the forest remnants outside
the official government Forest Reserves on the northern end of the
range (Figure 3.2d). The area was heavily forested in 1955 (from aerial
Integrated conservation and development projects 49
Uluguru North
Forest Reserve
Boundary
Uluguru North
Catchment
Forest Reserve
Forest 1955
Tandai Village
Forest 1977
Forest 2000
Note: This area is closely co-incident with that of the focal project area as it is here where
most conflicts between biodiversity conservation and human use of the land occur.
Figure 3.3 Loss of the non-reserved forest outside the Uluguru North
Catchment Forest Reserve, 1955–2000
photographs), but had been largely deforested by 2000, apart from some
remnants (Burgess et al., 2002a; Figure 3.3). The project attempted to
preserve these fragments by building them into the village land use pattern
as ‘Village Forest Reserves’. In the Phase 3 project there will be a greater
spread of interventions around the mountain, both north (DOF/WCST)
and south (GEF/CARE), and more funding for the conservation of the
Forest Reserves that contain the highest levels of biodiversity.
the entire landscape) and the scale of project interventions (Figure 3.2d).
Project interventions were focused in a smaller part of the mountain that
had the greatest problems in terms of forest and biodiversity loss (Figure
3.3), and where there was the highest rate of commercial agriculture and
impact from outside interests. During the design of the third phase of
activities on the mountain, efforts were made to expand activities to cover
the entire landscape. However, funding remains insufficient to fully tackle
the whole area.
There is real local ownership The earliest phases of project input into
the Ulugurus were designed and implemented in collaboration with
regional government partners, who managed the programme as their own.
However, these earlier phases did not adequately involve the people living
around the mountains and apart from studies, training, and some tree
planting efforts, no significant impacts of project interventions were felt in
the villages on the mountain.
The second and third phases of this ICDP engaged with district govern-
ment officers, village governments, farmers’ groups, tree planting groups,
women’s groups and government forestry officers based in the mountains.
By working at these levels the project has found greater resonance with
local people, but has also experienced some problems of ‘partnership’,
especially within the elements being coordinated by CARE. By working at
the local level, the communities agreed to set aside patches of both natural
forest and human-made woodlots as Village Forest Reserves. Towards
the end of the second phase, the project started to work closely with the
traditional chiefs as well as with a broader range of government-appointed
staff in the villages (Figure 3.4). This has further improved the perception
and ownership of project interventions among the local communities, and
has also raised awareness of the project and the conservation issues of
these mountains at the national level. Changes to a more people-focused
approach to forest conservation in the Ulugurus have been facilitated
by the publication of a new Forest Policy (GOT, 1998), Guidelines for
Community-based Forest Management (GOT, 2001), and a new Forest Act
(GOT, 2002). These legal changes provide the mechanisms to empower
local populations to manage forest resources, either in collaboration with
the central government, or alone.
Implementation
2500
Implementation
300
2000
scores
scores 1500 200
1000
100
500
0 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Implementation periods Implementation periods
Output 2.2 January 1999 onwards Output 3.2, January 1999 onwards
Implementation scores
Implementation scores
6 200
5
150
4
3 100
2
50
1
0 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Implementation periods Implementation periods
Output 4.2, June 1999 onwards Output 4.4, January 1999 onwards
600
90
Implementation scores
Implementation scores
500 80
70
400 60
300 50
40
200 30
20
100
10
0 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Implementation periods Implementation periods
Note: Implementation periods refer to six month reporting periods to DANIDA, with
the first reporting period (1) being the baseline when the project started. Scores relate
to a variety of measures easily gathered by the project management, often with several
measures added to produce this index of change. The scheme was not continued for the
full three years of the project phase due to changes in staff and because political changes in
government priorities in Denmark resulted in much additional work for staff in Tanzania.
Explanation of outputs:
Output 1.1 Administration of WCST and skills of its staff enhanced.
Output 2.1 Activities provided to involve Tanzanian members and volunteers in the work
of the Society.
Output 2.2 Training provided to develop skills of members and volunteers as a resource
to promote the work of the Society.
Output 3.2 Uluguru project assists the formulation of agreements between District
Forestry and local people on sustainable uses of the Uluguru Public Land.
Output 4.2 Uluguru project supports sustainable agricultural practices in villages adjacent
to Uluguru Forest Reserves.
Output 4.4 Uluguru project produces written materials to promote its work within
Tanzania and internationally.
Between 1993 and 1995 extensive further studies were undertaken to feed
into the development of further ICDP activities in the Ulugurus (Bhatia
and Ringia, 1996; Bhatia and Buckley, 1998). The results of these studies
were used to design the Phase 2 DANIDA support on this mountain. At
this point a logical framework approach was used to capture the links
between the inputs and outputs of the project, and the ways to measure
conservation achievement. Planning of the Phase 3 project involved
Tanzanian and foreign development experts, social scientists and a series
of consultative meetings with relevant local people living on the mountain
to further refine the series of project interventions (Hartley and Kaare,
2001). A further detailed logical framework was developed, but despite
the increased stakeholder involvement it was quite similar to that from
the second phase. Designing the third phase did, however, highlight the
importance of the traditional leadership on the mountain. The village gov-
ernment that was part of the Tanzanian government structure held some
power, but it was not in charge of land allocation, which passed through
the female line of different clans of the Luguru people. By looking closely
at different stakeholders, the Phase 3 proposals were able to capture the
facts that:
The biggest compromise during the design process from the side of
those wishing to retain the reserves was to agree to explore methods of
collaborative management of the forest resources with forest-adjacent vil-
lages. Devolution of power and authority from district and national gov-
ernment level to village and traditional authorities would be required for
this, and its effective implementation will need a period of negotiation and
formalization through signed agreements (bye-laws). Currently ICDPs on
the Ulugurus have only been gathering experience on the potential ways to
achieve this goal by working in remaining patches of non-reserved forests
to establish Village Forest Reserves. The experience provides some models
that can be applied to the village communities living around the official
government Forest Reserves.
54 A handbook of environmental management
0 100 km Lake
0 10 km
NIGERIA
CHAD
CAR
CAMEROON
KUMBO
ATLANTIC
OCEAN Mt. Oku
EQU L GABON CONGO
GUINEA s
n d
BAMENDA a
l
h
g
i
H
a
d
n
e
m
a
B
KEY
Forest cover
Figure 3.5 Location of forest patches that form part of the Bamenda
Highlands ICDP network, within the geographical extent of
the Cameroon Highlands
Project targets are clearly formulated Over the 19 years that BirdLife
International has been working in the Bamenda Highlands, the plan-
ning mechanisms have been constantly developed. Project interventions
were based on a detailed logical framework that was itself created from
a detailed problem tree developed with project staff and villagers around
the forests.
Detailed logframes and workplans have proved critical tools in the
regular cycle of planning, implementation, monitoring and evaluation, and
have been used in a flexible way, with managers prepared to modify objec-
tives (with the agreement of donors) if circumstances made that appropri-
ate. However, what the full problem tree demonstrates is an immense web
of problems that can only partly be solved by a project approach of fixed
duration (and budget). The Bamenda Highlands project aimed to put in
place a sustainable outcome within the constraints of politics and national
economics (the context – national debt and an underpaid civil service).
These factors are not within a single project’s ability to influence and yet
clearly they significantly affect what can be achieved – and the strategies
that must be put in place to try to accomplish a project’s objectives.
motivated to manage the forest). The project has helped to rebuild the
traditional authority of the fon and kwifon within a parallel and integrated
system of management and control by community-based institutions of
users (FMIs). However, experience shows that government support is still
essential as a back-up and endorsement of FMIs and traditional authority
rules, especially where powerful outside (and internal) interests threaten
to destabilize the situation. For example, the valuable bark of Prunus
africana is illegally exploited by outside gangs that are often armed, and
illegal livestock graziers in the forest enter with the backing of wealthy
and influential livestock owners. This experience suggests that a three-
pronged approach (FMIs–traditional authorities–government) may be the
most effective combination, and that each group has its role to play in an
effective overall protection system.
the process forward (first and foremost) possibly combined with some
form of ‘subsidy’ to enable national government and local communities to
conserve a resource of global significance into the future. As a result the
present project strategy for sustainability is based on achieving sustainable
institutions for the long-term management of the forest. This will work
at three levels – that of community institutions (FMIs), the traditional
authorities and the government. As suggested above in relation to pro-
tection activities, each of these levels needs to work effectively for forest
management to succeed. It was envisaged that these three institutional
elements would be supported financially in the long term through a trust
fund (CAMCOF – CAmeroon Mountains COnservation Foundation) to
support sustainable management and conservation of forests through-
out the Cameroon Highlands, with an initial focus on the Kilum-Ijim
Forest and Mount Cameroon. However, despite considerable investment
from the Global Environment Facility and the UK’s Department for
International Development towards project development, CAMCOF
failed to get the necessary support and the Foundation has been closed.
Sustainable financing for conservation and sustainable use in the region
remain unresolved issues.
Discussion
Looking at our two ICDP examples from the forests of Africa, a number
of issues emerge. First, it is clear that neither of these ICDPs is perfect,
even to those who have been involved with them over a period of years.
In this regard we accept some of the criticisms that the ICDP approach
does not deliver as much conservation or development as some originally
proposed it would. But, both of these projects are working in some of the
least developed regions of the world, where billions of dollars of develop-
ment assistance and the best economists in the world have largely failed to
improve national economic fortunes (UNDP, 2001). We therefore believe
that any conservation successes need to be set in the context of greater
economic failures.
both of these areas, as places for the ancestors to live in. Moreover, in the
Uluguru Mountains of Tanzania the national cash values of the forests in
terms of maintaining water flow to the capital city and most of the nation’s
industry are huge. The appreciation of these values and the development
of systems that capture some of this value and use it for long-term man-
agement, offers one of the best ways to achieve sustainable management
of the forest resources and some assistance to the development of local
human populations.
Ownership
Both of our two example projects illustrate a gradual shift in emphasis from
forest ownership by the national government to a situation where local
people have a role in the management of government-owned reserves (for
example, in the Ulugurus), or more promisingly perhaps where they estab-
lish and manage Village Forest Reserves on their own land and where the
government, or a local NGO, is a facilitating and problem-solving agency.
The legal mechanisms that allow these community approaches to forest
ownership and conservation may provide a boost to forest conservation
efforts more widely across Africa in coming decades. An evolving issue in
development thinking involves attempts to ensure that issues of equity and
rights are considered fully in development projects. This novel thinking,
especially on rights, is likely to become an important aspect of ICDP design
and implementation, especially given the global re-emphasis on solving
some of the fundamental issues of poverty and inequality across the devel-
oping world, especially in Africa. One of the risks of this approach is that
the choices that local people make might not be ones that ‘conservationists’
want, but equally there is a potential for people to reject centralized govern-
ment models (for example, large-scale concessions, clearance for industrial
agriculture – oil palms and so on) and choose their own pathway.
Planning
In our opinion one of the most helpful mechanisms for designing and
managing an ICDP to ensure that it works towards its goals, and has the
chance to periodically review and alter these goals, has been the Logical
Framework Approach (or related planning systems). By building a set
of interventions around solving the environmental (and human develop-
ment) problems in an area, and monitoring these carefully over time, best
practice conservation management can result. However, even in cases
where log frames have been developed, many are poorly formulated and
do not attempt to measure conservation impact – instead they monitor
whether activities are progressing and funding is being used. The major-
ity of ICDPs in operation have this flaw, which is one reason why it has
66 A handbook of environmental management
been easy for them to be criticized – most cannot provide data to answer
what their conservation achievements have been. In this regard we would
endorse exploring ways to measure the pressure/threat to an area and
how it has changed, the state of the system (both biodiversity/habitat and
socioeconomic) and what responses occur (reserves declaration, attitude
changes, activity changes, degradation changes, governance changes and
so forth). If logical frameworks could be used to develop and help main-
tain monitoring programmes that capture information on these broad
areas, this would be a significant step forward. If a sufficiently large sample
of ICDPs were operating similar monitoring schemes then some statisti-
cally analysed conclusions about the success or failure of the ICDP model
might be developed.
Sustainability
Long-term sustainability has rarely been achieved by ICDPs, even those
that have operated for a decade or more. It may be that this model of
project cannot achieve a sustainable end point, especially when working in
developing countries where the economic situation is stagnant and there
are few funds from government or local leaders to support conservation
activities. Solving the macroeconomic problems of many African nations
would enhance the chances of long-term sustainability for projects operat-
ing in poor rural areas. In the absence of economic improvements, working
to establish mechanisms that ensure the supply of modest funding over the
long term, and the availability of reliable and trained staff, may offer the
best chances to reach a sustainable end point. If there are no funds then
good staff will move to other areas, or will start to engage in other activ-
ities to support themselves. If there is too much funding for a known short
period, then people may seek to capitalize on it while it is there.
Neither of our two example ICDPs are close to being economically
sustainable. The models used by these projects have involved significant
sums of money, expatriate support, purchase of transport and fuel, inter-
national travel and some foreign management costs. The local economy
of these areas involves small amounts of money, local decision-making, a
lack of mechanized transport, few income-generating opportunities and
traditional beliefs and norms. In order for the ICDP approach to become
more sustainable it has to become financially, technically and operation-
ally closer to the normality for the areas concerned, which is a serious
challenge using current project implementation models.
Protection components
We endorse the criticism that ICDPs do not expend as much effort as
required on natural resource conservation. Our experience with ICDPs
Integrated conservation and development projects 67
Implementation constraints
Our two example ICDPs, and especially the Uluguru Mountains ICDP
managed by CARE have been dogged by implementation constraints.10
This has affected the efficiency of the projects, and has resulted in some
significant time delays and failures to achieve some of the planned targets.
This issue has already been explored in some detail in the review by Wells
and McShane (2004) where they note that even a well-designed project
can fail because of problems with its implementation strategy – including
problems of obtaining suitable staff, and so on.
Learning components
One general observation is that ICDPs would benefit from a more scien-
tific approach, including designing interventions to test hypotheses about
different kinds of interventions. The learning component of many ICDPs
is generally small and often given a low priority. However, this means that
ICDPs will continue to fail to show what they have achieved, or indicate
what interventions give the best value for money.
Local people can collect much of the data required to monitor conser-
vation impact. This can both simplify the methods, allow local under-
standing of what is required and what the project is trying to achieve, and
also keep costs low (Danielsen et al., 2001). However, as with many other
elements of ICDPs, the data collected by local investigators will need peri-
odic field validation to ensure that standards are maintained. These locally
based methods of monitoring can tell a lot about resource use and man-
agement actions, but they might not satisfy the requirements of conserva-
tion biologists interested in the number of particular species or details of
ecological services. In these cases more professionally based monitoring
may be required, involving trained scientists.
In addition to measuring biological and threat-related measures within
68 A handbook of environmental management
than US$2 per locally based person (assuming around 100 000 people
on the mountain) per annum over eight years. Although this is not a
major financial inducement, it is a more tangible sum than most received
from the project activities. However, we predict that the direct payments
model would be difficult to implement in poor rural communities. The
mechanism of delivering funds would need to be carefully worked out and
monitoring this would require considerable effort – and would therefore
rapidly become expensive. Funds would also need to be available over
the long term if this was the only mechanism employed to conserve the
forests. The direct payment approaches may work best linked to a trust
fund mechanism that provides small funding to local communities over
long periods.
In conclusion, the ICDP model has certainly been challenged in recent
years but we believe that the jury is still out and nothing is yet in place/
proposed that can realistically (proven to) replace it. Few would argue
that it makes sense (moral, practical) to conserve areas that are rich
in biodiversity without involving the people that are living in the area.
Falling back totally on the strict ‘protection’ approach with the exclusion
and marginalization it implies is not a direction most conservationists in
Africa want to take. The integration of conservation at high biodiversity
sites with alleviation of social and economic problems is a goal that has
popular support, but the challenge is to find ways of making it work,
to learn from the successes (and failures) of existing projects and not to
dismiss the approach without proposing viable alternatives backed by
detailed scientific analysis.
Notes
1. BirdLife International managed the Kilum-Ijim Forest Project and Bamenda Highlands
Forest Project in collaboration with the Cameroon Ministry of the Environment and
Forestry and forest-adjacent communities. The projects received funding from the
Global Environment Facility (GEF/UNDP), the UK Community Fund (National
Lottery Charities Board), the British Department for International Development
(DFID) through the Civil Society Challenge Fund, the Joint Funding Scheme
(DFID), the Global Environment Facility (GEF-World Bank) through the Cameroon
Biodiversity Conservation and Management Programme, the Dutch Ministry of
Agriculture, Nature Management and Fisheries through the Programme International
Nature Management (PIN) and WWF Netherlands. Current work at Kilum-Ijim is
funded by the JJ Charitable Trust and the Dutch Ministry of Foreign Affairs.
Conservation Projects in the Uluguru Mountains landscape have been funded
by the European Union, the Royal Society for the Protection of Birds (RSPB), the
Government of Tanzania, Danish International Development Agency (DANIDA),
Dansk Ornitologisk Forening (DOF) and the Wildlife Conservation Society of
Tanzania (WCST), Christian Aid, the Spanish NGO INTERMON and will soon
receive funds from the GEF. We would like to the thank the following Tanzanian staff
from the various parts of government and projects working around the Ulugurus for
their support and assistance: Lameck Noah, Cheyo Mayuma, Elisha Mazengo, Elisa
70 A handbook of environmental management
Pallangyo, Sia Aroko, Phanuel Bwimba, John Mejissa, Eliakim Enos, Ernest Moshi,
Prof. Amon Mattee, Athman Mgumia. The following also collected data in the field in
Tanzania, some of which is used here: Andrew Perkin, Tom Romdal, Marcel Rahner,
Anders Tøttrup, Klaus Tølbøl Sørensen and Olivier Hymas.
2. See http://www.care.org/careswork/projects/TZAO38.asp, accessed 11 August 2009.
3. See http://www.wikipedia.org/wiki/logical_framework_approach, accessed 11 August
2009.
4. See www.ecosystemmarketplace.com, accessed 12 August 2009.
5. See www.africanconservation.com/uluguru, accessed 12 August 2009.
6. See www.easternarc.or.tz for details of the Nature Reserve Process, accessed 12 August
2009.
7. See www.easternarc.or.tz, accessed 12 August 2009.
8. Formerly the Ministry of Environment and Forestry – MINEF.
9. A recent (2003) independent mid-term review of the project wrote that ‘Regarding
general awareness and support for natural resource conservation the work of the past
has paid off. The Northwest Province is without doubt the most conservation minded
in the entire land, and past efforts by the Kilum-Ijim Forest Project and more recently
the Bamenda Highlands Forest Project have contributed immensely to this achieve-
ment through its hard work in the field of Environmental Education. This has been so
successful, that the output may be considered achieved at this point in time. An impres-
sive list of Environmental Education material has been developed and disseminated,
ranging from e.g. 22 000 posters, courses for 60 biology teachers, to 32 newspaper
articles, 25 radio programmes, etc. The conservation constituency is so overwhelmingly
present at all levels of North-western society, that it would not be irresponsible for the
Project to consider winding down its activities in this domain, unless in direct support
of achievement of other outputs, and reallocate the available resources in time, money
and staff to the implementation of other activities’ (Bamenda Highlands Forest Project,
2003, independent mid-term review, BHFP, Cameroon).
10. See progress reports on www.easternarc.or.tz, accessed 13 August 2009.
References
Abbot, J., S.E. Neba and M.W. Khen (1999), ‘Turning our eyes from the forest: the role of
the livelihoods programme at Kilum-Ijim Forest Project, Cameroon in changing attitudes
and behaviour towards forest use and conservation’, Cambridge, UK: unpublished report
to BirdLife International.
Abbot, J.I.O., D.H.L. Thomas, A.A. Gardner, S.A. Neba and M.W. Khen (2001),
‘Understanding the links between conservation and development in the Bamenda
Highlands, Cameroon’, World Development, 29(7), 1115–36.
Adams, W.M. and D. Hulme (2001), ‘If community conservation is the answer in Africa,
what is the question?’, Oryx, 35(3), 193–200.
Alpert, P. (1996), ‘Integrated Conservation and Development Projects: examples from
Africa’, BioScience, 46(11), 845–55.
Anderson, D. and R. Grove (eds) (1987), Conservation in Africa: Peoples, Policies and
Practice, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Ashley, C. and D. Roe (1998), Enhancing Community Involvement in Wildlife Tourism: Issues
and Challenges, London: IIED Wildlife and Development Series No. 11.
Attwell, C.A.M. and F.P.D. Cotterill (2000), ‘Postmodernism and African conservation
science’, Biodiversity and Conservation, 9(5), 559–77.
Barrett, C.B. and P. Arcese (1995), ‘Are Integrated Conservation-Development Projects
(ICDPs) sustainable? On the conservation of large mammals in sub-Saharan Africa’,
World Development, 23(7), 1073–84.
Bhatia, Z. and P. Buckley (1998), ‘The Uluguru Slopes Planning Project: promoting com-
munity involvement in biodiversity conservation’, Journal of East African Natural History
Society, 87(1), 339–49.
Integrated conservation and development projects 71
Bhatia, Z. and O. Ringia (1996), Socio-economic Survey of Selected Villages in the Uluguru
Mountains, Tanzania. Uluguru Slopes Planning Project Report No. 3, Sandy, UK: Royal
Society for the Protection of Birds.
Borrini-Feyerabend, G. and D. Buchan (1997), Beyond Fences. Seeking Social Sustainability
in Conservation. Volume 1: A Process Companion, Gland, Switzerland: IUCN.
Brandon, K. and M. Wells (1992), ‘Planning for people and parks: design dilemmas’, World
Development, 20(4), 557–70.
Brown, M. and B. Wyckoff-Baird (1993), Designing Integrated Conservation and Development
Projects, Washington DC: Biodiversity Support Program.
Bruner, A., R.E. Gullison, R.E. Rice and G.A.B. da Fonseca (2000), ‘Effectiveness of parks
in protecting tropical biodiversity’, Science, 291(5501), 125–8.
Burgess, N.D. and G.P. Clarke (eds) (2000), The Coastal Forests of Eastern Africa, Gland,
Switzerland and Cambridge, UK: IUCN Forest Conservation Programme.
Burgess, N.D., M. Nummelin, J. Fjeldså, K.M. Howell, K. Lukumbuzya, L. Mhando,
P. Phillipson and E. Vanden Berghe (eds) (1998), ‘Biodiversity and conservation of the
Eastern Arc Mountains of Tanzania and Kenya’, Special Issue: Journal of the East African
Natural History Society, 87(1–2), 1–367.
Burgess, N.D., N. Doggart and J.C. Lovett (2002a), ‘The Uluguru Mountains of eastern
Tanzania: the effect of forest loss on biodiversity’, Oryx, 36(2), 140–52.
Burgess, N.D., T. Lehmberg, C. Loucks, J. D’Amico and J. Morrison (2002b), ‘Some aspects
of designing conservation landscapes: with an example from eastern Africa’, in P. Schultz
and D. Noppen (eds), Integrating Conservation and Development with a Landscape
Approach, Copenhagen, Denmark: Environment and Development Network.
Caldecott, J. (1998), Designing Conservation Projects, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press.
Carney, D. (1999), ODI Poverty Brief: Approaches to Sustainable Livelihoods, London:
Overseas Development Institute.
Chambers, R. (1997), Whose Reality Counts? Putting the First Last, London: Intermediate
Technology Publications.
Danielsen, F., D.S. Balete, M.K. Poulsen, M. Enghoff, C.M. Nozawa and A.E. Jensen (2001),
‘A simple system for monitoring biodiversity in protected areas of a developing country’,
in H. Agersnap and M. Funder (eds), Conservation and Development: New Insights
and Lessons Learnt, Copenhagen: Environment and Development Network, pp. 231–
72.
Doggart, N., J. Lovett, B. Mhoro, J. Kiure and N.D. Burgess (2005), ‘Biodiversity surveys in
eleven Forest Reserves in the vicinity of the Uluguru Mountains, eastern Tanzania’, Dar
es Salaam, Tanzania: Wildlife Conservation Society of Tanzania, and Tanzania Forest
Conservation Group, www.easternarc.or.tz, accessed 12 August 2009.
Dubois, O. and J. Lowore (2000), The Journey towards Collaborative Forest Management in
Africa: Lessons Learned and Some Navigational Aids, London: IIED, Forestry and Land
Use Series No. 15.
Ferraro, P.J. and A. Kiss (2002), ‘Direct payments to conserve biodiversity’, Science,
298(5599), 1718.
Fisher, R.J. (1995), Collaborative Management of Forests for Conservation and Development.
Issues in Forest Conservation Series. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN and WWF.
Franks, P. (2001), ‘Poverty and environmental degradation in the context of Integrated
Conservation and Development Projects: what makes an ICDP integrated?’, in
H. Agersnap and M. Funder (eds), Conservation and Development: New Insights and
Lessons Learnt, Copenhagen: Environment and Development Network, pp. 95–104.
Franks, P. and T. Blomley (2004), ‘Fitting ICD into a project framework: A CARE per-
spective’, in T.O. McShane and M.P. Wells (eds), Getting Biodiversity Projects to Work:
Towards More Effective Conservation and Development, New York: Columbia University,
pp. 77–97.
Ghimire, K.B. and M. Pimbert (eds) (1997), Social Change and Conservation, London:
Earthscan.
72 A handbook of environmental management
Govt. of Tanzania (GOT) (1998), Tanzanian Forest Policy, Dar es Salaam, Tanzania:
Division of Forestry and Beekeeping.
Govt. of Tanzania (GOT) (2001), Community-based Forest Management Guidelines, Dar es
Salaam, Tanzania: Division of Forestry and Beekeeping.
Govt. of Tanzania (GOT) (2002), Forest Act, Dar es Salaam, Tanzania: Division of Forestry
and Beekeeping.
Grove, R. (1995), Green Imperialism, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Hackel, J.D. (1999), ‘Community conservation and the future of Africa’s wildlife’,
Conservation Biology, 13(4), 726–34.
Hannah, L. (1992), African People, African Parks: An Evaluation of Development Initiatives
as a Means of Improving Protected Area Conservation in Africa, Washington DC:
Conservation International.
Hartley, D. and S. Kaare (2001), ‘Institutional, policy and livelihoods analysis of communi-
ties adjacent to the Uluguru Mountains Catchment Reserves, Eastern Arc Mountains’,
Dar es Salaam, Tanzania: CARE Tanzania, www.africanconservation.com/uluguru,
accessed 12 August 2009.
Hughes, R. and F. Flintan (2001), Integrated Conservation and Development Experience:
A Review and Bibliography of the ICDP Literature, London: IIED, Biodiversity and
Livelihoods Issues Series No. 3.
Hulme, D. and M. Murphree (1999), ‘Communities, wildlife and the “new conservation” in
Africa’, Journal of International Development, 11(2), 277–86.
Hymas, O. (1999), ‘Bananas in the hills’, MSc dissertation, University College London,
www.africanconservation.com/uluguru, accessed 12 August 2009.
Hymas, O. (2000), ‘Assessment of the remaining forests on the Uluguru Mountains and the
pressures they face, Morogoro, Tanzania: Uluguru Mountains Biodiversity Conservation
Project’, www.africanconservation.com/uluguru, accessed 12 August 2009.
Hymas, O. (2001), ‘People on the hills: an assessment of forest disturbance of the Ulugurus
in relation to access, Morogoro, Tanzania: Uluguru Mountains Biodiversity Conservation
Project’, www.africanconservation.com/uluguru, accessed 12 August 2009.
IIED (1994), Whose Eden? An Overview of Community Approaches to Wildlife Management,
Nottingham, UK: Russell Press.
Jeanrenaud, S. (2002a), ‘Changing people/nature representations in international conserva-
tion projects’, IDCS Bulletin, 33(11), 111–22.
Jeanrenaud, S. (2002b), People-orientated Approaches in Global Conservation: Is the Leopard
Changing its Spots?, London: IIED, Institutionalizing Participation Series.
Kilum-Ijim Forest Project (2002), Report from the Ecological Monitoring Programme,
July 2001–October 2002, Cameroon: Kilum-Ijim Forest Project, BirdLife International/
MINEF.
Kleiman, D.G., R.P. Reading, B.J. Miller, T.W. Clark, J.M. Scott, J. Robinson, M.L.
Wallace, R.J. Cabin and F. Felleman (2000), ‘Improving the evaluation of conservation
programmes’, Conservation Biology, 14(2), 356–65.
Koziell, I. (2000), Diversity not Adversity: Sustaining Livelihoods with Biodiversity, London:
IIED.
Kramer, R., C. van Schaik and J. Johnson (eds) (1997), Last Stand. Protected Areas and
Defense of Tropical Biodiversity, New York and Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Kremen, C., A.M. Merenlender and D.D. Murphy (1994), ‘Ecological monitoring: a vital
need for Integrated Conservation and Development Programs in the tropics’, Conservation
Biology, 8(2), 388–97.
Larson, P.S., M. Freudenberger and B. Wyckoff-Baird (1998), WWF Integrated Conservation
and Development Project: Ten Lessons from the Field 1985–1996, Washington DC: WWF.
Leach, M., J. Fairhead and K. Amanor (eds) (2002), ‘Science and the policy process: perspec-
tives from the forest’, IDS Bulletin, 33(1), 1–126.
Leader-Williams, N., J.A. Kayera and G.L. Overton (1996), Community-based Conservation
in Tanzania, Gland, Switzerland and Cambridge, UK: IUCN.
Lovett, J.C. and T. Pócs (1993), Assessment of the Condition of the Catchment Forest
Integrated conservation and development projects 73
Introduction
Biodiversity conservation has emerged as one of the most important and
controversial global environmental issues in recent years (UNEP, 1995).
First, it has been suggested that we are on the verge of mass extinctions,
the like of which have not been observed in the fossil record (Wilson,
1985). Second, it is argued that biodiversity loss matters because it is of
fundamental importance to human society. It provides food, shelter, fuel,
supports recreation and tourism and is thought to play an important part
in global life support and in the functioning of ecosystems (Lindberg,
1991; Raven et al., 1992; Brown et al., 1994).
A decline in habitat is thought to be one of the most significant causes
of the loss in terrestrial biodiversity (Wilson, 1985). A large proportion
of the earth’s fertile land has been converted into managed agricultural,
forest and urban landscape. Recent estimates by the FAO (2004) indicate
that some 38 per cent of land globally is now utilized for agriculture. One
solution proposed by ecologists is to expand reserves and protected areas.
However, there are a number of problems with this approach: protected
areas cover a limited area – approximately 11 per cent of the earth’s
surface (WRI, 2005); protected areas generally exclude economic activities
and they can impose costs on land managers and prevent future economic
opportunities from taking place. Consequently, it is unlikely that the pro-
portion of land allocated to protected areas will be sufficient to maintain
all biodiversity.
In recent years a number of studies indicate that biodiversity conserva-
tion must focus on managed human-dominated ecosystems (Miller, 1996;
Reid, 1996; Daily et al., 2001; Rosenzweig, 2003; Polasky et al., 2005).
Economically valuable managed landscapes do not necessarily have to
exclude biodiversity conservation goals. A wide range of species occur in
the presence of human activities and much of the world’s biodiversity is
found in human-dominated ecosystems (Pimmental et al., 1992). Instead
of threatening biodiversity, many managed systems may actually enhance
biodiversity because of, rather than in spite of, the day-to-day manage-
ment activities carried out by land managers. Indeed, the phenomenon
75
76 A handbook of environmental management
However, millions of species have not even been identified let alone evalu-
ated for their potential values to humans. There are difficulties in predict-
ing which species will be important in the future since the present functions
performed by a species may provide no clues as to its role when environ-
mental conditions change (Main, 1982; Lovejoy, 1988). Tree species that
colonize gaps in tropical forests and species that require fire to enhance
germination provide such examples. The population of Cactoblastis
cactorum, which is relatively rare in Australia today, would not provide
an accurate description of its importance in controlling Opuntia in that
country in previous decades. However, studies on ecosystem function may
reveal clues as to the most sensitive components of food webs, and nutri-
ent and energy flows. Research reveals that the most sensitive components
of ecosystems are those in which the number of species performing a
particular function is thought to be very small (Schindler, 1990).
Most ecologists recognize that some species play a more important
functional role than others. But what does this imply in terms of the prop-
erties of an ecosystem? Land managers are principally concerned with
ecosystem productivity and its variability. The next section provides a
review of the relationship between biodiversity and the stability, resilience
and productivity of ecosystems.
200 A
180
160
220 B
200
180
Plant biomass (g/m2)
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
0 1 2 3 4 5
Functional diversity
(number of functional groups added)
Note: Curves shown are simple asymptotic functions fitted to treatment means.
50
Species richness
40
(no. sp./4 m2)
30
20
10
height and above-ground biomass of all three species. Some studies in the
UK report a high number of seedlings within fenced enclosures compared
with unfenced areas (Sykes and Horrill, 1979; Marrs and Welch, 1991;
Staines, 1995). Historical records have also been used that suggest that
deer may prevent natural regeneration of Scots pine (Pinus silvestris) in
the United Kingdom. With respect to stocking densities, studies inves-
tigating the impact of ungulates foraging on upland heaths in Scotland
suggest that red deer (Cervus elaphus) at stocking densities of .1 deer/20
ha can prevent tree regeneration (Staines et al., 1995).
Persistent high levels of disturbance are also thought to affect ecosystem
function, particularly where these eliminate important functional groups
that affect ecosystem processes. Groups of grass species may be significant
in maintaining the productivity of savanna ecosystems (Walker et al.,
1981). Walker et al. found that grasslands with persistent intensive grazing
by settled peasant farmers had lower levels of productivity than moderate
opportunistic grazing practices employed by nomadic pastoralists. In the
former case, productive functional groups declined because herbivores
showed a preference for the most palatable species, whilst in the latter
case these preferred species were able to persist in the sward and adapt to
change and instabilities caused by grazing and drought, thereby maintain-
ing structural resilience.
Overgrazing may exacerbate the high inter-annual variation in produc-
tivity on many rangelands. Walker (1988) has observed a much higher
phenological diversity in semi-arid systems not subject to heavy grazing
compared with those that are intensively grazed. On lightly grazed areas
he noted an even mix of early, mid- and late season grasses that were
able to respond to rainfall wherever it occurred in the season. Heavy
grazing leads to an absence of highly palatable early season species that
are replaced by later growing species (Silva, 1987). The implication being
that forage production was lower and more unstable on heavily grazed
areas compared with lightly grazed land because the sward was not able
to respond to early season rains. In the Serengeti, McNaughton (1985)
has also shown that forage production was more stable where the number
of species contributing to biomass was high compared with swards where
relatively few species contributed to forage production.
Many complex ecosystems that aim to maximize heterogeneity (such as
non-equilibrium systems) may be threatened by intensive grazing regimes
that attempt to restrict livestock movements. This may have a negative
impact on the stability and sustainability of the system. In areas where the
fodder resource is widely dispersed seasonally and spatially, restrictions
on stock movements by using paddocks can lead to land and vegetation
degradation (Hoffman and Cowling, 1990). Increasing the connectivity
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 91
New Zealand found that the highest levels of bird diversity were recorded
in disturbed productive forests while undisturbed mature forests contained
less bird diversity, though they were populated predominantly by native
bird species. Sternberg et al. (2000) conducted a four-year study on the
response of a Mediterranean herbaceous community to grazing manage-
ment in north-eastern Israel. Contrasting different grazing treatments they
found that low and high grazing regimes reduced herbaceous diversity but
that moderately grazed areas increased diversity.
The study of long-term grazing–vegetation interactions (102–106 years)
using palaeovegetation data permits the reconstruction of vegetation and
herbivore abundance and associations. Data from Jutland in Denmark
from the Holocene about 5000–7000 years ago suggests that large forest
herbivores did not have a significant influence on regional forest structure
(Bradshaw and Mitchell, 1999). This is because either large predators
held populations at modest levels, or the diversity of grazing species held
populations at stable, low populations of individual species.
Moderate levels of insect herbivory may actually increase productivity.
For example, Holling (1978) carried out an experiment on the defoliation
of balsam fir (Abies balsamea) by spruce budworm. The larvae result in the
death of mature trees aged 55–60 years though young trees are unaffected.
Saplings grow rapidly after mature forest is damaged, and the forest is
restored by its juvenile population. In the short term there is a shortfall
in the production of timber, but over the longer term wood production
remains unaffected. In fact, production rates of the juvenile forest remain
above that of the mature forest because in a mature stand, most trees
have passed their rapid-growth phase. Mattson and Addy (1975) reached
similar conclusions in their study on the effects of forest tent caterpillars
on aspen.
French et al. (1997) conducted a study on the development of Scots
pine in the Cairngorm mountains in Scotland and found that recruitment
is possible provided grazing/browsing pressure remains at a low level.
Similarly Sun et al. (1997) evaluated the effects of cattle grazing and seed-
ling size on the establishment of Araucaria cunninghamii in a silvo-pastoral
system in north-east Australia. They report that grazing did not cause
unacceptable mortality due to the fact that the tree has prickly needles,
which prevented browsing by cattle. They recommend that grazing does
not affect recruitment and can begin immediately after tree planting pro-
vided that a moderate stocking rate is used. Elsewhere, modelling has
also shown that plant populations may be little affected by low levels of
herbivory. Kienast et al. (1999) used a succession model – FORECE − to
assess the long-term dynamics of alpine forests in Central Europe. They
report that moderate levels of browsing posed no threat to the long-term
94 A handbook of environmental management
survival of these forests and did not alter the successional sequence of
forest development.
Recent developments on the functional complexity of ecosystems show
that small disturbances may actually enhance ecosystem function and
increase resilience. Holling (1986) and Holling et al. (1994) suggest that
some natural disturbances initiated by fire, wind and herbivores are an
inherent part of the internal dynamics of ecosystems and in many cases
set the timing of successional cycles.These natural perturbations are part
of ecosystem development and evolution, and seem to be crucial for main-
taining ecosystem resilience and integrity (Costanza et al., 1993). In the
absence of such shocks, the system will become highly connected and this
will provoke even larger perturbations that are more destructive to the
ecosystem because they reduce the ability of the system to survive similar
shocks in the future (Scholes and Walker, 1993).
Some empirical studies reveal that herbivores may enhance a system’s
ability to resist environmental perturbation. For example, in their work
on Florida mangroves, Simberloff et al. (1978) reported that the action of
isopod and other invertebrate root borers resulted in new growth of roots
at the point of attack. More extensive root systems in mangroves result in
greater stability and resistance to storms and therefore benefit the plant.
In Britain, Hulme et al. (1999) carried out a study to evaluate the effects
of sheep grazing on the productivity of upland Agrostis-Festuca grassland.
The experiment controlled sheep grazing at light, heavy and moderate
levels. Both low and high levels of grazing resulted in the spread of less
desirable species such as Nardus stricta and Molinia caerulea. Moderate
levels of grazing maintained preferred species such as Festuca rubra and
Agrostis capillaris and prevented the spread of Nardus stricta and Molinia
caerulea.
Non-equilibrium rangeland systems as practised by nomadic pastoral-
ists in parts of Africa have evolved opportunistic management regimes
that employ moderate levels of grazing intensity that do not eliminate key-
stone elements but instead maintain the resilience of these components.
Scholes and Walker (1993) have suggested that events such as fire and
herbivory may play an important role in maintaining the diversity and
resilience of such systems. Nutrient release following small fires supports
a flush of new growth without destroying all of the old growth. Rangeland
patches are affected but the forage resource remains intact. Small fires
prevent the accumulation of forest biomass, which fuels very large fires
that can decimate large areas of rangeland (Scholes and Walker, 1993) or
whole forests (Holling et al., 1994). Such events may affect the parameters
of the system and cause it to cross a threshold into an alternative state,
which may alter the system’s capacity to provide ecological services. For
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 95
of public goods, in particular they are indivisible and perhaps also non-
excludable, making their exchange in markets unlikely (Table 4.1).
The public good nature of biodiversity creates difficulties for its valu-
ation. These will be discussed in some detail in the sections that follow.
Because managed landscapes provide high levels of unpriced public ben-
efits, in terms of wildlife and landscape quality, private agents will have no
incentive to take account of these benefits in decisions over land use.
Conventional economic theory seeks to cast government in the role of
an objective and well-informed ‘third force’ (in addition to individuals
and firms), with some ability to intervene to correct for market failures.
Government or policy failure occurs when policy decisions required to
correct for market failure are not implemented and fail to fully recognize,
or incorporate, the values associated with environmental resources. Policy
failure may also arise where government decisions themselves induce eco-
nomic inefficiencies. For example, agri-environment policies, through cre-
ating incentives for farmers to expand production, may result in a greater
privately optimal level of degradation than would be the case in the absence
of such policies. Poorly formulated policy instruments and incentives may
distort the allocation of resources unintentionally. Simpson et al. (1998)
suggest that high stocking rates are caused by incentives to graze moorland
to achieve profit maximization, encouraged by support from the Common
Agricultural Policy (CAP). They indicate that increases in the ewe flock
across the Northern Isles (in Orkney from 37 000 in 1983 to nearly 55 000
in 1992, and in Shetland from 116 000 in 1982 to 156 000 in 1993) was in
response to the EU’s sheep meat regime introduced in the early 1980s. The
scheme offered headage payments and a variable premium in fat lamb sales.
They suggest that the policy has been sufficient to increase stocking levels,
and hence heather utilization rates, across the Northern Isles. McNeely
(1993) suggests that in Botswana, national and European Union subsidies
have led to excessive uncontrolled grazing of rangelands and degradation
of grazing savanna, which have affected the long-term productivity of the
resource. Subsidies that aim to promote cash crops to secure export revenue
may result in land degradation, soil nutrient losses and a reduction in the
resilience of ecosystems (Grainger, 1990). Royalties in forestry can lead to
excessive rates of deforestation (Repetto, 1989; Barbier et al., 1991).
The catch-all term ‘market failure’ is defined so as to refer to all situa-
tions where the market signals perceived by private individuals fail to coin-
cide with social values (and fail to produce economic efficiency). However,
some necessary conditions for market efficiency, which may be violated
in practice, tend to be omitted from discussions of market failure, and are
worth briefly mentioning here. The discussion above relates mainly to what
might be called the ‘complete set of markets’ condition (Common, 1995).
98 A handbook of environmental management
Valuing biodiversity
The main point that is frequently made by environmental economists
working on valuation with regard to market and policy failure is that
private resource users do not attribute sufficient weight to biodiversity.
Valuation, it is argued, aims to redress this imbalance and sets out to
determine what weight should be given to biodiversity in the interests of
society as a whole.
The literature indicates that a variety of methods have been employed to
estimate wildlife values in managed landscapes. Studies on wildlife value
have focused on their use and non-use values. These values are based on
an individual’s willingness to pay (WTP) or willingness to accept (WTA)
compensation. Gross willingness to pay might include the cost of travel,
purchase of equipment to participate in the recreation activity, actual fees
associated with the activity and consumer surplus. The concept of ‘total
economic value’ (TEV) has been used to describe the components of value
as shown in Figure 4.3. Use values associated with managed landscapes
refer to the actual and/or planned use of a service by an individual and
include recreational activities such as bird watching or hunting. Use values
also include the following: option value, that is, the value of the option
to guarantee use of the service by the individual in the future (Weisbrod,
1964); and quasi-option value, that is, the value of future information
protected by preserving the resource now, given the expectation of future
growth in knowledge relevant to the implications of development (Arrow
and Fisher, 1974; Perman et al., 2003).
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 99
use value is the same as that outlined above and includes, for example,
harvesting timber from a forest or the use of recreation services provided
by a national park. Indirect use value on the other hand refers to the life
support services provided by ecosystems. These include ecosystem func-
tions such as flood control, catchment protection, nutrient cycling and
carbon sequestration. The biological diversity of managed landscapes may
serve an important role in maintaining ecosystem functions and thus serve
to support the productive process.
mycorrhiza are not consumed themselves, they are essential for the growth
of many timber species that are harvested and they are necessary to
support the production process that produces goods and services that are
consumed directly.
Similarly, the importance of bird species used as a biological control
agent can be captured from increased timber sales associated with insect
pest reduction. Takekawa and Garton (1984) used the substitution
method to determine the value of a bird species, the evening grosbeak
(Hesperiphona vespertina) in controlling spruce budworm populations
affecting stands of Douglas fir (Pseudotsuga menziesii) in Washington.
They substituted the costs of insecticide to produce the same mortality
that birds cause and established that it would cost at least $1820 per square
km per year over a 100-year rotation.
Economic instruments
In what follows we outline two types of policy instruments of relevance to
land managers – economic incentives and command and control regula-
tions. We discuss economic incentives first.
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 105
they are still protected regardless of any cost–benefit analysis having been
undertaken.
Conclusions
Rapidly increasing human populations and associated economic develop-
ment around the world have imposed real pressures on natural habitat
and its biodiversity. This is a subject of major concern to policy-makers
and the public at large because it is recognized that biodiversity loss could
seriously diminish the options open to future generations. All too often
market and policy imperfections obscure the social costs of managed
lands, giving rise to inefficient land use and biodiversity loss.
Protected areas represent a high cost solution to biodiversity conserva-
tion in many areas. They impose considerable costs on producers, limit
future development options, reduce the supply of market produce and
they fail to engage land managers in conservation initiatives.
Joint production of commercial goods and biodiversity in managed
landscapes represents an important alternative to reserves. Indeed there is
evidence to suggest that biodiversity can coexist in landscapes of economic
importance and that it is important in supporting productive processes
in managed areas. However, highly intensive managed systems may pose
a threat to biodiversity in some areas and it is vital that managers and
policy-makers work together to develop strategies to avoid such losses.
Policy-makers should contribute to this process by developing instru-
ments that internalize biodiversity values into market behaviour. This
will help to avoid intervention failure and perverse incentives that lead
to biodiversity loss, ensuring that biodiversity values are protected and
provided efficiently.
Uncertainty over the benefits and costs of biodiversity and its role in the
functioning of ecosystems point towards the need for a diversified strategy
that includes protected areas as well as privately managed land used for
production. In the absence of a concerted effort by policy-makers and
land managers, the opportunity to develop initiatives that include private
lands in such a strategy to achieve biodiversity conservation goals will be
missed.
Note
1. Biodiversity thus represents the diversity of all life as being a characteristic property of
nature, rather than a resource. The term also has a broader meaning for the set of organ-
isms themselves. For example, a biodiverse tropical rainforest, therefore, refers to the
quality or range of diversity within it.
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 109
Bibliography
Ahlén, I. (1975), ‘Winter habitats of moose and deer in relation to land use in Scandinavia’,
Viltrevy, 9(3), 1–88.
Alés, Fernandez R., A. Martin, F. Ortega and E.E. Alés (1992), ‘Recent changes in landscape
structure and function in a Mediterranean region of SW Spain (1950–1984)’, Landscape
Ecology, 7(1), 3–18.
Alonso, J.A., J.C. Alonso and R. Muñoz-Pulido (1990), ‘Areas de invernada de la grulla
común Grus grus en España’, in J.A. Alonso and J.C. Alonso (eds), Distribución y
demografia de la grulla común (Grus grus) en España, Madrid: ICONA.
Altieri, M. and M. Liebman (eds) (1986), ‘Insect, weed, and plant disease management
in multiple cropping systems’, in C. Francis, Multiple Cropping Systems, New York:
Macmillan.
Arrow, K.J. and K.C. Fisher (1974), ‘Environmental preservation, uncertainty and irrevers-
ibility’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88, 312–19.
Baldock, D., G. Beaufoy, G. Bennet and J. Clark (eds) (1993), Nature Conservation and
New Directions in the EC Common Agricultural Policy, Arnhem: Institute for European
Environmental Policy, HPC.
Barbier, E.B. (1994), ‘Valuing environmental functions: tropical wetlands’, Land Economics,
70, 155–73.
Barbier, E.B. (2000), ‘Valuing the environment as input: review of applications to mangrove–
fishery linkages’, Ecological Economics, 35(1), 47–61.
Barbier, E.B., J.C. Burgess and A. Markyanda (1991), ‘The economics of tropical deforesta-
tion’, Ambio, 20(21), 55–8.
Barbier, E.B., J.C. Burgess and C. Folke (1994), Paradise Lost? The Ecological Economics of
Biodiversity, London: Earthscan.
Bateman, I. and K. Willis (1995), Valuing Environmental Preferences: Theory and Practice of
the Contingent Valuation Method, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Bedell, T.E. (1973), ‘Botanical composition of a subclover-grass pasture as affected by single
and dual grazing by cattle and sheep’, Agronomy Journal, 65, 502–4.
Bell, F.W. (1997), ‘The economic value of saltwater marsh supporting marine recreational
fishing in the Southeastern United States’, Ecological Economics, 21(3), 243–54.
Benson, J. and K. Willis (1991), ‘The demand for forests for recreation’, in Forestry
Expansion: A Study of Technical, Economic and Ecological Factors, Edinburgh: Forestry
Commission.
Bishop, R. (1978), ‘Endangered species and uncertainty: the economics of a safe minimum
standard’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 60(1), 10–18.
Bokdam, J. and M. Gleichman (2000), ‘Effects of grazing by free ranging cattle on vegetation
dynamics in a continental north-west European heathland’, Journal of Applied Ecology,
37(5), 415–31.
Borchert, M.I., F.W. Davis, J. Michaelsen and L.D. Oyler (1989), ‘Interactions of factors
affecting seedling recruitment of blue oak (Quercus douglasii) in California’, Ecology,
70(2), 389–404.
Bowes, M. and J. Krutilla (1989), Multiple Use Management: The Economics of Public
Forestlands, Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.
Bowker, J. and J.R. Stoll (1988), ‘Use of dichotomous choice nonmarket methods to value
the whooping crane resource’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 70(2), 372–81.
Boyle, K.J. and R.C. Bishop (1987), ‘Valuing wildlife in benefit–cost analyses: a case study
involving endangered species’, Water Resources Research, 23(5), 943–50.
Bradshaw, R. and F.J.G. Mitchell (1999), ‘The palaeoecological approach to reconstructing
former grazing–vegetation interactions’, Forest Ecology and Management, 120(1), 3–12.
Brookshire, D., B. Ives and W. Schulze (1976), ‘The valuation of aesthetic preferences’,
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 3(4), 325–46.
Brown, G.M. (1990), ‘Valuation of genetic resources’, in G.H. Orians, G.M. Brown, W.E.
Kunin and J.E. Swierbinski (eds), The Preservation and Valuation of Biological Resources,
Seattle: University of Washington Press.
110 A handbook of environmental management
Brown, G.M. and W. Henry (1993), ‘The economic value of elephants’, in E.B. Barbier (ed.),
Economics and Ecology: New Frontiers and Sustainable Development, London: Chapman
and Hall.
Brown, G.M., D. Layton and J. Lazo (1994), ‘Valuing habitat and endangered species’,
Discussion Paper No. 94-1 (January), Institute for Economic Research, University of
Washington.
Callaway, R.M. (1992), ‘Effect of shrubs on recruitment of Quercus douglasii and Quercus
lobata in California’, Ecology, 73(6), 2118–28.
Campbell, R.W. and R.J. Sloan (1976), ‘Influence of behavioural evolution on gypsy moth
pupal survival in sparse populations’, Environmental Entomology, 5(6), 1211–17.
Carrascal, L.M., L.M. Bautista and E. Lázaro (1993), ‘Geographical variation in the density
of the white stork Ciconia ciconia in Spain: influence of habitat structure and climate’,
Biological Conservation, 65(11), 83–7.
Casey, D. and D. Hein (1983), ‘Effects of heavy browsing on a bird community in deciduous
forest’, Journal of Wildlife Management, 47(3), 351–96.
Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. (1968), Resource Conservation: Economics and Policies, Berkeley:
University of California.
Clawson, M. and J. Knetsch (1966), Economics of Outdoor Recreation, Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Clout, M.N. and P.D. Gaze (1984), ‘Effects of plantation forestry on birds in New Zealand’,
Journal of Applied Ecology, 21(3), 795–815.
Coase, R. (1960), ‘The problem of social cost’, Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–44.
Common, M. (1995), Sustainability and Policy: Limits to Economics, Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Common, M. and C. Perrings (1992), ‘Towards an ecological economics of sustainability’,
Ecological Economics, 6(1), 7–34.
Conway, A., A. McLoughlin and W.E. Murphy (1972), ‘Development of a cattle and sheep
farm’, Animal Management Series No. 2, An Foras Taluntais, Dublin.
Costanza, R., W.M. Kemp and W.R. Boynton (1993), ‘Predictability, scale and biodiversity
in coastal and estuarine systems’, in C. Perrings, K.-G. Mäler, C. Folke, B.O. Jansson and
C.S. Holling (eds), Biodiversity Loss: Ecological and Economic Issues, Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Cousins, S.H. (1991), ‘Species diversity measurement: choosing the right index’, Tree, 6(6),
190–2.
Crozier, R.H. (1992), ‘Genetic diversity and the agony of choice’, Biological Conservation,
61(1), 11–15.
Cumming, D.H.M. (1993), ‘Multispecies systems: progress, prospects and challenges in sus-
taining range animal production and biodiversity in east and southern Africa’, Proceedings
of the 7th World Conference on Animal Production, Edmonton, Alberta.
Daily, G.C. (ed.) (1997), Nature’s Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems,
Washington, DC: Island Press.
Daily, G.C., P.R. Ehrlich and N.M. Haddad (1993), ‘Double keystone bird in a keystone
species complex’, Proceedings of the Natural Academy of Sciences, 90(2), 592–4.
Daily, G.C., T. Soderqvist, S. Aniyar, K. Arrow, P. Dasgupta, P.R. Ehrlich, C. Folke,
A. Jansson, B.O. Jansson, N. Kautsky, S. Levin, J. Lubchenco, K.G. Maler, D. Simpson,
D. Starrett, D. Tilman and B. Walker (2000), ‘The value of nature and the nature of value’,
Science, 289(5478), 395–6.
Daily, G.C., P.R. Ehrlich and G.A. Sanchez-Azofeifa (2001), ‘Countryside biogeography:
use of human dominated habitats by the avifauna of southern Costa Rica’, Ecological
Applications, 11(1), 1–13.
Dambach, C.A. (1944), ‘A ten-year ecological study of adjoining grazed and ungrazed wood-
lands in northeastern Ohio’, Ecological Monographs, 14(3), 69–105.
De Miguel, J.M., M.A. Rodriguez and A. Gómez-Sal (1997), ‘Determination of animal
behavior–environment relationships by correspondence analysis’, Journal of Range
Management, 50(1), 85–93.
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 111
Debussche, M. and P. Isenmann (1994), ‘Bird-dispersed seed rain and seedling establishment
in patchy mediterranean vegetation’, Oikos, 69(33), 414–26.
DeGraaf, R.M., W.M. Healy and R.T. Brooks (1991), ‘Effects of thinning and deer brows-
ing on breeding birds in New England oak woodlands’, Forest Ecology and Management,
41(3–4), 179–191.
Di Falco, S. and J.-P. Chavas (2006), ‘Crop biodiversity, farm productivity and the man-
agement of environmental risk in rainfed agriculture’, European Review of Agricultural
Economics, 33(3), 289–314.
Di Falco, S. and C. Perrings (2003), ‘Crop genetic diversity, productivity and stability of
agroecosystems: a theoretical and empirical investigation’, Scottish Journal of Political
Economy, 50(2), 207–16.
Di Falco, S. and C. Perrings (2005), ‘Crop biodiversity, risk management and the implica-
tions of agricultural assistance’, Ecological Economics, 55(4), 459–66.
Diamond, P.A. and J.A. Hausman (1994), ‘Contingent valuation: is some number better
than no number?’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(4), 19–44.
Díaz, M., E. González, R. Munoz-Pulido and M.A. Naveso (1996), ‘Habitat selection pat-
terns of common cranes Grus grus wintering in holm oak Quercus ilex dehesas of central
Spain: effects of human management’, Biological Conservation, 75(22), 119–23.
Dobzhansky, T. (1970), Genetics of the Evolutionary Process, New York: Columbia
University Press.
Edwards, K.J., G. Whittington and W. Ritchie (2005), ‘The possible role of humans in
the early stages of machair evolution: palaeoenvironmental investigations in the Outer
Hebrides, Scotland’, Journal of Archaeological Science, 32(3), 435–49.
Ellis, G.M. and A.C. Fisher (1987), ‘Valuing the environment as an input’, Journal of
Environmental Management, 85(2), 149–56.
Elton, C. (1958), The Ecology of Invasions of Animals and Plants, London: Chapman and
Hall.
Erdelen, M. (1984), ‘Bird communities and vegetation structure: I. Correlations and com-
parisons of simple and diversity indices’, Oecologia, 61(2), 277–84.
Espelta, J.S., M. Riba and J. Retana (1995), ‘Patterns of seedling recruitment in West-
Mediterranean Quercus ilex forests influenced by canopy development’, Journal of
Vegetation Science, 6(4), 465–72.
Faliñski, J.B. (1986), Vegetation Dynamics in Temperate Lowland Forests, Dordrecht: Junk
Publishers.
FAO (2004), http:www.faostat.fao.org/corp/statistics/en, accessed 13 August 2009.
Faraco, A.M., F. Fernandez and J.M. Moreno (1993), ‘Post-fire dynamics of pine wood-
lands and shrublands in the Sierra de Gredos’, in L. Traubaud and R. Prodon (eds), Fire in
Mediterranean Ecosystems, Ecosystems Research Report No. 5, pp. 101–13.
Fay, P.A. and D.C. Hartnett (1991), ‘Constraints on growth and allocation patterns of
Silphium integrifolium (Asteraceae) caused by a cynipid gall wasp’, Oecologia, 88(2),
243–50.
Ford, H.A. (1987), ‘Bird communities on habitat islands in England’, Bird Study, 34(3),
205–18.
Fox, L.R. and P.A. Morrow (1992), ‘Eucalypt responses to fertilization and reduced her-
bivory’, Oecologia, 89(2), 214–22.
French, D.D., G.R. Miller and R.P. Cummins (1997), ‘Recent development of high-altitude
Pinus sylvestris scrub in the Northern Cairngorm mountains, Scotland’, Biological
Conservation, 79(2–3), 133–44.
Fuller, R.J., D. Hill and G.M. Tucker (1991), ‘Feeding the birds down on the farm: perspec-
tives from Britain’, Ambio, 20(6), 232–7.
Garrod, G.D. and K.G. Willis (1997), ‘The non-use benefits of enhancing forest biodiversity:
a contingent ranking study’, Ecological Economics, 21(1), 45–61.
González Bernáldez, F. (1991), ‘Ecological consequences of the abandonment of traditional
land use systems in central Spain’, in J. Baudry and R.G.H. Bunce (eds), Land Abandonment
and its Role in Conservation, Options Mediterranéennes Ser. A15, pp. 23–9.
112 A handbook of environmental management
Gourlay, D. (1996), ‘Loch Lomond and Stewartry ESAs: a study of public perceptions of
policy’, unpublished PhD dissertation, School of Agriculture, University of Aberdeen.
Grainger, A. (1990), The Threatening Desert – Controlling Desertification, London: Earthscan.
Griffin, J.R. (1971), ‘Oak regeneration in the upper Carmel valley, California’, Ecology,
52(5), 862–8.
Haigh, N. (1993), The Precautionary Principle and British Environmental Policy, London:
Institute for European Environmental Policy.
Hanemann, W.M. (1994), ‘Valuing the environment through contingent valuation’, Journal
of Economic Perspectives, 8(4), 19–44.
Hanley, N. (1995), Rural Amenities and Rural Development: Empirical Evidence, Synthesis
Report to the Rural Development Programme, OECD, Paris.
Hanley, N. and S. Craig (1991), ‘Wilderness development decisions and the Krutilla–Fisher
model: the case of Scotland’s flow country’, Ecological Economics, 4(2), 145–64.
Hanley, N. and C. Spash (1993), Cost–Benefit Analysis and the Environment, Aldershot, UK
and Brookfield, VT, USA: Edward Elgar.
Hanley, N., A. Munro, D. Jamieson and D. Ghosh (1991), ‘Environmental economics and
sustainable development in nature conservation’, unpublished NCC Report.
Hanley, N., J.F. Shogren and B. White (1997), Environmental Economics: In Theory and
Practice, London: Macmillan.
Hausman, J.A. (ed.) (1993), Contingent Valuation: A Critical Assessment, Contributions to
Economic Analysis, Amsterdam: North Holland Publishers.
Hernandez, M.P.G. and F.J. Silva-Pando (1996), ‘Grazing effects of ungulates in a Galician
oak forest (Northwest Spain)’, Forest Ecology and Management, 88(1–2), 65–70.
Herrera, J. (1995), ‘Acorn predation and seedling production in a low-density population of
cork oak (Quercus-suber L.)’, Forest Ecology and Management, 76(1–3), 197–201.
Hester, A.J., F.J.G. Mitchell and K.J. Kirby (1996), ‘Effects of season and intensity of
sheep grazing on tree regeneration in a British upland woodland’, Forest Ecology and
Management, 88(1–2), 99–106.
Hoffman, M.T. (1988), ‘Rationale for Karoo grazing systems: criticisms and research impli-
cations’, South African Journal of Science, 84, 556–9.
Hoffman, M.T. and R.M. Cowling (1990), ‘Vegetation change in the semi-arid eastern Karoo
over the last 200 years: an expanding Karoo – fact or fiction?’, South African Journal of
Science, 86, 286–94.
Holling, C.S. (1973), ‘Resilience and stability of ecological systems’, Annual Review of
Ecological Systems, 4(1), 1–24.
Holling, C.S. (ed.) (1978), Adaptive Environmental Assessment and Management, Chichester,
UK: John Wiley and Sons.
Holling, C.S. (1986), ‘Resilience of ecosystem: local surprise and global change’, in E.C.
Clark and R.E. Munn (eds), Sustainable Development of the Biosphere, Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Holling, C.S. (1988), ‘Temperate forest insect outbreaks, tropical deforestation and migra-
tory birds’, Memoirs of the Entomological Society of Canada, No. 146, 21–32.
Holling, C.S. (1992), ‘Cross-scale morphology, geometry and dynamics of ecosystems’,
Ecological Monographs, 62(4), 47–52.
Holling, C.S., D.W. Schindler, B.W. Walker and J. Roughgarden (1994), ‘Biodiversity in
the functioning of ecosystems: an ecological primer and synthesis’, in C. Perrings, K.-G.
Mäler, C. Folke, B.O. Jansson and C.S. Holling (eds), Biodiversity Loss: Ecological and
Economic Issues, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Holmes, R.T., J.C. Schultz and P. Nothnagle (1979), ‘Bird predation on forest insects: an
exclosure experiment’, Science, 206(4417), 462–3.
Hulme, P.D., R.J. Pakeman, J.M. Torvell, J.M. Fisher and I.J. Gordon (1999), ‘The effects
of controlled sheep grazing on the dynamics of upland Agrostis-Festuca grassland’, Journal
of Applied Ecology, 36(66), 886–900.
Hutchinson, G.E. (1961), ‘The paradox of the plankton’, American Naturalist, 95(882),
137–47.
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 113
IUCN (1988), ‘General Assembly of the International Union for Conservation of Nature
and Natural Resources’, Costa Rica.
Jackson, T. and P.J. Taylor (1992), ‘The precautionary principle and the prevention of
marine pollution’, Chemistry and Ecology, 71(1–4), 123–34.
James, F.C. and N.O. Wamer (1982), ‘Relationships between temperate forest bird commu-
nities and vegetation structure’, Ecology, 63(1), 159–71.
Jane, G.T. (1994), ‘The impact of browsing animals on the stand dynamics of monotypic
mountain beech (Nothofagus solandri) forests in Canterbury, New Zealand’, Australia
Journal of Botany, 42(22), 113–24.
Jeltsch, F., S.J. Milton, W.R.J. Dean and N. van Rooyen (1997), ‘Analysing shrub encroach-
ment in the southern Kalahari: a grid-based modelling approach’, Journal of Applied
Ecology, 34(6), 1497–1509.
Joffre, R. and S. Rambal (1993), ‘How tree cover influences the water balance of
Mediterranean rangelands’, Ecology, 74(2), 570–82.
Joffre, R., J. Vacher, C. de los Llanos and G. Long (1988), ‘The dehesa: an agrosilvopastoral
system of the Mediterranean region with special reference to the Sierra Morena area of
Spain’, Agroforestry Systems, 6(1), 71–96.
Jorritsma, I.T.M., A.F.M. van Hees and G.M.J. Mohren (1999), ‘Forest development in
relation to ungulate grazing: a modelling approach’, Forest Ecology and Management,
120(1–3), 23–4.
Just, R.E. and R.D. Pope (1978), ‘Stochastic representation of production functions and
econometric implications’, Journal of Econometrics, 7(1), 67–86.
Kienast, F., J. Fritschi, M. Bissegger and W. Abderhalden (1999), ‘Modelling successional
patterns of high-elevation forests under changing herbivore pressure – responses at the
landscape level’, Forest Ecology and Management, 120(1–3), 35–46.
Kingery, J.L. and R.T. Graham (1991), ‘The effect of cattle grazing on ponderosa pine regen-
eration’, Forestry Chronicle, 67(3), 245–8.
Köhler-Rollefson, I. (1993), ‘Traditional pastoralists as guardians of biological diversity’,
Indigenous Knowledge and Development Monitor, 1(3), 14–16.
Kruess, A. and T. Tscharntke (1994), ‘Habitat fragmentation, species loss and biological
control’, Science, 264(5165), 1581–84.
Krutilla, J.V. (1967), ‘Conservation reconsidered’, American Economic Review, 57(4), 778–86.
Lindberg, K. (1991), Policies for Maximizing Nature Tourism’s Ecological and Economic
Benefits, Washington, DC: World Resources Institute.
Linder, P., B. Elfving and O. Zackrisson (1997), ‘Stand structure and successional trends in
virgin boreal forest reserves in Sweden’, Forest Ecology and Management, 98(1), 17–33.
Londo, G. (1990), ‘Conservation and management of semi-natural grasslands in
Northwestern Europe’, in U. Bohn and R. Neuhäusl (eds), Vegetation and Flora of
Temperate Zones, The Hague: Academic Publishing.
Long, J., E. Cromwell and K. Gold (2000), On-farm Management of Crop Diversity: An
Introductory Bibliography, London: Overseas Development Institute for ITDG.
Lovejoy, T.E. (1988), ‘Diverse considerations’, in E.O. Wilson and F.M. Peter (eds), Issues in
Risk Assessment, Washington, DC: National Academy Press.
Lynch, J.F. and D.F. Whigham (1984), ‘Effects of forest fragmentation on breeding bird
communiites in Maryland, USA’, Biological Conservation, 28(44), 287–324.
MacArthur, R.H. (1955), ‘Fluctuations of animal populations and a measure of community
stability’, Ecology, 36(3), 533–6.
MacArthur, R.H. and J.W. MacArthur (1961), ‘On bird species diversity’, Ecology, 42(3),
594–8.
MacArthur, R.H. and E.O. Wilson (1967), The Theory of Island Biogeography, Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Main, A.F. (1982), ‘Rare species: precious or dross?’, in R.H. Groves and W.D.L. Ride (eds),
Species at Risk: Research in Australia, Canberra: Australian Academy of Science.
Maquis, R.J. and C.J. Whelan (1994), ‘Insectivorous birds increase growth of white oak
through consumption of leaf-chewing insects’, Ecology, 75(7), 2007–14.
114 A handbook of environmental management
Marañon, M. (1986), ‘Plant species richness and canopy effect in the savannah-like dehesa of
south-west Spain’, Ecologia Mediterranea, 12(1), 131–41.
Marrs, R.H. and D. Welch (1991), Moorland Wilderness: The Potential Effects of
Removing Domestic Livestock, Particularly Sheep, ITE Report to the Department of the
Environment.
Mate, I.D. (1992), ‘The theoretical development of machair in the Hebrides’, Scottish
Geographical Magazine, 108(1), 35–8.
Mattson, W.J. and N.D. Addy (1975), ‘Phytophagous insects as regulators of forest primary
production’, Science, 190(4214), 515–22.
May, R.M. (1973), Stability and Complexity in Model Ecosystems, Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
McNaughton, S.J. (1984), ‘Grazing lawns: animals in herds, plant form and co-evolution’,
American Naturalist, 124(6), 863–86.
McNaughton, S.J. (1985), ‘Ecology of a grazing ecosystem: the Serengeti’, Ecological
Monographs, 55(3), 259–94.
McNeeley, J.A. (1988), Economics and Biological Diversity, Gland, Switzerland: IUCN.
McNeeley, J.A. (1993), ‘Economic incentives for conserving biodiversity: lessons for Africa’,
Ambio, 22(2–3), 144–50.
Metrick, A. and M.L. Weitzman (1994), ‘Patterns of behavior in biodiversity preservation’,
Policy Research Working Paper No. 1358, Environment, Infrastructure, and Agriculture
Division, The World Bank, Washington, DC.
Mill, G.A., T.M. van Rensburg, S. Hynes and C. Dooley (2007), ‘Preferences and mul-
tiple use forest management in Ireland: a contingent valuation approach’, Ecological
Economics, 60(3), 642–53.
Miller, H.G. (1999), Forest Policy: The International and British Dimensions, Department of
Forestry, University of Aberdeen.
Miller, K.R. (1996), ‘Conserving biodiversity in managed landscapes’, in R.C. Szaro and
D.W. Johnston (eds), Biodiversity in Managed Landscapes: Theory and Practice, Oxford,
UK: Oxford University Press.
Miller, T.E. (1982), ‘Community diversity and interactions between the size and frequency of
disturbance’, American Naturalist, 120(4), 533–42.
Mitchell, F.J.G. and E. Cole (1998), ‘Reconstruction of long-term successional dynamics of
temperate woodland in Bialowieza forest, Poland’, Journal of Ecology, 86(6), 1042–59.
Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson (1989), Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent
Valuation Method, Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.
Montgomery, C.A., G.M. Brown and D.M. Adams (1994), ‘The marginal cost of species pres-
ervation: the northern spotted owl’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
26(2), 111–28.
Moore, A.D. (1990), ‘The semi-Markov process: a useful tool in the analysis of vegetation
dynamics for management’, Journal of Environmental Management, 30(2), 111–30.
Morgan, R.K. (1991), ‘The role of protective understorey in the regeneration system of a
heavily browsed woodland’, Vegetatio, 92(2), 119–32.
Morris, R.F., W.F. Cheshire, C.A. Miller and D.G. Mott (1958), ‘The numerical response
of avian and mammalian predators during a gradation of the spruce budworm’, Ecology,
39(3), 487–94.
Myers, N. (1992), ‘Population/environment linkages: discontinuities ahead’, Ambio, 21(1),
116–18.
Naveh, Z. (1994), ‘The role of fire and its management in the conservation of Mediterranean
ecosystems and landscapes’, in J.M. Moreno and W.C. Oechel (eds), The Role of Fire in
Mediterranean-type Ecosystems, New York: Springer Verlag.
Naveh, Z. and R.H. Whittaker (1979), ‘Structural and floristic diversity of shrublands
and woodlands in northern Israel and other Mediterranean areas’, Vegetatio, 41(3),
171–90.
Nolan, T. and J. Connolly (1977), ‘Mixed stocking by sheep and steers – a review’, Herbage
Abstracts, 47(11), 367–79.
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 115
O’Neill, R.V., D.L. DeAngelis, J.B. Waide and T.F.H. Allen (1986), A Hierarchical Concept
of Ecosystems, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Opdam, P., G. Rijsdijk and F. Hustings (1985), ‘Bird communities in small woods in an
agricultural landscape: effects of area and isolation’, Biological Conservation, 34(4),
333–51.
Pearce, D.W. and R.K. Turner (1990), Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment,
Hemel Hempstead, UK: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Perman, R., Y. Ma, J. McGilvray and M. Common (2003), Natural Resource and
Environmental Economics, New York: Pearson Education, Longman.
Peterken, G.F. and C.R. Tubbs (1965), ‘Woodland regeneration in the New Forest,
Hampshire, since 1650’, Journal of Applied Ecology, 2(1), 159–70.
Pezzey, J. (1989), ‘Economic analysis of sustainable growth and sustainable development’,
Environment Department Working Paper No. 15, The World Bank, Washington, DC.
Pignatti, S. (1978), ‘Evolutionary trends in Mediterranean flora and vegetation’, Vegetatio,
37(3), 175–85.
Pimm, S.L. (1984), ‘The complexity and stability of ecosystems’, Nature, 307(26), 321–6.
Pimmental, D., U. Stachow, D.A. Takacs, H.W. Brubaker, A.R. Dumas, J.J. Meaney, J.A.
O’Neill, D.E. Onsi and D.B. Corzilius (1992), ‘Conserving biological diversity in agricul-
tural/forestry systems’, Bioscience, 42(5), 354–62.
Polasky, S., E. Nelson, E. Lonsdorf, P. Fackler and A. Starfield (2005), ‘Conserving species
in a working landscape: land use with biological and economic objectives’, Ecological
Applications, 15(4), 1387–1401.
Portney, P.R. (1994), ‘The contingent valuation debate: why economists should care’,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(4), 3–18.
Power, M.E., D. Tilman, J.A. Estes, B.A. Menge, W.J. Bond, L.S. Mills, G. Daily, J.C.
Castilla, J. Lubchenko and R.T. Paine (1996), ‘Challenges in the quest for keystones’,
BioScience, 46(8), 609–20.
Randall, A., B. Ives and C. Eastman (1974), ‘Bidding games for the valuation of aesthetic
environmental improvements’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
1(2), 132–49.
Ratcliffe, P.R. (1993), Biodiversity in Britain’s Forests, Edinburgh: The Forest Authority.
Raven, R.H., K. Beese, T. Eisner, N. Morin, T. Duncan, S.L.A. Hobbs, J. Hodges, W.F.
Rall, R.R. Colwell and J. Swings (1992), ‘Biotechnology and genetic resources: United
States–Commission of the European Communities Workshop’, 21–22 October, Airlie,
Virginia, USA; Brussels, Belgium: Commission of the European Communities.
Reid, W.V. (1996), ‘Beyond protected areas: changing perceptions of ecological management
objectives’, in R.C. Szaro and D.W. Johnston (eds), Biodiversity in Managed Landscapes:
Theory and Practice, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Reinhammar, L.-G. (1995), ‘Evidence for two distinct species of Pseudorchis (Orchidaceae)
in Scandinavia’, Nordic Journal of Botany, 15(5), 469–81.
Relva, M.A. and T.T. Veblen (1998), ‘Impacts of introduced large herbivores on Austrocedrus
chilensis forests in northern Patagonia, Argentina’, Forest Ecology and Management,
108(1–2), 27–40.
Repetto, R. (1989), ‘Economic incentives for sustainable production’, in G. Schramme and
J.J. Warford (eds), Environmental Management and Economic Development, Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins for the World Bank.
Roland, M.A. and P.D. Taylor (1997), ‘Insect parasitoid species respond to forest structure
at different spatial scales’, Nature, 386(6636), 710–13.
Rosenzweig, M.L. (2003), Win-Win Ecology: How the Earth’s Species Can Survive in the
Midst of Human Enterprise, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Schemske, D.W. and N. Brokaw (1981), ‘Treefalls and the distribution of understorey birds
in a tropical forest’, Ecology, 62(4), 938–45.
Schindler, D.W. (1990), ‘Experimental perturbations of whole lakes as tests of hypotheses
concerning ecosystem structure and function’, Proceedings of 1987 Crafoord Symposium,
Oikos, 57(1), 25–41.
116 A handbook of environmental management
Schindler, D.W., S.E.M. Kasian and R.H. Hesslein (1989), ‘Biological impoverishment
in lakes of the northeastern United States from acid rain’, Environmental Science and
Technology, 23(5), 573–80.
Schmida, A. and M.V. Wilson (1985), ‘Biological determinants of species diversity’, Journal
of Biogeography, 12(4), 1–20.
Scholes, R.J. and B.H. Walker (1993), An African Savanna: Synthesis of the Nylsvlei Study,
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Silva, J. (1987), ‘Responses of savanna to stress and disturbance: species dynamics’, in B.H.
Walker (ed.), Determinants of Tropical Savannas, Oxford, UK: IRL Press.
Simberloff, D., B.J. Brown and S. Lowrie (1978), ‘Isopod and insect root borers may benefit
Florida mangroves’, Science, 201(4356), 630–32.
Simpson, I.A., A.H. Kirkpatrick, L. Scott, J.P. Gill, N. Hanley and A.J. MacDonald (1998),
‘Application of a grazing model to predict heather moorland utilization and implications
for nature conservation’, Journal of Environmental Management, 54(3), 215–31.
Smale, M., J. Hartell, P.W. Heisey and B. Senauer (1998), ‘The contribution of genetic
resources and diversity to wheat production in the Punjab of Pakistan’, American Journal
of Agricultural Economics, 80(3), 482–93.
Solow, A., S. Polasky and J. Broadus (1993), ‘On the measurement of biological diversity’,
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 24(1), 60–68.
Soulé, M.E. and B.A. Wilcox (eds) (1980), Conservation Biology, an Evolutionary Ecological
Perspective, Sunderland, MA: Sinauer Associates.
Staines, B.W. (1995), ‘The impact of red deer on the regeneration of native pinewoods’, in
Forestry Commission, Our Pinewood Heritage, Conference proceedings, Inverness, 1994,
Farnham, UK: Forestry Commission, RSPB, SNH.
Staines, B.W., R. Balharry and D. Welch (1995), ‘The impact of red deer and their manage-
ment on the natural heritage in the uplands’, in D.B.A. Thompson, A.J. Hester and M.B.
Usher (eds), Heaths and Moorlands: Cultural Landscapes, Edinburgh: Scottish Natural
Heritage.
Sternberg, M., M. Gutman, A. Perevolotsky, E.D. Ungar and J. Kigel (2000), ‘Vegetation
response to grazing management in a Mediterranean herbaceous community: a functional
group approach’, Journal of Applied Ecology, 37, 224–37.
Stoll, J.R. and L.A. Johnson (1984), ‘Concepts of value, non-market valuation and the case
of the whooping crane’, Transactions of the Forty Ninth American Wildlife and Natural
Resources Conference, 49, 382–93.
Stowe, T.J. (1987), ‘The management of sessile oakwoods for pied flycatchers’, RSPB
Conservation Review, 1, 78–83.
Sumner, D.R., B. Doupnik and M.G. Boosalis (1981), ‘Effects of reduced tillage and multiple
cropping on plant diseases’, Annual Review of Phytopathology, 19(3755), 167–87.
Sun, D., G.R. Dickinson and A.L. Bragg (1997), ‘Effect of cattle grazing and seedling size
on the establishment of Araucaria cunninghamii in a silvo-pastoral system in Northeast
Australia’, Journal of Environmental Management, 49(4), 435–44.
Sykes, J.M. and A.D. Horrill (1979), ‘Regeneration of native pinewoods’, Institute of
Terrestrial Ecology Annual Report 1978, pp. 103–6.
Takekawa, J.Y. and E.O. Garton (1984), ‘How much is an evening grosbeak worth?’, Journal
of Forestry, 82(7), 426–8.
Takekawa, J.Y., E.O. Garton and L.A. Langelier (1982), ‘Biological control of forest insect
outbreaks: the use of avian predators’, Transactions of the 47th North American Wildlife
Conference, pp. 393–409.
Telleria, J.L. and L.M. Carrascal (1994), ‘Weight–density relationships between and within
bird communities: implications of niche space and vegetation structure’, The American
Naturalist, 143, 1083–92.
Telleria, J.L. and T. Santos (1995), ‘Effects of forest fragmentation on a guild of wintering
passerines: the role of habitat selection’, Biological conservation, 71(1), 61–7.
Telleria, J.L., T. Santos, A. Sanchez and A. Galarza (1992), ‘Habitat structure predicts bird
diversity distribution in Iberian forests better than climate’, Bird Study, 39(1), 63–8.
Biodiversity conservation in managed landscapes 117
Terborgh, J. (1985), ‘Habitat selection in Amazonian birds’, in M.L. Cody (ed.), Habitat
Selection in Birds, Orlando: Academic Press.
Tilman, D. (1996), ‘Biodiversity: population versus ecosystem stability’, Ecology, 77(3),
350–63.
Tilman, D. and J.A. Downing (1994), ‘Biodiversity and stability in grasslands’, Nature, 367,
363–6.
Tilman, D., J. Knops, D. Wedin, P. Reich, M. Ritchie and E. Siemann (1997), ‘The influ-
ence of functional diversity and composition on ecosystem processes’, Science, 277(5330),
1300–02.
Tinbergen, L. (1960), ‘The natural control of insects in pinewoods. I. Factors influencing the
intensity of predation by songbirds’, Archives Neerlandaises de Zoologie, 13(3), 265–43.
Tucker, G.M. and M.F. Heath (1994), Birds in Europe: Their Conservation Status, Cambridge,
UK: BirdLife International.
Turner, R.K. (ed.) (1993), Sustainable Environmental Economics and Management, London:
Belhaven Press.
UNEP (1995), Global Biodiversity Assessment, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press.
Valderrábano, J. and L. Torrano (2000), ‘The potential for using goats to control Genista
scorpius shrubs in European black pine stands’, Forest Ecology and Management, 126(33),
377–83.
Van Dorp, D. and P.F.M. Opdam (1987), ‘Effects of patch size, isolation and regional abun-
dance on forest bird communities’, Landscape Ecology, 1(1), 59–73.
Vane-Wright, R.I., C.J. Humphries and P.H. Williams (1991), ‘What to protect? Systematics
and the agony of choice’, Biological Conservation, 55(3), 235–54.
Van Hees, A.F.M., A.T. Kuiters and P.A. Slim (1996), ‘Growth and development of silver
birch, pedunculate oak and beech as affected by deer browsing’, Forest Ecology and
Management, 88(1–2), 55–63.
Van Rensburg, T.M., G.A. Mill, M. Common and J.C. Lovett (2002), ‘Preferences and mul-
tiple use forest management’, Ecological Economics, 43(2–3), 231–44.
Walker, B.H. (1988), ‘Autoecology, synecology, climate and livestock as agents of range-
lands dynamics’, Australian Range Journal, 10(2), 69–75.
Walker, B.H. (1992), ‘Biodiversity and ecological redundancy’, Conservation Biology, 6,
18–23.
Walker, B.H., D. Ludwig, C.S. Holling and R.M. Peterman (1981), ‘Stability of semi-arid
savanna grazing systems’, Ecology, 69(2), 473–498.
Walker T.S., R.P. Singh and N.S. Jodha (1983), Dimensions of Farm-level Diversification
in the Semi-arid Tropics of Rural South India, Economic Program Progress Report, 51
ICRISAT, Patancheru, India.
WCED (1987), Our Common Future, The World Commission on Environment and
Development, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Weber, G.E., F. Jeltsch, N. van Rooyen and S.J. Milton (1998), ‘Simulated long-term veg-
etation response to grazing heterogeneity in semi-arid rangelands’, Journal of Applied
Ecology, 35(5), 687–99.
Weisbrod, B. (1964), ‘Collective consumption services of individual consumption goods’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 78(3), 471–7.
Weitzman, M.L. (1998), ‘The Noah’s ark problem’, Econometrica, 66(6), 1279–98.
Weslien, J. and M. Schroeder (1999), ‘Population levels of bark beetles and associated insects
in managed and unmanaged spruce stands’, Forest Ecology and Management, 115(2–3),
267–75.
Westoby, M., B.H. Walker and I. Noy-Meir (1989), ‘Opportunistic management for range-
lands not at equilibrium’, Journal of Range Management, 42(4), 266–74.
Whiteman, A. (1991), A Cost–Benefit Analysis of Forest Replanting in East England,
Edinburgh: Forestry Commission Development Division.
Whittaker, R.H. (1977), ‘Evolution of species diversity in land communities’, Evolutionary
Biology, 10(1), 1–67.
118 A handbook of environmental management
Willis, K.G. (1991), ‘The recreational value of the Forestry Commission estate in Great
Britain: a Clawson–Knetsch travel cost analysis’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy,
38(1), 58–75.
Willis, K.G. and J.F. Benson (1988), ‘Financial and social costs of management agreements
for wildlife conservation in Britain’, Journal of Environmental Management, 26(1), 43–63.
Willson, M.F. (1974), ‘Avian community organization and habitat structure’, Ecology, 55(5),
1017–29.
Wilson, E.O. (1985), ‘The biological diversity crisis’, BioScience, 35(11), 700–706.
Wilson, E.O. (ed.) (1988), Biodiversity, Washington, DC: National Academy Press.
Wilson, W.L. and A.D. Johns (1982), ‘Diversity and abundance of selected animal species
in undisturbed forest, selectively logged forest and plantations in east Kalimantan,
Indonesia’, Biological Conservation, 24(3), 205–18.
World Resources Institute (WRI) (2005), ‘Earth trends: the environmental information
portal’, http://earthtrends.wri.org/, accessed 13 August 2009.
Zohary, M. (1973), Geobotanical Foundations of the Middle East. Vol 1, Stuttgart: Gustav
Fisher Verlag.
5. How do institutions affect the
management of environmental resources?
Bhim Adhikari
Introduction
In recent years, institutions and institutional arrangements have become
central in the study of the success or failure of environmental resource
management. The enforcement of institutions such as contracts1 and prop-
erty rights plays a crucial role in managing natural resources, affecting the
equity and efficiency of resource management regimes. The centrality of
contracts and property rights in understanding the diversity of institutional
arrangements began in the research programme initiated by Coase (1937,
1960) and implemented by new institutional economics (NIE), and is now
widespread throughout the economics literature (Menard, 2000). NIE
focuses on explaining the determinants of institutions and their evolution
over time and evaluates their impact on economic performance, efficiency
and distribution (Nabil and Nugent, 1989). The theoretical framework of
NIE has been used in many disciplines, ranging from sociology, anthro-
pology and legal studies to applied fields such as policy analysis, planning
and organizational development. It is recognized that ‘institutions matter’
and that the associated incentive structure in a particular form of institu-
tion substantially influences economic performance (Bardhan, 1999).
NIE provides a coherent theory of how contracts and collective action
can be seen as the logical outcome of rational individuals’ utility maximi-
zation and how institutional changes alter the pattern of individual choice
and incentive directions. Lin and Nugent (1995) divide NIE into two
broad categories, one studying the demand for institutions and one study-
ing the supply of institutions. So the institutional analysis has adopted two
inter-related approaches: (1) the transaction costs and information costs
approach and (2) the collective action approach (Nabil and Nugent, 1989).
The former is concerned with the role of transaction costs in economic
organizations. The general hypothesis is that institutions are transaction-
cost-minimizing arrangements, which may change and evolve with changes
in the nature and sources of transaction costs and the means for minimiz-
ing them. The transaction costs approach is thus suitable for analysing
the functional role of common property institutions (that is, demand for
institutions). A second theme is the collective action approach, which
119
120 A handbook of environmental management
well defined, (2) transactions are costless and (3) there is no income effect
(Baland and Platteau, 1996). The Coase theorem was later criticized for
the following reasons. First, in a game involving more than two individu-
als (parties), the solution that leads to an efficient outcome through decen-
tralized bargaining depends on the initial assignment of rights. Second, the
negative effects of many resource and environmental problems occur in
the distant future. The Coase theorem is not clear about how the concern
of future generations is taken into account in the bargaining process.
Despite some crucial difficulties, there is no doubt that the Coase theorem
demonstrates the importance of property rights and transaction costs in
order to internalize the externality associated with public good manage-
ment. The basic motivations for contracting property rights are as follows.
First, individuals do not have to consider the full social costs of their
activities with respect to resource use in the absence of well-defined prop-
erty rights. Second, resources will be undervalued because reallocation of
the resources to higher-value uses becomes more costly and not feasible if
property rights are absent. I shall clarify this argument in the subsequent
discussion.
This chapter proceeds as follows. The second section focuses on the
current debate concerning property rights transformation, placing the
problem in a broader theoretical context. I then analyse the notion of
common property resources and show how open access resources differ
fundamentally from resources held under community ownership. The role
of transaction costs is then examined before considering the impact of
group heterogeneity.
being equal, the greater the losses of the common pool then the greater
the size of the anticipated aggregate benefits of institutional change
and the more likely new property rights will be sought and adopted.
Nationalization of environmental resources in many developing countries
seems to be influenced by this hypothesis as well as ‘the tragedy of the
commons’ metaphor. In this metaphor, resources managed under common
property rights and open accesses were frequently viewed as synonymous.
It was thought that a resource held under a CPR regime is inherently inef-
ficient since individuals do not get proper incentives to act in a socially effi-
cient way. As a consequence scholars have long questioned the incentive
for efficient use of CPRs under common property regimes (Gordon, 1954;
Scott, 1955; Hardin, 1968) and solutions have been proposed, such as state
control and management (Hardin, 1968) or privatization of the commons
(Demsetz, 1964). In explaining the tragedy of the commons, the economic
theory focuses less upon the weakness of the individuals and more upon
the imperfections in the social systems to which they respond. In fact,
economists are less convinced of the importance of human failing in deter-
mining social outcomes, simply because economists have believed in a
special form of social synergism since the time of Adam Smith. However,
more careful analysis of the foundation of common property regimes in
developing countries has shown that local institutional arrangements,
including customs and social conventions designed to induce cooperative
solutions, can overcome the collective action problems and help achieve
efficiency in the use of such resources (Gibbs and Bromley, 1989; Ostrom,
1990). In the following section, I present a critical analysis of the common
property and open access resource systems and explain how common
property institutions were misunderstood.
Regime
Open access (res nullius) Free for all; no defined group of users or owners
and benefit stream is available to anyone interested
in entering into harvesting the resource, resource
use rights are neither exclusive nor transferable
State property (res publica) Ownership and management control held by the
nation state, state has right to determine use/access
rules (but in real world, use rights and access rights
are often not enforceable without high cost)
Common property (res Use rights for the resource are controlled by an
communes) identifiable group and are not privately owned or
managed by government; rules exist concerning who
may use the resource, who is excluded from using
the resource, and how the resource should be used;
the co-owner has both rights and duties with respect
to use rate and maintenance of the property owned
Private property Owned by individual; individuals have right to
undertake socially acceptable uses; claim rests with
the individual or the corporation
a good can dispose of it as desired and can exclude other people from its
use. On the other hand, a public good can be jointly consumed with others
and is therefore non-exclusive. The rate of consumption of such goods
is independent of the number of consumers and how the good is utilized
(Oakerson, 1986). A common good has characteristics of both private
(subtractable) and public goods (difficult to exclude) since it contains a
certain degree of subtractability and excludability. This implies that the
consumption of a common good by one individual will reduce another
individual’s ability to consume the same good. The rate of consumption of
a common good, however, varies according to the number of users and the
type of use. It appears that it is difficult to exclude anyone from utilizing the
benefits generated by common goods, which characterizes the problem of
common property as the provision of these benefits becomes problematic.
However, it is not impossible for co-owners to jointly benefit from
common resources, as long as there are mechanisms to exclude non-
owners from their use. Common property resources are partly joint
and partly exclusive, which means that a type of property regime has to
apply to exclude certain sections of society from entering into resource
appropriation and exploitation. Communal or common property regimes
try to achieve this exclusion by making the resource accessible only to
an identifiable group or members, who devise certain mechanisms to
regulate the pattern of resource use. Many policy prescriptions towards
centralized management of CPRs in the developing world stem from a
fundamental misunderstanding of possible resource regimes. Due to this
confusion, common property carries the false and misplaced burden of
‘inevitable’ resource degradation that properly lies with situations of open
access (Bromley, 1991). Policy-makers without complete knowledge of
tenurial differences and systems of customary rights quite often advocate
the argument that the efficient utilization of CPRs is only possible under
state property regimes. Nationalization of Nepal’s forests is an example of
transformation of private/communal systems of property rights into state
property (de facto open access), which actually upset centuries of social
arrangements adopted by villagers to overcome resource degradation and
make common property regimes viable. In the following section I will take
up further discussions that underscore theoretical aspects of open access
and common property regime systems.
Open access
Open access conditions occur when there is no exclusively defined access
and use right to a particular resource system. Resources that fall into this
category are subject to use by any person who has the capability and desire
to harvest or extract the resource. This situation often results from the
128 A handbook of environmental management
in an in situ condition. This means that a physical unit of the resource in its
in situ or fugitive state cannot be associated with a particular owner unlike
a private property regime where an in situ resource can be said to belong
to a particular real or legal person. So in an open access condition anyone
who possesses the social and physical capital to exploit the resource and
the desire to enter into resource harvest can do so.
Another fundamental problem associated with an open access regime
is that the over-exploitation of CPRs under open access will then result in
symmetric or asymmetric negative externalities. A symmetric externality is
present in an open access regime where each entrant to resource use imparts
a negative externality to all other producers. The new entrant, in turn,
simultaneously has a negative externality imposed on them by the others.
The externality is reciprocal or symmetric. Common examples include fish-
eries, wildlife, open grazing land, ground water, unregulated woodland and
forests, and common oil and gas pools. On the other hand, an asymmetric
externality occurs when the production or consumption decisions of actors
enter the production or utility functions of others while the recipients of
the externality do not cause any reciprocal effects (Stevenson, 1991). A
typical example includes the classic case of a smoking factory dirtying a
nearby laundry’s clothes. Most of the literature on resources held under
open access has concentrated on the symmetric externality, however, the
concept can easily be extended into both types of externality.
There is a vast literature developing on the issue of resource exploitation
as characterized by an open access regime. In his analysis of deforestation
in Nepal, Wallace (1981) reached several important conclusions in respect
to exploitation of forest resources under an open access condition. First,
resource users over-consume the resource in two different ways: they over-
use the resource relative to other goods, and they over-use the resource
this year relative to next year. Both kinds of over-exploitation occur
because the cost of resource use to each individual is less than the cost to
society. For each user, the cost of a particular product from the commons
next year depends mostly on this year’s consumption by other users. The
benefit of the resource next year is assumed to be independent of this
year’s consumption. Unable to influence this year’s consumption by other
harvesters, each user will consume the resources until this year’s marginal
benefit equals this year’s marginal cost. Second, with two substitutable
resources, resource users may consume too much of one and too little of
another, even if total use is efficient. This unbalanced consumption mix
also results from the divergence of private and social costs of resource con-
sumption. Resource users in open access regimes tend to react to average
rather than marginal costs and the unbalanced consumption mix is the
result of different average and marginal costs (Wallace, 1981).
130 A handbook of environmental management
Common property
Common property refers to resources for which there are communal
arrangements for the exclusion of non-owners and allocation among co-
owners. Common property exists when a defined group of resource users
holds property rights to natural resources and there is a restriction on the
number of people who can reap a benefit from the commons. As I noted
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 131
1. The resource unit has bounds that are well defined by physical, bio-
logical and social parameters.
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 133
The first point indicates that a resource held under common property
must be defined either by biological, physical or social conventions, or a
combination of these. At this point I again emphasize the clear distinc-
tion between the resource and common property regime. As was shown
above, common property refers to management institutions that underline
the relation between individuals, which differ from physical objects. In
contrast, the resource is the physical or intangible asset that a group can
own and manage as common property. Since the institution cannot exist
without the resource that it controls, demarcation of resources, nonethe-
less, must be included in the definition of the social institution of common
property (Stevenson, 1991).
The second point specifies that there are two groups in respect to the
resource: included users and excluded persons. The first group consists of
an identifiable and countable number of users. The second set of persons
do not have the right to use the resource (Stevenson, 1991). This is in con-
trast to open access where everyone is a potential user. Third, more than
two users utilize a common property resource. This clearly distinguishes
common property from private property, where a single person is consid-
ered to be the sole owner. Fourth, the existence of rules (formal/informal)
regarding resource appropriation and exploitation in order to guide the
groups of resource users is the main characteristic that helps distinguish
common property from an open access condition. This includes how rights
are transferred, what financial obligation a user has to the group, what
contribution he or she makes and how the rules themselves are changed.
The rules may be formal and explicit or they may be informal and implic-
itly accepted (Stevenson, 1991).
The fifth point provides an essential difference between common and
private property. It also highlights the relationship between common prop-
erty and a public good. Unlike common property, in private property the
in situ resource belongs to a particular owner. However, under a common
134 A handbook of environmental management
property regime, the user may have a secure expectation of getting certain
amounts of product from the commons, but not particular physical units.
The joint, non-exclusive entitlement condition means that participants in
common property arrangements have simultaneous, ex ante claims on any
particular unit of the resource and it can be argued that an essential step
in the use of common property resources (except the resources that have a
pure public good characteristic) is that they be ‘reduced’ to sole ownership
by capture (Stevenson, 1991). As indicated earlier, point five also provides
some basis to distinguish between common property and public goods.
First, some common property resources like national parks, reserves and
so on have public good characteristics that do not exhibit rivalry at low or
moderate levels of use. Reducing the resource to sole ownership through
capture does not apply in the way that it does to resources that exhibit
rivalry in extraction. Second, these resources exhibit joint, non-exclusive
entitlement, because all participants who use the resource have an ex
ante claim to benefits from the resource. For these reasons, reduction to
sole ownership through capture is not a necessary condition for common
property, but joint, non-exclusive entitlement is (Stevenson, 1991).
Point six indicates that, though multiple users compete for the resource
appropriation and exploitation in common property, they undertake
mutual capital investments in resource conservation. To better understand
this idea, reconsider the problem of common goods. As in an open access
condition, extraction by one user of the resource in a common property
regime may generate negative externalities for other users. However, the
difference lies in the extent to which externalities are generated. Point
seven recognizes that the resource users and resource owners do not
always coincide in a common property regime. Common property rights
holders may rent their resource use rights to the actual users subject to
the condition that the rights holders are a group of people who fulfil the
institutional criteria of common property regimes (Stevenson, 1991).
This is not meant to preclude the situation in which a government entity
coordinates or imposes rules regarding resource extraction on users and
rights holders. A common property resource, therefore, is a resource held
by an identifiable community of interdependent users in which these users
exclude outsiders while regulating use by members of the local community
(Feeny et al., 1998).
Nature of the Firm’, Coase (1937) discussed why firms exist and sowed
the seed of the concept of transaction costs in the economics literature.
Coase underlines the important role of transaction costs in the organiza-
tion of firms and other contracts. Coase’s theory was later developed by
many scholars (Coase, 1960; Cheung, 1969, 1983; Alchian and Demsetz,
1972; Williamson, 1985). Coase (1960) observed that identifying relevant
parties, collecting information, undertaking negotiation, enforcing agree-
ments and so on could be sufficiently costly to prevent many transactions
from being achieved. When two or more parties agree to exchange or
transfer goods or services, the transaction can be seen as a form of con-
tract (Drennan, 2000). Arrow (1969) defines transaction costs as the costs
of running the economic system. Transaction costs are the costs of arrang-
ing, monitoring, or enforcing agreements; the cost associated with all the
exchanges that take place within an economy (Eggertsson, 1990; North,
1990). North (1997, p. 150) points out, ‘the study of transaction costs, in
addition to giving us insights into static economic analysis, also holds the
key to unlocking the doors to an improved understanding of economic
and societal performance through time’.
The importance of transaction costs can be studied through ‘transaction
cost economics (TCE)’, which is a new type of economics first mentioned
in Williamson (1991). According to him, TCE is focused on reducing
maladaptation costs through ex ante selection of governance structure
for the antecedent conditions. Its working hypothesis is that economic
organization is really an effort to ‘align transactions, which differ in their
attributes, with governance structures, which differ in their costs and com-
petencies, in a discriminating (mainly, transaction cost economizing) way’
(Williamson, 1991). TCE tries to explain how trading partners choose,
from the set of feasible institutional alternatives, the arrangements that
offer protection for their relationship-specific investments at the lowest
total cost (Shelanski and Klein, 1995). TCE maintains that in a complex
world, contracts are typically incomplete because agents are boundedly
rational, or because certain quantities or outcomes are unobservable. Due
to this incompleteness, parties who invest in relationship-specific assets
expose themselves to a risk: if circumstances change, their trading partners
may try to expropriate the rents accruing to the specific assets. A variety
of governance structures could be adopted in order to avoid this risk.
Nevertheless, the appropriate one depends on the particular character-
istics of the relationship. In this respect, TCE can be seen as the study of
alternative institutions of governance.
Transaction costs are incurred in different stages of production and
exchange. Dahlman (1979) separates transaction costs into three broad cat-
egories: (1) search and information costs, (2) bargaining and decision costs
136 A handbook of environmental management
and (3) policing and enforcement costs. He documented that all of these
costs represent resource losses due to lack of information. Transaction
costs are a real and unavoidable aspect of any economic system. It is not
even possible to eliminate transaction costs by prohibiting all transac-
tions because such a decree would have to be deliberated and enforced
and other institutions would emerge to replace banned markets. Libecap
(1989) points out that having lower transaction costs is a necessary rather
than a sufficient condition for adoption of an institutional arrangement.
The inevitability of transaction costs means that any notion of Pareto
optimality7 is incomplete until transaction costs are incorporated (Griffin,
1991). It is therefore appropriate to examine transaction costs when evalu-
ating the potential of new institutions as alternatives to the existing one.
Transactions differ in a variety of ways. Williamson (1985) identifies
asset specificity, uncertainty and frequency as three major attributes of
transactions that have direct cost implications. These three attributes of
the transactions are also relevant to many natural resource systems. Asset
specificity can be defined as investment in assets specifically relevant for
a particular transaction. This is generally regarded as the most impor-
tant of the three attributes because it creates market imperfections and
allows asset owners to earn rents (Drennan, 2000). It can take the form
of a physical asset related to location, an asset dedicated to a particular
consumer, or a tangible asset that can be easily duplicated. It turns out
to be the case that asset specificity creates information asymmetry, which
permits owners to earn economic rents. Having private information
makes it possible for people to behave opportunistically towards others
who contract for their services. However, asset specificity also reduces the
mobility of assets into alternative uses, with consequent market imperfec-
tions (Drennan, 2000). Most of the physical assets in the form of natural
resources (forests, wildlife, fish and so on) are very site specific. Based
upon this site specificity, species are considered endemic or endangered in
their natural habitat. Transactions in natural resource systems also differ
in the required specificity of human resources. It is useful to distinguish
between idiosyncratic site-specific knowledge, especially the indigenous
knowledge of a local community, and scientific knowledge required for
planning and implementation of resource management activities (Birner
and Wittmer, 2000).
The second attribute of transactions with costly implications for con-
tracting is the extent of uncertainty surrounding the contract. Transactions
surrounded by little or no uncertainty require minimal governance because
ex ante and ex post information about the transaction is available to all
concerned parties while uncertainty in defining and observing perform-
ance makes it difficult to place contracts on that performance (Drennan,
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 137
TCDcc
TCIp
TCDp TCIcc
Care-intensity Care-intensity
Threat to resource Threat to resource
Measurement costs Measurement costs
TCp
TChp
TCcc
Transaction costs
c1 c2
Care-intensity
Threat to resource
Measurement costs
TChp TCcc
Transaction costs TCp'
TC hp' TCp
TCcc'
c⬘ Care-intensity
Threat to resource
Measurement costs
suggests that sole state ownership over natural resources is less likely to
be efficient in protecting these resources. For example, biodiversity losses
may increase more rapidly due to difficulties faced by state governance in
preventing over-exploitation of biological resources due to high enforce-
ment and monitoring costs. As discussed earlier, increased social capital
reduces the transaction costs of collective action through coordinating
the resource users and implementation of instruments of social control.
Figure 5.3 shows that hybrid private governance is comparatively efficient
for c . c9 and co-management is the optimal choice for c . c9 (Birner and
Wittmer, 2000).
Table 5.2 provides a summary of the institutional choice and govern-
ance structure for natural resource management under different state
capability and social capital.
If both state capability and social capital are low, private sector manage-
ment with state regulation is superior to community-based management.
This significantly reduces the transaction costs of resource management.
Participatory management is especially suited to cases where there is a
high probability of strong community participation. User involvement
in decision-making processes enhances compliance with resource use
regulation. Moreover, community-based management is best suited where
equity issues need to be taken into account. Co-management may be the
optimal choice where governance structure places less demand on social
146 A handbook of environmental management
Empirical studies
Having described transaction cost theory and the criteria in selecting
appropriate governance structures I now provide a brief overview of
empirical attempts that try to measure the transaction costs of collec-
tive action. The concern in this section is with three types of transaction
costs: (1) information costs, (2) bargaining costs and (3) enforcement
costs, as described in the previous section. Very few empirical studies
have attempted to measure the transaction costs of community-based
resource management. Davies and Richards (1999) extensively reviewed
the literature on economic analysis of participatory forest management to
Table 5.3 Important attributes of different property rights’ structure in natural resource management
147
Demand on frame conditions
State capability ++ − − + + +
Social capital − ++ − + − +
Accommodation of public
interests
Local − ++ − + − ++
Higher level/Sovereign ++ − − ++ ++ +
understand the incentives for different stakeholders. They found that these
studies tend to be biased towards benefits in general as opposed to costs like
transaction costs and ex ante studies for project preparation as opposed to
ex post monitoring and impact analysis. Cheung (1987) suggests that the
challenge to economists is to specify and identify what these transaction
costs are and how they will vary under differing circumstances.
Despite this, few empirical studies on transaction costs exist. For
example, Crocker (1971) conducted an empirical analysis of the role of
transaction costs in natural resource transfer using the case of the impact
of air pollution on agricultural land use. He concluded that transaction
costs for affected farmland owners to bargain with polluters were very
high. Leffler and Rucker (1990) applied transaction costs analysis to the
structure of timber harvesting contracts and established empirical evidence
for the influence of specific types of transaction costs on contractual pro-
visions. Kumm and Drake (1998) estimated the private transaction costs
incurred in relation to participation in the Swedish agri-environmental
programme, using data from a survey of 90 randomly selected farmers.
Transaction costs were defined to include expenditure for assistance from
agriculture or conservation consultants, mapping, communication costs
related to participation and time inputs (individuals’ working hours). On
average, consultants’ costs accounted for approximately one-third of the
total costs and the individuals’ labour accounted for approximately two-
thirds. Transaction costs, as a share of actual compensation received, are
typically around 12 per cent and private transaction costs have risen over
recent years.
Drake et al. (1999) carried out a pan-European survey to determine
the cause of participation and non-participation of farmers in agri-
environmental programmes in eight EU member states. They outlined a
theoretical econometric participation function related to parameters like
the direct resource costs of conservation (in terms of reduced production
levels), the direct utility of the farmer derived from conservation activities,
and the transaction costs borne by farmers in relation to participation.
They found that transaction costs borne by farmers might pose constraints
on participation. Information-gathering, for example, on the economics
of organic conversion and how to change management practices, is often
a key component of the transaction costs incurred by farmers wishing to
participate in conservation schemes (Drake et al., 1999).
Aggarwal (2000) undertook a case study of group-owned wells in
southern India in an attempt to understand the possibilities and limita-
tions to cooperation in small groups by looking at the transaction costs
associated with these activities. He observed that start-up costs of well
construction in these villages included the costs associated with digging,
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 149
Platteau (1996, p. 301), point out that, too often, ‘heterogeneity is blamed
as a matter of principle without enough effort being devoted to spelling
out the precise conditions under which it undermines collective action’.
Indeed, the role of group heterogeneity in the evolution of local manage-
ment institutions is ambiguous. What deserves credit in this respect is to
clarify the various forms of heterogeneity and the way they bear upon
collective action dilemmas. In the subsequent discussion I will critically
examine group heterogeneity and the success or failure of collective action
drawing upon evidence from theoretical and empirical work from both the
economic and social science literatures.
The source of heterogeneities are diverse, and include differences in
asset holding, appropriation skills and access to technology, caste, gender,
ethnicity, opportunity cost, political influence and other local differences,
which might influence the equity of resource distribution and thus per-
formance of collective action. Kant (2000, p. 288), points out, ‘resource
users will often have somewhat different preferences regarding resource
management, or assign different priorities to the various objectives of
resource management, either because of differing personal interest in the
resource or differing degree of involvement in the social group’. The het-
erogeneity of individual interest with respect to how a resource is managed
affects individual incentives and thus economic use of the local commons.
As rightly pointed out by Seabright (1993), the degree of trust economic
agents, participating in some form of collective action, have in one another
serves a crucial role in common property regimes. He developed a model
of ‘habit forming’ cooperation. The model revealed the fact that players’
belief about each other’s trustworthiness is confirmed and contributes
to cooperative behaviour. Such a ‘habit-forming’ process is, however,
unlikely to work in a community which starts with a high level of het-
erogeneity with respect to resource management preference (Kant, 1998).
Moreover, economic inequality or socioeconomic heterogeneity among
the members of a resource-using group might be associated with different
degrees of access to, and control over, the local commons. Intra-group
heterogeneity in terms of private payoffs, therefore, can often lead to con-
flicts of interest and thus hinder the emergence of egalitarian institutions
and the performance of any cooperative arrangements. Ostrom (1990)
argues that none of the successful CPR situations involves participants
who vary greatly in regard to ownership of assets, skills, ethnicity, race, or
other variables that could strongly divide a group of individuals.
Socioeconomic heterogeneity, relative income effect and the political
framework in which policy decisions are taken determine the benefit-
sharing arrangements in commons management. Income inequality pro-
duces the gap between poor individuals’ ability to pay and willingness to
152 A handbook of environmental management
pay for collective action. The level of the poorer users is so low that they
might not be able to participate in community-based management systems,
because they cannot meet the costs involved. For example, groups that
depend heavily on daily wage labour sometimes find it difficult to contrib-
ute their share of resource management costs. As a result they are deemed
ineligible for the benefits. McKean (2000) observes that common property
regimes do not always serve to equalize income within the user group.
Communities may vary enormously in how equally or unequally they
distribute the products of the commons to eligible users. Decision-making
rights tend to be egalitarian in the formal sense; however, richer house-
holds may actually have additional social influence on decisions due to the
relative strength of their socioeconomic position. Greater homogeneity,
on the other hand, promotes both equity and efficiency by facilitating the
adoption of more coordination and cooperative arrangements at the local
level. In a similar vein, Guggenheim and Spears (1991) argue that in light
of likely scenarios of sociopolitical heterogeneity within spatially defined
community groupings, participation in community decision-making can
be skewed in favour of more powerful subgroups. Asymmetries among
participants facing CPR provision and appropriation problems, therefore,
can present substantial barriers to overcoming the disincentives associated
with collective action (Ostrom and Gardner, 1993).
The sources of heterogeneities are diverse and there are several possible
definitions of heterogeneity. A number of researchers seem to be much
focused on economic inequality as a major source of heterogeneity, that is,
inequality in wealth or income among the community members involved
in collective action. However, Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson (2000) also
noted other kinds of inequality within a resource-dependent community
such as ethnic and social heterogeneity, and environmental or state vari-
ables like low levels of trust or social cohesion. They noted a U-shaped
relationship between inequality and commons management: very high
and very low levels of inequality are associated with better commons
performance, while mid-range levels of inequality are associated with
poor outcomes. Social heterogeneity increases the cost of negotiation
and bargaining inherent in the process of crafting institutions. Economic
inequality, combined with other constraints, severely limits the possible
bargaining outcomes available to resource users. In this regard, inter-
related ‘commons outcomes’ that might be affected by inequality include
resource conservation, maintenance of infrastructure, the supply of local
institutions, monitoring and enforcement of regulations and conflict
resolution (Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson, 2000).
Economic opportunities available to resource users outside the local
commons are considered to be a complicated form of heterogeneity that
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 153
Bardhan (1999) considers ‘exit options’. He argues that the effect of exit
options on conservation is complicated. Nonetheless, this depends in part
on the nature of the relationship between wealth and the exit options. If a
resource harvester’s exit option is a concave function of wealth – meaning
that the value of the outside option rises very quickly with wealth at low
levels of wealth, but increases more slowly at higher wealth levels – then
increases in inequality, starting from relatively equal wealth distributions,
will reduce conservation and thus performance of cooperative arrange-
ments. In that case, the relatively poorer harvesters will not be interested
in optimal conservation; as her/his wealth declines, their gain from con-
servation falls off more rapidly than the gain from exercising her/his exit
option. On the other hand, if the exit option is a convex function of the
wealth level then increased inequality might either enhance or damage
the prospects for conservation: the effect is intermediate. If resource users
have relatively lucrative earnings outside the commons, this can affect
their individual incentives. Wealthier households might have reduced
incentives to participate in collective action, as their wealth endowments
afford them attractive outside earning opportunities. For those enjoying
such opportunities, the discounted value of their future income flows from
the CPR may fall below that of alternative incomes available. On the
other hand, users lacking such outside opportunities attach a higher value
to the future state of the resources, which may enhance the likelihood of
collective action.
In his simple numerical model, Kanbur (1992) investigated the role of
group heterogeneity in the success or failure of common property resource
management. He argues that cooperative arrangements are less likely
when agents are highly heterogeneous. Moreover, existing arrangements
are also likely to break down as a group becomes more heterogeneous.
Drawing upon the conclusions from various case studies, he vividly
presents the fact that greater equity (at least greater homogeneity) pro-
motes greater efficiency by facilitating adoption of cooperative arrange-
ments, in situations where externalities make non-cooperative outcomes
inefficient. Tang (1992) presents a synthesis based on careful analysis of
47 case studies of community irrigation systems and found that a low
variance of average family income among irrigators tends to be associated
with a high degree of rule conformance and good maintenance: 72 per
cent more of the cases with low-income variance are characterized by both
a high degree of rule conformance and good maintenance than the cases
with high income variance. This finding may throw new light on the fact
that successful schemes are to be found in relatively homogeneous commu-
nities, and it is precisely in these communities that one is unlikely to find
arrangements that favour one subgroup over another (Kanbur, 1992).
154 A handbook of environmental management
Molinas’ findings, his model shows that the effect of economic inequality
is complicated and not monotonic (Dayton-Johnson, 2000).
Varughese and Ostrom (2001) investigate the role of heterogeneity in
affecting the likelihood of collective action in a study of 18 forest user
groups in Nepal. Their study focuses on some important community
attributes that affect users’ incentives to cooperate in resource manage-
ment like the size of the community of resource users, locational differ-
ences among users with respect to forest areas, differences in forest users’
income and presence or absence of economic/social/ethnic disparities
and the availability of alternative forest resources. They, however, con-
clude that social and cultural heterogeneity does not have a determinant
impact on the likelihood or success of collective action. Successful groups
overcome stressful heterogeneities by crafting innovative institutional
arrangements well matched to their local circumstances within which user
groups decide how to organize themselves and which rules to adapt to
allocate rights and duties as well as costs and benefits. They further argue
that communities would collectively manage local-level natural resources
where there are very substantive benefits to be obtained through collective
action. Heterogeneity is not a variable with a uniform effect on the likeli-
hood of organizing self-governing enterprises, as communities put effort
into devising rules to cope with heterogeneities and they may be able to
invest more heavily in finding effective rules that are considered fair, effec-
tive and efficient to most users (Varughese and Ostrom, 2001).
A study of CPR management in Fulanui village in Mali (Velded, 2000)
demonstrated little direct relationship between the degree of heterogene-
ity and the success of collective action. It was found that homogeneity
among elite groups enhanced capacity for collective action. However,
when heterogeneity in economic interests between elite groups intensi-
fied and coincided with other dimensions of heterogeneity, such as het-
erogeneity in economic wealth, access to land and CPRs and agreement
over authority of the leadership, the collective action became difficult to
achieve. He further observed that heterogeneity of wealth and ethnicity
do not prevent ‘common interest’ among elite and subordinate groups in
collective action. Rather, Velded argues that the political elite of the com-
munity can assume leadership in local organization of CPR management
and provide an authority structure for monitoring and rule enforcement.
On the other hand, conflict was observed in a similar setting when eco-
nomic interests differed with regard to use of CPRs. Moreover, in terms of
resource use, access to local CPR grazing is more exclusively for the noble
elite and influential section of the community. This study suggests that as
long as there is reasonable homogeneity among elite groups, cooperative
outcomes can be relatively persistent even among heterogeneous social
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 157
groups (Velded, 2000). However, in line with Baland and Platteau (1995,
1996), Velded emphasized that there is a need to distinguish between
various forms of heterogeneity in analysis and explanation of collective
action, especially in relation to heterogeneity in endowments, entitlements
(wealth) and economic interests.
Kant (2000) developed an optimal control model for a dynamic
approach to forest regimes in developing economies integrating the natural
system and socioeconomic factors of the resource users. The model dem-
onstrates that the dynamics of the optimal forest regimes depend on the
change in natural factors, socioeconomic factors (user group heterogene-
ity) and on the interaction between natural and socioeconomic factors.
The model defines cultural, economic, ethical and other social differences
as a basic level of heterogeneity. Due to this basic heterogeneity, members
of the user groups may have diverse preferences for timber and non-timber
products and hence prefer a different mix of products, which is considered
as second-level heterogeneity. Preference for diversified forest products
often leads to different preferences for resource management regimes,
which can be further described as a third level of heterogeneity. Therefore,
heterogeneity with respect to resource regimes is treated as a function of
the product preference differences, which in turn is treated as a function of
cultural, economic and social heterogeneity. Though the model is crucial
to understanding optimal resource regimes, their linkages with socioeco-
nomic factors (heterogeneity), and the dynamics of these optimal regimes
and socioeconomic factors, it is explicit about how and to what extent
intra-community heterogeneity or wealth endowment affects equitable
benefit-sharing mechanisms among resource users.
While there has been a great deal of work on the management of local
environmental resources in recent years, there has been surprising little
work, either theoretical or empirical, on how inequality helps or hinders
cooperative management of the local commons (Bardhan, 1999). Not much
is understood on how socioeconomic status of resource users promotes or
discourages participation in CPR management and consequently the equity
of resource distribution. Nonetheless, evidence from South Asia suggests
that the socioeconomic status of resource users may place stringent limits
on the extent to which certain groups are able to participate and benefit
from the management of CPRs. The landless, agropastoralists, and other
politically and economically marginalized user groups may not be able to
take advantage of incentives for tree growing (Guggenheim and Spears,
1991). Moreover, participatory forest management in South Asia illustrates
the sharp equity problem elsewhere since social structure itself is for the
most part inherently unequal. These resource management initiatives were
supposed to help the poorest of the village population, lighten women’s
158 A handbook of environmental management
workload and relieve family budgets. The income of many such projects,
however, has been invested in other community development activities
like village schools, rural roads and small-scale irrigation and very often
productivity gained from such investments is captured by relatively well-
off farmers. Entitlement to products of the commons varies to a surprising
extent (McKean, 1992a). Hill and Shields (1998) observed that the com-
munity incentives in joint forest management (JFM) in India are not so
clear-cut, however, the main losses in JFM are fuel wood head loaders who
are often from the poorest subgroup within the village. Many studies have
shown that the poor and the disadvantaged do not necessarily benefit from
community-based forest management (Bhatia, 1999). While the aggre-
gate gains from reducing common pool problems or promoting economic
growth through the definition or redefinition of property rights are unlikely
to be controversial, the distribution of wealth and political power inherent
in the proposed rights structure will be a source of dispute (Libecap, 1989).
The recent literature on common property resource management,
however, indicates that sustaining environmental resources is not depend-
ent on a particular structure of property rights regime, but rather on a
well-specified property rights regime and a congruence of that regime with
its ecological and social context (Hanna and Munasinghe, 1995). Success
of the property rights regime depends upon the congruence of ecosystem
and governance boundaries, the specification and representation of inter-
ests, the matching of governance structure to ecosystem characteristics,
the containment of transaction costs and the establishment of monitoring,
enforcement and adoption processes at the appropriate scale (Eggertsson,
1990; Ostrom, 1990; Bromley, 1991 and Hanna et al., 1995). More impor-
tantly, the equity and distributional aspects of the CPR regime are con-
sidered to be one of the major determinants of long-term sustainability
of CPR institutions. Since the nature of property rights regimes and the
distribution of access to natural resources affect both the level of poverty
and the quantity and quality of the environmental resource base in the
long run (Dasgupta and Maler, 1991), property rights institutions will
have to be more egalitarian in order to avoid unilateral appropriations of
the commons. Empirical regularities that link inequality to better or worse
outcomes of community-based resource management would be a basis for
asset redistribution programmes including land reform and poverty alle-
viation that target communities based on the level of inequality (Bardhan
and Dayton-Johnson, 2000).
Conclusions
This chapter explores the role of institutions in managing local-level envi-
ronmental resources. The basic purpose was to explain the emergence of
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 159
Notes
1. I borrow the idea of Libecap (1989) to conceptualize the process of defining or changing
property rights in terms of contracting. Contracting includes both private bargaining to
assign or adjust informal ownership arrangements and lobbying efforts among private
claimants, politicians and bureaucrats to define, administer and modify more formal
property institutions (Libecap, 1989).
2. Common pool resources refer to the natural resource that is available in the commons,
whereas common property regime refers to the institutional property rights arrangement
by which the resource is managed. The two are often confused as the same acronym,
CPR, is used for both.
3. Williamson (2000) notes that NIE operates at two different levels: macro and micro. The
macro level deals with the institutional environment, or rules of the game, which affect
the behaviour and performance of economic actors in which organizational forms and
transactions are embedded. Williamson discusses it as the set of fundamental political,
162 A handbook of environmental management
social and legal ground rules that establish the basis for production, exchange and dis-
tribution. The micro-level analysis, on the other hand, also known as the institutional
arrangements, deals with the institution of governance. These refer to the modes of man-
aging transactions including market, quasi-market and hierarchical modes of contract-
ing (Williamson, 2000).
4. Public goods are resources that can be accessed by anyone and the consumption of the
resource by one person does not affect the consumption by anyone else. Enjoyment of
a sunrise is a classic example. However, many natural resource public goods can be
readily over-exploited, which is why property rights need to be defined and consumption
regulated.
5. Economic rent is the difference between the actual cost of bringing something into pro-
duction and the amount that is paid for the product. Economic rents are low if there is a
lot of competition and tend to be higher when there are monopolies.
6. Production externalities are costs of production that are incurred by someone other than
the producer. For example, a logging company exploiting old growth forest will pay
stumpage costs on each tree extracted to the owner of the land, but does not compensate
society for the loss of a valuable habitat.
7. Pareto optimality is when goods are exchanged until no one can be made better off
without someone being made worse off. Under these conditions the market is efficient in
that it is responsive to supply and demand.
8. Social capital comprises features of social organization such as networks, norms and
trust that can improve the efficiency of a community by facilitating cooperation and
coordination of relations between actors and among actors (see Coleman, 1990; Putnam,
1993). Social capital is also productive since it makes possible the achievement of certain
outcomes that would not be attainable otherwise (Coleman, 1990; Molians, 1998) and it
also reduces the transaction costs of collective action.
References
Adhikari, B. and J.C. Lovett (2006a), ‘Transaction Costs and Community-based Natural
Resource Management in Nepal’, Journal of Environmental Management, 78(1), 5–15.
Adhikari, B. and J.C. Lovett (2006b), ‘Institutions and Collective Action: Does Heterogeneity
Matter in Community-based Resource Management?’, Journal of Development Studies,
42(3), 426–45.
Adhikari, B., S. Di Falco and J.C. Lovett (2004), ‘Household Characteristics and Forest
Dependency: Evidence from Common Property Forest Management in Nepal’, Ecological
Economics, 48(2), 245–57.
Aggarwal, R.M. (2000), ‘Possibilities and Limitations to Cooperation in Small Groups:
The Case of Group-owned Wells in Southern India’, World Development, 28(8),
1481–97.
Alchian, A.A. (1965), ‘Some Economics of Property’, II Politico, 30(4), 816–29.
Alchian, A.A. and H. Demsetz (1972), ‘Production, Information Costs, and Economic
Organization’, American Economic Review, 62(5), 777–95.
Aredo, D. (1999), ‘Institution and Development: A Note on Conceptual Framework’,
Economic Focus, 2(2).
Arrow, K.J. (1969), ‘The Organization of Economic Activity: Issues Pertinent to the Choice
of Market versus Non-market Allocation’, in The Analysis and Evaluation of Public
Expenditure: The PBB-System, Joint Economic Committee, 91st Congress, 1st Session,
Vol 1, Washington, DC.
Axelrod, R. (1981), ‘The Emergence of Co-operation among Egoists’, American Political
Science Review, 75(2), 306–18.
Baden, J.A. (1998), ‘A New Primer for the Management of Common-pool Resources and
Public Goods’, in J.A. Baden and D. Noonan (eds), Managing the Commons, Bloomington,
IN: Indiana University Press.
Baland, J. and J. Platteau (1995), ‘Does Heterogeneity Hinder Collective Action?’, Working
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 163
Coleman, J.S. (1990), Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Cox, S.J.B. (1985), ‘ No Tragedy on the Commons’, Environmental Ethics, 7(1), 49–61.
Crocker, T.D. (1971), ‘Externalities, Property Rights and Transactions Costs: An Empirical
Study’, Journal of Law and Economics, 14(2), 451–64.
Dahlman, C.J. (1979), ‘The Problem of Externality’, Journal of Law and Economics, 22(1),
141–62.
Dasgupta, P. (1999), ‘Economic Progress and the Idea of Social Capital’, in P. Dasgupta
and I. Serageldin (eds), Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, Washington, DC: The
World Bank.
Dasgupta, P.S. and G.M. Heal (1979), Economic Theory and Exhaustible Resources,
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Dasgupta, P. and K.G. Maler (1991), ‘The Environment and Emerging Development Issues’,
Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Issues.
Davies, J. and M. Richards (1999), ‘The Use of Economics to Assess Stakeholders’ Incentives
in Participatory Forest Management: A Review’, European Union Tropical Forestry
Paper No. 5, Overseas Development Institute, London.
Dayton-Johnson, J. (2000), ‘Determinants of Collective Action on the Local Commons: A
Model with Evidence from Mexico’, Journal of Development Economics, 62(1), 181–208.
Demsetz, H. (1964), ‘The Exchange and Enforcement of Property Rights’, Journal of Law
and Economics, 70(4), 414–30.
Demsetz, H. (1967), ‘Towards a Theory of Property Rights’, American Economic Review,
52(2), 347–79.
Dove, M.R. (1993), ‘A Revisionist View of Tropical Deforestation and Development’,
Environment Conservation, 20(1), 17–24.
Drake, L., P. Bergstrom and H. Svedsater (1999), ‘Farmers’ Attitude to and Uptake of
Countryside Stewardship Policies’, draft final report to the STEWPOL Project, Chapter 5,
FAIRI/CT95/0709, University of Uppsala, Sweden.
Drennan, L.G. (2000), ‘The Efficient Mix of Performance Controls: A Transaction Cost
Economics Perspective’, Proceedings of International Symposium of New Institutional
Economics, 22–24 September 2000, Tubingen, Germany.
Eggertsson, T. (1990), Economic Behaviour and Institutions, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.
Falconer, K. (2000), ‘Farm-level Constraints on Agri-environmental Scheme Participation:
A Transactional Perspective’, Journal of Rural Studies, 16(3), 379–94.
Feeny, D., F. Berkes, B.J. McCay and J.M. Acheson (1998), ‘The Tragedy of the Commons:
Twenty-two Years Later’, in J. Baden and D. Noonan (eds), Managing the Commons,
Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.
Fenoaltea, S. (1984), ‘Slavery and Supervision in Comparative Perspectives: A Model’,
Journal of Economic History, 44(3), 635–68.
Gibbs, J.N. and D.W. Bromley (1989), ‘Institutional Arrangements for Management of
Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes’, in F. Berkes (ed.), Common Property
Resources: Ecology and Community-based Sustainable Development, London: Belhaven
Press.
Gordon, H.S. (1954), ‘The Economic Theory of a Common Pool Resource: The Fishery’,
Journal of Political Economy, 62(2), 124–42.
Griffin, R.C. (1991), ‘The Welfare Analytics of Transaction Costs, Externalities and
Institutional Choice’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, August, 601–14.
Grima, A.P.L. and F. Berkes (1989), ‘Natural Resources: Access, Rights-to-use and
Management’, in F. Berkes (ed.), Common Property Resources – Ecology and Community
Based Sustainable Development, London: Belhaven Press.
Guggenheim, S. and J. Spears (1991), ‘Sociological and Environmental Dimension of Social
Forestry Projects’, in M.M. Carnea (ed.), Putting People First: Sociological Variables in
Rural Development, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 304–39.
Hanna, S. (1995), ‘Efficiencies of User Participation in Natural Resource Management’,
in S. Hanna and M. Munasinghe (eds), Property Rights and the Environment: Social and
How institutions affect the management of environmental resources 165
Ecological Issues, The Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics and The
World Bank.
Hanna, S. and M. Munasinghe (1995), ‘An Introduction to Property Rights and the
Environment’, in S. Hanna and M. Munasinghe (eds), Property Rights and the Environment:
Social and Ecological Issues, The Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics
and The World Bank.
Hanna, S., C. Folke and K. Maler (1995), ‘Property Rights and Environmental Resources’,
in S. Hanna and M. Munasinghe (eds), Property Rights and the Environment: Social and
Ecological Issues, The Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics and The
World Bank.
Hardin, G. (1968), ‘The Tragedy of Commons’, Science, 162(3859), 1243–8.
Hill, I. and D. Shields (1998), ‘Incentives for Joint Forest Management in India: Analytical
Methods and Case Studies’, World Bank Technical Paper No. 394, Washington, DC: The
World Bank.
Johnson, O.E.G. (1972), ‘Economic Analysis, the Legal Framework and Land Tenure
Systems’, Journal of Law and Economics, 15(1), 259–76.
Kanbur, R. (1992), ‘Heterogeneity, Distribution and Cooperation in Common Property
Resource Management’, background paper for the 1992 World Development Report, Office
of the Vice President, Development Economics, The World Bank, Washington, DC.
Kant, S. (1998), ‘Community Management: An Optimal Resource Regime for Tropical
Forests’, Department of Economics, Faculty of Forestry, University of Toronto, mimeo.
Kant, S. (2000), ‘A Dynamic Approach to Forest Regimes in Developing Economies’,
Ecological Economics, 32(2), 287–300.
Keohane, R.O. and E. Ostrom (eds) (1995), Local Commons and Global Interdependence,
Heterogeneity and Cooperation in Two Domains, London: Sage.
Kherallah, M. and J. Kirsten (2001), ‘The New Institutional Economics: Applications
for Agricultural Policy Research in Developing Countries’, International Food Policy
Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington, DC.
Kumm, K.I. and L. Drake (1998), ‘Transaction Costs to Farmers of Environmental
Compensation’, unpublished report, Department of Economics, SLU, University of
Uppsala, Sweden.
Kuperan, K., N. Mustapha, R. Abdullah, R.S. Pomeroy, E. Genio and A. Salamanca (1998),
‘Measuring Transaction Costs of Fisheries Co-management’, paper presented at the 7th
Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property,
Vancouver, www.indiana.edu/~iasip/Drafts/kuperan.pdf, accessed 18 August 2009.
Leffler, K. and R. Rucker (1990), ‘Transaction Costs and the Efficient Organization of
Production: A Study of Timber Harvesting Contracts’, Journal of Political Economy,
99(5), 1060–87.
Libecap, G. (1989), Contracting for Property Rights, New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Lin, J.Y. and J.B. Nugent (1995), ‘Institution and Economic Development’, in J. Behrman
and T.N. Srinivasan (eds), Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. III, Amsterdam:
Elsevier, pp. 2303–70
McKean, M. (1992a), ‘Success on the Commons: A Comparative Examination of Institutions
for Common Property Resource Management’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 4(3),
247–81.
McKean, M. (1992b), ‘Management of Traditional Common Lands (Iriachi) in Japan’, in
National Research Council Proceedings of the Conference on Common Property Resource
Management, Washington, DC: National Academic Press, pp. 533–89.
McKean, M. (2000), ‘Common Property: What It Is, What Is It Good for, and What
Makes It Work’, ‘Forests, People and Governance: Some Initial Theoretical Lessons’,
in C.C. Gibson, M.A. McKean and E. Ostrom (eds), People and Forests, Communities,
Institutions, and Governance, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Meinzen-Dick, R. and A. Knox (1999), ‘Collective Action, Property Rights and Devolution
of Natural Resource Management: A Conceptual Framework’, paper presented at the
166 A handbook of environmental management
Runge, C.F. (1984), ‘Institutions and the Free Rider: The Assurance Problem in Collective
Action’, Journal of Politics, 46, 154–89.
Schlager, E. and W. Blomquist (1998), ‘Resolving Common Pool Resource Dilemmas and
Heterogeneities Among Resource Users’, paper presented at ‘Crossing Boundaries’, the
Seventh Annual Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common
Property, 10–14 June, Vancouver, BC, Canada.
Scott, A. (1955), ‘The Fishery: The Objectives of Sole Ownership’, Journal of Political
Economy, 63(2), 116–24.
Seabright, P. (1993), ‘Managing Local Commons: Theoretical Issues in Incentive Design’,
The Journal of Economic Perspective, 7(4), 113–34.
Shelanski, H.A. and P.G. Klein (1995), ‘Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics:
A Review and Assessment’, The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 11(2),
335–61.
Smith, R.J. (1981), ‘Resolving the Tragedy of the Commons by Creating Private Property
Rights in Wildlife’, CATO Journal, 1(2), 439–68.
Smith, V.L. (1968), ‘Economics from Production of Natural Resources’, American Economic
Review, 58(3), 409–31.
Stevenson, G.G. (1991), Common Property Economics: A General Theory and Land Use
Application, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Sugden, R. (1984), ‘Reciprocity: The Supply of Public Goods through Voluntary
Contributions’, Economic Journal, 94(376), 772–87.
Tang, S.Y. (1992), Institutions and Collective Action: The Case of Irrigation Systems, San
Francisco: ICS Press.
Uphoff, N. (1998), ‘Community-based Natural Resource Management: Connecting
Micro and Macro Processes, and People with their Environment’, paper presented at
International Workshop in Community-based Natural Resource Management, 10–14
May, Washington, DC: World Bank.
Varughese, J. (1999), ‘Villagers, Bureaucrats, and Forests in Nepal: Designing Governance
for Complex Resource’, unpublished PhD dissertation, Indiana University, USA.
Varughese, J. and E. Ostrom (2001), ‘The Contested Role of Heterogeneity in Collective
Action: Some Evidence from Community Forestry in Nepal’, World Development, 29(5),
747–65.
Vätn, A. (2001), ‘Environmental Resources, Property Regimes, and Efficiency’, Environment
and Planning: Government and Policy, 19(5) 665–80.
Velded, T. (2000), ‘Village Politics: Heterogeneity, Leadership and Collective Action’,
Journal of Development Studies, 36(5), 105–34.
Wallace, M.B. (1981), ‘Solving Common-property Resource Problems: Deforestation in
Nepal’, unpublished PhD Dissertation, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.
Wang, N. (2001), ‘The Coevolution of Institutions, Organizations, and Ideology: The
Longlake Experience of Property Rights Transformation’, Politics and Society, 29(3),
415–45.
Williamson, O.E. (1979), ‘Transaction-cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual
Relations’, Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 233–61.
Williamson, O.E. (1985), The Economic Institution of Capitalism, New York: The Free
Press.
Williamson, O.E. (1991), ‘Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete
Structural Alternatives’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2), 269–96.
Williamson, O.E. (1999), ‘Public and Private Bureaucracies: A Transaction Cost Economics
Perspective’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organizations, 15(1), 306–41.
Williamson, O.E. (2000), ‘The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead’,
Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), September 2000, 595–613.
Zak, P.J. and S. Knack (2001), ‘Trust and Growth’, The Economic Journal, 111(470),
295–321.
6. Analysing dominant policy perspectives –
the role of discourse analysis
David G. Ockwell and Yvonne Rydin
Introduction
The last decade has seen a ‘linguistic turn’ within policy analysis
(Edelman, 1988; Rydin, 1998, 1999; Hastings, 1999) as it becomes increas-
ingly accepted that language use and appeals to different discourses by
various actors in the policy-making sphere have a direct influence on
the nature of any policy. In this chapter we explore how to undertake a
discursive policy analysis. Rather than focus on the theoretical debates
on this approach, we address the practical problems and potential for
undertaking discourse analysis of environmental policy through a case
study of the policy governing anthropogenic fire in Cape York Peninsula,
Queensland, Australia. We begin by exploring the rationale for and ben-
efits of using discourse analysis. Then we emphasize the need to find an
appropriate ‘middle range’ theory for application in any specific context.
To illustrate our point, two alternative frameworks for undertaking such
an analysis are outlined. We then apply these frameworks in detail to our
case study and use them to understand why a particular policy perspective
has dominated fire policy in Cape York. This demonstrates the nature of
the insights that the two approaches facilitate and provides the opportu-
nity for exploring the methodological difficulties and practicalities of such
an analysis.
168
The role of discourse analysis 169
independently from the material power of economic actors and their skill
in persuasion (Rydin, 2003).
Another way of considering the inter-relationship between language
and actors’ interactions with one another is to see language as also con-
stitutive of the incentives facing actors – the costs and benefits (monetary
and otherwise) that they take into account in deciding on their behav-
iour. For example, researchers have suggested that reputation can be a
key factor shaping behaviour (Ostrom, 1990; Chong, 1991). Actors may
seek to promote and protect a good reputation and avoid behaviour that
is going to expose them to public shame and blame. But reputation is a
social variable constructed through social communicative interactions.
The detailed language of interactions will be central to assessments (by the
actor concerned and others) of whether a reputation is being damaged or
enhanced.
And third, as well as understanding policy actors and the dynamics
of policy processes more fully, the discursive dimension allows the pos-
sibility for devising new modes of communication to achieve normatively
better policy outcomes. There has been a lot of emphasis on creating
more inclusive and deliberative spaces for communication (Burgess et al.,
1998; Hillier, 1998; Healey, 1999; Mason, 1999). Much of the literature on
these policy innovations has arisen from an engagement with the notion
of policy as an inherently discursive process. There has, however, been a
tendency towards an overly procedural approach in devising new spaces
for communication. Graham Smith is one of the most insightful writers on
deliberation but in his discussion of institutional design and deliberation
(2003), he concentrates on procedures and decision rules, specifically how
to ensure equality of voice, defence of deliberation against strategic action
and sensitivity to the scope, scale and complexity of environmental issues.
But how do these procedures and decision rules change the communica-
tion within deliberation? This can only be understood through considering
the detailed language of that communication. The lesson of the linguistic
turn is that communication between actors is not just a matter of how that
communication is arranged. The language of the interaction also needs to
be considered.
Even more restrictively, deliberation is often equated with communica-
tion as if this not only characterizes deliberation but distinguishes it from
other types of policy intervention. This fails to see the communicative
dimension of all policy work (Majone, 1989) and, furthermore, the linguis-
tically mediated nature of all social activity. Language does play a pivotal
role in deliberation, but it is also implicated in many other institutional
arenas. This can provide insights into how language expresses values and
enables or disables agreement, including consensus.
The role of discourse analysis 171
The roots of this lack of attention to the details of language even within
those analysts of policy who see policy as essentially communicative,
derives from the Habermasian roots of most work on deliberative democ-
racy and its planning applications (Dryzek, 1990, 2000; Healey, 1999).
This identified a specific potential within communication between actors –
that is, the potential to create consensus. Where actors engage in commu-
nication with a performative stance towards mutual understanding, then
consensus between parties is immanent in the communication. The major
constraint on achieving such a consensus is pinpointed as the absence of
an ideal speech situation in which communicative rationality can hold
sway. This has led to the emphasis being placed on the circumstances
within which communication occurs rather than the nature of the commu-
nication in linguistic terms. This has been confirmed in Habermas’s most
recent work (1996). In our chapter we want instead to turn back towards
the language of policy and the detailed analysis of that language in specific
situations.
There is one particular problem within environmental policy that this
approach seems particularly well suited to address. This concerns the mis-
match between complex environmental problems and simple dominant
policy responses. This simplicity is at odds with the inherent variability
and complexity of the ecosystems whose healthy functioning such policy
aims to sustain. It ignores the fact that environmental problems are char-
acterized by a high degree of uncertainty. On one level, uncertainty exists
as a result of scientists’ incomplete understanding of ecosystem function-
ing. Additionally, however, environmental problems are invariably linked
to issues of resource distribution. As a result, there are always economic,
social and political implications of any environmental policy (see, for
example, Wheeler and McDonald, 1986; Rees, 1990; see also, for example,
Flournoy, 1993). As Dryzek (1997) highlights, when ecological systems
interact with economic, social and political systems through the policy
process, the level of uncertainty associated with environmental problems
is greatly magnified. Hajer and Wagenaar (2003) refer to this as policy-
making under conditions of ‘radical uncertainty’.
Increasing evidence suggests that such uncertainty is often reflected in
inappropriate environmental policies due to the application of standard-
ized management techniques that ignore the spatial, temporal, social,
economic and political complexity of environmental problems. Leach and
Mearns (1996) give the example of the woodfuel crisis in Africa, which is
widely perceived as a classic example of a supply gap where demand for
woodfuel exceeds supply. This has been met by a standardized response of
mass tree planting by governments, NGOs and inter-governmental organi-
zations. The basic assumptions that define the supply gap, however, ignore
172 A handbook of environmental management
more subtle issues such as the fact that most woodfuel comes from clearing
wood for agriculture or from lopping branches valued for fruit and shade.
From a broader perspective there is not one big problem of energy supply
but many smaller problems of command over trees and their products to
meet a wide range of basic needs. The range of policy solutions is therefore
equally diverse. Why is it then that one policy outcome can emerge and be
sustained in the face of conflicting evidence? Discourse analysis offers a
valuable approach to answering this question.
Hajer
In the development of the study of discourse Foucault’s work has been
pivotal. Through the study of the history of sexuality, madness and the
disciplinary basis of the academy, Foucault, referring to what he called
power/knowledge, developed the idea that knowledge, and hence dis-
course, is a reflection of power within society. As such, language is seen
as the operation of power (Foucault, 1980, 1984; Bevir, 1999; Rydin,
1999; Hastings, 2000; Watt and Jacobs, 2000). Hajer has sought to work
within a Foucauldian framework, in terms of engaging with the combined
concept of power/knowledge, while adjusting it to the problem of under-
standing environmental policy situations. Hajer’s work focuses on the
discursive nature of environmental policy-making (Hajer, 1995; Hajer and
Wagenaar, 2003). Discourse is seen as constituting both text and practice
The role of discourse analysis 173
Dryzek
John Dryzek is well known as a normative political theorist. He has sought
to apply Habermas’s concept of communicative rationality and delibera-
tive democracy to the specific issue of the environment (Dryzek, 2000),
a development that has been welcomed as a major advance in political
theory. Here, though, the focus is on his work in analysing environmental
discourse. In this work he explicitly counters the Foucauldian approach
and instead adopts a more agency-centred model. Dryzek sees discourse
and power as interconnected in all kinds of ways, whereas Foucault would
deny such a distinction between power and discourse as discourse is the
operation of power (Dryzek, 1997). Furthermore, Dryzek sees constraints
on the power of discourse, as powerful actors may override developments
at the discursive level by ignoring them in terms of policy. Alternatively,
discourses may be absorbed to suit the interests of a firm or government
(ecological modernization springs to mind). Another constraint may arise
The role of discourse analysis 175
from the need for capitalist governments to fulfil a number of basic func-
tions irrespective of discourses that may have been captured by government
officials, especially continued economic growth. Within his rejection of the
Foucauldian discursive approach, Dryzek points to the very existence of
authors such as Foucault as evidence that individuals subject to discourses
are able step back and make comparative assessments and choices across
different discourses. Dryzek also rejects the hegemonic terms used by
Foucauldians to describe discourse. He asserts that variety is as likely as
hegemony, with the disintegration of the previously hegemonic discourse
of industrialism since the 1960s as evidence of just such variety.
Dryzek sets out his approach to discourse analysis with the aim of
advancing ‘analysis of environmental affairs by promoting critical com-
parative scrutiny of competing discourses of environmental concern’
(Dryzek, 1997, p. 20). He is thus interested in explaining how environmen-
tal discourses inform political programmes. A four-fold typology is put
forward where ways of thinking about environmentalism are character-
ized in terms of their departure from the discourse of industrialism (Elliott,
1999). These departures can be reformist or radical, prosaic or imaginative
and result in the identification of four main categories of environmental
thought. These four strands are categorized as follows. The discourse of
environmental ‘problem-solving’ is prosaic and reformist. It takes the
political-economic status quo as given but in need of adjustment to cope
with environmental problems, especially via public policy. The discourse
of ‘survivalism’, popularized by the Club of Rome (Meadows et al., 1972)
is also prosaic, but radical. It is radical because it seeks wholesale redis-
tribution of power within the industrial political economy and wholesale
reorientation away from perpetual economic growth to avoid exhausting
natural resources and the assimilative capacity of the environment. It is
prosaic because it sees solutions in terms of options set by industrialism,
especially greater control of existing systems by administrators, scientists
and other responsible elites. The discourse of ‘sustainability’ is imaginative
and reformist, beginning in the 1980s with imaginative attempts to dissolve
the conflicts between environmental and economic values that are charac-
teristic of the discourses of problem-solving and survivalism. Finally, the
discourse of ‘green radicalism’ is also imaginative, but radical. It rejects
the basic structure of industrial society and the way the environment is
conceptualized therein. Due to such radicalization and imagination, it
features deep intramural divisions.
In common with the roots of Habermas’s work in argumentation
theory, Dryzek also adopts a rhetorical method, marrying this with a more
basic social constructivist perspective (see Rydin, 2003, ch. 2). This offers
a fairly tightly controlled comparative analytical device for identifying the
176 A handbook of environmental management
elements through which discourses construct stories. First the basic enti-
ties whose existence is recognized or contrasted must be identified. Dryzek
refers to this as the ‘ontology’ of a discourse. Second, assumptions held
about natural relationships, such as Darwinian struggle or cooperation,
should be explored. This includes hierarchies of gender, expertise, political
power, intellect, race, and so on. Propositions about agency and motiva-
tion constitute the third area of investigation. Agents may, for example,
be seen as benign, public-spirited administrators or selfish bureaucrats.
They could include enlightened citizens, rational consumers, ignorant and
short-sighted populations, and so on. Finally, the key metaphors and rhe-
torical devices that a discourse invokes should be scrutinized. This might
include, for example, metaphors such as spaceships (Boulding, 1966) that
may act as rhetorical devices to convince listeners or readers. It may also
include other devices like an appeal to widely accepted institutions or
practices such as established rights. A discourse could also accentuate
negatives such as horror stories regarding government mistakes.
In order to demonstrate the nature of the insights that Hajer and
Dryzek’s approaches facilitate and to explore the methodological difficul-
ties and practicalities of such analysis, we now apply them to a case study
of environmental policy governing anthropogenic burning in Cape York
Peninsula (Cape York), Queensland, Australia.
Injinco
Wattle Hills
Weipa Lockhart River
Great
Aurukun Barrier
Reef
Cape
Pormpuraaw York
Hope Vale
Peninsula
Kowanyam Cooktown
Cairns
As well as its role in coordinating the Permit to Light Fire system, the
Rural Fire Service also works with Cape York landholders in implement-
ing a series of ‘controlled’ burns at the beginning of each dry season. This
is done via a series of workshops held across Cape York prior to each dry
season where interested landholders can attend and request that the Rural
Fire Service carry out burning on their land. The Rural Fire Service then
flies a light aircraft along the boundaries of participating properties and
drops incendiary bombs that are intended to burn a series of firebreaks
between each property. The rationale for this practice is one of hazard
reduction. As outlined above, the rationale is that by burning the available
ground fuel on property perimeters, the spread of wildfires later in the dry
season might be avoided. Some stakeholders, however, are critical of this
practice as being too indiscriminate and not accounting for environmental
considerations in terms of whether the various affected ecosystems are
able to cope with regular, or indeed, any fire. Indeed, as Russell-Smith
et al. (2003) highlight, as well as there being no consensus over what fire-
oriented landscape management should aim for, neither is it clear whether
humans have the tools or resources to implement particular regimes over
a large spatial scale.
When applying for a Permit to Light Fire, a landholder is required to
disclose to the local Fire Warden any arrangement they have with other
government agencies that obliges them to protect some aspect of their
property from fire for environmental reasons or otherwise. Such arrange-
ments are rare but do include agreements between landholders and the
Queensland Department of Natural Resources, Mines and Energy to
undertake burning to kill back weeds such as rubber-vine (DNR, 2001),
or, in a few examples, to maintain the habitat of the endangered golden
shouldered parrot, Psephotus chrysopterygius, which relies on late dry-
season fires to create necessary nesting conditions (Crowley et al., 2003).
The only instance where such an agreement might limit burning is where a
public road runs through a property. There is only one main, unsurfaced
dirt road in Cape York so this is rarely an issue. Once a landholder has
informed their Fire Warden of any such agreement, it is then up to the
Warden to consider this when detailing the conditions of the Permit to
Light Fire. Wardens are all local stakeholders themselves chosen by the
Rural Fire Service on the basis of assumed local knowledge of their area
of responsibility (areas of responsibility range from just the Warden’s own
land to including theirs and a few of their neighbours’ properties). The
Rural Fire Service states that ‘the local volunteer Fire Warden should not
be responsible for policing environmental issues’ (RFS, 2001, 1-1) on the
basis of them not possessing sufficient knowledge to do so.
In addition to the Rural Fire Service, Queensland’s Environmental
180 A handbook of environmental management
Prosaic Imaginative
Reformist Problem-solving discourse Sustainability discourse
Government scientists Pastoralists
Independent scientists (less
critical discourse)
Pastoralists
Radical Survivalism discourse Green radicalism discourse
Aborigines (everyday Aborigines (underlying
management discourse) spiritual discourse)
Independent scientists (more Wattle Hills (self-sufficiency
critical discourse) discourse)
Wattle Hills (everyday
management discourse)
186 A handbook of environmental management
and/or may relate to the way that Aboriginal voices were largely repre-
sented by other semi-professionalized voices. In either case, it suggests
that the categories are not very helpful in furthering the analysis where the
Aboriginal discourse is concerned.
A similar point can be made about the discourses of the independent
scientists and the residents of Wattle Hills. The independent scientists
adopted a strong critique of contemporary industrialism. This very much
put them on the borders between a reformist and a radical discourse. It
certainly distanced them from the more firmly pro-status-quo stance of
the government scientists. And while, like the government scientists, they
remained prosaic rather than imaginative in their discourse, it did make it
difficult to simply assign the independent scientists to either the problem-
solving or survivalism category. The Wattle Hills story-line emphasized
the need to ‘let nature take its course’. Policies promoting fire were seen as
misleading and neglectful of life, reverence for life being of primary impor-
tance. This suggests a radical, imaginative departure from industrialism
that fits within Dryzek’s definition of ‘green radicalism’ (Dryzek, 1997). In
much of their more specific discussion of management practices, however,
the discourse of the Wattle Hills residents is distinctly prosaic, suggesting
a place in the survivalism category instead.
Indeed, only the government scientists (clearly a prosaic reformist
discourse of problem-solving) and the pastoralists (an imaginative but
reformist discourse of sustainability) fall clearly into one box of Dryzek’s
typology. This can be interpreted in two ways. Either the typology fails
the ‘ideal type’ test and is not a useful analytic tool. Or the lack of discur-
sive clarity of some of the actors’ discourses may be a significant factor in
explaining the pattern of discursive coalition formation and the success
or failure of individual actors to achieve discursive influence. Before con-
cluding on this, however, the second part of Dryzek’s framework deserves
consideration.
This concerns the detailed social constructivist/rhetorical analysis of
the discourses. Some, but by no means all of this analysis is summarized
in Table 6.3. What is immediately evident here is the wealth of detail that
such an analysis offers. Furthermore, such an analysis is able to incor-
porate more of the emotional impact of the different discourses. The
emphasis on story-lines, while couched in terms of narrative rather than
logic, still privileges an account of connections and makes little reference
to the language in which the narrative is delivered. Much of the impact
of language is not just to be found in the plot of the story being told but
in how that story is told. It is here that rhetorical analysis in particular
demonstrates its strengths.
Starting with the Aboriginal discourse, the key entities here are
The role of discourse analysis 187
such thing as natural management’ (p. 13). This places modern scientific
management on a par with traditional Aboriginal management. The ethos
of scientific rationality that is relied on here, therefore, does not undermine
the potential for an alliance with the Aboriginal discourse.
As well as adding such detail to the workings of a discourse coalition
between the government scientists and the Aborigines, the rhetorical
analysis provides an insight into the emotional appeal of such a discourse.
The government scientists’ discourse is a rhetorically rich discourse. In
particular, there is very active rhetorical engagement with the key term of
‘fire’. As they say, colloquially, ‘Fire ain’t fire’ (p. 13). Instead the discourse
describes fire in terms of a ‘management tool’, a ‘traditional practice’, a
form of ‘rejuvenation’ (p. 12), and as having an ‘evolutionary’ role (p. 15).
Fire is not a negative thing when discussed in such language. It makes it
possible to combine positive reference to ‘fire’ in a discourse that also talks
of having ‘love’ for the land (p. 34).
And yet the negative effects of using fire are acknowledged. There is
reference to individual birds and animals killed by fire. This is, however,
set against a synecdochical account of how burning can save the habitat
of two key species – the malleefowl and ground parrots (pp. 12–13). The
extent of the intended burning is also firmly set in context by invoking the
extremely emotive term ‘the holocaust’. What the government scientists
are doing is making ‘choices’ (p. 14) or ‘playing God’ (p. 16) in order to
avoid ‘policies of inaction’ that would result in a ‘holocaust of extinction’
(p. 38). The fire of government scientists prevents the fire of complete
annihilation.
The third party to the dominant discourse coalition, the pastoralists, has
a similar discourse in the sense of mixing scientific and emotive rhetoric.
The pastoralists’ discourse again constructs the key entities in terms of, on
the one hand, nature described in scientific terms – botanical communities
with scientific names for species – and, on the other hand, humans as indi-
viduals who are able to act responsibly (although this is acknowledged as
an individual choice, not as inevitable). The relationship assumed between
nature and humans is seen in terms of the kind of win-win scenarios that
are typical of the broader sustainability discourse. The value that this dis-
course adds over the scientific/traditional management discourses of the
government scientists and the Aborigines is its suggestion that economic
profit can also be harnessed to the goal of conservation. As a result, the
combination of the three discourses is rhetorically very strong indeed.
Similar to the government scientists’ discourse, there is also a rich use
of emotive rhetoric within the pastoralists’ discourse, combining scientific
terminology with moral imagery. Pastures are portrayed as biotic commu-
nities with ‘stability’ and ‘integrity’, both moral and eco-scientific terms.
190 A handbook of environmental management
In these terms, the pastoralists also see fire as a strong cultural reference
point to support the management claims for their burning practices:
‘mankind has held fire in both a revered and feared position . . . Fire has
been given God qualities and worshipped’ (p. 29). The symbolism of fire is
related to scientific claims for fire as rejuvenating habitats with ‘old trees
sacrificed for new seedlings’ (p. 12).
Conversion, another religious theme, features too. The representa-
tive from the Cape York Peninsula Development Association (CYPDA)
employs a persuasive rhetorical technique, emphasized by Dryzek, in
stating his original affinity with the anti-burning discourse, which changed
over time as he realized that his views were factually misguided (pp. 39–42).
Fire is portrayed as an ‘emotional issue clouded by folklore’, which con-
trasts to the rational scientific reality of its being merely ‘a fast form of oxi-
dation’. The ‘community disharmony’ that exists over the use of fire is put
down to a simple ‘lack of understanding’ on behalf of those opposed to
burning. This establishes further discursive affinities with the government
scientists’ argument.
Turning to the Wattle Hills residents, this is the only discourse to con-
struct humans and nature as part of the same entity; effectively this places
humans as part of nature. This undermines the notion of human agency.
Instead, the appropriate role becomes one of non-intervention and self-
sufficiency. By contrast, nature is credited with substantial agency as well
as superior knowledge: ‘nature knows best’. This detailed construction of
the residents’ discourse puts them discursively at odds with the previous
three discourses; it therefore reinforces the structure of the discourse coali-
tions discussed above. In addition, the Wattle Hills discourse is the most
emotive of the five presented in the workshop. It uses Haiku poetry and
highly charged language. It refers to Australia as a ‘fire-shaped continent’
(p. 10) and anthropomorphizes the larger animals, referring also to the
‘tender growth’ where birds nest (p. 9). Reference is made to ‘QPWS arson-
ists’ alongside ‘pyromaniacs’ and ‘vandalism’ (pp. 9 and 17). The QPWS
policy, which implies ‘nature can no longer take its course’, is dismissed as
being ‘spawned’ by some ‘dark philosophy’ (p. 9). A strong line is taken in
establishing the destructiveness of fire through the use of emotive phrases
such as ‘bushfires kill and destroy’, they bring ‘death and destruction’
The role of discourse analysis 191
‘disaster’ and ‘catastrophe’. There is also the use of tropes that imply
nature would be better off unmanaged. Burning is equated to a violation
(p. 17), suggesting a virgin state would be preferable. And wilderness, pre-
sented as unmanaged land, is compared favourably with managed land-
scapes (p. 20), in particular as wilderness is seen as the source of sublime
romantic encounters: ‘a place where we can stand with our senses steeped
in nature’ (p. 20).
The rhetoric used drives the independent scientists’ argument towards
the conclusion that humans will inherently destroy rather than conserve
nature and that management conflicts with the natural state of the land.
The government scientists, by contrast, managed the ethos to imply a more
positive message. In policy debates this may well carry greater weight than
a purely negative and oppositional discourse. While negative rhetoric
such as this is highly influential within environmentalism and can assist
in building coalitions among environmentalist groups, it is less effective
within governmental policy settings.
work and a balance between creativity and reflection on the part of the
researcher are all elements that make for successful and effective discourse
analysis.
Finally, however, a note of caution must be raised in the context of the
pervasive power accounts of the influence of discourse discussed above.
These arguably suggest an implicit responsibility for us as analysts to be
aware of our own ontological and epistemological beliefs and understand-
ings. This implies a need to adopt a critical and fundamentally reflexive
approach where we explicitly consider how our own interests may wit-
tingly, or unwittingly, be reflected in the production of knowledge that
might be inherently perspective-bound (Hastings, 2000; Heller, 2001).
This is of particular importance given the degree of legitimacy afforded
to academic perspectives (Hastings, 2000). The question must always be
asked: would another author analysing the same text reach the same con-
clusions? Discourse analysis carried out in the spirit of such critical and
reflexive enquiry can then fulfil its potential as a heuristically powerful and
potentially emancipatory tool for policy analysis.
Notes
1. For further detailed explorations of this case study see Ockwell and Rydin (2006) and
Ockwell (2008).
2. This euro-anthropocentric interpretation of Aboriginal burning is contested by contem-
porary anthropologists and many Aboriginals – this is outlined further below.
3. See Ockwell and Rydin (2006) for a more in-depth discussion of the dominant pro-
burning policy paradigm in Cape York.
4. See www.firenorth.org.au/nafi2, accessed 19 August 2009.
5. Note: page references in parentheses from hereon refer to the ‘Tropics Under Fire’
seminar transcript under analysis.
References
Bakker, K. (1999), ‘Deconstructing discourses of drought’, Transactions of the Institute of
British Geographers, 24(3), 367–78.
Bevir, M. (1999), ‘Foucault, power, and institutions’, Political Studies, 47(2), 345–59.
Boulding, K.R. (1966), The Economics of the Coming Spaceship Earth, Baltimore, MD: Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Bowman, D.M.J.S. (1998), ‘Tansley Review No. 101 – The impact of Aboriginal landscape
burning on the Australian biota’, New Phytologist, 140, 385–410.
Bowman, D.M.J.S. (2000), Australian Rainforests: Islands of Green in a Land of Fire,
Cambridge, UK and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Burgess, J., C.M. Harrison and P. Filius (1998), ‘Environmental communication and the cul-
tural politics of environmental citizenship’, Environment and Planning A, 30(8), 1445–60.
Buttel, F.H. (1997), ‘The politics of environmental discourse: ecological modernization and
the policy process’, Social Forces, 75(3), 1138–40.
CAFNEC (1992), ‘Tropics under fire: fire management on Cape York Peninsula’, Public
Seminar, Cairns and Far North Environment Centre, Australia.
Chong, D. (1991), Collective Action and the Civil Rights Movement, Chicago: The University
of Chicago Press.
Crowley, G.M., S. Garnett and S. Shephard (2003), ‘Management guidelines for golden-
The role of discourse analysis 195
Healey, P. (1999), ‘Sites, jobs and portfolios: economic development discourses in the plan-
ning system’, Urban Studies, 36(1), 27–42.
Heller, M. (2001), ‘Critique and sociolinguistic analysis of discourse’, Critique of
Anthropology, 21(2), 117–41.
Hill, R. (2003), ‘Frameworks to support indigenous managers: the key to fire futures’, in G.
Cary, D. Lindenmayer and S. Dovers (eds), Australia Burning: Fire Ecology, Policy and
Management Issues, Collingwood, Australia: CSIRO Publishing, pp. 175–86.
Hillier, J. (1998), ‘Beyond confused noise: ideas towards communicative procedural justice’,
Journal of Planning Education and Research, 18(1), 14–24.
Jones, R. (1969), ‘Fire-stick farming’, Australian Natural History, 16(7), 224–8.
Keeley, J. and I. Scoones (2000), ‘Knowledge, power and politics: the environmental policy-
making process in Ethiopia’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 38(1), 89–120.
Leach, M. and R. Mearns (1996), The Lie of the Land. Challenging Received Wisdom on the
African Environment, Oxford, UK: James Currey.
Lees, L. (2004), ‘Urban geography: discourse analysis and urban research’, Progress in
Human Geography, 28(1), 101–7.
Majone, G. (1989), Evidence, Argument and Persuasion in the Policy Process, New Haven,
NJ: Yale University Press.
Marlow, D. (2000), A Guide to Fire Management in Queensland (incorporating fire manage-
ment theory and departmental practice), Queensland: Queensland Department of Natural
Resources, Mines and Energy.
Mason, M. (1999), Environmental Democracy, London: Earthscan.
Meadows, D.H., D.L. Meadows, J. Randers and W.W. Behrens (1972), The Limits to Growth
(a report for the Club of Rome’s project on the predicament of mankind), New York:
Universal.
Myerson, G. and Y. Rydin (1996), The Language of Environment: A New Rhetoric, London:
UCL Press.
Nossiff, R. (1998), ‘Discourse, party, and policy: the case of abortion, 1965–1972’, Policy
Studies Journal, 26(2), 244–56.
Ockwell, D. (2008) ‘“Opening up” policy to reflexive appraisal: a role for Q Methodology? A
case study of fire management in Cape York, Australia’, Policy Sciences, 41(4), 263–92.
Ockwell, D. and J.C. Lovett (2005), ‘Fire assisted pastoralism vs. sustainable forestry – the
implications of missing markets for carbon in determining optimal land use in the wet-dry
tropics of Australia’, Journal of Environmental Management, 75(1), 1–9.
Ockwell, D. and Y. Rydin (2006), ‘Conflicting discourses of knowledge: understanding the
policy adoption of pro-burning knowledge claims in Cape York Peninsula, Australia’,
Environmental Politics, 15(3), 379–98.
Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective
Action, New York: Cambridge University Press.
QPWS (2000), Fire Management System, Brisbane: Queensland Parks and Wildlife Service.
Queensland State Government (1990), Fire and Rescue Service Act 1990.
Queensland State Government (1994), Environmental Protection Act.
Rees, J. (1990), Natural Resources. Allocation, Economics and Policy, London: Routledge.
RFS (2001), Fire in the Landscape and Beyond 2000, Queensland: Rural Fire Service.
Richardson, T. and O.B. Jensen (2000), ‘Discourses of mobility and polycentric development:
a contested view of European spatial planning’, European Planning Studies, 8(4), 503–20.
Rose, D.B. (1996), Nourishing Terrains: Australian Aboriginal Views of Landscape and
Wilderness, Canberra: Australian Heritage Commission.
Russell-Smith, J., P.J. Whitehead, R.J. Williams and M. Flannigan (2003), ‘Fire and savanna
landscapes in northern Australia: regional lessons and global challenges – preface’,
International Journal of Wildland Fire, 12(3/4), v–ix.
Rydin, Y. (1998), ‘The enabling local state and urban development: resources, rhetoric and
planning in East London’, Urban Studies, 35(2), 175–91.
Rydin, Y. (1999), ‘Can we talk ourselves into sustainability? The role of discourse in the
environmental policy process’, Environmental Values, 8(4), 467–84.
The role of discourse analysis 197
Introduction
Many modern environmental problems are not occasional random events
that suddenly arise, but are rather the result of long-term processes requir-
ing effective management through time instead of instant solutions. Their
causes and effects are complex issues, strongly interlinked with other
aspects of social, political and economic realities. When these problems
are of a transboundary, or global nature, then their management must
be attempted through regional (bilateral or multilateral) or international
agreements.
Traditionally the focus of academic research has been on issues associ-
ated with the challenge of achieving international cooperation, in other
words on regime formation, but recently there has been an increasing
interest in implementation issues, that is, regime effectiveness. This
chapter aims to discuss the concept of effectiveness of international envi-
ronmental agreements as debated within the academic literature. In the
first section the major theoretical perspectives on international relations
are presented as the context for understanding different explanations given
to international cooperation. Different approaches to defining and meas-
uring effectiveness of the agreements are then described in more detail. In
the second section there is specific reference to a particular example of an
environmental agreement. The Mediterranean Action Plan was chosen
for this purpose since it has not been studied extensively and in addition
its effectiveness is ambiguous according to different viewpoints. Finally in
the last section, a new definition of effectiveness is given, drawing insights
from the aforementioned literature, suggesting that for a regime to be
effective it has to use a holistic approach, to have a pragmatic vision and
to be of a dynamic nature. This perspective attempts to provide a new
approach to the future study of international environmental agreements.
198
A case study of the Mediterranean Action Plan 199
Prince and Hobbes’s Leviathan and has been mainly concerned with state
security (Haas, 1990, p. 35). Emphasizing the political sphere, the realist
approach analyses relationships among states only according to issues
of power and self-interest (Kütting, 2000a, p. 12). It assumes that states
are only guided by national interest and that their purpose must be to
maximize power, a process that ultimately leads to war as states compete
amongst themselves. According to realists the actors (states) act rationally
and prefer those options that best suit their interests, under the assump-
tion that they have full awareness of world events and thus can estimate
both costs and benefits of alternative solutions. Those solutions chosen
concern the acquisition of power (Haas, 1990, p. 35). Hence only when the
effectiveness of an international environmental agreement coincides with
the interests of the states, can the agreement be effective (Kütting 2000a,
p. 12). However, since international discussions about environmental
problems are often concerned with common threats to livelihoods and not
about power, there is a difference in focus between realist thought about
war and power on one hand, and concerns about environmental degrada-
tion on the other. Moreover, Haas (1990, p. 36) notes that there has been
substantial criticism about realism not being an appropriate model for the
analysis of environmental cooperation because of the importance it places
on matters of security, which are generally not salient features of environ-
mental agreements. However, if security could be extended to matters of
public health or security of borders then it could be included as a theme
when studying international environmental agreements.
from the pure politics of maximization of interest. This view suggests that
regimes may matter but only under fairly restrictive conditions, for instance
when independent decision-making leads to unwanted outcomes. Finally,
the Grotian view lays emphasis on social factors, and even though it sees
the states as still the main actors in the international sphere, it assumes
that these actors are necessarily bound by specific norms and rules. This
last orientation considers regimes as much more persistent and accepts
them as a fundamental part of all patterned human interaction, including
interaction in the international system (Krasner, 1983, pp. 6–10).
Nevertheless, the distinction between the above three orientations does
not really play an important role. Regimes cannot always be irrelevant,
and they cannot always be necessary. So the view that regimes may matter
under certain conditions, is the most appropriate. Their effectiveness is
of great importance, since only effective regimes may make a difference.
More details will be given below on the way that regime theory is applied
to the study of international environmental regimes when discussing how
regime theorists define and measure environmental regime effectiveness.
Epistemic communities: a popular tradition within environmental inter-
national regime theory is that of ‘epistemic communities’ (Haas, 1989).
This theory highlights the role of knowledge-based ‘epistemic communi-
ties’ consisting of specialists responsible for articulating policies and iden-
tifying the national interest. Initially, the term ‘epistemic community’ was
used in literature on the sociology of knowledge. It was later borrowed by
international relations specialists and adapted to describe a specific com-
munity of experts. This community ‘shares a belief in a common set of
cause-and-effect relationships as well as common values to which policies
governing these relationships will be applied’ (Haas, 1989, p. 384). The
community, even though originating from various disciplines, operates
within a common network where there is an exchange of ideas, concerns,
results and solutions, aiming at the same political objectives (Haas,
1990, p. 55). This approach focuses on the groups of people who initiate
cooperation rather than on which states are the leading actors who start
the process. However, supporters of this theory do not suggest it should
replace the older international relations theories, but rather complement
them. For instance, as will be described below, Haas (1990) in his study
about the Mediterranean Action Plan explains the cooperation by refer-
ring to ‘epistemic communities’, but he also offers other explanations from
the perspectives of realism/neorealism and historical materialism.
not only how these agreements were formed, but also if they were effec-
tive afterwards. There is a growing interest in the effectiveness aspect
of regimes, but it is a matter of debate because quite different defini-
tions are used, resulting in different ways of estimating effectiveness. As
Kütting (2000a, p. 30) observes ‘Within the effectiveness debate in regime
theory. . . on one level effectiveness is seen in terms of institutional work-
ings through good institutional structures. . . on another level effectiveness
is measured on the basis of environmental impact’.
Usually regime theorists look at effectiveness as institutional perform-
ance and not as environmental improvement. Even though some of them
recognize the need to look at the environmental impact, only a few actu-
ally try to measure it. For example, some of the Norwegian regime theo-
rists (Wettestad and Andresen, 1991; Underdal, 1992) have considered the
environmental problem but still focus on the institutional performance of
a regime. Also, Haas et al. (1993, p. 7) ask the question whether the quality
of the environment is better because of the regime but they do not indicate
how such change could be measured and how much of it could be assigned
to the regime itself, rather than to other external factors. Nevertheless,
change itself is not a sufficient measurement of effectiveness (Kütting,
2000b). However, recently there has been an attempt by Kütting (2000a,
2000b) to introduce the concept of environmental effectiveness when
studying environmental regimes by distinguishing the concept of effective-
ness as seen in institutional terms from that of accounting for improved
environmental quality, though still having a regime theory perspective.
Furthermore, the attempts to measure effectiveness have been mainly
qualitative. These qualitative methods vary in whether their view is
descriptive (trying to explain what did happen), predictive (trying to
estimate what will happen), normative (looking at what should ideally
happen) or explanatory (trying to explain the reasons why something hap-
pened) (Mitchell and Bernauer, 2002, p. 2). However, a small but increas-
ing number of researchers have approached the subject quantitatively,
recognizing the need for these methods to complement each other in
order to produce more reliable results. A brief discussion of some of these
methods is provided below.
cases other actors such as NGOs are involved in this process. However,
verification is still mainly dependent on national reports, which might
be unreliable or even false especially when national interests are at stake.
Hence, practically, it could be the case that compliance is not achieved
even if reporting indicates to the contrary. Furthermore, it is crucial to
properly set the standards against which compliance will be measured so
as to be meaningful (Ausubel and Victor, 1992). Only recently have studies
paid attention to the issue of compliance in international climate regimes
(Barrett and Stavins, 2003; Victor, 2003) noting that successful imple-
mentation means high levels of participation and compliance. Barrett
and Stavins (2003), commenting on the Kyoto Protocol, find that it does
not induce significant participation and compliance and propose different
approaches to improve it by offering positive or negative incentives. In the
Montreal Protocol, for instance, a threat of restrictions on trade of CFCs
or products containing CFCs between the countries participating in the
agreement and those not participating proved successful in motivating
more countries to participate. However, it is commonly acknowledged,
especially in the case of the Kyoto Protocol, that compliance alone (even
if fully achieved) cannot always mitigate the environmental problem,
since some of the heavier polluters might not choose to participate in the
agreement at all.
Transparency, openness and participation: one of the issues requir-
ing attention from international environmental regime practitioners and
scholars is transparency and openness. According to Ausubel and Victor
(1992) transparency refers to the clear presentation of the regime’s activi-
ties and information collected, whereas openness means access of actors
to the negotiating process and information, irrespective of whether these
actors come from within the government or not. They also note that suc-
cessful environmental regimes should provide for these conditions, since
in their case studies of arms control regimes the latter proved unsuccess-
ful partly due to concealment and restricted participation (Ausubel and
Victor, 1992). Moreover, von Moltke (2000) also stresses the importance
of transparency and participation in environmental affairs in general,
though remarkably few formal rules have been adopted in international
environmental agreements to address these needs. A first step in this
direction was the adoption in 1998 of the Aarhus Convention on Access
to Information, Public Participation in Decision-making and Access to
Justice in Environmental Matters (von Moltke, 2000).
Domestic politics: another important factor that affects international
environmental cooperation is change in the patterns of domestic politics.
According to Weale (1992, p. 200), domestic public policy can naturally be
affected by actors and procedures in the international sphere. However,
A case study of the Mediterranean Action Plan 215
about Mediterranean Sea pollution arose between the late 1960s and 1974
when some Mediterranean officials expressed for the first time a need
for action and governments sought ways to obtain information on the
extent of marine pollution by identifying sources and types of pollutants
and on possible ways to deal with the situation. Since adequate informa-
tion was not yet available the attention focused on oil pollution resulting
from maritime traffic and accidental spills, as this was the most visible
form. Afterwards, however, several scientific meetings and conferences
revealed a variety of pollutants and their sources, with the most impor-
tant being the land-based, so in 1974 a first draft of a treaty was prepared
by the Food and Agriculture Organization. However, later the same
year, Mediterranean governments approached another United Nations
organization, the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) to
guide and support this regional effort, which in turn, with the help of 40
Mediterranean marine experts, developed a comprehensive plan. Finally,
in 1975 the Mediterranean Action Plan was adopted including seven
monitoring and research projects, for an entire set of pollutant types and
sources, and several pilot demonstration projects (Haas, 1990, ch. 3).
Thereafter MAP gradually widened its scope through creation of proto-
cols covering land-based sources of pollution, marine dumping, tanker oil
pollution, as well as pollution transported by rivers and in the atmosphere
and by extending the lists to include more pollutants. The environmental
assessment component of MAP also evolved as the research and monitor-
ing projects increased from seven to 12 and some interim standards were
developed (Haas, 1990, ch. 4).
However, following the 1992 UN Conference on Environment and
Development ‘Earth Summit’ in Rio and the requirements of the Rio
Declaration on Environment and Development (Agenda 21), MAP
attempted to translate the results of the summit onto the regional
Mediterranean level, and adapted Agenda 21 to the Mediterranean
context by setting up Agenda MED 21. This led to adoption of the Action
Plan for the Protection of the Marine Environment and Sustainable
Development of the Coastal Areas of the Mediterranean (MAP II) on 10
June 1995 (UNEP, 1995b). MAP II reflected both increasing concern for
the pressures exerted on the Mediterranean environment and commitment
of Mediterranean states to the ideal of sustainable development.
or states to coordinate decisions and actions with the other actors involved.
Reaching an international political agreement is difficult and there are dif-
ferent explanations about the conditions under which cooperation in the
Mediterranean Basin was achieved through the framework of MAP and
the Barcelona Convention. Haas (1990) summarizes these different inter-
pretations into the main categories described below, explaining the causes
of cooperation, its effects and its forms in each one of the views.
Realism and neorealism are concerned mainly with the relationship
between state power and order in security affairs and the political economy
of advanced industrialized societies. Realists and neorealists would relate
cooperation to the distribution of power between the Mediterranean
states. Under this perspective the regional hegemonic leadership of France
would play a key role in developing cooperation under conditions of
international anarchy. This hegemony would dictate that the scope of
the agreements would mainly cover pollutants of interest to France but
also extend to other issues of national French interest. The strength of
cooperation – how weak or binding it is – would be dependent on French
power and might also depend on information available. Under a realistic
view the duration of the cooperation – how persistent it is – would also
vary with the two previous factors and the effects of the cooperation would
be to strengthen the influence of France in the region and achieve common
benefits for all the Parties. However, this explanation did not prove
adequate when, after the decline of the regional French hegemony, MAP
continued to exist and to receive increased support both from the hegemon
and also from weaker states, showing that it is difficult to predict potential
change in the motives of the states (Haas, 1990, ch. 6).
Historical materialism, as discussed earlier, is basically concerned with
distribution of economic resources and international equality, very often
expressed as the North–South divide. Historical materialists explain
cooperation in terms of the control of powerful capitalist states (that is,
European countries in the case of the Mediterranean region) over weaker
less-developed ones (that is, North African and/or Middle East coun-
tries in the same case). According to them the imperialism of European
states would lead to cooperation under conditions of capitalism. The
scope of the cooperation would not be clear but it would strengthen
areas where European states have interests. Both strength and duration
of the cooperation would vary with European dominance and effects of
cooperation would be imposition of unwanted forms of development
on less-developed countries, excluding alternatives, and the provision
of relatively more benefits to European states, thus increasing com-
mercial dependence of the less-developed countries on them. So, in the
context of MAP, under a historical materialist interpretation, northern
220 A handbook of environmental management
The legal component of MAP MAP seeks to achieve all its objectives
through its legal component, the Barcelona Convention and related proto-
cols. The Convention for the Protection of the Mediterranean Sea against
Pollution was signed in 1976, and has been in force since 1978. In 1995 it
A case study of the Mediterranean Action Plan 221
the maritime waters of the Mediterranean Sea proper, including its gulfs and
seas, bounded to the west by the meridian passing through Cape Spartel light-
house, at the entrance of the Straits of Gibraltar, and to the east by the south-
ern limits of the Straits of the Dardanelles between Mehmetcik and Kumkale
lighthouses.
This Protocol was amended and recorded as the ‘Protocol for the
Prevention and Elimination of Pollution in the Mediterranean Sea
by Dumping from Ships and Aircraft or Incineration at Sea’. It
was signed in 1995 but still awaits entry into force. The Dumping
Protocol commits states to banning dumping of certain substances
– the ‘black list’ – and issue permits for dumping of less hazardous
substances – the ‘grey list’. Factors to be considered when establish-
ing criteria governing issue of permits include characteristics and
composition of wastes or other matter, features of the dumping site
and method of deposit of matter to the site. An exception to the
Protocol’s provisions is the case of force majeure due to stress of
weather or any other cause when human life or the safety of a ship
or aircraft is threatened.
● Prevention and Emergency Protocol. The full title is ‘Protocol
Concerning Cooperation in Preventing Pollution from Ships, and,
in Cases of Emergency, Combating Pollution of the Mediterranean
224 A handbook of environmental management
Sea’. This Protocol was signed in 2002, and has been in force since
2004, replacing the existing ‘Protocol Concerning Cooperation in
Combating Pollution of the Mediterranean Sea by Oil and Other
Harmful Substances in Cases of Emergency’, which was in force from
1976. The Prevention and Emergency Protocol commits states to
notify each other in case of an oil spill and to cooperate in the clean-
up. In the event of an oil spill or other emergencies UNEP and also
any other state likely to be affected must be informed. Moreover, in
the framework of this Protocol, a regional activity centre (REMPEC
– Regional Marine Pollution Emergency Response Centre for the
Mediterranean Sea) has been established in Malta, administered by
the International Maritime Organization and the United Nations
Environment Programme to deal with the implementation of this
Protocol. Cooperation in the clean-up includes salvage or recovery
of packages containing hazardous or noxious substances released or
lost overboard. The Protocol also provides for other actions such as
dissemination of reports and information. The article about assist-
ance allows for it to be asked for and given by the regional activity
centre or by any other signatory state in the form of equipment,
products and facilities, expert advice and the costs of any action
shall be borne by the requesting Party.
● LBS (Land-Based Sources) Protocol. The full title is ‘Protocol for
the Protection of the Mediterranean Sea against Pollution from
Land-Based Sources’. It was signed in 1980 and has been in force
since 1983. This Protocol was amended as the ‘Protocol for the
Protection of the Mediterranean Sea against Pollution from Land-
Based Sources and Activities’. The amendment was signed in 1995
but still awaits entry into force. The LBS Protocol covers some
sectors of activity, including heavy metal industries, agriculture,
energy production and waste treatment, binding the countries to
adopt new industrial, agricultural and waste treatment practices.
It also commits states to ban or strictly limit a number of com-
pounds such as organohalogens, organophosphorus compounds,
organotins, heavy metals, chlorinated hydrocarbons, radioactive
substances and thermal discharges inter alia. The Protocol in itself
does not define specific emission or time limits; however, it provides
that states should progressively adopt such guidelines and meas-
ures. Following this, in 1997 the MED POL programme assisted
countries to design and adopt the ‘Strategic Action Programme
to Address Pollution of the Mediterranean Sea from Land-Based
Activities (SAP)’, which entails more specific emission and time
limits for pollution reduction.
A case study of the Mediterranean Action Plan 225
Phase II of MED POL lasted from 1981 until 1990 and was named the
‘Long-term Pollution Monitoring and Research Programme’. For effective
implementation of its specific objectives it was divided into four distinct
components: monitoring, research and study topics, data quality assur-
ance, and assistance. Overall coordination of Phase II was in the hands of
the Mediterranean Action Plan Coordinating Unit (the Secretariat of the
Barcelona Convention) acting on behalf of UNEP, even though the coun-
tries were fully responsible for monitoring activities as stated in Article 12
of the Barcelona Convention and in Article 8 of the Land-Based Sources
Protocol.
MED POL has recently finished its Phase III, which started in 1996 and
lasted until 2005. Just before the end of Phase II important events at both
international and regional levels took place, which guided MED POL to
change its direction. These events were the adoption of Agenda 21 in Rio
1992 and the Global Plan of Action (GPA) in 1995 in Washington (UNEP,
1995a) to address pollution from land-based sources and activities, and
creation of the Mediterranean Commission for Sustainable Development
(MCSD) together with the amended LBS Protocol at regional level. Hence
there was a slow change from pollution assessment to pollution control,
with MED POL becoming a tool for the countries to properly manage
their marine and coastal areas. MED POL Phase III, adopted in 1995 and
called the ‘Programme for the Assessment and Control of Pollution in
the Mediterranean Region’, was directly concerned with implementation
of the two relevant protocols (Dumping and LBS), since it focused more
on management of pollution control (UNEP, 1999). It included activities
such as pollutant trend monitoring and assessing effects of contaminants
on living organisms as well as inventory of pollution sources and loads
and finally the setting up of a database. Regarding control, compliance
230 A handbook of environmental management
Conclusion
Environmental problems, instead of a solution per se, demand an effective
management through time. Since this management especially in the case
of global or transboundary environmental problems is very often in the
hands of international environmental regimes, special attention should be
paid to the design and implementation of these regimes, as well as to their
assessment. The new perspective on international environmental regime
effectiveness might perhaps prove a helpful tool towards this direction.
Nevertheless, further research is needed in order to specify new ways
that would bridge the gap between science and policy, which would
provide realistic solutions reconciling conflicting interests and that would
give life to human-made institutions.
Note
1. The author is very grateful to Neil Carter for his valuable comments on earlier drafts
of this study. Special thanks go to Evangelos Raftopoulos for his inspiring ideas during
several discussions on the research. Thanks also go to Jon Lovett and Gabriela Kütting
for their overall support. The Firos Foundation is gratefully acknowledged for funding
the author’s doctoral studies.
References
Ausubel, J.H. and D.G. Victor (1992), ‘Verification of International Environmental
Agreements’, Annual Review of Energy and Environment, 17(1), 1–43.
238 A handbook of environmental management
Levy, M.A., O.R. Young and M. Zürn (1994), ‘The Study of International Regimes’,
Working Paper No. 94-113, Laxenburg, Austria: International Institute for Applied
Systems Analysis.
Levy, M.A., O.R. Young and M. Zürn (1995), ‘The Study of International Regimes’,
European Journal of International Relations, 1(3), 267–330.
Massoud, M.A., M.D. Scrimshaw and J.N. Lester (2003), ‘Qualitative Assessment of
the Effectiveness of the Mediterranean Action Plan: Wastewater Management in the
Mediterranean Region’, Ocean & Coastal Management, 46(9–10), 875–99.
Miles, E.L., A. Underdal, S. Andresen, J. Wettestad, J.B. Skjaerseth and E.M. Carlin (2002),
Environmental Regime Effectiveness: Confronting Theory with Evidence, Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Mitchell, R.B. (2004), ‘A Quantitative Approach to Evaluating International Environmental
Regimes’, in A. Underdal and O.R. Young (eds), Regime Consequences: Methodological
Challenges and Research Strategies, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.
Mitchell, R.B. and T. Bernauer (2002), ‘Qualitative Research Design in International
Environmental Policy’, Working Paper No. 2-2002. Zurich: Swiss Federal Institute of
Technology.
Morgenthau, H. (1978), Politics Among Nations, 5th edition, New York: Knopf.
North, D.C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, New York
and Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Paterson, M. (1996), Global Warming and Global Politics, London: Routledge.
Paterson, M. (2000), Understanding Global Environmental Politics: Domination, Accumulation,
Resistance, London: Macmillan.
Pavasovic, A. (1996), ‘The Mediterranean Action Plan Phase II and the Revised Barcelona
Convention: New Prospective for Integrated Coastal Management in the Mediterranean
Region’, Ocean & Coastal Management, 31(2–3), 133–82.
Raftopoulos, E. (1993), The Barcelona Convention and Protocols. The Mediterranean Action
Plan Regime, London: Simmonds and Hill.
Raftopoulos, E. (1997), Studies on the Implementation of the Barcelona Convention: the
Development of an International Trust Regime, Athens: Ant. N. Sakkoulas.
Raftopoulos, E. and M.L. McConnell (2004), Contributions to International Environmental
Negotiation in the Mediterranean Context, Athens and Brussels: Ant. N. Sakkoulas,
Bruylant.
Sands, P. (2003), Principles of International Environmental Law, 2nd edition, Cambridge,
UK: Cambridge University Press.
Skjaerseth, J.B. (1996), ‘The 20th Anniversary of the Mediterranean Action Plan: Reason to
Celebrate?’, in H.O. Bergesen and G. Parmann (eds), Green Globe Yearbook 1996, Oxford,
UK: Oxford University Press.
Skjaerseth, J.B. (2002), ‘The Effectiveness of the Mediterranean Action Plan’, in E.L.
Miles, A. Underdal, S. Andresen, J. Wettestad, J.B. Skjaerseth and E.M. Carlin (eds),
Environmental Regime Effectiveness: Confronting Theory with Evidence, Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Stevis, D. and V.J. Assetto (2001), The International Political Economy of the Environment:
Critical Perspectives, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Swatuk, L.A. (2006), ‘Environmental Security’, in M.M. Betsill, K. Hochstetler and D. Stevis
(eds), International Environmental Politics, Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Underdal, A. (1992), ‘The Concept of Regime Effectiveness’, Cooperation and Conflict, 27(3),
227–40.
Underdal, A. (2002), ‘One Question, Two Answers’, in E.L. Miles, A. Underdal, S. Andresen,
J. Wettestad, J.B. Skjaerseth and E.M. Carlin (eds), Environmental Regime Effectiveness:
Confronting Theory with Evidence, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
UNEP (1978), Mediterranean Action Plan and the Final Act of the Conference of
Plenipotentiaries of the Coastal States of the Mediterranean Region for the Protection of the
Mediterranean Sea, New York: United Nations.
UNEP (1995a), Report of the Ninth Ordinary Meeting of the Contracting Parties to the
240 A handbook of environmental management
Convention for the Protection of the Mediterranean Sea against Pollution and its Protocols,
UNEP(OCA)/MED IG.5/16, Athens: UNEP.
UNEP (1995b), Global Programme of Action for the Protection of the Marine Environment
from Land-Based Activities, UNEP(OCA)/LBA/IG.2/7, Washington, DC: UNEP.
UNEP (1999), MED POL – Phase III, Programme for the Assessment and Control of
Pollution in the Mediterranean Region, MAP Technical Reports Series No. 120, Athens:
UNEP.
UNEP/MAP (2003), Report of the Thirteenth Ordinary Meeting of the Contracting Parties
to the Convention for the Protection of the Mediterranean Sea against Pollution and its
Protocols, UNEP(DEC)/MED IG.15/11, Athens: UNEP/MAP.
UNEP/MAP (2005a), Convention for the Protection of the Marine Environment and the
Coastal Region of the Mediterranean and its Protocols, Athens: UNEP/MAP.
UNEP/MAP (2005b), Evaluation of MED POL Phase III Programme (1996–2005),
UNEP(DEC)/MED WG.270/Inf.10, Athens: UNEP/MAP.
UNEP/MAP (2005c), Recommendations for 2006–2007, UNEP(DEC)/MED IG.16/5,
Athens: UNEP/MAP.
Vallega, A. (1996), ‘Geographical Coverage and Effectiveness of the UNEP Convention on
the Mediterranean’, Ocean & Coastal Management, 31(2–3), 199–218.
Victor, D.G. (2003), ‘International Agreements and the Struggle to Tame Carbon’, in J.M.
Griffin (ed.), Global Climate Change: The Science, Economics and Politics, Cheltenham,
UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.
von Moltke, K. (2000), ‘Research on the Effectiveness of International Environmental
Agreements: Lessons for Policy Makers?’, in Final Conference within the EU-financed
Concerted Action Programme on the Effectiveness of International Environmental
Agreements and EU Legislation held in Barcelona 9–11 November 2000, Lysaker, Norway:
The Fridtjof Nansen Institute.
Waltz, K.N. (1979), Theory of International Politics, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Weale, A. (1992), The New Politics of Pollution, Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Wettestad, J. and S. Andresen (1991), The Effectiveness of International Resource
Cooperation: Some Preliminary Findings, Lysaker, Norway: The Fridtjof Nasnen
Institute.
Young, O.R. (1989), International Cooperation: Building Regimes for Natural Resources and
the Environment, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Young, O.R. (1999), The Effectiveness of International Environmental Regimes: Causal
Connections and Behavioral Mechanisms, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Young, O.R. (2001), ‘Inferences and Indices: Evaluating the Effectiveness of International
Environmental Regimes’, Global Environmental Politics, 1(1), 99–121.
Young, O.R. (2003), ‘Determining Regime Effectiveness: A Commentary on the Oslo–
Potsdam Solution’, Global Environmental Politics, 3(3), 97–104.
8. The price of fish and the value of seagrass
beds: socioeconomic aspects of the
seagrass fishery on Quirimba Island,
Mozambique1
Fiona R. Gell
Introduction
Marine resource use is an important component of the local economy
in many tropical coastal areas. The importance of marine resources to
a community depends on the geographic and economic situation of the
area: the level of development, the role of tourism and the availability of
alternative sources of income (Ruddle, 1996a). In areas near international
airports and large cities, marine resources can be exported to an interna-
tional market or sold to tourists and can fetch high prices. In more isolated
places without a developed transport infrastructure, marine resources may
only be used on a subsistence level in the immediate local area and thus
have a much lower economic value (White et al., 1994; Lindén and Lundin,
1996; Birkeland, 1997). However, in such isolated places the local value of
marine resources is high because they are often the most important source
of income and animal protein.
To manage marine resources it is important to assess the ecological
status of the habitats and organisms that are being exploited. It is also
important to assess how local people use marine resources and their role
in the local economy. As the socioeconomic structures of coastal com-
munities develop and change, the intensity with which marine resources
are exploited also changes. In the past this generally happened on a local
or perhaps national level. However, at the beginning of the twenty-first
century, the phenomenon of ‘globalization’ means that few places really
are remote or inaccessible any longer. Economic growth and social change
in one place can affect the extent to which marine resources are exploited
in other parts of the same country, in other countries and even in other
continents. For instance, rapid economic growth in Asia has had a direct
impact on the sustainable use of marine resources throughout the Pacific,
from Taiwan to the Galapagos, with large Asian companies buying live
reef fish, sea cucumbers and other marine products to supply the growing
Far Eastern markets (Birkeland, 1997).
241
242 A handbook of environmental management
Study area
This study was conducted as part of the Frontier-Moçambique Quirimba
Archipelago Marine Research Programme. Much of the socioeconomic
data presented here were collected on Quirimba Island, one of the two
most densely populated islands in the Archipelago, during 13 months’
fieldwork over a period of two years (1996 and 1997). Quirimba Island
is 6km long by 2km wide. It is situated within a few kilometres of the
Mozambican mainland and is part of Ibo District in the province of Cabo
Delgado. At low spring tides it is possible to walk between the island and
the mainland and also to Ibo Island to the north and Sencar Island to the
south. Quirimba has 3000 inhabitants, most of whom live in Quirimba
village at the northern tip of the island. A few hundred people live outside
the village, the majority in the Kumilamba area in the south of the island.
The seagrass beds of the island have a high diversity of fish with 249
species identified (Gell and Whittington, 2002), which is more than 10 per
cent of the total number of fish species in the Western Indian Ocean.
(Boxer, 1963). This is surprising because they were a key part of the Arab
and Portuguese Indian Ocean empires. Davidson (1961 in Boxer, 1963)
suggests that research on the Quirimbas would enable new insights into
the wide-ranging scope of the Indian Ocean trade. Before the Portuguese
arrived in the sixteenth century, the islands were important as prosperous
Arab trading posts for ivory and slaves. In the seventeenth century they
suffered in the wars between the Portuguese and the Omani Arabs, and
at the end of the seventeenth century the Omanis destroyed most of the
buildings in the stone towns on the islands. In the early nineteenth century
the islands were devastated by Madagascan raiders (Sousa, 1960; Boxer,
1963). Unlike Zanzibar, Mombasa, Kilwa or Mozambique Island, the
Quirimbas did not continue to exist as important Indian Ocean trading
ports or become known for their long histories. The Catholic church in
Quirimba village (now used as the school) dates back to 1894 and there is
also a ruined church, Nossa Senhora do Rozario, that was built around
1580 (Sousa, 1960). Santa Maria beach, where the Frontier-Moçambique
project was based, was said to be where some of the first Portuguese set-
tlers in the Quirimba Archipelago had lived (J. Gessner pers. comm. –
from C.R. Boxer, the historian who visited Quirimba in the 1950s).
Historically the islands seem to have been very productive agriculturally
and able to support residents and visiting traders. They were well placed for
trading goods from the interior such as ivory and gold. Ibo and Quirimba
were also important centres for the Indian Ocean slave trade. Records
from early visitors (mainly Portuguese and British) describe the islands as
productive in terms of agricultural produce, goats and, of course, fish, and
a good place to stop for supplies (Sousa, 1960; Boxer, 1963).
For over 400 years there were Portuguese inhabitants on the islands and
a strong Catholic presence, with parish priests on Ibo and Quirimba. Now
the residents are virtually all of African or mixed African, European and
Arab origin. The coastal people traditionally associated with the coast
of Cabo Delgado are the Mwani who speak a dialect of Kiswahili called
Kimwani, and were traditionally traders and fishers. The coastal Mwani
people are mainly Muslim. They are not as strictly Muslim as many coastal
Tanzanian communities and there is still a strong system of traditional
pre-Islamic beliefs. Witch-doctors or curandeiros are important figures
in the community and are consulted for a huge variety of problems. The
other main group on the island are people of Makua origin, the biggest
ethnic group in Mozambique (West, 1998) living throughout the northern
provinces of the country. A third ethnic group present in small numbers
are the Makonde, from the area around the Tanzania–Mozambique
border. The Makonde are known for their skilled wood carving.
Until 1975 Mozambique was under Portuguese colonial rule, with many
244 A handbook of environmental management
colonial plantations and factories in the rural north. The Portuguese were
strict enforcers of fisheries regulations such as mesh size regulations and in
colonial times there were regular incinerations of illegal nets on Quirimba
(J. Gessner pers. comm.). In 1975 Mozambique gained independence and
the 17-year civil war started. The civil war was fought predominantly in the
ordinary villages of rural Mozambique and the ordinary people of Cabo
Delgado province suffered brutal guerrilla warfare. Tens of thousands of
people became deslocados, refugees within their own country, fleeing vil-
lages that were being destroyed. Many of the deslocados fled to the coast,
and in particular the islands, because the guerrillas would not cross water
and so would not pursue refugees to the islands. This influx of people from
the mainland led to an increase in population on the coast (Massinga and
Hatton, 1997) and on the islands (J. Gessner pers. comm.) and a greater
mix of ethnic groups. Many of the refugees were Makuas and some were
Makondes from the northern Mozambican interior.
In the years following the end of the civil war in 1992, Mozambique
gained a level of stability with the government rebuilding the politi-
cal and economic structure (Macia and Hernroth, 1995). The Human
Development Index of the country as determined by UNDP has risen
over recent years, but Mozambique is still the world’s tenth poorest
country (UNDP, 2006). Development is now happening very quickly in
all sectors of Mozambican life, from tourism to heavy industry. However,
the Quirimbas have been somewhat neglected. They are over 2000km
from the national capital Maputo and difficult to reach and are therefore
rarely visited by politicians and other decision-makers. Infrastructure is
poor and there are few opportunities for the people of the Quirimbas to be
represented or heard at a national level.
Methods
Socioeconomic data were collected on Quirimba using several methods:
suggested other people to talk to, took me to their houses and the houses
of family and friends to learn more about life on Quirimba and showed
me their allotments (machambas) and their other daily work. The informa-
tion presented in the results is therefore assembled from a large number of
mainly informal interviews with a wide spectrum of people in the commu-
nity. The key informants are acknowledged at the end of this chapter.
Some biological information about the women’s invertebrate fishery
was collected in the first year of the project and has been presented in
Barnes et al. (1998). Additional social and economic information about
these fisheries was collected through informal discussion with women in
the village, by accompanying them fishing and through two workshops.
Workshops were organized with the local OMM (Organizaçao da Mulher
Moçambicana – Mozambican Women’s Organization) representative in
the village. The workshops were conducted in Portuguese, Makua and
Kimwani. Most women in Quirimba were illiterate and many did not
speak Portuguese so it was important to use visual methods that were
accessible to all participants.
Locally consumed resources The majority of fish caught locally are con-
sumed locally by fishers and their families or by other local people who
trade goods or services for them.
Locally sold resources Some fresh fish and shellfish are sold locally.
There is no fish or seafood market in the village as such – buyers usually
go to the beach where fish or shellfish that have been collected that day are
landed. Dried produce is occasionally sold between Quirimba residents on
a casual basis.
Table 8.1 Marine species exploited on Quirimba Island with method of capture, user group, habitat captured from,
market and use for the species
247
vaigiensis parrotfish and seine Mainland/ Dried
Pemba
Lethrinus Variegated Sololo Suri trap and Local men Seagrass Local Eaten fresh
variegatus emperor seine net Mainland/ Dried
Pemba
Gerres oyena Blacktip Sala Seine net and Local men Seagrass and Local Eaten fresh
mojarra gill net reef flat Mainland/ Dried
Pemba
Lethrinus Pink ear Njana Seine net Local men Seagrass and Local Eaten fresh
lentjan emperor coral Mainland/ Dried
Pemba
Table 8.1 (continued)
Molluscs
Octopus Octopus Mweza Stick, hook Local women Reef flat Local Eaten fresh and
248
vulgaris dried
Barbatia Ark shell Ombay Hand Local women Intertidal sand Mainly Dried
fusca and seagrass mainland/
Pemba
Pinna Pinna shell Macaza Hand Local women Intertidal sand Mainly Dried
muricata and seagrass mainland/
Pemba
Pinctada Oysters Mbari Hand Local women Intertidal Mainly Dried
nigra seagrass mainland/
Pemba
Pleuroploca Tulip shell Kome nlume Hand/collected Men Seagrass Operculum Animal eaten
trapezium on net or trap sold in fresh
fishing trips Tanzania
Chicoreus Murex Makome Hand/collected Men Seagrass Operculum Animal eaten
ramosus on net or trap sold in fresh
fishing trips Tanzania
Terebralia Mangrove Hand Men/children Mangrove/ None Used for
palustris whelk intertidal flat baiting traps
Echinoderms
Holo- Sea cucumber Magajojo Hand Local finfishers Seagrass and Export Dried for food
thuriidae and itinerants intertidal and medicinal
Mask and Local finfishers Seagrass and Export uses
canoe and itinerants shallow reef
SCUBA Itinerant fishers Reefs Export
Crustacea
249
Panulirus Crayfish Hand/spear/ Local fishery/ Reef Pemba Restaurants
spp. hook some
itinerant/
tourist
Scylla serrata Mangrove Hand Local fishers Mangrove Local Eaten fresh
crabs European
Portunus Swimming Hand/bycatch Children/trap Intertidal flats, Local Eaten fresh
pelagicus crab in traps fishers shallow water
Reptiles
Chelonidae Turtle Assa Incidental catch Local and Reef and Local Eaten fresh
in net itinerant seagrass
Source: From personal observation and interviews and workshops with fishers.
250 A handbook of environmental management
Resources sold outside Quirimba Large quantities of dried fish are sold
off the island in two main ways. First, island-based traders buy fish from
fishers, particularly trap fishers, accumulate a large quantity of dried
fish then sell it in the market in Pemba or in markets elsewhere in Cabo
Delgado province. They buy fish, often a lot of Lethrinus variegatus and
Leptoscarus vaigiensis, for 3000MZN (meticais) per kilo wet weight, and
sell it for 15 000–20 000MZN dried (12 000MZN was equal to approxi-
mately US$1 during the study period, so traders paid US$0.25 per kilo
for fish and sold it for US$1.25–1.67). This seems like a large profit but
in fact the dried fish will have lost up to three-quarters of its wet weight
through drying, gutting and cleaning. Net fishing boat owners also buy
fish to sell on the mainland. They have an arrangement with their boat’s
crew whereby they either buy the majority of fish caught at a reduced price
or they pay their crew a certain wage and receive the majority of the fish as
their share of the operation. They dry this fish and accumulate it in storage
until they have enough to make the trip to Pemba to sell it.
The other main route to sale for Quirimban fish is through fishers
from the mainland who come to Quirimba and the other islands in the
Archipelago to fish. A small proportion of these fishers are from villages
on the nearby mainland such as Mahate and as far south as Pemba. Many
of them have been coming to the Quirimbas to fish for many years. Most
are farmers in the wet season and fish the Quirimbas in the dry season.
The dried fish supplements their family’s diet of maize and cassava, and
can also be sold for cash to buy any goods that the family cannot produce
themselves, such as clothes, cooking oil and medicines.
The majority of the visiting fishers are from the next province south,
Nampula, and have only been fishing the Quirimbas in large numbers for
a few years (from interviews with Nampula fishers and J. Gessner pers.
comm.). These fishers are in a similar situation to those described above –
they have agricultural work in the wet season and come to the Quirimbas
in the dry season to catch fish to dry and take back to eat over the wet
season and to sell. Traders also come to Quirimba to buy dried fish,
which they said is ‘better quality’ than the fish they can buy in Nampula.
These traders deal in hundreds of kilos of fish, which they drive down to
Nampula.
marine resources caught locally, such as shark fin. At the end of the study
period this fishery had temporarily ceased. At least one Tanzanian sea
cucumber fishing operation was active in the Archipelago, using SCUBA
gear. Traditionally, local fishers collect sea cucumbers by snorkelling, thus
limiting the depth range over which they are vulnerable. Ordinary net or
trap fishers who collect sea cucumbers while they are fishing can sell them
individually to traders for up to 1000MZN (less than US$0.10) each. Other
incidental catches that can be sold to traders include seahorses for which a
fisher can get 5000MZN (US$0.40) for a 7cm individual and the opercula of
some shells, which can be sold by the kilo for 150 000MZN (US$12.00) or
individually for a few hundred meticais. These traders sell these resources
on in bulk across the border in Tanzania to be sold on to the Far East.
The prices for fish caught in the seagrass and coral reef fisheries of
Quirimba were remarkably consistent. Fresh fish were sold for a set
price of between 4000 and 5000MZN per kilo. Occasionally large, good
quality lethrinids caught in baited traps or by hook and line were sold
for a higher price (reportedly up to 10 000MZN per kilo) because of
the good quality of lethrinid flesh. Otherwise, everything from a kilo of
7–10cm Lethrinus variegatus or other small fish, to a kilo of a large jack
(Carangidae) or snapper (Lutjanidae) caught in a fence trap was sold for
around 4000MZN. 5000MZN per kilo of fish was the standard price for
fish throughout rural coastal Cabo Delgado. The same price was charged
in the rural Mecufi district south of Pemba, where 5000MZN was quoted
as the lowest price of fish in Mozambique (Loureiro, 1998). Set prices are
common for a variety of commodities in northern Mozambique, from
shellfish to sweet potatoes.
The only way to preserve fish on Quirimba is to dry it in the sun. This is
done on drying racks outside houses in the village. Dried fish was sold on
the mainland for between 15 000 and 20 000MZN per kilo. Small fish are
dried closed (fechado) and were sold for 15 000MZN per kilo and larger fish
are dried open (aberto – like a kipper) and sold for the slightly higher price
of 16 000MZN per kilo. Dried fish often have a slightly ‘off’ taste, which
does not prevent their sale or consumption. Occasionally seagrass parrot-
fish (Leptoscarus vaigiensis) die in the marema traps, and are retrieved in a
partially rotted state. These fish are not discarded and are dried as normal
and sold for consumption. The highest prices, some exceeding 25 000MZN
per kilo were given for dried fish sold in villages a long way inland. The
prices of fish and marine invertebrates on Quirimba are shown in Table
8.2, along with a selection of other local prices for comparison. Note the
high prices per kilo of fresh invertebrates (10 000–15 000MZN) compared
with that of fish (3000–5000MZN), and also the high price of imported
goods such as sugar (20 000MZN per kilo) and onions (25 000 per kilo).
Table 8.2 Prices paid on Quirimba Island for fish, agricultural produce and other goods, their source, mode of
production and how they are made available to the community
252
dry 16 000 1.30 Local and men
Pen shells fresh/kg 15 000 1.25 Local Collected by women Sold direct at beach
Ark shells fresh/kg 10 000 0.83 Local Collected by women Sold direct at beach
Oysters/kg 12 000 1.00 Local Collected by women Sold direct at beach
Mangrove crab/kg 5000 0.42 Local Collected by men
Sweet potato/kg 2000 0.17 Local Grown in Sold in machambas
machambas
Cassava leaves/kg 5000 0.40 Local Grown in Sold in machambas
machambas
Peanuts/kg 4000 0.33 Mainland Sold in village market
Coconut (each) 1000 0.08 Local Machambas and Sold in village market
plantation
Onions/kg 25 000 2.08 Mainland Imported Sold in village market
occasionally/
Quissanga market
Eggs (each) 1000 0.08 Local From chickens kept Sold from home
in village and
machambas
Bread flour/kg 10 000 0.80 Mainland Sold in village shop
Maize flour/kg 6000 0.50 Mainland/local Maize from Sold in village shop
machambas
Rice/kg 10 000 0.80 Mainland Sold in village shop
Papaya (each) 500–2000 0.04–0.16 Local Grown in Sold in machambas
machambas
Mango (each) 100–1000 0.01–0.08 Local Machambas and in Sold in village market
plantation seasonally
Sugar/kg 20 000 1.60 Malawi Imported Sold in village shop
253
Condensed milk 15 000 1.25 Maputo/South Imported Sold in village shop
Africa
Chicken (each) 15 000–25 000 1.25–2.08 Local Reared in village or Sold from home
in machambas
Capulana (sarong – 40 000–80 000 3.33–6.66 Maputo/Tanzania Imported (cheapest Sold in village shop
two pieces) from India)
T-shirt 10 000 0.80 Mainland Imported Sold in village market
occasionally
Trousers 20 000 1.60 Mainland Imported Sold in village market
occasionally
TB medication 40 000 3.33 Mainland Imported Sold at village clinic
(course of
treatment)
Note: Prices are shown in the local currency of Mozambican meticais and US dollars.
254 A handbook of environmental management
Little or no personal investment The main group in this category are the
crew of the seine net fishing boats who need to make very little invest-
ment to start fishing. Some have their own strong shoes to protect against
urchins, others have their own masks but the majority have neither. Young
boys go straight into the seine net fishery and strangers to the island are
also free to enter this fishery.
The women’s invertebrate fishery requires very little personal invest-
ment, needing only a bucket or other container. Women collect inverte-
brates from the intertidal at Santa Maria and Pantopi, and also make trips
on boats out to exposed sand banks at low spring tides. Young children
who collect small species of mollusc from the upper intertidal, and women
who collect these shells for occasional meals can also be included in this
category.
Table 8.3 The average costs of the major items of gear for seine net and
marema trap fishing
A large initial personal investment The main group in this category were
the seine net fishing boat owners. The same person usually owned the net
and the boat, which together could be an investment of over 6 million
MZN (US$500, see Table 8.3). These boat owners were the entrepreneurs
of Quirimba. They had the largest stone-built houses and were amongst
the only people to own motorbikes and other major consumer items. Some
of the boat owners also had other business concerns apart from trading
fish; some had shops in the village, others traded across the border in
Tanzania.
Table 8.4 The major forms of employment on Quirimba, average time worked, salaries and location of the work
Employment Hours Days Daily Salary Daily Salary Annual Annual Salary Location
Worked Worked per Meticais US$ Salary US$
Month Meticais
Trap fisher 4 hours 22–24 15 000–40 000 1.25–3.33 4–10 million 333–833 Montepuez Bay
Net fisher 5 hours 18–20 10 000 0.83 2 160 000 180 Montepuez Bay
Net fishing captain 5 hours 18–20 14 000 1.17 3 024 000 252 Montepuez Bay
Net fishing boat Various Various 111 000 9.25 23 976 000 1998 Montepuez Bay
owner
Work in machamba Various Various – could Food Machambas
(mainly – seasonal be whole day (Kumilamba)
subsistence)
256
Worker in coconut 8 hours 6 days a week 10 000 0.83 3 138 600 262 Plantation
plantation
Fish processor 1–2 hours 18–20 (same as net 4000 0.33 864 000 72 Quiwandala
fishers)
Intertidal 3 hours 6–8 days around 20 000 + 1.67 1 680 000 140 Santa Maria, Saja, etc
invertebrate spring tides
collector
Making bread Various 18–20 (same as net Fish Quiwandala
and cakes to barter fishers)
for fish
Trader Various Various Various Quirimba, Pemba,
Tanzania
Socioeconomic aspects of the seagrass fishery on Quirimba Island 257
The stories of how fishing boat owners made the money to initially
buy the fishing boats varied. Some were local men who had worked their
way up from being a fisher crewing a large seine net fishing boat, to trap
fishing, to buying their own large boat. A few had family money from land
ownership, others had come from the mainland specifically to fish.
The seine net fishing boats were built in Quirimba village with wood
imported from the continent. A 3m boat cost from 2 to 2.5 million meticais
(around US$200). A 4m boat cost around 3 million meticais. One of the
boat owners interviewed had bought his current fishing boat for 1.5 million
four years previously. The nets were bought on the mainland, usually in
Pemba. A new net complete with floats, weights and ropes reportedly
cost 10 million meticais but all the boat owners interviewed had bought
their nets second-hand for around 3 million meticais. They expected the
nets to last for 10–15 years. Various systems of payment were used on the
fishing boats. Some of the boat owners paid their crew 4000MZN per kg
of fish caught and said their catch could range from a few kilos to a few
hundred kilos. The pay per trip for the crew worked out at 10 000MZN per
fisher and 14 000MZN for the captain, and some small share of the catch,
usually 1kg. The owners also had to pay four or so people to clean the fish.
They were usually paid one kilo of fish or 4000MZN each day. (See Table
8.4 for salaries for the various fishing jobs on Quirimba and Table 8.5 for
the costs and earnings in the seagrass trap and net fisheries.)
Table 8.5 Summary of average values for various aspects of the seagrass
trap and net fisheries
managed this way to work harder to maximize their earnings. The boats
that seemed to work the most efficiently were those with small crews of
five or so. They had to work harder than larger crews to haul the nets but
they often seemed more efficient at getting their boats out, catching the fish
and returning to port. Many of the boats with large crews of 12 or more
seemed to be primarily a social occasion that just happened to result in
something to eat and some money.
Socioeconomic aspects of the seagrass fishery on Quirimba Island 259
Trap fishing The average daily catch per fisher for trap fishing was 7kg,
an average daily earning of 28 000MZN, nearly three times the average
salary as a labourer or as fishing crew. Trap fishers fished alone and
cleaned their own fish and so had no expenditure on a day-to-day basis. If
fishers could sell their catch fresh in the village they would get 4 000MZN
whereas if they sold it all in one go to a fish trader they would only get
3000MZN per kilo (21 000MZN for an average catch) but they could
organize this in advance and would be guaranteed to sell it all on the day
they caught it. Trap fishers usually retained about 1kg of their catch for
their own consumption. Very few trap fishers dried their own fish.
fire, their tough skins protecting the flesh from burning. Other toxic fish
such as scorpionfish (Scorpaenidae), catfish (Plotosidae) and most puffer-
fish and tobies (Tetraodontidae) were discarded but some large pufferfish
were retained for sale to Makua people in Pemba and Nampula. Some
Makua people eat these fish and know the special methods for preparing
them to avoid fatal poisoning.
Fishing traditions
Fishing communities all over the world have long traditions and complex
systems of beliefs and superstitions (Ruddle, 1996b), from the South
Pacific (Johannes, 1981) to the Isle of Man (pers. obs.; Manx Heritage
Foundation, 1991). In southern Kenya, where the habitats and fishing
methods are similar to those used on Quirimba and the coastal people
have a broadly similar cultural history with strong Arab influences, strong
fishing traditions still exist (McClanahan et al., 1997). There were few
traditions associated with fishing in Quirimba but it was difficult to ascer-
tain whether this was because there had been a complex system of beliefs
that had gradually disappeared or whether there had never been such a
belief system. The seine net fishers did not seem to have any traditions or
superstitions directly associated with fishing apart from a vague concept
of ‘luck’. One fisher sometimes wore a seamoth fish (Pegasidae) round
his neck as a talisman to bring luck. Seeing dolphins during fishing was
considered good luck. On the other hand, fishers in some parts of Kenya
still hold ritual ceremonies and have sacred sites at sea where offerings
are made to spirits to improve fishing. These rituals are gradually being
lost, in many instances because Islam is increasing in strength and the
younger generation of Muslim fishers see the traditional rituals as against
Islam. Although there has been a lot of population movement around the
Kenyan coastal area, it probably does not approach the large-scale migra-
tion of people around the north of Mozambique as a consequence of the
war. McClanahan et al. (1997) suggest that the more recent Islamization
of culture in Kenya is linked to the decay of the rich and elaborate cul-
tural traditions of coastal management. This may also be the case to some
extent in Quirimba.
There were a number of traditions associated with eating fish or other
marine products. When dugongs were caught, and they were fished in the
area up until the 1990s, they had to be taken to the mosque for blessing
before they were eaten. Dugong meat was given to pregnant women to
make their babies ‘beautiful’. Other fish species were by tradition not eaten
by pregnant women because they were said to harm the baby. (In a place
where a large proportion of women lost babies at late stages of pregnancy
and where infant mortality was high it was not surprising that there were
Socioeconomic aspects of the seagrass fishery on Quirimba Island 261
since 1994 but the prices of nets have evidently fallen as supply networks
to the area have improved. In the 1980s the price of fish in Cabo Delgado
was kept artificially elevated; the price of fish decreased nine-fold since
1986 from US$3.37 for a kilo of fish in Pemba to just US$0.39 in 1993
(during the 1980s ordinary people in Pemba did not eat local fish, but
ate fish imported from around Africa – there was a notorious poisoning
incident from freshwater fish – M. Carvalho pers. comm.). Fishers in the
area have very low financial incentives and little access to new gear, pre-
cluding anything more than subsistence fishing (Republic of Mozambique
State Secretariat of Fisheries, 1994a) and also face the storage and
transportation problems mentioned above.
National per capita consumption of fish was estimated at 5.1kg per year
in 1994 (Republic of Mozambique State Secretariat of Fisheries, 1994b). It
is likely that per capita consumption of fish on Quirimba greatly exceeded
this national value. Fishers and their families shared about 1kg of fish per
fishing day. Each person ate approximately 100g per day on fishing days
(16 days per month), giving 1.6kg per month and a minimum of 19.2kg
of fish per year. In addition to this dried fish was also often eaten on the
non-fishing days.
In 1989 Cabo Delgado had 4539 fishers accounting for 0.7 per cent of
the working population, the same proportion of fishers in the population
as was seen on a national scale. Quirimba Island had approximately 400
fishers in a population of 3000, so fishers there accounted for at least 10 per
cent of the population and a much higher percentage of the working popu-
lation. Between 1989 and 1994 the number of fishers nationally increased
from 52 000 to 80 000 and a similar increase would be expected in Cabo
Delgado. This increase has mainly been attributed to the displacement
of the population towards the coast because of the civil war (Republic of
Mozambique State Secretariat of Fisheries, 1994b; Hatton and Massinga,
1994). With this migration there has been a disproportionate increase in
the numbers of people living off subsistence fishing, often the only source
of food and employment to displaced people. The pressure on artisanal
coastal fisheries has been particularly intense because, although there was
a surge of people to the coast in the 1980s and early 1990s, there was no
accompanying development of the local fishing industry or related diver-
sification of activities. This situation is described as having led to the local
population and the refugees collectively mining as opposed to husbanding
the littoral resources (Hatton and Massinga, 1994).
changeable and it was often not possible to anchor the project’s research
boat off the outer reef of Quirimba to do survey dives. It was regularly not
possible to get the boat out onto the east coast of the island at all because
of strong winds and rough seas. Traditional sailing dhows were almost
certainly better suited to fishing in the shallow seagrass beds than boats
with outboard engines. There was thus no incentive to ‘develop’ fishing
techniques.
in the wet season (November to April) but many people were involved
all year round. The food available in the local market was very limited
and imported shop-bought food was prohibitively expensive, so most
people relied on food grown in their machambas for the bulk of their food,
with fish or shellfish providing the animal protein. The machambas were
constantly being expanded into the few remaining areas of forest and
scrub by slash and burn clearing methods. On Inhaca Island in southern
Mozambique this method has produced land that is high in nutrients
for the first year of cultivation but that soon becomes poor in nutrients
and becomes impossible to cultivate after 15 years (Serra King, 1995).
Erosion is also a problem in land cleared by slash and burn, and this may
be something that will impact on the coastal habitats. The cash economy
was very limited so there were few shops and it was virtually impossible
to buy a meal or cooked food of any kind in the village, so there were few
opportunities in service jobs. This situation may be typical of a largely
cashless economy for poor rural Mozambicans. In Tanzania many rural
areas are much more developed and there are more opportunities for jobs
with regular salaries and cash (Andersson and Ngazi, 1998). Street food
is common and provides an extra employment opportunity. There was no
tourist industry mainly because of the inaccessibility of the island and the
lack of basic infrastructure.
The gender roles in the fishery at Quirimba were fairly typical of those
found in tropical artisanal fisheries around the world. Women throughout
East Africa, South East Asia and the South Pacific glean intertidal flats
for invertebrates and the fishery for fish is dominated by men (Palau –
Matthews and Oiterong, 1995; South East Asia – Bailey and Pomeroy,
1996; Kenya – Juma, 1998). Although the biology of the women’s inver-
tebrate fishery was not included in the present study and can be found
in Barnes et al. (1998), the socioeconomics were studied to some extent.
Women collected the three main species of mollusc on the intertidal
(mainly Thalassia hemprichii) and upper subtidal seagrass beds (mainly
Enhalus acoroides).
The community on Quirimba utilized a wide variety of resources.
Although seine net fishing in the seagrass beds was the main single
employer, most households used a wide range of sources of subsistence
food and additional income, typically a mixture of men’s income from
fishing by net or trap, food from the machambas grown predominantly
by women, invertebrates gleaned from the seagrass intertidal by women
and some additional invertebrates collected by children. Consequently,
although many people were involved in the seagrass-based fish and inver-
tebrate fishery very few people, except maybe some boat owners, were
entirely reliant on the seagrass fishery. As Bailey and Pomeroy (1996)
270 A handbook of environmental management
Itinerant fishers
Small numbers of itinerant fishers from local mainland villages have
fished seasonally in the Quirimbas, but in the five years preceding the
272 A handbook of environmental management
fish to provide protein in local diets will increase. The pressure to exploit
resources for sale outside the community to bring in much-needed cash for
medicines and other manufactured goods will increase and these commu-
nities may already be exceeding sustainable levels of exploitation.
Influx of visiting itinerant fishers from outside the local area The influx
of itinerant fishers was a recent phenomenon and had only really had a
major impact on the islands since the beginning of the 1990s (Gessner pers.
comm.). It is likely, however, that the numbers of itinerant fishers and the
intensity with which they fish will increase as the pressures on fisheries and
other resources in their home villages and towns increase and more people
seek the reputed wealth of resources in the Quirimbas. The commercial
fishing sector is also likely to grow to feed the expanding tourist market.
and his family. Malaria and tuberculosis are both common potentially
life-threatening illnesses, and both can be controlled using medicines that
are cheap by Western standards, but even the most basic treatments can
be prohibitively expensive. There will be an increasing pressure on the
people of the Quirimbas to find ways of earning cash so that they can deal
with these emergencies and also so that they have the freedom to buy the
consumer goods that are becoming available.
Based on this analysis, four basic needs can be identified that could
begin to address the potential problems in the Quirimbas:
within the province. The use of unacceptably small mesh sizes, in some
cases even finer material such as sacking, and other fishing gear infringe-
ments also need to be addressed. Active fisheries monitoring in the islands
is definitely required.
Conclusions
In conclusion, the study reported here showed that fishing was the single
most important source of food and employment on Quirimba Island,
along with subsistence agriculture and the women’s invertebrate fishery,
but the majority of people and households relied on a combination of
marine resource use and agriculture. Seagrass beds were the main habitat
to be exploited on Quirimba and therefore the most valuable habitat to
the community. There was a hierarchy of earnings in the seagrass fishery
in Quirimba, with boat owners being the highest earners, then trap fishers
followed by boat captains and boat crew. Net fishing was the biggest single
source of employment on the island and yielded the lowest wages of jobs
Socioeconomic aspects of the seagrass fishery on Quirimba Island 279
for young men. Net fishing may have been preferred to better-paid trap
fishing or plantation work because it was sociable, flexible and seemed to
be enjoyable. Small fish may have been preferred for social and economic
reasons. They could be used easily for barter and were easy to cook, dry and
sell. Interestingly, there were remarkably few conflicts between the users of
marine resources despite the fact that there were overlapping uses of the
resource and many recently arrived fishers. However, an increasing popula-
tion and a declining resource base will inevitably lead to competition and
environmental degradation unless there is investment in the community.
Note
1. There were many people in Quirimba village and in Kumilamba who gave generously
of their time to assist in the collection of the information in this chapter. Much of the
information was collected with the help of trap fisher Anibal Amade who suggested
many useful interviewees, provided translation assistance where necessary and also pro-
vided detailed information on the trap fishery. Seine net fishers Mussa and Lamu from
Quirimba spent hours explaining the workings of the Quirimba fisheries and introduced
me to many other fishers, including reef flat gill netters. Saidi Ndiki, an older gill net
fisher, was interviewed on a number of occasions about this fishery. Captains Ibrahimo,
Manueli and Jabira from the seine net fishery provided a great deal of useful informa-
tion. Oscari, Zaidu and Momadi from Santa Maria were key informants on the fisheries.
For general information on the economics of life on Quirimba, Awaje Shale and her
family were very helpful. The workshop with the invertebrate fishers was organized with
Fatima Mussa and other women from OMM (Mozambican Women’s Organization) in
the village. Mario Carvalho and Alex Corrie of The Frontier-Moçambique project pro-
vided assistance with translation and setting up interviews and so on, and the rest of the
Frontier staff, visitors and volunteers provided invaluable support at various times. The
Quirimbas National Park was designated in 2002.
References
Andersson, J. and Z. Ngazi (1998), ‘Coastal communities’ production choices. Risk diver-
sification and subsistence behaviour: responses in periods of transition’, Ambio, 27(8),
686–93.
Bach, S.B., J. Borum, M.D. Fortes and C.M. Duarte (1998), ‘Species composition and
plant performance of mixed seagrass beds along a siltation gradient at Cape Bolinao, the
Philippines’, Marine Ecology Progress Series, 174, 247–56.
Bailey, C. and C. Pomeroy (1996), ‘Resource dependency and development options in coastal
Southeast Asia’, Society and Natural Resources, 9(1), 190–99.
Barnes, D.K.A., A. Corrie, M.W. Whittington, M.A. Carvalho and F.R. Gell (1998),
‘Coastal shellfish resource use in the Quirimba Archipelago, Mozambique’, Journal of
Shellfish Biology, 17(1), 51–8.
Birkeland, C. (1997), ‘Disposable income in Asia – a new and powerful external pressure
against sustainability of coral reef resources on Pacific Islands’, Reef Encounter, 22,
9–13.
Boxer, C.R. (1963), ‘The Querimba Islands in 1744’, Studia, 11, 343–60.
Chambers, R. (1997), Whose Reality Counts? Putting the First Last, London: Intermediate
Technology Publications.
Dahalani, Y. (1997), L’Impact de la pêche au ‘djarifa’ sur le recrutement des populations
des poissons et des crustacés en face des mangroves du littoral côtier de Mayotte (baie de
Chiconi), Centre d’Océanologie de Marseille and Service des Pêches et de l’Environment
Marin de Mayotte.
280 A handbook of environmental management
Dayaratne, P., O. Linden and R. De Silva (1995), ‘Puttalam Lagoon and Mundel Lake, Sri
Lanka: A study of coastal resources, their utilization, environmental issues and manage-
ment options’, Ambio, 24(7), 391–401.
Gayanilo, F.C. and D. Pauly (1997), FAO Stock Assessment Tools: Reference Manual,
Rome: ICLARM/FAO.
Gell, F.R. and M.W. Whittington (2002), ‘Diversity of fishes in seagrass beds in the Quirimba
Archipelago, northern Mozambique’, Marine and Freshwater Research, 53(2), 115–21.
Gengenbach, H. (1998), ‘“I’ll bury you in the border!”: Women’s land struggles in post-war
Facazisse (Magude District), Mozambique’, Journal of Southern African Studies, 24(1),
7–36.
Guard, M. and M. Masaiganah (1997), ‘Dynamite fishing in southern Tanzania: Geographical
variation, intensity of use and possible solutions’, Marine Pollution Bulletin, 34(10),
758–62.
Hatton, J. and A. Massinga (1994), The Natural Resources of Mecufi District. Mecufi Coastal
Zone Management Project, Maputo, Mozambique: Ministry of Environment.
Jennings, S. and N.V.C. Polunin (1996), ‘Fishing strategies, fishery development and socio-
economics in traditionally managed Fijian fishing grounds’, Fisheries Management and
Ecology, 3, 335–47.
Johannes, R.E. (1981), Words of the Lagoon, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Juma, S.A. (1998), ‘Men, women and natural resources in Kwale District, Kenya’, Ambio,
27(8), 758–9.
Lindén, O. (1993), ‘Resolution on integrated coastal zone management in East Africa signed
in Arusha, Tanzania’, Ambio, 22(6), 408–9.
Lindén, O. and C.G. Lundin (1996), ‘The journey from Arusha to the Seychelles: Successes
and failures in integrated coastal zone management in Eastern Africa and island states’,
Proceedings of the Second Policy Conference on Integrated Coastal Zone Management
in Eastern Africa and Island States, Seychelles, 23–25 October: World Bank and Sida/
SAREC.
Loureiro, N.L. (1998), ‘Estudo da ictiofauna coralina e pesqueira do distrito de Mecúfi,
Província de Cabo Delgado’, Tese de Lienciatura, Universidade Eduardo Mondlane,
Maputo, Mozambique.
Lundin, C.G. and O. Lindén (eds) (1997), ‘Integrated coastal zone management in
Mozambique’, Proceedings of the National Workshop, Inhaca Island/Maputo,
Mozambique 1996: World Bank and SIDA/SAREC.
Macia, A. and L. Hernroth (1995), ‘Maintaining sustainable resources and biodiversity while
promoting development – a demanding task for a developing nation’, Ambio, 24(7–8),
515–17.
Manx Heritage Foundation (1991), Manx Sea Fishing, Douglas, Isle of Man: Manx Heritage
Foundation Publications.
Massinga, A. (1997), ‘Mecufi coastal zone management project’, Proceedings of the National
Workshop on Integrated Coastal Zone Management in Mozambique, Inhaca Island and
Maputo, Mozambique, May 1996.
Massinga, A. and J. Hatton (1997), ‘Status of the coastal zone of Mozambique’, Proceedings
of the National Workshop on Integrated Coastal Zone Management in Mozambique,
Inhaca Island and Maputo, Mozambique, May 1996.
Matthews, E. and E. Oiterong (1995), ‘Marine species collected by women in Palau,
Micronesia’, Micronesia, 28(1), 77–90.
McClanahan, T.R., H. Glaesel, J. Rubens and R. Kiambo (1997), ‘The effects of traditional
fisheries management on fisheries yields and the coral-reef ecosystems of southern Kenya’,
Environmental Conservation, 24(2), 105–20.
McManus, J.W. (1993), ‘Managing seagrass fisheries in Southeast Asia: An introductory
overview’, in M.D. Fortes and N. Wirjoatmodjo (eds), Seagrass Resources in South
East Asia, technical papers from the advanced training course/workshop on Seagrass
Resources, Research and Management (SEAGRAM 2), Quezon City, Philippines, 1990.
MICOA (Ministry for the Coordination of Environmental Affairs, Mozambique) (1997),
Socioeconomic aspects of the seagrass fishery on Quirimba Island 281
Introduction
Over the last two decades, sustainable development has become widely
accepted as the goal that environmental management should strive to
achieve. The idea of sustainable development has evolved due to the inherent
tensions between economic development and the desire to protect the envi-
ronment. The most commonly used definition comes from the Brundtland
Report, which defines sustainable development as: ‘Development that
meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future
generations to meet their own needs’ (WCED, 1987, p. 43).
The argument in favour of sustainable development has often been
characterized as a response to the fact that economic development
in a capitalist market economy leads to environmental degradation
(Carter, 2001; Anand, 2003). This, however, fails to recognize that some
approaches to protecting the environment can result in negative economic
impacts where such protection prevents previous economic uses of natural
resources – a particularly important issue for developing countries where
the poorest people often depend most directly on natural resources for
their livelihoods. In such situations, the challenge for environmental man-
agers working to achieve sustainable development is how to protect and
conserve natural resources at the same time as protecting the livelihoods of
poor people. Furthermore, management approaches also need to enable
poor people to develop opportunities to improve their economic situation
and lift themselves out of poverty in the long term. Recognition of this
link between sustainable environmental management and the eradication
of poverty is central to the thinking behind goals 1 and 7 of the United
Nations Millennium Development Goals, which aim, respectively, to erad-
icate extreme poverty and ensure environmental sustainability. Within this
context, therefore, ‘environmental management for sustainable develop-
ment’ needs to protect the environment at the same time as protecting and
developing the livelihoods of those people who depend on it.
282
A case study of semi-arid Tanzania 283
et al., 2001; Stanhill and Cohen, 2001; Roderick and Farquhar, 2002).
Lower surface solar radiation reduces the energy available for evaporation
leading to reduced rainfall and disruption of tropical circulation patterns
(Ramanathan et al., 2001).
The climate of semi-arid regions and its variability has a strong influ-
ence on the vegetation found in semi-arid regions. Vegetation distribu-
tion, diversity and productivity are all influenced in the first order by
climate, but also by soils, competition, fire and grazing (O’Brien, 1993;
HilleRisLambers et al., 2001). Two large phytogeographical regions are
recognized to cover most of the semi-arid region of Tanzania, the Somalia-
Maasai region and the Zambezian region as described by White (1983)
(see Figure 9.1). The Somalia-Maasai region is the driest vegetation type
found predominantly in north and central Tanzania and is comprised of
a range of grass-dominated savanna habitats. Savannas vary from com-
pletely grass-dominated grass savanna through bushland, thicket and
shrubland, to tree savannas and wooded savannas (Jacobs et al., 1999).
Trees and shrubs can comprise up to 50 per cent of species composition
but the canopy remains open (Trapnell and Langdale-Brown, 1972).
Included within the Somalia-Maasai region are the edaphic savanna
grasslands found on the Serengeti plains (see Figure 9.1). These grasslands
occur on soils derived from volcanic ash, which tend to be alkaline and
often have a hard calcareous pan created by the leaching of carbonates
through the soil by rainfall (White, 1983). The calcareous pan creates a
barrier to root growth, preventing the growth of woody vegetation, and
is also impermeable to water so that these areas can be prone to flooding
during the rainy season. Savannas are believed to have existed in East
Africa for 20 million years and were, in part, created by the development
of seasonal rainfall patterns that restricted the distribution of tropical
rainforests (Pratt et al., 1966). Today a mixture of climate, soils, natural
fires, grazing and anthropogenic influences maintain the open nature of
savanna ecosystems.
The Zambezian region consists of miombo woodland dominated by
trees from the genus Brachystegia (Kingdon, 1971; White, 1983; Lovett
et al., 2001). The region forms a crescent in the south of Tanzania around
the more arid Somalia-Maasai region (see Figure 9.1). It is less recognized
as a semi-arid ecosystem even though it can occur in areas with rainfall
as low as 500mm per year. Drier miombo woodland tends to be less
diverse while wetter miombo woodland vegetation has to be adapted to
periods of flooding and waterlogging followed by long dry seasons with
little available water and frequent fires. It has been argued that in some
areas miombo forests may be the result of long-term human disturbance
(Hamilton, 1982; White, 1983). Certainly, in areas with deeper soils,
286 A handbook of environmental management
EDAPHIC GRASSLAND
SOMALIA-MAASAI VEGETATION
ZAMBEZIAN VEGETATION
MAJOR LAKES
N
Note: Rainfall upper limit of 900mm per annum, equivalent to the FAO
agroclimatological classification of semi-arid regions; growing period 75–119 days. (Seasons
are defined on the basis of climatic fluctuations in Tanzania and take into account the long
rains and short rains.)
and discrete tribes, rather that tribal membership was fluid and the result
of adaptation to the landscape (Iliffe, 1979). Tribal membership also did
not mean isolation from other groups. Many shared a common heritage
and continued to interact through trade, intermarriage and migration
(Homewood and Rodgers, 1991).
Kieran (1972), Shorter (1974) and Iliffe (1979) have attempted to discuss
in detail the origins and history of people in East Africa. The historical
development of societies in Tanzania will be discussed here based on their
A case study of semi-arid Tanzania 291
designated and used for dry or wet season grazing, or only used in years
of drought. Fire was often used to clear woody vegetation and encourage
grass growth in grazing areas, reducing woody biomass and maintaining
a more open savanna system. Agricultural groups also used fire to clear
areas for growing crops, and brought in new plant species such as banana,
sorghum, millet and maize, which they grew in different areas depending
on soil quality and rainfall. As a result, settlement patterns depended on
soil quality and water availability. Only in the highlands where soils were
generally more fertile, rainfall higher and competition for land greater did
communities settle for long periods and invest in their fields. In semi-arid
regions agricultural communities moved regularly to clear new areas for
cultivation in response to declining soil fertility or inadequate rainfall. It is
likely that both pastoral and agricultural groups were responsible for clear-
ing woody vegetation in many areas, creating open savanna or secondary
miombo woodlands and reducing dry tropical forest cover (White, 1983).
Today some 110 tribes are recognized in Tanzania (Gulliver, 1972).
Although they can be grouped according to their linguistic and historical
traditions they show divergent patterns in livelihood systems and social
organization (Gulliver, 1972). Tribal identification has been fluid and
was often related to location; many tribal names can be translated to
mean ‘highlanders’, ‘northerners’ or ‘from the waterless country’ (Iliffe,
1979). Therefore, it was possible to change tribal affiliation by moving
and changing livelihood strategies. As a result, linguistic origin is not
always useful in delineating livelihood strategies. Although Cushitic and
Nilotic tribes were generally pastoralists and Bantu, cultivators, in fact
many tribes adapted their livelihood strategies according to the ecology
and environment in which they lived. The diversity of soils and variability
in climate that created ecological heterogeneity in semi-arid regions were
also responsible for the heterogeneity found in tribal identity and liveli-
hoods. Both Cushitic and Bantu tribes cultivated crops as well as owning
livestock and the relative importance of these strategies varied with loca-
tion and especially rainfall. Tribal identity was inextricably linked to the
local ecology.
Sociopolitical change has had a huge impact on livelihoods and ecology
in Tanzania. The influx of pastoral and agricultural groups changed the
way that people interacted with the environment and as a result the ecology
of semi-arid regions. In the past there was a close link between livelihoods
and ecological conditions. More recently, however, a process of decou-
pling of people and environment has occurred. This process began with
the spread of livestock and human diseases into East Africa in the early
1800s. The spread of rinderpest is recognized as being particularly impor-
tant in its impact on people and environment and the relationship between
A case study of semi-arid Tanzania 293
Selous Game Reserve was created in order to prevent people from moving
back into the tsetse-infested area (Matzke, 1976). The creation of the game
reserve also meant that the land was now in the control of the state rather
than outside it. Only later did the remit of the reserve change to include
conservation aims.
Even with independence the process of social control over rural commu-
nities has continued, with its resultant impact on the environment. Ujamaa
villages created by the process of villagization were originally conceived as
cooperative villages where people would work together to increase agri-
cultural production (Hyden, 1975; McHenry, 1979; Kikula, 1997). These
villages would also facilitate the delivery of social and agricultural services
to often remote and dispersed communities. However, the independent
government, along with the colonial governments who preceded it, failed
to recognize the influence of ecology on patterns of settlement. Variable
rainfall, soils, wildlife and disease all determined settlement patterns,
livelihood choices and population distributions. In particular, rainfall
distribution meant that 60 per cent of the population lived in 20 per cent
of the land area of Tanzania (Maro and Mlay, 1978). Villagization settled
agricultural groups in areas marginal for farming and so contributed to
the conflict that already existed between pastoral and agricultural ethnic
groups, as these villages were often located on or near to important water
sources. Pastoralism was perceived to be a more primitive livelihood strat-
egy and so pastoral communities were encouraged to settle into villages,
regardless of the ecological need to move livestock. Although villagization
was planned as a way to increase production it was a failure and led to
declines in food and cash crop production (Smith, 2001).
To summarize, the ecology of semi-arid regions is characterized by both
inter-annual and intra-annual variability in rainfall. Large volumes of
rain can fall over short periods, while single and multi-year droughts are
common. This variability in climate, along with variability in geology and
soils, results in spatial and temporal heterogeneity in vegetation composi-
tion, primary production and water availability. Semi-arid regions are
therefore characterized by variability. It is now more widely recognized,
however, that the ecological conditions presently found in semi-arid
regions are, at least in part, the result of long-term human activity in these
areas. At the same time, the climatic variability in semi-arid regions is a
huge challenge for people in trying to sustain their livelihoods. As a result,
in semi-arid Tanzania both pastoral and agricultural livelihoods strate-
gies are found and each has developed flexibility in order to cope with
variability. Traditional pastoral livelihoods common to the region allow
for mobility of people and livestock so that adequate forage can be found
throughout the year, in much the same way as wild ungulate populations
A case study of semi-arid Tanzania 295
Ecological paradigms
Until relatively recently the predominant paradigm for understanding
the ecology of semi-arid regions, and rangelands in particular, has been
equilibrium theory. This paradigm developed from a European and
US perspective of rangelands in temperate climates (Clements, 1916).
Equilibrium theory is based on the assumption that vegetation composi-
tion will progress towards a climax community, depending on climate and
soil conditions, through the processes of succession (Begon et al., 1990;
Behnke and Scoones, 1993). The climax community is therefore consid-
ered to be the most stable plant community that could occur. Disturbance,
either natural or anthropogenic, will result in the vegetation being ‘pushed
back’ to an earlier successional stage and once the disturbance ceases or
is removed then natural processes will lead back to the climax condition
(Briske et al., 2003). The most commonly used example of succession is
the clearing of forest for agriculture in temperate regions. Once the land
is abandoned then it is assumed that a climax forest community will
eventually return (Behnke and Scoones, 1993). These ideas were applied
to grazed rangelands in sub-Saharan Africa, as well as elsewhere, where
different grass communities were considered to represent different suc-
cessional stages with certain ecological communities representing climax
(Brown and MacLeod, 1996).
An important element of equilibrium theory as applied to grazed range-
lands is the concept of carrying capacity. If, as suggested by equilibrium
theory, secondary production is linearly related to the successional status
of vegetation then it is possible to calculate carrying capacity in terms of
wild herbivores or livestock that can be supported on the range. In equi-
librium theory the interaction between plants and animals is an important
negative feedback mechanism that regulates the ecosystem (Briske et al.,
2003). This density dependence relationship means that at ecological
carrying capacity herbivore numbers are controlled by primary produc-
tion so that the number of births equals the numbers of deaths and the
vegetation is held back from reaching the climax composition that would
occur without such disturbance from grazing. For managers of rangelands
A case study of semi-arid Tanzania 297
a particular rangeland lies. Briske et al. (2003) argue that in drier regions
where the intra-annual variation in rainfall is greatest then rangelands are
likely to exhibit non-equilibrium dynamics, however in wetter areas where
variation in rainfall is less then equilibrium theory is more appropriate.
Following this argument in Tanzania would lead to the Somalia-Maasai
region being considered a non-equilibrium system since rainfall is highly
variable. In contrast the Zambezian region would be subject to equilibrium
dynamics since rainfall averages are higher and more consistent. However,
even in the Zambezian region rainfall is highly seasonal and intra-annual
variation is still high, although total rainfall is generally greater than in the
Somalia-Maasai region. As a result non-equilibrium dynamics cannot be
discounted as important for at least some parts of this system.
Social paradigms
The two different ecological paradigms outlined above are central in
determining which social paradigm influences policy, because each focuses
on a different cause of environmental degradation. In equilibrium theory
overstocking and overpopulation are seen as the primary causes of deg-
radation of rangelands and management regimes should seek to control
stocking rates and change land tenure so as to maintain rangelands in
an optimal condition. Equilibrium theory leads to the pastoral paradigm
being the dominant theory that frames understanding of communities.
In the pastoral paradigm pastoral communities are seen as unable to
adequately manage rangeland resources, leading to degradation (Warren,
1995). Population increases accompanied by inappropriate management
are therefore considered to be key problems that require intervention in
order to prevent over-use and protect natural resources and wildlife. In
Tanzania the predominance of the equilibrium paradigm in understand-
ing rangeland ecology has helped support the view that pastoral ways of
life are primitive and economically unproductive (Armitage, 1996). Early
successional stages in rangeland composition are given as evidence that
pastoral communities overstock the rangelands leading to degradation.
Interventions that de-stock and change land tenure are therefore seen as
necessary to prevent degradation and ultimately soil erosion and desertifi-
cation (Ellis and Swift, 1988; Warren, 1995).
In contrast, abiotic factors, particularly rainfall, are attributed the key
role in determining range condition in non-equilibrium theory. As a result,
managing stocking rates would not necessarily lead to improvements in
range condition. In addition, it is now recognized that most development
efforts based on equilibrium theory and the pastoral paradigm have ulti-
mately ended in failure (Oba et al., 2000). While it could be argued that
failures have been due to resistance of pastoral communities to accept
A case study of semi-arid Tanzania 299
Policy discourses
The choice between the ecological and social paradigms outlined above,
together with the long-term sociopolitical changes that have characterized
Tanzania’s history over the last few hundred years, have been central in
defining contemporary policy discourses. Colonial rule in Tanzania has
had a profound effect on the subsequent management of resources in
these areas and the way in which local communities are perceived. When
the British and other European nations began to colonize large parts of
East Africa in the late 1800s the received wisdom was that Africa was one
of the last great wildernesses untouched by humankind (Anderson and
Grove, 1987; Leach and Mearns, 1996; Neumann, 1996). National Parks
were created by the British colonial administration in part to protect this
wilderness, but they were also created to preserve the aristocratic lifestyle
that was diminishing in the United Kingdom as the result of social and
political changes in land ownership (Neumann, 1995, 1996). In reality, the
first National Parks were less to do with conserving wildlife as it is under-
stood today and more about protecting hunting rights and a particular
way of life, and exercising social control through exclusion and settlement
of indigenous communities (Anderson and Grove, 1987; Neumann, 1995).
These early ideas of separating people and nature became entrenched in
the colonial administration and the independent administrations that fol-
lowed. This ‘people versus environment’ discourse in policy is inextricably
linked with conservation thinking, equilibrium theory and the pastoral
paradigm. Today wildlife is perceived as a common heritage that should be
conserved for its own sake and for the sake of future generations (Lovett
et al., 2001). Maintaining biodiversity through the exclusion of livestock,
which under the equilibrium paradigm is believed to out-compete native
ungulates for forage, is seen as a necessary part of conservation strategy.
Local communities are perceived to be at odds with sustainable man-
agement of resources and top-down interventions are advocated. This
300 A handbook of environmental management
There were women wasted to skeletons from whose eyes the madness of star-
vation glared. . .‘warriors’ scarcely able to crawl on all fours, and apathetic,
languishing elders. These people ate anything. Dead donkeys were a feast for
them, but they did not disdain bones, hides, and even the horns of the cattle.
(Iliffe, 1979, p. 124)
Note
1. Maji is Kiswahili for water. During the conflict water was distributed that was believed
to protect the drinkers from German weapons. Unfortunately, the water did not work
and many lost their lives as a result.
References
Anand, P. (2003), ‘Economic analysis and environmental responses’, in A. Blowers and
S. Hinchliffe (eds), Environmental Responses, Milton Keynes: Open University and
Chichester: John Wiley and Sons Ltd.
Anderson, D. and R. Grove (1987), ‘The scramble for Eden: Past, present and future in
African conservation’, in D. Anderson and R. Grove (eds), Conservation in Africa: People,
Policies and Practice, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–12.
Armitage, D.R. (1996), ‘Environmental management and policy in a dryland ecozone: The
Eyasi-Yaeda basin, Tanzania’, Ambio, 25(6), 396–402.
A case study of semi-arid Tanzania 305
Begon, M., J.L. Harper and C.R. Townsend (1990), Ecology: Individuals, Populations and
Communities, 2nd edition, Oxford, UK: Blackwell Science.
Behnke, R. and N. Abel (1996), ‘Revisited: The overstocking controversy in semi-arid
Africa’, World Animal Review, 87(2), 4–27.
Behnke, R.H. and I. Scoones (1993), ‘Rethinking range ecology: Implications for rangeland
management in Africa’, in R.H. Behnke, I. Scoones and C. Kerven (eds), Range Ecology
at Disequilibrium: New Models of Natural Variability and Pastoral Adaptation in African
Savannas, London: Overseas Development Institute, pp. 1–30.
Bourn, D. and R. Blench (eds) (1999), Can Livestock and Wildlife Co-exist? An
Interdisciplinary Approach, London: Overseas Development Institute.
Briske, D.D., S.D. Fuhlendorf and F.E. Smeins (2003), ‘Vegetation dynamics on rangelands:
a critique of the current paradigms’, Journal of Applied Ecology, 40(4), 601–14.
Brooke, C. (1967), ‘The heritage of famine in Central Tanzania’, Tanzania Notes and
Records, No. 67, 51–9.
Brown, J.R. and N.D. MacLeod (1996), ‘Integrating ecology into natural resource manage-
ment policy’, Environmental Management, 20(3), 289–96.
Campbell, B.M., A. Mandondo, N. Nemarundwe, B. Sithole, W. De Jong, M. Luckert and
F. Matose (2001), ‘Challenges to proponents of Common Property Resource systems:
Despairing voices from the social forests of Zimbabwe’, World Development, 29(4),
589–600.
Carter, N. (2001), The Politics of the Environment: Ideas, Activism, Policy, New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Clements, F.E. (1916), Plant Succession: An Analysis of the Development of Vegetation,
Washington, DC: Carnegie Institute Publishers.
Coulson, A.C. (1976), ‘Crop priorities for the lowlands of Tanga region’, Tanzania Notes and
Records, Nos. 81–82, 43–53.
Ellis, J.E. and D.M. Swift (1988), ‘Stability of African pastoral ecosystems – alternate para-
digms and implications for development’, Journal of Range Management, 41(6), 450–59.
Giblin, J. and G. Maddox (1996), ‘Introduction’, in G. Maddox, J. Giblin and I.N.
Kimambo (eds), Custodians of the Land: Ecology and Culture in the History of Tanzania,
London: James Currey.
Griffiths, C. J. (1993), ‘The geological evolution of East Africa’, in J.C. Lovett and S.K.
Wasser (eds), Biogeography and Ecology of the Rainforests of Eastern Africa, Cambridge,
UK: Cambridge University Press.
Griffiths, J.F. (1972), ‘Climate’, in W.T.W. Morgan (ed.), East Africa: Its Peoples and
Resources, Nairobi: Oxford University Press, pp. 107–18.
Gulliver, P.H. (1972), ‘Peoples’, in W.T.W. Morgan (ed.), East Africa: Its Peoples and
Resources, Nairobi: Oxford University Press, pp. 35–40.
Hamersley, A. (1972), ‘Agriculture and land tenure in Tanzania’, in W.T.W. Morgan (ed.),
East Africa: Its Peoples and Resources, Nairobi: Oxford University Press, pp. 189–98.
Hamilton, A.C. (1982), Environmental History of East Africa: A Study of the Quaternary,
London: Academic Press.
Hamilton, A.C. (1989), ‘The climate of the East Usambaras’, in A.C. Hamilton and
R. Bensted-Smith (eds), Forest Conservation in the East Usambara Mountains, Tanzania,
Cambridge, UK: IUCN, pp. 97–102.
HilleRisLambers, R., M. Rietkerk, F. van den Bosch, H.H.T. Prins and H. de Kroon (2001),
‘Vegetation pattern formation in semi-arid grazing systems’, Ecology, 82(11), 50–61.
Homewood, K. (1995), ‘Development, demarcation and ecological outcomes in
Maasailand’, Africa, 65(3), 331–50.
Homewood, K. and W.A. Rodgers (1987), ‘Pastoralism, conservation and the overgrazing
controversy’, in D. Anderson and R. Grove (eds), Conservation in Africa: People, Policies
and Practice, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 111–28.
Homewood, K. and W.A. Rodgers (1991), Maasailand Ecology: Pastoral Development and
Wildlife Conservation in Ngorongoro, Tanzania, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press.
306 A handbook of environmental management
Shorter, A. (1974), East African Societies, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Smith, C.D. (2001), Ecology, Civil Society and the Informal Economy in North West Tanzania,
Aldershot: Ashgate.
Snyman, H.A. and H.J. Fouche (1993), ‘Estimating seasonal herbage production of a semi-
arid grassland based on veld condition, rainfall and evapotranspiration’, African Journal
of Range & Forage Science, 10(1), 21–4.
Stanhill, G. and S. Cohen (2001), ‘Global dimming: A review of the evidence for a wide-
spread and significant reduction in global radiation with discussion of its probable causes
and possible agricultural consequences’, Agricultural and Forest Meteorology, 107(4),
255–78.
Stocking, M. (1996), ‘Soil erosion: Breaking new ground’, in M. Leach and R. Mearns (eds),
The Lie of the Land: Challenging Received Wisdom on the African Environment, Oxford,
UK: The International African Institute in association with James Currey, pp. 140–54.
Stott, P. and S. Sullivan (2000), ‘Introduction’, in P. Stott and S. Sullivan (eds), Political
Ecology: Science, Myth and Power, London: Arnold, pp. 1–15.
Sullivan, S. and R. Rohde (2002), ‘On non-equilibrium in arid and semi-arid grazing
systems’, Journal of Biogeography, 29(2), 1595–1618.
Trapnell, C.G. and I. Langdale-Brown (1972), ‘Natural vegetation’, in W.T.W. Morgan (ed.),
East Africa: Its Peoples and Resources, Nairobi: Oxford University Press, pp. 127–40.
Van Keulen, H. and N.G. Seligman (1992), ‘Moisture, nutrient availability and plant pro-
duction in the semi-arid region’, in T. Alberda, H. Van Keulen, N.G. Seligman and C.T.
de Wit (eds), Food from Dry Lands: An Integrated Approach to Planning of Agricultural
Development, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 25–81.
Walter, A. (1939), ‘A note on the seasonal rains in East Africa and their causation’,
Tanganyika Notes and Records, No. 8, 21–6.
Warren, A. (1995), ‘Changing understandings of African pastoralism and the nature of
environmental paradigms’, Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 20(2),
193–203.
WCED (1987), Our Common Future, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Wenner, C.G. (1983), ‘Soil conservation in Tanzania: The HADO project in Dodoma
Region’, a report on a visit in April–May 1983, Dar es Salaam, SIDA.
White, F. (1983), The Vegetation of Africa: A Descriptive Memoir to Accompany the
UNESCO/AETFAT/UNSO Vegetation Map of Africa, Paris: UNESCO.
10. Exploring game theory as a tool for
mapping strategic interactions in
common pool resource scenarios
Vanessa Pérez-Cirera
Introduction
The objective of this chapter is to introduce game theory as an analytical
tool for understanding and mapping strategic interactions amongst indi-
viduals and institutions in the management of common pool resources.
The chapter on the economics of common property resources explores
the relation between poverty and property rights in natural resource
management and emphasizes the role of transaction costs in the govern-
ance structure of common property systems and how these costs shape
the outcome of these systems (Adhikari, Chapter 5, this volume). The
chapter on the economic valuation of the different forms of land-use in
Tanzania emphasizes the importance of identifying and incorporating
non-marketed/non-priced values of environmental goods and services and
how such valuations can be undertaken so that optimal levels of land-use
are identified (Kirby, Chapter 11, this volume). A question that remains
open is if and how these optimal solutions can be reached. This section
intends to contribute towards this broad question by introducing game
theory as a useful analytical tool that helps us understand how decision-
making processes are made in the management of common pool resources.
The review explains how strategic decision-making can be mapped in
a game-theoretic fashion so that variables that are key for arriving at
socially optimal solutions can be identified.
The first section of the chapter gives an introduction to game theory as
a method for the construction of game-theoretic models, introducing the
reader to game-theoretic language and representation forms. The second
section will review the most frequently used games for depicting problems
encountered in CPR settings and illustrate the use of game theory in
analysing binding agreements as institutional solutions to CPR dilemmas.
The last section will aim to illustrate how game theory can be applied
to understanding decision-making processes and assessing the desir-
ability and viability of policy options with illustrations from semi-arid
Tanzania.
309
310 A handbook of environmental management
Rain ()
X1
Settle
Pastoralist.1
Rain ()
X3
Migrate
a continuum ranging from no rain at all to a lot of rain, but to keep this
game simple, consider these two extremes. The two nodes for nature (N.1
and N.2) are chance decision nodes as there is uncertainty on what nature
will do. In chance decision nodes, all branches deriving from them have a
probability distribution equal to 1 (for example, b 1 1 − b 5 1). The agro-
pastoralist can have some information on these probabilities, such as what
the rainfall was last year, however, there is still uncertainty on what in fact
will happen.
The letters or numbers, in this case X’s at the terminal nodes, repre-
sent the payoffs2 of each decision path. These payoffs will depend on the
utility functions of the players in the game. In this case only the actions
of nature will have an effect on the payoffs for the agro-pastoralist and
not vice versa. Therefore, only one payoff is sketched. In the case that
two or more players have a payoff contingent on the final scenario,
these payoffs will be written at the end of the terminal nodes separated
by a comma, the first letter or number being the payoff for player 1, the
second letter or number the payoff for player 2 and so forth. In the game
considered here, if the agro-pastoralist settles and it rains, she or he will
receive X1, if he or she settles and there is drought, she will receive X2
and so on.
In order to find a solution for this game, we have to compute the
expected payoffs at each node, starting from the right and moving to the
left. This commonly used method is called solving by backward induction.
In this game we thus have to compute the expected payoffs at N.1 and
N.2, that is, the expected payoffs from settling and moving respectively.
To compute the expected payoffs of a decision under uncertainty, one has
to multiply the payoff by the probability of each payoff and add them.3
For example, the expected payoff from settling in this game would be:
Ep(S) 5 b(X1) 1 (1 − b)(X2). The same would have to be done for the
other available strategies for player 1. These two payoffs would have to
be computed and compared in order to derive a preferred strategy.4 To
identify the preferred strategy, an arrow in the branch that represents the
preferred strategy can be drawn. To make this clearer, numerical payoffs
to this example are given below.
Consider the hypothetical payoffs for the agro-pastoralist from each
of her or his available strategies as those depicted in Figure 10.2. These
payoffs would have to include all benefits and costs (for example, mon-
etary costs from moving, opportunity costs, and so on) derived from each
of her or his strategies given the actions of nature. That is, the payoffs
reflect the net benefits of all contingent scenarios.
Given the payoffs from Figure 10.2, the expected payoff for the
agro-pastoralist from settling would be:
Exploring game theory 313
Rain (0.5)
6
Settle
Pastoralist.1
Rain (0.5)
2
Migrate
Given these payoffs and probabilities, the best strategy for the agro-
pastoralist would be to settle since the expected payoff from settling will be
higher than the expected payoff from moving (Ep(S) . Ep(M)). An arrow
on the ‘settle’ branch denotes this.
Now, let us consider another approach to this game. What if the agro-
pastoralist is not sure about the probabilities of drought or rain? How
much would the expected probability have to fall or rise in order for
the chosen strategy to still be preferred? To find a solution, we need to
compute the same expected payoffs and solve for b:
Ep(S) 5 6b 2 3(1 2 b) 5 9b 2 3
9b 2 3 . 3b 2 1
314 A handbook of environmental management
Solving for the past inequality, b would have to be higher than 2/6 for set-
tling to be the preferred strategy for the agro-pastoralist. This means that
for all probabilities of rain higher than 0.33 it will always be best for the
agro-pastoralist to settle.
Clearly this is a simplified view of the available decisions to the agro-
pastoralist and of the variables that will shape his or her payoffs. However,
once familiar with the way games can be constructed and solved, and the
interactions amongst several players, games illustrating real-life situations
can be constructed. The next section will introduce the other, usually more
often used, form of game in non-cooperative game theory, the ‘normal’ or
strategic form game.
Past.2
Settle Migrate
0.75 1.5
Settle *
0.75 0.5
Past.1
0.5 –1
Migrate
1.5 –1
box within the matrix, the payoff to the left top corner of the box being
the payoff for player 1 (agro-pastoralist 1) and the one located at the right
bottom of the box, being the payoff for player 2 (agro-pastoralist 2). One
of the players plays the columns and the other player plays the rows. The
names of the players and available strategies are written at the top of the
columns and at the side of the rows, respectively.
Drawing on the example presented in the past section, suppose that the
payoffs for the agro-pastoralists are not only dependent on what she or
he thinks nature will do, but on what other agro-pastoralists do. Suppose
then that the payoffs from settling for the agro-pastoralist will be shaped
by what other agro-pastoralists do and vice versa. For example, if land
is scarce then if both agro-pastoralists settle in the same area the benefits
for each agro-pastoralist will be reduced. If both agro-pastoralists decide
to settle in the area (settle, settle), the payoff for each agro-pastoralist will
no longer be 1.5 as derived in the past example. If both agro-pastoralists
decide to stay, each will only receive 0.75. If only one of them decides to
migrate, the one who settles will receive 1.5 while the one who migrates will
receive 0.5. If, on the other hand both players decide to migrate, each of
them will receive –1. That is, both players would carry the costs and risks
of migrating and the fact that both will graze in the same area imposes a
burden on one another.
In order to derive the contingent or best response strategies for each
player given the payoffs for the game and what the other player does, let
us start with player 1. What would the best response for agro-pastoralist
1 be if she or he thinks agro-pastoralist 2 will settle (left column)? Given
that strategy by player 2, the best response strategy for player 1 is to settle
since 0.75 . 0.5 (the two payoffs at the left top corner of the two boxes in
the left column). If, on the other hand, agro-pastoralist 2 migrates (right
column), the best response for agro-pastoralist 1 would be to settle since
1.5 . −1. These best response strategies are illustrated by arrows at the
sides of the matrix. The vertical arrows illustrate agro-pastoralist 1’s best
response strategies for this game. In this game, player 1 (agro-pastoralist
1) has a dominant strategy. A dominant strategy is a strategy that given
the rules and payoffs of the game, in any specific node, is preferred by a
player no matter what the other player does.
The procedure followed with player 1 now needs to be done with player
2. What would the preferred strategy for player 2 be, given the actions
of the other player? If player 1 decides to settle (top row), player 2’s best
response strategy would be to settle given that 0.75 . 0.5 (bottom right
payoffs from boxes in the top row). If, on the other hand, player 1 decides
to migrate (bottom row), the best response strategy for player 2 will still
be to settle, since 1.5 . −1 (bottom right payoffs from boxes in the bottom
316 A handbook of environmental management
row). Thus, the dominant strategy for player 2 will also be to settle. The
horizontal arrows represent the best response strategies for player 2.
When a game has at least one of a player’s arrows pointing to a box and
at least an arrow of the other player pointing to the same box, then the
pair of strategies is said to be in a Nash equilibrium.5 A Nash equilibrium
is thus defined as any pair of strategies with the property that each player
maximizes her or his payoff given the actions of the other player. In this
case, the Nash equilibrium for this game is settle/settle.
There are additional names for specific strategies and equilibria. A pure
strategy is one that does not involve chance (probabilities). And a pure
Nash equilibrium is the equilibrium reached when each player plays a pure
strategy. In the game illustrated in Figure 10.3, there is only one Nash
equilibrium (S,S) and this is a pure Nash equilibrium, since it does not
involve probabilities. Another type of strategy, not present in this game, is
mixed strategies. A mixed strategy requires a player to randomize her or
his pure strategies in order to keep the opponent guessing. Consequently,
a mixed equilibrium is the equilibrium reached when each of the players is
playing a mixed strategy.
Two further equilibrium notations are used for specific purposes in
game theory. Symmetric equilibrium, in which every player chooses the
same strategy and an asymmetric equilibrium in which at least two players
choose different strategies. When there is only one equilibrium in the
game, this is called the unique Nash equilibrium and when there is more
than one equilibrium, it is said that the game has multiple Nash equilibria.
In the game presented in Figure 10.3, there is a unique pure symmetric
Nash equilibrium. This equilibrium is represented with a star in the middle
(note the star in the middle of the box settle/settle), though there are many
other identifiable forms for illustrating where the Nash equilibria are.
Having presented a brief review of game-theoretic language and repre-
sentation forms, next section will review the game-theoretic approach to
CPRs.
from the resource and (2) the subtractability of the benefits consumed by
one individual from those available to others (Ostrom et al., 1994). These
characteristics have been considered to generate two broad problems: that
of appropriation and that of provision. The first relates to extracting more
than the socially optimal level.7 The difficulty of excluding others from the
use of a CPR creates the problem of effectively limiting use (Ostrom et al.,
1994). In the case of renewable natural resources, such as a common prop-
erty forest land, for example, the concern is that the flow extracted will not
exceed its regeneration rate. The second problem refers to the difficulty of
investing for the ‘adequate’ provision of the CPR or in activities related to
its improvement or maintenance. Both these problems can be considered to
generate negative consequences for other appropriators/users.
Player 2
C D
a c
C
a c
Player 1
c d
D *
b d
Figure 10.4 Adaptation of the prisoner’s dilemma game (c > a, d > c and
a > d)
Player 2
C D
a c
C *
a c
Player 1
c d
D *
b d
Figure 10.5 Adaptation of the assurance game (a > c, c > d and d > b)
is, both players would be willing to cooperate if, and only if, the other
player cooperates. As can be seen in Figure 10.5, this game has multiple
equilibria.
Lastly, the chicken game has been used to illustrate assignment prob-
lems when there are different resource locations with different richness.
Consider, for example, two fishing grounds with different distances to a
protected area. This game has multiple equilibria, as does the assurance
game. If one of the locations is much better than another, both players
will want to use the same location (D,D) and this might not be optimal
Exploring game theory 319
Player 2
C D
a c
C *
a c
Player 1
c d
D *
b d
Figure 10.6 Adaptation of the chicken game (c > a, c > d and b > d)
for the group as a whole. If both locations are equally good (Figure 10.6),
players will be indifferent and will play a mixed strategy leading either to
one (C,D) or the other equilibrium (D,C).
Due to the attributes of CPRs, individuals jointly using CPRs are many
times stuck in a dilemma. Without previous communication and the lack
of institutions (norms and conventions), agents pursuing their own inter-
ests will engage in non-rational collective outcomes that result in resource
degradation. Institutional choice theorists have focused on identifying
viable institutional alternatives by which appropriators of the CPR can
choose (1) how much, when, where and with what technology to withdraw
units and (2) how much, when and where to invest in the maintenance
of the CPR (Ostrom et al., 1994). The next section outlines the game-
theoretic logic for such viable institutional solutions.
C 10,10
C
D –1,11
1 2 C 11,–1
D
D 0,0
Now, consider that this game is not finite. That is, there is not only one
round to the game, but that the game is played over and over again. This
leads to the alternative game set by Ostrom (1990) following the structure
of the prisoner’s dilemma game but adding two branches for each player
at the beginning of the game. These branches are termed: agree (A) or do
not agree (~A). That is, players can get together and arrange a contract in
order to arrive at a joint payoff (Figure 10.8).
In this game, the issues are: (1) whether the contracts can be binding,
that is, there is unfailing enforcement and (2) whether the payoffs are such
that the transaction costs of enforcing the contract are lower than the
expected gains from the contract. A binding contract is interpreted in non-
cooperative game theory as one that is unfailingly enforced by an external
actor. The cost of enforcing the agreement is denoted in Figure 10.8 by e.
Given the payoffs and structure of the game, the dominant equilibrium
is having both parties agreeing to cooperate. The equilibrium is shown
in the rectangle at the bottom of the tree. If these strategies are followed,
players will receive the joint benefit from cooperation minus the shared
enforcement costs (10 – e/20, 10 − e/20). Note that this equilibrium will
hold only if joint enforcement costs (e) are lower than 20.
Encouraged by this and other parallel work, over the past few decades
theorists have explored the relationships between rules, institutions,
property rights and resource user characteristics for arriving at coopera-
tive outcomes that can enhance collective benefits. The next section will
illustrate the use of game theory for identifying key variables and levels of
Exploring game theory 321
D 0,0
D
~A C
11,–1
D
C –1,–11
~A
C
10,10
D
0,0
D
* e < 20 C
A 11,–1
D
C –1,11
C
10,10
1 2 1 2 D
0,0
D
~A C
11,–1
D
C –1,11
C
A 10,10
A
10 – e/2, 10 – e/2
variables that can enhance cooperation and for assessing the viability and
desirability of policy options using examples from common pool resource
management in semi-arid Tanzania.
Player 2
I ~I
10 –1
I
10 11
Player 1
11 0
~I *
–1 0
degradation and soil erosion affecting the already low living standards of
people living in those areas.
Consider an area with a high degree of land erosion. Erosion can depend
on natural factors such as rainfall patterns, wind and topography but can
also result from human activities such as deforestation, clearing for cul-
tivation, overgrazing, extensive fuel wood cutting, and so on. Erosion in
turn affects the productivity of the natural resource base. The negative
impacts of erosion can be ameliorated by investments in the common
property land such as afforestation, the construction of diversion ditches,
ridge banking, de-stocking, and so on. The implementation of these activi-
ties would provide joint benefits for all users; however, problems of provi-
sion can arise with free-riders benefiting from the resource without having
contributed efforts towards these activities.
Recall that provision problems in CPRs can be modelled, depending on
provision technology, with the prisoner’s dilemma or with the assurance
game, the former having no one contributing to resource provision and the
latter having players contributing if, and only if, the others are to contrib-
ute. These two games are illustrated in Figures 10.9 and 10.10.
The individual profits from realizing the investments are the individual
benefits derived from the investment, minus the costs incurred in the
investment, including the opportunity costs of time devoted to the activity.
Realization of these investments will depend on having the flow of money
or resources required for realizing the investment, but will also depend on
what an individual thinks other members of the village will do.
Consider the payoffs and strategies of Figure 10.9. Two different
Exploring game theory 323
Player 2
I ~I
10 –2
I *
10 9
Player 1
9 0
~I *
–2 0
D (␣)
–F
t
Ch.1
B
~D (1 – ␣)
M.1
~t
outside the reserve. If, on the other hand, the member is detected (D)
she or he will carry the cost of the fine (−F) with probability a. If the
member does not trespass she or he will remain under status quo (SQ)
conditions.
Let us derive the expected probabilities for the unique decision node for
the members of the reserve adjacent community:
Ep(t) 5 a (−F) 1 (1 − a) B 5 −a F 1 B − aB 5 −a (F 1 B) 1 B
Ep(~t) 5 0
(1) a . B / (F 1 B) or
(2) F . B (1 − a) / a or
(3) B , aF / (1 − a)
From the previous set of equations, there are four ways of making not
trespassing to be a preferred strategy. These are either to:
The use of game theory is not a substitute for assessing side-effects from
each of the available strategies. These can be built up in other rounds of
the game or subsequent games. Possible side-effects from each of these
policy options are, for example, increasing the probability of getting
caught would mean having to invest more resources in monitoring activi-
ties, increasing the level of the fine might foster corruption and so on. The
usefulness of this example rests in illustrating a situation to identify the
key variables shaping a decision and their levels.
Let us now consider that complete exclusion is not the only scenario
into which reserve adjacent communities can be put. The state, or the
managers of the reserve, could have a continuum of possibilities ranging
from uncontrolled access to total exclusion (Figure 10.12).
Merging Figure 10.11 and 10.12, we could construct a game with
two players: the state (or managers of the reserve) and reserve-adjacent
326 A handbook of environmental management
Uncontrolled
access
R.1
Total
exclusion
UA
–L, B
t –m +f, –f
D (␣)
RA ~D (1 – ␣)
R.1 –m –L, B
~t
M.1 –m –l, b
t –M –L +F, –F
D (␣)
~A ~D (1 – ␣)
–M –L, B
M.2 ~t
–M, 0
communities (Figure 10.13). R.1 is the first and only decision node for the
reserve managers (or the state) in this game and M.1 and M.2 are two dif-
ferent nodes for the members of the resource-adjacent communities. For
simplicity consider the three available strategies for the managers of the
reserve to be (1) uncontrolled access denoted by UA, (2) regulated access
denoted by RA and, (3) total exclusion denoted by ~A (no access). For
the adjacent communities, consider the same available strategies at each
decision node as those in Figure 10.11.
If the state decides to impose a policy of unregulated access, the reserve
will bear a cost from the loss of resources (−L) and the adjacent com-
munities will receive a benefit (B) from unregulated access to additional
resources within the reserve.11 If the state decides to regulate access,
allowing uses that do not threaten the ecological stability of the reserve,
Exploring game theory 327
the adjacent communities have two options, to trespass and carry out
activities that are not allowed (t) or not to trespass (~t). If they trespass (t),
and are detected (D), the reserve will bear the costs of monitoring illegal
activities (−m) and will receive the level of the fine (f), whilst the adjacent
communities will bear the cost of the fine (−f). If community members
are not detected (~D), the reserve will bear the costs of monitoring (−m)
anyway and the total losses from activities (L). In this case, the members
of the adjacent communities will receive the benefits from the additional
resources (B). If the communities do not trespass (~t), the reserve will bear
the cost of monitoring (−m) plus a smaller loss (−l) due to allowed activi-
ties. The communities in this case will receive a smaller benefit due to the
allowed activities (b). In the third strategy, if no access is allowed (~A), the
reserve will carry the costs of monitoring for all types of activities (−M).12
The adjacent communities, if trespassing and detected, will receive the
level of the fine (−F), minus the loss from additional resources (−L). If
members are not detected (~D), the reserve will bear the no access moni-
toring costs (−M) minus the loss from resources (−L). Communities in this
case will receive the additional benefits (B). If adjacent communities do
not trespass, the reserve will bear the monitoring costs of no access (−M)
and the adjacent communities will remain under status quo conditions
(SQ).
Let us give hypothetical numerical payoffs to solve for this game.
Suppose that:
L 5 180 B 5 150 m 5 20 f 5 20 l 5 20 b 5 80
M 5 30 F 5 40 a 5 0.5
If the member were in M.2, the best she or he can do is to trespass since the
expected payoff from trespassing is higher than that of not trespassing:
Given this preferred strategy for the community member, the best the
reserve can do is to regulate access (RA) since the expected payoffs from
regulating access are higher than those of unregulated access (UA) and
higher than those of no access (~A):
328 A handbook of environmental management
UA
–180, 150
0, –20
t D (0.5)
RA ~D (0.5)
–200, 150
R.1
~t
M.1 –40, 80
–170, –40
t D (0.5)
~A ~D (0.5)
–210, 150
M.2 ~t
–30, 0
Figure 10.14 The trespassing game with two players and numerical values
Note that if the state decided to completely restrict access (~A) the best
response strategy for the community would be to trespass (t), the payoffs
for these strategies being (−190, 55), yielding a negative joint payoff of
–135.
Given the rules, available strategies and values for this game, the result
will be to regulate access and not to trespass (RA, ~t) illustrated by a
square. Note that from the way in which the payoffs were given, the result-
ing pair of strategies is also the one that yields the higher social profits, since
the joint profits of regulating access and not trespassing (RA,~t) are equal
to 40, being the highest joint profit that can be achieved in this game.
Notes
1. Current applications of game theory include biology, engineering, political science,
internal relations, computer science and philosophy.
2. In economic jargon, the payoffs represent utilities that comply with the Von Neumann–
Morgenstern axiom.
3. If there are subsequent nodes involving probabilities, starting with the payoffs at the
terminal nodes, we would move from right to left computing the conditional or inde-
pendent probabilities, following the rules for independent or conditional probabilities
respectively.
4. In some cases knowing that one outcome is preferred over another is enough to derive
a preferred strategy.
5. A pair of strategies with these properties is called a Nash equilibrium, after J. Nash
(1953) who showed that all games with a finite number of strategies have at least
Exploring game theory 329
one equilibrium, provided that mixed strategies are allowed. Mixed strategies will be
explained later.
6. This section is adaptively drawn from Ostrom et al. (1994).
7. There are some problems in determining the socially optimal point. In addition to its
praxis it will depend on which and how many involved or affected agents are introduced
to the equation. In this case, social optimality is considered the result of equating mar-
ginal social benefits to marginal social costs of appropriators, taking appropriators to
be the individuals sharing the use of the CPR (Ostrom et al., 1994).
8. The ‘prisoner’s dilemma’ was originally framed by Merrill Flood and Melvin Dresher in
1950. Albert W. Tucker formalized the game in an academic presentation in the 1950s
with prison sentence payoffs and gave it the ‘prisoner’s dilemma’ name. Imagine that
two suspects have been arrested by the police. The police have insufficient evidence for
a conviction, and, having separated both prisoners, visit each of them to offer the same
deal. If one testifies (defects from the other) for the prosecution against the other and
the other remains silent (cooperates with the other), the betrayer goes free and the silent
accomplice receives , say, the full ten-year sentence. If both remain silent, both prisoners
may be sentenced to only six months in jail for a minor charge. If each betrays the other,
they each receive a five-year sentence. Each prisoner must choose to betray the other or
to remain silent. Each one is assured that the other would not know about the betrayal
before the end of the investigation. How should the prisoners act? (For more details on
the origin and formalization of the prisoner’s dilemma see Poundstone, 1992).
9. The ‘chicken game’, also known as the hawk–dove or snowdrift game, was first formal-
ized by John Maynard Smith and George Price in 1973. The principle of the game is
that while each player prefers not to yield to the other, the outcome where neither player
yields is the worst possible one for both players. The name ‘chicken’ has its origins in
a game in which two drivers drive towards each other on a collision course: one must
swerve, or both may die in the crash, but if one driver swerves and the other does not,
the one who swerved will be called a ‘chicken’, meaning a coward.
10. The ‘assurance game’ is a generic name after Sen (1967), for the game also known as the
stag hunt game. The French philosopher Jean Jacques Rousseau, in his 1755 writings
on inequality, presented the following situation: two hunters can either jointly hunt a
stag (an adult deer and rather large meal) or individually hunt a rabbit (tasty, but sub-
stantially less filling). Hunting stags is quite challenging and requires mutual coopera-
tion. If either hunts a stag alone, the chance of success is minimal and thus there is the
need of cooperation and trust to achieve a larger joint benefit.
11. Non-priced/non-marketed values could be incorporated to the payoffs of each
alternative.
12. It could be argued that M is very similar to m, as the costs of monitoring for additional
activities, while monitoring anyway may be very small (decreasing marginal costs).
Even if this difference is small, it exists and so, for illustrative purposes, let us denote it
by using the letter M.
References
Baland, J.-M. and J.-P. Platteau (1996), Halting Degradation of Natural Resources. Is There a
Role for Rural Communities?, Rome: FAO and Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Binmore, K. (1994), Just Playing: Game Theory and the Social Contract, Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Dawes, R.M. (1973), ‘The commons dilemma game: an n-person mixed motive game with
a dominating strategy for defection’, Oregon Research Institute Research Bulletin, 13(2),
1–12.
Maynard Smith, J. and G. Price (1973), ‘The logic of animal conflict’, Nature, 246, 15–18.
Nash J. (1953), ‘Non-cooperative games’, Annals of Mathematics, 54(2), 286–95.
Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective
Action, New York: Cambridge University Press.
330 A handbook of environmental management
Ostrom, E. and R. Gardner (1993), ‘Coping with asymmetries in the commons: self-governing
irrigation systems can work’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(4), 93–112.
Ostrom E., R. Gardner and J. Walker (1994), Rules, Games and Common Pool Resources,
Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press
Poundstone, W. (1992), Prisoner’s Dilemma, John Von Neumann, Game Theory and the
Puzzle of the Bomb, New York: Anchor Books, Doubleday.
Sen, A. (1967), ‘Isolation, assurance and the social rate of discount’, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 81, 112–24.
Snidal, D. (1985), ‘The Game Theory of International Politics’, World Politics, 36(1),
25–57.
Von Neumann, J. and O. Morgenstern (1944), Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour,
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Weissing, F. and E. Ostrom (1991), ‘Irrigation institutions and the game irrigators play: rule
enforcement without guards’, in R. Shelten (ed.) Game Equilibrium Models II: Methods,
Morals and Markets, Berlin, New York: Springer.
11. Economic valuation of different forms
of land-use in semi-arid Tanzania
Deborah Kirby
Introduction
In many ecosystems there is a conflict of interest between land-users who
wish to utilize the land for different purposes. In most of these situations,
the overriding factor influencing the use of the land is its perceived economic
value. A forest or savanna region may produce many different types of goods
for human use. Although these goods have a value to humankind, many
have traditionally been excluded from estimates of valuation. This has arisen
because policy-makers have generally assumed that natural ecosystems such
as forests or savannas have no economic value other than their direct use of
producing saleable products, and thus non-monetary values from their land-
use have been excluded from any economic analysis. Thus, forested areas
have only been valued in terms of timber production or land area available
for farming (Barreto et al., 1998), and savanna areas for the volume of sale-
able livestock (for example, Bembridge and Steenkamp, 1976).
A comparison of the relative values of the different forms of land-use,
which includes all values of the resource, monetary and non-monetary,
can help identify a socially equitable use of land. This chapter considers
how valuations of different forms of land-use can be made and emphasizes
the importance of establishing linkages between ecological and economic
systems to facilitate valuation of biological goods and services in a devel-
oping country, Tanzania. In this context, the use of a particular tool in
economic analysis, the production function, is described.
331
332 A handbook of environmental management
Ecosystem values
In the past few decades, attention has been increasingly turning towards
recognizing the fact that natural ecosystems such as forest and savanna
provide a wide range of products that are highly valuable but may not
have an immediately apparent market value (Scoones et al., 1992). It
is realized that failure in the past to include these types of ecosystem
values in analyses of land-use has led to the undervaluing of ecosystems
(Swanson and Barbier, 1991). Scientists and to a certain extent policy-
makers are therefore now recognizing that if the total economic value of
an ecosystem is to be realized, a monetary value must be assigned to the
resources in question, enabling them to be ‘counted’ in an estimation of
the ecosystem’s worth.
The lack of a market value, and thus underestimation or complete
absence of the resource’s value, may be for one of two reasons. First,
the resource may not be one that is exchanged in the marketplace. For
example, hunting and gathering of wild products for subsistence living will
directly use many natural resources but these may be consumed directly
rather than sold (Campbell et al., 1997). In the case of livestock, animals
may be used for products other than meat that do not have a market value,
such as transport or labour (Scoones, 1992). Second, the value of the
resource may be in supporting the production of other goods rather than
through its own direct utilization.
The remainder of this section describes in detail the differences between
different forms of ecosystem products. These products can be separated
into three categories, according to their type of use.
Economic valuation of land-use in semi-arid Tanzania 335
Commercial values
Extraction of timber or production of livestock from an ecosystem will
directly produce revenue for the land-users. If they are marketed, their value
will be equal to the revenue from selling the timber or livestock minus the
costs of production and transport to market (Godoy, 1992). If they are not
marketed but kept for home consumption they will also have a value although
this will be considerably harder to impute, and may not be equal to the value
that they would realize if they were sold on the open market (Godoy, 1992).
External benefits
The third category of goods and services that can be derived from ecosys-
tems are described as indirect-use resources. Many ecosystems will provide
invisible benefits to other ecosystems or people, both within the geographi-
cal area of the ecosystem, as well as outside it. In the case of both forest and
savanna ecosystems, these external benefits can be considered to exist at two
separate levels. A number of empirical studies have shown that forest ecosys-
tems provide protection for other ecosystems located downstream from the
336 A handbook of environmental management
forest. In particular, forests have been shown to provide soil protection for
downstream agricultural land (Anderson, 1987), protect downstream water
courses from increased levels of sedimentation caused by surface run-off
and increased erosion and leading to high costs of de-siltation (Panayotou,
1990; Lal, 1997), to impact on water yield and groundwater recharge, and
to control watershed hydrology and provide protection against erosion
(Rawat and Rawat, 1994; Ataroff and Rada, 2000; Putuhena and Cordery,
2000). For dry savanna ecosystems, the invisible benefits may be as signifi-
cant as those of forest ecosystems. Hydrological functions of dry savannas
have been shown to have a direct impact on the productivity of surrounding
areas. The vegetation cover of woodlands is thought to stabilize the local
climate and maintain rainfall patterns (Myers, 1995) as well as prevent soil
erosion and flooding, and control the recharging of groundwater reservoirs
(Huntoon, 1992). These positive external effects, although they may occur
outwith the boundary of the ecosystem, are nonetheless specific in their area
of impact. As such, there is a limit to the number of individuals upon which
they will have an effect.
A second type of externality, however, is also provided by forest and
savanna ecosystems, and has a greater range of impact. It is now known
that areas of vegetation cover, in particular forested areas, act as import
sinks for atmospheric carbon (Harmon, 2001; Pautsch et al., 2001; Uri,
2001). This function is globally important in terms of regulating atmos-
pheric composition and controlling global temperature. Many savanna
ecosystems also form the watershed zones of major international rivers,
for example, the Zambezi (Kundhlande et al., 2000), which are interna-
tionally important for domestic water consumption and power supply.
This type of ecosystem service differs from all others in that its use is
‘public’ in nature, that is, it is used by society as a whole, and individuals
do not have a choice over whether or not they wish to use it.
Both of these invisible benefits are termed indirect-use values, since
although not consumed directly they are essential for the production of
direct-use values. However, their very nature implies that they will have
no direct market value and thus are difficult to quantify in a cost–benefit
analysis.
From the above-cited studies it can be seen that any comparison of the
relative values of forest resources encounters serious difficulties. First,
several of the studies do not consider the full economic value of non-
timber forest products but only of a few selected species. In particular,
none of the studies includes the value of faunal products from the forest.
Second, largely differing values were derived for studies that occurred
over the same areas (for example, Peters et al., 1989; Pinedo-Vasquez et
al., 1992) bringing into question the validity of these studies. In addition,
Nations (1992) and Hecht (1992) consider only the gross value of the
resources they estimated, making comparisons with studies that estimated
net values impossible.
Fewer studies have attempted to value wildlife resources in forest or
savanna ecosystems in Africa. Those early studies that attempted to do so
concentrated mainly on animal rather than plant resources, for example,
Martin (1983), Redford and Robinson (1985) and Barbier et al. (1990).
Scoones et al. (1992) reviewed much of the literature on the use and
value of wild resources in agricultural systems. Although much literature
existed about the use of wild resources, it was shown that almost nothing
was known about the value of these products. One of the few studies to
undertake the economic assessment of wildlife resources is that of the
International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED) and
Hadejia-Nguru Wetlands Conservation Programme (HNWCP) (1997).
The principal method of data collection was Participatory Rural Analysis
(PRA), and the extensive report gives a detailed description of the
methods used to obtain the data; which products were used, how they
were harvested, the quantities taken and their value. An overall economic
value is derived for a number of the wildlife resources based on a simple
cost–benefit analysis of value equals quantity sold times price, minus costs
of production. However, no assessment of the value of crops and livestock
is made in this study.
In addition to wildlife resources, livestock resources are also of high
value to the people living in and around many savanna ecosystems. As was
discussed earlier in this report, the value of livestock has frequently only
been seen in their commercial meat production. This has frequently led to
the belief by policy-makers that traditional production systems of livestock
are backward and inefficient compared with those of commercial systems
such as cattle ranching. In recognition of this shortcoming, research was
initiated to attempt to assess the true productive value of traditional forms
of livestock production systems (for example, Cossins, 1985). Scoones
(1992) recognized that to understand the full value of livestock within
agropastoral systems required a detailed study of all of the useful outputs
from the livestock in the system. He defined productivity not simply in
Economic valuation of land-use in semi-arid Tanzania 339
terms of meat production, which had a marketed value, but also included
non-marketed products such as milk and manure. In addition, services
provided by the livestock were also valued, such as the provision of labour
and transport. Finally, Scoones also included the costs of production of
livestock in the study area, and made a comparison between the relative
benefits of different types of livestock production. This study was carried
out through a simple cost–benefit analysis, that is, the total value of any
animal was calculated as equal to the value or price of it and its products
minus the costs of production. Data on the production parameters of
livestock (for example, births, deaths, milk production, and so on) were
obtained though household surveys. A comparison of livestock productiv-
ity on different soil types was also made to assess the effect of a change in
this ecological parameter. He found that the productivity of communal
cattle was higher than that of beef cattle in the same region and that this
was at least partly due to the higher stocking rate of the communal cattle.
Campbell et al. (1997) estimated values for both plant and animal wild-
life resources in a Zimbabwean savanna. A large number of products that
were used by the local population were identified, for example, firewood,
wood for construction, fruit, birds and thatch. As with Scoones et al.
(1992), the total value of the ecosystem was calculated by multiplying the
amount of each good produced by its value. For many of these resources,
an economic value was imputed by subtracting the costs of production (for
example, labour and transport costs) from their market value. Two differ-
ent methods were used to estimate how much of a good was produced by
each area of land. For products that were regularly used by households,
such as firewood and some wild foods, the amount that could be sustain-
ably produced by the forest was taken to be the amount of the product used
(an assessment of sustainability was also made). However, for other goods,
such as wild fruits, the amount used was judged to be a proportion of the
total annual biological production. Thus, in these cases, an ecological analy-
sis was made of the productivity of each plant species each year. Although
not explicitly stated, in this latter case a simple production function was
therefore set up, where the quantity consumed by households equalled
a proportion of the quantity produced by the vegetation. Although the
analysis made by Campbell et al. was extremely precise and detailed it did
not include a valuation of the livestock and crops produced in the region.
Campbell et al. (2000b) compared the economics of four different cattle
production scenarios in communal grazing lands in Zimbabwe. In this
study, data on inputs to, and outputs from, livestock production, and data
on prices, were obtained through surveys of households. This allowed the
researchers to identify relationships between the inputs into production
of livestock (for example, feeding, herding labour, dipping) and various
340 A handbook of environmental management
of land-use have been made. With the progressive increase in data avail-
ability and a growing understanding of the requirements for making such
studies, it is anticipated that total valuation of different forms of land-use
will become progressively easier.
50
Agricultural land-use
Forested land-use
40
Marginal profit/hectare
30
20
10
0
0 20 C1 40 60 C2 80 100 C3 120
–10
Percentage area cover of forest (ha)
Figure 11.1 Showing the level of marginal profits for different types of
vegetation cover
Direct-use values
Ecosystems provide many important functions for humankind, which, as
has already been described, can be grouped according to their direct-use
or indirect-use values.2 The valuation of an ecosystem is frequently made
Economic valuation of land-use in semi-arid Tanzania 343
according to its tangible outputs (direct-use values), for example, the value
of the crop harvested, and where no indirect-use value of the ecosystem
exists, this valuation is perfectly acceptable. A production function can
then be developed to quantify the components of an ecosystem that con-
tribute towards the production of a good. In doing this, an estimate can be
made of the relative values of each of the inputs into production.
If a comparison is being made of the relative values of different forms of
ecosystem use, it is imperative that all components of the production func-
tion are included in the analysis. For example, the production of livestock
and/or game in a particular area (Q), will require inputs of labour (L) and
forage (F ). However, as was shown by Scoones (1992), the productivity of
livestock may also be dependent on factors such as the physical conditions
of the environment. Thus, in the case of Scoones’ research, livestock pro-
ductivity was also affected by soil type. If this latter factor is overlooked and
excluded from the livestock production function, the result will be an under-
valuation of the soil value (S), giving it the incorrect production function:
Q 5 f (L, F)
rather than:
Q 5 f (L, F, S) .
Indirect-use values
In agriculture and forestry, which involve the primary production of
goods, in addition to providing direct-use goods, in many cases the eco-
system may provide an ecological function that has an indirect value in
supporting the production of marketable goods. The ecological function
is then a ‘factor input’ in the production process. As already discussed, the
ecological function may have an important input for activities that are far
removed, either spatially or temporally, from the production process, and
344 A handbook of environmental management
thus the benefits derived may not be easily ascribed to it. For example,
deforestation may result in increased erosion, leading to sediment deposi-
tion on downstream farmland, potentially affecting the nutritional content
of the deforested soil and crop production on the downstream farmland.
Thus, in addition to its value for timber production, the forested land may
also have a direct influence on crop and livestock/game production in the
immediate area and crop production in a different area. Including forest
area as a determinant of livestock/game or crop production may therefore
capture some element of the economic contribution of this ecological
function. In mathematical terms this can be described as:
Q 5 f (xi. . . . .xn, A)
Worked examples
amount of labour used in herding and veterinary costs. This could, for
example, be represented as:
Where:
In this example, primary data would be required for the input and output
variables given in Equation 11.1. These data could be obtained through a
questionnaire survey of the local population answering the following type
of questions:
Ql 5 L0.5
l As
0.5
R2 5 1 (11.2)
Ql 5 4.5Ll 1 2As
Once again, it should be noted that this illustration gives an example of the
kinds of questions that should be asked in a questionnaire survey, but does
not give the form that the questions should take.
With this information, a profit function can be written:
Pl 5 PlQl 2 Cl (11.3)
Where:
Pl 5 Rl (L0.5
l As ) 2 Cl
0.5
(11.4)
The total profit from livestock production can then be identified for any
given levels of land and labour.
Thus, if Pl 5 10, Ll 5 200, As 5 20 and Cl 5 500:
Step 3: Identifying the production function for forest goods In exactly the
same manner as described for the production function of livestock, a pro-
duction function of forest products can also be identified.
The amount of a good, for example, wild fruit, produced by the forest
will be partially dependent on the area of forest. It will also be dependent on
other factors such as the amount of time spent in collecting it. The methodol-
ogy required would be the same as that for identifying the livestock produc-
tion function in that data would be obtained through a questionnaire survey
of the local population. Therefore further details are not given here. In
Equation 11.6, an example is given of a possible fruit production function:
Qf 5 2 (At 2 A0.2
s ) 1 3Lf
0.7
(11.6)
Economic valuation of land-use in semi-arid Tanzania 349
Where:
Note that the area of land is given as the total area of the study area minus
the area of land used for livestock production, that is, the area of forested
land.
Step 4: Calculating the value of the fruit production As with the livestock
profit function, a fruit profit function can be estimated through identi-
fying the price of the fruit and the costs of its production. This would
give a profit function such as that shown for livestock in Equation 11.3.
Substituting Equation 11.6 into this will then give the total profit func-
tion, as shown in Equation 11.7. An example of the fruit profit function
is given in Equation 11.8 for values of Pf 5 5, Lf 5 200, At 5 50 and Cf
5 25.
Where:
Step 5: Identifying the total value of produce from the region and the optimal
level of different vegetation covers To identify the total value of the area,
the values of all the forms of production must be summed together. In this
worked example, these values are simply the value from livestock produc-
tion and the value from wild fruit harvesting. Thus, the total value of the
region would equal the sum of Equations 11.5 and 11.8, given algebrai-
cally in Equation 11.9 and numerically in Equation 11.10.
0Pt
5 5 (20.4 (50 2 A20.8 ) 1 0.5 (10 * 2000.5A20.5 ) 50
0A s s
As 5 1.0 (11.12)
Thus, for a total study area of 50 hectares, the optimal area of agricul-
tural land is one hectare and hence the optimal area of forested land is 49
hectares.
It is obvious that for reasons of clarity and simplicity, this worked
example has been chosen with only a few variables. However, in carry-
ing out the complete research, two critical points must be noted. (1) To
identify the total value of the land, all of the products from it must be
identified and assessed. Summing the total profit from all of these prod-
ucts would then give the total value of the region. For the sake of brevity,
in this worked example only one product from each type of land-use is
given, however the method is equally applicable with numerous products
from each type of land-use. (2) Acquiring the data outlined here requires
a detailed socioeconomic knowledge of the population living within the
region. It must be noted that although the questions outlined here for
obtaining information on the production of goods give a guideline as to
the type of information required, they do not precisely illustrate the meth-
odology for obtaining that information. Much of this information may
not be directly obvious but may have to be imputed through other means.
For example, to obtain an estimation of the price of wild foods that are
not marketed will require more than a simple question. The value may be
able to be imputed, for example, by comparison with the value of other
goods that are marketed. The reader is referred to the other valuation
studies referenced in this report for more detailed descriptions of survey
techniques (for example, Scoones, 1992; Campbell et al., 1997; IIED and
HNWCP, 1997).
Economic valuation of land-use in semi-arid Tanzania 351
Q 5 Aa WbLcFdSe (11.13)
Where:
It should be noted that again this illustration gives an example of the kinds
of questions that should be asked in a questionnaire survey, but not of the
form the questions should take.
In addition to this data, the level of rainfall must be known for the study
area. To make a comparison over time, two different approaches can be
taken: either the survey can be longitudinal, that is, carried out over a
number of years, or cross-sectional, that is, carried out at the same time
but over a number of different study sites. This will then provide variation
in the data of rainfall and the other inputs into production. A simplified
example of the results of such a study is given in Table 11.2 using only
three inputs, rainfall, labour and land area, and three study areas.
To identify the quantitative relationship between these variables, a
multiple regression analysis can be carried out using the quantity of crop
produced as the dependent variable and the input data as the independent
variables. The results of the multiple regression for this example are given
in Equation 11.14.
Q 5 W0.7L0.2A0.1 R2 5 1 (11.14)
Economic valuation of land-use in semi-arid Tanzania 353
P 5 PCQ 2 C (11.15)
Where:
P 5 total profit ($);
PC 5 price of crop ($/kg);
Q 5 quantity of crop produced (kg);
C 5 costs of production of crop ($).
Substituting Equation 11.14 into Equation 11.15 gives:
354 A handbook of environmental management
P 5 RC (W 0.7L0.2A0.1) 2 C (11.16)
The change in the value of crop production for changing levels of rainfall
can be identified for any given levels of rainfall, labour, area and costs. It
is important to note that these other variables must be held constant and
can be chosen to be at any level.
Thus, if P 5 10, W 5 1000, L 5 800, A 5 50 and C 5 5000:
But reducing the rainfall level by half to W 5 500 mm per annum gives:
Thus, the value of rainfall changing from 1000 mm per annum to 500 mm
per annum would be estimated as $−2723 ($−636 − $2087).
This example does not quantify a relationship between the amount of
forest cover in a region and the changes in crop productivity but simply
quantifies the relationship between rainfall levels and crop production.
Including the valuation of the area of forest cover in the region would
require a second production defining the relationship between forest cover
and average annual rainfall. If this relationship is known, it can be simply
incorporated into the original production function. For example, if:
W 5 F 0.5 (11.17)
Where:
Substituting Equation 11.17 into Equation 11.16 will give Equation 11.18.
Exactly the same calculations can then be carried out as before but with
changing forest cover values rather than rainfall levels to provide a value of
the change in crop production for a change in forest levels in the region.
Conclusions
Any research project that aims to undertake work in evaluating different
land-use systems would be required to consider several different areas
of research. The research would require the integration of ecological,
sociological and economic skills in order to gain a full understanding of
the problem. To assess the total economic productivity of the ecosystems
of Tanzania under different forms of land-use, for example, nomadic
systems, sedentary agricultural systems, ranching and commercial hunting/
tourism, each system of land-use must be considered in turn, and an esti-
mate made of the total economic value of that system. As described in
previous sections of this report, total economic value comprises the direct-
use and indirect-use values of the ecosystem. Therefore an analysis must
incorporate an estimate of both types of value.
To assess the primary products utilized by individuals from the eco-
system, that is, the direct-use value of the system, studies will be required
to estimate the off-take from the environment of natural products, both
vegetation and animal, as well as the number of people sustained by this
system (population density). This can be achieved through, for example,
sociological studies that directly measure the quantity and type of natural
resources used. The productivity of agricultural goods can also be meas-
ured in this manner.
To estimate the value of products that are not marketed, a market value
must be assigned to them. This can be through comparison with values of
similar resources that have a market value or, alternatively, an estimate
may be made of the compensation that individuals would have to receive
in order to provide themselves with similar products to the ones pro-
vided by their ecosystem. For systems of land-use where the products are
marketed a direct estimate can be made of their economic value.
To estimate the indirect-use values of the ecosystem, an understanding
of the role of ecological support functions of an ecosystem must be gained
through, for example, ecological, geographical or hydrological studies.
With this knowledge, a production function approach, as outlined earlier,
can then be used to translate these ecological relationships into economic
values.
356 A handbook of environmental management
Notes
1. For a detailed explanation of the mathematics of profit maximization, see Dowling
(1992).
2. Non-use values have also been identified but are not considered in this case. Estimation
of their values is extremely difficult and not deemed relevant here. See Heywood (1995)
for further information.
3. The mathematics of the problem-solving are not given here but are relatively simple to
carry out.
4. Further details of how to carry out partial differentiation can be found in Dowling
(1992).
References
Anderson, A.B. and E.M. Ioris (1992), ‘The logic of extraction: resource management and
income generation by extractive producers in the Amazonian estuary’, in K.H. Redford
and C. Padoch (eds), Conservation of Neotropical Forests: Working from Traditional
Resource Use, New York: Colombia University Press, pp. 175–99.
Anderson, D. (1987), Economic Aspects of Deforestation: A Case Study in Africa, Washington,
DC: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Ataroff, V. and F. Rada (2000), ‘Deforestation impact on water dynamics in a Venezuelan
Andean cloud forest’, Ambio, 29(7), 440–44.
Barbier, E.B. (1994), ‘Valuing environmental functions: tropical wetlands’, Land Economics,
70, 155–73.
Barbier, E., J. Burgess, T. Swanson and D. Pearce (1990), Elephants, Economics and Ivory,
London: Earthscan Publications.
Barreto, P., P. Amaral, E. Vidal and C. Uhl (1998), ‘Costs and benefits of forest management
for timber production in eastern Amazonia’, Forest Ecology and Management, 108(1/2),
9–26.
Bembridge, T. and J. Steenkamp (1976), ‘An agroeconomic investigation of beef produc-
tion in the Matabeleland Midlands provinces of Rhodesia’, Rhodesian Agriculture, 73(2),
100–112.
Campbell, B.M., M. Luckert and I. Scoones (1997), ‘Local-level valuation of Savanna
resources: a case study from Zimbabwe’, Economic Botany, 51(1), 59–77.
Campbell, B.M., R. Costanza and M. van den Belt (2000a), ‘Special section: Land-use
options in dry tropical woodland ecosystems in Zimbabwe: Introduction, overview and
synthesis’, Ecological Economics, 33(3), 341–51.
Campbell, B.M., D. Dore, M. Luckert, B. Mukamuri and J. Gambiza (2000b), ‘Economic
comparisons of livestock production in communal grazing lands in Zimbabwe’, Ecological
Economics, 33(3), 413–38.
Coe, M.J., D.M. Cumming and J. Phillipson (1976), ‘Biomass and production of large
African herbivores in relation to rainfall and primary production’ [cited in Campbell et al.,
2000a], Ecology, 22(4), 341–54.
Common, M.S. (1996), Environmental and Resource Economics: An Introduction, London:
Longman.
Cossins, N. (1985), ‘The productivity and potential of pastoral systems’, ILCA Bulletin, No.
21, 10–15.
Economic valuation of land-use in semi-arid Tanzania 357
Dixon, J.A. and P.B. Sherman (1990), Economics of Protected Areas. A New Look at Benefits
and Costs, London: Earthscan Publications Ltd.
Dowling, E.T. (1992), Introduction to Mathematical Economics, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Fuentes, E. (1980), ‘Los Yanomami y las plantas silvestres’ (The Yanomami and wild plants),
Antropologica, 54(3), 3–138.
Godoy, R. (1992), ‘Some organizing principles in the valuation of tropical forests’, Forest
Ecology and Management, 50(1/2), 171–80.
Godoy, R., R. Lubowski and A. Markandya (1993), ‘A method for the economic valuation
of non-timber tropical forest products’, Economic Botany, 47(3), 220–33.
Hanemann, W. (1988), ‘Economics and the preservation of biodiversity’, in E.O. Wilson and
F.M. Peters (eds), Biodiversity, Washington, DC: National Academy Press, pp. 193–9.
Harmon, M.E. (2001), ‘Carbon sequestration in forests – addressing the scale question’,
Journal of Forestry, 99(4), 24–9.
Hecht, S. (1992), ‘Valuing land-use in Amazonia: colonist agriculture, cattle and petty extrac-
tion in comparative perspective’, in K.H. Redford and C. Padoch (eds), Conservation
of Neotropical Forests: Working from Traditional Resource Use, New York: Colombia
University Press, pp. 379–99.
Heywood, V.H. (1995), Global Biodiversity Assessment, New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Hill, C., W. Griffiths and G. Judge (1997), Undergraduate Econometrics, New York: John
Wiley and Sons.
Huntoon, P.W. (1992), ‘Hydrogeologic characteristics and deforestation of the stone forest
karst aquifers of South China’, Ground Water, 30(2), 167–76.
IIED and HNWCP (1997), ‘Local-level assessment of the economic importance of wild
resources in the Hadejia-Nguru wetlands, Nigeria’, Sustainable Agricultural Programme
Research Series, 3(3).
Kirby, D.K. (2000), ‘An ecological economic approach to upland heather moorland manage-
ment’, DPhil thesis, York: University of York.
Kundhlande, G., W.L. Adamowicz and I. Mapaure (2000), ‘Valuing ecological services
in a savanna ecosystem: a case study from Zimbabwe’, Ecological Economics, 33(3),
401–12.
Lal, R. (1997), ‘Deforestation effects on soil degradation and rehabilitation in western
Nigeria. IV. Hydrology and water quality’, Land Degradation and Development, 8(2),
95–126.
Martin, G. (1983), ‘Bushmeat in Nigeria as a natural resource with environmental implica-
tions’, Environmental Conservation, 10(2), 125–32.
Myers, N. (1995), ‘The world’s forests – need for a policy appraisal’, Science, 268(5212),
823–4.
Nations, J.D. (1992), ‘Xateros, chicleros and pimenteros: harvesting renewable tropical forest
resources in the Guatemalan Petén’, in K.H. Redford and C. Padoch (eds), Conservation
of Neotropical Forests: Working from Traditional Resource Use, New York: Colombia
University Press, pp. 208–19.
Niamir-Fuller, M. (1998), ‘The resilience of pastoral herding in Sahelian Africa’, in F. Berkes,
C. Folke and J. Colding (eds), Linking Social and Ecological Systems, Cambridge, UK and
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Nicholson, W. (1992), Microeconomic Theory, Orlando: Dryden Press.
Oommachan, M. and S.K. Masih (1988), ‘Multifarious uses of plants by the forest tribals of
Madhya Pradesh: wild edible plants’, Journal of Tropical Forestry, 4(2), 163–9.
Panayotou, T. (1990), ‘The economics of environmental degradation. Problems, causes
and responses’, Development and Discussion Paper No. 335, Harvard Institute for
International Development, Cambridge, MA.
Pautsch, G.R., L.A. Kurkalova, B.A. Babcock and C.L. Kling (2001), ‘The efficiency of
sequestering carbon in agricultural soils’, Contemporary Economic Policy, 19(2), 123–34.
Peters, C.M., A.H. Gentry and R.O. Mendelsohn (1989), ‘Valuation of an Amazonian
rainforest’, Nature, 339(6227), 655–6.
358 A handbook of environmental management
Phillips, O., A.H. Gentry, C. Reynel, P. Wilkin and C. Galvezdurand (1994), ‘Quantitative
ethnobotany and Amazonian conservation’, Conservation Biology, 8(1), 225–48.
Pinedo-Vasquez, M., D. Zarin and P. Jipp (1992), ‘Economic returns from forest conversion
in the Peruvian Amazon’, Ecological Economics, 6(2), 163–73.
Putuhena, W.M. and I. Cordery (2000), ‘Some hydrological effects of changing forest cover
from eucalypts to Pinus radiata’, Agricultural and Forest Meteorology, 100(1), 59–72.
Rawat, J.S. and M.S. Rawat (1994), ‘Accelerated erosion and denudation in the Nana-
Kosi watershed, Central Himalaya, India. 1. Sediment load’, Mountain Research and
Development, 14(1), 25–38.
Redford, K.H. and J. Robinson (1985), ‘Hunting by indigenous peoples and conservation of
their game species’, Cultural Survival, 8(4), 41–4.
Scoones, I. (1992), ‘The economic value of livestock in the communal areas of southern
Zimbabwe’, Agricultural Systems, 39(4), 339–59.
Scoones, I., M. Melnyk and J.N. Pretty (1992), The Hidden Harvest: Wild Foods and
Agricultural Systems, Sustainable Agricultural Programme, London: International
Institute for Environment and Development.
Swanson, T. and E. Barbier (1991), Economics for the Wilds. Wildlife, Wildlands, Diversity
and Development, London, Earthscan Publications Ltd.
Toledo, V.M., A.I. Batis, R. Becerra, E. Martinez and C.H. Ramos (1995), ‘The useful forest
– quantitative ethnobotany of the indigenous groups of the humid tropics of Mexico’,
Interciencia, 20(4), 177–87.
Uri, N.D. (2001), ‘The potential impact of conservation practices in US agriculture on global
climate change’, Journal of Sustainable Agriculture, 18(1), 109–31.
Wilson, E.O. (1994), The Diversity of Life, London: Penguin.
12. Economic growth and the environment
Dalia El-Demellawy
Introduction
This chapter critically reviews empirical literature on the relationship
between economic growth and the environment. It starts with outlining
the debate around the relationship and then presents basic models used in
the empirical studies. Finally, the various empirical studies are discussed.
Study of the relationship between economic growth and the environ-
ment goes back to the 1960s. It started in developed countries when
considerable concern arose regarding the impact that economic develop-
ment was having on their environment. This growing concern led to the
1972 United Nations World Conference on the Human Environment in
Stockholm. This conference highlighted the conflict of interest between
developed and developing countries regarding the relationship between
economic growth and the environment. The developing countries were
more concerned with development at the expense of the environment.
In other words, slowing economic development to protect the environ-
ment was not appreciated. Even in developed countries there was con-
flict of interest among different groups in society, with workers ranking
improvements of their standard of living associated with technological
advancements above environmental concerns (Beckerman, 1992). Despite
conflict of interest, concerns about the natural environment and its link to
problems of economic development were explicitly stated. It was argued
that exhaustion of the environmental resource base, in terms of minerals
and food production, would provide limits for future economic growth.
However, it was not thought that economic collapse was inevitable. On
the contrary, it was concluded that the world economic system could be
sustainable into the future provided that radical changes in the way it was
being run were adopted (Meadows et al., 1972).
Awareness of the relationship between the environment and economic
growth gained prominence in 1987 for a number of reasons. First, the
widespread environmental and economic problems in the world; particu-
larly high levels of poverty and famines in various countries. Second, the
urgent and complex problem of the national and global scale of environ-
mental pollution; especially that associated with climate change due to
increasing emissions of greenhouse gases (GHGs) causing global warming.
This, in turn, was considered to lead to serious unfavourable effects on (1)
359
360 A handbook of environmental management
but to the rich ones as well. Also, some of the problems facing the world,
such as global warming and ozone depletion, stem from high consumption
in the richer countries. Moreover, the international community allows
and facilitates the access to cleaner technologies and lessons learned from
developed countries by less-developed ones (IBRD, 1992).
Third, the nature of environmental protection, being a public good,
makes it difficult to control due to transboundary and free-rider effects. A
public good is defined as ‘non-rival and non-excludable in use’ (Common,
1995, p. 129). The transboundary effect results when environmental deg-
radation crosses national boundaries. This can take a number of forms.
The first is where neighbouring countries share a common resource and
the action of one country affects the others. Examples that fall in this
category are acid rain and the management of regional seas and interna-
tional rivers. The second is when one country’s action affects the world’s
global environmental resources, such as the atmosphere, and thereby has
an effect on all of the other countries. Examples that fall in this category
are ozone layer depletion and global warming. The third form is when
resources belonging to one country have high values for the international
community. Examples that fall in this category are tropical rainforests,
individual species and special ecological habitats. The free-rider effect,
where countries have the incentives to take advantage of the efforts of
others to provide the public good without paying their share or contribut-
ing to this step, also necessitates the existence of institutions and policies
(IBRD, 1992; Goodstein, 1999; Stavins, 2000).
Fourth, the international community negotiates international environ-
mental standards and sets them based on common principles and rules of
collaboration among the various countries. It gives proper weight to the
interests of all countries, including the poor and politically weak ones. In
addition, it monitors, enforces and abides by multilateral agreements on
environmental matters (Congleton, 1992; IBRD, 1992).
The relationship between economic development and environmental
pollution is complex as it involves a lot of different interrelated factors.
Among these factors are: the size of the economy, the sectoral structure,
the age of technology, the public demand for environmental quality and
the level and quality of environmental protection expenditure (Goodstein,
1999). However, the relationship mainly centres around five questions.
First, does the EKC relationship between income and environmental deg-
radation exist, and if yes, what is the income turning point? Second, what
are the other factors affecting this relationship, such as population growth/
density, international trade, policy, geography and income distribution and
what roles do they play? Third, how reliable are the results derived from
cross-sectional country or panel data in forecasting the environmental
Economic growth and the environment 363
A fourth type of model included trade variables and per capita income
as independent variables, commonly using a quadratic form equation.
Examples of trade variables are export or import manufacturing ratio,
commerce intensity and prices for goods, such as wood or steel (Cropper
and Griffiths, 1994; Cole et al., 1997; Suri and Chapman, 1998; Kaufmann
et al., 1998):
The last and more comprehensive type of models included policy vari-
ables in addition to population density, growth and per capita income as
independent variables, applying a cubic form equation (Panayotou,
1997):
and Heston (1991) (Penn World Tables). They found that concentrations
for sulphur dioxide and smoke increased with higher per capita GDP at
low levels of national income and decreased with higher levels of income,
with a turning point between $4000 and $5000, measured in 1985 US
dollars of GDP. For the mass of suspended particles, in a given volume of
air, they found that the relationship was monotonically decreasing. They
also found that all three pollutants increased at an income level of $10 000
to $15 000.
In another study, Grossman and Krueger (1995) examined the relation-
ship between per capita income and four types of environmental indica-
tors: urban air pollution (SO2, smoke and heavy particles), the state of the
oxygen regime in river basins (dissolved oxygen, biological oxygen demand
(BOD), chemical oxygen demand (COD) and concentration of nitrates),
faecal contamination of river basins (faecal coliform and total coliform)
and contamination of river basins by heavy metals (concentration of lead,
cadmium, arsenic, mercury and nickel). They used panel data across many
countries for the 14 environmental indicators obtained from the GEMS.
They found evidence that, for most indicators, environmental quality ini-
tially deteriorated with economic growth, followed by a subsequent phase
of improvement. They also found that the turning points for the different
pollutants varied but, in most cases, were below an income per capita level
of $8000, measured in 1985 US dollars of GDP. They also found that for
seven indicators there was a statistically significant positive relationship
between environmental quality and per capita income GDP of $10 000.
Only in the case of total coliform did they find a significant adverse rela-
tionship at this level of income. They also highlighted that there were a few
points to be taken into account with regard to their findings. First, there
was no reason to believe that improvement in environmental quality as a
result of economic development was an automatic process. Second, the
reason for the downward slope and inverted U-shaped curve could be due
to countries ceasing to produce pollution-intensive goods as they imported
these goods from other countries. Third, the relationship observed in
previous research reflected the technological, political and economic con-
ditions existing at that time, from which poor countries could learn and
avoid the mistakes of earlier growth experiences.
Shafik and Bandyopadhyay (1992) explored the relationship between
economic growth and environmental quality in a background paper for
the World Development Report, which was later published by Shafik in
1994. They conducted a systematic analysis on environmental quality data
from 149 countries for the period 1960 to 1990. They used ten environ-
mental indicators: lack of clean water, lack of urban sanitation, ambient
levels of SPM, ambient sulphur oxides (SO2), change in forest area and
Economic growth and the environment 369
the best method for reducing the rate of deforestation in developing coun-
tries. They also said that deforestation was the problem of market failure,
which resulted from the lack of defining and enforcing property rights,
where people had no right in land ownership, and therefore no incentive
to make efficient decisions in the use of land.
Antle and Heidebrink (1995) examined the relationship between income
and two classes of environmental amenities: parklands and forests in low-
and high-income countries. The environmental indicators used were total
area of parks and protected areas (PARKS), deforestation (DEFOR),
afforestation (AFFOR) and total forest area (FOR). They gathered their
income data and area values from the World Development Report 1987,
PARKS data from the 1989/90 Environmental Data Report by the United
Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) and FOR and DEFOR data
from World Resources 1990/91. The income data used were per capita
GNP in 1985 nominal US dollars. They found a U-shaped relationship
and the income elasticity of demand for environmental quality was near
zero for countries with income per capita of around $1200–$2000, while
being positive and generally exceeding unity for countries with higher per
capita income levels.
However, in an empirical study done by Koop and Tole (1999) in
which they examined the relationship between deforestation and per
capita GDP, using less restrictive model specifications, they did not find
an EKC relationship between the two variables. They used data for 76
tropical developing countries for various years during the period 1961–92.
The deforestation indicator used was the loss in forest cover derived
from the FAO Production Yearbook. The per capita GDP data were
taken from the Penn World Table. Also they included two demographic
measures; the population density and population change, which were
derived from the FAO Production Yearbook and the Penn World Table.
The authors concluded that the extreme assumptions used in previous
studies that assumed uniformity across the countries led to the existence
of the EKC pattern between deforestation and per capita income. Upon
adopting random coefficient specifications, as they did in their study,
the inverted U-shaped relationship did not exist. They added that their
approach was more realistic given the wide variety of physical and social
characteristics across the countries.
With respect to urban environmental quality, a large number of studies
concentrated on air pollution. Selden and Song (1994) carried out an
empirical study using a cross-national panel of data on aggregate emis-
sions to examine the relationship between pollution and economic devel-
opment. They used aggregate emissions instead of urban air quality data
as they believed that the latter was valid if the objective was to understand
372 A handbook of environmental management
the factors underlying the pollution faced by urban dwellers. On the other
hand, they were trying to understand the environmental impact beyond
urban areas, and therefore the analysis using aggregate emissions was per-
ceived to provide greater insight. They concentrated on four air emissions:
SPM, SO2, NOx and CO across 30 countries and across time. Out of the
30 countries, 22 were categorized as high income, six were middle income
and two were low income. The emissions data constructed from fuel con-
sumption figures were obtained from the World Resources Institute (1991)
and were measured in terms of kilograms per capita on a national basis.
The income data used were per capita GDP in 1985 US dollars. Their
findings showed a U-shaped curve of per capita emissions for all four air
pollutants and per capita GDP. However, they found substantially higher
turning points for the similar pollutants used by Grossman and Kreuger.
The estimated turning points were $8709 for SO2, $11 217 for NOx, $10 289
for SPM and $5963 for CO. They considered this to be reasonable given
their use of aggregate emissions data as opposed to urban atmospheric
concentrations. On the other hand, their results were widely different from
those found by Panayotou, who also used aggregate emissions data. As
the turning points were high enough above the per capita income of most
countries, they concluded that global emissions of these pollutants would
continue to increase in the foreseeable future.
Cole et al. (1997) examined the relationship between per capita income
and a wide range of environmental indicators, which had indirect impact
on the environment using cross-country panel data sets. These indica-
tors were carbon dioxide, CFCs and halons, methane, nitrogen dioxide,
sulphur dioxide, suspended particulate matter, carbon monoxide, nitrates,
energy consumption, municipal waste and traffic volume. They arrived at
three main conclusions. First, the EKC existed only for local air pollut-
ants, while indicators with more global or indirect impact either increased
monotonically with income or had turning points at very high levels of per
capita income with large standard errors, unless they had been subjected
to a ‘multilateral policy initiative’, which implied that the process was not
automatic. Second, concentrations of local air pollutants in urban areas
peaked at a lower per capita income level than total emissions, which
implied that it was easier to improve the quality of urban air than to
reduce national emissions. Third, transport-generated local air pollutants
peaked at a higher per capita income level than total emissions per capita,
which implied the severity and need to tackle the problem in the transport
sector.
On the other hand, in a number of studies it has been found that CO2
follows an EKC pattern. In a study by Holtz-Eakin and Selden (1995) in
which they examined the relationship of CO2 emissions and GDP, they
Economic growth and the environment 373
second was the 1987 Montreal Protocol that obliged developed countries
to reduce their CFC emissions to half 1986 levels by June 1999 and limits
the future consumption of CFCs by developing countries. He used the
type of regime as a proxy to the personal characteristics of decision- or
policy-makers. Gastil’s classification of countries (1987) had been used to
construct the type of regime, market structure, shares of national income
and time horizon of policy-makers. The country’s area was used as a
proxy for its resource endowments and population was proxied for labour
force. Both of these data were taken from the World Fact Book (1988).
Finally, the data on real GNP in 1987 US dollars were gathered from the
World Petroleum Institute (1990/91). Congleton arrived at three main
conclusions. First, authoritarian regimes faced a higher price for pollution
abatement than democratic governments. Second, authoritarian regimes
had uncertain career paths and shorter terms of office, and thereby would
tend to adopt less stringent environmental policies and regulations than
democratic ones. Third, they were less willing to sign international agree-
ments to protect their environments. The author concluded that political
institutions, rather than economic endowments, technology or market
institutions, would determine the level of domestic and international
environmental policies and regulations in the country.
Also Panayotou (1997) presented a study that focused on the policy
scope and provided a more analytical and structural approach to the
income–environment relationship. The roles of economic growth and pop-
ulation density were also explored. He examined the relationship between
income growth rate and policy variables against the level of sulphur dioxide
using panel data for 30 developed and developing countries for the period
1982 to 1994. The data for SO2 were gathered from the GEMS, while
those for GDP were obtained from the Penn World Table (1995) and were
measured in terms of 1985 constant US dollars as purchasing power parity
(adjusted GDP figures) was not available beyond 1992. He used proxies
for the quality of institutions to represent environmental policies. He
used five indicators to represent the quality of institutions obtained from
Knack and Keefer (1995). These indicators were enforcement of contracts,
quality of bureaucracy, the rule of law, corruption in government and the
risk of expropriation. Panayotou found an inverted U-shaped relation-
ship with a per capita turning point just under $5000. He also found that
the emission elasticity with respect to the improvements in the quality of
institutions was much higher than those of economic growth and popula-
tion density: a 50 per cent improvement in the efficacy of institutions and
policies at income levels between $10 000 and $20 000 could result in 50 per
cent reduction in the concentrations of SO2. On the other hand, at lower
income levels, the same improvement did not result in a similar reduction
378 A handbook of environmental management
with its high pollution, especially in the early stages, to the less pollut-
ing service industries. One of the reasons for this pattern could be that
wealthier countries dumped their polluting processes in poorer countries.
This, in turn, meant that it was not possible for all nations to experience
improvements in environmental quality. The second reason they gave was
that the EKC might be based on two separate relationships. First was the
‘scale effect’, where higher economic activity generated more pollution
and wealthy countries, with more polluting activity, generated more pollu-
tion. This was referred to as pollution activity. Second was the ‘technique
effect’, where citizens in wealthy countries demanded more environmental
quality in the form of regulations to protect the environment and to reduce
the amount of pollution per unit of activity. This was referred to as pollu-
tion intensity. Therefore, the shape of the pollution–income relationship
was the product of pollution activity and pollution intensity. So their con-
clusion was that polluting activity increased with income, while polluting
intensity decreased with income and the product of the two followed an
inverse U-shape.
Midlarsky (1998) examined the relationship between democracy and
the environment. He used six environmental indicators as the dependent
variables: CO2 emissions, deforestation, soil erosion by water, land area
protection, freshwater availability and soil erosion by chemicals. He found
that democratic countries had higher CO2 emissions, deforestation and
soil erosion. However, they tended to protect a higher percentage of their
land area. For the last two environmental indicators he found no signifi-
cant relationship and concluded that there was no uniform relationship
between democracy and the environment.
Tuan (1999) found similar results for CO2 emissions to those found by
Panayotou for SO2. He presented a paper on the relationship between
income and environmental quality, mainly CO2 emissions. He used panel
data for six countries at different stages of economic development. The
countries examined were Vietnam, Thailand, Korea, France, Japan and
the United States. In addition to the income variable, he included in his
model other social variables, such as population, economic growth and
institutional capacity in order to examine the underlying impacts on the
EKC trajectory. The environmental data for the three developed coun-
tries were obtained from the OECD Environmental Data Compendium
for the years 1993, 1995 and 1997. The energy data for the three Asian
countries were obtained from the ENERDATA database. The per capita
GDP data were in 1987 constant US dollars and were obtained from
the database of ENERDATA as well as the data on economic growth
rates and demographic density. For the political or institutional capacity
variable, the author used four indicators from the Business Environmental
Economic growth and the environment 381
pollutants as a result of higher per capita income. The air and water pol-
lutants examined were sulphur dioxide, smoke, heavy particles, dissolved
oxygen, faecal coliform, access to safe water and access to sanitation. For
the first five pollutants, they used data from the GEMS for the period
1977 to 1991. The air pollution data contained observations from 19 to
42 countries and that for water pollution contained observations from 58
countries. The percentages of population with safe water and sanitation
were obtained from the United Nations Development Programme (1994)
and were national-level variables with no time series dimension. The per
capita income used were measured in real PPP adjusted for 1985 US
dollars. The income data for per capita GDP were taken from Summers
and Heston (1991), while the national income levels data were taken from
the UNDP (1994).
The authors predicted that the higher the power inequality, the higher
the levels of pollution, so they included other variables as proxies for
power inequality, such as Gini ratio of income inequality, literacy rates
and political rights and civil liberties. Four of the seven environmental
indicators showed EKC patterns when excluding the power inequality
variable. These indicators were sulphur dioxide, smoke, access to safe
water and access to sanitation with turning points of $3890, $4350, $11 255
and $10 957, respectively. Heavy particles monotonically decreased with
rising income while dissolved oxygen and faecal coliform monotonically
increased. When including the power equality variable, only three pol-
lutants showed EKC patterns, which were sulphur dioxide, dissolved
oxygen and access to safe water with turning points of $3360, $19 865 and
$6900, respectively. Access to sanitation increased monotonically, while
the relationships for smoke, heavy particles and faecal coliform were sta-
tistically insignificant. They arrived at two main conclusions. First, equi-
table distribution of power, in the form of equitable income distribution,
wider literacy and greater political liberties and civil rights, would lead to
better environmental quality, especially in low-income nations. Second,
improvements in environmental quality would not automatically accom-
pany continued growth in per capita income.
Also, Deacon (1999) argued that the form of government in a country
played a crucial role in the way economic growth would affect the envi-
ronment and that omitting it as a determinant of environmental quality
could lead to biased results and interpretation. He presented a study to
examine the effect of the government regime on the provision of envi-
ronmental public goods and environmental policies using cross-sectional
analysis of 118 countries. Deacon classified governments into groups with
similar political attributes using compiled data sets from two sources. The
first was the Cross-national Time-series Data Archive, which was first
Economic growth and the environment 383
(ISIC). The income data were GDP per capita in 1985 nominal US dollars.
They found an inverted U-shaped relationship for pollution intensity per
unit of GDP, however, they did not find the same pattern for toxic inten-
sity per unit of industrial output. On the contrary, they found that manu-
facturing output increased steadily with income. They concluded that this
was the result of development in these countries, and, therefore, a shift
in the production structure from industry towards services, which were
lower in pollution. They also analysed the relationship of toxic intensity
and trade policy in less developed countries (LDCs) and they found that
the closer the country to international trade, the more rapid the growth of
toxic intensity of manufacturing. They concluded that, for the majority of
countries, there would be an increasing long-term trend of industrial emis-
sions, with respect to both GDP and manufacturing output. This would
also be higher in the poorer countries mainly due to the tighter environ-
mental regulations in the industrialized nations since 1970.
Grossman and Krueger (1991) also included a trade variable in their
study as they studied the effect of reduction in trade barriers on the envi-
ronment in Mexico and assessed the relative magnitudes of change in the
level of pollution resulting from further trade liberalization. They found
significant evidence that trade helped to reduce the level of pollution for
only one of the three pollution variables, which was urban concentrations
of SO2. Shafik and Bandyopadhyay (1992) tested the hypothesis that trade
induced the use of cleaner technology, and thereby would reduce pollution.
However, they found weak evidence between the two variables.
Rock (1996) studied the relationship between trade policy and the
environment in rich and poor countries using cross-country data over the
period 1973 to 1985. He used the pollution data on toxic chemical intensity
of GDP, which were previously used by Hettige et al. (1992) in their study.
However, he included two other variables: the manufacturing share of
GDP and the energy intensity of GDP. The first variable was included to
separate the effect of the broad composition of output on pollution inten-
sity from that of trade policy, while the latter was included to separate the
effect of energy price policy from trade policy. The trade orientation data
were taken from the World Bank (1987) where countries were grouped
into four categories depending on their trade policies. The four groups
were strongly outward-oriented, moderately outward-oriented, moder-
ately inward-oriented and strongly inward-oriented. He found evidence of
higher pollution intensity in countries with more open trade policies and
that the most inward-oriented developing countries had the lowest toxic
chemical pollution intensity of GDP.
The relationship between per capita income and consumption of
primary commercial energy was examined by Suri and Chapman (1998)
386 A handbook of environmental management
using pooled cross-country and time series data in order to quantify the
impact of the actual movement of goods between countries. They used
observations from 33 countries over the period 1971 to 1990. The energy
data, expressed in oil equivalents, were obtained from the IEA, while the
income and trade data were obtained from the Penn World Table and the
income data were expressed in 1985 US dollars PPP. The authors pre-
sented two types of models. The first model implicitly captured the impacts
of both structural change and international trade, while the second model
explicitly analysed the effect of international trade on commercial energy
use. The variable representing structural change was the share of total
manufacturing in GDP (that is, manufacturing for domestic market and
production for exports). International trade variables were represented
by import- and export-manufacturing ratios. In both models, the EKC
pattern was depicted, with a turning point of $55 000 in the first model and
$224 000 in the second one. Accordingly, they concluded that, all things
being equal, international trade would tend to increase the pollutant
emissions related to commercial energy consumption. The authors also
found that energy use increased in both industrialized and industrializing
countries, however, it was substantially higher in the latter. Moreover, as
opposed to industrializing countries, whose imports were largely interme-
diate and capital goods, which were essential for building an industrial
base, industrialized nations benefited from importing manufactured goods
from industrializing countries. Therefore, their relative increase in energy
requirements to GDP was substantially lower. The authors concluded that
the imports of manufactured goods, in addition to the structural change
from manufacturing to non-energy-intensive service sector, were the result
of this decline.
Some authors concentrated on trade patterns and consumption, rather
than production, in examining the income–environment relationship.
Rothman (1998) studied the relationship between per capita GDP and
consumption activities using data on eight categories of consumer goods
from the United Nations International Comparison Programme (1994).
Among the commodities used were food, beverages and tobacco, clothing
and footwear, gross rent, fuel and power, medical care and services, trans-
port and communications, recreation, entertainment and education. The
unit for each commodity was the quantity that could be bought for $1 at
average international prices. The data used for the per capita GDP were in
1985 US dollars PPP. The only commodity they found showing evidence
of EKC was food, beverages and tobacco with a turning point of $12 889.
Other commodities, in terms of shares, also changed with income, such as
clothing and footwear, gross rent, fuel and power and medical care and
services, with turning points of $35 263, $23 278 and $47 171, respectively.
Economic growth and the environment 387
However, this was due to changes in relative share rather than a decline in
consumption.
The extent of the so-called pollution haven hypothesis (PHH) in
explaining the EKC relationship was assessed by Cole (2004). The PHH
was defined as the migration or displacement of pollution-intensive
industries from developed to developing countries due to more stringent
environmental regulations in the former countries. The author estimated
the EKC model for ten air and water pollutants for a sample of OECD
countries over the period 1980 to 1997. The air pollutants were CO2, NOx,
SO2, CO, SPM and volatile organic compounds (VOC), while the water
pollutants were the level of nitrates, the level of phosphorous, BOD and
the levels of dissolved oxygen. To capture the PHH effects, the author
included the share of pollution-intensive exports and imports to and from
non-OECD countries in total exports and imports. He also included the
share of manufacturing in GNP to capture the effect of structural change
within the economy on pollution. To reflect trade openness/intensity, the
author used the ratio of the sum of imports and exports to GNP. Cole
found that, with the exception of VOC and CO, all the other eight pollut-
ants exhibited an EKC relationship with per capita income, with turning
points ranging between $1973 and $35 140. He also found a positive rela-
tionship between the manufacturing share of GNP and environmental
quality for eight pollutants, of which seven were statistically significant.
This indicated that structural change within the economy was partially
responsible for pollution reduction at higher income levels. With respect
to PHH, Cole found mixed results. There was a negative relationship
between the share of pollution-intensive imports to total imports and envi-
ronmental quality for seven pollutants (five air pollutants and two water
pollutants), of which five were statistically significant. On the other hand,
there was a positive relationship between the share of pollution-intensive
exports to total exports and environmental quality for five pollutants (one
air pollutant and four water pollutants), of which four were statistically
significant. Nevertheless, upon omitting the pollution haven variables, the
EKC turning points were lower for eight out of the ten pollutants, suggest-
ing that these effects contributed to the reduction of emissions at higher
levels of income. With respect to trade openness, the author found a nega-
tive relationship between trade openness and environmental quality for
eight out of the ten pollutants, of which six were statistically significant.
The author concluded that the reduction in emissions at higher levels
of income was due to higher demand for environmental regulation and
investment in abatement technologies, trade openness, structural change
within the economy and increased imports of pollution-intensive indus-
tries. Nevertheless, the author could not ascertain that the developing
388 A handbook of environmental management
kilometre were associated with high levels of ambient SO2 emissions, being
70 kg/km3. As population density increased, SO2 levels dropped, reaching
their lowest level of 45 kg/km3 at a population density level of 170 persons
per square kilometre and then started to increase again. The author attrib-
uted the higher SO2 levels at lower population density to the lack of pres-
sure in countries with spare population to control emissions. However, as
population density increased, more pressure was exerted to control emis-
sions as more people were exposed to pollution. This continued up to the
level where the household use of coal and non-commercial fuels exceeded
the pressure for pollution abatement.
Similarly, as mentioned before, Tuan (1999) tested the impact of popu-
lation density on the EKC trajectory. He hypothesized that the higher the
population density, the lower the turning point of the EKC, and, thus, a
better environmental quality. He found an EKC relationship between per
capita income and CO2 emissions with a turning point of approximately
$18 000. However, with respect to the impact of economic growth and
population rate on CO2 emissions, Tuan found that their impact varied
according to the level of income and the country’s stage of development.
At income levels below $2000 per capita, a highly dense population had a
negative impact on the environment. On the other hand, at income levels
of $2000 per capita or more, a highly dense population had a positive
effect on the environment. For instance, at an income level of $1000 per
capita, an increase in the population density of 67 per cent resulted in a
12 per cent increase in CO2 emissions. However, at an income level of
$10 000 per capita, a similar increase in the population density resulted in
a 22 per cent reduction in CO2 emissions. The author concluded that at
higher income levels, the higher the population density, the more pressure
was being exerted to control emissions as more people were being exposed
to the pollution.
Vincent (1997) presented an analysis for a single country, Malaysia, in
an attempt to examine the pollution–income relationship. Unlike previous
studies that conducted an analysis on cross-sectional or panel data for a
sample of developed and developing countries, Vincent used a panel data
set for the 13 Malaysian states and he analysed the relationship between
income and a number of air and water pollutants over time (1970s to
1990s). He also measured the impact of population density on the various
pollutants. The pollutants were TSPs, BOD, COD, ammoniacal nitrogen,
pH and suspended solids. The data used were ambient levels measured by
monitoring stations.
He chose Malaysia for several reasons. First, the country had a rich data
set with nearly two decades of readings on ambient air and water pollu-
tion. Second, the country’s economy had been one of the fastest growing
390 A handbook of environmental management
in the world since the 1970s, and therefore its income data contained
ample variation over time, even within the states as growth had not been
equally rapid across all states. Third, income data overlapped between
the states. Fourth, the borders of most states were determined by ridges
that separated the major water basins and, to a certain extent, air basins.
Fifth, the states shared the same pollution policies, which varied across
pollutants.
According to Vincent’s study, there was no evidence of EKCs for any of
the six income–pollution relationships in Malaysia. This result was incon-
sistent with previous research conducted using cross-country relationships.
With respect to population density, Vincent found that the net impact of
population density on TSP concentrations was positive and the interaction
term between population density and time was statistically significant but
negative. He attributed the positive impact to the various household activi-
ties, which were important sources of TSP concentrations, such as heating,
cooking, rubbish disposal and transportation. The negative interaction
term indicated a reduction in the per capita TSP concentrations due to the
pressure exerted through the enforcement of effective anti-pollution regula-
tions. For the water pollutants, and while holding income constant, Vincent
found that higher population densities were associated with worse water
quality for BOD and ammoniacal nitrogen, and better water quality for sus-
pended solids. He attributed this to the higher sewage discharge as a result
of higher population, in the case of BOD and ammoniacal nitrogen, and
the movement of people from rural to urban areas in the case of suspended
solids. The interaction term between population density and time was also
significant. It was negative in the case of BOD and ammoniacal nitrogen as
a result of the introduction of regulations to reduce BOD discharge and the
percentage of population without access to sanitary facilities. The interac-
tion term was positive for suspended solids indicating agriculture and set-
tlement movements to steeper and erosion-prone areas. In conclusion, the
author said that his findings did not mean that EKC did not exist anywhere,
but it meant that policy-makers should not assume that economic growth
was an automatic solution for the air and water pollution problems.
Kaufmann et al. (1998) attempted to explore the effects of income and
spatial intensity of economic activity on the atmospheric concentration
of SO2. They used a panel of international data for 23 countries with
observations between 1974 and 1989. Out of the 23 countries, 13 were
developed nations, seven were developing nations and three were centrally
planned economies. The data on SO2 were obtained from the United
Nations Statistical Yearbook (1993) and GDP per capita and population
data were obtained from Summers and Heston (1993). The income data
were expressed in 1985 nominal US dollars. They used two variables to
Economic growth and the environment 391
proxy the spatial intensity of economic activity, one for cities and the other
one for the entire nation. The variable for spatial intensity of economic
activities in cities was the product of a city’s population density and the
per capita GDP of the nation in which the city was located, while that for
the nation was the GDP divided by the nation’s area. The result of their
study indicated a U-shaped relationship between both per capita GDP
and atmospheric concentration of SO2. The concentration of SO2 tended
to reduce as per capita income rose from $3000 to $12 500, however,
it increased beyond $12 500. On the other hand, there was an inverted
U-shaped relationship between spatial intensity of economic activity and
atmospheric concentration of SO2 with turning points of $6.7 million per
square mile for the nation variable and $153 million per square mile for the
city variable. They suggested that the impetus for policies and technologies
to reduce SO2 atmospheric concentration was spatial intensity of economic
activity rather than income. This implied that atmospheric concentration
of SO2 would decline faster than indicated in previous studies, however, it
would depend on the rate of income growth relative to population growth.
They suggested that the inverted U-shape found in previous studies might
be due to the omission of the variables representing changes in the mix
and spatial intensity of economic activity, and therefore the pattern was a
proxy for changes in the mix of economic activity associated with changes
in per capita GDP.
preferences that were consistent with a high income elasticity of demand were
neither necessary nor sufficient for pollution to grow with income. Simple
392 A handbook of environmental management
models showed that preferences that were consistent with a high income elas-
ticity of demand for environmental quality were attenuated by high and rising
abatement costs or a high impact of pollution on production. Hence, it would
be feasible for pollution to decline with a zero income elasticity of demand for
environmental quality, or to increase with a high income elasticity of demand
for environmental quality.
In another study, Kahn (1998) examined the effect of per capita income
on hydrocarbon emissions of vehicles. He used the 1993 Random Roadside
Test created by the California Department of Consumer Affairs Bureau of
Automotive Repairs, whereby vehicles at random are selected to have
an emissions test. He used the 1990 Census of Population and Housing,
which included the zip code median household income as a proxy for
household income. The hydrocarbon emissions were measured in parts per
million (ppm) and household income was measured in thousands of US
dollars. The author tried to study the total annual contribution of a house-
hold to local pollution in relation to its income. He presented evidence of
an inverted U-shaped relationship between income and emissions, with a
turning point between $25 000 and $35 000. He also found that average
emissions for vehicles owned by households with income levels below
$35 000 were twice as high as those for households with income levels
over $45 000, showing a higher demand for better vehicle quality at higher
levels of income.
Pfaff et al. (2001) examined the linkage between income and house-
hold choices and its impact on the environment. The model they used
emphasized two main features. First, environmental degradation was a
by-product of the household activities. Second, households could recog-
nize their activities, and therefore would substitute for more expensive,
less environmentally degrading commodities, with higher income. They
highlighted that this would occur with the assumption that environmental
quality was a normal good and given the elimination of natural constraints
of desirability and feasibility of substitution. They found a non-monotonic
relationship between income and environmental quality, generating an
EKC at the household level as substitution constraints were eliminated.
In another paper, Pfaff et al. (2002) provided an explanation for the
EKC using their household-choice framework. They showed that at low
income levels, the marginal rate of substitution between household con-
sumption and the environment made abatement undesirable for the house-
hold. As income increased, both consumption and abatement expenditure
rose. They concluded that both household consumption preferences and
abatement technologies were necessary and sufficient conditions to gener-
ate the EKC path. They also applied their model to a set of externalities
and multiple agents who voted for environmental spending and taxation.
Economic growth and the environment 393
They found evidence for the EKC. As the chosen tax rate increased with
income, abatement occurred after a certain range, and therefore environ-
mental quality deteriorated at first and then improved.
Also Chaudhuri and Pfaff (2002), using the above model, studied the
linkages between household fuel-choice preference and income on the envi-
ronment, specifically indoor air pollution, in Pakistan. The individual and
house-level data were obtained from the Pakistan Integrated Household
Survey (1991), which covered the energy consumption of 4800 households.
To derive their sample, they used a multi-state stratified sampling proce-
dure from the Federal Bureau of Statistics based on the 1981 census. The
authors found significant evidence of an inverted U-shaped relationship
between monthly household income and monthly household emissions, in
terms of the quantity of the monthly fuel consumption due to the transi-
tion in the fuel-choice behaviour of the household. As per capita income
increased, the household moved from using traditional fuel and invested
in cleaner modern fuel. However, for all modern fuel consumption, their
quantities increased with higher incomes, forming a concave curve.
In a recent study by Khanna and Plassmann (2004), they examined the
impact of demand for environmental quality on the relationship between
income and pollution. They argued that the ability of the consumers to
separate themselves from the source of pollution played a decisive role
in the consumer’s decision to limit their exposure to pollution as income
increased. Also they argued that the turning point of the EKC would be
lower for pollutants where spatial separation was possible. Unlike Shafik
and Bandhopadhyay (1992) and Suri and Chapman (1998) who used
multi-country panel data that combined the effects of other factors, such
as structural changes, technology and consumer preferences for environ-
mental quality, Khanna and Plassmann used cross-sectional census-tract-
level data for the United States to isolate the effects of changes in income
from those in other factors. The census-tract-level data were the smallest
geographical unit for which detailed socioeconomic data were available.
The authors tested their hypothesis on five air pollutants: SO2, particulate
matter (PM), CO, ground level O3 and NOx. They used ambient con-
centrations data from the EPA AIRS database. They found an EKC
relationship for SO2 and PM, with turning points of $8653 and $11 412,
respectively. For the other three pollutants, the income–pollution relation-
ship continued to increase.
The authors concluded that the EKC hypothesis was an equilibrium
relationship between income and pollution based on the interaction
between consumer preferences and technology. For pollutants where
spatial separation was relatively straightforward, the opportunity cost of
pollution abatement was relatively low, and therefore the turning point of
394 A handbook of environmental management
that would lead to a new trajectory. In the case of CO2, the oil price shock
was the impetus that changed its trajectory. Second, a national capacity
existed for a rapid and persistent change under the proper stimuli. In the
case of CO2, the change in its trajectory happened within a single year and
continued at a particular emission level despite the continued economic
growth and the decline in oil prices.
Stern and Common (2001) criticized the EKC models by saying that they
lacked adequate specification due to the omissions of a number of variables
that were correlated with GDP. Their criticism was based on the results of
statistical tests from their study on the relationship between sulphur emis-
sions and per capita GDP. They applied fixed and random effects models
to a subset of panel data from 73 countries over the period 1960 to 1990.
They used data from the ASL and Associates (1997) database, consisting
of data on sulphur emissions for most of the countries of the world over
the period 1850 to 1990. An EKC relationship was found in both models,
however, the turning points were much lower when using data for only the
OECD countries (fixed effects: $9239, random effects: $9181), than when
estimating EKC for the whole sample (fixed effects: $101 166, random
effects: $54 199). Similarly the estimated turning points were extremely
high for non-OECD countries (fixed effects: $908 178, random effects:
$343 689), implying a monotonic EKC relationship between per capita
income and sulphur emissions in the case of non-OECD countries and the
whole sample. They said that their findings suggested that the inclusion of
trade variables would be important as OECD countries could outsource
the production of pollution-intensive products to the rest of the world.
However, inclusion of global macroeconomic trends and shocks, such as
the oil crisis of the 1970s, seemed unimportant.
In a study by Halkos (2003) using the same sample data from ASL and
Associates (1997) as Stern and Common (2001), he empirically tested
the relationship between environmental damage from sulphur emissions
and per capita GDP. He applied two econometric methods: random coef-
ficients and the Arellano–Bond Generalized Method of Moments (A–B
GMM). The per capita GDP data were derived from the Penn World
Table in Summers and Heston (1991), together with the population data.
The sample of countries chosen by Halkos in his study represented 81
per cent of the world’s population. He found an EKC pattern relation-
ship in the case of an A–B GMM model with turning points well within
the sample for all cases (global, OECD and non-OECD), ranging from
$2805 to $6230. However, unlike the results found by Stern and Common
(2001), the turning point for only the OECD countries was higher than
those for the global and non-OECD countries. On the other hand, no
support for the EKC hypothesis was found using the random coefficients
Economic growth and the environment 399
16 industrialized countries, using panel data over the period 1960 to 1998.
Their results showed robust support for weak dematerialization in indus-
trialized countries, whereby the aggregate material intensity, measured
in mass units, reduced as per capita income levels increased. The authors
suggested that this relationship could be due to (1) the higher material use
at lower levels of income to respond to infrastructural needs and (2) the
structural change within the economy towards an increase in the service
sector as income increased.
Dinda (2004) reviewed a number of studies on the EKC hypothesis and
ended up by saying that the subject was open-ended and the existence of
the EKC was inconclusive. He also highlighted several areas that required
further research. First, the choice of economic models was important
to properly reflect the physical and ecological aspects of the economy.
Second, unfolding the underlying factors behind the EKC was a priority
for any research. Third, moving towards structural rather than reduced-
form models and decomposition analysis might be needed. Fourth, using
of time series rather than panel data was essential to identify the develop-
ment of pollution associated with economic growth in individual coun-
tries. Finally, determining the policy measures and regulations necessary
to allow sustainable development.
Conclusion
This chapter reviewed the extensive research conducted in examining
the relationship between economic growth and the environment. Earlier
studies on the income–environment relationship used the reduced-form
single-equation approach to show the relationship between economic
growth and environmental degradation, without understanding the
dynamics of this relationship. In order to test whether income was the
determinant of the behaviour of the environmental indicator(s), recent
studies moved towards decomposition analysis and more structural and
analytical models to identify the real factors or influences behind the
income–environment relationship. Most of the studies used cross-sectional
country or panel data instead of time series data across countries due to
the difficulty and limited availability of the latter. Furthermore, although
some research explored the role of policies and institutions, a limited
number of empirical studies examined the influence of international envi-
ronmental legislation on the relationship between economic growth and
the environment.
References
Andreoni, J. and A. Levinson (1998), ‘The Simple Analytics of the Environmental Kuznets
Curve’, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Working Paper No. 6739.
404 A handbook of environmental management
Antle, J.M. and G. Heidebrink (1995), ‘Environment and Development: Theory and
International Evidence’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 43(3), 603–25.
Arrow, K., B. Bolin, R. Costanza, P. Dasgupta, C. Folke, C.S. Holling, B.-O. Jansson, S.
Levin, K.-G. Maler, C. Perrings and D. Pimentel (1995), ‘Economic Growth, Carrying
Capacity, and the Environment’, Ecological Economics, 15(2), 89–95.
Ayres, R.U. (1995), ‘Economic Growth: Politically Necessary but not Environmentally
Friendly’, Ecological Economics, 15(2), 97–9.
Barnett, H. and C. Morse (1961), Scarcity and Growth: The Economics of Natural Resource
Availability, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press.
Barrett, S. and K. Graddy (2000), ‘Freedom, Growth, and the Environment’, Environment
and Development Economics, 5(1), 433–56.
Beckerman, W. (1992), ‘Economic Growth and the Environment: Whose Growth? Whose
Environment?’, World Development, 20(4), 481–96.
Bhattarai, M. and M. Hammig (2001), ‘Institutions and the Environmental Kuznets Curve
for Deforestation: A Cross-country Analysis for Latin America, Africa and Asia’, World
Development, 29(6), 995–1010.
Brundtland, G. (1987), Our Common Future: The World Commission on Environment and
Development, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Canas, A., P. Ferrao and P. Conceicao (2003), ‘A New Environmental Kuznets Curve?
Relationship between Direct Material Input and Income per Capita: Evidence from
Industrialized Countries’, Ecological Economics, 46(2), 217–29.
Carson, R.T., Y. Jeon and D.R. McCubbin (1997), ‘The Relationship between Air
Pollution Emissions and Income: US Data’, Environment and Development Economics,
2(4), 433–50.
Cavlovic, T.A., K.H. Baker, R.P. Berrens and K. Gawande (2000), ‘A Meta-analysis of
Environmental Kuznets Curve Studies’, Agricultural and Resource Economics Review,
29(1), 32–42.
Chaudhuri, S. and A. Pfaff (2002), ‘Economic Growth and the Environment: What Can
We Learn from Household Data’, School of International and Public Affairs, Columbia
University, Paper No. 0102-51.
Coase, R.H. (1990), The Firm, the Market, and the Law, Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Cole, M.A. (2004), ‘Trade, the Pollution Haven Hypothesis and the Environmental Kuznets
Curve: Examining the Linkages’, Ecological Economics, 48(1), 71–81.
Cole, M.A., A.J. Rayner and J.M. Bates (1997), ‘The Environmental Kuznets Curve: An
Empirical Analysis’, Environment and Development Economics, 2(4), 401–16.
Common, M. (1995), Sustainability and Policy: Limits to Economics, Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Congleton, R.D. (1992), ‘Political Institutions and Pollution Control’, Review of Economics
and Statistics, 74(3), 412–21.
Cropper, M. and C. Griffiths (1994), ‘The Interaction of Population Growth and
Environmental Quality’, Population Economics, 84(2), 250–54.
De Bruyn, S.M. (1997), ‘Explaining the Environmental Kuznets Curve: Structural Change
and International Agreements in Reducing Sulphur Emissions’, Environment and
Development Economics, 27(2), 485–503.
De Bruyn, S.M., J.C.J.M. Van Den Bergh and J.B. Opschoor (1998), ‘Economic Growth
and Emissions: Reconsidering the Empirical Basis of Environmental Kuznets Curves’,
Ecological Economics, 25(2), 161–75.
Deacon, R. (1999), ‘The Political Economy of Environmental Development
Relationships’, Santa Barbara, Preliminary Framework Working Paper, University
of California.
Dinda, S. (2004), ‘Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis: A Survey’, Ecological
Economics, 49(4), 431–55.
Farber, S. (1995), ‘Economic Resilience and Economic Policy’, Ecological Economics, 15(2),
105–7.
Economic growth and the environment 405
and National CO2 Estimates from Fossil Fuel Burning, Cement Production, and Gas-flaring:
1751–1996, Oak Ridge, TN: Carbon Dioxide Information Analysis Center.
McConnell, K.E. (1997), ‘Income and the Demand for Environmental Quality’, Environment
and Development Economics, 2(1), 383–99.
Meadows, D.H., D.L. Meadows, J. Randers and W.W. Behrends (1972), The Limits to
Growth, London: Earth Island Limited.
Midlarsky, M.I. (1998), ‘Democracy and the Environment: An Empirical Assessment’,
Journal of Peace Research, Special Issue on Environmental Conflict, 35(3), 341–61.
Moomaw, W.R. and G.C. Unruh (1997), ‘Are Environmental Kuznets Curves Misleading
Us? The Case of CO2 Emissions’, Environment and Development Economics, 2(4),
451–63.
Moomaw, W.R. and G.C. Unruh (1998), ‘An Alternative Analysis of Apparent EKC-type
Transactions’, Ecological Economics, 25(2), 221–9.
Munasinghe, M. (1999), ‘Is Environmental Degradation an Inevitable Consequence of
Economic Growth: Tunneling through the Environmental Kuznets Curve’, Ecological
Economics, 29(1), 89–109.
Page, T. (1995), ‘Harmony and Pathology’, Ecological Economics, 15(2), 141–4.
Panayotou, T. (1993), ‘Empirical Tests and Policy Analysis of Environmental Degradation
at Different Stages of Economic Development’, World Employment Programme Research
Working Paper No. WEP2-22/WP 238, Geneva: International Labour Force.
Panayotou, T. (1997), ‘Demystifying the Environmental Kuznets Curve: Turning a Black
Box into a Policy Tool’, Environment and Development Economics, 2(4), 465–84.
Panayotou, T. (2000), ‘Economic Growth and the Environment’, CID Working Paper No.
56, Center for International Development, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.
Panayotou, T., J. Sachs and Peterson (1999), ‘Developing Countries and the Control of
Climate Change: A Theoretical Perspective and Policy Implications’, CAER II Discussion
Paper No. 45, August.
Perrings, C.A. and A. Ansuategi (2000), ‘Sustainability, Growth and Development’, Journal
of Economic Studies, 27(1/2), 19–55.
Pfaff, A.S.P., S. Chaudhuri and H.L.M. Nye (2001), ‘Why Might One Expect Environmental
Kuznets Curves? Examining the Desirability and Feasibility of Substitution’, Columbia
University, 9 July, Paper No. 0102-45.
Pfaff, A.S.P., S. Chaudhuri and H.L.M. Nye (2002), ‘Endowments, Preferences, Abatement
and Voting: Microfoundations of Environmental Kuznets Curves’, Columbia University,
Paper No. 0102-46.
Ravallion, M., M. Heil and J. Jalan (1997), ‘A Less Poor World, but a Hotter One?
Carbon Emissions, Economic Growth and Income Inequality’, Working Paper No. 13,
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Roberts, J.T. and P.E. Grimes (1997), ‘Carbon Intensity and Economic Development
1962–91: A Brief Exploration of the Environmental Kuznets Curve’, World Development,
25(2), 191–8.
Roca, J. (2003), ‘Do Individual Preferences Explain the Environmental Kuznets Curve?’,
Ecological Economics, 45(1), 3–10.
Rock, M. (1996), ‘Pollution Intensity of GDP and Trade Policy: Can the World Bank Be
Wrong?’, World Development, 24(3), 471–9.
Rothman, D.S. (1998), ‘Environmental Kuznets Curves – Real Progress or Passing the Buck?
A Case for Consumption-based Approaches’, Ecological Economics, 25(2), 177–94.
Schmalensee, R., T.M. Stoker and R.A. Judson (1998), ‘World Carbon Dioxide Emissions:
1950–2050’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(1), 15–27.
Selden, T.M. and D. Song (1994), ‘Environmental Quality and Development: Is There a
Kuznets Curve for Air Pollution Emissions?’, Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 27(2), 147–62.
Selden, T.M. and D. Song (1995), ‘Neoclassical Growth, the J Curve for Abatement, and the
Inverted U Curve for Pollution’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
27(2), 162–8.
Economic growth and the environment 407
Introduction
The widely accepted principles of sustainable development are that the
present generation should be able to meet its own needs without compro-
mising the needs of future generations. Essentially this implies that we can
continue to have economic growth, but the means by which we achieve
this should not do so much damage that our children look back in anguish
and question our actions. In the last two centuries economic growth has
been powered by burning fossil fuels with the consequent release of carbon
dioxide. In recent years this release has been increasing rapidly: between
1961 and 2002 humanity’s carbon footprint grew more than 700 per cent
(Kitzes et al., 2007). In the last few decades there has been widespread
concern that observed increases in atmospheric carbon dioxide and global
temperatures are causally linked. Confidence in the general scientific
consensus has reached the point where policy-makers are willing to take
firm action, for example the 10th Session of Working Group I of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) in Paris (February
2007) concluded that:
408
Biodiesel as the potential alternative vehicle fuel 409
States, a major carbon emitter, and big emitters like China and India are
not required to reduce their emissions at present, the policy and practices
within the EU – the largest economic bloc in the world – provide a much-
needed credibility to the Kyoto Protocol and impetus to development of
technological innovations that will allow present generations to have their
energy supply without leaving a drastically altered planet for the future.
Among various measures to cut GHG emissions within the EU, the use
of biofuels derived from agricultural or forestry products is considered
a viable alternative to fossil fuels, especially for the transport sector. As
such, the EU Directive 2003/30/EC set targets for biofuels to be used in
EU transport at 2 per cent by the end of 2005 and 5.75 per cent by the
end of 2010. This directive with other complementary directives, resolu-
tions and legislation on renewable fuels could play a major role in the
EU’s attempts to reduce GHG emissions from the transport sector. This
drive has been further strengthened by the recent announcement about the
minimum efficiency requirements set for vehicle manufacturers that limit
the emissions from the vehicles to be manufactured in the future.1
Substitution of biofuels for fossil fuels also helps to fulfil other policy
objectives. First, the world’s main oil reserves are located in geopoliti-
cally sensitive areas. Climate change notwithstanding, this is perhaps the
main incentive for switching from oil to a more costly fuel supply. The
economic rise of countries such as China and India mean that there
are major players in the global quest for natural resources that are not
necessarily inside the traditional European sphere of political influence.
Environmental considerations are thus in line with the strategic needs of
national security. Second, agricultural subsidies have historically been a
major European expenditure and source of considerable debate within the
Union. Support for growth of biofuel feedstocks could provide a bridge
to resolve differences between the Member States. Third, rapid expansion
of the European Union has led to economic disparities between the new
and old members. The political need for harmonization requires invest-
ment from the rich and markets for the poor. For example, Bulgaria and
Romania, who joined the Union in January 2007, have abundant agricul-
tural land and could potentially become major biofuel suppliers. Fourth,
biofuels open a huge new market for developing countries that have spare
land and cheap labour. Biofuel production could help these countries
meet the Millennium Development Goal of poverty alleviation through
economic growth based on primary production.
These potential multiple benefits of biofuel use make them attractive to
policy-makers, but there have been criticisms too. For example, although
some calculations demonstrate a positive energy balance for biofuel use
(Hill et al., 2006), other work suggests that the GHG footprint of biofuel
410 A handbook of environmental management
in the Member States (for example, The Council of the European Union,
1998; The European Parliament and the Council of the European Union,
2001, 2003). The Council Resolution of 1998 on renewable sources of
energy states:
aims at promoting the use of biofuels or other renewable fuels to replace diesel
or petrol for transport purposes in each Member State, with a view to con-
tributing to objectives such as meeting climate change commitments, environ-
mentally friendly security of supply and promoting renewable energy sources.
(Article 1, Directive 2003/30/EC)
commitments as set out in the Kyoto Protocol. The directive lists ten
products it classifies as biofuels, including biodiesel and bioethanol – the
biofuels that are already available and used in significant proportions
around the world. In Article 3, this directive also sets minimum targets for
all the Member States, and encourages them to set their own ‘indicative
targets’.2
Furthermore, the directive provides flexibility as to how the biofuels for
transport are made available in the market, allowing for the supply of pure
biofuels (biodiesel and bioethanol) or blended with fossil fuels. Where the
biofuels are supplied as blends, the directive requires specific labelling of
such fuels only when the quantity of biofuels in such blends exceed 5 per
cent (Directive 2003/30/EC, OJ L 123, p. 45). Finally, the directive sets out
the guidelines for reporting the annual progress in meeting the set targets
by the Member States, before 1 July each year. The directive stated that
the Commission would draw up an evaluation report on the progress
made in the first phase by 31 December 2006, adding that:
If this [evaluative] report concludes that the indicative targets are not likely to
be achieved for reasons that are unjustified and/or do not relate to new scien-
tific evidence, these proposals shall address national targets, including possible
mandatory targets, in the appropriate form. (Directive 2003/30/EC, OJ L 123,
p. 46)
So, although the targets set by the directive were non-binding and more
as guidelines, if the Member States were not doing enough to promote
the use of biofuels in transport during the first phase as set out by the
directive, without justifiable reasons, the directive clearly stated that the
Commission could make the targets mandatory in the second phase.
Indeed, despite a relatively low minimum target set by the directive for the
first phase, it is now clear that the 2 per cent target for the minimum pro-
portion of biofuels and other renewable fuels that should have been placed
on the markets of the EC Member States by the end of 2005 has not been
met by the Member States except for Germany and Sweden (European
Commission, 2006, 2007b). According to the 2006 progress report, the
share of biofuels in the transport market for the 21 Member States where
biofuels are in use was only 1 per cent by the end of 2005. Although this
1 per cent market share is ‘a good rate of progress – a doubling in two
years’ according to the 2006 progress report, it is only half the target set
by Directive 2003/30/EC, and less than the 1.4 per cent share that would
have been achieved if all the Member States had met their annual indica-
tive targets (European Commission, 2007b, p. 6). Furthermore, both the
progress among the Member States and the rate of adoption of biofuels
seemed very uneven – with only Germany (3.8 per cent) and Sweden (2.2
Biodiesel as the potential alternative vehicle fuel 413
per cent) exceeding the 2 per cent target. In terms of adoption of biofuels,
biodiesel was significantly ahead of ethanol – with biodiesel achieving a 1.6
per cent share of the diesel market, whereas ethanol achieved only a 0.4 per
cent share of the petrol market (European Commission, 2007b, p. 6).
The main policy instrument to facilitate meeting this target was the
EU Directive 2003/96/EC (The Council of the European Union, 2003)
on energy products taxation, which allowed Member States to reduce, or
apply total or partial exemption in the level of taxation to fuels from renew-
able sources. Moreover, schemes like Energy Crop Payments – a premium
payment of €45/ha for growing energy crops under the 2003 Common
Agricultural Policy (CAP) reform – and allowing energy crops to be grown
on set-aside land, were thought to encourage farmers in producing energy
crops to meet the demand for biofuel feedstocks. In addition, increasing
prices of fossil fuel and insecurity of supply, particularly in the past two
to three years, either due to natural disasters like Hurricane Katrina or
due to conflicts in the Middle East and elsewhere (such as the supply dis-
putes between Russia and Ukraine or Russia and Georgia), should have
provided further incentives, in theory, to invest in, produce and promote
biofuels in the Member States. Even with these biofuel-favourable poli-
cies, and geopolitical conditions, the share of biofuels on the transport fuel
market has been negligible in most of the Member States.
The next milestone in the EU Directive 2003/30/EC on promotion of
the use of biofuels or other renewable fuels for transport is the target of
5.75 per cent – the proportion of biofuels and other renewable fuels that
should be placed on the transport fuel market by the end of the year 2010.
As in the first phase, most of the Member States have set their own annual
indicative targets for the second phase in the promotion of biofuels in the
transport fuel market. The indicative targets set by the 19 Member States,
if achieved, will increase the share of biofuels in the transport market to
5.45 per cent by 2010, slightly less than the 5.75 per cent target. However,
the 2006 progress report concludes, judging by the progress made by a
majority of the Member States during the first phase of biofuels promo-
tion in their transport fuel markets, that ‘the biofuels directive’s target [of
5.75 per cent] for 2010 is not likely to be achieved’ (European Commission,
2007b, p. 6).
Although a number of the EU Member States have put in place ‘biofuel
obligations’,3 the 2006 biofuels progress report calls for legislative meas-
ures to support the promotion of biofuels in transport in the EU, arguing
that such a legislative measure will ‘send a signal of the [European] Union’s
determination to reduce its dependence on oil use in transport’ (European
Commission, 2007b, p. 14). The report further argues that the legislative
framework in favour of biofuels will
414 A handbook of environmental management
give support to national, regional and local authorities working towards the
objective of reducing dependence on oil use in transport; give confidence to
companies, investors and scientists who are working on more efficient ways
to do this; and give pause to those who believe that European consumers will
always remain hostage to oil prices, whatever the price. (European Commission,
2007b, p. 7)
feedstocks required to produce the biofuels to meet this target unless food-
crops are replaced by biofuel crops.4 For example, the United Kingdom
could produce enough feedstocks to meet the 2 per cent target by cultivat-
ing oilseed crops in less that 1 million hectares of arable farmland, which
could be available by using part of the set-asides, part of grasslands under
five years old (which are considered arable land) and without replacing
a significant proportion of the food-crops. However, to produce enough
feedstocks to meet the target of 5.75 per cent, the United Kingdom will
require around 2 million hectares of arable farmland, which in a country
with total arable land of just 5.8 million hectares5 (of which about 1.2
million hectares is grassland under five years old), is not feasible without
significantly altering the production of food-crops and the agricultural
landscape. The area of the set-asides is only about 0.5 million hectares, so
using part of this land will not contribute a significant proportion of the
total land required to produce the feedstocks. Thus, the only alternative
would be to import the biofuels and/or biofuel feedstocks from countries
outside the EU – mainly from countries like Indonesia and Malaysia (for
biodiesel) and Brazil (for bioethanol).
The EU Strategy for Biofuels (European Commission, 2006), and the
Biomass Action Plan (European Commission, 2005) call for ‘supporting
developing countries’ to develop internal and export markets for biofuels,
making sure minimum sustainability standards are met in their cultiva-
tion. The potential environmental and socioeconomic impacts from the
cultivation of biofuel feedstocks and the production (and consumption)
of biofuels are similar in the developing countries to in the EU. However,
increasing demand for biofuels from the EU and other developed coun-
tries is expected to not only provide opportunities for developing countries
to benefit from their production and export, but also to generate nega-
tive environmental and socioeconomic consequences, especially where
there are few laws in place to ensure sustainable production of biofuels.
Although the biofuels progress report refutes the claim that Europe’s
biodiesel consumption has caused tropical deforestation in palm-oil-
producing countries such as Malaysia and Indonesia, and suggests that the
global palm oil demand is mainly driven by the food market (European
Commission, 2007b), the increasing use and demand for such oils, not only
for foods but for biofuels in the West as well as in fast-growing economies
like China and India, is likely to be responsible for tropical deforestation
both in the Brazilian Amazon and in Indonesia (Casson, 2003; Monbiot,
2004, 2005; Mortished, 2006b). Hence, even if the EU restricts its import
of biofuels and biofuel feedstocks to those produced meeting its sustain-
ability criteria, other large-scale importers such as China may not apply
similar restrictions. Unless the countries producing biofuels have in place
416 A handbook of environmental management
Finally, the biofuels progress report is also in line with a broader policy
document from the EU – the Renewable Energy Road Map (European
Commission, 2007a). Like the biofuels progress report, the Renewable
Energy Road Map also calls for revision to existing voluntary targets for
use of biofuels in the EU, proposing instead a ‘mandatory (legally binding)
target of 20% for renewable energy’s share of energy consumption in the
EU by 2020’, along with the proposal for necessary legislative frameworks
to make sure such targets are met (p. 3). Like most other documents from
the EU relating to use of renewable energy, the Renewable Energy Road
Map is inherently optimistic: ‘The challenge [that is, meeting renewable
energy targets] is huge, but the proposed target can be achieved with
determined and concerted efforts at all levels of government assuming
the energy industry plays its full part in the undertaking’ (European
Commission, 2007a, p. 3).
This document also sees biofuels as the ‘only available large-scale sub-
stitute’ for transport fuels, recognizing barriers in trade as one of the key
factors that could hinder the EU Member States in meeting their biofuels
target, especially if they are dependent on biofuels imports from outside
the EU (European Commission, 2007a, p. 7). Furthermore, the document
is keen to stress the need to take an incentive-based approach, such as cer-
tification schemes with preferential trade agreements for biofuels, when it
comes to importing biofuels from developing countries, in order to ‘avoid
rain forest destruction’ and other forms of losses in biodiversity.
Mortimer et al., 2003; Puppan, 2002; Booth et al., 2005; Bozbas, 2005).
Individual studies differ in many respects however, making it difficult to
generalize all aspects of environmental impacts of biodiesel. Using life-
cycle assessment of RME (rapeseed methyl ester) and conventional diesel,
Franke and Reinhardt (1998) present a comparative overview of the
environmental impacts of both these diesel fuels. Of the six environmental
impacts considered, three are shown to favour RME and the remaining
three to favour fossil fuel diesel. Although RME could have a potentially
lower greenhouse effect (CO2 equivalents), low eco and human toxicity
(NOx) and lower resource demand (finite energy), it is shown to have a
significant ozone depletion potential due to nitrous oxide (N2O) emissions.
Furthermore, potential eutrophication and acidification from the use of
fertilizers, pesticides and herbicides in rapeseed production adds to the
potential negative environmental impacts of biodiesel.
Franke and Reinhardt (1998) is one of the few studies that can be termed
‘complete’ life-cycle assessment in that they cover almost all aspects of the
life cycle of the products in question for both RME and conventional
diesel. As such, the results from the study also seem very balanced with
regard to which fuel is more ecologically sound. Nevertheless, the authors
conclude – ‘under certain assumptions, RME has or can have an “overall”
ecological advantage against diesel oil’ (Franke and Reinhardt, 1998,
p. 1032).
The carbon balance and ecological footprint of ethanol as a fuel were
analysed by Dias de Oliveira et al. (2005) for the examples of Brazil and
the United States. Controversially they conclude that using ethanol as a
substitute for petroleum is not environmentally sustainable when emis-
sions from agricultural inputs (in the case of sugarcane) and conversion (in
the case of maize) are taken into account. In contrast, a study on ethanol
from maize and biodiesel from soybeans showed that ethanol yields 25 per
cent more energy than that invested in its production and biodiesel yields
93 per cent more (Hill et al., 2006). The situation is further complicated by
the use of nitrogen fertilizers in biofuel production because N2O release
from fertilizer application significantly contributes towards GHG emis-
sions (Crutzen et al., 2007), though if nitrogen demand is reduced by using
second generation biofuel feedstocks such as grasses and woody coppice,
this problem is alleviated.
One of the major environmental impacts from the burning of fossil fuel
diesel comes from the emission of sulphur. Biodiesel, on the contrary, pro-
duces virtually zero sulphur emissions, making it much cleaner compared
with fossil fuel diesel (Puppan, 2002; Bozbas, 2005). With biodiesel, there
is also a significant reduction in other emissions, such as carbon monoxide,
hydrocarbons and soot (Puppan, 2002; Mortimer et al., 2003; Nwafor,
Biodiesel as the potential alternative vehicle fuel 419
2004; Schmidt, 2004). Although NOx emissions from vehicles using bio-
diesel are found to be generally higher than from those using conventional
diesel, studies have shown that this can be reduced by a slight modification
of the diesel engine (Schmidt, 2004; Booth et al., 2005). A major drawback
in using biodiesel compared with conventional diesel seems to be the higher
emission of N2O, both from production processes (that is, from feed-
stock production) and vehicle emissions, which has stratospheric ozone-
depleting potential (Franke and Reinhardt, 1998; Poitrat, 1999). Although
Poitrat (1999) contests this drawback, stating that the overall greenhouse
effect of biodiesel is four or five times less than that of conventional diesel,
Franke and Reinhardt (1998, p. 1037) are more cautious and state that this
drawback actually favours conventional diesel over RME given the ‘high
to very high ecological importance’ of this ozone depletion potential.
Many different studies have come up with different figures as to the
level of emissions and emission reductions for various gases and particu-
late matters when using biodiesel. While Ryan et al. (2006) state that for
biodiesel the CO2 equivalent emissions savings could range from 36 per
cent to 83 per cent compared with conventional diesel, Mortimer et al.
(2003) conclude that savings in total CO2 emissions of 72 per cent to 86 per
cent are possible by using biodiesel derived by conventional and modified
production respectively compared with ultra low sulphur diesel. Similarly,
net energy balance (measured as NER – Net Energy Ratio) for biodiesel
use has been reported to be from between 1.59 and 2.08 (Turley et al.,
2002) through to between 1.9 and 2.7 (Poitrat, 1999).
Feedstocks, comprising mainly oilseed rape and other competitor oils
like soybean, sunflower and palm oil, are the main input in the production
of biodiesel fuel. The production of these feedstocks could have two major
environmental impacts, namely an impact on land use and an impact on
biodiversity. The general consensus in terms of the potential impacts of
biodiesel feedstock production on the environment is that there would be
little or no negative impact if the feedstock were grown on existing agri-
cultural land (Anderson et al., 2004). However, Puppan (2002) warns of
dangers to the environment from large monoculture oilseed farms, as well
as land and water pollution from excess use of fertilizers and pesticides
in commercial oilseed plantations. In terms of the impact of biodiesel
feedstock production on biodiversity, Anderson et al. (2004) argue that
production of oilseed rape could have a positive impact on biodiversity,
especially for farmland bird species that feed on seeds and invertebrate
(that is insect) species within the crop. However, they warn against using
large areas of set-aside land for oilseed production, as that could have
negative impacts on the birds inhabiting such land (Anderson et al., 2004;
Anderson and Ferguson, 2006).
420 A handbook of environmental management
biodiesel could be reduced by using low cost oils, such as used frying oils
from restaurants and non-edible oils that are usually cheaper than edible
oils (Azam et al., 2005; Barnwal and Sharma, 2005; Demirbas and Balat,
2006).
Although the higher environmental benefits from the use of biodiesel
could justify a higher cost (price), for the majority of the customers it
is the price they pay that matters. Thus, unless the price of biodiesel is
competitive with that of fossil fuel diesel, it is unlikely that the average
consumer will look into using biodiesel instead of diesel. Environmentally
aware ‘green consumers’ may be willing to pay a higher price for biodiesel,
but their use will be negligible in comparison with the use of diesel by the
majority of other consumers. Provision of government subsidies could
lower the price of biodiesel and increase its adoption in the short run,
but subsidies are not a long-term solution. Thus, the only way to increase
adoption of biodiesel by an average consumer in the long run would be to
make it competitive with fossil fuel diesel in terms of price.
biofuels are usually higher, thereby making them more expensive com-
pared with fossil fuels, which enjoy an economy of scale. However, the
short- and long-term benefits of biofuel use even at a small scale could be
significant with regard to savings in carbon emissions and those of other
greenhouse gases. Moreover, competition for land use to grow feedstocks
for biofuels on a small scale is minimal, which means it is less likely that
the problems related to land use and land degradation will be significant at
this level of biofuels production and use.
In large-scale production and use of biofuels the savings on carbon
emissions will certainly be significantly higher, especially when production
does not involve intensive use of fossil fuels. Moreover, greater production
and use of the biofuels is likely to reduce their production costs, and hence
their market price, encouraging even more use of such fuels as substitutes
for fossil fuel. However, there is a growing concern that this large-scale
production of biofuels would encourage extensive land conversion to
produce feedstocks, such as soybean, corn, rapeseed and sugarcane, espe-
cially in the tropics. If this is the case then benefits of reduced greenhouse
emission from such fuels are easily cancelled out by tropical deforestation
and biodiversity loss resulting from land conversion to provide feedstocks
for biofuel production. In this case, biofuels, instead of being an environ-
mentally friendly alternative to the fossil fuels, could become an environ-
mentally harmful source of energy. This means they might not be able to
provide double benefits as they are currently promoted as being able to do,
at present and in the future.
Conclusion
Growing demands for fuel, uncertainty and conflicts surrounding fossil
fuels, and increasing concern for the environment from the use of fossil
fuels have inevitably led to the search for alternatives to fossil fuels, espe-
cially renewable sources of fuels. Biofuels have been considered one of the
best alternatives to fossil fuels for the transport sector. The use of biofuels
in transport has been growing worldwide with bioethanol and biodiesel
leading the way. Although the price of biofuels is generally higher than
fossil fuels at this stage of biofuel production and use, incentives provided
by governments, such as subsidies, have helped promote the growing
use of biofuels. Favourable policies are in place, especially in the EU, to
promote use of biofuels as transport fuels. Despite the Council directive
on the use of biofuels in transport, which sets the target for the Member
States to ensure a minimum supply of biofuels in their transport fuel
market up to 2010, and favourable policies to go with the directive, the
target set by the directive has not been met and according to the Council’s
own progress report, the target set for 2010 is not likely to be met either.
426 A handbook of environmental management
This shows that legally non-binding targets, such as the biofuels targets,
will be difficult to meet despite favourable policies and economic incen-
tives – the reason why the Council’s biofuels progress report calls for a
legislative framework to make such targets legally binding (European
Commission, 2007b). Furthermore, the EU is proposing legislation
to force vehicle manufacturers to make technological improvement in
vehicles to reduce emissions.8
There is clear evidence of environmental benefits from using biofuels
generally, and biodiesel particularly, when reductions in greenhouse gas
emissions by vehicles running on biodiesel are considered. However, the
benefits are not so clear-cut when the environmental impacts of biofuels
production are accounted for, especially production of biofuel feedstocks
such as palm, soybean, rapeseed, sugarcane and corn – mainly in the
tropics. In its policy documents, such as the Biomass Action Plan, and
the Strategy for Biofuels, the EU sets out policies for promoting biofuels
production in developing countries, setting guidelines for ‘sustainable
production’ and supply of such fuels, and appropriate incentives, such
as guaranteed investments, for such ‘good practices’. However, it is not
guaranteed that producer countries will follow the EU guidelines, when
they are faced with growing demands for fuels from the rapidly indus-
trializing countries such as China and India. Indeed, lack of stringent
environmental policies and/or lack of enforcement of environmental
policies in place has been blamed for the growing loss of tropical rain-
forest in Malaysia and Indonesia to make way for palm oil plantations.
Recent years have seen a massive growth in such plantations mainly
to meet the demands for oil, so far mainly for the food industry, from
China. However, countries like China will have to rely more and more on
alternative fuel sources in the future to meet their insatiable demand for
energy, which would mean more pressure on the production of biofuels
among other sources of energy. This will no doubt increase pressure on
land use, especially in the tropics where most of the biofuels feedstocks
come from.
Certification schemes, which will guarantee that the biofuels produced
in any country, especially in the developing countries, are produced in an
environmentally sustainable way, are seen as a possible solution to concern
about potential tropical deforestation and habitat destruction during the
production of such fuels (European Commission, 2005). Restrictions on
the imports of biofuels and biofuel feedstocks to the EU based on such
certification schemes could encourage producers to produce biofuels in an
environmentally sustainable way; however, implementing such a scheme
is not without problems. International trade agreements and WTO rules
require that such certification schemes be non-discriminatory between
Biodiesel as the potential alternative vehicle fuel 427
Notes
1. http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/europe/6334327.stm, accessed 31 August 2009.
2. 1. (a) Member States should ensure that a minimum proportion of biofuels and
other renewable fuels is placed on their markets, and, to that effect, shall set
national indicative targets.
(b) (i) A reference value for these targets shall be 2%, calculated on the basis of
energy content, of all petrol and diesel for transport purposes placed on
their markets by 31 December 2005.
(ii) A reference value for these targets shall be 5.75%, calculated on the basis
of energy content, of all petrol and diesel for transport purposes placed
on their markets by 31 December 2010.
(Article 3, Directive 2003/30/EC, OJ L 123, pp. 44–5)
3. A measure that requires the oil suppliers to put a certain percentage of biofuels in the fuel
they supply to the market.
4. It is estimated that 17 million hectares of arable land will be needed to produce biofuels
to meet this target completely from the domestic production. Given the total arable land
in the EU of 97 million hectares, meeting the biofuels target set for 2010 entirely from the
EU domestic production is thought to be ‘technologically feasible in principle’. However,
due to WTO regulations and other trade agreements, the EU cannot block the import of
(potentially cheaper) biofuels and biofuel feedstocks (mainly from developing countries).
‘Therefore, the scenario of 100% domestic production is a theoretical one and would not
be possible in practice’ (European Commission, 2005).
5 http://statistics.defra.gov.uk/esg/quick/agri.asp, accessed 31 August 2009.
6. Net energy balance is the difference between energy in the biofuels and the energy
equivalence of fossil fuel inputs used in producing, harvesting and processing the fuel.
Net energy balance is usually calculated as a ratio – called Net Energy Ratio (NER) – of
biofuel energy to the fossil fuel energy used in production of the biofuel. NER greater
than 1 shows a ‘positive’ net energy balance, which indicates that the biofuel generates
more energy than that used to produce it.
7. http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/south_asia/4988018.stm, accessed 31 August 2009.
8. http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/europe/6334327.stm, accessed 31 August 2009.
References
Anderson, G.Q.A. and M.J. Ferguson (2006), ‘Energy from biomass in the UK: sources,
processes and biodiversity implications’, Ibis, 148(1), 180–83.
Anderson, G.Q.A., L.R. Haskins and S.H. Nelson (2004), ‘The effects of bioenergy crops
on farmland birds in the UK: a review of current knowledge and future predictions’,
in K. Parris and T. Poincet (eds), Biomass and Agriculture: Sustainability, Markets and
Policies, Paris: OECD.
Azam, M.M., A. Waris and N.M. Nahar (2005), ‘Prospects and potential of fatty acid
methyl esters of some non-traditional seed oils for use as biodiesel in India’, Biomass and
Bioenergy, 29(4), 293–302.
Barnwal, B.K. and M.P. Sharma (2005), ‘Prospects of biodiesel production from vegetable
oils in India’, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 9(4), 363–78.
Booth, E., J. Booth, P. Cook, B. Ferguson and K. Walker (2005), Economic Evaluation of
Biodiesel Production from Oilseed Rape Grown in North and East Scotland, report prepared
by SAC Consultancy Division.
Bozbas, K. (2005), ‘Biodiesel as an alternative motor fuel: production and policies in the
European Union’, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 12(2), 542–62.
Casson, A. (2003), Oil Palm, Soybeans & Critical Habitat Loss: A Review Prepared for the
WWF Forest Conservation Initiative, Zurich, Switzerland: WWF Forest Conservation
Initiative.
Crutzen, P.J., A.R. Mosier, K.A. Smith and W. Winiwarter (2007), ‘N2O release from
Biodiesel as the potential alternative vehicle fuel 429
431
432 A handbook of environmental management
Offshore Protocol 223, 225 biodiversity hotspots 9, 10, 16, 18, 410
Prevention and Emergency Protocol biofuels
222, 223–4 benefits and costs of 7, 409–10, 416,
SPA (Specially Protected Areas) and 417–22, 424, 426
Biodiversity Protocol 222, 225 certification schemes for 426–7
Bardhan, P. 119, 150, 152, 153, 155, EU renewable fuels policy and 7,
157, 158, 161, 311, 313, 314 409, 410–17, 425–7
bargaining costs 135, 138, 146, 148, potential to provide double benefits
149, 401 422–5, 427
Barnes, D.K.A. 245, 269 price of 421–2, 424–5
Barnett, H. 401 products classified as 412
Barnwal, B.K. 421, 422 biogeographic spatial units 13–14
Barreto, P. 331 biological diversity, definition of 76
Barrett, C.B. 31 biological oxygen demand (BOD) 368,
Barrett, S. 214, 383–4 384, 387, 389, 390
barter 259, 279 Biomass Action Plan 415, 416, 426
Barzel, Y. 121 bird species
Bateman, I. 101 biofuel feedstock production and
Baumann, O. 300 419
Bazaruto Archipelago marine conservation of 9, 10, 12, 14, 17, 18,
protected area 271 20, 22–3, 35, 56, 62, 63, 83, 87,
beavers 78 88, 92, 102, 104
Beckerman, W. 359, 360, 361 bird watching 98
beech (Fagus silvatica) 89–90 BirdLife International 23, 59, 60, 69
Begon, M. 296 Birkeland, C. 241
Behnke, R.H. 296, 297, 299 Birner, R. 136, 137, 140, 141, 142, 143,
Beira 271 144, 145, 146, 147
Belgium 394, 397 Bishop, R.C. 102, 107, 126, 131, 132
Bell, F.W. 102 black list 222, 223
Bembridge, J. 331 Black Sea 221
Benham, A. 140 blackcap (Sylvia atricapilla) 78
Benson, J.F. 100, 105 blacktip mojarra fish (Gerres oyena)
bequest value 99 247
Berkes, F. 126, 132, 143 Blench, R. 287
Bernauer, T. 206 Blomley, T. 31
Betula 88 Blomquist, W. 150
Bevir, M. 172 Blue Plan 217, 230, 231
Bhatia, A. 158 Blue Plan Regional Activity Centre
Bhatia, Z. 48, 52 (BP/RAC) 228, 230
Bhattarai, M. 365, 381 Bokdam, J. 84
Biermann, F. 203 Booth, E. 418, 419
Binmore, K. 310 Borchert, M.I. 87
biodiversity conservation in managed Borrini-Feyerabend, G. 30
landscapes see managed Bosnia and Herzegovina 221
landscapes, biodiversity Bosphorus 221
conservation in Botswana 97
biodiversity conservation priorities, Boulding, K.R. 176
global see global biodiversity bounded rationality 135
conservation priorities Bourn, D. 287
biodiversity conservation treaties 199 Bowes, M. 100
434 A handbook of environmental management
endangered species 102, 136, 137, 179, epistemic communities 5, 203, 205,
185 220, 231–2, 233, 235
endemic bird areas 9, 10, 12, 14, 18 equal-area grids 13
endowment 369, 377 equilibrium theory, ecological
ENERDATA database 380 paradigms based on 5, 296–8,
energy consumption 372, 385–6, 400, 302–3
410 policy discourse associated with 6,
see also net energy balance 299–300, 301, 303, 304
Energy Crop Payments 413 equity
enforcement costs 136, 138, 142, 145, development projects and 65
146, 149, 150 distinction between economic
England 88 efficiency and 95
environment and society institutions and 119, 137, 145–6,
ecological and social paradigms and 149, 152, 153, 157–8, 161
5–6, 295–304 non-equilibrium theory and 301
reciprocal relationship between see also income and wealth
283–95, 303–4 inequality
environmental effectiveness 206, 208, Er, K.B.H. 13
233, 234, 235 Erdelen, M. 92
Environmental Impact Assessment Erwin, T.L. 21
(EIA) 221, 223, 225 Espelta, J.S. 87
environmental Kuznets curve 6, 360, ethanol 412, 413, 414, 415, 416, 418,
362 425
basic studies of 367–76 Ethiopia 291
decomposition analysis and 378, EU Directive 2003/30/EC 409, 411–12,
388–9, 396–9 416, 425
ecological thresholds and 399–403 EU Directive 2003/96/EC 413
household preferences and 391–4 EU Strategy for Biofuels 415, 416, 426
international trade and 367–8, 375, European Commission 411, 412,
384–8, 398, 400 413–14, 415, 416, 417, 423–4, 426,
policies and political institutions and 427, 428
369, 376–84, 399, 402 European Convention on Long-range
population density and 370, 371, Transboundary Air Pollution
377, 381, 388–91 (LRTAP) 211
technology shifts and 369–70, 385, European Habitats Directive 83
394–5 European Parliament 411
environmental price 402 European Union
Environmental Protection Act Common Agricultural Policy (CAP)
(Queensland, 1994) 180 97, 106, 413
environmental protection agencies funding for ICDPs 48, 69
(EPAs) 375 participation in agri-environmental
see also Queensland Environmental programmes in 148
Protection Agency (EPA); participation in Mediterranean
US Environmental Protection Action Plan 217, 221, 231
Agency policy on biofuels 7, 409, 410–17,
Environmentally Sensitive Area (ESA) 425–7
scheme 105–6 potential for double benefits from
EPA (Queensland Environmental biofuel use 422–5, 427
Protection Agency) 178, 179–80 evening grosbeak (Hesperiphona
EPA AIRS database 393 vespertina) 104
440 A handbook of environmental management