01chapters1 2 PDF
01chapters1 2 PDF
01chapters1 2 PDF
Introduction
1.1 Background
1.2 Problem statement and objectives
1.3 Research methodology
1.4 Delimitation and limitations of research
1.4.1 Delimitation
1.4.2 Limitations of study
1.5 Itinerary
1.1 Background
The 1960s was an epochal phase in the political history of Africa. Emerging
from the throes of colonialism and oppression, independence elites set out to
show the world that Africa was capable of giant strides. Such optimism was
fuelled by the economic boom of the 1940s to the 1960s - the consequence of a
steep increase in the prices of commodities such as cocoa, coffee and mineral
resources.1 Compared to Asian economies, African countries in the 1960s
showed better prospects and potential.2 In addition to this, many of the African
leaders who took over the reign of government from the colonialists had
received western education and as such were considered intellectually capable
of steering the administration of their countries.3 True to expectations,
ideologues such as Kwame Nkrumah and Julius Nyerere came up with
blueprints aimed at re-enacting a romantic pre-colonial African society, devoid
of socio-economic inequalities.
However, underlining this optimism were a number of stark realities. The Berlin
Conference of 1884/85 made Africa the most fragmented continent in the world.
1
Meredith M, The state of Africa: A history of fifty years of independence. Johannesburg: Jonathan Ball
Publishers (2005) 142.
2
See e.g. Roemer M, ‘Could Asian policies propel Africa’s growth?’ Available at
http://www.cid.harvard.edu/hiid/543.pdf (Accessed 10 November 2009).
3
See e.g. Dowden R, Africa: Altered states, ordinary miracles. London: Portobello Books (2008) 66-68.
1
A number of post-colonial African countries were landlocked, had small
populations and were not economically viable.4 The nature of colonial
administration in Africa contributed a great deal to the disarticulated economies
and underdevelopment of most post-colonial African states. As Ake remarks,
unlike colonial experiences in the Americas, Europe and Asia, colonialism in
Africa was ‘statist’.5 Ake employs the term ‘statist’ to describe the arbitrary
colonial governance framework, which ensured the redistribution of land, forced
labour, restriction of economic activities by Africans and the suppression of
dissensions.6 Infrastructure was developed not as a means of improving the
lives of the people but simply as of a way of facilitating the collection and
distribution of commodities.7 Thus, the task of newly independent African states
was the restructuring the colonial economic structures into a viable machinery
of growth and development.
It was against this backdrop that the idea of regional integration was elevated to
a topical discourse. Together with domestic policies, regional integration was
seen as a tool for enhancing unity and meaningful socio-economic
advancement. According to post-independence elites like Nkrumah, regional
integration was the panacea for underdevelopment and prevention of
hegemonic threats.8 As such, the establishment of regional organisations was
regarded as utmost priority. Apart from pan-Africanism,9 another factor which
significantly influenced regional integration was the post-1945 worldwide
proliferation of regional integration initiatives. The integration efforts in Europe
4
African states, according to Agyeman, are ‘plagued by the deficiency trilogy of smallness, unnaturalness
and illegitimacy’. Agyemen O, Pan Africanist - federalism, Center for Economic Research on Africa,
Montclair University, New Jersey (1990) 6. Available at
http://www.alpha.montclair.edu/~lebelp/CERAFRM035Agyeman1991.pdf (Accessed 20 March 2008).
5
See Ake C, Democracy and development in Africa. Washington DC: The Brookings Institution (1996) 1-
2.
6
Ibid, 2-3; see also Ake C, A political economy of Africa. New York: Longman (1981).
7
Ake (1996) 2; Ake (1981) 44-45.
8
See generally, Nkrumah K, Africa must unite. New York: Praeger (1963).
9
As will be discussed in subsequent chapters, pan-Africanism is an ideal that encapsulates both the racial
and geographical oneness of Africans.
2
and the successful federal arrangement in the United States of America
provided a reference framework for proponents of a United States of Africa.10
10
See e.g. Nkrumah (1963); see also e.g. Asante S, Regionalism and Africa’s development. London:
Macmillan (1997) 2-3.
11
See e.g. Asante S, African development: Adebayo Adedeji’s alternative strategies. London: Hans Zell
Publishers (1991) 94.
12
Ibid, 96.
13
Other political concerns of the OAU were the fight against apartheid, resolution of conflicts and the
protection of refugees.
3
framework for the protection of human rights.14 The African Charter on Human
and Peoples’ Rights (ACHPR) was eventually adopted in 1981.
The disappointing record of human rights violations since the adoption of the
ACHPR indicates the little regard attached to the consideration of democratic
norms as an indispensable component of regional integration in Africa. The
inability to entrench good governance and democratic norms is better
understood within the peculiar trajectory of political development in post-colonial
Africa. Post-colonial Africa is in a number of ways, an embodiment of
contradictions and ironies. Having made a substantial sacrifice in eliminating
colonialism and actualising basic human rights, the euphoria of independence
quickly dissolved into a rather traumatic experience. Post-independence leaders
adopted arbitrary laws reminiscent of the colonial era, which they had previously
criticised, in suppressing all forms of dissent and consolidating their new earned
powers.15 Instead of improving the lives of the citizenry, coercive policies were
put in place to ensure utmost conformity and obedience. Like a contagion,
military coups, corruption and one-party system became the norm. The promise
of show-casing how traditional African values can influence governance and
economic development gradually derailed amidst the rampant assault on
fundamental norms and values.16
Unlike the situation in parts of Asia, where the centralisation of power was also
used in enhancing economic development, African leaders’ obsession with
power resulted in the absence of concerted and meaningful development
policies.17 Although development was a dominant theme in the speeches of
African leaders, Ake views this more as a strategy of consolidating power than a
14
Ouguergouz F, The African Charter on Human and Peoples’ Rights: A comprehensive agenda for human
dignity and sustainable development in Africa. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff (2003) 36-40.
15
Ake (1996) 3.
16
As noted above, ideology-driven post-colonial elites such as Nyerere and Kenyatta designed policies aimed at
providing governance with a distinct, Afro-centric feel. These include Ujamaa in Tanzania and Harambee in Kenya.
17
Ake (1996) 7. Also the transfer of powers to regional institutions was inconceivable as this would result
in the diminution of their territorial influence.
4
framework for economic transformation.18 Underdevelopment and good
governance deficit further exposed African countries to internal conflicts and
acts of destabilisation.
18
African leaders narrowly construed development as a project that would require utmost obedience and
conformity. To them, political opposition was an unnecessary distraction and impediment to the attainment
of effective and sustainable development. As such, the suppression of dissensions was a necessary
component of the march towards developmental state. See Ibid, 9.
5
the existence of strong national institutions, a position which is absent in Africa,
then the state of integration in Africa requires utmost reconsideration. As such,
the task should be centred on re-evaluating the position of the present state of
regional institutions so that they not only embody ideals of democracy but also
become a major driver of entrenching fundamental values across the continent.
The foregoing exposition thus raises some fundamental questions. The first
challenges the seriousness of regional integration in Africa.19 In light of the
deficiency of political will among member states to create the necessary
operational environment at both the national and regional spheres, for the
success of regional integration, it needs to be asked whether there is a
conscious effort by the political elites to realise qualitative integration.
Conscious effort should, however, not be confused with grand speeches or
dictatorial zeal to impose a United States of Africa. This is because such calls
are made against the backdrop of debilitating factors such as the absence of
good governance, weak economic structures and dysfunctional institutional
frameworks. In this sense, there needs to be a nexus between democratic
ideals and the attempts at instituting integration initiatives.
19
See e.g. Udombana J, ‘A harmony or a cacophony? The music of integration in the African Union treaty
and the New Partnership for Africa’s Development’. Indiana International and Comparative Law Review.
13 (2002), 202.
6
This leads to the second question, namely whether a new path should be
carved for the realisation of a qualitative and viable integration process. Simply
put, is there a need for a paradigm shift in the conceptualisation of African
integration, from a narrowly construed idea to one which adopts democratic
norms as an indispensable prerequisite? In order to answer these questions,
one needs to consider salient issues such as:
7
1.2 Problem statement and objectives
The core problem which this study intends to investigate is two-fold: a) whether
a supranational AU20 is feasible and b) if this is possible, what should the nature
of its institutional framework be?
20
A supranational AU, as will be discussed later, envisages an organisation that is autonomous from its
member states through its capacity to issue binding directives to its member states.
8
community participation in matters which affect the common good, and
universal standards provide the democratic framework for deepening regional
integration and unity? The success of European supranationalism is instructive
as it presents the nexus between commitment to democratic ideals and the
proper articulation and implementation of supranational policies. The twin
sanctity of democratic institutions in member states and the autonomy of the
European Union (EU) are at the core of the (supranational) institutional
development of the EU. If any lesson needs to be drawn from the European
experience, it is essentially the imperative of infusing and clothing the trajectory
of regional integration with democratic ethos.
The task of this study is, therefore, to examine the politico-legal feasibility of
carving an integration path strictly based on adherence to democratic norms
and values. Against the backdrop of an ingrained philosophy of including all
African states in the integration process, coupled with the prevalent paucity of
good governance, this study seeks to formulate a nuanced methodology of
achieving a democratic supranational AU.
In addition to the desk and library research, field visits were made to the Pan-
African Parliament (PAP) Secretariat and the United Nations Headquarters. The
visit to PAP Secretariat was aimed at collecting relevant documents and
attending a session of the PAP. The PAP session was useful for the
understanding and assessment of the functioning and relevance of the
9
institution. With funding provided by the University of Pretoria, this two months,
June 1 – July 31 2009, were spent at the UN Office of Legal Affairs in New
York. The visit provided an opportunity to gain valuable insight into the
operations of an intergovernmental institution especially the compliance level of
member states and the development of international law.
10
successful integration process. In this sense, adherence to democratic
standards is adopted as a ‘political filter’ for determining the membership of a
supranational AU. The fact that the prevalent ideology of limiting democratic
values to a secondary component of the integration process has not resulted in
any significant improvement, makes this approach an attractive and pertinent
alternative.
The study of regional integration is extensive and covers all facets of human
endeavours. Even within the adopted politico-legal approach of the study, there
is a wide-range of issues which shape the theories and practicalities of the
integration process. This study has, however, been restricted to how democratic
standards can influence supranational institutional development. The motivation
behind this is that the development of a qualitative supranational institution can
provide the requisite impetus for addressing the multiple issues under the
umbrella of integration.
11
In terms of the temporal scope of this study, the cut-off time is 31 December
2009. Regional integration, nay African integration is at an interesting phase,
with changes occurring rapidly. Important events and documents published post
cut-off date, especially impacting on the subject-matter, may render
recommendations made either obsolete or confirmed by subsequent events.
1.5 Itinerary
The introductory chapter sets out the background to the study, identifies the
problem that the study intends to investigate, the adopted methodology and the
limitations of the study.
12
Chapter five builds on the points identified in chapter four by considering how
they can be channelled into the institutional transformation of the AU. It
examines the theories of (supranational) institution building and the different
perspectives on the quest for AU transformation. Furthermore, this chapter
attempts to present a detailed analysis of the institutional design of a future
supranational AU.
13
Chapter 2
A politico-legal observation
2.1 Introduction
exclusive?
of unity
Africa?
2.4 Summary
21
Cited in Covey S, Everyday Greatness. Nashville: Thomas Nelson (2006) 299.
14
2.1 Introduction
The increasing powers and relevance of the EU in global realpolitik has evoked
a special interest in regional integration. Not only has the European experiment
in integration stimulated a significant global trend;22 it has also engendered a
multi-disciplinary focus on its phenomenal evolution into an organisation that
defies the traditional logic of public international law. While the EU remains an
international organisation, it functions like nation-states in respect of some
policies such as monetary, agriculture and trade. It is this distinctive quality that
sets the EU apart from other international organisations and also gives impetus
to the study of regional integration, especially supranationalism.
22
Regional integration has been implemented in other parts of the globe – North America through the
North America Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA); Latin America through the Southern Common Market
(MERCUSOR); Africa through the African Union (AU) and the various Regional Economic Communities
(RECs); South East Asia through the Association of South East Asian Nations (ASEAN); Asia Pacific
through the Asian Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC); and the Caribbean through the Caribbean
Community and Common Market (CARICOM).
15
organisations. Like any other field of human endeavour, the study of regional
integration lends itself to both abstraction and empiricism, either based on
theoretical suppositions or the resultant effect of inter-state cooperation vis-à-vis
granting powers to international organisations. In light of this, the various
manifestations of regional integration will be considered. It starts with an
attempt to define the concept of regional integration, then moves on to discuss
the theories of integration and lastly, considers the relationship between
national sovereignty and regional integration.
16
between states in order to lose the factual attributes of sovereignty, cooperation
describes steps on the way to integration.26 In other words, cooperation
precedes integration and may not necessarily lead to formal integration
between states; it is rather a phase in the process of integration.27
[T]he process whereby political actors in several distinct national settings are
persuaded to shift their loyalties, expectations and political activities toward a
new centre, whose institutions possess or demand jurisdiction over the pre
existing national states. The end result of a process of political integration is a
new political community, super imposed over the pre-existing ones.29
Although Haas sees the end result of the process of integration as ‘a new
political community, superimposed over the pre-existing ones’,30 he equally
notes that the shifting of loyalties does not necessarily imply the repudiation of
national state or government; rather individuals may exercise multiple loyalties
based on the functional advantages to be derived from the ‘new centre’ or
nation states.31 This analysis reinforces the durability of nation states in the face
of changing dynamics of inter-states relations. This is further exemplified by the
26
Haas E, ‘The study of regional integration: Reflections on the joy and anguish of pretheorising’.
International Organisation. 24/4 (1970) 610.
27
Ibid.
28
Hay (1966) 1. Since nation-states remain the dominant participant in international relations, the success
or failure of integration process largely depend on the political will and enthusiasm of nation-states. A case
in point is the relative success of the EU which has been attributed to the willingness, not at all times, of the
member states to relinquish parts of their national sovereignty.
29
Haas E, The uniting of Europe: Political, social and economic forces 1950-1957. Stanford: Stanford
University Press (1958) 16.
30
Ibid, 16.
31
Ibid, 14.
17
assertion that integration is primarily driven by public officials (and also interest
groups) of member states.32
32
Ibid, 17.
33
Hay (1966) 1.
34
Cantori L & Spiegel S, The international politics of regions – A comparative approach. Englewood
Cliffs: New Jersey: Prentice-Hall (1970) 10-11.
35
Venables A, ‘International trade: Regional economic integration’. International Encyclopaedia of Social
and Behavioural Sciences (2000) 1. Available at
http://www.econ.ox.ac.uk/members/tony.venables/regenc2.pdf (Accessed 25 November 2008).
36
Deutsch k, Political community and the north Atlantic area. New York: Greenwood Press (1957) 5
37
Ibid.
38
See e.g. O’Neill M, The politics of European integration. London: Routledge (1996) 10.
18
Integration should however not be seen as a ‘big-bang’ occurrence, rather it
should be understood as a multi-layered process which happens over a length
of time. The length of time over which integration has persisted plays a
significant part in its consolidation.39 The trajectory of integration thus involves
crossing a minimalist threshold of political commitment of political actors to a
maximalist outcome, which entails the creation of a new political union.40 A
‘maximalist outcome’ or termination point of the regional integration process is
not necessarily dependant on the initial objectives of political actors, but on
variable factors influencing every step of the integration process. Therefore, to
view integration as a straight-forward, linear process - excluding the vagaries of
(sub) national political and economic forces - is not only unsound but also
ignores the realities of a state-centric global framework.
39
Deutsch et al (1957) 6.
40
O’Neill (1996) 12
19
policies including common currency.
Source: Economic Commission for Africa, Assessing Regional Integration in Africa. Addis
Ababa: Economic Commission for Africa (2004) 10. [Hereinafter referred to as ECA (2004) ]
Writing on the stages or forms of regional integration, Caproso & Choi note that
‘at best we have a set of labels that may be useful for categorising the path of
members undergoing regional integration, rather than a natural sequence
through which all integrating states must pass’.41 In this sense, member states
may decide to start with a customs union and move right ahead to forming a
political union, without necessarily going through all the stages outlined above.
Ultimately, it is the degree of political will among member states that will
determine the pace of the integration process.
41
See Caproso & Choi in Carlsnaes et al (2002) 483.
20
evolutionary nature of integration and also the consequences of the integration
process on national and international politico-legal framework. It is against this
backdrop that this section will discuss the theories of integration under two
rubrics: legal and political.
42
Weiler J, The Constitution of Europe: Do the new clothes have an emperor? And other essays on
European integration. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (1999) 221.
43
Ibid.
44
Weiler J, ‘The community system: The dual character of supranationalism’. Yearbook of European Law.
1 (1981) 270.
45
Ibid.
46
Hay (1966) 6-8.
21
A key implication of regional integration is what international lawyers refer to as
the ‘internationalisation of constitutional law’ or ‘constitutionalisation of
international law’.47 Although these two concepts have different meanings, they
both have similar results. While the former denotes the emergence of
international parallel constitutions as a result of transfer of functions to regional
institutions, the latter explains the transformation of treaties into domestic-like
constitutions.48 These concepts jointly highlight the growing influence of
international organisations and the possibility (or existence) of an overarching
framework by which domestic constitutions should be measured.49 An
(un)intended consequence of an inter-state arrangement is a regulatory
framework or a semblance of national constitutional mechanism, which more or
less operates on familiar constitutional terminologies.50 In the context of
international organisations, ‘international constitutionalism’ or constitutionalism
provides a framework for uniform actions, attribution of powers and
implementation of shared values.51 (This will be discussed in detail in
subsequent chapters)
47
Cottier T & Hertig M, ‘The prospect of 21st century constitutionalism’. Max Planck Yearbook of United
Nations Law. 7 (2003) 269-70.
48
Ibid, 270-271.
49
See e.g. Werner W, ‘Constitutionalisation, fragmentation, politicisation, the constitutionalisation of
international law as a janus-faced phenomenon’, Griffen’s View. 8/2 (2007)19-22.
50
As Cottier & Hertig highlights, some organisations such as FAO and UNESCO explicitly refer to their
founding treaties as ‘constitutions’ and the European Court of Justice termed EU founding treaties as ‘the
constitutional Charter of a Community based on the rule of law’. See Cottier & Hertig (2003) 277.
51
Werner (2007) 22; Weiler (1999) 221; Cottier & Hertig (2003) 271-272.
52
Dashwood A, Wyatt D, Arnull A & Ross M, European Union law. London: Sweet & Maxwell (2000)
151.
22
states, so it is crucial that legal mechanisms are put in place to safeguard their
national interests.
23
• direct binding effect of law emanating from the organisation on natural
and legal persons
• attribution of powers which differs markedly from powers bestowed on
other organisations
60
Weiler (1981) 271.
61
Ibid, 273-280.
62
Weiler (1981) 271.
63
See Pescatore P, The Law of integration. Leiden: Sijthoff (1974) 51-52.
64
Ibid; see also Weiler (1981) 305.
24
Table 2.2: Differences between supranational and intergovernmental organisations
Source: Adapted from Weiler (1999) 275.
25
b. Political science theories of integration
The political science theories of integration can be classified under two broad
headings: intergovernmentalism and supranationalism. The supranationalist
school of thought questions the logic of nation state, especially after the chaotic
consequences of the two world wars.65 At the core of supranationalist theory is
the assignment of sovereign powers to a neutral, transnational entity, devoid of
the foibles of nation states.66
i) Functionalism
Buoyed by the disastrous aftermath of the Second World War (economic
meltdown and absence of peace), the protagonists of this approach advocated
for the creation of technocratic institutions to handle transnational socio-
economic problems.69 Functionalists display an unyielding belief in the ability of
technocratic institutions to manage transnational human needs, peace and
public welfare.70 As Mitrany highlights, these functional bodies will differ from
traditional international organisations in the sense that they would be ‘executive
agencies with autonomous tasks and powers’.71 This approach presents an
alternative to global governance framework, an attempt to dislocate nation
65
O’Neil (1996) 21.
66
Ibid, 21-23.
67
Ibid, 54-57.
68
Ibid, 56; see also Blokker N & Schermers H, International institutional law: Unity within diversity. The
Hague: Martinus Nijhoff (1995) 40.
69
Mitrany D, The Functional theory of politics. London School of Economics and Political Science (1975)
126; see also Rosamond B, Theories of European integration. London: McMillan (2000) 33.
70
For a detailed analysis of the functionalist theory, see generally, Mitrany D, A working peace system.
Chicago: Quadrangle Books (1966) 25-99.
71
Mitrany (1975) 125.
26
states from matters that border on common (transnational) interests.72
Furthermore, this idea predicts that the efficient performance of responsibilities
by transnational functional agencies would lead to the transfer of loyalty from
nation state to these agencies (attitudinal change).73
Functionalism pessimists argue that this idea ignores the highly political nature
of international relations. Mitrany’s advocacy of detached and unaffiliated
technocratic agencies disregards the state-centric posture of global politics.
According to critics, a project which excluded this reality lacked scientific and
empirical basis.74 They also questioned the functionalist assumption of human
attitudinal change by arguing that this line of thinking falls within the scope of
morality rather than politics.75 The pervasive and deep-rooted attachment to
nationality not only by political actors but individuals essentially rendered the
‘attitudinal change’ theory impractical.
ii) Neo-functionalism
Neo-functionalism was a reaction to the perceived inadequacies of
functionalism. Neo-functionalists regarded integration as a more complex
process than the apolitical method or ‘technocratic automaticity’ prescribed by
functionalism.76 Neo-functionalism, like its theoretical precursor, highlights the
irrelevance of nation states and their inability to maintain peace and security.77
It, however, acknowledged the primacy of nation states and its political elites
(including political parties and interest groups) in the integration process.78
Thus, this established the empirical foundation of neo-functionalism.
27
further economic integration within and beyond such sector.79 The logic behind
spillover is that once nation states agree to place the control of a certain sector
in the hands of a supranational authority, with success in such sector and with
the passage of time, there would be pressures to extend control to other related
policy areas. Supranational institutions rather than nation states are seen as the
drivers of this process.
Moravcsik, however, argued that spillover into related sectors has not being as
consistent as expected.80 He further notes that neo-functionalism fails to offer
an explanation for the domestic dynamics that shapes supranational
decisions.81 Neo-functionalism suffered its greatest setback when the then
French president, Charles de Gaulle, altered the trajectory of European
integration.82 In sharp contrast to the postulations of functionalist theorists, de
Gaulle rejected the European Commission’s (EC) modest attempt to reduce the
powers of nation states within the community.83 In reaction to the growing
influence of the EC, de Gaulle, in 1965, remarked that only existing European
states ‘had the rights to give orders and power to be obeyed’.84 This singular
event exposed the empirical limitations and the rigidities of this approach. It
brought to the fore the influence of nation states in the integration process.
79
This is called ‘functional spillover’. See Rosamond (2000) 60.
80
Moravcsik A, ‘Preferences and power in the European Community: A liberal intergovernmentalist
approach’, Journal of Common Market Studies. 31/4 (1993) 476.
81
Ibid, 477.
82
Ibid, 476.
83
O’Neill (1996) 45.
84
Cited in Agyemen (1990) 19.
85
The term ‘anarchic’ implies that international politics is a system without government or a centralised
authority to forestall the threat of violence and the recurrent use of force. See Waltz K, Theories of
international politics. New York: McGraw-Hill (1979) 88, 102-3.
28
interstate cooperation.86 In the pursuit of national interests (security) and
survival, states collaborate with other states which have comparative military
and economic advantages. To the realists, nation-states remain the principal
actors and the only source of legitimate authority; any attempt to replace the
nation state with supranational institutions is deemed unnatural and
misguided.87
Critics argue that the dynamics of European integration over the years have
rendered (neo) realism obsolete. A case in point is the increasing allocation of
powers to the community institutions. According to critics, this proves that the
86
Rosamond (2000) 132. Huntington, however, argues that different types of states define their interests in
different ways. Such interest may include similarities in cultural values, ideologies and (democratic)
institutions. See Huntington S, The clash of civilization and the remaking of world order. The Free Press
(2002) 34.
87
Ibid; see also Godwin G, ‘The erosion of external sovereignty?’ Government and Opposition. 9/1 (1974)
63-64.
88
Ibid, 132.
89
Waltz (1979) 96-97.
90
Ibid, 97.
91
Ibid, 105; see also Rosamond (2000) 132.
92
Waltz (1979) 105.
93
Ibid.
29
structural attribute of international politics is not necessarily static and
anarchic.94
94
Rosamond (2000) 134.
95
Ibid, 136.
96
Ibid.
97
Ibid.
98
Moravcsik (1993) 481.
99
Ibid.
100
Moravcsik A, ‘Liberal inergovermentalism and integration: A rejoinder’. Journal of Common Market
Studies. 33/4 (1995) 612.
101
Rosamond (2000) 135.
102
Moravcsik (1993) 481.
30
Wincott criticises liberal intergovernmentalism for being an approach rather than
a theory because it fails to state conditions under which it can be empirically
refuted.103 He further argues that liberal intergovermentalism fails to take into
account the influence of day-to-day policy decisions of the community
institutions, rather than that of member states, on the laws of the EU.104
31
clout of non-state actors such as international organisations is indicative of a
paradigm shift in the conceptualisation of sovereignty.
What then is this ‘intoxicant’ which emboldens states to act with impunity within
and outside their territorial entities? As Geldenhuys puts it, ‘sovereignty is the
final sanctuary of the autocrat in contemporary world politics’.106 In the name of
sovereignty, leaders continue to subjugate their citizens, mismanage state
economies and frustrate all forms of meaningful intervention (Zimbabwe,
Myanmar and North Korea spring to mind here).
Contemporary state sovereignty has its roots in the 1648 agreement to end the
discord between feuding European powers.107 The 1648 Treaty of Westphalia,
amongst other provisions, principally laid the foundation for the territorial
integrity of nation states.108 The traditional form of sovereignty can be divided
into two: internal and external sovereignty. Internal sovereignty connotes the
‘exercise of supreme authority by states within their individual territories’109 or
what Bodin described as the exclusive right ‘to give lawes unto all and everie
one of its … subjects and to receive none from them’.110 According to James, a
state’s claim of internal sovereignty is dependent on constitutional
independence.111 Thus, a state under colonial rule cannot lay any claim to
sovereignty because such right lies with the colonial administration. External
sovereignty on the other hand implies the legal independence of a sovereign
state - which can only be limited by international law - from other states.112 It
therefore implies the equality of nation states, regardless of differences in
106
Geldenhuys D, ‘Brothers as keepers: Africa’s new sovereignty regime’, Strategic Review For Southern
Africa. XXVIII/1 (2006) 1.
107
The full text of the ‘Treaty of Westphalia’ is available at
http://www.yale.edu/lawweb/avalon/westphal.htm (Accessed 21 0ctober 2007).
108
Ibid.
109
Goodwin (1974) 61.
110
Ibid.
111
James A, Sovereignty statehood: The basis of international society. London: Allen & Unwin (1986) 24-
25.
112
Kelsen H, ‘The principle of sovereign equality of states as a basis for international organisation’. Yale
Law Journal. 53/2 (1944) 208.
32
capacities, in the international community. The inclusion of the term ‘sovereign
equality’113 in the United Nations Charter further reinforced the sanctity of
statehood in international law.114
113
According to the Friendly Relations Declaration of the United Nations General Assembly, the term
‘sovereign equality’, amongst other provisions, implies the jurisdictional exclusivity of states, equal rights
and duties of states and political independence of states. See GA 2625 (XXV) 1970.
114
See UN Charter, article 2(1). Article 2(7) of the Charter prohibits the UN from intervening in matters
within the domestic jurisdiction of member states.
115
Franck views the emergence of transnational institutions as one of the greatest innovations of
international law in the 20th Century. See Franck T, ‘Three major innovations of international law in the
twentieth century’, Quinnipiac Law Review. 17/1 (1997) 139.
116
See e.g. Cassese A, International law. Oxford: Oxford University Press (2005) 59; see also Brownlie I,
Principles of public international law. Oxford: Oxford University Press (2003) 293.
117
Hay (1966) 68.
33
the transfer of powers to regional organisations. As Hay indicates, a state owns
the totality of sovereign powers (bundle of rights) and has the prerogative to
share it with other states or institutions.118 Hay’s formulation regards external
sovereignty as a direct function of internal sovereignty.119 What this means is
that when a state transfers part of its internal sovereignty or jurisdiction, for
example in relation to making immigration laws, to an international organisation,
there is also a corollary understanding that the organisation will have the
powers to represent such state(s) on the particular subject when dealing with
third states.120
Lauterpacht agrees that the nation states possess plenitude of powers but that
such powers terminate where international obligation begins.121 The implication
of this is that states have powers to exercise national sovereignty, for example
the enactment of legislations, as long as it does not conflict with their obligations
to the international community.122 Mitrany views that ‘it would indeed be
sounder and wiser to speak not of surrender but of a sharing of sovereignty’.123
This requires the pooling of sovereign authority for the joint performance of a
particular task.124 Mitrany sees sovereignty as a functional concept, that is, the
transferral of sovereign powers should be based on the need to execute certain
task or function.125 MacCormick’s conception of sovereignty is rather different.
He remarks that:
We must not envisage sovereignty as the object of some kind of zero sum
game, such that the moment X loses it, Y necessarily has it. Let us think of it
rather more as of virginity, which can in at least some circumstances be lost to
the general satisfaction without anybody else gaining it.126
118
Hay (1966) 70.
119
Ibid, 71.
120
Ibid, 70-74.
121
Lauterpacht E, ‘Sovereignty – myth or reality? International Affairs. 73/1 (1997) 149.
122
Ibid.
123
Mitrany (1966) 31.
124
Ibid 31-32.
125
Ibid, 31.
126
MacCormick N, ‘Beyond the sovereign state’. The Modern Law Review. 56/1 (1993) 16.
34
There is no doubt that the concept of absolute sovereignty underwent radical
reformulation over the years. The ‘global village’ narrative has ensured that
states are continuously probed about the treatment of their citizens, natural
resources and the environment. Even when states have not explicitly or
impliedly limited their sovereign powers, their actions are increasingly being
measured by a ‘universal or community values’127 barometer. The increasing
competence of the EU, the influence of the Bretton Wood institutions
(International Monetary Fund and the World Bank) on the monetary and fiscal
policies of developing countries, the UN’s and AU’s right to militarily intervene in
member states clearly indicates that the evolution of sovereignty is yet to reach
a terminal point.128
The end of the nation state is by no means near but the doctrine of sovereignty
will continue to adapt to new realities by evolving into a space big enough to
accommodate national concerns and transnational imperatives. In this era of
globalisation and technological advancement, both sceptics and optimists will
accept that the rules are changing, with no one being able to categorically
identify the terminal point of sovereignty. The realities of the twentieth century
helped to reshape the concept of sovereignty, who knows what the twenty-first
century has in stock. As Carr pointedly puts it, ‘the concept of sovereignty is
likely to become in future even more blurred and indistinct than it is at
present’.129
127
See e.g. Werner (2007) 17; see also Olivier M, ‘International and regional requirements for good
governance and the rule of law’. South African Yearbook of International Law. 32 (2007) 52.
128
As Jackson notes, ‘… there is no teleological terminus, no determinate and final destination, and no end
of history in the evolution of sovereignty’. See Jackson R, Sovereignty: Evolution of an idea. New York:
Polity (2007) 112.
129
Carr E, The twenty years crisis 1919-1939. London: Macmillan (1978) 230-231.
35
theorists and politicians are divided on the best approach to African integration.
This lack of unanimity continues to define the paradigms of African integration.
This section will thus aim to place African integration in perspective by tracing
its origins, theoretical contributions to the idea, the possible benefits of
integration, and lastly, the feasibility of continental integration.
The supreme irony, according to Mazrui, is that ‘it took European colonialism to
inform Africans that they were indeed Africans’.131 The consciousness of being
an ‘African’, as distinct from being an Ashanti or Yoruba or Zulu, was a reaction
to external subjugation either in the form of colonialism or racial prejudice.132
Nyerere captures this in the following words ‘the Africans looked at themselves
and knew that vis-à-vis the Europeans, they were one’.133 Along with this racial
consciousness was also an awareness of ‘geographical contiguities’, the
realisation that Africans inhabit the same territorial space.134 The geographic
element of pan-Africanism should be understood as not only complementary to
130
Nicol A, ‘The meaning of Africa’ in Weaver R & Bruchac J (eds) Aftermath: An anthology of poems in
english from Africa, Asia, and the Caribbean. New York: Greenfield Review Press (1977) 76.
131
Mazrui A, ‘Who are Africans: Identity in search of unity’ in Falola T, Laremont R & Seghatolislami T
(eds) African redefined: Collected essays of Ali. A. Mazrui, Vol 1. New Jersey: Africa World Press
Incorporated (2002) 37.
132
See e.g. Nyerere J, ‘A United States of Africa’. Journal of Modern African Studies. 1/1 (1963) 1; see
also Akinyemi B, ‘Nigerian foreign policy in the 21st century’. Lecture delivered at the National Institute of
Public and Strategic Studies (NIPSS) Kuru, Nigeria (17 June 2003) 7-8. Available at
http://www.profbolajiakinyemi.com/Prof%20Bolaji%20Publications/NIPS%20FINAL%20LECTURE.doc
(Accessed 20 May 2008).
133
Cited in Akinyemi B, ‘Kwame Nkrumah and pan-Africanism’. Thisday (Nigeria). Available at
http://www.thisdayonline.com/nview.php?id=125197 (Accessed 15 October 2008).
134
Mazrui A, ‘On the concept of “We are all Africans” The American Political Science Review. 57/1
(1963) 89-90.
36
the racial consciousness but also an attempt to include Africa North of the
Sahara in the discourse on pan-Africanism.135 Africa is much a geographic
description as it is a racial entity.136 As the saying goes, nations can choose
their friends but not their neighbours; therefore, the geographic composition of
the continent is an inescapable reality which informs the quest for unity.
Moreover, Mazrui posits that age-long cultural ties between North and sub-
Saharan Africa cannot be discounted.137 This, he notes, is evident in the
vocabulary of some of the most widely spoken languages on the continent.138 It
is noteworthy that the debate on the racial divide between North and sub-
Saharan Africa has had little or no impact on programmes aimed at continental
integration.139 As will be argued later in this thesis, the basis of unity should
rather be based on the existence of the shared norms of rule of law and
democratic governance.
135
For example, it is on record that ex-president Mobutu Sese Seko of Zaire (now Democratic Republic of
Congo) advocated the establishment of an exclusive sub-Saharan (black) African organisation. See Mazrui
(2002) 39; see also Akinyemi (2008). Also, Obafemi Awolowo, a prominent Nigerian nationalist, had this
to say: ‘The Sahara Desert is a natural line of demarcation between the Northern and Southern parts of
Africa. It is my considered view that the countries of North Africa should, as a first step, constitute a
Zone…other territories south of the Sahara…should constitute another Zone’ Cited in Legum C, Pan
Africanism: A short political guide. London: Pall Mall Press (1962) 270.
136
For a detailed discussion on the geographical dynamics of the African continent, see Mazrui A, The
Africans: A triple heritage. New York: Little, Brown & Company (1986) 23-38.
137
Mazrui (2002) 39
138
Ibid; Mazrui (1986) 243.
139
According to Akinyemi, the following factors are responsible for the little impact of North Africa versus
sub-Saharan Africa debate on African unity: the strong cooperation and friendship between Gamel Nasser
of Egypt and Kwame Nkrumah of Ghana; the need to build a united front against a cold-war-ridden world
and Apartheid in South Africa. He is, however, quick to add that these factors have receded into the
background, with the resurgence of such debate among politicians and the intelligentsia alike. See
Akinyemi (2008).
140
See e.g. Thompson V, Africa and unity: The evolution of pan-Africanism. London: Longman (1969) 33.
Nyerere remarks that Africa’s pre-colonial history demanded that ‘African unity must have priority over all
other associations’. Cited in Mazrui (1963) 93.
37
emotions’141 which lends itself to various manifestations. For Africans in the
Diaspora, it represented a bond to a disconnected past, a search for common
identity and the restoration of freedom and dignity in an oppressed society.142
Within the continent, Asante observes that pan-Africanism was ‘viewed both as
an integrative force and as a movement of liberation’.143
141
Legum (1962) 14. Akinyemi calls Pan-Africanism an ‘experiential phenomenon (a phenomenon that
arises as a reaction to an experience) …’ See Akinyemi (2008); Murithi refers to it as ‘an invented idea’.
See Murithi T, The African Union: Pan-Africanism, peace-building and development. Hampshire, England:
Ashgate (2005) 35.
142
Ibid, 14-23; see also Thompson (1969) 3-19.
143
Asante (1997) 32; see also Legum (1962) 38.
144
Mazrui refers to this attitude as ‘the nationalism that looks inwardly territorially’. See Mazrui (1963) 92.
Ramutsindela rhetorically questioned whether post-colonial states ‘have been socialised into colonial
spaces’. See Ramutsindela M, ‘Deterritorialisation and the African superstate: Do we need a second glass
of sherry?’ in Maloka E (ed) A United States of Africa? Pretoria: African Institute of South Africa (2001)
100. The answer to this is neither yes nor no. If one was to answer this question in light of the various intra-
state conflicts in places like DRC, Nigeria, Rwanda, Burundi, Sudan and Ethiopia, the answer will be a
resounding ‘no’. However, in places like Tanzania and Zambia, one can argue that to some extent, these
countries have been able to forge a national identity, superior to ethnic interests.
145
Fanon F, Wretched of the earth. New York: Grove Press (1968) 159.
146
In a bid to forestall fratricidal border struggles between post-colonial African states, the Organisation of
African Unity (OAU) in 1964 adopted the uti possidetis rule, which mandated member states to respect
existing frontiers. This, however, failed to stem the tide of border clashes between African states – Somalia
and Kenya, Somalia and Ethiopia, Libya and Chad, Nigeria and Cameroon, Morocco and Western Sahara,
just to mention a few. See e.g. Oyebode A, International law and politics: An African perspective. Lagos:
Bolabay Publications (2003) 24-25.
147
Asante (1997) 34-35.
38
The earliest manifestation of pan-Africanism as an ‘integrative force’ dates back
to the 1920s.148 At that time, a group of intellectuals from the four British
dependencies of West Africa - Nigeria, Sierra Leone, Gambia and Gold Coast
(later Ghana) - called for closer cooperation and integration of West Africa.149
One of the principal initiators of this idea, Joseph Casely Hayford (Ghana),
presented a demand to the colonial office in London, asking for the
establishment of a West African Court of Appeal and a West African
University.150 Although this idea was dismissed by the colonial authorities as
‘premature’, it laid the foundation for the politically-charged activism of the
1940s, with Nkrumah as a principal player. This era witnessed a renewed focus
and an attempt to include Francophone West Africa in the ‘integrative’
agenda.151 The Nkrumah-led West African National Secretariat, an offshoot of
the 1945 Fifth Pan-African congress in Manchester, resolved in 1946 to use the
idea of ‘a West African Federation as an indispensable lever for the ultimate
achievement of a United States of Africa’.152 From this point, the consciousness
of continental integration became ingrained in the corpus of the pan-Africanism
narrative. Ironically, it also laid the foundation for the idea of integrating Africa
on a regional basis.153
The independence of Ghana in 1957 provided Nkrumah with the solid base to
vigorously pursue the African unity project.154 Nkrumah’s assertion that Ghana’s
148
Browne argues that the origins of pan-African integrative agenda can be traced back to the ancient
kingdoms of West Africa. He writes that kingdoms such as Ghana, Mali and Songhai encompassed several
ethnic groups and ecological zones. See Browne D, ‘Pan-Africanism and the African Union’. Available at
http://www.siue.edu/~mafolay/JournalInfo/Vol-2/Issue%201%20revised.pdf (Accessed 20 October 2009).
149
See Thompson (1969) 28.
150
Ibid.
151
Nkrumah traveled to France in order to consult with Francophone West African intellectuals such as
Lamin Gueye, Léopold Senghor, Sourou-Migan Apithy and Houphöuet- Boigny. See Ibid, 90.
152
Legum (1962) 32-33; Thompson (1969) 90-91; Ajala A, Pan Africanism: Evolution, progress and
prospects. London: St. Martin Press (1973) 12.
153
In 1942, Nkrumah remarked that all West African colonies ‘must first unite and become a national unity,
absolutely free from the encumbrances of foreign rule, before they can assume the aspect of international
cooperation on a grand scale’. Cited in Asante (1997) 32.
154
Nkrumah’s critics, however, describe his pan-African project as a megalomaniac drive. Omari points out
that ‘Nkrumah sacrificed Ghana on the altar of pan-Africanism, and for his grandiose dreams of African
leadership’. See Omari T, Kwame Nkrumah: The anatomy of an African dictatorship. London: C. Hurst &
Company (1970) 2; see also Meredith (2005) 187. Mazrui also describe Nkrumah as ‘a great African but
39
independence was incomplete without the total independence of other African
states not only reinforced the solidarity message inherent in the pan-Africanist
thought, it also demonstrated the readiness to give practical effect to the
integrative agenda. Building on the momentum of the 1945 Fifth Pan-African
congress in Manchester155 and the 1946 West African National congress,
Nkrumah convened the first conference of independent African states in 1958.
The conference was attended by the eight already independent African states –
Ethiopia, Libya, Liberia, Morocco, Sudan, Tunisia, the United Arab Republic and
Ghana. The participating states agreed to establish a Joint Economic Research
Committee, charged with the responsibility of promoting trade among African
countries, coordinate economic planning and investigate the feasibility of an
African common market.156
not a great Ghanaian’. See Mazrui A, Nkrumah’s legacy and Africa’s triple heritage: Between
globalisation and counter-terrorism. Accra: Ghana University Press (2004) 4.
155
The Manchester conference marked a turning point in the history of Pan-Africanism because for the first
time, Africans took a leading part in the deliberations and the resolutions that followed. See Ajala (1973)
10-1
156
Final Communiqué of the Conference of Independent African States, 15 April to 22 April, 1958, in
Thompson (1969) 348-9.
157
Cameroon, Ethiopia, Ghana, Guinea, Liberia, Libya, Morocco, Sudan, Togo, Tunisia and the United
Arab Republic.
158
Ajala (1973) 25.
159
Resolution of the Second Conference of Independent African States, June 15-24, 1960, in Legum (1962)
158.
160
Ibid, 46-47.
40
Casablanca and Monrovia - with differing views on African integration. The
Casablanca group was a juxtaposition of two elements: an immediate political
union and functional cooperation.161 As Nweke observes, the element of
political union within this group gave birth to the 1961 Ghana-Guinea-Mali Union
(Union of African States) while the functional element was reflected in the
provisions of the Casablanca Charter.162 On the other hand, the Monrovia group
was united in their call for functional cooperation at regional levels as the best
approach.163 The creation of the Organisation of African Unity (OAU) in 1963
was the culmination of decades of efforts aimed at giving the debate on unity a
practical effect. Although the OAU Charter represented a triumph of a state-
centric, functional cooperation, it was able to unite the differing ideologies under
the same banner.
Although the initiatives outlined above exposed the cleavage that existed, and
still exists, in relation to the modus operandi of African integration, it helped in
forging a template for the on-going debate on integration. The idea of ‘Africa’
might have started as a sentimental attachment to a common heritage; the
setting up of institutions both at the regional and continental levels have all
contributed to moving pan-Africanism from the realm of romanticism to a
realistic and practical objective. Whether through the creation of a Pan-African
Parliament (PAP) or the New Partnership on Africa’s Development (NEPAD) or
the African Peer Review Mechanism (APRM) or the African Charter on Human
and Peoples’ Rights (ACHPR), pan-Africanism continues to be expressed in
nuanced and adaptive forms.
161
Nweke G, ‘The Organisation of African Unity and intra-African functionalism’. Annals of the American
Academy of Political and Social Sciences. 489 (1987) 136; see also Legum (1969) 56-7.
162
Nweke (1987) 136.
163
Legum (1969) 56
41
consensus were erroneously brandished.164 When African dictators argue that
pre-colonial Africa knew no form of party politics and that community decisions
are arrived at through consensus, they cleverly leave out the methodology of
how such consensus was arrived at and how dissensions were handled.
Political elites conveniently ignore the traditional constitutional principle of
checks and balances. As Elias observes, pre-colonial African societies
employed some form of control over the paramount king.165 Elias’ analysis is
worth quoting:
It is fair to say that the constitutional principle has long been established that, if a
king or paramount chief abuses his power, subordinate chiefs have the right to
either depose him or to secede from the kingdom with their own people…among
the Yorubas, the King would in former times be requested by his chiefs to “open
the calabash”, that is, to commit suicide by voluntarily taking poison or to go into
voluntary exile … in chiefless societies, somewhat different principles apply: here,
the chief of the chief-in-council is invariably replaced by a council of elders.166
The Gold Coast native is no fool…sovereignty in the Gold Coast tribe lies in the
people themselves who elect their chiefs and can, if they desire so, deprive them
of office. Each chief is, in fact, but the mouth-piece of his State (Oman) Council,
164
Mazrui (2004) 5-6. Robert Mugabe also used the ‘traditional-Africa-logic’ to justify the imposition of a
one-party state in Zimbabwe in the mid-1980s:
You never have two chiefs in a given area. There is only one chief. And various people
meet to express their views. Some views may be critical of the chief but at the end of the
day, it is the generality of the people’s desire which becomes either the rule or the way of
life for that particular region.
Cited in Shaw W, ‘Towards one party state in Zimbabwe.’ Journal of Modern African Studies. 24/3 (1986)
377. The former Ivorien president, Houphouet-Boigny also famously proclaimed that African chief cannot
know his successor. See Adebayo W, ‘Now, the empire strikes back’. Africa Today. November 2009, 8; see
also Meredith (2005) 167-170.
165
Elias T, Africa and the development of international law. Leiden: Sijthoff (1972) 37-40; see also Elias T,
The nature of African customary law. Manchester: Manchester University Press (1965) 8-36.
166
Elias (1972) 38-39; see also Adaramola F, Basic jurisprudence. Lagos: Nayee Publishing (2002) 142-
143.
42
without whose approval no chief can perform any executive or judicial act.
Accordingly, when the Heads of Chiefs of a province are summoned to the
Provincial Council in order, say, to elect representatives of their people as
Members of the Legislative Council, each Chief carries with him instructions
which he is to pursue and the manner in which he is to record his vote…in order
to satisfy themselves that the Head Chief carries out his duties in the manner
which the State Council has prescribed, he is accompanied by eight councillors
who report the result of the mission on its return home. Could anything be more
167
democratic or more representative of the wishes of a people?
The challenge, which is the main thrust of this thesis, is to translate pan-
Africanism or the idea of ‘Africa’ into a transformative agenda. Africa, in the
words of Mazrui, ‘must stand ready to selectively borrow, adapt, and creatively
formulate its strategies for planned development’.168 The ability to adapt
concepts such as regional integration and supranationalism to African realities
and to also use them as developmental tools should be the key goal.169 Beyond
the rhetoric of pan-Africanism and the ‘United States of Africa’, efforts should be
geared towards aligning the practicalities of regional cooperation with local
specificities and the developmental needs of the African populace. It should
draw from traditional African values, which ensures broad-based community
participation in matters that affect the common good.
167
Ibid.
168
Mazrui A, ‘Africa must not just remain a learner’. Daily Monitor (Uganda). Available at
http://www.monitor.co.ug/artman/publish/opinions/Africa_must_not_just_remain_a_learner_71811.shtml
(Accessed 30 September 2008).
169
This is discussed below.
43
2.3.2 Theoretical perspectives on African integration
To rule out a step by step progress towards African unity is to hope that the Almighty will one
day say, ‘Let there be unity in Africa’, and there shall be unity; or to pray for a conqueror. But
even a conqueror will have to proceed step by step.
Julius Nyerere170
Our objective is African Union now. There is no time to waste. We must unite now or perish.
Kwame Nkrumah171
One thing that African integration does not lack is a plethora of theoretical
suppositions. Since the colonial era, African intellectuals have, depending on
their ideological beliefs and location, offered their views on how to proceed with
African integration. If colonialism was the catalyst for the quest for unity, the
paradox of Africa’s underdevelopment shaped, and continues to shape, the
debate on African integration.172 The unanimity of ideas in respect of unity does
not, however, extend to the methodology of attaining such goal. Numerous
sobriquets have been used to define the differing opinions on African
integration.173 Basically, theoretical perspectives on African integration can be
classified under three schools of thought: idealists, realists and idealists-cum-
reterritorialists. This categorisation is based on the philosophical approach of
each group to the idea of African integration. While certain groups advocate the
pursuance of African integration based on the realities on ground (inherited
170
Nyerere J, Freedom and unity uhuru na umoja: A selection from writings and speeches 1952-1965.
Oxford: Oxford University Press (1966) 302.
171
Nkrumah K, ‘Address to the conference of African heads of state and government, 1963, in
Revolutionary path. London: PANAF (1973) 233-234.
172
Writing in 1963, Nkrumah outlines the abundance of natural resources on the continent and argues that
only through ‘a gigantic self-help programme’ can Africa realise its potential. See Nkrumah (1963) 150-
151; see also New Partnership for Africa’s Development (2001) 3. The developmental feature of regional
integration is discussed below.
173
Agyeman for example use terms such as ‘militant versus gradualist’ and ‘all-out Pan-Africanist versus
the territorial Patriot-cum-Pan Africanist.’ See generally, Agyeman O, Nkrumah’s Ghana and east Africa:
Pan-Africanism and African interstate relations. Rutherford: Fairleigh Dickinson University Press (1992)
78-95. Legum use terms like ‘political union (or organic union)’ and ‘functional cooperation’. See Legum
(1962) 57; Maluwa refers to ‘absolute integrationists’ versus ‘minimal integrationists’. See Maluwa T,
‘Fast-tracking African unity or making haste slowly? A note on the amendments to the constitutive act of
the African Union’. Netherlands International Law Review. 51/2 (2004) 201.
44
colonial boundaries and understanding the differences that exists), others
propound either conjuring an ‘African leviathan’ or a cartographic
rearrangement of African boundaries. This section will thus chronicle selected
thoughts of Africans on the issue of integration, along the lines of the above-
mentioned schools of thought.
need not infringe the essential sovereignty of the African states. These states
would continue to exercise independent authority, except in the fields defined and
reserved for common action in the interest of the security and orderly
development of the whole continent.177
He further recommends that such Union should pursue three objectives: overall
economic planning on a continental basis; unified military and defence strategy;
174
See e.g. Nkrumah (1963) 163-164; see also Nkrumah (1973) 277-297.
175
Nyerere points out that the fact that Nkrumah, the major proponent of this idea, went to school in the
United States of America largely influenced his ideological position on African unity. He opines: ‘Kwame
[Nkrumah] went to Lincoln University, a black college in the US. He perceived things from a US history,
where 13 colonies revolted against the British formed a union’. Cited in Mwakikagile G, Nyerere and
Africa: End of an era. Las Vegas: Protea Publishing (2002) 300.
176
Nkrumah (1963) 163-164.
177
Ibid, 218. In line with this, Nkrumah ensured that the Ghanaian constitution stipulated the partial or
wholesale surrendering of sovereignty as a contribution towards the attainment of continental unification.
See Nkrumah K, I speak of freedom. New York: Praeger (1961) 221. Guinea, Mali, Tunisia and Egypt also
provided for limitation of sovereignty in their constitutions. See Legum (1962) 66.
45
and a unified foreign policy and diplomacy.178 On the institutional architecture of
such Union, Nkrumah, in 1964, suggests:
The idea of regional federations in Africa is fraught with many dangers. There is
the danger of the development of regional loyalties, fighting against each other. In
effect, regional federations are a form of balkanisation on a grand scale…the best
means…is to begin to create a larger and all-embracing loyalty which will hold
Africa together as a united people with one government and one destiny.180
The advocates of this theory [regional federations] suggest that we have to wait
for Somalia to unite and then Eritrea and Ethiopia. We have to wait for Egypt,
Libya, Tunisia, Algeria and Morocco (which is outside the African Union) and
178
Nkrumah (1963) 218-220.
179
Nkrumah (1973) 295-296. In his address to African leaders at the 1965 OAU Summit in Accra,
Nkrumah further proposed that in addition to a Union president, the Assembly should elect a number of
Union Vice-Presidents. See Nkrumah (1973) 309.
180
Nkrumah (1963) 214-215.
181
Ghaddafi M, ‘Address by the leader of the revolution at the opening session of the north African
popular activists’ forum’ in Tripoli, Libya (21 June, 2007) 4-8. (On file with the author).
46
Mauritania, and Sahara to become one state…it is impossible for these regions to
establish one state.182
One of the fundamental flaws of this ideology is its lack of a sound theoretical
basis. Its adherents point to a shifting of loyalty without providing practicalities
or methodology for such a shift. For example, no theoretical exposition is
provided on how to measure the general acceptance of this idea by the African
populace except for anchoring it on an emotional pan-Africanist ideology.
Neither is this idea anchored to democratic values. Post-colonial African elites
like Nkrumah and Sekou Toure simply assumed position of the essential
alchemists, garbed with the superior intellectual prowess to dictate the course of
African history.185
This line of reasoning stems from the domestic credentials of its major
proponents. A roll call of the proponents of this ideology reveals a pattern of
182
Ibid, 5.
183
Ibid, 6.
184
Maluwa (2004) 6.
185
Mazrui & Tidy put it aptly:
Paradoxically, however, Nkrumah became the main obstacle to unity in Africa. In his fanatical
adherence to idea of Union Government of all Africa and his opposition to regional grouping …
he alienated other African heads of state in the early 1960s.
See Mazrui A & Tidy M, Nationalism and new states in Africa. London: Heinemann (1985) 63. At the
1964 OAU summit in Cairo, Nyerere denounced the approach of the federalists, of which Nkrumah was an
arrowhead, as ‘propaganda’. He notes ‘Nothing could be more calculated to bring ridicule to the whole
concept of a continental Government in Africa than this incessant and oft-repeated propaganda …’ See
Nyerere (1966) 301.
47
personality cults, suppression of dissension, dogmatic ideologies and a
tendency to personalise the unification discourse.186 This is not to say that other
African leaders who espouse different integration ideologies did (and do) not
have personal agendas, nevertheless, the issue of continental unification is a
sensitive matter that requires utmost exemplary qualities. When leaders operate
repressive regimes and in the same breath advocate a ‘United States of Africa’,
it is only natural that people express cynical views on how such leaders intend
to either run or fit into the administrative structure of a continental union.187
Another flaw is that this paradigm makes the assumption that Africa is
homogenous. In an attempt to present a common front, it glosses over the deep
cleavages that exist on the continent. There are vast differences - sociological,
political, economic and cultural - between countries and regions on the
continent. Despite the prescriptions of regional instruments and international
donors, democratic ideals are still an exception rather than the rule on the
continent. The unevenness of democratic practise, which is evident in the fewer
numbers of fair electoral process, the growing number of dictators and the
suppression of opposition reveals the absence of shared norms and values.
The question is whether a democratic South Africa or Mauritius would feel
comfortable to enter into any federal union with a Libya or Zimbabwe? The
impracticality of this lies in how administrative structures in the former will
interface with the ones in the latter, where institutions are either ineffectual or
non-existent.
186
One of the accusations often leveled against Nkrumah and Ghaddafi is their ambition to become the
president of a ‘United States of Africa’. See e.g. ‘Qaddafi, ruler of Africa? The Economist, September 16-
22 (2000) 51; see also Legum (1962) 54-55. For a critical assessment of post-colonial elites, see e.g.
Meredith (2005); Omari (1970); Mazrui (2004).
187
Mazrui surmised Nkrumah’s legacy thus: ‘His dream of trying to create “one-Africa by abolishing
separate states” was an inspiration. His policy of trying to “create one Ghana by abolishing separate
political parties” was usurpation’. See Mazrui (2004) 3; see also Mazrui & Tidy (1985) 60-62.
48
As will be shown below, the economies of most African countries are largely
underdeveloped.188 Suffice to add that since regional integration requires a
uniform level of sound economic development across member states, the case
for an immediate federal African state appears premature. In addition, the
disintegrative tendencies within certain African states need to be properly
addressed before any attempt to create a federal union. While it can be argued
that these conflicts are a result of the arbitrary balkanisation of the continent by
colonialists, there is no proof that replacing the fault lines of African states - with
their internal contradictions - with a single government would obliterate these
problems. Rather, African integration requires a more fundamental approach in
the form of uniform adherence to democratic norms by member states. The
evenness of democratic practise can help establish the basis for unity – shared
norms and values. This point will be further elaborated upon in subsequent
chapters.
188
Mo Ibrahim, the Sudanese philanthropist, bluntly notes, ‘the fact is a large number of African
countries are not viable … If they were companies, they would have been declared bankrupt. You switch
off the light; you say bye-bye, it doesn’t work’. Cited in New African Magazine (February 2010) 12.
189
See e.g. Agyeman (1992) 78-95.
49
federation should thus be through the orthodox functional approach. Below is an
analysis of the realist ideology.
The regional federalists are closer to the idealists in the sense that they propose
the establishment of a federated union albeit on a (sub) regional basis. As
Kenyatta succinctly puts it, ‘I want to see first East Africa united and federated,
then the whole of Africa as one’.190 The rationale behind this thesis is based on
the fact that it is easier for states that share similar cultural, administrative and
linguistic identities to form a union rather than plunging the whole of Africa, with
its internal contradictions and complexities, into a union. According to Nyerere,
the advantage(s) of a regional federation lies in the fact that it would enable the
area concerned, ‘to achieve quickly at least the benefits of greater unity and
great strength’ and, also, reduce ‘the number of states which have to sit down
together and agree on the final forms of African unification’.191 The relative
successes of sub-regional organisations in Africa in areas such as monetary
integration and the harmonisation of policies vindicate Nyerere’s sentiments.
Through regional federations, as Nyerere reckoned, the road to an ultimate
continental union will be smoothened and made less cumbersome. Nkrumah,
however, rejected this theory by arguing that regional federations will only
amount to ‘balkanisation on a grand scale’.192 He also perceived this idea as a
neo-imperialist agenda, aimed at creating division on the continent.193
190
Cited in Legum (1962) 65.
191
Nyerere (1966) 347.
192
Nkrumah (1963) 214-215.
193
Agyeman (1992) 82. Nyerere responded to this assertion in the following words: ‘To say that the step by
step method was invented by the imperialists is to reach the limits of absurdity’. See Nyerere (1966) 302.
194
Nye (1966) 13-17; Nweke (1987) 135-137.
50
the functionalist ideology lies in the successful experiments of colonial-inspired
functional cooperation195 that existed in Africa prior to the emergence of the
OAU in 1963. The two major functional organisations were the British initiated -
East African Common Services Organisation (EACSO)196 and French inspired -
Union Africaine et Maghreb (UAM).197 Based on the prescriptions of orthodox
functionalism, intra-African functionalists stress the assignment of functional
tasks to transnational institution.198 However, intra-African functionalism differs
from orthodox functionalism in the sense that some of the functional institutions
have little or no autonomy and resources (human and material) necessary for
effective functioning.199
51
leanings of political parties and programmes of interest groups across European
frontiers.202
Another reason cited for the unsuitability of intra-African functionalism is the low
level of intra-African trade and investment (see table 2.3 below).203
1970 1980 1990 1998 2003
Exports
Imports
Source: International Monetary Fund, Direction of trade statistics. Available at
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2005/wp0536.pdf Accessed (23 June 2007).
52
there will be an increment in the volume of trade among those countries (trade
creation).204 Placing this in an African context, analysts have argued that the
fact that most African countries are primary producers in the same range of
products,205 thus making their products competitive rather than complementary,
simply eliminates any prospect of trade creation.206 The externalisation of
external tariffs, that is the creation of a customs union, will result in a substantial
loss of revenue, especially in countries where customs revenue forms a chunk
of government revenue.207 If African states decide to pursue functionalism, in
spite of the above constraints, it is argued that lowest income countries within
the union will suffer real income loss due to trade diversion.208 Venables
illustrates this point in the following words:
Membership in an FTA changes the sources from which products are supplied to
member country markets, increasing supply from the partner countries as these
receives preferential treatment, but possibly also reducing supply from domestic
production and from the rest of the world. To the extent that overall supply is
increased and lower cost of imports from the partner country replace higher cost
(previously protected) domestic production.209
The Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) of the EU has been cited as an example
of trade diversion.210 As Fernandez & Portes observe, the CAP entails that
certain European countries have to abandon buying cheaper agricultural
products from other parts of the world and rather purchase them from high-cost
204
Agyeman (1990)10; see also Gambari I, Political and comparative dimensions of regional integration:
The case of Ecowas 2.London: Humanities Press (1991) 7-8.
205
Four non-manufacturing goods constitute 50% of intra-African trade: petroleum, cotton, maize and
cocoa. See Naude & Krugell (2001) 498.
206
Gambari (1991) 7-8; Agyeman (1990) 10-11.
207
ECA (2004) 12. For example, study has shown that Zambia and Zimbabwe could loose substantial
government revenue amounting to 5.6% and 9.8% respectively if free trade is introduced in the Southern
African Development Community (SADC). See Venables A, ‘Regional integration agreements: A force for
convergence or divergence?’ World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no. 2260 (1999) 6.
208
See e.g. Ibid, ii.
209
Ibid, 3-4.
210
See ECA (2004) 11-12; Fernandez R & Portes J, ‘Returns to regionalism: An analysis of nontraditional
gains from regional trade agreements’. The World Bank Economic Review. 12/2 (1998) 200-201.
53
European sources.211 This results in domestic price increases for such
products.212
211
Fernandez & Portes (1998) 201.
212
Ibid.
213
Naude & Krugell (2001) 501.
214
See Agyeman (1990) 27-8.
215
See generally, Mutua (1995) 1113-1176; see also Bello A, ‘The boundaries must change’. West Africa,
April (1995) 546; Gakwandi A, ‘Towards a new political map of Africa’ in Abdul-Raheem T (ed) Pan-
Africanism: Politics, economy and social change in the 21st Century .London: Pluto (1996) 87.
216
According to Dowden, ‘all but two of Africa’s concocted countries combine several ethnic groups.’ See
Dowden (2008) 3.
217
The statement by a British official who was involved in drawing boundary between Nigeria and
Cameroon aptly captures the triviality and insensitive approach of the colonial experts. He remarks:
In those days, we just took a blue pencil and a rule, and we put down at Old Calabar, and
drew that line to Yola…I recollect thinking when I was sitting having an audience with
the Emir of Yola, surrounded by his tribe, that it was a very good thing that he did not
know that I, with a blue pencil, had drawn a line through his territory.
Cited in Mutua (1995) 1135. Also, another colonial administrator, Lord Salisbury, sarcastically remarked;
We have been engaged in drawing lines upon maps where no white man’s feet have ever
trod; we have been giving away mountains and rivers and lakes to each other, only
hindered by the small impediment that we never knew exactly where the mountains and
rivers and lakes were.
Cited in Hargreaves J, ‘The making of boundaries: Focus on west Africa’ in Asiwaju A (ed) Partitioned
Africans: Ethnic relations across Africa’s international boundaries 1884-1984. Lagos: University of Lagos
Press (1985) 22.
54
the extent that in some cases it separated communities that shared common
ancestry, customs and socio political and economic institutions.218 As Asiwaju
observes:
Much has been written about the (illegal) acquisition of African territories. In an
attempt to bring the continent under the European sphere of influence,
depraved and illegal methods were employed to dispossess Africans of their
territories.220 For example, the King of Lagos, Dosumu, and his chiefs were
forced to sign a treaty of cession in 1861 which stipulates:
I, Docemo, do with the consent and advice of my Council, give transfer, and by
these presents grant and confirm unto the Queen of Great Britain, her heirs and
successors forever, the Port and Island of Lagos, with all the rights, profits,
territories and appurtenances whatsoever thereunto belonging, and as well the
profits and revenues and direct, full and absolute dominion and sovereignty of the
said port, island and premises, with all the royalties thereof, freely, fully, entirely
and absolutely. I do also covenant and grant that the quiet and peaceable
possession thereof shall, with all possible speed, be freely and effectually
delivered to the Queen of Great Britain, or such persons as Her Majesty shall
thereunto appoint, for her use in the performance of this grant; the inhabitants of
the said island and territories, as the Queen’s subjects, and under her
218
Asiwaju A, ‘The Conceptual Framework’, in Asiwaju A (1985) 2-3. For a detailed tabulated list of
partitioned ethnic groups in Africa, see Asiwaju (1985) 256-258. Brownlie, however, argues that the
European powers did not always ignore ethnological considerations when delimiting African frontiers. See
Brownlie I, African boundaries: A legal and diplomatic encyclopaedia. Berkeley: University of California
Press (1979) 6.
219
Ibid, 3. For example, the United Kingdom and Ethiopia entered into an agreement in 1954 that nomadic
Somali would be allowed to graze their animals across the border (in Ethiopia) but upon the independence
of British Somaliland in 1960, Ethiopia decided not to honour the agreement. See Oyebode (2003) 23.
220
The British used Treaties as a pretext for acquiring territories. In most cases, the content of such treaties
were either misinterpreted to African chiefs or coercive measures were employed to make them sign. There
is no gainsaying that these measures are blatantly in violation of the principles international law, especially
rules relating to the validity of treaties. See e.g. Ibid, 90-100; Mutua (1995) 1130-1134.
55
sovereignty, crown, jurisdiction, and government, being still suffered to live
there.’221
Such was the fate of the continent under what is aptly termed ‘the scramble for
Africa’. Although some argue that partitioning is not peculiar to Africa,222 the
resultant effect of this colonial adventure is the designation of Africa as the
world’s most fragmented region.223 The presence of 15 landlocked states in
Africa, some of which are not economically viable, is evidence of the
arbitrariness of African frontiers.224
It is against this backdrop that calls have been made that ‘we should sit down
with square-rule and compass and re-design the boundaries of African
nations’.225 Mutua questions the moral and legal legitimacy of ‘colonial’ states
by arguing for a compression of the 54 states in Africa into 14 large entities.226
According to Mutua, the criteria of such cartographic exercise include factors
such as historical circumstances; population density; resources and economic
viability and ethnic, cultural and geographic variables.227 In the same vein, Bello
views that the states trapped within colonial frontiers have failed.228 Citing the
example of the collapse of the Soviet Union, Bello calls for the redrawing of
Africa’s boundaries on ‘a rational and logical basis to take cognisance of the
linguistic, cultural and ethnic diversities as is the case with most successful
221
Oyebode (2003) 90-1.
222
Asiwaju notes that the boundaries of African countries such as Nigeria, Senegal and Mozambique are
older than the boundaries of countries like Austria, Hungary, Poland, Greece and Finland. See Asiwaju A,
‘The Global Perspective and Border Management Policy Options’ in Asiwaju (1985) 233, 248.
223
Akonnor notes that Africa has 165 demarcated borders. See Akonnor K, ‘Stuffing old wine in new
bottles: The case of the African Union’ in Mazama A (ed.) Africa in the 21st Century: Toward a new future,
London: Routledge (2007) 200.
224
Englebert A, Tarango S & Carter M, Dismemberment and suffocation: A contribution to the debate on
AfricanbBoundaries. Pomona College (2001) 4. Available at
http://www.politics.pomona.edu/penglebert/borders_FINAL.pdf (Accessed 1 November 2008). African
states, according to Agyeman, are ‘plagued by the deficiency trilogy of smallness, unnaturalness and
illegitimacy’. See Agyeman (1990) 6.
225
This statement is credited to the Nigerian Nobel laureate, Wole Soyinka. Cited in Ramutsindela (2001)
96.
226
Mutua (1995) 1117-8.
227
Ibid.
228
Bello (1995) 546.
56
nations all over the world.’229 Gakwandi also suggests the redrawing of the
political map of Africa into seven states.230 The rationale, according to
Gakwandi, behind this includes the elimination of border disputes, easing of
ethnic tensions, solid economic development and the emergence of politically
and economically viable states.231
Apart from the apparent logistical nightmare, the redrawing of Africa’s map
remains impossible due to the fact that African elites will never reach a
consensus on the modus vivendi of such exercise. The pragmatic approach will
be to de-emphasise the importance of these arbitrary borders by turning them
229
Ibid.
230
Gakwandi (1996) 87.
231
Ibid.
232
Ramutsindela (2001) 98.
233
Ibid; Englebert et al (2001) 5-7; Brownlie (1979) 14-15.
234
Englebert et al (2001) 6.
235
Before independence, the Masai ethnic grouping in Kenya and Tanzania petitioned the Colonial
authorities for reunification but after independence, this claim has evaporated largely because they have
reconciled themselves to the reality of their ‘new’ homes. See e.g. Ibid. Another factor that reduces the call
for border revision is agreements which allowed frontier populations to pursue their everyday economic
and social activities without restrictions. See Brownlie (1979) 171, 246, 401, 1051-61.
57
into a productive and positive ‘theatre of operations’.236 Asiwaju identifies the
three ways of doing this:
(1) Development programmes with specific reference to border areas; (2) border
areas within the wider context of bilateral relations and co-operation between the
states concerned; and (3) border areas in the still wider context of functional
international organisations aimed at regional grouping or integration of the
several states in geographically contiguous areas.237
[W]e should explore the areas which unite us as Africans and one of the best
ways of achieving this must be to study and encourage cultural links across
political boundaries – which should be emphasised as points of contact and not
of separation.240
236
Ramutsindela (2001) 100; Asiwaju (1985) 243-245.
237
Asiwaju (1985) 243-244.
238
See Ibid, 233-6; see also Asiwaju A, ‘Borderlands in Africa: A comparative research perspective with
particular reference to Western Europe’ in Asiwaju A & Nugent P (eds), African boundaries: Barriers,
conduits and opportunities. London: Pinter (1996) 254-9.
239
See e.g. Phiri S, ‘National integration, Rural development and frontier communities: The case of the
Chewa and the Ngoni astride Zambian boundaries with Malawi and Mozambique’ in Asiwaju (1985) 121-
4; Barkindo B ‘The Mandara astride the Nigeria-Cameroon boundary’ in Asiwaju (1985) 46; see also
Asiwaju (1996) 260.
240
Barkindo (1985) 46.
58
2.3.3 Searching for an elixir: Is regional integration beneficial to Africa?
A post-integrative era of socio-political and economic upliftment witnessed in
Europe is an empirical proof of the development feature of integration. Apart
from the old guard (EU-15),241 new entrants into the EU,242 especially the
Central and East European Countries (CEEC) have recorded significant
economic growth. This economic effect is measured based on variables such as
the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita growth, investment inflow (factor
mobility effect), single market effect and trade effects.243 Breuss observes that
the impact of elimination of trade (export) tariffs on the real GDP of CEECs,
over the period 2001-2010, was around 4.5 percent.244 Trade between the EU-
15 and the CEECs (EU-10) rose from 56% in 1993 to 62% in 1995.245 In
addition, CEECs have recorded substantial FDI inflow from EU-15. FDI flows to
the EU-10 account for about 40% of GDP.246 These empirical factors are largely
responsible for the EU’s designation as a successful regional integration
initiative.
Having outlined the foregoing, the question is this: what benefits can Africa
derive from integration? The benefits to be derived from regional integration can
be classified into two: traditional and non-traditional gains.247
241
The EU-15 include: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy,
Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom.
242
In 2004, 10 member states from CEEC, also known as the EU-10, joined the EU. They are Czech
Republic, Cyprus, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Slovenia and Slovakia. In 2007, two
more member states from the CEEC joined the organisation: Bulgaria and Romania.
243
Borota T & Kutan A, ‘Regional integration and economic growth: The case of the European Union’. The
Journal of International Trade and Diplomacy. 2/1 (2008) 94; see also Breuss F, Macroeconomic effects of
EU enlargement for old and new members. (2001) 4. Available at http://fritz.breuss.wifo.ac.at//Breuss.PDF
(Accessed 30 November 2008); see also Breintenfellner A, Cuaresmer J, Mooslechner P & Ritzberger-
Grunwald D, ‘The impact of EU enlargement in 2004 and 2007 on FDI and migration flows: Gravity
analysis of factor mobility’. Monetary Policy and the Economy. Quarter 2 (2008) 102. Available at
http://www.oenb.at/en/img/mop_2008_2_analyses_5_tcm16-88559.pdf (Accessed 30 November 2008).
244
Breuss (2001) 6.
245
European Commission, ‘Enlargement, two years after: An economic evaluation’. Occasional Paper No
24 (2006). Available at http://ec.europa.eu/enlargement/archives/press_corner/newsletter/110506_en.htm
(Accessed 1 December 2008).
246
Ibid.
247
See e.g. Fernandez & Portes (1998).
59
At the core of traditional gains from regional integration is the concept of trade
creation.248 The classical underlying logic of regional integration is that the
reduction of trade barriers between countries would enable citizens and firms to
obtain goods and services from the cheapest source of supply, thereby,
ensuring that production is located based on comparative advantage.249 To put
it simply, trade creation displaces higher cost domestic production in state A
with lower cost production from partner state B because tariffs have either been
reduced or completely eliminated.250 The result of this would be an
improvement of terms of trade among member states because the removal of
tariffs will make goods originating from an integration area less expensive than
those from non-member states.251 As earlier pointed out, this same advantage
could also lead to a welfare loss252 especially for economically weak countries
which depend heavily on tariff revenues. For example, analysts have pointed
out that the introduction of a free trade area in the Southern Africa Development
Community (SADC) would lead to substantial revenue loss for Zambia (5.6%)
and Zimbabwe (9.8%).253 It, has, however been argued that this situation could
also provide a stimulus for finding alternative ways of raising funds in such
countries.254
248
Ibid, 200; Venables (2000) 3.
249
Venables (2000) 3.
250
Ibid; see also ECA (2004) 11.
251
Fernandez & Portes (1998) 221.
252
As Casella postulates
If economics of scale imply that firms located in large countries enjoy lower costs, then the gains
from enlarging the bloc will fall disproportionally on small countries, because the entrance of new
members diminishes the importance of the domestic market and improves the small countries’
relative competitiveness.
Casella A, ‘Large countries, small countries and the enlargement of trade blocks’. European Economic
Review. Vol. 40/2 (1996) 389.
253
Venables (2000) 6.
254
ECA (2004) 11. Venables observes that Cambodia introduced value added tax (VAT) after it lost
substantial tariff revenues (56%) upon its entry into ASEAN. Venables (2000) 6.
255
Venables (2000) 7; Fernandez & Portes (1998) 201-2.
60
balkanisation of Africa, highlighted above, gave birth to mini-states, with small
populations and economies. Only five African countries - DRC, Ethiopia, Egypt,
Nigeria and South Africa - have a population of more than 30 million.256 It is thus
important that the continent fashion a strategy of combining its markets in order
to stimulate investment flows by domestic and foreign investors. For example,
the creation of a customs union can serve as incentive to foreign investors to
engage in tariff jumping – that is, invest in a member country in order to trade
freely with other members.257 Such investment can spur knowledge and
technology transfers and spillovers.258
256
Asante (1997) 29.
257
Fenandez & Portes (1998) 202. Research has shown that integration initiatives such as NAFTA
substantially increased FDI in Mexico, and MERCUSOR did the same in Argentina and Brazil. See ECA
(2004) 13.
258
AU & ECA (2006) 81.
259
Fenandez & Portes (1998) 204-205.
260
Ibid, 205; Venables (2000) 10. Schmidt highlights that European integration was responsible for major
economic reforms in France from the 1960s through to the 1980s. See Schmidt V, The untold story: The
impact of European integration on France in the Mitterrand-Chirac era (1981-1997). Paper prepared for
delivery at the European Community Studies Association Fifth Biennial International Conference (Seattle,
WA, May 29-June 1 1997) 1-2. Available at http://biblioteca.universa.net/ficha.do?id=13753042-31k
(Accessed 30 November, 2008).
261
For example, the threat of economic and diplomatic isolation by MERCURSOR was responsible for the
prevention of a coup d’état in Paraguay in 1996. See Fenandez & Portes (1998) 208. Ram also observes
that European integration was the impetus for large scale political reforms witnessed in Romania in the
1990s. See generally, Ram M, Romania’s reforms through European integration: The domestic effects of
European Union law. 1-23. Available at
http://www.hks.harvard.edu/kokkalis/GSW1/GSW1/20%20Ram.pdf (Accessed 30 November 2008)
61
mechanisms, they are likely to invest in such country.262 Illustratively, where
country A, widely known to be a command economy joins a regional
organisation that espouses liberal policies, such action will signal to potential
investors that country A has adopted liberal policies and thus open for
investment.263
62
countries involved in regional integration initiatives reported that coordinated
macro-economic policies helped control inflation, almost the same number
highlighted that it helped reduce budget deficit and about 44% held that it
increased the volume of investment.267 A breakdown of the sectoral impact of
regional integration reveals that 50% of member states have benefited from
trade and market integration initiatives, 47% from transport, 39% from macro-
economic policy convergence, 28% from agricultural and food policy and 26%
from energy.268
267
AU & ECA (2006) 82.
268
Ibid.
269
ECA (2004) 22.
63
African integration, one must consider both internal and external factors that will
influence African integration.
a) Social imperative
On the internal factors, it is pertinent to consider the sociological implication of
the integration narrative. As mentioned earlier, the term ‘Africans’ is a
constructed idea, an idea which is antedated by ethnic affiliations. Ethnic
affiliations are so strong that in some cases they transcends national
citizenship.270 Therefore, any attempt to ‘impose’271 an African identity, without
paying adequate attention to ethnic complexities and values and how these can
inform and nourish the integration debate, can only be disadvantageous.272
Dowden’s observation about Africa’s identity is worth quoting in full:
270
Citing the example of the Chewa and the Ngoni of Zambia, Mozambique and Malawi, Phiri notes that
the behavioural pattern of these ethnic groups shows an overriding attachment to cultural ties as opposed to
their national domain. See Phiri in Asiwaju (1985) 105-25, 245.
271
I use this word only to refer to how some post-colonial elites skilfully gloss over ethnic cleavages in an
attempt to create a façade of unity and cohesion. As Nye aptly notes:
The choice between them - between tribalism and Pan-Africanism - was not made by any popular
plebiscite, but by the educated elite, who have generally opted for Pan-Africanism because of their
views about size and power in world politics. They believe that tribal nations would be divided
and ruled from outside, whereas a Pan-African nation would mean world power and dignity.
64
same planet as Mali. Every time you say ‘Africa is …’ the words crumble and
break. For every generalisation you must exclude at least five countries.273
Musjawarah means ‘that a leader should not act arbitrarily or impose his will, but
rather make gentle suggestions of the path a community should follow, being
careful always to consult all other participants fully and to take their views and
feelings into consideration before delivering his synthesis conclusions.’ Mufukat
means consensus and is the goal toward which musjawarah is directed.277
273
Dowden (2008) 10.
274
Asiwaju (1985) 245-246.
275
Fontaine P, Europe in 12 lessons. Brussels: European Commission (2006) 6.
276
Narine S, Explaining ASEAN: Regionalism in south-east Asia. Boulder Colorado: Lynne Rienner (2002)
31.
277
Ibid.
65
designed’.278 Such ‘architecture’ should be autochthonous and sensitive to local
specificities. Nevertheless, it should also include elements that have been
responsible for the success of other integration initiatives. These include
variables like peace and security, good governance and human rights.
b) Democratic imperative
Be it at the sub-regional or continental levels, architects of African integration
should make concerted efforts at fashioning a consensus on democratic values.
As Dare rhetorically intones,
As the world struggles to build new structures … isn’t it time also to reconsider a
system that subjects fragile developing countries to violent spasms every four or
five years, keeps them in suspended animation in between, and yet solves
nothing and settle nothing?279
While it is not suggested that Africa should devise a system that encourages the
ubiquitous ‘sit-tight syndrome’,280 African democracy should be adapted to
reflect what Ake calls ‘socio-cultural realities’.281 Without sacrificing the inherent
values and principles of democracy, Ake argues that the starting point of
democracy in Africa should be an emphasis on the communal over the
individual – a system which prioritises social welfare and common good.282 He,
however, admits that a unique African democracy will not emerge from a
rational blueprint but rather, from ‘practical experience and improvisation in the
course of a hard struggle’.283 The reality is that Africa cannot afford to pursue
concrete unity without some form of common grundnorm. Africa’s tapestry of
rich cultural traditions is an adequate reference point for developing such basic
278
Olivier G & Olivier M, ‘Models of regional integration: The European Union and the African Union’,
SA Public Law. 19/1 (2004) 362.
279
Dare O, ‘Up from misbegotten orthodoxies’. The Nation (Nigeria) 4, November, 2008. Available at
http://www.thenationonlineng.com/dynamicpage.asp?id=68527 (Accessed 4 November, 2008).
280
This phrase is used to describe African leaders who have decided to rule perpetually.
281
Ake C, ‘The unique case of African democracy’ International Affairs. 69/2 (1993) 242.
282
Ibid, 242-4. Nyerere defines African democracy as ‘government by discussion’. See Nyerere (1966)
104.
283
Ibid, 244.
66
norms. The challenge is thus to devise a framework for achieving this. (This
point will be fully elaborated upon in subsequent chapters).
c) Technology imperative
Envisaging an integrated Africa in the 21st century without adequate
consideration of the development of Information and Communication
Technology (ICT) simply amounts, at the very best, to a pipe dream. Africa can
safely be classified as what De Wet refers to as a ‘technology colony’.284 He
observes that although many developing countries have gained political
independence, they are yet to achieve technology independence, that is, the
technological know-how necessary for economic development.285 To put it
simply, Africa operates at the periphery of global technological innovation.
Painting the dire state of technology on the continent, a NEPAD report views:
67
process of collaboration on academic, leisure and business projects across the
continent. Since integration also requires cooperation of interest and voluntary
groups across frontiers, technology will help create a platform for enhancing
such initiatives. These points are not lost on architects of African integration,
hence the initiative to establish a submarine optic fibre ring around Africa
coastline.288
288
See NEPAD ICT Document; see also ‘East African Submarine Optic Fibre Project’. Available at
http://www.icglr.org/common/docs/docs_repository/3310eassy.pdf (Accessed 30 October 2008).
289
The following are examples of such initiatives: SAT-3/SAFE; GLO-1; AWCC; SEACOM; EASSy; and
TEAMS. See African Economic Outlook (2009) 90-93; see also ‘Banding together’. BBC Focus on Africa
(April-June 2009) 44-46.
290
African Economic Outlook (2009) 101; see also
http://www.zain.com/muse/obj/lang.default/portal.view/content/About%20us/Worldwide%20Presence/Afri
ca-13%20countries (Accessed 25 November 2008).
291
See African Economic Outlook (2009) 93-95. Between 2000 and 2007, record shows that private
investment in African telecommunication rose from USD5.4 billion to USD13.5 billion. See Ibid, 96.
According to the Secretary General of the International Telecommunications Union (ITU), about USD8
billion was invested in the development of ICT in Africa in 2008. Available at
http://allafrica.com/stories/200909140463.html (Accessed 1 November 2009).
68
However, for ICT to efficiently play a significant role in shaping the integration
process, more needs to be done. While the harmonisation of ICT policies in
Africa remains the ultimate objective, it is essential to consider some preliminary
measures. In order to guarantee the confidence of potential and current
investors, it is essential that African governments grant more powers and
autonomy to national regulatory agencies.292 As Gasmi et al note, the
independence of regulatory institutions should not be considered in isolation but
rather as part of a broader strategy of good governance.293 The independence
of regulatory institutions cannot be gauged by merely observing a change in
structure; instead the general environment within which they operate must
conform to democratic ideals and standards.294
292
See African Economic Outlook (2009) 95-96.
293
Gasmi F, Noumba Um P, Recuero Vito P, ‘Political accountability and regulatory performance in
infrastructure industries: An empirical analysis’. World Bank Economic Review (2009) 20.
294
Ibid.
69
d) External imperatives
The external dimension or influence on integration cannot be understated. For
example, the European integration came about as a result of a geo-political
reaction to what De Gaulle referred to as the ‘two hegemonies’: the Soviet
Union and the United States of America.295 In the same vein, the US provided
the financial assistance for the economic reconstruction of Europe, a move
which provided a much needed fillip for the integration experiment.296 As Africa
grapples with integrative issues in the 21st century, the influence of external
actors and conditions will play a huge role in shaping this discourse. The shift in
global balance of power, or what Cilliers refers to as the ‘rise of the rest’,297 will
no doubt impact on Africa. Also, the increasing relevance of the EU, especially
as a model and as a global force, will provide useful and sober parallels for
integration initiatives across the continent.
The (economic) rise of countries like India, China and Brazil, especially in
relation to their quest for Africa’s natural resources, has key implications not
295
See Hoffmann S, ‘Obstinate or obsolete? The fate of the nation-states and the case of Western Europe’
in Cantori & Spiegel (1970) 81.
296
The Marshall Plan (known officially as the European Recovery Programme), an initiative named after
US Secretary of State George Marshall, was a post World War II economic recovery plan for Europe. As
Hogan puts it:
The strategic assumption behind this policy held that an integrated economic order,
particularly one headed by supranational institutions, would help control German
nationalism, reconcile Germany’s recovery with France’s economic and security
concerns, and thus create a balance of power in the West sufficient to contain Soviet
power in the East. The economic assumptions grew fundamentally out of the American
experience at home, where a large internal economy integrated by free-market forces and
central institutions of coordination and control seemed to have laid a ground work for a
new era of economic and social stability. An economic United States of Europe would
bring similar benefits…and in the process would realise all of their goals on the continent.
See Hogan M, The marshall plan: America, Britain, and the reconstruction of Western Europe, 1947-1952.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (1987) 27.
297
See Cilliers J, Africa in the new world: How global and domestic developments will impact by 2025.
Pretoria: Institute of Security Studies (2008) 18. See also Zakariah F, The post-American world. New
York: W.W Norton (2009). This reality is poignantly painted in a report published by the US National
Intelligence Council (2008) titled - Global trends 2025: A transformed world – The national intelligence
council’s 2025 project. The report, amongst other provisions, predicts that the rules of the international
system and global architecture would change as a result of the emergence of new players like Brazil, India,
Russia and China. Available at http://www.dni.gov/nic/PDF_2025/2025_Global_Trends_Final_Report.pdf
(Accessed 25 November 2008).
70
only for individual African countries but also for the continent as a whole. The
volume of investment by the so-called ‘non-traditional financiers’, of which
China and India are key role players, illuminates the potential for infrastructure
development necessary for regional integration.298 According to a World Bank
report (2008), the sizeable investments of these Asian giants in infrastructural
projects, helps to fill the gap of annual infrastructure deficit estimated at US$22
billion.299 Analysts have viewed that this changing investment landscape
portends a replacement of the (in) famous ‘Washington consensus’ with an
equally suspicious ‘Beijing consensus’.300 While the former hinges the
deployment of aid to democratic governance, the latter accentuates non-
interference in the domestic affairs of states.301 In a continent where democratic
governance is an exception rather than the norm, the ‘Beijing consensus’
represents not only a boost for autocrats but also a de-emphasis of the
centrality of democracy and rule of law in the integration process.
e) Other imperatives
As stated previously, the foregoing discussion is not an exhaustive outline of
African integration issues, since more will be discussed in subsequent chapters;
however, it represents some of the fundamental issues that will shape this
discourse. African integration draws a lot of scepticism, notably as a result of
issues such as absence of democratic practise, levels of intra-African trade and
the smallness of African markets. The experiences of past and present
experiments should serve as a useful navigation tool (This will be discussed in
the next chapter). Obsession with theories, including debates over their
practicability in the African context, has in a way eclipsed the focus on devising
other strategies for integrating the continent. As Schoeman, for example
298
China’s investment in Africa peaked at USD8 billion in 2006, an amount four times that of India, and
dropped to USD5 billion in 2007. See Foster V, Butterfield W, Chen C & Pushak N, Building bridges:
China’s role as infrastructure financier for Africa. World Bank (2008) 52. Available at
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTAFRICA/Resources/Building_Bridges_Master_Version_wo-
Embg_with_cover.pdf (Accessed 20 November 2008); see also Cilliers (2008) 24-25.
299
Foster et al (2008) 23.
300
Alden C, ‘China in Africa’. African Security Review. 17/1 (2008) 122.
301
Ibid; see also Foster et al (2008) 6.
71
observes, the emphasis should shift from the volume of intra-African
transactions (quantity) to the beneficial value of such transaction (quality).302
Illustratively, the emphasis could be on strengthening the position of Africa in
international forums by articulating a common agenda on issues concerning the
welfare of the continent.303 Also, regional powers can play an important role in
the field of human resources by sending experts to countries in shortage of
necessary skills. Such cooperation will help foster cooperation between African
states.
2.4 Summary
The search for alternatives to guarantee continental peace and economic
prosperity in Europe after the Second World War gave birth to regional
integration and its different theories. At the core of regional integration - be it in
the developed or the developing world - lies the need for peace, security and
meaningful development. The developmental feature of regional integration, as
experienced in Europe, provides a concrete proof for its adoption.
72
operandi of integration in Africa. Lastly, this chapter argues that in spite of the
utilitarian feature of integration, the continent should chart its own integration
trajectory, based on experiences and peculiarities. The next chapter will
examine some of the experiments of supranationalism within the African
context.
73