Economic
Economic
Economic
M THE
EMA ATIC
CS F
FOR
E ONO
ECO OMIIC A
ANAALYSSIS –II
IIII Sem
mester
CO
OMPLE
EMENT
TARY COURS
C E
B ECON
BA E NOM
MICS
(20
011 Adm
mission))
U VERS
UNIV SITY OF
O CALIC
C CUT
SCH
HOOL OF
F DISTAN
NCE EDU
UCATION
N
Calicut Un
niversity P.O. Malapp
puram, Kerrala, India 673
6 635
38
86
School of Distance Education
UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT
SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION
STUDY MATERIAL
COMPLEMENTARY COURSE
III Semester
Scrutinised by: Dr. C. Krishnan,
Associate Professor ,
Department of Economics,
Govt. College, Kodanchery.
Layout: Computer Section, SDE
©
Reserved
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 2
School of Distance Education
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 3
School of Distance Education
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 4
School of Distance Education
CHAPTER 1
I. 1: LIMITS
r=5+
A function f(x) is said to approach the limit ‘L’ as ‘x’ approach to ‘a’ if the
difference between f(x) and ‘L’ can be made as small as possible by taking ‘x’ sufficiently
nearer to ‘a’.
lim
→
lim 2 16
→
i.e., the difference between x2 and 16 can be made as small as possible by taking ‘x’
sufficiently nearer to 4.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 5
School of Distance Education
Rules of Limits
1. If K is a constant
lim
→
lim
→
3. If ‘K’ is a constant
lim lim
→ →
lim → 0]
Examples
2. lim 2 52 25 [Rule 2]
→
= 23 + 3 x 2 = 8 + 6 = 14
lim
5. 8 5 lim 8 . lim 5 [Rule 5]
→ →
→
= (4 + 8)(4 - 5) = -12
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 6
School of Distance Education
6. 4 2 5 10 [Rule 6]
lim lim 4 2 5 10 lim 10 5
→ 10 5 → →
= =
7. If f(x) = (x + 2) [Rule 7]
lim 22 lim 2 2 3 2 2 52 25
→ →
INDETERMINATE FORM
∴ write
–
= =x+3=6
Here to find the limit value we have to divide the numerator and denominator by
x2
1
lim
→ α 1
=
Since, → 0 as x → α
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 7
School of Distance Education
We get =1
========
= = = =
======
Problems:
4. Find lim [Ans: 8]
→
6. Find lim [Ans: ]
→
1.2 CONTINUITY
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 8
School of Distance Education
Conditions for continuity
3. lim
→
Y
Y
f(x)
g(x)
If the conditions for continuity are not satisfied for any value of x, f(x) is said to be
discontinuous for that value of ‘x’.
∴f(x) is continuous for any value of ‘a’ except 2 and f(x) is not continuous at a = 2.
Problems:
Indicate whether the following function is continuous at the specific points.
1. f(x) = 5x2 – 8x + 9 at x = 3
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 9
School of Distance Education
lim 30 = f(3)
→
∴ f(x) is continuous at x = 3.
2. f(x) = at x = 3
f(3) = =
3 3
lim 2 lim
→ 9 → 3 3
= lim =
→
lim = ≠ f(3)
→
∴ f(x) is discontinuous at x = 3.
[Ans: Continuous]
The slope of a curvilinear function is differ from point to point; i.e., the slope of
each point is different. The slope at a given point is measured by the slope of a line
tangent to the function at that point. So in order to measure the slope of a curvilinear
function at different points we requires separate tangent lines.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 10
School of Distance Education
Y Secant line S
Y
Tangent line
f(x) 3 ∆Y 3 Y2 = f(x1 + ∆x)
g(x)
2 ∆X 3
∆Y 2
∆X 2
1 Y1 = f(x1)
∆Y 1
∆X 1
X1 ∆X X2= x1 + ∆x
Fig 1.3 x Fig 1.4
The slope of a tangent line is derived from the slopes of a family of secant lines
(secant line ‘S’ is a straight line that intersects a curve at two points.)
Slope S =
∆
Slope S =
∆
∆
=
∆
If the distance between x2 and x1 is made smaller and smaller ie. if ∆x → 0, the
secant line pivots back to the left and draws progressively closer to the tangent line. If
the slope of the secant line approaches a limit as ∆x → 0, the limit is the slope of the
tangent line T, which is also the slope of the function at that point.
∆
Slop T= lim
∆ → ∆
Ans.
∆
Slop T= lim
∆ → ∆
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 11
School of Distance Education
∆
Slope T = lim
∆ → ∆
∆x 2 is in the a
∆ ∆
= lim [ x b 2 form
∆ → ∆
∆ ∆
= lim
∆ → ∆
∆ ∆
= lim
∆ → ∆
∴ Slope = 8x
=====
1.4 THE DERIVATIVE
Given the function y = f(x), the derivative of f(x) with respect to x is the function
f’(x) and is defined as
∆ –
f’(x) = lim Here f’(x) is the derivative of ‘f’ with respect to ‘x.
∆ → ∆
Example:
Find the derivative of the following function using the definition of the
derivative f(x) = 4x2 + 10x + 25.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 12
School of Distance Education
4 ∆ 10 ∆ 25 4 10 25
lim
∆ ∆
4 2 ∆ ∆ 10 10∆ 25 4 10 25
lim
∆ ∆
4 8 ∆ 4 ∆ 10 10∆ 25 4 10 25
lim
∆ ∆
8 ∆ 4 ∆ 10∆
lim
∆ ∆
f(x) r P
q q
P r
O a b Y
fig.1.5
In the fig.1.5 f(x) is not differentiable at ‘a’ because gap exist in the function at that
point, and the derivative cannot be taken at any point where the function is
discontinuous.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 13
School of Distance Education
Continuity alone does not ensure differentiability. In the above figure f(x) is
continuous at ‘b’, but it is not differentiable at ‘b’ because at a sharp point or kink (cusp)
an infinite number of tangent lines line such as pp, qq, rr in the figure can be drawn.
There is no one unique tangent line for that sharp point or kink.
Then = 0
Ex. If y = 10 =0
The derivative of the product of a constant and a function is equal to the product
of the constant and the derivative of the function.
= =
Then = = = m
Example
=10
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 14
School of Distance Education
Rule No. 3: The Power Function Rule
Examples
(1) y = ; =5 =5
(2) y = =-4× = 4 =
=5 3 5
(3) y = , 3
= 52 = 52
(4) y= ,
The derivative of a sum of two function is simply equal to the sum of the separate
derivatives.
Ex. 1:
If y = +6 - 5x + 10
= + 6 5 10
=3 +6 - s x+ 10
=3 12 5
=========
Ex. 2
If y = 10 3 +4 +10 +5find
= 60 + 12 - 12 + 20x
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 15
School of Distance Education
Rule No.5: Subtraction Rule
The derivative of a difference of two functions is equal to the difference of the separate
derivates.
If y = u – v then
= - (ie derivative of the first function – minus the derivative of the second
function)
Ex. 1
If y = -4 -6 +10
= -4 - 6 + 10
= 5 - 12 - 12x
=========
Ex. 2
If Q = 20 -2 - 4P - 50 find
20 -2 -4 P- 50
= 60 –8 –4
=====
Then
(u.v) = u +v
Ex. 1
If y = 3 2 5 find
=12 , =2
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 16
School of Distance Education
= (3 2) + (2x-5) 12
=6 + 24 - 60
= 30 - 60
=====
Ex.2
Find if y = ( )
=u + v.
The derivative of the quotient of two functions is equal to the denominator multiplied by
the derivative of the numerator minus the numerator multiplied by the derivative of the
denominator, all divided by the square of the Denominator.
.
=
Ex. 1.
Given f(x) = find
here u =5 = 15
v = 4x + 3 =4
=
40 45
= 4 3
Ex.2.
If y = find
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 17
School of Distance Education
u= = 6
V = = 3
=
= =
If ‘y’ is the function of ‘u’ where ‘u’ is the function of ‘x’,then the derivative of ‘y’
with respect to ‘x’ ie is equal to the product of the derivative of ‘y’ with respect to ‘u’
and the derivative of ‘u’ with respect to ‘x’.
then =
Ex. 1
If y = 7u + 3 and u = 5 find
=
= = 7, 10x
= 7×10x = 70x
Ex.2
If y = 5 3 find using the chain rule
Let u = 5 3
y=
=
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 18
School of Distance Education
= 4 = 10x
=4 10
= 40x 5 3
[Ans : 21 ]
Problem 2. Find If y = 3
[Ans: 6 + 24 +18x]
Rule No.9: Parametric Function Rule
If both ‘x’ and ‘y’ are the differential function of ‘t’ then the derivative of ‘y’ with
respect to ‘x’ is obtained by dividing the derivative of ‘y’ with respect to ‘t’ by the
derivative of ‘x’ with respect to ‘t’. ie. If x = f(x) and y = g(t) then
= = ÷
Examples
Find if x = and y =4at
= 4a =4
= =
The derivative of Exponential function is the exponential itself, if the base of the function
is ‘e’, the natural base of an exponential.
If y = , then =
If y = , then =
If y = , then =
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 19
School of Distance Education
Examples
1. If y = find
= 2
If y = , where u = g(x), then
= . =
Examples
Ex. 1
Find if y =
Let u = 3, then = 2x
y=
= = 2x
=2x since u = +2
=====
Ex. 2
Find if y =
Let u = = 2x
= 2x
=====
Ex. 3
Find if y =
[Ans : ( ) (12 +12x)
log
= =
If y = log u, when u = g(x), then
= .
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 20
School of Distance Education
= · = ·
Y = log u since x3 = u
= · 3x2
= · 3x2 since u = x3
= =
Rule No. 12: Differentiation of One function with respect to another Function
Let f(x) and g(x) be two functions of ‘x’ then derivative of f(x) with respect to g(x)
is
=
x2 1 = 2x
= =1
x2 5x = 2x + 5
=
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 21
School of Distance Education
3. Differentiate with respect to
Let u =
=
Let u
=
=
= =
The derivative of the inverse function (ie )is equal to the reciprocal of the
ie =
Examples:
= 5x4
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 22
School of Distance Education
= =
y = (x2 + 2) (x2 + 4)
=
4x3 12x
It measures the slope and the rate of change of the first derivative, just as the first
derivative measures the slope and the rate of change of the original or primitive function.
The third order derivative measures the slope and the rate of change of the second
order derivative etc.
Ex. If f(x) = 5x4 + 4x3 + 3x2 + 10x
′ = 20x3 + 12x2 + 6x + 10
″ = 60x2 + 24x + 6
= 120x + 24
120
Problems
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 23
School of Distance Education
1.9 IMPLICIT DIFFERENTIATION
An equation y = 10x2+5x+2 directly expresses ‘y’ in terms of ‘x’. Hence this
function is called ‘Explicit Function’.
As equation x3y + xy + 2x = 0 does not directly express ‘y’ in terms of ‘x’. This
types of function is called ‘Implicit Function’. Some implicit functions can be easily
converted to explicit function by solving for the dependent variable in terms of the
independent variable, others cannot. For those not readily convertible, the derivative
may be found by implicit differentiation.
In order to find the derivative of implicit function every term in both sides of the
function is to be differentiated with respect to ‘x’.
Examples:
1. Find of the following 3x-2y = 4
= 3x - 2y = 4
=3–2 = 0
= -2 = -3
= = 3/2 = 1.5
4x2 - y3 = 97
4x2 = 8x, 97 = 0
y3 =3.y2
= 3y2
The derivative of the function is
8x – 3y2 =0
– 3y2 = -8x
= =
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 24
School of Distance Education
3. Find the derivative of the function 3y5 – 6y4 + 5x6 = 243 [Ans: ]
A function is and increasing function if the value of the function increases with an
increase in the value of the independent variable and decrease with a decrease in the
value of the independent variable.
For a function y f(x)
When x1 < x2 then f(x1) ≤f(x2) the function is increasing
When x1 < x2 then f(x1) < f(x2) the function is strictly increasing
A function is a decreasing function if the value of the function increases with a fall
in the value of independent variable and decrease with an increase in the value of
independent variable.
For a function y = f(x)
When x1 < x2 then f(x1) ≥ f(x2) the function is decreasing
When x1 < x2 then f(x1) > f(x2) the function is strictly decreasing
The derivative of a function can be applied to check whether given function is an
increasing function or decreasing function in a given interval.
If the sign of the first derivative is positive, it means that the value of the function
f(x) increase as the value of independent variable increases and vice versa.
i.e. a function y = f(x) differentiable in the interval [a, b] is said to be an increasing
function if and only if its derivatives an [a, b] is non negative.
i.e. > 0 in the interval [a, b]
The derivative of a curve at a point also measures the slope of the tangent to the
curve at that point. If the derivative is positive, then it means that the tangent has a
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 25
School of Distance Education
positive slope and the function (curve) increases as the value of the independent variable
increase. Similar interpretation is given to the to the decreasing function and negative
slope of the tangent.
A function that increases or decreases over its entire domain is called monotonic
function.
Y Fig. 1.7
Y Fig. 1.6
O a X O b X
Solution: 3x3 3x2 x – 10
= 9x2 + 6x + 1 = (3x+1)2
The function is always positive because (3x+1)2 is positive since square of a real
number is always positive. Therefore the function is increasing.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 26
School of Distance Education
1.11 CONCAVITY AND CONVEXITY
Convex Function
A function is convex at x = a if in an area very close to [a, f(a)] the graph of the
function lies completely above its tangent line.
″
i.e. if second derivative of a function f(x) is positive i.e. > 0, the function is
said to be a convex function in the given interval.
″
> 0 f(x) is convex at x = a.
Y Fig. 1.9
Y Fig. 1.8
O a X O a X
′ ″ ′ ″
> 0, >0 < 0, >0
Concave Function
A function f(x) is concave at x = a if in some small region close to the point [a, f(a)]
the graph of the function lies completely below its tangent line.
″
i.e. if the second derivative of a function f(x) is negative i.e. < 0 , then the
function is said t be a concave function in the given interval.
″
< 0, f(x) is concave at x = a.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 27
School of Distance Education
Y
Y
O a X O a X
Fig. 1.11
Fig. 1.10
′ ″
′
> 0, ″
<0 < 0, <0
Example: 1
Show that the curve of y = 2x – 3 +1 convex from below for all positive values of
x.
Solution:
Y = 2x – 3 + 1
=2-1
=2
Since =2 > 0 for x > 0 the curve is convex from below for all positive
values of x.
Example: 2
Show that the demand curve P = – 8 is downward sloping and convex from
below
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 28
School of Distance Education
=
= is positive, the demand curve is convex from below.
Example:3
Test to see if the following functions are concave or convex at x = 3
(a) Y = -2x3 + 4x2 + 9x – 15 [Ans: Concave]
(b) Y = (5x2 – 8)2 [Ans: Convex]
″
(a) > 0 shows function is convex, graphs of function lies completely above its
tangent line at x = a and the function is at a relative minimum at x = a.
″
(b) < 0 shows function is concave, graphs of function lies completely below its
tangent line at x = a and the function is at a relative maximum at x = a.
″
(c) = 0, the test is inconclusive.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 29
School of Distance Education
Y
Y
O a X O a X
Fig. 1.13
Fig. 1.12
Relative Minimum at x = a Relative Maximum at x = a
Ex. 1
Find the relative extrema for the following functions by (a) finding the critical
value (b) determining if at the critical values the function is at a relative maximum or
minimum
(a)
f(x) = -7x2 + 126x – 23
′ = -14x + 126
x
x = 9 critical value
″ = -14
x
″ = -14 < 0 concave, relative minimum
x
(b)
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 30
School of Distance Education
1.13 INFLECTION POINTS
An inflection point is a point on the graph where the function crosses its tangent
line and changes from concave to convex or vice versa.
Inflective points occurs only where the second derivative equals zero or is
undefined. The sign of the first derivative is immaterial.
Conditions
1. ″ a = 0 or is undefined
2. Concavity changes at x = a
3. Graph crosses its tangent line at x = a
a a a
a ′
a =0 ′
a <0 ′
a >0
′
a =0 ″
a =0 ″
a =0 ″
a =0
″
a =0
Example:
For the following function find the critical values and test to see it at the critical
values the function is at a relative maximum, minimum or possible inflection point.
If y = (5 = x)3
′
= 3(5-x)2 -1 = -3(5 – x)2 = 0
X = 5 critical value.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 31
School of Distance Education
″
= 6 (5 – x)
″
(5) = 6(5 – 5) = 0 test inconclusive
Since the second derivative is zero the function is at an inflection point at x = 5 not
relative maximum or minimum.
1.14 CURVE SKETCHING
Whether we are interested in function as a purely mathematical object or in
connection with some application to the real world; it is often useful to know what the
graphs of the function looks like. We can obtain a good picture of the graph using certain
crucial information provided by derivatives of the function and certain limits. Curve
sketching is a practical application of differential calculus. We can make a fairly accurate
sketch of any function using derivatives.
By using the first and second derivatives we can determine whether a function is
maxima or minima at a particular value of ‘x’ the concavity of the function, the point of
inflection etc.
The General guide lines for curve Sketching
The following steps are helpful when sketching curves. Since they are the general
guidelines for all curve, each step may not always apply to all functions.
(a) Domain: Find the domain of the function. This will be useful when finding
vertical asymptotes and determining critical numbers.
(b) Intercepts: Find the ‘x’ and ‘y’ intercepts of the function if possible. To find the ‘x’
intercept, we set y = 0 and solve the equation for x. Similarly for ‘y’.
(c) Symmetry: Determine whether the function is an odd function, an even function
or neither odd nor even. If f(-x) = f(x) for all ‘x’ in the domain, then function is
even and symmetric about the ‘y’ axis. If f(x) = -f(x) for all ‘x’ in the domain, then
the function is odd and symmetric about the origin.
(d) Asymptotes: For vertical asymptotes, check for rational functions zero
denominators, or undefined by function points. For horizontal asymptotes,
consider lim
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 32
School of Distance Education
(g) Concavity and points of Inflection: Determine when ″ x is positive and
negative to find the intervals where the function is concave upward and concave
″
downward and also determine inflection point checking where x = 0 or
″′
x does not exist.
(h) Plot intercepts, critical points, inflection points, asymptotes, and other points as
needed.
(i) Connect plotted points with smooth curve.
1.15 OPTIMIZATION OF FUNCTION
Optimization is the process of finding the relative maximum or minimum of a
function. Without the help of graph, this is done with the techniques of relative extrema
and inflection points.
Steps
(1) Take the first derivative, set it equal to zero, and solve for the critical points. This
step is known as necessary condition or first order conditions. It shows the
function is neither increasing no decreasing; but at a plateau at that level of ‘x’.
(2) Take the second derivative, evaluate it at the critical point and check the signs. If
at a critical point ‘a’.
″
< 0, the function is concave at ‘a’ and hence at a relative maximum.
″
> 0, the function is convex at ‘a’ and hence at a relative minimum.
″
= 0, the test is inconclusive.
This test is known as second order condition or sufficient condition.
= 6(x-3)(x-7) = 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 33
School of Distance Education
X = 3, x = 7
″
= 12x – 60
″
3 = 12 3 – 60 = -24 < 0 concave, relative maximum
″
7 = 12 7 – 60 = 24 > 0 convex, relative minimum.
If TR = TR (Q); then MR =
Examples: 1
If TC = 25Q2 + 7Q + 10
Then MC = = 50Q + 7
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 34
School of Distance Education
If TR = 50Q - 2Q2
Then MR = = 50 - 4Q
Ex. 2
Given the demand function P = 50 – 5Q, then the marginal revenue function can
be found by first finding the total revenue function and then taking the derivative of the
function with respect to Q.
Demand function P = 50 - 5Q
TR = P Q = (50 – 5Q)Q
= 50Q – 5Q2
MR = = 50 – 10Q
Ex. 3
Find maximum profits ‘π’ for a firm, given total revenue R = 4000Q – 33Q2 and
total cost function C = 2Q3 – 3Q2 + 400Q + 5000, assuming Q > 0.
Profit function: π = R – C
Π = (4000Q – 33Q2 )– (2Q3 – 3Q2 + 400Q + 5000)
= -2Q3 – 30Q2 + 3600Q – 5000
Taking the first derivative, set it equal to zero, and solving this for Q we get
critical points.
′ = -6Q2 – 60Q + 3600 = 0
= -6(Q2 + 10Q + 600) = 0
= -6(Q + 30)(Q – 20) = 0
Q = -30 Q = 20 critical points
[We can also use Quadratic formula]
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 35
School of Distance Education
The function is concave and relative maximum. It means profit is maximum at Q = 20
When Q=20 the profit π is
π(20) = 2(20)3 – 30(20)2 + 3600(20) – 5000 = 39000
Ex. 4
Maximize the following total revenue TR function by finding the critical values,
testing the second order conditions and calculating the maximum TR If TR = 32Q – Q2
TR = 32Q – Q2
TR′ = 32 – 2Q
Setting TR′ = 0, 32 – 2Q = 0
32 = 2Q Q 32/2 = 16 critical value
AR = = = 15 – Q
MR = TR′ = = 15 – 2Q
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 36
School of Distance Education
MR when Q=7.5 is 15-2(7.5)=15-15=0
Ex. 6.
From the total cost function TC = Q3 – 5Q2 + 60Q find (1) the average cost AC
function (2) the critical value at which AC is minimized and (3) the minimum average
cost.
TC = Q3 – 5Q2 + 60Q
(1) AC = = = Q2 – 5Q + 60
(2) AC is minimum at
AC′ = 2Q – 5 = 0, Q = 2.5
Ex. 7:
A firm has the following total cost, C and demand function Q
C = 1/3 Q3 – 7Q2 + 111 Q + 50 and P = 100 – Q
(1) Write down the total revenue function R in terms of Q
(2) Formulate the total profit function
(1) Price function P = 100 – Q
Revenue = P Q
The revenue function is R = PQ = 100Q – Q2
(2) Profit function is TR – TC functions
= (100Q – Q2) – (1/3 Q3 – 7Q2 + 111Q + 50)
Π = -1/3 Q3 + 6Q2 – Q – 50
Ex. 8.
A producer has the possibility of discriminating between the domestic and foreign
markets for a product where the demands functions are
Q1 = 24 – 0.2P1 Q2 = 10 – 0.05P2
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 37
School of Distance Education
Where TC = 35 + 40Q, what price will be firm charge (a) with discrimination and
(b) without discrimination.
(a) With discrimination
Q1 = 24 – 0.2P1
(Multiply with 5 to get 1P1)
5Q1 = 120 – P1
P1 = 120 – 5Q1
TR1 = (120 – 5Q1)Q1 = 120Q1 -5 Q12
MR1 = 120 – 10Q1
The firm will maximize profit where MC = MR1 = MR2
TC = 35 + 40 Q
MC = 40
When MC = MR1, 40 = 120 – 10 Q1, Q1 = 8
When Q1 = 8, P1 = 120 – 5(8) = 80
In the second market with Q2 = 10 – 0.05P2
Multiplying with 20 on both sides
20 Q2 = 200 – P2
P2 = 200 – 20 Q2
TR2 = (200 – 20 Q2) Q2 = 200 Q2 - 20 Q22
MR2 = 200 – 40 Q2
When MC = MR2, 40 = 200 - 40 Q2
Q2 = 4
P2 = 200 – 20(4) = 120
Hence P1 = 80, P2 = 120, Q1 = 8, Q2 = 4
(b) If the producer does not discriminate, P1 = P2 = P and two demand function can be
combines as follows.
Q = Q1 + Q2 = 24 – 0.2 P + 10 – 0.05 P
= 34 – 0.25P
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 38
School of Distance Education
P = 136 – 4Q
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 39
School of Distance Education
CHAPTER 2
CALCULUS AND MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS
It is evident that all sciences are concerned with large number of inter-related
variable quantities and that only by a process of severe simplification can functional
relations between two variables be applied at all. For example, in economics, when one
individual considers his purchases on a market, the demand for any good depends, not
only on the price of the good, but also on his money income and on the prices of related
goods.
∆ , ,
= lim∆
∆
, ∆ ,
= lim∆
∆
Example 1:
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 40
School of Distance Education
When finding (or fx), we must bear in mind that y is to be treated as a constant
during differentiation. As such, y will drop out in the process if it is an additive constant
(such as the term 4y2), but will be retained if it is a multiplicative constant (such as in
term xy). Thus we have
= fx = 6x + y
= fx = x + 8y
Example 2:
Given z = f(u, v) = (u + 4) (3u + 2v), the partial derivatives can be found by use of
the product rule. By holding v constant, we have
fu = [(u+4) 3] + [1 (3u+2v)]
= 2(3u+v+6)
fv = [(u+4)2] + 0(3u+2v)
= 2(u+4)
Example 3:
Given z = (3x – 2y)/(x2 + 3y), the partial derivatives can be found by use of the
quotient rule.
= fx =
=
= fy =
=
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 41
School of Distance Education
2.2 RULES OF PARTIAL DIFFERENTIATION
Partial derivatives follow the same basic patterns as the rules of differentiation in
one-variable case. A few key rules are given below.
1. Product Rule:
Given z = g(x, y) h (x, y)
= g(x, y) + h (x, y)
= g(x, y) + h (x, y)
Example:
= 6x + 10 + 6x + 18y
= 12x + 18y + 10
= 18x + 30 + 0
= 18x + 30
2. Quotient Rule
,
Given z =
,
, ,
=
,
, ,
=
,
Example:
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 42
School of Distance Education
=
=
=
=
=
=
Given z = ,
=n ,
=n ,
Example:
Given z = 9
=5 9 4
= 20 9
=5 9 18
= 90y 9
Given a function z = f(x, y), the second-order (direct) partial derivative signifies
that the function has been differentiated partially with respect to one of the independent
variables, twice while the other independent variable has been held constant.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 43
School of Distance Education
= = fxx
= = fyy
In effect, fxx measures the rate of change of the first order partial derivative fx with
respect to x while y is held constant. And fyy measures the rate of change of the first-
order partial derivative fy with respect to y while x is held constant.
The cross (or mixed) partial derivatives fxy and fyx indicate that first the primitive
function has been partially differentiated with respect to one independent variable and
then that partial derivative in turn been partially differentiated with respect to the other
independent variable.
fxy = =
fyx = =
By young’s theorem, if both cross partial derivatives are continuous, they will be
identical.
Example:
The first, second, and cross partial derivatives for z = 2x3 – 11x2y + 3y2
= fx = 6 22
= fy = 11 +6
= fyy = 6
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 44
School of Distance Education
Cross – partial derivatives
22
2
22
(1) The first – order partial derivatives must equal zero simultaneously. That is
= fx = 0
= fy = 0
This indicates that at the given point (a, b), called a critical point, the function is
neither increasing nor decreasing with respect to the principal axes but is at a relative
plateau.
(2) The second – order direct partial derivatives, when evaluated at the critical point (a,b)
must both be negative for a relative maximum and positive for a relative minimum. That
is,
= fxx < 0
When x = a and y = b, the
values derived from the first
= fyy < 0
condition
= fxx > 0
= fyy > 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 45
School of Distance Education
This ensures that from a relative plateau at (a, b) the function is concave and
moving downward in relation to the principal axes in the case of a maximum and convex
and moving upward in relation to the principal axes in the case of a minimum.
(3) The product of the second – order direct partial derivatives evaluated at the critical
point must exceed the product of the cross partial derivatives also evaluated at the
critical point. Since fxy = fyx by Young’s theorem, this condition can also be written as
If fxx . fyy – (fxy)2 < 0, the function is at an inflection point when fxx and fyy have
the same signs and the function is at a saddle point when fxx and fyy have different signs.
If fxx.fyy – (fxy)2 = 0 the test is inconclusive.
Example:
Find the critical points and test whether the function is at a relative maximum or
minimum, given
Z = 2y3 – x3 + 147x – 54y + 12
(a) Take the first – order partial derivatives, set them equal to zero, and solve for x and y
= -3x2 + 147 = 0
3x2 = 147
x2 = 49
x=±7
= 6y2 - 54 = 0
6y2 = 54
y2 = 9
y = ±3
With x = ±7, y =±3, there are four distinct sets of critical points:
(7, 3), (7, -3), (-7, 3), (-7, -3)
(b) Take the second – order direct partial derivatives, evaluate them at each of the critical
points, and check the signs
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 46
School of Distance Education
fxx = -6x
fyy = 12y
Since there are different signs for each of the second direct partials in (i) and (iv) ,
the function cannot be at a relative maximum or minimum at (7, 3) or (-7, -3). With both
signs of the second direct partial derivatives negative in (ii) and positive in (iii), the
function may be at a relative maximum at (7, -3) and at a relative minimum at (-7, 3), but
the third condition must be tested first to ensure against the possibility of an inflection
point.
(c) Take the cross partial derivatives and check to make sure that fxx . fyy – (fxy)2 > 0
fxy = 0
at (-7, 3)
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 47
School of Distance Education
= 0), multiplying it by (that is, [k – g(x, y)]), and adding the product to the original
function:
= Lx = 0
= Ly = 0
=L =0
Where
fxx =
|H| =
0
fyy =
fxy =
If all the principal minors are negative, the bordered Hessian is positive definite,
and a positive definite Hessian always satisfies the sufficient condition for a relative
minimum.
If all principal minors alternate consistently in sign from positive to negative, the
bordered Hessian is negative definite, and a negative definite Hessian always meets the
sufficient condition for a relative maximum.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 48
School of Distance Education
Example:
= Lx = 8x + 3y – =0
= Ly = 3x + 12y – =0
= L = 56 – x – y = 0
(6) Substituting the critical values (that is, x = 36, y = 20) in the objective function we get
= 9744
(7) To see whether this is relative minimum or maximum, we consider second – order
condition in terms of bordered Hessian.
8 3 1
|H| = 3 12 1
1 1 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 49
School of Distance Education
Starting with the second principal minor |H|
2.7 DIFFERENTIALS
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 50
School of Distance Education
dz = dx + dy
= +
Example:
Given z = x4 + 8y and y = x2 + 2x + 10, the total derivative with respect to x is
= +
= 4x3; = 8; = 2x + 2
Substituting, we get
= 4x3 + 8 (2x + 2)
= 4x3 + 16x + 16
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 51
School of Distance Education
2.10 IMPLICIT AND INVERSE FUNCTION RULES
Functions of the form y = f(x) express y explicitly in terms of x and are called
explicit functions. Functions of the form f(x, y) = 0 do not express y explicitly in terms of
x and are called implicit functions. For example, x2 + y2 = 16 is an implicit function
between x and y.
If an implicit function f(x, y) = 0 exists and 0 at the point around which the
implicit function is defined, the total differential is simply
+ =0
Since a derivative is a ratio of differentials, we can then rearrange the terms to get
the implicit function rule.
Notice that the derivative is the negative of the reciprocal of the corresponding
partial derivatives. That is,
1
= =
of the original function is , the derivative of the inverse function [x = f-1 (y)] is ,
and
= provided 0
Example 1:
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 52
School of Distance Education
=
=
Example 2:
Given y = 40 – 4p, find the derivative for the inverse of the function.
= =-
The marginal product of capital (MPk) is defined as the change in output brought
about by a small change in capital when all other factors of production are held constant.
Given a production function such as
Q = 36 KL – 2K2 – 3L2
MPK = = 36L – 4K
Similarly, the marginal product of labour (MPL) is measured by taking the partial
derivative .
That is,
MPL = = 36K – 6L
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 53
School of Distance Education
Example:
Find the marginal productivity of inputs x and y, given the production function
Q = x2+2xy+3y2
MPx = = 2x + 2y
MPy = = 2x + 6y
Income elasticity of demand y measures the percentage change in the demand for
a good resulting from a small percentage change in income, when all other variables are
held constant. Cross elasticity of demand c measures the relative responsiveness of the
demand for one product to changes in the price of another, when all other variables are
held constant. Given the demand function
Q1 = a – bP1 + cP2 + mY
Where y = income and P2 = the price of a substitute good, the income elasticity of
demand is
y
=
=m
=
– 1 2
c
=
=c
2
=
– 1 2
Example:
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 54
School of Distance Education
Qb = 4850 - 5Pb + 1.5 Pp + 0.1Y with Y = 10,000, Pb = 200, and the price of
pork Pp = 100.
y
=
= 0.1
.
=
4850 5 200 1.5 100 0.1 10000
=
4850 1000 150 1000
= 0.2
c
=
= 1.5
4850 5 200 1.5 100 0.1 10000
.
=
4850 5 200 1.5 100 0.1 10000
= 0.03
dz = dx
The effect of larger changes can be approximated by multiplying the partial derivative by
the proposed change. Thus
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 55
School of Distance Education
∆z ≈ ∆x
∆
=
∆
∆z = ∆x
Example:
A firm’s costs are related to its output of two goods x and y. The functional
relationship is
TC = x2 – 0.5xy + y2
dTC = MCx dx
= (2x – 0.5y)dx
∆TC ≈ ∆x
≈ (2x – 0.5y) ∆x
Example:
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 56
School of Distance Education
To find the profit-maximizing level of output for each of the two goods.
(a) Take the first order partial derivatives, set them equal to zero, and solve for x
and y simultaneously
Πx = 64 – 4x + 4y = 0
Πy = 4x – 8y + 32 = 0
When solved simultaneously, we get
X = 40 and y = 24
(b) Take the second-order direct partial derivatives and make sure both are
negative, as is required for a relative maximum.
Πxx = -4 < 0
Πyy = -8 < 0
(c) Take the cross partial derivatives to make sure that Πxx Πyy – (Πxy)2 > 0
Example:
Find the critical values for minimizing the costs of a firm producing two goods x
and y when the total cost function is C = 8x2 – xy + 12y2 and the firm is bound by contract
to produce a minimum combination of goods totaling 42, that is subject to the constraint
x + y = 42.
(b) Take the first order partial derivatives and set them equal to zero.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 57
School of Distance Education
Lx = 16x – y – =0
Ly = -x +24y – =0
L = 42 – x – y = 0
(d) Consider the second-order condition in terms of bordered Hessian |H|to ensure
that the critical values x = 25, y = 17 and = 383 minimizes the function
16 1 1
|H| = 1 24 1
1 1 0
= 4621
MUx = = 6x + 5y
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 58
School of Distance Education
Similarly, the marginal utility of commodity y (MUy) is measured by taking the
partial derivative . That is
MUy = = 5x + 12 y
U = 3x2y + 5xy2 + 7
The MRSxy is measured by taking the ratio of partial derivatives of the utility function
with respect to x and y. That is
6 5 2
MRSxy = =
3 2 10
The negative sign prefixed indicates that an increase in x should result in a decrease in y.
Q = AL K
The MRTSLK is measured by taking the ratio of partial derivatives of the production
function with respect to labour and capital. That is,
MRTSLK = =
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 59
School of Distance Education
CHAPTER III
SPECIAL DETERMINANTS AND MATRICES IN ECONOMICS
3.1. THE JACOBIAN
Then, |J|=
Note that the elements of each row we the partial derivatives of one function with
respect to each of the independent variables x1, x2, …… If |J|=0, the equations we
functionally dependent and if |J| ≠ 0, the equations we functionally independent.
,
Sometimes Jacobian is also expressed as |J| =
,
Example 1:
Y1 = 2x1 + 3x2
|J| =
=2
= 3
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 60
School of Distance Education
= 8x1 + 12x2
= 12x1 + 18x2
2 3
∴|J| =
8x1 12x2 12x1 18x2
|J| = 0
Example 2:
Use Jacobian to test for functional dependence for the following system of equations
Y1 = 6x1 + 4x2
Y2 = 7x1 + 9x2
|J| =
=6
= 4
=7
=9
6 4
∴|J| =
7 9
|J|= 26
========
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 61
School of Distance Education
Example 3:
Y1 = x12 - 3x2 + 5
|J| =
= 2x1
= -3
= 4x13 – 12x1x2
= -6x12 + 18x2
2x1 3
∴|J| = 3
4x1 – 12x1x2 6x12 18x2
|J| = 0
Example 4:
Y2 = 2x1 + 8x2
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 62
School of Distance Education
|J| =
= 3x1 + 12x2
= 12x1 + 48x2
=2
=8
|J| = 0
Z = f(x, y) then
| | =
If the first element on the principal diagonal or first principal minor, IH1I = Zxx is
positive and the second principal minor IH2I = is also positive, then the
Hessian is called positive definite. That is, if IH1I>0 and IH2I > 0, then IHI is positive
definite.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 63
School of Distance Education
Positive definite Hessian fulfils the second order condition for minimum. Similarly, if
the first principal minor IH1I =Zxx is negative and second principal minor IH2I =
is positive, then the Hessian is negative definite. That is, if IH1I < 0 and IH2I
> 0, the Hessian is negative definite. A negative definite Hessian fulfills second order
condition for maximum.
Example 1:
| | =
Zx = 6x – y – 4
Zxx = 6
Zxy = -1
Zy = -x + 4y – 7
Zyy = 4
Zyx = -1
| | = 6 1
1 4
6 1
Second principal minor | 2| = = 23 > 0
1 4
Since | 1| 0 and | 2| > 0, the Hessian is positive definite and Z is minimized.
Example 2:
| |=
Qu = 10u + 3v
Quu = 10
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 64
School of Distance Education
Quv = 3
Qv = 3u + 4v
Quv = 3
Qvv = 4
10 3
∴| |=
3 4
| 1| = 10 > 0
10 3
2= = 31 > 0
3 4
∴ Q is positive definite.
Example 3:
U = 2x2 + y2 – 4x + 8y
| |=
Ux = 4x - 4
Uxx = 4
Uxy = 0
Uv = 2y + 8
Uyx = 0
Uyy = 2
4 0
∴| |=
0 2
| 1| = 4 > 0
4 0
2= =8>0
0 24
∴ U is minimum.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 65
School of Distance Education
Example 4:
Given the profit function π = 15Q1 + 18Q2 – 2Q12 – 2Q1Q2 – 3Q22, use the Hessian for
second order condition
| | = π11 π12
π21 π22
Π1 = 15 – 4Q1 – 2Q2
Π11 = -4
Π12 = -2
Π2 = 18 – 2Q1 – 6Q2
Π21 = -2
Π22 = -6
4 2
∴| |=
2 6
| 1| = -4 < 0
4 2
| 2| = = 20 > 0
2 6
∴ U is minimum.
Since | 1| < 0 and | 2| > 0, Hessian is negative definite, and the profit function (Π) is
maximized.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 66
School of Distance Education
| |=
If the first principal minor | 1| = a is positive and the second principal minor | 2|
= is also positive then the discriminant | | is called positive definite. That is, if
| 1| > 0 and | 2| > 0, | | is positive definite and z is positive for all non-zero values of x
and y. If | 1| < 0 and | 2| > 0, the discriminant | | is negative definite and z is negative
for all non-zero values of x and y.
Example 1:
2
| |=
8
| |= 2 2.5
2.5 8
| 1| = 2 > 0
| 2| = 2 2.5
= 9.75 > 0
2.5 8
Example 2:
Find discriminant if Q = 22Y12 + 46Y1Y2 + 42Y22, use discriminate to test for definiteness.
22
| |=
42
| | = 22 23
23 42
| 1| = 22 > 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 67
School of Distance Education
22 23
| 2| = = 395 > 0
23 42
Example 3:
| |= 5 1.5
1.5 2
| 1| = 5 > 0
| 2| = 5 1.5
= 7.75 > 0
1.5 2
Example 4:
2
| |= 5
3
2 2 1
| |= 2 5 1
1 1 3
| 1| = -2 < 0
| 2| = 2 2
=6>0
2 5
2 2 1
| 3| = 2 5 1
1 1 3
| 3| =-2 5 1 2 1 2 5
-2 1
1 3 1 3 1 1
| 3| = -7 < 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 68
School of Distance Education
Since | 1| < 0, | 2| > 0 and | 3| < 0, Y is negative definite.
Given Y = f(x1, x2, x3) the third order Hessian denoted as | | consist of the
elements of various second order partial derivatives of Y. That is,
11 12 13
| |= 21 22 23
31 32 33
Conditions for a relative minimum or maximum depend on the signs of first,
second and third principal minors respectively. The principal minors are
| 1| = Y11
| 2| = 11 12
21 22
| 3| | |
If | 1| > 0, | 2| > 0 and | 3| > 0 then Hessian is positive definite and fulfills the
second order conditions for a minimum. If | 1| < 0, | 2| > 0 and | 3| < 0, then Hessian
is negative definite and fulfills the second order conditions for a maximum.
That is, if all principal minors of Hessian is positive, | | is positive definite and
second order conditions for a relative minimum we met. If all principal minors of
alternative sign between negative and positive |H| is negative definite and second order
conditions for a relative maximum are met.
Example 1:
Y Y Y
|H| = Y Y Y
Y Y Y
Y = -10 + 10 +
Y = -10 Y =0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 69
School of Distance Education
Y = 1
Y = -4 +4+2
Y = 0 Y = -4 Y 2
Y = 2 8
Y = 1 Y =2 Y 8
10 1 1
H= 0 4 2
1 2 8
|H | = -10 0
|H | = 10 0
= 40 0
0 4
|H | = -10 4 2 0 2 0 4
-0 +1 = - 276
2 8 1 8 1 2
Example 2:
Z Z Z
|H| = Z Z Z
Z Z Z
Z = 4 + +
Z = 4 Z =1
Z = 1
Z = + 8
Z = 1 Z =8 Z 2
Z = 2
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 70
School of Distance Education
Z = 1 Z =0 Z 2
4 1 1
|H| = 1 8 0
1 0 2
|H | = 4 0
|H | = 4 1 = 31 0
1 8
|H | = 4 8 0 - 1 1 0 + 1 1 8
0 2 1 2 1 0
= 54 0
Example 3:
Y= 3 5 6 4 2 4 +2 3
Y Y Y
|H| = Y Y Y
Y Y Y
Y = 6 -5- - 3
Y = 6 Y = -1
Y = -3
Y = - + 12 - 4+ 2
Y = -1 Y = 12 Y 2
Y = 2 8 2 3
Y = -3 Y =2 Y 8
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 71
School of Distance Education
6 1 3
|H| = 1 12 2
3 2 8
|H | = 6 0
|H | = 6 1
= 71 0
1 12
|H | = 6 12 2 - -1 1 2 -
+ 3
1 12
2 8 3 2 3 2
= 448 0
Example 4:
for maximum
|H| =
= -8 = -3
= -2
= 200-3Q - 2Q -10Q
= -3 = -10 2
= 150 2Q 2Q 8Q
= -2 = -2 8
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 72
School of Distance Education
8 3 2
|H| = 3 10 2
2 2 8
|H | = 8 0
|H | = 8 3
= 71 0
3 10
|H | = -8 10 2 - 3 2 - 3 10
- 3 + 2
2 8 2 8 2 2
= -520
The first order conditions are found by taking partial derivatives of F with respect to all
three independent variables and setting them equal to zero. That is, Fx = 0, Fy = 0, F =
0. The second order conditions can be expressed in terms of bordered Hessain, denoted
as
F F g
|H| = F F g
g g 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 73
School of Distance Education
or
0 g g
|H| = g F F
g F F
Example 1:
56 – x – y = 0
Z=4 + 3 xy +6 + [56 – x - y]
Zx = 0 8x + 3y – =0
Zy = 0 3x + 12y - =0
Z = 0 56 - x - =0
Zxx = 8 Zxy = 3
Zxy = 3 Zyy = 12
= 1 = 1
8 3 1
|H| = 3 12 1
1 1 0
|H| 12 1 3 1 3 12
8 – 3 +1
1 0 1 0 1 1
|H| -14 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 74
School of Distance Education
Example 2:
Maximise the utility function U = 2xy subject to a budget constraint equal to 3x + 4y = 90.
Find out the critical values of , and and use bordered Hessian to test for second
order condition
Applying , we have
Ux = 2y –3 =0
Uxx = 0 Uxy = 2 3
Uy = 2x - 4 =0
Uyx = 2 Uyy = 0 4
U = 90 – 3x – 4y = 0
0 2 3 0
2 0 4 = 0
3 4 0 90
|A| = 0 0 4
-2
2 4 - 2
+ 3
0
4 0 3 0 3 4
= 48
0 2 3
|A | = 0 0 4
90 4 0
0 4 0 4 - 0 0
|A | = 0 -2 + 3
4 0 90 0 90 4
= 720
| |
x= | |
= = 15
0 0 3
A = 2 0 4
3 90 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 75
School of Distance Education
0 4 2 4 - 2 0
|A | = 0 -0 + 3
3 0 3 0 3 90
|A | = 540
| |
y = | |
= = 11.25
0 2 0
A = 2 0 0
3 4 90
|A | = 0 0 0
-2
2 0
+0
2 0
4 90 3 90 3 4
| |
λ = | |
= = 7.5
U U g
|H| = U U g
g g 0
0 2 3
|H| = 2 0 4
3 4 0
|H| 0 4 2 4 2 0
0 – 2 -3
4 0 3 0 3 4
|H| 48 0
Example 3:
U = xy + x + [110 – 6x – 2y]
Ux = 0 y + 1 - 6 = 0
Uxx = 0 Uxy = 1 g =6
Uy = 0 x - 2 = 0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 76
School of Distance Education
Uyx = 1 Uyy = 0 g =2
In matrix form A = B
0 1 6 1
1 0 2 = 0
6 2 0 110
|A| = 0 0 2
-1
1 2 - 1
+ 6
0
2 0 6 0 6 2
= 24
1 1 6
A1 = 0 0 2
110 2 0
|A1| = -1 0 2
-1
0 2 -
+ 6
0 0
2 0 110 0 110 2
= 224
| |
x = | |
= = 9.33
0 1 6
A2 = 1 0 2
6 110 0
|A2| = 0 0 2 - 1 2 - 1 0
- 1 + 6
110 0 6 0 6 110
|A2| 672.
| |
y= | |
= = 28
0 1 1
A3 = 1 0 0
6 2 110
0 0 1 0 1 0
|A3| = 0 -1 + -1
2 110 6 110 6 2
= 112
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 77
School of Distance Education
| |
λ= | |
= = 4.66
U U g
|H| = U U g
g g 0
0 1 6
|H| = 1 0 2
6 2 0
0 2 1 2 1 0
|H| 0 – 1 +6
2 0 6 0 6 2
|H| 24
Example 4:
Minimise the total cost C = 45 + 90 xy +90 when the firm has to meet a production
quota equal to 2x + 3y = 60
Cx = 0 90x + 90y - 2 = 0
Cy = 0 90x + 180y - 3 = 0
C =0 60 - 2x 3y = 0
In matrix form AX = B
90 90 2 0
90 180 3 = 0
2 3 0 60
x = 12
y = 12
= 1080
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 78
School of Distance Education
C C g
Now forming bordered Hessian |H| = C C g
g g 0
90 90 2
|H| = 90 180 3
2 3 0
|H| = - 450
Reference
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 79
School of Distance Education
CHAPTER IV
INTEGRAL CALCULUS: THE INDEFINITE INTEGRAL
But here an important question is, if the marginal utility function is 2q, what is the
total utility function? The problem is reversed here: because we are now given the
marginal utility function and we are to find the total utility function, or in other words
we are given the change in quantities and we have to calculate the total effects of the
change. This reverse process involves summation of the differences. Process of such
calculations is called integration.
Thus, reversing the process of differentiation and finding the original function
from the derivative is called integration or antidifferentiation. The original function F(x)
is called the integral, or antiderivative, of F’(x).
Definition
If the differential coefficient of F(x) w.r.t. x is f(x), then the integral of f(x) with respect to x
is F(x).
The sign ‘ ’ is used to denote the process of integration. The differential symbol ‘dx’ is
written by the side of the function to be integrated to indicate the independent variable
with respect to which the original differentiation was made and with respect to which we
are now to integrate. In this way . means integration of f(x) w.r.t. x.
We know that 1 1
. =
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 80
School of Distance Education
In symbols therefore,
where C is called the constant of integration. Since C can take any constant value, the
integral is called indefinite integral. Here the left-hand side of the equation is read, “the
indefinite integral of f with respect to x.” The symbol is the integral sign, f(x) is the
integrand, and C is the constant of integration.
Rules of Integration
1.
6
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 81
School of Distance Education
2.
1
2
3.
1
4.
√ dx = +C= √ +C
5.
dx = +C= C
, since = and
ie.
= +C
Integral of sum (or difference) of a number of functions is equal to the sum (or difference)
of their separate integrals.
i.e. = , and
Example
1. 1 =
1
=
+ - + +x +
=
- +x+C
Note : In the final answer we have to add up all the constants into a single constant C
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 82
School of Distance Education
Rule 5. The integral of a Constant
The integral of the negative of a function is the negative of the integral of that function.
Example
1. 4 =4 = + C = +C
2. 5 =5 - +4
=5 + + 4log x + C
Standard Results
1.
=
2.
= log
3.
=
4.
.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 83
School of Distance Education
Initial conditions and Boundary Conditions
The initial condition mean y assumes a specific value when x equals zero (ie y =
when x = 0) and the boundary condition means y assumes a specific value when x
assumes a specific value (ie y = when x = ) In many problems an initial condition or a
boundary condition uniquely determines the constant (+C) of integration. By permitting
a unique determination of constant C, the initial or boundary condition clearly defines
the original function.
Examples
11=2(3) + C
ie. C = 5
Here y = 3 dx
= 6
Substituting the initial condition y = 0 when x = 0 we get c = 0,
Hence y = 6
Integration By Substitution
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 84
School of Distance Education
12 2
cannot be done directly by using the simple rules. However if the integrand can be
expressed as a constant multiple of another function ‘ ’ and its derivative , integration
by substitution is possible. By expressing the integrand f(x) as a function of ‘ ’ and its
derivative , and integrating with respect to x.
The substitution method reverses the operation of the chain rule and the generalized
power function rule in differential calculus.
Examples
Let u = + 2, then
dx =
=
12 2 12 . .
3
=
4
Then integrate w.r.t. ‘u’ using the power rule of integrate we get
4 4 =2
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 85
School of Distance Education
convert back to the terms of the original problem by substituting 2 for u, we have
12 2 =2 +C
=2 2 +C
when checking the answer by differentiating with the generalized power function
rule or chain rule, we have
2. Integrate 5 7
Here we shall try to reduce it to the standard form : for this the obvious
way is to substitute u = (5x + 7). Then the given integral becomes
I= dx
But dx too will have to be changed to ‘du’ otherwise integration will not be possible.
Since u = 5x + 7
=5
or,
du = 5.dx
dx =
Therefore I = =
= +C
= +C
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 86
School of Distance Education
Integration By Parts
If an integral is a product or quotient of differentiable functions of x and cannot be
expressed as a constant multiple of u. , integration by parts is frequently useful. This
method is derived by reversing the process of differentiating a product.
f(x)g(x) = ’ ’
Then solving algebraically for the first integral on the right hand side.
’ ’
For more complicated functions integration tables are generally used. Integration tables
provide formulas for the integrals of as many as 500 different functions.
Example
1. Integrate 4 1
Here integration by parts is used to determine 4 1
First separate the two parts amenable to the following formula.
As a general rule, consider first the simpler function for f(x) and the more complicated
function for g’(x). By letting f(x) = 4x and g’(x) = 1 Then
then g(x) = 1 1 +
Then substitute the values for f(x), f ‘(x) and g(x) in the formula, we get
4 1 = f(x)g(x) – .
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 87
School of Distance Education
= 4x 1 – 1 4
=x 1 +4 – 1 4 dx
4 1 =x 1 4 - 1 -4 x+C
=x 1 – 1 +C
Then check the answer by letting y(x) = x 1 - 1 +C and using the product
and generalized power function rules,
y'(x) = .4 1 1 .1 – 1
= 4x 1
=====
= dx, we have
2 = . . .
= 2 . - 2
= 2 . -2
= =K(t) + C = K(t) + Ko
Here = I(t) is an identity, it shows the synonymity between net investment and
the increment of capital. Since I(t) is the derivative of K(t), it stands to reason that K(t) is
the integral or antiderivative of I(t), as shown in the last equation.
K(t) =
or K(t) =
where C = the initial capital stock
Example
/
1. The rate of net investment is given by I(t) = 140 and the initial stock of capital
at t = 0 is 150. What is the time path of capital K?
By integrating I(t) with respect to t, we obtain
=
= 140
= 140
By the power rule
K = 140 +C
= 80 +C
But C = =150, Therefore
K = 80 +150
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 89
School of Distance Education
Estimate Total Function From a Marginal Function
Given a total function (e.g, a total cost function) the process of differentiation can yield
the marginal function (eg., marginal cost function). Because the process of integration is
the opposite of differentiation, it should enable us, conversely, to infer the total function
from a given marginal function.
For example, since marginal cost is the change in total cost from an incremental
change in output MC = , and only variable costs change with the level of output, then
TC = dQ = VC + C = VC + FC
Since C = the fixed or initial cost FC
Problems
I. Determine the following Intergrals
a) 3.5
b)
c)
d)
e) 4
f)
g)
h) 5 2 3
a) 10 3
b) 9
c) dx
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 90
School of Distance Education
d)
a) 15 4
b) dx
c) 16
a) The rate of net investment is I =40 and capital stock at t = 0 is 75. Find the
capital function K
b) The rate of net investment is I =60 ,and capital stock at t = 1 is 85. Find K
c) Marginal cost is given by MC = =25+ 30 -9 , fixed cost is 55. Find i) Total
cost ii)Average cost and iii) variable cost function
d) Marginal revenue function is given by MR = 60 – 2Q -2 . Find i)TR function and
ii) the demand function P =f(Q)
Answers
a) 3.5x + C
b) x +C
c)
d) +C
e)
f) +C
√
g) logx + C
h) + + +C
i) +6
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 91
School of Distance Education
j) y = 2 – 3x + 22
II)
a) 3 +C
b) 9 +C
c) - +C
d) +C
III)
a) 6x 4 - 4 +C
b) - + C
c) −16x – 16 +C
IV)
a) K = 25 + 75
b) K = 45 + 40
c) i)TC =25Q + 15 –3 + 55
ii) AC = 25 + 15Q - 3 +
d) i) 60Q -- - +C
ii) 60 – Q -
REFERENCES
4. Mehta & Madamani, “Mathematics for Economists”, Sultan Chand & Sons.
5. R.G. D. Allen, “Mathematical Analysis for Economics”, A.I. T. B.S. Publishers &
Distributers.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 92
School of Distan on
nce Educatio
C
CHAPTE
ER V
INTEG
GRAL CALCUL
C LUS : TH
HE DEFIN
NITE IN
NTEGRA
AL
5.1. AR
REA UNDE
ER A CUR
RVE
The graph
h of a contin
nuous fun
nction y = f(x) is draw
wn in Fig 5..1.
This, thou
ugh, is obv
viously nott the area under
u the curve we seek, but only a verry
rough approximaation thereeof.
Mathema nomic Analysiis II
atics for Econ Page 93
9
School of Distance Education
What makes A* deviate from the true value of A is the unshaded portion of the
rectangular block; these make A* an over estimate of A. If the unshaded portion can be
shrunk in size and be made to approach zero, however, the approximation value A* will
correspondingly approach the true value A. This result will be materialize when we try
a finer and finer segmentation of the interval (a, b), so that n is increased and ∆xi is
shortened indefinitely. Then the blocks will become more slender (if more numerous),
and the protrusion beyond the curve will diminish, as we can be seen in Figure 5.1 (b).
Carried to the limit, this “slandering” operation yield
Lim Lim
∑ ∆x i = A* = area A
n→∞ n→∞
Provided this limit exists. This equation, indeed, constitutes the formal definition
of an area under a curve.
If we choose two values of x in the domain, say a and b (a < b), substitute them
successively into the right side of the equation, and found the difference
- = F(b) – F(a)
We get a specific numerical value, free of the variable x as well as the arbitrary
constant C. This value is called the definite integral of f(x) from a to b. We refer to a as
the lower limit of integration and to b as the upper limit of integration.
In order to indicate the limits of integration, we now modify the integral sign to
the form . The evaluation of the definite integral is then symbolized in the
following steps:
b
= F(b) – F(a)
a
b b b
Where the symbol (also written as or ………….. ) is an instruction to
a a a
substitute b and a, successively, for x in the result of integration to get F(b) and F(a), and
then take their difference. As the first step, however, we must find the indefinite integral,
although we may omit the constant c, since the latter will drop out in the process of
difference – taking any way.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 94
School of Distance Education
Example 1:
Evaluate 3 2
Since the indefinite integral has the value x3 + c , the definite integral is
a
3 3
3 2 = x3 b = 5 – 1 = 125 – 1 = 124
Example 2:
Evaluate 2
2 = ln 5 16 - ln 1 0
= ln 5 16
lim ∆
Here ‘a’ is the lower limit and ‘b’ is the upper limit of integration.
(i) Reversing the order of the limits changes the sign of the definite integral
(ii) If the upper limit of the integration equals the lower limit of integration, the
value of the definite integral is zero.
0
(iii) The definite integral can be expressed as the sum of component subintegrals.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 95
School of Distan on
nce Educatio
(iv) The su
um or diffeerence of two
t integrrals with identical
i liimits of in
ntegration is
equal to
t the defin
nite integra
al of the su
um or diffeerence of th
he two funcctions.
5.3 AR
REA BETW
WEEN CUR
RVES
The area oof a region between tw wo or morre curves can be evaluated by applying
a th
he
properrties of deffinite integ
grals outlin
ned above.. The proccedure can
n be demo onstrated by
b
using the
t examplle given beelow:
Examp
ple:
(a) Dra
aw a rough
h sketch of the graph of the funcction and shade
s in th
he desired area
Mathema nomic Analysiis II
atics for Econ Page 96
9
School of Distance Education
A= 3 2 6 8 2 2 4 1
A= 3 2 6 8 2 2 4 1
A= 5 2 10 7
= 3 5 2 7 0
2
= 20 14 - 0
CONSUMERS’ SURPLUS
A demand function p = f(Q) represents the different prices consumers are willing
to pay for different quantities of a good. If the equilibrium price is PE and equilibrium
quantity is QE, then consumers who would be willing to pay more than PE benefit. Total
benefit to consumers is called consumers’ surplus. Mathematically,
Example
Given the demand function P = 42 – 5Q – Q2. Assuming that the equilibrium price
is 6, the consumer’s surplus is evaluated as follows
at P = 6 42 – 5Q – Q2 = 6
Q2 + 5Q – 36 = 0
(Q + 9)(Q – 4) = 0
Therefore, Q = -9 or Q = 4
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 97
School of Distance Education
= 168 40 - 24
= - 24
PRODUCERS’ SURPLUS
Producers’ Surplus = QE PE -
Example
Given the supply function P = (Q + 3)2, find the producers’ surplus at PE = 81 and
QE=6
Producers’ Surplus = 6 x 81 - 3 2
3 3
6
= 486 -
0
= 486 - 243 9
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 98
School of Distance Education
CHAPTER 6
INTRODUCTION TO DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS AND
DIFFERENCE EQUATIONS
Definition
A differential equation is an equation which express an explicit or implicit
relationship between a function y = f (t) and one or more of its derivatives or differentials
y’, y”, ……… yn.
Symbolically a differential equation may be written as F(t, y’, y”, ……, yn) = 0
By integrating both sides of the differential equation, we are able to find the
relation between the dependent variable and the independent variable.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 99
School of Distance Education
Example
To solve the differential equation y” (t) = 7 for all the functions y (t) which satisfy
the equation, simply integrate both sides of the equation and find integrals, i.e.,
y’ (t) = 7 dt = 7t + c1
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 100
School of Distance Education
3. = 4x + 3 is the 3rd order differential equation
Definition
A difference equation expresses a relationship between a dependent variable and
a lagged independent variable or variables whish changes at discrete intervals of time.
For exempt It = f (yt – 1), where I & Y are measured at the end of each year and
thus difference equation relates the independent variable, the dependent variable and its
successive difference.
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 101
School of Distance Education
Therefore F (t, yt , ∆ yt , ∆ yt, ……………… ) = 0 is a difference equation
= Δ = Δ -
Where Δ is an operator replacing which is used to measure continuous change in
differential equation.
Example
1. It = a (yt-1 – yt-2) is a difference equation of order 2
2. Qs = a + b pt-1 is a difference equation of order 1
3. yt+3 - 9 yt+2 + 2 yt+1 +6 yt = 8 is a difference equation of order 3
4. Δ = 5 yt, that is
yt+1 – yt = 5 yt
i.e. yt+1 = 6 yt is a difference equation of order 1
5. Δ +Δ = yt is equivalent to
Problems
1. Find the order and degree of following differential equations
a) + = 18x
b) = 3
c) + y – 4 =0
d) -5 =0
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 102
School of Distance Education
e) + + 0
c) Δ
d) yt+2 + a1 yt+1 + a2 yt = c
Answers
I a) Third order, first degree
b) First order, first degree
c) Third order, first degree
d) First order, fourth degree
e) Second order, first degree
II a) First order
b) First order
c) Second order
d) Second order
References
1. Edward T Dowling, “Introduction to Mathematical Economics” Third Edition,
Schaum’s Outline series, Mc Graw-Hill International Edition.
2. Knut Sydsacter & Peter J Hammond, “Mathematics for Economic Analysis”,
Pearson Education.
3. Mehta & Madanani, “Mathematics for Economists”, Sulthan Chand & Sons.
4. Alpha C Chiang & Kevon Wainwright, “Fundamental Methods of Mathematical
Economics”, Fourth Edition, Mc Graw Hill International Edition.
*****
Mathematics for Economic Analysis II Page 103