BERMÚDEZ The Neoliberal Pattern of Domination Capital S Reign in Decline
BERMÚDEZ The Neoliberal Pattern of Domination Capital S Reign in Decline
BERMÚDEZ The Neoliberal Pattern of Domination Capital S Reign in Decline
Studies in
Critical Social Sciences
Series Editor
David Fasenfest
Wayne State University
Editorial Board
Chris Chase-Dunn, University of California-Riverside
G. William Domhofff, University of California-Santa Cruz
Colette Fagan, Manchester University
Martha Gimenez, University of Colorado, Boulder
Heidi Gottfried, Wayne State University
Karin Gottschall, University of Bremen
Bob Jessop, Lancaster University
Rhonda Levine, Colgate University
Jacqueline O'Reilly, University of Brighton
Mary Romero, Arizona State University
Chizuko Ueno, University of Tokyo
VOLUME 43
By
Translated by
Martin Boyd
LEIDEN • BOSTON
2012
Cover illustration: Art work by Alejandro Magallanes.
HB501.S2783 2012
332’.041--dc23
2012014875
This publication has been typeset in the multilingual “Brill” typeface. With over 5,100 characters
covering Latin, IPA, Greek, and Cyrillic, this typeface is especially suitable for use in the
humanities. For more information, please see www.brill.nl/brill-typeface.
ISSN 1573-4234
ISBN 978 90 04 22377 6 (hardback)
ISBN 978 90 04 23156 6 (e-book)
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, translated, stored in
a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical,
photocopying, recording or otherwise, without prior written permission from the publisher.
Acknowledgements ..................................................................................................ix
Prologue by R.A. Dello Buono .................................................................................xi
Introduction .................................................................................................................1
PART ONE
THE DOMINATION OF CAPITAL:
ITS LOGICAL AND HISTORICAL FORMS
PART TWO
THE NEOLIBERAL PATTERN:
SECOND EMERGENCE OF THE NATURAL FORM OF DOMINATION
PART THREE
CONCLUSION
Bibliography ...........................................................................................................335
Subject Index .........................................................................................................351
Index of Authorities .............................................................................................357
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
I would like to thank the Autonomous University of Nayarit and its Council
for their support in the completion of my doctoral studies and the research
that enabled me to prepare this work, and to express my profound grati-
tude to Víctor Figueroa Sepúlveda, my friend and teacher, for his generos-
ity in sharing his knowledge; to R.A. Dello Buono for his invaluable support
and encouragement; and to both for their efffort and intellectual consis-
tency in a world full of so much inconsistency placed at the service of
capital.
And fijinally, to Mari, because if my life has been a life, it has been because
she has shared her life with me; to Omar and Magaly, the most cherished
lives in my life, the lives which, although we gave them life through ours,
we did not make them, because each life makes its own life; to Mireya,
because she has been an anchor in my life and a source of profound feel-
ings, always so remote and so present; and to Isadora, Mirna and Priscila,
because we have been learning how to share life, which is no small thing
in these times of alienation in a neoliberal labyrinth designed to kill the
emotional capacity of human beings.
It is not my purpose to abuse the patience of my readers or bore them
with the details of my personal emotional bonds which are a private mat-
ter. In reality, I only wish to say that I just like every one of the more than
six billion human beings who inhabit this planet loves life – that brief
parenthesis between two eternities which can and must be glorious.
It simply doesn’t seem reasonable that a handful of profijit-obsessed luna-
tics bent on serving the logic of capital should be able to deem life insig-
nifijicant and destroy it, as they have done to many millions of lives in Iraq,
Afghanistan, Eastern Europe, Africa, and the Middle East. Likewise here
in Latin America, some countries with devastated economic and politi-
cal structures are increasingly incapable of attending the most basic needs
of a growing proportion of their inhabitants and have been turning into
territories controlled by bands of armed murderers.
task of critical thought and this task has been important from the perspec-
tive of the interests of the exploited and oppressed. But in the current
phase of the development of capitalism, it seems more important than
ever. This is so for at least two reasons:
First, due to its exclusive concern for increasing profijit levels, capital has
devastated the institutional channels that once contained its own vorac-
ity, destroying whole societies, condemning millions of human beings to
economic, moral and intellectual misery and annihilating nature, placing
the very existence of humanity at risk.
Second and in spite of the sufffering that its domination inflicts on con-
temporary society, capital in the form of a handful of gigantic multina-
tional corporations that control production and the world market, is
supposed to have risen victorious. This is expressed by the rather euphoric
tone of the discourse of its organic intellectuals. The working class and the
socialist project appear to have been defeated; the apologists of capital
claim this defeat is fijinal, but those of us who examine the process and not
merely the moment, and who like Bloch (1986)2 have hope that humanity
still has a future, believe the defeat is merely transitory.
The contribution of this study is to give visibility to both the phenom-
enon of class domination (which, together with exploitation, is the object
of analysis most ignored and obscured by the dominant ideology) and
the subject that produces it; to help dispel its apparently natural character,
i.e., the presumed absence of a producer, all of which the dominant
ideology uses to “explain” the very disasters provoked by capital in con-
temporary society.
To examine the domination of capital, this book is divided into two
parts. The fijirst part, consisting of four chapters, sets forth a conceptual
framework for the analysis of the general conditions of the domination of
capital over the working class, its basis and its forms, both logical and
historical.
In the fijirst chapter, I analyze the content of the domination of capital –
operating as the support to capitalist exploitation by reducing the work-
ing class to obedience, subordinating it economically, politically and
ideologically – as a power built around a single basic social relation that
2 It should also be added, however, as Mokhiber and Weissman note, that “the future of
the scattered movement against the power of the corporations is uncertain. It is clear that
it has a long way to go before it overturns the iron rule of the corporations over society. But
our greatest hope lies in the task of saving our lives and our planet from the grip of the
corporations” (Mokhiber and Weissman, 2005b).
introduction 3
establishes and constitutes the essential factor in the capitalist world: the
capital relation, the relation that separates producers from the means of
production. The analysis of this essential relation – the relation between
capital and wage-labor, the concentration of the means of production and
subsistence into the hands of the capitalist class and, as a result, the dis-
possession and separation between producer and means of production
and subsistence – constitutes the organizing principle behind this entire
work, from the fijirst to the last chapter.
In the second chapter, I identify the general forms, or logical principles,
of the domination of capital: its natural and its contained form. While the
content of domination is articulated through exploitation, the forms of
domination express a link between the two, defijined in the conditions
organized by the capital relation itself.
This analysis is founded on one basic principle: that the exploitation of
the working class by the capitalist class is expressed as production and
appropriation of surplus-value. Capital is value that appreciates but,
unlike pre-capitalist forms of exploitation, which recognized a limit in the
use value and consumption of the exploiting class, the capitalist form of
exploitation has an insatiable need to appropriate the labor of others, as
“its constant tendency… [is its] appetite for the labor of others” (Marx,
1867: Ch. 15), which makes capital extremely reluctant to grant conces-
sions to the working class.
As this logic is the natural tendency of capital and organizes its immedi-
ate, direct and spontaneous movement, the natural form in capitalist
domination is the efffort to ensure the submission of the working class to
the need for the spontaneous movement of the exploitation and accumu-
lation of capital, stripping it of the conditions that make resistance and
bargaining possible; the aim is not merely to prevent workers from stop-
ping exploitation, but even from attempting to moderate it, to bargain or
negotiate the conditions of their exploitation, and to win some form of
concession from capital.
In contrast, in the contained form, capital is faced with a working class,
and a society in general, that has managed to establish a certain level of
containment of its spontaneous movement, and so adapts its domination
to these conditions. In this context, in its most immediate sense, the con-
tained form of domination derives from the struggle of the workers to
wrestle concessions from capital, to achieve some degree of recognition of
its material interests.
As we are dealing with general forms, not restricted to a particular
historical period but constructed through theoretical abstraction, it is
4 introduction
possible to work with them not as periods but as criteria for periodizing
the history of domination. These general forms may assume diffferent
modes of historical expression, thereby allowing us to consider the history
of capitalist domination not only as a succession of periods, but also as an
alternation of its general forms.
In the third chapter, I examine the concept of the pattern of domina-
tion as a historical expression of a general form of capitalist domination
which, while realizing in a specifijic context the basic processes defijined by
that general form, enables the delimitation of a historical period and,
therefore, the construction of a world history of capitalist domination,
correlated with a world history of capitalist economics.
The concept of the pattern of domination establishes an intermediate
fijield of theoretical and historical analysis in a description moving from
the general to the specifijic, between a general theory of capitalist domina-
tion and actual specifijic national cases of domination. It defijines a peri-
odization which, on the one hand, exhibits enough features to identify
and diffferentiate periods in the world history of capitalist domination, but
which, on the other hand, given the general nature of the features, allows
for a multiplicity and diversity of specifijic forms of domination in diffferent
nation-states in the historical period concerned.
The intention behind the pattern of domination concept is thus to
identify a historical trend that may defijine basic outlines in the prevailing
form of capitalist domination, to fijind basic structures, broad cycles in the
history of domination that allow us to posit a periodization that can be
applied to a synthetic analysis of the historical evolution of capitalist
domination. This periodization would also allow the identifijication,
beyond the infijinite diversity that can be found among all the specifijic
cases, of general tendencies in capitalist domination.
In the fourth chapter, examining the history of capitalist domination
from the perspective offfered by the concept of the pattern of domination,
three major periods are identifijied, defijined in their basic historical expres-
sion by developed capitalism; in the fijirst, the natural form predominates,
in the second, the contained form and in the third, once again the natural
form.
In developed Western capitalism, these three periods are defijined by
three patterns of domination: liberal, Keynesian and neoliberal. The fijirst
and the third are historical manifestations of the natural form, while the
second is a historical manifestation of the contained form of capitalist
domination. The liberal pattern constitutes the fijirst historical expression
of the natural form and the neoliberal pattern is its second expression,
while the Keynesian pattern is an expression of the contained form.
introduction 5
3 It is obvious that the U.S. oligarchy is the one that most openly promotes its aspiration
to hold the central position in the power structure of globalization. And it is also clear that
there are many obstacles in its way, including, in addition to acute social resistance, oppo-
sition from other oligarchical conglomerates established through various economic and
political channels which may potentially lead to open military conflicts. But I must stress
that the purpose of this work is to study the capital-labor relation, and so the examination
of the development of inter-imperialist struggles, as important as it is, is not possible here.
introduction 9
The ninth chapter explores the project for the future that this global
fijinancial oligarchy – already in an advanced state of gestation – offfers
humanity and according to which it exercises its intellectual and moral
leadership over contemporary society.
The fijirst two sections of this chapter examine the general features of
this intellectual and moral leadership, constructed in a social environ-
ment founded on disorganization and reduction to isolation in order to
prevent the construction of interests that would transcend individual par-
ticularities and express the recognition of a social relation, a relation
between social classes, by alienating individuals in competitiveness and
criminal activity, in solitude and fear. A basic outline is presented to con-
nect economics, politics and ideology in the current historical context,
in order to round out the overview of the neoliberal pattern of domina-
tion and explain why the state administration of criminal activity is ulti-
mately established as the core of the whole system of the intellectual and
moral leadership of neoliberal capital: criminalizing and dissolving class
opposition against its domination, reducing society to powerlessness
and legitimizing its repression and its positioning of police and military
forces against society by presenting it as a response to a demand made by
society itself.
This increasing priority given to the state administration of criminal
activity in the ideological and practical framework of neoliberal capital is
neither accidental nor provisional, but necessary, as its future trajectory
requires the increasing development of necrophilia and genocide. The last
two sections of the chapter offfer a reflection on the project for the future,
the project of civilization that neoliberal capital offfers humanity, based on
which it exercises its intellectual and moral leadership and its economic,
political and ideological practices.
In its struggle to establish absolute monopoly – to consummate its sta-
tus as a global oligarchy concentrating all of the world’s means of produc-
tion and subsistence – it subordinates everything to its supreme purpose
and, as such, lacks the capacity for concern about anything as insignifijicant
as the wellbeing or the lives of billions of human beings.
Any consideration or respect for life becomes irrelevant in the face of
the “magnifijicence” of the dystopia that dazzles its contemporary personi-
fijications,4 and subordinates them (following the concept developed by
4 “Human beings and life concepts disappear from economic concepts… the theory
and praxis of economics no longer take as their point of departure the real needs of men,
10 introduction
society loses its primacy over economics and any reflection on society vanishes… Free
competition between individual economic interests is fijinally replacing all forms of social
coexistence” (Kurnitzky, 2000).
5 The metaphor is inspired by a proposition offfered in Ianni, 1996.
6 According to Lyotard’s analysis of the post-modern condition, capital operates as a
“self-regulated system” that is “self-programmed like an intelligent machine”, which dis-
misses anything that opposes it, and which, although its logic aggravates society’s ills,
allows for no alternative or possibility for solutions to the problems it creates (Lyotard,
1984).
introduction 11
struggle, as capital tends to aggravate the social ills that it provokes, and
opposition to its domination is becoming as necessary and irrevocable as
the defense of life itself.
The purpose of the tenth chapter is to relate the historical succession of
patterns of domination to the tendencies that organize the long term or
life cycle of capitalism (the gestation, development and extinction of its
social classes), the period from its birth as a social mode of organizing
production to its death. For this analysis, there are just three periods to
consider: infancy, maturity and decline.
The essential point in this analysis is the fact that the capital relation,
the separation of producers from the means of production, develops
together with the development of the productive force of labor and
unleashes the profound tendencies, the general trends that shape the
future of capitalist society and point to its end: increased labor productiv-
ity, increased organic composition of capital, concentration and central-
ization of capital, expulsion of the work force from the labor process,
expansion of the industrial reserve army and worker overpopulation, and
fijinally, as a result of the above, a drop in the rate of profijit.
The theoretical space that allows us to link the pattern of domination
with the long term history of capitalism derives from the capital relation
and the development of its internal tendencies. The delimitation of each
of its periods is drawn from the decisive moments in the development of
the productive force of labor; i.e. from the decisive moments in the devel-
opment of the capital relation. In this development lies the common basis
for both the world history of capitalist economics and the world history of
capitalist domination.
The relation between the historical succession of patterns of domina-
tion and the long term history of capitalism is established in accordance
with the patterns of domination prevailing in developed capitalism, as it is
these that defijine the basic features of the historical period. Thus, the lib-
eral pattern corresponds to the infancy of capitalism, while the Keynesian
pattern, the fijirst and only historical expression of the contained form of
domination corresponds to its period of maturity.
The neoliberal pattern of domination, the second historical expression
of the natural form of domination, corresponds to its decline. For capital,
decline means an increasing organic composition and a decreasing rate of
profijit, and as a result, a renewed need to increase the rate of surplus-value
in a fijinal efffort to restore the level of the rate of profijit, along with a renewed
hostility toward making concessions to the working class, becoming even
more intense as it draws closer to its end. For those dispossessed of the
12 introduction
The conflict between capital and labor entails its necessary negation.
The development of capital is neither eternal nor reducible to a scenario
of political wills and struggles between social classes, as these struggles
unfold in the context of objective conditions defijined by the capital rela-
tion, which will ultimately lead to its end. It is a necessity contained in the
development of necessary relations that are independent of the will and
consciousness of men, but the form that this necessity takes will depend
on the class struggle: it is will and consciousness in action.
Anyone who has read the novel Moby Dick will probably agree that what
is outrageous about the story is not so much Captain Ahab’s obsession
with the great white whale, but the inability of the crew of the Pequod to
unite and save their own lives by casting the insanity into the sea, just as
humankind needs to do today with this increasingly insane Captain Ahab
that is the capital relation. Without the additional insanity of obedience to
a madman, Captain Ahab would be a harmless lunatic locked up in an
anonymous asylum, rather than the pilot of this increasingly bleak space-
ship of which we are all passengers.
But beyond the outrage, this situation poses a challenge: to understand
domination and how it prevents unity in the defense of the lives of the
vast, multifarious mass of human beings dispossessed of the means of pro-
duction and subsistence and divided in conflict and competition against
one another.
The concept of the pattern of domination, and particularly the neolib-
eral pattern of domination, is proposed as a means of identifying the dif-
fijiculties to be overcome in order to organize, expand and win the battle
against the capital relation. It is constructed to examine the conditions of
the problem, not the conditions of the solution. But I believe that by
explaining one, we can go a long way toward comprehending the other, as
to a large extent the conditions of the problem contain those of the solu-
tion. It is to that comprehension that I wish to contribute this modest
work.
PART ONE
The aim here, however, is not to explore any relationship of rule and sub-
ordination, of control and obedience between any two groups of human
beings, but relations between social classes. The essential relationship
under capitalism, the underlying social relation between its classes, con-
sists in the separation between direct producers and the means of produc-
tion and subsistence: “the social form of production is determined fijirst of
all by a particular relation between direct producers and the means of pro-
duction and subsistence. Under the regime of capital, ownership is merely
the manifestation of the separation between direct producers and their
means. When we speak of separation, we mean capitalists on one side and
paid workers on the other, and this is the essential relation under capital-
ism” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 8, emphasis added).
This is the essential social relation under capitalism, that which consti-
tutes the capitalist social form: the workers are apparently dispossessed of
the means of production and subsistence, which are set up against them
as an autonomous power. “It is this separation that constitutes the concept
of capital.”2 For Marx – and this is his general concept – the working
class is made up of people dispossessed of the means of production
punishment, who seek in this way to make clear who the masters of society really are.
Indeed, throughout the history of capitalism in general, and that of Latin America in par-
ticular, there is an abundance of evidence of the fragile line, in the eyes of the dominant
class, between the dignity of a human life and the banality of a worthless object.
2 From Marx’s Theories of Surplus Value (as quoted in Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 38).
20 chapter one
(and, therefore, of the means of subsistence), while the capitalist class are
the possessors of the means of production (expressed in legal terms as
property); in its basic, general sense, the working class is made up of that
great mass of human beings who lack means of production and subsis-
tence, and are required to sell their labor-power to capital for a wage in
order to survive and who are, therefore, constantly seeking to maximize
their own utility, to serve a function within the complex social framework
of capitalism.
This essential relation does not change according to the form taken by
this autonomous power with which the direct producer is faced. The varia-
tions may have a range of signifijicant meanings, but in terms of their essen-
tial characteristics, as constituent parts of class relations in capitalism, it
matters little whether the means of production and subsistence are pre-
sented to workers distributed over multiple owners, as in the competitive
capitalism of the fijirst two thirds of the 19th century, concentrated in the
hands of a few macro-capitalists, as in the great global monopolies of the
“globalized” capital of the late 20th century, in the hands of the state as
“nationalized” property, or in the hands of a state-organized collective
owner, as in the so-called “real socialism” of the 20th century. Of course,
the legal form that this separation takes is also of no real importance. In all
cases, the separation between producer and means of production and
subsistence remains the same and, with it, the class relation between capi-
talists and workers.3
If the constitution of the capitalist class allows variety and modifijica-
tions in form without necessarily altering its essential content, the same
may be said of those dispossessed of the means of production and subsis-
tence.4 Their existence in capitalism takes on a wide variety of forms5
which, for the function they fulfijill at the service of capital (at least with
3 From this we can conclude that the self-acclaimed “real socialism” of the 20th century
was merely a form of state capitalism managed by a collective of property owners orga-
nized into the “Communist Party”, and into a “Socialist State”, that the collapse of this sys-
tem simply represented a change in its capitalist structure, and that capitalism will only be
overcome with the efffective appropriation of its means of production and subsistence by
the producer class.
4 For this reason it is important to understand working class as referring to the dispos-
sessed as a group (a more inclusive concept which encompasses the diversity of forms
assumed by the dominated class in capitalism) and not only to the workers (which tends to
be associated with the industrial proletariat). On the other hand, the concepts of middle
classes and marginalized seem to me inconsistent and tendentious, and as such are ideo-
logically useful to the domination of capital.
5 “The idea of a more or less homogeneous mass of workers is as obsolete as the idea of
labor that thinks and plans as it acts” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 57).
the basis of capitalist domination 21
regard to the relationship between the working class and production capi-
tal), could be grouped into a few basic categories: active workers – divided
into productive (general labor6 and immediate labor7) and non-produc-
tive (monitoring and supervision tasks8 and commodity circulation tasks);
and non-active workers (the industrial reserve army, the section of the
workforce that slips in and out of the dynamic of capital accumulation,
and the absolute surplus population, the section that is simply surplus to
the needs of capital with the many social forms that it adopts).
Not all are exploited, as not all produce surplus value, but all are domi-
nated, subordinated to the needs of capital, and all share the same basic
separation from their means of production and/or subsistence, compelled
to sell their only possession – their personal attributes – to survive.
Exploring diverse combinations of meanness and pettiness with wit and
creativity, whether in white collars or blue collars, denizens of the noisy,
sufffocating atmosphere of the factory or the neat and quiet space of the
offfijice, cubicle or laboratory; tramps in the poor quarters of the cities,
street walkers or beggars; the fate of all the inhabitants of the kingdom of
capital is defijined according to the same basic social relation – the capital
relation.
The defijinition of domination given by UNESCO’s Diccionario de cien-
cias sociales, associated with the notion of an “ecological system,” offfers a
graphic image for the idea presented here: “domination is linked to con-
trol, which one species exercises over the material conditions of suste-
nance of the other species of the system. The dominant species organizes
the activities of the others, assigns to the subordinate species their
diffferent ranks, stabilizes, maintains order and permits the growth of the
system, integrates the activities of the diffferent species and performs
functions of coordination and control. This entails a center or focal
point from which influence is exerted and an area or territory in which
this control is imposed. The subordinate species are positioned in relation
6 The section of the workforce engaged in scientifijic and technological research, and
general planning of production processes, made up of a diverse range of scientists and
professionals.
7 The section of the workforce engaged in operative tasks, those who directly produce
the merchandise, comprising the industrial proletariat in the strict sense of the term.
8 “At fijirst, the capitalist is relieved of manual labor. Then, when his capital grows and
with it the collective labor that he exploits, he hands over the work of direct and constant
supervision of the individual workmen and groups of workmen to a special kind of wage-
laborer. An industrial army of workmen, under the command of a capitalist, requires sub-
ordinate offfijicers (managers, overlookers, foremen) who, while the work is being done,
command in the name of the capitalist” (Marx, 1867: Ch.13).
22 chapter one
9 “The essential condition for the existence and for the sway of the bourgeois class is
the accumulation of wealth in the hands of individuals, the formation and augmentation
of capital. The condition for the existence of capital is wage-labor. Wage-labor rests exclu-
sively on competition between the laborers” (Marx and Engels, 1848, emphasis added).
10 Lu Xun’s tale, “The True Story of Ah Q”, illustrates a case which, although extreme, is
nonetheless common in our society. The story tells of two beggars fijighting, with consider-
able fury but little energy due to their starving condition, for the privilege to beg on a “good”
street corner. Gogol’s story “The Overcoat” narrates the tragicomic effforts of a lower-level
bureaucrat to win the recognition of his superiors. Hundreds of examples of such scenar-
ios, all expressions of the Ah Q Syndrome, can be found by observing the behavior of sec-
tions of the dominated not only within “economic” institutions, such as capitalist
corporations, but also within cultural or political institutions, such as universities or politi-
cal parties.
the basis of capitalist domination 23
11 In contrast, Marx proposed that “in place of the old bourgeois society, with its classes
and class antagonisms, there will arise an association in which the free development of
each is the condition for the free development of all” (Marx and Engels, 1848).
12 There is no doubt that, depending on the level and complexity of their qualifijications,
foremen are more dispensable than scientists. But scientists are not indispensable to
24 chapter one
Of course, this diversity and multiplicity of forms derives from the his-
torical evolution of capitalist society and from the diffferent positions
defijined by the capitalist class for diffferent segments of the dominated
classes, according to its needs of exploitation and domination. However,
two points need to be added in this regard:
1. The relative importance of each of the sections of the labor force
referred to above is modifijied by the evolution and behaviors of capital
accumulation; the composition of the working class changes with the
unfolding of the tendential laws of capitalist development.13
2. Capitalism is a global economic system, with its social classes orga-
nized on a global scale and, as such, the spatial distribution of the difffer-
ent sections of the working class needs to be observed.14
With this in mind, to examine the composition of the working class, we
need to consider its functional and spatial distribution at the global level,
as well as the circumstances of the historical period and the degree of
development of the tendential laws of capitalism.
This same essential relation, the capital relation,15 the separation between
producers and their means of production and subsistence, which estab-
lishes the social classes in capitalism, constructs the basic articulation
between the economic, political and cultural dimensions of relations
capital; currently, certain types of highly qualifijied personnel in Europe and the U.S. are
being displaced by competition from their colleagues in India, who offfer services of equal
quality at lower costs.
13 Thus, in the 19th century, the industrial proletariat, the section of the labor force that
performs immediate labor, was the predominant sector of the working class as a whole.
Over the course of the 20th century, the section responsible for scientifijic and technological
research acquired greater strategic importance, which it continues to hold today. And cur-
rently, due to the very same dynamic of capitalism, and the development of productive
forces, the segment of the “excluded”, the surplus population, is assuming, at least quantita-
tively, increasing importance.
14 This perspective enables us to identify certain basic processes; for example, that the
section that performs general labor tends to be concentrated in developed countries, while
the industrial reserve army and surplus population tend to be concentrated in developing
countries.
15 Hereinafter, to avoid repetition, I will refer to this condition of separation between
producers and their means of production and subsistence, constituting the capital/wage
labor relation, as the capital relation.
the basis of capitalist domination 25
16 “Debate in our societies is nothing more than the debate over specifijic social relations,
which in turn constitute the common core of economic, political, cultural relations, etc.
The economic and political spheres are never separated, for the simple reason that they are
each no more than diffferent dimensions of a single process, the process of the social form
that constitutes the movement of societies” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 8).
17 “The proletariat, the class of modern laborers, who live only so long as they fijind work,
and who fijind work only so long as their labor increases capital” (Marx and Engels, 1848).
26 chapter one
18 “The ‘despotism of the factory’ is imposed upon proletarians who are subjected to
market coercion, as they are dispossessed of everything except their own arms. And market
coercion entails employment uncertainty” (Brunhofff, 1980: 226).
the basis of capitalist domination 27
21 Its opposite, the historical necessity that has still yet to be realized, is the socialist
State, the organization of the working class, whose essential task would be to ensure unity
between producers, organized as a workers’ collective, and their means of production and
subsistence.
the basis of capitalist domination 29
From the mid-19th century to the fijirst decades of the 20th, the workers’
movement, not creating a project but rather contributing to the identi-
fijication of a historical necessity, developed through Marxism an acute
awareness of the need to destroy the capital relation, and converted
this awareness into revolutionary attempts to transform capitalist society.
In that period, as in no other period since, this historical necessity
entailing the destruction of the capital relation through the social re-
appropriation of the means of production and subsistence acquired force
and intensity.
Over the course of the rest of the 20th century, the vicissitudes of the
class struggle numbed this awareness, but this is not to say that the domi-
nation of the state became irrelevant; subsequently, the workers’ move-
ment, not to destroy but rather to negotiate the conditions for capitalist
exploitation and domination, established complex bargaining and protest
processes that necessitated constant management by the state to regulate
and direct the conflicts. The state established itself as the force for order,
for the reconciliation of contradictions which, if not resolved, would have
led to societal paralysis.
Now in the early 21st century, as if waking from a long slumber, in an
awkward process of trial and error, spurred on by the renewed voracity of
capital, a new march is beginning, a long and complex march towards the
future. The struggles of this huge, complex, diverse, scattered, multifac-
eted, passionate and conflictive segment of humanity, separated from its
means of production and subsistence, articulated in the capital relation as
the exploited and/or dominated class, are not a topic belonging to the past
or specifijic to any particular period in the history of capitalism. The vicis-
situdes of their struggle stretch across the whole history of capitalism; the
“automatism” of the market has never been sufffijicient assurance of the
preservation of the capital relation, and in every period the state has been
guarantor of its continued existence and a constant manager of its
development.
As the essential task of the state is to prevent the destruction of the
capital relation, political domination is coordinated to support class
exploitation. In reality, the raison d’etre of political domination is to ensure
exploitation. “The young Marx,” argues Sánchez Vázquez, “focused his
attention on the state, but the discovery of what Hegel had mythologized
(the relations between state and civil society) led Marx to uncover the real
basis of the state. In doing so, he revealed the limitations of Hegelian the-
ory on the state, and the need to begin a critique of the real basis of social
division and political power: the economy” (Sánchez Vázquez, 1999: 33,
30 chapter one
emphasis added). “Capital (Marx’s book),” he adds, “is not purely a work of
economics, unrelated to politics; it explains the real basis of politics.”22
Exploitation is not possible unless it is sustained through domination,
and domination has no purpose except as a support to exploitation. The
separation of domination from exploitation, according to Sánchez
Vázquez, fetishizes power:23 “if the political is founded on the social, the
anatomy of which is the economic, there can be no exclusively political
criticism (such criticism is unfounded and insufffijicient on its own), but
only political criticism founded on economic criticism” (Sánchez Vázquez,
1999: 34).
Economics, politics, and ideology are not self-contained fijields sepa-
rated one from the other. They all form part of a social power, the domina-
tion of one class over the other, based, in all its dimensions, on the same
social relation – the capital relation: “Against the tradition of bourgeois
thought, which views political power as absolute, Marx is a theorist of eco-
nomic power, considering it in relation to political and ideological pow-
ers” (Sánchez Vázquez, 1999: 48).
The raison d’etre of the state, the power organization of the dominant
class, is to provide support for the exploitation perpetrated by that class.
Capitalist domination takes on diverse forms,24 but it is essentially based
on force, on the capacity of the dominant class to inflict violence upon the
dominated classes, while stripping them of their capacity for violent
response.
According to Lenin, “the standing army and the police are the chief
instruments of state power,” and, in this sense, the basic task assumed by
the state is to “deprive the oppressed classes of defijinite means and
methods of struggle for the overthrow of the oppressors” (Lenin, 1918).
22 “Marx takes a new perspective on social thought, which, from Machiavelli to Hobbes
and Hegel, had examined power, while exploitation remained in the shadows” (Sánchez
Vázquez, 1999: 11).
23 This is the basis of his criticism of Marcuse and Foucault: for the fijirst, he says, “the
rationale of power is technological. The technological logos develops in an inherent fash-
ion, whatever may be the relations of production,” and for Foucault, “the power relation
[is] a network of powers (factory, school, church, family, etc.); reticulate or capillary power,
which is everywhere; it is not localized in the state system or in its repressive function. He
objects to viewing this network of powers as a simple projection of political power, but
doesn’t recognize the nexus that unites this power to the relations of production, its nature
as a class and the role it plays in the class struggle” (Sánchez Vázquez, 1999: 13).
24 The State has the “possibility of adopting diverse forms of power or of government
(authoritarian or democratic) to better serve, in specifijic historical conditions, the interests
of the dominant class” (Sánchez Vázquez, 1999: 38).
the basis of capitalist domination 31
25 “Bourgeois rule as the outcome and result of universal sufffrage, as the express act of
the sovereign will of the people; this is the meaning of the bourgeois constitution. It is the
duty of the bourgeoisie to regulate the right to sufffrage so that it wills the reasonable, that
is, its rule. Our dictatorship has hitherto existed by the will of the people; it must now be con-
solidated against the will of the people” (Marx, 1895); “The assertion that class rule is essen-
tially dictatorial does not mean that dictatorial methods are invariably used, but that these
methods are necessary for class rule in a sense in which constitutional methods are not”
(Moore, 1957: 30).
32 chapter one
26 Ideological power “is exercised in the realm of ideologies. It contributes to the main-
tenance of political power and the economic and social bases that sustain that power…
Because of its capacity to mobilize consciousnesses, it contributes to the creation of a con-
sensus of approval of the political power, to its legitimization, and to the acceptance of the
general conditions of exploitation” (Sánchez Vázquez, 1999: 48–49).
the basis of capitalist domination 33
The dominated must operate their margin of freedom within the fijield
of domination structured by capital, perhaps without realizing, or perhaps
without caring very much. Nevertheless, the history of capitalism abounds
with evidence that, while in certain conditions capital is capable of domi-
nating with the active or passive acceptance of the dominated, in other
conditions the domination of capital does not appear to constitute a fijield
of freedom, but a degree of oppression that is insuffferable in the eyes of a
certain number of its victims.28
In such conditions, the victims do not obey because they are convinced,
but because “they have no alternative: they obey in spite of their beliefs,
reasoning or better judgment… They do not wish to obey; in other
cases, obedience is internalized before it is externalized. Now there is the
alternative of disobedience; but certain conditions are needed for this
possibility to be realized, such as the willingness of the victim to assume
the risk in light of a power that could exercise its last resort – the use of
force. The revolutionary struggle is a kind of act of disobedience” (Sánchez
Vázquez, 1999: 21–22).
For those dispossessed of the means of production and subsistence,
obedience is a necessity, and to question it, to assume disobedience as a
historical possibility – not as a simple passive rejection of the power of
capital, but as an active struggle to destroy it – they must question the
capital relation and consider the historical conditions needed to over-
come it. The reality of their situation, their subordinate position in the
capital relation, cannot be resolved by a magic, illusory freedom, but by an
efffective, real transformation of the conditions that deprive them of the
means of production and subsistence and subject them to obedience, sub-
ordinating them to the control of capital.
Only changes occurring to the capital relation can alter the reality of
the condition of the exploited and/or dominated in capitalist society.
Everything aimed at diverting their attention from the central axis of
magical, metaphysical, mystical or religious, from which people may choose, freely, the one
that best meets their needs for intellectual, emotional and spiritual development.
28 However, the importance and complexity of ideological domination must not be
underestimated. Consider, for example, the extreme but increasingly common case in our
societies, of the surplus population; while little has been achieved to establish some sense
of class consciousness, not even the most influential of the mass media, the most impas-
sioned political discourse, the most brilliant formula of distinguished intellectuals will
convince them, as they watch their children starving, of the benefijits of a society that has
provided them with everything so that they can “be free.”
the basis of capitalist domination 35
29 And Engels adds: “Hegel was the fijirst to state correctly the relation between freedom
and necessity. To him, freedom is the insight into necessity: ‘Necessity is blind only in so far
as it is not understood.’ Freedom does not consist in any dreamt-of independence from
natural laws, but in the knowledge of these laws and in the possibility this gives of system-
atically making them work towards defijinite ends” (Engels, 1878).
30 “What occurs in the consciousness of the individual also varies historically; what
passes through the consciousness is not a purely individual afffair, but is conditioned – as
every individual is a social being – by the forms of individuality determined by the difffer-
ent systems of social relations” (Sánchez Vázquez, 1999: 20).
36 chapter one
What could possibly show better the character of the capitalist mode of produc-
tion, than the necessity that exists for forcing upon it, by Acts of Parliament, the
simplest appliances for maintaining cleanliness and health?
K. Marx
Capital
1 “In the social production of their existence, men inevitably enter into defijinite rela-
tions, which are independent of their will, namely, relations of production appropriate to a
given stage in the development of their material forces of production” (Marx, 1859: Preface).
2 “Ever since the dissolution of the primaeval communal ownership of land, all history
has been a history of class struggles, of struggles between exploited and exploiting, between
dominating and dominated classes…” (Marx and Engels, 1883).
the general forms of capitalist domination 39
He also suggests that the same tendencies that push down the rate of
profijit generate counter-tendencies, such as constant reduction of capital
and an increase in its technical composition more intense than the
increase in its value-composition. The search for counter-tendencies by
capital to avoid the drop in the rate of profijit covers a wide range of possi-
bilities, but the basic counter-tendency, which ultimately supports all
others, is to increase the rate of surplus-value. In this way, capitalist devel-
opment is, inevitably, development of the productive force of labor. This
development is expressed in the tendency of the rate of profijit to fall, a
trend which must be slowed down or temporarily reversed through the
implementation of counter-tendencies. These tendencies, which organize
the historical time of capitalism, running from its birth as a social mode of
organizing production through to its death, articulate its long term; the
historical duration of the capitalist mode of production.
With this basic theoretical proposition, an fijield of analysis has been
established3 for the study of the historical development of capitalism as a
series of phases of economic expansion, the fundamental condition for
which is the existence of a historical set of economic, political and ideo-
logical circumstances that ensure a rate of profijit that is satisfactory for
capital, and phases of depression resulting from the exhaustion of the
conditions that ensured an increased rate of profijit during the period of
expansion that preceded it. The effforts of the capitalist class during the
period of depression will therefore be focused on searching for new his-
torical modes to increase the rate of profijit once again.
Between one stage and another there is a basic continuity in terms of
the tendential laws of capitalist development; each stage begins with the
levels of labor productivity, organic composition and concentration of
capital with which the previous stage ended. From that point, the capital-
ist class must undertake the task of historical restructuring in order to
reactivate the rate of profijit.
This is how the new economic, political and ideological modes that will
ensure the profijitability of capital are defijined, and also how the members
of the capitalist class who will be able to operate successfully in the new
conditions are determined; each historical era defijines the dominant fac-
tion of the capitalist class, the faction that will be able to operate in the
new circumstances. Ultimately, this is the faction which, by saving itself,
saves capitalism as a whole.
The exploitation of the working class by the capitalist class consists in the
appropriation of surplus-value; capital is value that appreciates. Unlike
pre-capitalist forms of exploitation, which recognized a limit on the use
value and the consumption of the exploiting class, the capitalist form of
exploitation has an insatiable need to appropriate the labor of others: “If
machinery be the most powerful means for increasing the productiveness
of labor, i.e., shortening the working time required for the production of a
commodity,” states Marx, “it becomes in the hands of capital the most pow-
erful means… for lengthening the working-day beyond all bounds set by
human nature. It creates, on the one hand, new conditions by which capital
is enabled to give free scope to this its constant tendency, and on the other,
new motives with which to whet capital’s appetite for the labor of others”
(Marx, 1867: Ch.15, emphasis added).
Value, as pure condensation of work-time, is separated from use value;
capitalists don’t exploit to consume, but to accumulate, and they accumu-
late to exploit further, thereby generating a necessary dynamic of develop-
ment, structured within a context of specifijic social contradictions. The
capitalist and the capitalist class, the personifijication of the exploiting
party in this social relation, is the personifijication of capital. The contradic-
tions and needs of incessant appreciation and accumulation of capital are
assumed as interests of the capitalist class: “Strictly speaking, it is capital,
and not ‘the capitalists’, that governs the process, imprinting its global
logic on the decisions which, stoked by individual capitalists, are taken by
the state” (Thwaites Rey and Castillo, 1999).
The existence of the working class, the personifijication of the exploited
party in this social relation, is an absolute condition for the existence of
capitalist society. Without an exploited class there can be no exploitation
or exploiters; there can be no capital, no capitalists, and no accumulation.
The two social classes are constituent parts of the capitalist social relation,
structured within a context of necessary relations, “independent of their
will and their consciousness.” However, the capitalist, as the attentive and
diligent personifijication of capital, is necessarily active in this relation.
Capital accumulation is a contradictory process, fraught with hurdles and
obstacles that must constantly be removed for accumulation to continue,
until new obstacles appear. Capitalists must therefore necessarily estab-
lish themselves as an organized class. It is not enough that each individual
capitalist attend to the needs of reproduction and accumulation of his
own capital; the class as a whole must set up forms of organization that
will permit it to attend to the general needs of capital accumulation.
The main obstacle to exploitation and the accumulation which that
exploitation must produce is, of course, the resistance posed by the
exploited against their exploitation. The capitalist class organizes itself
into a state to pursue its own interests, i.e. to overcome the resistance of
the workers and attend to the needs of exploitation and capital accumula-
tion, whatever name it may give those interests and needs: progress, civili-
zation, or simply the laws of the market. By organizing itself into a state,
the exploiting class also becomes the dominant class, endowed with the
42 chapter two
conditions required for the creation of the social order it needs to pursue
its interests, imposing that order on the dominated class. From this per-
spective, the history of capitalism can be analyzed as the history of the
struggle of the capitalist class to create the social order that capital requires
for its development.
The capitalist social relation involves one pole, the dominant, capitalist
class, necessarily organized and active in pursuing its class interests, while
for the opposite pole, the dominated working class, the situation is more
complex. Depending on the modes of domination and resistance, the
working class, viewed from the perspective of its organization as a class,
will assume one of three general modes:
• Disorganized – the situation that Marx calls the “class in itself,” simply
existing as a reality in the system of production relations, as a basis for
capitalist relations of exploitation;
• Organized, with an independent class organization to fijight for its class
interests – the situation that Marx calls the “class for itself”;
• Organized, under terms compatible with bourgeois domination,
restricted within the framework of what Lenin calls “trade unionism.”5
Thus, on the side of capital, we have the “appetite for the labor of others,”
a constant tendency, an insatiable need, a logic that organizes its sponta-
neous movement, present throughout its historical cycle, and each and
every one of the historical stages of its development, regardless of the
period analyzed, is a short or middle term; this logic, this tendency, orga-
nizes the immediate, direct, spontaneous movement of capital. On the
other side, we have the working class, which may assume diffferent modes
and levels of organization and of capacity for resistance, depending on the
circumstances of the class struggle in its economic, political and ideologi-
cal context.
Based on this dual set of circumstances, we can identify two logical
forms, two general forms of capitalist domination: its natural form and its
contained form. In its natural form, capital organizes a type of domination
5 The following quote of Kautsky’s, cited by Lenin, defijines “trade unionism”: “The object
of the mass strike… cannot be to destroy state power; its only object can be to make the
government compliant on some specifijic question, or to replace a government hostile to
the proletariat with one willing to meet it half-way. But never, under any circumstances,
can it (the proletarian victory over a hostile government) lead to the destruction of state
power; it can only lead to a certain shifting of the balance of forces within the state power”
(Lenin, 1918: Ch. 6).
the general forms of capitalist domination 43
6 “In the domain of Political Economy, free scientifijic inquiry meets not merely the same
enemies as in all other domains. The peculiar nature of the materials it deals with, sum-
mons as foes into the fijield of battle the most violent, mean and malignant passions of the
human breast, the Furies of private interest” (Marx, 1867: Preface to the 1st German
Edition).
7 Organization, according to Poulantzas, is the condition for the exercise of a specifijic
class practice (Poulantzas, 1973: 128).
8 It is no coincidence that the favorite slogan of capital in these times of globalization is
“to make labor relations more flexible.”
44 chapter two
The general conditions for this form of domination are the weakness
and lack of organization of the workers, on the one hand, and a state per-
missive of “private initiative” (i.e. spontaneous, individual movements of
capital by each individual capitalist) on the other. The workers have suf-
fered some political and ideological defeat, and capital has transformed
and developed the capital relation with some technological revolution
which, on the one hand, increases its control on manufacturing and, on
the other, increases the surplus worker population, superfluous to the
needs of capital appreciation. In light of the weakness of the working
class, the state assumes the role, as Marx and Engels describe it, of “a com-
mittee for managing the common afffairs of the whole bourgeoisie” (Marx
and Engels, 1848), as the mere expression of the logic of capital.
Under these conditions, each individual capitalist will search for the
strategies that best suit him to increase his rate of profijitability, with no
concern as to whether the outcome degrades the workers, society in gen-
eral and the environment, because attending to his long-term preserva-
tion, although a condition for reproduction for capital itself, is not
necessarily worthwhile from the perspective of immediate profijitability.
And, in so far as his actions yield competitive advantages over other capi-
talists, these others will imitate his practices and even outdo them;9 the
logic of competition between capitalists contributes to the activation of a
spiral of growing social degradation, even to the detriment of their own
long- and medium-term interests.
However, according to Marx, “capital, which has such ‘good reasons’ for
denying the suffferings of the legions of workers that surround it, is in prac-
tice moved as much or as little by the sight of the coming degradation and
fijinal depopulation of the human race, as by the probable fall of the earth
into the sun” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 10). By way of explanation, he adds, “looking
at things as a whole, all this does not, indeed, depend on the good or ill will
of the individual capitalist. Free competition brings out the inherent laws
of capitalist production, in the shape of external coercive laws having
power over every individual capitalist” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 10). The more
the process is abandoned to the initiative of individual capitalists, i.e. the
more absent the capitalist state is in the regulation of their behavior, the
9 “The division of labor within the society brings into contact independent commodity
producers, who acknowledge no other authority but that of competition…. [and]
denounces with equal vigor every conscious attempt to socially control and regulate the
process of production” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 14).
the general forms of capitalist domination 45
less control capitalists actually have and the more capital governs the
process.
Because “the fijirst birthright of capital is equal exploitation of labor-
power” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 10), the individual capitalist who best embodies
the logic of capital – for example, the one who establishes the longest
working day (if, given the technical combinations between duration and
intensity, this proves a profijitable option) or the one who best organizes
the army of workers at his disposition, “making labor relations more flex-
ible and globalized” – will be the one who sets the pattern for all other
capitalists to follow, regardless of the processes of degradation that these
initiatives may unleash upon society. The limits on this form of domina-
tion depend on the extremes to which capital itself will go before it places
the general conditions for its reproduction at risk and provokes the grow-
ing resistance of workers, of society in general and, ultimately, the inter-
vention of the state to moderate and regulate its actions.
The resistance of the workers must be organized in such a way so as to
compel the capitalist class as a whole; restraining one individual capitalist
would probably only result in his bankruptcy, without resolving anything
in terms of the general mode of class relations. The trade union battle,
bringing one group of workers into confrontation with one individual cap-
italist, is not enough. To break this form of domination, workers must
achieve a certain level of general organization in the form of class organi-
zation. When it reaches its limit, this form of domination offfers a number
of possible conclusions:
• The struggle of the workers provokes the capitalist state, representative
of the whole capitalist class, to regulate and moderate the excesses of
capitalists.
• The struggle of the workers ultimately destroys the capital relation.
• The workers fail in their attempt and capital continues its work of
destruction and degradation.
In the fijirst case, the natural form of domination of capital shifts to a con-
tained form. In the second case, capitalist society moves towards social-
ism. In the third case, at least while the failure of the workers persists or
until the capitalist state itself reacts, society and nature will continue to
sufffer the efffects of a growing process of degradation.
In summary, with the natural form of domination, the spontaneous
movement of capital, the movement arising from its internal logic, from
its insatiable need for surplus-value, from its exclusive attention to its own
interests, in the absence of a “general public interest” being imposed upon
46 chapter two
The fijirst condition for the appearance of the contained form of the
domination of capital is thus a process of complex and intense worker
organization and struggle, a class struggle, which places the workers in
confrontation not (or not only) with individual capitalists, but with the
state, the general representative of capital. Secondly, as a result of this
struggle, the containment must be imposed on capital by the state, and
must assume a form that is binding, coercive and legal: “The English
Factory Acts… curb the passion of capital for a limitless draining of labor-
power, by forcibly limiting the working-day by state regulations, made by
a state that is ruled by capitalist and landlord” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 10).
Thirdly, the restrictions will meet with violent opposition from capital-
ists: “The working-class was everywhere proclaimed, placed under a ban,
under a virtual law of suspects. The manufacturers had no need any longer
to restrain themselves. They broke out in open revolt… against the whole
of the legislation that since 1833 had aimed at restricting in some measure
the ‘free’ exploitation of labor-power” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 10).
Fourth, if restrictions cannot be prevented, the capitalists afffected will
demand that they be imposed upon all, to prevent disparities in their
“right to equal conditions” in the exploitation of the workers and competi-
tive disadvantages. The Factory Acts in England, the fijirst labor legislation
enacted by a capitalist state, began as a set of special laws for mechanical
spinning and weaving mills, but the industries subject to the regulations
wanted an even playing fijield, since “the fijirst birthright of capital is equal
exploitation of labor-power by all capitalists,” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 10), and so
demanded the universal application of the legislation.
Fifth, the restrictions should include the workers themselves, to prevent
the possibility that competition between them, job uncertainty and
unemployment may compel them to submit defenselessly to the condi-
tions imposed by capital: “For protection… the laborers must put their
heads together and, as a class, compel the passing of a law, an all-powerful
barrier that shall prevent the very workers from selling, by ‘voluntary con-
tract’, themselves and their families into slavery and death” (Marx, 1867:
Ch. 10, emphasis added).
These conditions are the fijirst signs of the transition toward the con-
tained form of capitalist domination. But there is one other condition
essential to defijining the possibility of consolidating this transition: “When
the barons of industry submitted to what they had not been able to pre-
vent, and even reconciled themselves to the outcome, the force of resis-
tance of capital began little by little to weaken” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 13). In
other words, capital fijinds some kind of compensation: if the working day
48 chapter two
when the working class receives a genuinely larger portion of the com-
modities produced for consumption each year. It seems, therefore, that
capitalist production entails conditions that do not depend on good or ill
will, conditions that only fleetingly tolerate this relative prosperity of the
working class, and always in the nature of a storm-bird, a harbinger of the
crisis.”10
A capitalist economic crisis is always, essentially, the result of a reduc-
tion in the rate of profijit; whatever the specifijic historical circumstances
may be that have brought about the crisis, capital and its state will turn on
the workers to raise the rate of surplus-value and restore the level of the
rate of profijit and, in circumstances of a crisis in capital accumulation and
a drop in the rate of profijit, they will consider it totally inadmissible and
absolutely impossible to grant concessions to the workers: “the recovery
from the state of crisis will always be accompanied by an intense attack on
the living conditions of the masses” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1989: 133).
From that moment, capital and its state will make every efffort to dis-
mantle the system of concessions established during the period of the
contained form of domination. Workers will try to hold onto the conces-
sions, which represent veritable historic victories won with great efffort
and intense struggle, with blood shed and lives sacrifijiced by whole genera-
tions; however, having reached its limit, the logical way out offfered by this
form of domination is a return to the natural form. The workers, after a
reasonably long period that placed them in a political and ideological con-
text in which they could negotiate with capital and its state rather than
struggle against them, are unlikely to fijind the ideological and political
conditions necessary to turn this crisis in capital accumulation into a revo-
lutionary crisis that could bring about the destruction of the relation of
capital to wage-labor.
With the return to the natural form of domination, and in a context of
new historical circumstances, in a new stage of the life cycle of capitalism,
of its middle and long term, the workers once again fijind very narrow ave-
nues for negotiation; capital unleashes its natural logic, its spontaneous
movement, and the workers will once again have the opportunity (and the
need) to struggle against capital, to disobey it, to oppose its economic,
political and ideological domination.
The class struggle, under the conditions of the contained form of domina-
tion, acquires a distinct framework, a means of processing the conflict
between the classes that is diffferent from the means applied under the
conditions of the natural form of domination; this framework is con-
structed based on the conditions for negotiating the concessions that
capital is willing and able to grant the workers and/or that labor is able to
wrestle from the capitalists.
In the establishment of this framework, the relationship between domi-
nant and dominated is not necessarily democratic. What distinguishes
one general form of domination from the other is not their degree of dem-
ocratic or authoritarian development (although we may acknowledge its
importance), but the recognition (or lack thereof) of the material interests
of the workers; i.e, the distinction does not lie exclusively in the political
sphere, as it is deeply rooted in the economic sphere, in the conditions
for exploitation of the workers and in the development of the capital
relation.11
Nor does the distinction between the forms of domination lie in the
sphere of ideology; the hegemony of the bourgeoisie, although expressed
as “intellectual and moral leadership,” according to Gramsci’s analysis, is
not a purely ideological matter. This hegemony requires material support:
“for the dominant class to ‘convince’ the other classes that it is the ideal
group to ensure the development of society, that is, that its own interests
are mixed up with the interests of the general public, it is necessary to
foster, within the economic structure, the development of the forces of
production, and the (relative) improvement of the standard of living of the
masses” (Thwaites Rey, 1994, emphasis added).
Marx, Engels and Lenin analyze the capitalist state as essentially
founded on its coercive capacity, what Gramsci calls “political society.”
Gramsci uses the term “East” to defijine societies under a backward form of
capitalism, with a gelatinous civil society. On the other hand, in the societ-
ies of advanced capitalism, in which the bourgeoisie has established a
11 A brief reference to the case of Mexico may clarify this idea: it is clear that Mexico’s
post-revolutionary, developmentalist “social authoritarian State” maintained a much
greater commitment to the interests and material needs of workers than the current “neo-
liberal State”, offfijicially labeled “democratic” or, at least, “in transition toward democracy”
(see, for example De la Garza, 1988). We thus fijind that “democracy”, restricted appropri-
ately, can prove more exclusionary than a form of “social authoritarianism” that regulates
social demands, negotiating, granting or rejecting them.
the general forms of capitalist domination 51
14 I refer here to Lenin insofar as the analysis of the form of domination is concerned.
With regard to the form of struggle and victory over capitalist domination, I feel that there
are crucial diffferences between Marx and Lenin, and that Gramsci is much more consis-
tent with Marx: there is a considerable distance between the Leninist “vanguard party”
(which represents, leads and, fijinally “liberates” the proletariat) and the Marxist proposi-
tion (“the emancipation of the proletariat can only be the work of the proletariat itself”),
just as there is between state capitalism, now long gone (which referred to itself as “real
socialism”) and the efffective socialization of the means of production and means of subsis-
tence, i.e. the real destruction of the capital relation.
15 For example, Portelli associates the “East” with pre-capitalism (Portelli, 1998: 143),
which would mean there would be nothing to learn from the “East” to explain the forms of
domination of the present day.
the general forms of capitalist domination 53
Gramsci and his analysis of the West might lead us to assume. It is clearly
the strong form of capitalist domination – strong in the sense that it is the
form that is presented as legitimate to the dominated and is therefore the
most susceptible to ideological manipulation to the benefijit of capital
domination. For this same reason it is more important, in theoretical, ide-
ological and political terms, to determine at what time and under what
conditions it appears in the life cycle of capital and whether it may possi-
bly reappear.
Third, my purpose is not simply to reproduce Gramsci’s East and West
with another name, but to seek out more general features, to attempt an
abstraction and to identify general forms of capitalist domination. If gen-
eral forms can be found (and not merely forms associated with specifijic,
unrepeatable historical conditions), it will then be possible to examine
them, not as periods in the history of domination, but as criteria for the
periodization of the history of domination, or general forms subject to dif-
ferent modes of historical expression. We may thus consider the history of
capitalist domination not only as a series of periods, but also as an alterna-
tion of forms of domination which, in their succession, acquire diffferent
historical meanings, associated with their position in relation to the long
term, the life cycle of capital.
Fourth, if with these general forms we can periodize the history of dom-
ination, we can identify variants within the same period in which a par-
ticular general form pervades, diverse and specifijic historical examples
which nevertheless correspond to the same period in the history of capi-
talist domination and share certain essential features; in other words, dif-
ferentiated examples sharing the same historical territory, the same
general form of domination. This will be explored further in the following
chapter.
CHAPTER THREE
Present-day bourgeois society, no less than its predecessors, [has been exposed]
as a grandiose institution for the exploitation of the huge majority of the people
by a small, ever-diminishing minority.
F. Engels
Karl Marx
In the work of Marx, as well as in that of Engels and other Marxists (Lenin
and Gramsci in particular), we can fijind the basis for a general theory
of capitalist domination. On the other hand, there is a vast number of
individual studies of capitalist domination in specifijic countries and in
particular periods. The natural space for the organization of capitalist
domination is the nation-state. It should therefore not be surprising that
the study of specifijic examples of capitalist domination naturally entails
the study of specifijic nation-states.
Pattern of Domination
1 “Marxism views the global economy not as a simple sum of its national parts but as a
powerful, independent reality created by the international division of labor and by the
global market, which, in our times, dominates every national market. The forces of produc-
tion of capitalist society swept away national boundaries some time ago. (…) The specifijic
features of a national economy, as important as they may be, constitute to an increasing
degree the elements of a higher unit known as the global economy, on which, ultimately,
internationalism is founded,” Leon Trotsky (as quoted in Ayala and Figueroa, 2001).
the pattern of domination 57
2 “Capital as personifijied by the Latin American bourgeoisie is not capital in general, but
underdeveloped capital, which at the same time makes it the carrier of the relations repre-
sented by underdevelopment and its main social and political base of support” (Figueroa
Sepúlveda, 1989: 91).
60 chapter three
3 Food and raw material production is still “evolving and is an object of progress… this
suggests that the region (Latin America) may be stagnating in the exportation of basic
products… Technical progress allows developed countries to reduce their dependence on
our countries” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1989: 164–165).
4 Two forms of economic growth reflecting particular patterns of industrial colonialism,
historical forms that express the basic tendencies of underdeveloped production in a
particular way” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 2001: 12).
the pattern of domination 61
fate of the economy is linked to the development of exports and the under-
developed economy does not control its own development. The second is
relative or “inward” growth: although it depends on the growth of exports,
accumulation is aimed at the internal market (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986:
153–155).
Of the features which, according to Figueroa Sepúlveda, characterize
each of these forms of growth, a few of relevance to our topic are outlined
below:
In conditions of absolute growth, as it involves the use of competi-
tive capacity at an international level, the predisposition toward open-
ness to and dependence on foreign capital is accentuated. The effforts of
the state are not focused on the unifijication of the nation or on the devel-
opment of the internal market, but on clearing obstacles to interna-
tional trade; the design is strengthened to keep wage levels down, as this
becomes a “comparative advantage.” Because it needs to operate with a
high organic composition, the capacity for absorption of labor-power is
greatly reduced, unemployment rises and competition between workers
intensifijies. This type of growth fosters a concentration of wealth and a
gap between the poles of rich and poor, and is characterized by authori-
tarianism in the political sphere and free trade in the economic sphere
(Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1989: 154–159).
In relative growth, industrialization, aimed at the internal market,
diversifijies the branches of immediate labor and expands internal demand;
the state establishes mechanisms for the protection of this industry, cre-
ates an infrastructure aimed at facilitating internal transactions and, in
general, unifijies and fosters the development of the internal market. The
number of workers expands, their organization is strengthened within set
limits and, if the process displays a certain continuity, wages should grow,
albeit slowly. This form of growth is characterized by an interventionist
state that is developed in the manner of a direct capitalist (Figueroa
Sepúlveda, 1989: 160–164).
Thus, as described above, if the political sphere (i.e. the sphere of domi-
nation, of regulation of relations between social classes) is inseparable
from the forms of economic organization, and if the basic distinction
between the general forms of capitalist domination lies in the recogni-
tion or denial of the material interests of the workers, it is clear that the
only possibility in underdevelopment5 for some mode of the contained
5 At least in the Latin American case, which is the case examined here, although it is
highly probable that the whole underdeveloped world shares the same essential
characteristics.
62 chapter three
6 Although the basis of the relation between capital and wage-labor lies in the separa-
tion of workers from the means of production and subsistence, capitalism makes a range
of other expropriations and constructs diverse needs of exploitation and domination that
require science for their development: “the separation of workers from the means of pro-
duction in the economy, from the means of war in the army, from material means of
administration in government, from the means of research in the academic institution and
66 chapter three
the laboratory, is a common decisive factor both to the modern military-state politi-
cal enterprise and to private capitalist economics” Max Weber (as quoted by Portantiero,
1981: 17).
7 “In the United States we fijind… from the direct enlistment of intellectuals, scientists
and academics in State and Defense department programs (see the Report of the Panel on
Defense Social and Behavioral Sciences, Trans-action, May 1968), to the incorporation of
social scientists into operations designed and piloted by the Pentagon and the CIA against
revolutionary movements (Irving Louis Horowitz: “The Life and Death of Project Camelot”,
in Professing Sociology, Aldine, Chicago, 1968), and even the use of private foundations (the
Ford Foundation and many others) and ad hoc associations (Congress for Cultural
Freedom, etc.) efffectively coordinated by the U.S. Administration to organize both intel-
lectual and media initiatives in order to promote the objectives of the United States”
(Vidal-Beneyto, 2002).
8 The laws of the market are, in bourgeois discourse, analogous to the laws of nature and,
particularly in neoliberalism (which in reality is a theology), they have the same logical
structure as the laws of God.
the pattern of domination 67
9 For example, the Cold War and the fijight against “the communist threat” at the peak of
the post-war period offfered vast territories of experimentation and development, just as
the so-called “fijight against organized crime” does today.
10 “The fact that the historical development of political and economic forms has seen
the rise of the ‘career’ civil servant, technically skilled in bureaucratic work (civil and mili-
tary), is of primordial importance in political science and in the history of forms of govern-
ment” Gramsci (as quoted by Portantiero, 1981: 49).
68 chapter three
11 See Lenin’s defijinition of the merging of banking and industrial capital (Lenin, 1916:
226).
CHAPTER FOUR
In any given society, the striving of some of its members conflicts with the striv-
ing of others, [and] social life is full of contradictions. Marxism has provided
the guidance – i.e. the theory of the class struggle – for the discovery of the laws
governing this seeming maze and chaos.
V.I. Lenin
Karl Marx
In the previous chapter I argued that, beyond the specifijic features of each
of the many diffferent nation-states, it is possible to identify periods in the
world history of capitalist domination in which either the natural form or
the contained form has predominated, and that the historical manifesta-
tion of a general form constitutes a pattern of domination in such a way
that its period of prevalence is efffectively a period in the world history of
capitalist domination. The purpose of this chapter is to examine the via-
bility of this proposition by analyzing the political history of capitalism (if
only in a general historical outline) in terms of the concept of the pattern
of domination.
period of time beginning in the late 18th century and running throughout
the 19th.
An examination of the spread of the natural form of capitalist domina-
tion, tracing its historical path from its birth and introduction around the
world, is beyond the scope of this study. I will therefore limit my study of
this historical panorama to the presentation of the general features that
this form assumed as the liberal pattern of domination in developed capi-
talism, particularly in England (which was the hegemonic state at the
global level during the period), and as the oligarchic pattern of domina-
tion in Latin America.
1 See Marx’s discussion of relative surplus-value (Marx, 1867) and his explanation of the
concepts of formal and real subsumption (Marx, 1863).
74 chapter four
2 “Private property, which constitutes the basis of bourgeois society, occupied the cen-
tral position in liberal theory and the constitutional systems of the period: to ensure the
inviolable character of property and the power to dispose of it freely, guaranteeing the
unimpeded development of industry and commerce” (Kuhnl, 1978: 50).
the history of capitalist domination 75
The fijirst aspect has already been partly addressed above. The public
sphere, which organizes the activities of the state, is clearly delimited; it
has the sole function of setting general rules regarding the movement of
private individuals and protecting their liberty and property. Everything
else falls within the private sphere and is beyond the authority of the state;
the state must remain neutral with regard to the content of the agree-
ments established between free and equal individuals.
It should be added here that democracy is a form of administration of
the public sphere – a form of administration of state activity. The limits of
the public sphere are therefore also the limits of the territory of democ-
racy; everything excluded from the public sphere is also excluded from the
administration of democracy. In other words, in the liberal state, the con-
tent of the agreements established between free and equal individuals are
not a public afffair, nor are they subject to any regulation arising from the
state’s administration of democracy. They are simply matters excluded
from the public agenda.
In relation to the second aspect – the form of organization and expres-
sion of inter-bourgeois relations – it should be noted fijirst of all that, in this
fijirst stage of the life cycle of capitalism, ownership of the means of pro-
duction and subsistence (i.e. the capital/wage-labor relation) was spread
out over a large number of capitalists. In its fijirst stage, the liberal state was
the political expression of competitive capital, in the phase of free capital-
ist competition: it was this multiplicity of capital owners that gave rise to
the liberal state in its fijirst stage, prior to the rise of imperialism in the last
third of the 19th century. The periodical elections of governments and
their control by legislative bodies reflected the conditions of inter-
capitalist competition and the need to prevent the state from being used
by individual capitalists to promote their accumulation over that of their
competitors.
Of course, the bourgeoisie has never been a homogeneous class at any
time in its history. It has always been divided into groups and factions, and
inter-bourgeois conflicts are reflected in the struggles for control of the
state. However, in this period (as never again in periods that followed), the
state was the state of the whole bourgeoisie, and its status as a democratic
institution, specifijically the principle of the division of powers, operated
efffijiciently. In the subsequent periods, as we will see later, the state favored
the interests of one faction of the capitalist class and, consequently, execu-
tive power acquired a clear preeminence over the other powers that con-
stitute the formal institutions of bourgeois democracy.
the history of capitalist domination 77
3 The criticism of bourgeois individualism does not imply a denial of the importance of
the individual; in Marx, in clear contrast with the so-called “real socialism” of the 20th
century, a socialist project of liberation only has meaning if it guarantees the full realiza-
tion of the individual (See for example Fromm, 1978; Mészáros, 1978).
78 chapter four
4 “With the victory of liberalism, social assistance measures were suppressed due to
their incompatibility with the principles of free economic expansion, legal equality of per-
sons and non-intervention of the State in the economy; as a result the working-day grew
longer and female and child labor increased. As any form of labor association was prohibited
under very severe laws, the afffected parties accepted the work conditions imposed upon
them. The submission of the workers to discipline and obedience would not have been
possible without the help of the bourgeois State” (Kuhnl, 1978: 81, emphasis added).
5 “A class in an upward phase like the bourgeoisie tends to develop an optimistic inter-
pretation of its social function and of the world in general. The basis of the liberal concep-
tion of the world rests on the conviction that history constitutes a rational evolution
toward superior forms of life; man learns to dominate nature with increasing ability and
will ultimately subject the development of society to the demands of reason. Man is con-
ceived as naturally good and capable of attaining perfection; he only needs the opportu-
nity to develop freely. Together with the doctrine of natural rights and the natural
the history of capitalist domination 79
equality of all men, optimism and humanism form part of this basic conception. This opti-
mistic, humanist faith in progress also characterized the philosophy of history in this
period” (Kuhnl, 1978 39). Needless to say, the bourgeois discourse in relation to history – the
discourse of “modernity” – contrasts violently with contemporary “post-modern”
discourse.
6 “The production relation that tended to be predominant and stable was slavery. This
constituted the basis of operations for large-scale production aimed at exportation; it
offfered the use of a massive work force that was compelled to work under the harshest
conditions… The Spanish colonial ‘mita’ or ‘cuatequil’ [systems of forced labor] difffered
from classical slavery, but nevertheless constituted slavery. The same is true of the peonage
or retainer… The ‘peón’ (general laborer) was not a free laborer with the ability to sell his
labor-power as a commodity, but a slave tied to the plantation and to the will of the land-
owner” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 211).
7 “In our case, the result of the Conquest and colonization could not have been a simple
slave-based economy. From the beginning, the aim was to organize the exploitation of
labor and production directly in order to increase exchange-value. What arose here was
therefore not a slave-based economy in the sense of the social relation represented by slav-
ery constituting the nucleus around which society is organized and its movement is deter-
mined; rather, slavery was set within another dynamic, which emerged from the developing
global market” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 212).
8 “The productive intentionality of the dominant classes continued to be export pro-
duction, both because there was no internal market and because they showed no interest
in developing local industry… production continued to depend on external demand”
(Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 219).
80 chapter four
9 Indeed, several institutions of the colonial past defended by the conservative current
within the oligarchy, such as the military and ecclesiastical authorities, aided by the
absence of an internal market, operated as forces to block the process to establish a nation-
state. See, for example, Ricaurte Soler (as quoted in Cueva, 1993: 46).
10 The inter-oligarchic struggles did not end because an internal solution was found,
but as the result of the economic growth produced by demand in the countries of devel-
oped capitalism; the oligarchy on its own was never capable of fijinding a way of establish-
ing itself as a nation-state or organizing a national economy. “After 1880, the new integration
of the Latin American economies into the global economy favored and strengthened all of
the oligarchies. Thanks to economic growth, inter-oligarchic struggles came to an end”
(Carmagnani, 1984: 98).
11 Macondo, the fijictional town in Gabriel García Márquez’s epic novel One Hundred
Years of Solitude, has often been interpreted as a metaphor for Latin America in the 19th
and early 20th centuries.
12 “The weak and scattered effforts to promote capitalist production found no echo
among those who controlled economic power, who showed practically no interest whatso-
ever in the ‘nation’ in terms of its development. Rather, they sat waiting for the benefijits
that independence might bring in terms of diversifijication of the external market” (Figueroa
Sepúlveda, 1986: 217).
the history of capitalist domination 81
13 From Marx’s Outlines of the Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 1 (as quoted in Figueroa
Sepúlveda, 1986: 220). “This does not impede, but rather entails,” adds Figueroa Sepúlveda,
“their non-capitalist behavior in relation to the labor they exploit.”
14 Even the so-called “middle classes” had the quality of a bureaucratic or professional
“clientèle”, at the service of the oligarchic boss not only in terms of their employment but
also in social and political terms (Quijano, 1977: 148).
15 “Wherever free labor is the rule, the laws regulate the mode of terminating the con-
tract. In some States, particularly in Mexico, slavery is hidden under the form of ‘peonage’.
By means of advances, payable in labor, which are handed down from generation to gen-
eration, not only the individual laborer, but his family, become, de facto, the property of
other persons and their families” (Marx as quoted by Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 211).
82 chapter four
For over one hundred years, from the revolutions of 1848 to the popular
revolutions after World War II, and even into the 1950s, Europe would be
the stage for decisive confrontations between capital and labor, the con-
frontations that have defijined the history of humanity up to this time.
84 chapter four
In Europe, for the fijirst time in human history, the working class became
self-aware, creating its own “conception of the world” and its own “civil
society,” and organizing itself into a multitude of labor and political orga-
nizations that sought not only to improve their situation within the capi-
tal/wage-labor relation, but to destroy the relation itself. For the fijirst time
in human history, the working class became a subject of history. But the
decisive events in this long struggle took place after World War I, over the
course of the 1920s – the “tragic decade” for the worker movement. Below
I attempt to outline the process leading to the key moments of that decade,
in order to situate my discussion in the context of the crisis and transfor-
mation of the liberal pattern of domination.
The liberal pattern of domination faced a crisis with the working class
struggle and, as the working class had become organized and established
as a subject of history, the crisis for this fijirst emergence of the natural form
of capitalist domination had two possible conclusions: the revolutionary
transformation and destruction of capitalism, or the restructuring of the
forms of capitalist domination.
As discussed above, during the liberal era there was clear and open hos-
tility toward any form of working class organization. According to the
logic of the liberal pattern of domination, worker organization was an
intolerable attack against liberty and the ordering principle of social life:
the private agreement between free and equal individuals. However (and
this is a point stressed by Marx in the Communist Manifesto), the develop-
ment of capitalism itself created a space in which, inevitably, the fijirst
forms of working class organization took shape: the factory. With the
expansion of capital, factories and the number of workers multiplied; the
expansion and the accumulation of capital also multiplied the number of
workers in a single factory, under the command of a single capitalist.
The proletariat was in the process of establishing itself as a revolution-
ary class, and this process, as Claudín points out, had two facets: on the
one hand, the constant deterioration – both absolute and relative – of the
living conditions of the proletariat, which compelled them to rebel; and
on the other, the factory as a breeding ground for unity, organization and
class consciousness (Claudín, 1976: 20–21). It should be noted that, accord-
ing to Marx’s analysis, the fijirst aspect explains the condition of the need
for rebellion, a particularly intense need under the conditions of capitalist
liberal domination. The second aspect offfers the condition for the possi-
bility of rebellion.
At the beginning of the liberal period, the central goal of capitalist dom-
ination was expressed in the efffort to eliminate the possibility of worker
the history of capitalist domination 85
By the fijinal decades of the 19th century, fijinancial capital was already
structured and widespread, giving rise to the fijinancial oligarchy, the fac-
tion of capital which, from that point on, would hold the reins of power in
capitalist society. From that time, the state was placed at the service of
fijinancial capital, and the social order that the state would strive to create
would be in line with the interests of fijinancial capital.
After the major revolutionary crises of 1848 and 1870, it became evident
that the liberal pattern of domination was coming to an end. To survive,
capitalist domination needed to be restructured; reform of the system of
domination was essential to prevent revolution, and the economic trans-
formations already underway would support this reconstruction of domi-
nation. In 1895, in his introduction to Marx’s book, The Class Struggles in
France, Engels made the fijirst reference to the transformations that the
form of domination was undergoing. Considering that the main political
element of change was the organized presence of the masses throughout
Europe, he writes: “the mode of struggle of 1848 is today obsolete in every
respect.”
The arguments put forward by Engels to explain this obsolescence
cover a wide range of issues, including changes to the military dimension
of domination. However, there are two issues Engels mentions which
I believe are central to my analysis.
The fijirst of these is the issue of democracy and the right to vote, as a
right seized by the workers from the capitalists with considerable struggle,
and the benefijits they obtained from this right. In particular, the workers
and German social democracy “have used the franchise in a way which has
paid them a thousandfold and has served as a model to the workers of all
countries… [the franchise has been] transformed by them from a means
of deception, which it was before, into an instrument of emancipation”
(Engels, 1895).
The second is the new meaning of the nation-state and democratic
institutions in the class struggle. Until then, electoral democracy, limited
to the participation of property owners, had been a simple instrument for
organizing the dominant class; but now, according to Engels, with the
“successful utilization of universal sufffrage… an entirely new method of
proletarian struggle came into operation… It was found that the state
institutions, in which the rule of the bourgeoisie is organized, offfer the
working class still further levers to fijight these very state institutions”
(Engels, 1895).
It is clear that Engels, a revolutionary socialist, is not interested in bour-
geois democracy as a means of “improving” capitalism, but rather as a
the history of capitalist domination 87
To resolve the problem that the mobilization of the masses and the cri-
sis in the liberal pattern of domination posed for the bourgeoisie, it was
necessary to “abandon the concept of the linear relation of the individual
to the sovereign, and locate that relation within the analysis of the organi-
zations that ensure the reproduction of domination” (Portantiero, 1981:
16). The reality of capitalism at the beginning of the 20th century was “a
reality of groups and institutions and could not be tackled using the notion
of the individualist contract” (Portantiero, 1981: 12); the reconstruction of
capitalist domination could only be based on the recognition of the cen-
trality of the worker organizations.
In this context, in 1917, in the midst of a revolutionary crisis on the rise,
Max Weber outlined the basis for the reconstruction of the bourgeois
political system as a “state of the masses,” asserting that the political left
(social democracy and the unions) would have to play a central role. The
masses, mobilized and determined to participate politically, could not be
treated as passive objects of the administration; however, as they think in
immediate terms, they are exposed to emotional influences and tend to
practice “street democracy.” This meant that “rationally organized parties”
and a “mature trade unionism” were needed: “the best guarantee against
the fijickle political moods of the ‘Spartacists’ was the integration of the
trade unions and of social democracy into the political system” (Portantiero,
1981: 14).
And indeed, the social democratic parties had been moving toward
“rationality and responsibility”; in the context of the imperialist war, they
had aligned themselves with their respective national bourgeoisies and
had concentrated their political effforts on modifying the forms of domina-
tion rather than destroying domination itself. For Bernstein, it was a pro-
cess of transition toward the “neutrality” of the state, while Cunow asserted
that “we are the state”; both viewed the capitalist state as a neutral space,
with “instrumental potential to protect diffferent social interests according
to the historically variable capacity manifested by whichever social sector
predominates in that originally empty space” (Portantiero, 1981: 28). For
Kautsky, the pressure of the organized masses modifijied the essence of the
state itself: “if it becomes the instrument of an exploiting minority, this is
not due to the nature of the state but to that of the working classes, their
disunity, their ignorance, their lack of autonomy or their inability to strug-
gle” (Portantiero, 1981: 28).
Such was the path of gradual transformation of the pattern of domina-
tion taken by the processes of capitalist restructuring in the 1920s and
the history of capitalist domination 89
1930s in Western Europe. The crisis of 1929 produced two major political
responses: on the one hand, an advance in the process of transformation
of the liberal pattern toward a contained form of domination and, on the
other, the brutal response of fascism and the destruction of the best sec-
tors of the worker movement, while the parties of the Second International
attempted to consolidate new forms under capitalist domination and the
parties of the Third International led the workers from one defeat to
another, unable to make sense of the process of capitalist domination that
was taking place or of its political efffects on the masses.
Following World War II, with the fall of fascism, having overcome the
crisis produced by the emergence of “people’s democracies” in Eastern
Europe and with relations with “Sovietism” relatively stabilized, Western
Europe began to consolidate and develop the Keynesian pattern of domi-
nation. Meanwhile, in Eastern Europe, where the forms of domination
had been left untouched by the restructuring that had occurred in Western
Europe from the end of the 19th century onwards, the conditions of the old
liberal pattern of domination remained in efffect, and in Tsarist Russia, the
Bolsheviks, “a small conscious minority at the head of masses lacking con-
sciousness,” seized power and built societies based on state capitalism,
fijirst in the former Russia and then in a wide region of Eastern Europe. The
Bolsheviks, after the elimination of a large portion of the old revolutionary
guard, turned into the pigs in Orwell’s Animal Farm16, a new form of
bourgeoisie.
Thus, in Western Europe, the restructuring of the forms of domination
allowed the bourgeoisie to defeat the proletariat in the revolutionary cri-
ses that occurred in the fijirst decades of the 20th century, while in Eastern
Europe, specifijically in Russia, the victories of the people’s revolutions
merely brought new forms of administration of capitalist development.
The working class was thus defeated on two fronts.
Nevertheless, a major change had occurred in the structures of domina-
tion; for the fijirst time in the history of capitalism, the bourgeoisie recog-
nized the need to accept a compromise with the proletariat, and the
16 This analysis does not attempt to examine the peculiarities of the so-called “real
socialism” of the 20th century, but I believe its essence lies in the diffference between
nationalization, which reproduces the separation between workers and means of produc-
tion, and socialization, the genuine appropriation of the means of production directly by
the worker: “the fact that capital is entirely centralized under the command of a single
corporation does not negate its capitalist nature” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1989: 56). In all other
respects, Orwell’s novella appears to me to be extraordinarily astute.
90 chapter four
therefore of the conditions for the genuine defeat of capitalism and its
transformation into socialism disappeared from the moment that the
SUCP destroyed the Soviets as institutions of real power. From that
moment, the “representatives of the proletariat,” the self-declared “revolu-
tionary vanguard,” took charge of the administration of state capitalism.
With the Cultural Revolution in Maoist China in the 1960s, the notion
made a brief reappearance, which was radically concluded with the coup
d’état of the seventies after Mao’s death; today, the Chinese Communist
Party is an efffijicient administrator of the development of neoliberal
capitalism.
Both the social democratic left (heirs to the Second International) and
the communist left (heirs to the Third International) were made up of
bourgeois elites; the social democrats orchestrated their inclusion in the
“political class” of Western capitalism while the communists became the
administrators of the state capitalism that they referred to as “real social-
ism.” However, both contributed to confijigure a new form of capitalist
domination which, in spite of all the diffferences existing between its indi-
vidual modalities, has one feature that is common to all of them: the
acceptance by capital of a compromise with the working class. As a result
of working class and popular movements around the world, a profound
transformation in the pattern of domination occurred and, during the
height of the post-war period, capitalism showed the most civilized face it
has ever worn. In the history of capitalism, working class and popular
organization and struggle has been the basic condition, not for the trans-
formation of capitalism into socialism (a mission yet to be fulfijilled), but
simply for the civilization of capitalism; without worker organization and
struggle there can be no revolution, but there can also be no reform that
improves the plight of the workers under the conditions of capitalist dom-
ination and exploitation.
17 The racist and xenophobic AFL, incapable of organizing a class struggle against capi-
tal was, on the other hand, an efffijicient defender of the trades: “As a practice very much of
92 chapter four
According to Coriat, it was Keynes who would complete the picture. Taylor
and Ford created the theory and the practice of mass production in the
the working class aristocracy, the defense of the trades was pursued with the most impla-
cable sectarian spirit and selfijishness… Racism and xenophobia were constituent parts of
the ideology of the AFL” (Coriat, 1992: 14).
18 “Mass production (the product of Taylorism and Fordism) requires the distribution of
sufffijicient purchasing power in the form of wages and income” (Coriat, 1992: 93).
the history of capitalist domination 93
workshop, while Keynes created the theory and practice for the type of
state and regulation that mass production required (Coriat, 1992: 88); his
general theory “formalized the conditions for the existence and reproduc-
tion of the mechanisms of mass production” (Coriat, 1992: 97). For Keynes,
the demands of the workers were legitimate; the challenge lay in respond-
ing to those demands or perishing. A new method of administrating labor-
power was a political necessity (Coriat, 1992: 98).
The new content of “labor policy” assumed by the state was defijined
during the “New Deal,” and during World War II this new content would
spread defijinitively throughout the developed capitalist world: the mini-
mum wage, the reduction of the length of the working-day, compensation
for workplace accidents, and unemployment insurance (Coriat, 1992: 98).
The state was established as the general operator of the reproduction of
wage-labor, the general administrator of the concessions that capital
would grant labor; for the fijirst time in its history, capitalism appeared to
acquire a certain ‘exteriority’ as a “system situated above social classes,”
establishing a legal framework which, fijirstly, regulated the direct relation
of exploitation (the conditions for the purchase and use of labor-power,
such as the length of the working day, overtime, child labor, wages, etc.),
secondly, defijined indirect wages (family allowances, health and education
services, medical insurance and retirement pensions) which ensured the
cheap reproduction of labor for capital, and thirdly, restructured unem-
ployment and disability assistance.
For the fijirst time in the history of capitalism, wages (as the sum of direct
wages paid by the employer to the worker, and indirect wages, as value
redistributed by the state) paid for the full value of labor-power, at least for
one section of the working class. As Suzanne de Brunhofff notes, “direct
wages permit the ‘reconstitution’ of the worker during the period of
employment, but not for the ‘maintenance’ of the unemployed or the ill,
or for the costs of family maintenance”; direct wages are thus lower than
the value of labor-power (Brunhofff, 1980: 226).
Under the conditions of the liberal pattern of domination, whereby the
labor relation is abandoned to the “agreement between two free and equal
owners,” the laborer, owner of his labor-power, is responsible for his
own maintenance, and this defijicit produced by unemployment, illness,
age and/or additional family responsibilities is compensated for by
community or family support for the worker, or by “the charity and benev-
olence of the employer,” as it is not considered a right of the worker, but a
donation made by the employer. Thus, also for the fijirst time in the history
of capitalism, the labor relation ceased to be the result of the supposed
“free agreement between willing individuals” that the liberal pattern of
94 chapter four
19 Coriat notes that in the United States, “the dominant phenomenon of the 1920s con-
tinued to be anti-worker violence… and during the crisis, union members were shot at in
Ford factories” (Coriat, 1992: 101). It is worth remembering that a decade later in Europe, the
Nazis massacred militant workers of both the Second and Third International.
the history of capitalist domination 95
20 “At the end of the war, African and Asian societies at the periphery of the global capi-
talist system were still subject to the colonial regime. The center/periphery polarization
had taken the form of a contrast between industrialized and non-industrialized regions.
The revolt of the peoples of Africa and Asia, the product of half a century of ideological and
political restructuring around the new notion of nationalism, began in 1945” (Amín,
2003b).
21 “After their political independence, the peripheries entered an era of industrializa-
tion, although their development was uneven… this gave rise to a growing diffferentiation
between a semi-industrialized ‘Third World’ and a Fourth World that had not yet begun to
industrialize” (Amín, 2003b).
22 In Mexico, the great rural worker uprising of 1910 had been defeated but not crushed,
and throughout Latin America the proletariat was growing in numbers and achieving cer-
tain levels of organization and combativeness: “The most solid cores of the working class
were consolidated fijirst in export production. Driven by their poverty… they began their
campaigns for better working conditions very early” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 168).
23 “With the great crisis that began in 1929 and lasted until the Second World War…
export production collapsed and absolute growth fell into serious discredit” (Figueroa
Sepúlveda, 1986: 169).
the history of capitalist domination 97
24 “The state, instead of limiting itself to regulating and enforcing the standards of eco-
nomic activity, acts directly as an economic agent” (Ianni, 1984: 148).
98 chapter four
First of all, the Latin American developmentalist state not only estab-
lished mechanisms for the protection of national industry; it also nation-
alized foreign companies, specifijically to take back control of key natural
resources in the structure of the export sector of the national economy,
and to ensure control of strategic sectors of the economy with state or
mixed companies, while reformulating the conditions for the entry and
exit of foreign capital and the conditions for its association with local
capital.
Only in this way can we understand descriptions like that offfered by
Ianni of the Mexican state in the era of President Cárdenas (1934–1940) as
the main decision-making center, with the capacity to expropriate and
redistribute assets for political and economic reasons determined by the
state, and to impose the modes of ownership and use on private, national
or foreign property in accordance with the national interest (Ianni, 1977b:
20).25 Ianni adds that during the Cárdenas presidency, government par-
ticipation in the national economy was expanded and systematized with
a global agricultural, industrial and educational plan, becoming the “orga-
nizing, dynamic and coordinated vanguard of production relations” and
of public and private accumulation (Ianni, 1977b: 14–15).
This margin of autonomy and of directorial capacity over the national
economy for the developmentalist state in Latin America could only occur
under conditions of relative or inward growth. It does not exist in condi-
tions of absolute or outward growth, as shown in the examination of the
oligarchic pattern, and as will be seen with the neoliberal pattern. In these
cases, the capacity of the state to direct the economy is practically nonex-
istent and the intervention of capitalists and imperialist states is direct;
imperialist capital directly appropriates the most profijitable activities,
and the subordination of the underdeveloped economy to the needs of
the developed world is direct and immediate. Relative growth, while it
does not mean either overcoming underdevelopment or breaking with
imperialism (i.e. it does not constitute a national project26 in the strictest
25 This was the case not only for the Mexican state, but for all Latin American states that
were able to move toward developmentalism: “Between 1930 and 1950, government powers
related to the economy and the economic role of the Latin American nation-state grew
enormously” (Ianni, 1984: 135).
26 ‘National project’ here refers to “a program that brings together a range of anti-impe-
rialist measures with the aim of breaking the subordination of the nation and the econ-
omy… Substitution industrialization was merely a strategy adopted by the local bourgeoisie
driven by conditions which they did not create… it was not applied outside the context of
developed countries, and certainly not against their interests… Whether or not the capital-
ists of developed countries interfere directly in our afffairs is unrelated to the essence of
the history of capitalist domination 99
sense), it does mean that neither capitalists nor imperialist states inter-
vene directly in the direction of the national economy.
Secondly, the development of the internal market diversifijied the
branches of immediate labor, expanded internal needs and allowed the
introduction of methods of production of relative surplus-value and job
growth. Under the conditions of the oligarchic pattern and of the predom-
inance of the primary export economy, the real subsumption of immedi-
ate labor spread in export production, but in goods consumed internally
(wage goods) there was no real subsumption or productivity-based growth.
“The production of relative surplus-value would come with relative growth
when the internal market took the central focus in the economy… It is in
this type of growth that the general tendency of capital toward the pro-
duction of relative surplus-value occurs… It constituted an element of the
fijirst transition, which took place when the worker movement had risen up
in protest against the length of the working day and existed as an orga-
nized, expanding force” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 184).
Increased productivity, real subsumption of labor to capital, production
of relative surplus-value, a rise in the rate of surplus-value and the rate of
profijit, in the context of the emergence of the masses, created the condi-
tions whereby capital (not without fijirst complaining, resisting, and assur-
ing that the end of the world was nigh) could view the prospect of granting
concessions to workers as tolerable, as part of the process of restructuring
its mode of domination.
For the fijirst time in the history of Latin America, “the government rec-
ognized the right of urban and rural workers to defend their interests and
to fijight to have them respected” (Ianni, 1977b: 23). They recognized the
workers’ social, economic and political rights; rights as workers and rights
as citizens. Among these was the right to freedom of movement, which
liberated the workers from the forms of coercive labor relations that
predominated in the oligarchic pattern of domination. The labor market
was formalized, legislation was passed to regulate labor relations, and
education, safety and public health programs were introduced, along with
unionization, paid holidays, health care, protection for pregnant workers
and maternity leave, free elementary education and the right to vote in
elections (Ianni, 1984: 136, 139). The labor relation became a contractual
relation supervised by the state, offfering contract conditions on the length
of the working day, a minimum wage and the rights to join a union and to
strike. Rights and duties were established for both wage-laborers and
employers. But in this process of granting concessions, the state also orga-
nized and controlled the workers.
The ideological framework upheld under the new form of domination
was developmentalist nationalism, which advocated harmony between
social classes in the name of the national struggle for economic emancipa-
tion and diversifijication, against socioeconomic backwardness, oligarchy
and imperialism. Societal peace was presented as a prerequisite for achiev-
ing the economic emancipation of the country and bringing social welfare
to all of the people; to give the country back to the people, it was necessary
to strengthen cooperation between capital and labor and the arbitration
of the state (Ianni, 1984: 149). But an ideological framework in itself is
never a sufffijicient condition for structuring domination. Populism, as a
starting point, as a moment of transition to the developmentalist pattern
of domination, constitutes a mode of direct and organic relation between
the state, the “populist” party and offfijicial unionism.27 Unionism is bureau-
cratized and formalized: “The union structure is established as a bureau-
cracy tied to or dependent on the state apparatus; its possibilities of
organization, initiative and interpretation of the interests of the class it
represents are delimited… state unionism politicizes the proletariat
according to the guidelines and limitations established by the regime…
the state-party-union system is developed as a central column of populist
power” (Ianni, 1984: 146–147).
In Mexico, this system of political domination was stabilized and per-
fected more than in any other Latin American country. The (urban and
rural) worker masses were classifijied in organizations directly linked to the
state, set up in opposition and mutual isolation so as to turn their diffferent
interests into instruments of control. All compromises were negotiated
with the union leaders, with no participation whatsoever by the worker
base. The leader, the benefactor responsible for everything achieved
“within the possibilities,” authoritatively directed “his” union. And the
leaders, as elite clientele, were offfered part of the booty (for this is really
what it amounted to) of the state: deputations, senate positions, etc.
27 “Priority is given to the union organization associated with the state apparatus…
non-populist union organizations are marginalized and even suppressed. At the same
time, the government reformulates the functional and organizational requirements of
unionism to keep it dependent on the state apparatus and limited to the purposes of popu-
list policy” (Ianni, 1984: 145).
the history of capitalist domination 101
The leaders were leaders because they had government support: “in the
defijinition of the power held by the leaders themselves, their connection
with the state is decisive and therein lies the essence of corporatist domi-
nation” (Córdova, 1979: 36, emphasis added). The state supports the offfiji-
cial leaders and represses any union movement organized against
corporatist domination in the hope of creating an independent union.
“What followed the conversion of the offfijicial party into a corporate
machine,” adds Córdova, “was no more than a prolonged process of per-
fecting the system of domination by and through organization. Once the
mobilizations ended, organization, now turned into an instrument of
political power, rapidly developed into a veritable prison for the organized
workers, as a power that they could not question, invincible and insuper-
able” (Córdova, 1979: 34).
And for rural workers, whom the neoliberal governments had invited to
become agricultural entrepreneurs to compete with the multinational
agricultural corporations, the outcome was even worse. While it is true
that agrarian reform responded partially to a very old rural demand, “rural
workers became the most politically degraded sector of the masses. In the
very process of agrarian reform developed by the Cárdenas government, a
colossal institutional network was woven which organized their produc-
tion and their whole lives” (Córdova, 1979: 36).
“Such is, in general terms,” concludes Córdova, “the gigantic structure of
domination that weighs upon the worker masses” (Córdova, 1979: 38).
Nevertheless, organized workers, with certain recognized rights and more
or less secure and stable access to their means of subsistence, were, in fact,
the fortunate ones; alongside them co-existed millions of “marginal” work-
ers, the immense majority of the working class, who were not unionized.
This solid structure of domination ensured the Mexican State of
decades of political stability. But other Latin American states did not
attain the level of perfection achieved by the Mexico, and workers were
able to establish their own political organizations and make their demands
heard. Domination became unstable, and the states violently reasserted it;
even during the height of World War II, the period of maturity of the devel-
opmentalist pattern of domination, the history of Latin America was
plagued with coups d’etat and violent authoritarian regressions.
The core problem lay in a nationalism that never sought to overcome
underdevelopment, and in the fragility of underdevelopment itself,
which rendered the state incapable of establishing a stable form of domi-
nation that would mean, at least to some degree, an improvement in the
working and living conditions of the workers: “what accumulation in
102 chapter four
The underlying premise here is the recognition that “the main political
element of change is the organized presence of the masses” (Portantiero,
1981: 25); in the developed capitalist nations (and throughout the world),
what marked the shift from the natural form of domination to the con-
tained form was a situation of emergence of the masses. From that time
on, the capitalist state operated in association with an “organized worker
the history of capitalist domination 103
28 These organizations may have been pre-existing, like the European social demo-
cratic organizations, or created ad hoc by the State itself, as in the case of the state corporat-
ism of underdeveloped capitalism.
104 chapter four
capital’s rate of profijit. A reduction in the rate of profijit would inhibit invest-
ment, reduce employment and work against the interests of the workers;
the notion of “rationality” established a space for negotiation and of “com-
mon interest” between the classes.
The whole scope of negotiation was thus delimited by one basic prin-
ciple: a rise in wages (both direct and indirect) depends on an increase in
productivity and on the various imperatives arising from the needs of
restructuring, competitiveness or modernization of capital. In a certain
sense, the workers became co-responsible for the efffijicient operation of
“their capital,” whether private or national; their interests appeared to be
tied to the efffective running of the company where they worked and the
economy of their country, in competition with other companies and other
countries.
Thus the agenda for negotiation and for what was negotiable also
acquired exact, predefijined parameters. The public institutions that
administrate part of the value of labor-power, according to Suzanne de
Brunhofff, “are constantly the site of class confrontations with regard not
only to their establishment, but to their form and size, and are only devel-
oped through compromises between the classes… These institutions…
constantly orientate administration relative to the demands of the work”
(Brunhofff, 1980: 236, emphasis added).
This delimited territory provides the structure for the endless bargain-
ing that keeps worker organizations permanently occupied; not only do
they negotiate the rights of the workers and the defijinition of the “rights
holders” (Brunhofff 1980: 248), but also, “the application of certain institu-
tional guarantees are the object of struggles… some of the capitalists act
outside the agreements of their class as a whole… and the uncertainty of
the outcome of the claims forms part of the insecurity of the proletariat.
There is no strictly progressive evolution in the integration of workers into the
system, not even in the case of the ‘stabilized’ sector of the proletariat”
(Brunhofff, 1980: 252).
Along with these transformations – not of form but of content – of
worker organizations, a separation occurred between the worker base and
the organizations representing it. There developed the widespread appli-
cation of what Coriat calls the policy of substitution, which “consisted in
depriving the unions of the general assistance functions that made them
popular with the workers” (Coriat, 1992: 55). Until this time, unions had
organized fijirst aid and mutual assistance funds for accidents, illnesses or
unemployment, in an expression of class organization, cohesion, solidar-
ity and consciousness.
the history of capitalist domination 105
29 The conversion from active player into passive observer is constantly promoted by
bourgeois ideology. This is the meaning behind the ideology of the hero incessantly pro-
moted in U.S. cinema and, in general, the meaning behind all spectacles: soccer in England
was the sport of the workers until it was turned into a spectacle and the workers into
spectators.
106 chapter four
well-being that workers in the 19th century and early 20th had never even
dreamed of. Such is the reward for political apathy and submission in the
workplace. But political apathy and workplace submission have a more
solid basis that is not limited to real or supposed worker conformism. The
traditional forms of protection against unemployment and illness (the
union, the family, the community) also constituted the social territory
where, in the 19th century and fijirst decades of the 20th, attitudes and
political positions were processed; in working class neighborhoods, in
their bars, in the heart of their family and community relations, the politi-
cal positions of the workers were defijined in relation to the various social-
ist projects.
The transformations produced by the new mode of capitalist develop-
ment destroyed these social spaces and fragmented the social organiza-
tion of the workers; they were individualized, isolated, atomized,
disintegrated, and confijined, in the best of cases, to the nuclear family.30
This left them with no social space in which to construct a political posi-
tion as a class. It was the transformation of the living conditions of the
workers that constituted the basis of the transformation of their values,
beliefs and attitudes, of their entire culture: “a new mass culture as a
reconstruction of a collective personality that required the introduction of
profound changes to everyday life” (Portantiero, 1981: 57).31
The risk that the emergence of the masses implied for the capitalist sys-
tem was resolved in a way that the liberals of the 19th century never would
have imagined. Its political design was centered on disorganizing, exclud-
ing and repressing the workers, while for Weber (according to Portantiero)
the problem of domination is a problem of the sociology of organiza-
tions: “contemporary reality is a reality of groups and institutions…
problem which, at the end of the 19th century and beginning of the 20th,
greatly preoccupied the capitalists and their hired intellectuals.32 For
Ford, the problem was resolved by influencing the living conditions of the
worker population. How to achieve this constituted a specifijic object of
scientifijic research. If experts on the topic did not exist, it would be neces-
sary to create them. Capital identifijied its problems and looked for answers:
“This era marked the beginning of cooperation between academically
trained experts (sociologists, psychologists, psychotechnicians, etc.) and
business leaders. Ford set up a ‘sociology department’ and a body of moni-
tors and inspectors… Their basic mission was to go out to the homes of
workers and the places they frequented in order to monitor their general
behavior and, in particular, how they spent their wages” (Coriat, 1992: 57).
With the results of this research, Ford turned the wage rises into a
means of control over all of the living conditions of the workers; he deter-
mined which workers could benefijit from higher wages (adults with at
least six months in the job, not women or underage workers); and he
established internal regulations to defijine the conditions for hiring (includ-
ing impeccable morals, cleanliness, no alcohol, smoking, games or bars)
and fijiring. The selection was strict and the benefijits could be withdrawn at
any time (Coriat, 1992: 57, 59).33
Another example may further illustrate this idea. While the National
Association of Manufacturers, anchored in the past, proclaimed that “we,
the employers, are responsible for the work carried out by our workers”
and resorted to physical violence to “discipline” the workers, Taylor assured
that there was no need to assert employer authority; the personal army
of that authority was reduced or eliminated, as thenceforth enforcing
its authority was a “scientifijic” exercise (Coriat, 1992: 32). Science, placed
at the service of capital domination not only investigated problems and
proposed solutions, but also, once the worker representatives had
renounced the possibility of a non-capitalist option and, together with the
representatives of capital and government, agreed to operate within
the scope of possibilities offfered by the logic of capital, science became
32 In both the U.S. and France, “the sessions and communications of the engineers were
focused fijirst and foremost remuneration systems. At the beginning of the 20th century, the
use of wages seemed to be the least risky method of keeping laborers in their place” (Coriat,
1992: 52).
33 Gramsci also reflects on the meaning of the processes occurring at this time: “The
puritan initiatives (in sex life, in prohibition of alcohol, etc.) have this meaning in the U.S.:
to modify habits and customs in order to develop ‘the new type of person demanded by the
rationalization of production and labor’” (Portantiero, 1981: 57).
the history of capitalist domination 109
the spokesperson for the needs and possibilities of capital, entrusted with
the task of presenting the rationale of capital in irrefutable terms, not as a
capitalist whim but as a natural law, and thus became an indispensable
aid in discussions between the representatives of capital and of labor.
The capitalist use of science, overdetermined by the needs of exploita-
tion and domination, inevitably result in a concentration of knowledge;
Ford, while explaining the achievements attained through rationalization
in his factory, boasted that 95% of “his” workers specialized in “a single
operation that the stupidest individual would be capable of learning within
two days” (Coriat, 1992: 45, emphasis added). Indeed, from the perspective
of the logic of the needs of capital, to reduce the largest possible number
of workers to stupidity (i.e. to make them more easily manipulated) is no
small achievement if it contributes to a rise in labor productivity and in
the rate of surplus-value.34 There is a possibility of stupidity and produc-
tive capacity coming into conflict with one another; the problem would
then lie in fijinding the optimal combination in accordance with the pre-
vailing technological designs and the composition of the collective of
laborers. But this is just what science is for – to solve these types of
problems.
The transformation of relations between the working class and the capi-
talist was necessarily combined with a transformation in the relations
inside the class itself. The working class became more heterogeneous and
diffferentiated35 and, as a result, in the context of the processes underway
at this time, more incapable of initiating large-scale group actions. The
worker parties and unions were transformed from organizations promot-
ing the political interests of the class into bureaucratic apparatuses inte-
grating the masses that received legal privileges and public funding. They
fijiltered and channeled demands, making them compatible with the con-
ditions of the system. They manipulated public opinion and tended to
34 The combination of Fordism and Taylorism means “a strict separation between the
conception of the production process (which is the task of the area of methods and orga-
nization) and the performance of standardized and formally prescribed tasks” (Lipietz,
1997); Taylorism takes capital appropriation of the conditions for the performance of
immediate labor to its most radical extreme.
35 Suzanne de Brunhofff distinguishes between an integrated proletariat that receives a
direct and indirect wage, one that receives only partial benefijits, a lumpenproletariat that
receives assistance, migrant workers, etc. (Brunhofff, 1980: 244–245).
110 chapter four
The shift from the liberal pattern to the Keynesian pattern of domination
constituted what Gramsci calls a passive revolution: “a process of transfor-
mations from on high, recovering a portion of the demands of those below
while taking from the latter all autonomous political initiative” (as quoted
in Portantiero, 1981: 44). The concessions made to workers administrated
by the state did not address all of the problems, nor were they offfered to all
of the workers, but they allowed the state to restructure domination on a
global scale: “Only government initiative was capable of giving assistance
a strategic global character: maintenance of ghettos, of underemployment,
of poverty, not as breeding grounds for disorder, but as elements of capi-
talist reproduction”37 (Brunhofff, 1980: 245, emphasis added).
The worldwide emergence of the masses, which sparked the crisis
for the liberal pattern and all the modalities of the fijirst emergence of the
natural form of domination and placed at risk the domination of capital
itself for the fijirst and until now the only time in history, was resolved with
1 “They need political liberty in order to unite all the Russian workers extensively and
openly… but millions of people cannot unite unless there is political liberty” (Lenin, 1903).
116 chapter five
2 Lenin suggested that “nations are an inevitable product, an inevitable form, in the
bourgeois epoch of social development. The working class could not grow strong, become
mature and take shape without ‘constituting itself within the nation’, without being
‘national’ (though not in the bourgeois sense of the word)” (Lenin, 1914). Neoliberal “global-
ization” has invested the matter of belonging to a nation-state with new complexities, such
as the location of working class organization and struggle.
neoliberal pattern of domination 117
that, at the onset of the crisis that brought the end of the post-war boom,
capital called for “free international mobility.”
3 In other words, any wage increase was contingent on an increase in the rate of sur-
plus-value and the rate of profijit.
4 For an explanation of the concepts of technological system and incremental innova-
tion, see Pérez, 1986.
118 chapter five
5 “The compatibility of capital profijits and the well-being of the masses had come to an
end… and the bases for the compromises between social classes likewise disappeared”
(Hirsch, 1996: 88).
6 “The leaders of the socialist parties have become one of the main bastions of the new
order. The heads of the major unions have transformed into the biggest dampers on worker
and popular protest. The old communist parties are beating a retreat in the political wake
neoliberal pattern of domination 119
of the socialist parties, in parallel with the restorationist about-turn of the CPs in Russia
and the countries of the East” (Ayala and Figueroa, 2001).
7 Both expressions are taken from Hirsch, 1996.
120 chapter five
But as supposed “socialism,” its worst features and its collapse – enthu-
siastically cited as the “collapse of socialism” by the ideologues of the
bourgeoisie around the world – created serious confusion and disillusion-
ment among the workers who still show no sign of rising up in a new
formulation of the socialist project. The “fall of socialism,” converted by
the spokespeople of the bourgeoisie into the end of history, in supposed
confijirmation of capitalism as the natural social organization of human-
kind, as its only possibility, helped to discourage and defuse any worker
response to the shift in the form of domination.
Meanwhile, Latin American developmentalism, which had never
sought to overcome underdevelopment, had also reached its limit. On the
one hand, the policy of import substitution, with the national market
relatively isolated from competition on the global market, had enabled
industrialization through the importing of obsolete production methods,
devalued in the developed world but still useful in the productive struc-
ture and market conditions of underdeveloped nations. In this way, indus-
trialization through import substitution reproduced, deepened and
perpetuated underdevelopment, creating an interminable spiral of import
needs.8
On the other hand, Latin American developmentalism opened up new
possibilities of appreciation for imperialist capital through the exporta-
tion of obsolete constant capital9 and the establishment of subsidiaries, in
alliance with local capital, within the Latin American economies. From
the mid-1950s on, the presence of subsidiaries of U.S. monopolies within
the Latin American economies – particularly the more industrialized
ones – was a growing trend. By the seventies, U.S. capital constituted the
hegemonic faction of capital within the most industrialized Latin
American countries, and, from within, it would pressure these countries to
adopt new modalities of growth.
By the end of the 1960s, Latin American developmentalism had reached
its limit with a process of industrialization that substituted imports, which
in fact required increasing quantities of imports, creating an industry
incapable of competing on the global market and therefore incapable
of exporting – that is, incapable of fijinancing its import requirements.
8 “The internal production of goods substitutes their importation, but creates new
import needs for intermediate and capital goods” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 162).
9 “This is why the U.S. bourgeoisie wasted no time in attempting to promote industrial-
ization (in Latin America), based precisely on obsolete material in the countries them-
selves” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1986: 173).
neoliberal pattern of domination 121
From the end of the sixties on, the foreign debts of Latin American coun-
tries began to rise, and by the late seventies and early eighties, an external
debt crisis arose which, due to the increase in interest rates imposed by
the Reagan administration, reached astronomical proportions until Latin
America was forced to undertake “structural adjustment” programs.10
“Inward growth” became a new modality of “outward growth,” no longer as
“primary export economics,” but through the creation of a new pattern of
industrial colonialism (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 2001), and the developmen-
talist pattern of domination disappeared to give way to the neoliberal
pattern.
In Latin America, as with the collapse of “real socialism,” the crisis in
developmentalism magnifijied the negative image of this socioeconomic
system, thereby facilitating the presentation of the transition from devel-
opmentalism to neoliberalism as a “transition to democracy and moder-
nity.” With the military dictatorships in South America, capital achieved
two goals. First, it crushed the popular struggles that had taken advantage
of the political space opened up by developmentalism, at least to the
extent of recognizing certain worker rights, encouraging some form of
nationalism and questioning the fragility and weakness of the underdevel-
oped world, the chronically subordinate pole in the imperialist relation, to
guarantee better working and living conditions for workers. And second, it
paved the road for the emergence of the new pattern of domination and
exploitation.
With these goals achieved, these dictatorships (along with fijinely-tuned
authoritarian corporatist regimes like that of Mexico) initiated what was
offfijicially referred to as the transition to democracy; the era of the dictator-
ships, the spokespeople for capital announced festively, had come to an
end, and a new era of civic maturity and development of “civil society,”
progress, respect for human rights and diversity, etc., had begun.
Throughout Latin America, a new era of economic progress was pro-
claimed, while in Mexico the discourse went even further and, with the
signing of the North American Free Trade Agreement with the U.S. and
Canada, the government asserted, with unequivocal certainty, that the
10 “The process of change had one fundamental point of support: the debt crisis, which
had been stimulated by the United States and which was precipitated by the abrupt change
in its monetary policy. The actions of the IMF and the World Bank would thus prove deci-
sive, as they made the aid offfered to cope with the rise in interest rates on the debt and the
total paralysis of the voluntary flow of funds conditional upon trade liberalization, eco-
nomic deregulation and privatization of the public sector” (Arceo, 2002).
122 chapter five
country was leaving the ranks of the underdeveloped once and for all and
entering the “First World.”
The capitalists successfully presented their strategic initiatives, aimed
at opening a new avenue to satisfy their appetite for the labor of others, as
the solution to the social ills of the previous period (ills which they them-
selves had created), and thus won the support of society for their new
projects, at least until the new ills provoked by the new initiatives become
evident and the hope inspired by the “new solutions” begin to fade, at
which point the cycle is initiated once again, with the proposal of some
new “solution.”
There is, however, a radical diffference between the transitions that
marked the shift from the natural form to the contained form and those
of the return to the natural form. While the fijirst meant that workers
around the world had managed to win some concessions from capital and
improve their working and living conditions (albeit within limits), the sec-
ond meant that capital resumed its normal role, rolling back the achieve-
ments that the workers had fought so hard to win.
The fijirst transition improved living and working conditions, while the
second was explicitly designed to worsen them: the reduction of direct
and indirect wages, the casualization of labor, increased unemployment,
and the resumption of direct control of underdeveloped nations. The
global wave that constituted the diffferent modalities of the contained
form of domination disappeared, giving way to a new emergence of the
natural form of capitalist domination that was imposed throughout the
world: the neoliberal pattern of domination.
In order to examine the neoliberal pattern of domination, I have
attempted to synthesize its general features into four processes that
I believe constitute the core of its dynamic. Although they are intimately
related, each of these processes requires separate analysis, and each one
constitutes an object of study of a process in progress, open to future turns
in the course of history. The aim here is thus to capture their tendencies,
their strategic purpose in the context of the capital/wage-labor relation,
without tying them to a particular moment in their development. It is thus
more an analysis on the logical plane than an attempt to defijine a historical
manifestation, although the United States and Latin America (particularly
Mexico) will serve as specifijic historical points of reference to illustrate cer-
tain tendential lines of the process. Another chapter is dedicated to the
analysis of each of these processes later in this work.
In Chapter 6, I provide a review of neoliberal economics: the so-
called globalization of big multinational fijinancial capital, based on free
neoliberal pattern of domination 123
As always, the party directing the process was developed capital. Its fijirst
responses were announced at the onset of the crisis in the late 1960s and,
from the 1980s onward with the initiation of a new technological revolu-
tion, big capital unleashed a strategic counterofffensive that would struc-
ture the new conditions for exploitation and accumulation and the new
conditions for domination. The neoliberal pattern of domination was
established as the political framework, the structure for domination, cor-
responding to the neoliberal economic model. Based on the proposition
of the concept of a pattern of domination as a general characterization of
capitalist domination in a specifijic historical period, my purpose here is
to trace the broad outlines of the process, viewing them as trends in
progress, particularly with regard to class relations and the imperialist
relation in Latin America, without attempting to study their historical
manifestations.
It is worth clarifying at this point that, as the main purpose of this work
is to analyze the capital-labor relation, no more than a brief examination
is offfered of the efffect that the inter-imperialist struggle (with the devel-
oped pole of imperialism redefijined in three major regional blocs) has had
in guiding the process, particularly through the initiatives of the United
States and its competitive strategies against the other blocs. It must be
stated, however, that as a result of a defijiciency in state administration of
development (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 1992), the United States has wasted no
time in launching strategies to compensate for its disadvantages and
increase competitiveness with its most efffijicient rivals, characterized by a
drastic disregard for the efffects that the behavior of its corporations have
126 chapter six
Free Mobility:
Neoliberal Internationalization of Capital
In my analysis of the Keynesian pattern I stressed one basic fact: all of the
institutions that regulated the capital-labor relation were constructed at
the level of the nation-state. This is a feature shared by all of the diffferent
modalities assumed by the contained form of domination; the working
and popular classes found a voice in the space of the nation-state and, for
the fijirst time in the history of capitalism, workers were affforded political,
economic and social rights, as well as relatively broad freedoms of organi-
zation, at least for negotiating better living conditions under capitalism.
Throughout the world, the working class and workers in general made
gains in terms of organization and their capacity for struggle in order to
wrestle concessions from capital, which were coordinated within their
respective nation-states.
I also stressed that, to affford the nation-state sufffijicient capacity to regu-
late class conflict through institutionalized mechanisms within the state
apparatus, it was necessary for it also to have the capacity to regulate the
economy (i.e. for the national economy to operate, to a certain degree,
under the regulation of the nation-state), and that a relative disconnec-
tion of the national economies from the global market was necessary, as
1 For an interesting examination of the contributions of the United States to the ram-
pant barbarism of today’s world, see Saxe-Fernández, 2006.
the neoliberal economy 127
2 “Fordism was basically organized under the nation-state structure. It revolved around
the expansion of internal markets on the basis of broad state intervention and institution-
alized class compromises” (Hirsch, 1996: 88).
3 “The institutions established under Bretton Woods – according to which macroeco-
nomic tensions were basically resolved at the national level, as each State could employ its
own monetary and fijiscal instruments to pursue full employment, but had to ensure levels
of growth of demand and prices compatible with the external balance” (Arceo, 2002).
4 “The interpenetration of capital on a collective scale shattered national production
systems and initiated their restructuring as segments of a globalized production system”
(Amín, 2003b).
128 chapter six
for free mobility sought to ensure the transition from Keynesian state reg-
ulation to regulation “by the markets,” that is, by the direct and immediate
needs of capital appreciation. The state would continue to intervene in
class relations, but its intervention would no longer be under the auspices
of a political pact; rather, it would be overdetermined – regulated, it could
be said – by “the markets,” by the interests of big internationalized capital.
The intention was thus to reestablish a state that not only permits but
vigorously supports the actions of “private initiative” (i.e. the actions of
the big international monopolies); a state adapted to the conditions of the
natural form of domination, to weaken and disorganize the workers and
destroy the diffferent modalities of the “social pact” that were structured
during the era of the contained form of domination.
The Keynesian state was transformed into the neoliberal state and
quickly began implementing the project that drove it: “all the conquests of
civilization that gave shape to the modern state (which today capitalism
destroys or negates) were the result of huge and bloody struggles. Through
the worldwide defeat inflicted by Capital on Labor by the end of the 1980s,
fijinancial capital was crudely reproducing, on a scale never seen before
and with advanced technology, many of the prevailing features of the last
quarter of the 19th century, from the imperialist wars of colonial conquest
to child slavery, the return of 10–12 hour work-days and the elimination of
labor regulations. It has been reconquering the space it had been forced to
give up, and reducing the political spaces of those whom it exploits,
oppresses and dominates. Only social resistance, which varies from coun-
try to country, places any limits on it” (Almeyra, 2007).
Money-Capital
Arceo examines the general framework which, by imposition of the
United States, the IMF and the World Bank, led to the “replacement of
the neoliberal economy 129
5 The relation between productive capital and fijinancial capital in this phase of capital-
ist development has particular features which are beyond the scope of this analysis: “a
crucial aspect of the constitution of global information capitalism is the contradictory
interrelation that has been established between production and fijinancial circulation.
There would seem to be a lack of correspondence or counterpoint between these two
spheres, as exchange rate speculation and volatility have translated into a series of regional
fijinancial crises, some of which have created momentary systemic instability that afffects
the growth of global production. However, the increasingly globalized fijinancial system has
come to play a key role in guaranteeing the cyclical reproduction of the new production
base, whose turnover rates have been considerably accelerated with an extremely high
potential for overproduction or overaccumulation” (Dabat et al, 2004).
130 chapter six
6 “Article 6 of the [Bretton Woods] agreement made it possible to control the interna-
tional movement of capital; this control was considered by its creators to be a central ele-
ment in order to prevent the interests of productive capital and of each society from
becoming subject to the demands of fijinancial capital, as had occurred in the period prior
to the Great Depression” (Arceo, 2002).
7 Speculative attacks that translate into major mass expropriations and conversions of
public and private resources which, before and after 1995 and with diverse variants, have
occurred periodically, coming to form part of what David Harvey calls “accumulation by
dispossession” (Harvey, 2004).
the neoliberal economy 131
the social relation that dominated and exploited them: the despotic, cruel,
fat-bellied capitalist with the black suit and gold chain. Under the condi-
tions of the Keynesian pattern, the visible party responsible for the behav-
ior of capital was the state and its governors. But now, the producer of the
workers’ hardships has disappeared and there is nobody to blame or to
fijight against; where does this Mr. Market live, exactly?
This transmutation of the world of social relations into a divinized
world of things, this extreme fetishization that has occurred under the
conditions of the neoliberal pattern and the use that domination by capi-
tal makes of it, must be borne in mind during the discussion that follows.
In redefijining its relation with the nation-state, with the liberalization of
fijinancial capital as the starting point, capital redefijined the whole struc-
ture of its economic, political and ideological domination.
Commodity-Capital
The process of freeing up the circulation of commodity-capital has been
rather more uneven and turbulent. On the one hand, there has been a
trend toward an increased opening up of national economies in order to
permit access to manufactured commodities on the international market.
This trend points to the shaping of a global capitalist market in line with
the interests of big internationalized capital as a whole, an expression of
its need and aspiration to have one single, unifijied world market at its dis-
posal. The fulfijillment of this purpose was the aim of the GATT, and of its
successor, the World Trade Organization.
But on the other hand, the current conditions of inter-imperialist com-
petition have led to the shaping of three regional blocs, each with their
own “spheres of influence,” and to the stagnation of the general advances
negotiated in the GATT and the WTO; so far, what has occurred in this area
is not so much globalization as regionalization, and its future develop-
ment will continue to depend on inter-imperialist competition. Even the
United States, the biggest advocate of free trade, “the form under which it
promotes the establishment of international regulations aimed at ensur-
ing the liberalization of trade and investments, is… strictly controlled by
an agenda that reflects the priority and interests of ‘its’ capital” (Arceo,
2002). For example, it simultaneously promotes “free trade” where and
how it suits its aims, and the establishment of Latin America as an area of
its exclusive influence.
The free mobility of commodity capital, less spectacular in its imme-
diate results than has been its twin, money capital, is nevertheless
the neoliberal economy 133
The above discussion makes it clear that the new modality of internation-
alization of money-capital and commodity-capital, while bringing pro-
found changes to the relation between capital and the state, constitutes
one of the pincers with which the pattern of domination will be radically
altered. What follows is an examination of the other pincer, the transfor-
mation of productive capital. I have given this phenomenon its own sec-
tion because it is here in the direct production relation where the essence
of the capital/wage-labor relation lies. The behavior of money capital and
commodity capital express the struggle for the appropriation of surplus-
value, but it is only in production that surplus-value is produced; the stra-
tegic purpose of the offfensive of capital lies in the restructuring of the
conditions for exploitation of the workers.
Although it may seem unnecessary, it is worth recalling here a few basic
truths, which should really be common sense but which tend to be over-
looked in the habitual ideological discourse of the neoliberal world, which
fosters the notion that capital appreciates without the need for workers.
Money-capital, particularly if it operates in speculative global waves, is
extraordinarily profijitable, but it can only transfer value; and for it to be
transferred value must fijirst exist – it must fijirst have been produced. And
to take control of the commodity market, it is fijirst necessary to produce
commodities. The secret of the whole capitalist universe, as Marx
explained, lies in the production of surplus-value, and the transformations
to the mode of operation of money-capital and commodity-capital only
fijind their true meaning when they are linked to transformations to pro-
ductive capital, re-establishing the unity of the M-C-M cycle which defijines
the unity (albeit with mediating and contradictory factors) between the
three forms of capital.
134 chapter six
10 Hirsch asserts that “the radical liberalization of commodities, services, money and
capital is the necessary prior condition for the renewed systematic rationalization of the
labor process in capitalist production, and this, in turn, is associated with the destruction
of the Fordist class compromise and its institutional bases” (Hirsch, 1986:89).
136 chapter six
avoid placing their jobs in jeopardy; and on the other, because the reloca-
tion had not only technical but political criteria: “a series of industrial
restructuring projects were implemented, aimed explicitly at relocating
the work force away from branches or regions that had shown the highest
combative force in the battles of the late sixties” (Thwaites Rey and Castillo,
1999, emphasis added).
This is an essential point which needs to be emphasized. The interna-
tionalization of money-capital and commodity-capital can operate
equally among developed countries and between developed and underde-
veloped countries. But the internationalization of productive capital must
necessarily operate in such a way that it links developed capital with the
reserve army of labor in the underdeveloped countries; its raison d’être
essentially lies in the promotion of opposition between the workers of the
developed and underdeveloped worlds. As this new capital initiative met
with success (i.e. as the bureaucracies ruling the unions and worker par-
ties showed their inability to challenge capital’s offfensive), it took on larger
dimensions, and the free trade zones which were negotiated in the late
1960s as restricted areas for the establishment of assembly plants11 began
to expand. In the 1980s, especially after the collapse of the Soviet Union,
the developed nations began to organize their expanded free trade zones
in the underdeveloped world encompassing whole countries and regions,
and the formation of an international labor-power market and access to
an international industrial reserve army became competition factors in
the inter-imperialist struggle.
In their respective spheres of influence, to ensure free mobility for their
productive capital, the developed nations promoted the elimination of
trade barriers, not only for the movement of commodities and capital but
for raw materials and equipment, as well as changes to customs systems to
make corporate imports and exports exempt of taxes. These were the nec-
essary conditions for the work force of the underdeveloped world to
become the real (and not merely the potential) industrial reserve army for
the capital of the developed countries.
With the advance and development of this process, its vast scope began
to be recognized: “as a long-term strategy, the free worldwide circulation
of capital was established as an unprecedented weapon for conditioning
the labor pole. As in capitalism no investment means no generation of
11 For example, the United States and Mexico negotiated parts of their border zone,
Europe relocated assembly plants to northern Africa, and Japan did the same in Southeast
Asia.
the neoliberal economy 137
14 “A new generation of less specialized means of production, through numerical con-
trol, the incorporation of microprocessors in the control of machine tools and the resulting
redesign of those tools… Thanks to the possibilities opened up by microprocessors, the
machine designed to carry out one given task on the production line for a specifijic product
is replaced by a tool that can be confijigured quickly to perform diffferent tasks, making it
possible to go from the production of one model or product to another and obtain high
rates of productivity with lower costs per product” (Revelli, 2004).
140 chapter six
On the other hand, for the segments that require easily replaceable
workers, those with fewer technical requirements, capital generally rejects
any compromise with labor and establishes what Lipietz calls bloody
Taylorism: external and hierarchical control of the labor process according
to the classical Taylorist method, but “without the social compensations of
the golden age of Fordism” (Lipietz, 1997), and these positions will usually
be concentrated in the underdeveloped nations. In these cases, flexibil-
ity15, a real or supposed technical necessity, often quickly turns into casu-
alization: “to make companies more competitive at the expense of job
security standards, increasing labor intensity and deregulating the condi-
tions of worker protection” (Sotelo Valencia, 1999: 118–119). This means
debased employment and wage conditions, job instability, the absence of
legal protection, and the nonexistence of union activity.
Thus, in the context of a segmented and globalized worker collective, a
single company can combine diffferent strategies within the same produc-
tion process, with a technological design coordinating the whole, for the
extraction of surplus-value ranging from the most barbaric and primitive
modes of production of absolute surplus-value to the most refijined strate-
gies for the production of relative surplus-value. For example, subcon-
tracting schemes often serve not only for technical flexibilization, but
also for worker casualization; imposing working days over the legal limit,
liberalizing severance procedures and evading employer obligations such
as the provision of medical insurance, holiday pay, profijit sharing, over-
time, etc.
In this way, a polarized labor market is established. At one end is a rela-
tively small core of qualifijied workers who enjoy social security, usually
guaranteed by the company itself, as a reward (given that it is no longer a
right) for their loyalty and membership of “the family.” At the other end is
“an army of ‘soldiers of fortune’, a work force ‘external’ to the corporate
community, extremely mobile, in certain aspects ‘nomadic’ and deprived
of job guarantees; workers with no identifying references, a solitary crowd
of freelancers with minimal qualifijications, prepared to accept employ-
ment according to the logic of the auction” (Revelli, 2004). Revelli suggests
that this tends to constitute “a ‘caste-based’ labor market, structured into
‘separate bodies’, each one with a diffferentiated legal status” (Revelli,
2004).
16 Former Mexican presidents Ernesto Zedillo and Vicente Fox affforded us highly
graphic and educational illustrations of how the State functions in its current natural form
of domination. Zedillo taught the world that to be a true “globalphile” in all issues related
to the “globalization” of capital means being totally “globalphobic” toward the “globaliza-
tion” of worker issues. Fox taught us how to respond to any call for social justice: “And
what’s it got to do with me?”
the neoliberal economy 143
17 For example, in Mexico nobody in their right mind would even dream that the
bureaucracy of the Confederación de Trabajadores Mexicanos (Confederation of Mexican
Workers) might be interested in producing an efffective policy for the defense of workers’
rights.
18 “The opportunities for ‘relocation’ to countries with low wage costs allows a capital
with no territorial ties to set up work forces tied to diffferent countries into competition
against one another and to override national labor legislation and collective wage agree-
ments” (Romero, 1998).
144 chapter six
19 “From the year 2000, a process of gradual dismantling (of maquiladoras) began due to
their migration to other countries in spite of the fact that Mexican labor is among the
cheapest in the world, and that the work conditions are, for 70% of the workers, exhaust-
ing, inadequate and extremely hazardous to their health… in China they are paying wages
of 50 U.S. cents per hour, without benefijits, unions or other obligations, in comparison with
the 2.50 dollars paid on average in Mexico” (Villegas Dávalos, 2004: 29).
20 In Mexico, according to the newspaper La Jornada on Wednesday, December 21,
2005, the president of the National Minimum Wage Committee “acknowledged that
Mexican workers have to choose between a very low wage increase and unemployment
and added that ‘the fijirst is preferable’.”
the neoliberal economy 145
21 According to the report in the magazine Forbes of the richest men in the world in
2008.
22 “The fijight for the increasingly scarce resources changes the nature of confrontations:
previously, for example, workers confronted their employers to obtain better wages, in a
vertical relation, but now, regions or groups confront one another to redirect the lean bud-
get offfered to others toward them instead, and this horizontal conflict, instead of creating
solidarity as in the case of vertical conflict, creates animosities and violence that tend to
breed and grow” (Almeira, n.d.).
146 chapter six
23 “The expansion of the new order to the periphery has been one of the fundamental
pillars of the process of capital transnationalization. It is the capacity of capital to organize
a production process on a global scale, locating each of its phases where its cost is lowest,
that has facilitated the gradual recovery of the rate of profijit through an offfensive against
labor, driven by competition between workers with markedly diffferent wage levels and the
expansion of the industrial reserve army in the areas of greatest resistance to the deteriora-
tion of living and working conditions” (Arceo, 2002).
24 As quoted in Dimas, 2002.
the neoliberal economy 147
the diffferent forms of resistance posed against the process are indicative
of the uneven advances in the process of liberalization of the underdevel-
oped world to developed capital in Asia, Africa, Latin America and Eastern
Europe. The FTAA project expresses the trend, with regard to the U.S.
approach to Latin America, but with uneven levels of development in dif-
ferent parts of the Americas, NAFTA being its most fijinished product.
However, with at least part of the underdeveloped world brought within
range of free mobility, capital’s next step is to select where to establish
what segment of its productive capital. Diverse factors influence this deci-
sion, including geoeconomic and geopolitical factors arising from compe-
tition between the three major imperialist blocs, administration by the
local state to create a “good economic and political environment” for mul-
tinational corporations (i.e. public investment in constant and variable
capital), industrial organization, transport costs and the location of mar-
kets, and the availability of natural resources in the country or region in
question.
In this regard, there are two factors of particular signifijicance. The fijirst
relates to the diffferent national conditions of labor-power, which essen-
tially defijine the location and segmentation strategies for productive capi-
tal; the aim is to coordinate the optimal combination of worker collectives
in terms of wage levels, labor rights, technical qualifijications and skills,
lack of political organization, worker discipline, etc. The second involves
the possibilities of industrialization in the underdeveloped world, which
have come to depend on the location strategies of the big multinationals
and, therefore, as the other side of the coin, on the countries’ ability to
make themselves attractive to those multinationals.
All of the underdeveloped countries that have opened up to the free
international mobility of capital have left behind the industrialization
strategy of import substitution. Now, it is basically the administration of
the work force made available to big multinational capital that determines
the possibilities of industrial development in the underdeveloped world:
“it is a new kind of enclave economy, through the development of an
updated version of the peripheral exporter model, in which the exploita-
tion of natural resources is replaced, with similar results, by cheap labor”
(Arceo, 2002, emphasis added).
For example, U.S. multinationals have an interest in NAFTA, an agree-
ment that is typical of inter-imperialist contradictions, as part of a com-
petitive strategy against the European and Japanese multinationals within
the U.S. market, but based on cheap labor in Mexico: “the MNCs looked for
competitive advantages in Mexico to win back positions in the heart of the
148 chapter six
U.S. market… The form adopted by the new pattern of industrial colonial-
ism in Mexico is directly in line with the interests of big U.S. corporations
in relation to competition within their own national market… U.S. corpo-
rate investment takes the form of the annexation of a strip of Mexico to its
own internal market as low wages and other advantages justify dealing with
other countries” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 2001: 26, emphasis added).
In the previous section, I analyzed the internationalization of produc-
tive capital as a global offfensive against workers. My purpose in this sec-
tion is to highlight a diffferent dimension: the internationalization of
productive capital and its strategies of profijit maximization as central to
the possibilities of industrialization in underdeveloped nations and the
efffects of this dynamic on their production structure. From now on, their
possibilities of industrialization will depend on being chosen by the big
corporations as the location for some segment of their production pro-
cesses, and this situation becomes more drastic the more open the under-
developed country is to the free mobility of capital in all its forms (not just
in production, but also money-capital) and, as a result, the more drastic its
renunciation is of any attempt to maintain an autonomous strategy of
industrialization and protection of its internal market. China is an exam-
ple of selective openness to production capital and commodity capital,
while Mexico is an example of indiscriminate openness.
Opening up to the productive capital and commodity-capital of the
developed nations necessarily involves a process that contributes to the
destruction of the local industrial base, as underdeveloped capital is not
competitive.25 It therefore means mortgaging the future to become an
attractive option for the establishment of segments of multinational pro-
ductive capital and to compete with other countries in a similar situation
in terms of their cheap labor-power, their basic source of international
competitiveness; under these conditions, competition is inevitably based
on constantly falling wages and increasing casualization of labor. Social
dumping thus becomes a basic competitive strategy.
What were known in the now long forgotten days of Keynesianism and
developmentalism as developing countries have disappeared, and in their
25 In Mexico, it is easy to document hundreds of cases of whole companies and indus-
trial sectors that have disappeared as a result of trade liberalization. One of these is
the production of automotive harnesses: “the independent producers of harnesses estab-
lished in Mexico during the phase of import substitution industrialization… disappeared
or moved into the spare parts market. Mustafá Mohatarem comments that ‘small, inefffiji-
cient and corrupt Mexican producers have gotten out of the game.’” (Carrillo and Hinojosa,
2003).
the neoliberal economy 149
26 A brief description of the “pattern of industrial colonialism” is offfered in Section 3.4
of this work.
150 chapter six
of worldwide production into the hands of the big capital of the developed
countries; the big multinationals are leading a process aimed at destroying
underdeveloped private capital, privatizing and transforming state
capital and deindustrializing the underdeveloped nations, turning them
into maquiladoras for partial production processes, subordinate links in
the production chain (Gerefffiji, 2006) that makes up their global factory.
Manufacturing activities have been concentrated into a few sectors
and a few corporations – basically big multinational monopolies or
oligopolies – and, after fijifty years of developmentalist effforts, the old
industrialization has been destroyed and any attempt to build a national
industrial system has been abandoned.
Capital and the state in the underdeveloped countries have even lost
control of primary production and the capacity to ensure national produc-
tion of the foods their population needs, as well as control of their basic
resources. Not only do the agri-food multinationals enjoy the conditions
and possibilities for organizing the production and marketing of all food
products worldwide, but also, as they control global scientifijic and techno-
logical research (biotechnology, genetic manipulation, nanotechnology,
etc.), they have a plan to control and monopolize worldwide food produc-
tion; in their strategic project, they seek to ensure a monopoly in food pro-
duction from the beginning, from seed production, thereby disabling any
other source of production. The development of this project represents,
for the fijirst time in history, a drastic break away from traditional agricul-
tural production, the production that has fed mankind since the dawn of
civilization.27 Inward growth, which has its political correlate in the devel-
opmentalist pattern of domination, has been replaced by a new modality
of outward growth, with a strict, direct subordination to the needs of the
developed pole, no longer as producers of raw materials and food prod-
ucts, but of labor-power, and the neoliberal pattern of domination pro-
vides the political framework for the new form of exploitation and
accumulation.
The imperialist relation between development and underdevelopment
has been redefijined, determined by the process of neoliberal internation-
alization of the capital of the developed nations (particularly by the inter-
nationalization of productive capital) and, although it is a process in
27 The huge importance, not only economic but political, of this control of both
food production and strategic natural resources worldwide should not be underestimated
(see, for example, Klare, 2002 and ETC Group, 2008).
the neoliberal economy 151
At this point it would be useful to turn briefly to the agents of the process,
the producers and benefijiciaries of the neoliberal order – the dominant
faction of the neoliberal pattern of domination. As has been shown, the
freeing up of the international movement of all functional forms of capital
(money, commodities and production) has tended to develop in degrees,
in modalities and at rates which, to a large extent, result from the circum-
stances of inter-imperialist competition. The establishment of a truly
global market is unlikely until the inter-imperialist struggle is resolved one
way or another.
However, with the development of this global market, although still in
its infancy, it is worth noting that, within the space of “free mobility”
opened up for big capital, competition has been exacerbated28 and, to
deal with it, an intense process of corporate reorganization and global
centralization and concentration of capital has begun, with mergers and
acquisitions between big monopolies – manifestations of an intensifijied
fijight for production and appropriation of surplus-value.29 The number of
corporations is constantly shrinking while their size and market share
28 “The wind of competition has become a storm, and the real hurricane still lies ahead
of us” (Heinrich von Pierer, President of the Siemens global consortium, as quoted in
Martin and Schumann, 1999: 15).
29 “In the decade from 1990 to 2000, the rate of mergers and acquisitions increased to a
level never seen before, beginning in 1990 with a total of 462 billion and closing in the year
2000 with an incredible peak of 3.5 trillion U.S. dollars, representing an increase of 7.5
times the initial level” (Ribeiro, 2007).
the neoliberal economy 153
30 Wal-Mart, for example, according to the report, “is the world’s largest corporation
and the world’s largest purveyor of food. A titanic power in global retailing, its corporate
conduct afffects business practices (labor, trade, environment and technology) all over the
planet. The company has 1.7 million employees; an estimated 138 million people shop at
Wal-Mart every week.” It is no coincidence that, as the report adds: “thirteen years ago, due
to pressure from the United States, the UN Center on Transnational Corporations in New
York was shut down and the intergovernmental community lost its capacity to monitor
global corporate activity. The United States is undoubtedly less enthusiastic today about
corporate monitoring than it was in 1993… ETC Group notes that access to corporate intel-
ligence is increasingly harder to come by” (ETC Group, 2005b).
154 chapter six
31 Martin and Schumann add: “358 multimillionaires put together are as rich as two bil-
lion fijive hundred million people – nearly half the world’s population” (Martin and
Schumann, 1999: 35).
CHAPTER SEVEN
A compact ruling elite seeks to plan, direct, structure and order all human
activity on the planet, backed up by their huge economic and fijinancial power.
So vast is this power that these elites no longer even think in terms of the planet,
as they consider the whole world to be their planet.
Salbuchi, Adrian,
El Cerebro del Mundo: La cara oculta de la Globalización
other… this enables the reciprocal and systematic oppression of national populations”
(Hirsch, 1996: 76, 98–99).
5 For an example of the defenders of this idea, see Ohmae, 1997.
6 “The most fundamental political decisions are disconnected from the democratic pro-
cesses of determination of the will and the interests of the people… political decisions are
made in direct negotiations between governments and powerful multinational consortia”
(Hirsch, 1996: 100).
158 chapter seven
7 With regard to the ‘national security strategy of the United States of America’, Rossana
Rossanda notes that the U.S. “has buried the period following the Second World War when
the United Nations and its Charter became the only forum for decision making and the
only source of legitimation of relations between States. The United States denies both the
content and the method; they are the ones who decide the universally valid ends, identify
the dangers and proceed to impose them by any means necessary. It is better if others fol-
low them, but not essential.” Rossanda, 2003.
8 In this world of disobedient States can currently be found – for diffferent reasons,
undergoing distinct processes and not forming any kind of common front – North Korea,
Iran, Cuba, Venezuela, Bolivia, etc., while others (Afghanistan and Iraq, for example) have
been punished and, with their rebellion, have become a problem that seems unresolvable
for the U.S. government.
the neoliberal state 159
12 To even attempt a list of the webs that the United States has woven around Latin
America – particularly Mexico – in the social, economic, political and military spheres is
beyond the scope of this work; it is also important to note that to a great extent, many of
the projects developed in this area are not disclosed to the public (see, for example, Saxe
Fernandez, 2007). Regarding U.S. military positioning in Latin America, see Petras, 2002.
13 The role played by so-called ‘think tanks’ in the development of public policy should
also be considered. See, for example, the strategic guidelines for the U.S. government in
relation to Latin America proposed in the Santa Fe documents (Committee of Santa Fe,
1980; 1988), and the articles by Abu-Tarbush, 2005 and Salbuchi, 1999.
14 The projects for the FTAA and the Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI)
reveal that the big multinationals certainly don’t lack imagination in establishing
their demands. The FTAA, according to Estay, ensures “the most complete facilities and
the neoliberal state 161
guarantees to foreign capital, and in particular to the major corporations of the hemi-
sphere (the vast majority of which are U.S. companies), putting these companies in a posi-
tion to establish the best of all possible scenarios for their full penetration into the
economies of Latin America and the Caribbean” (Estay, 2004). And the MAI, according to
Borón, “proposes no less than the unconditional surrender of society, represented by the
State, to all the dictates of capital… it is a kind of one-sided ‘International Treaty of Investor
Rights’ and a constitutional charter that sets forth the conditions for the full hegemony of
transnational capital” (Borón, 2001).
15 The result of these tax privileges for multinationals is, on the one hand, that taxes on
wages increase while taxes on profijits fall and “tax havens” abound: “the Cayman Islands,
with its 14 square kilometers and its 14,000 inhabitants, has fijive hundred banks and thou-
sands of registered companies and, of course, is the meeting place of a veritable Who’s Who
of barely disguised captains of fijinance and industry. In this way, capital evades national
jurisdiction” (Almeyra, n.d.)
16 “If the threatened denationalization of electricity and petroleum – already decapital-
ized and disconnected from the economy and the scientifijic and technological develop-
ment of the nation – were carried out, it would fatally accentuate the State’s budgetary
crisis and increase even more the dependence of companies and the government on the
policies of the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank and the U.S. Offfijice of the
Treasurer. In other words, it would plunge Mexico into a payments crisis, subjected to insis-
tent demands from globalization and neoimperialism for the delivery of more wealth,
resources and territory” (González Casanova, 2000).
162 chapter seven
17 This is, of course, part of a systematic strategy to sterilize democracy, as the local
spokespeople for globalization themselves admit: “it is the necessary institutional armor of
democracy against the distrust aroused by its seasonal and fast-paced politicians” (Luis
F. Aguilar, as quoted in Camil, 2005).
18 “Winning competitive capacity became the aim of States from the moment that big
capital had successfully imposed its free market system” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 2001: 21,
emphasis added).
the neoliberal state 163
attract global capital, making the creation of optimal conditions for that
capital their fundamental political priority and becoming caught in a spi-
ral which – viewed from the logic of capital – has no limits, as capital will
always demand more and will always seek out, among the diffferent
national scenarios, the one that offfers it more.19 Its establishment within
specifijic national boundaries is always provisional and, the moment a bet-
ter offfer appears, it will move on without any regret whatsoever; the chief
concern of the states thus becomes not only attracting investment from
global capital, but preventing it from leaving.20
The circle is closed with the evaluation (and the corresponding reward
or penalty) not only of the obedience of local governments, but of their
initiative and active involvement in responding to the needs of capital.
There is a direct and brutal manner of evaluating the behavior of states,
which is simply withdrawing from the territory of a state that has failed:
“the activity of the market itself, if there is full freedom of international
activity at the global level, tends by its own nature to give fijinancial capital
greater disciplinary power… Its mass withdrawal from countries open to
its activity in response to a policy that it rejects brings penalties which are
greatly feared in terms of exchange and fijinancial crises and contraction of
the real economy” (Arceo, 2002).21
Capital flight from a country is the most extreme consequence of a neg-
ative evaluation, but capital has designed detailed procedures to inform
the states of their desires and needs, i.e. their criteria for a positive evalua-
tion. Ultimately, the main intention is not to punish, but to foster appro-
priate government behavior and, to this end, clear and exact instructions
are required, as well as flexible adaptation and corrective mechanisms
19 “The struggle to attract investments is at the same time a constant efffort to deepen
the impoverishment of the workers and move resources toward big business… In this way,
the fijinancial oligarchy reproduces its world, as if its ravenous hunger for profijit could never
be satiated” (Figueroa Sepúlveda, 2003: 40).
20 For example, in spite of its geographical proximity and the existence of NAFTA, U.S.
companies decided to move their maquiladoras from Mexico to China, in search of labor-
power that is even cheaper than that offfered by Mexican workers: “How could Mexico
respond to this new situation? By reinforcing the same old mechanisms; i.e. pushing down
the cost of its labor, introducing ‘pending’ reforms related to opening up to foreign invest-
ment and enhancing tax incentives to attract that investment” (Figueroa Sepúlveda,
2001: 40).
21 On the same topic, Hirsch points out that the threatened response to any measure
that afffects capital profijitability is the flight of that capital: “this reaction of capital has been
made possible because there are now almost no political barriers to its international
mobility, and because the technical conditions for the flexible relocation of production are
constantly improving” (Hirsch, 1996: 98).
164 chapter seven
particular region,” and the general formula to overcome this lack of com-
petitiveness lies in offfering “moderate working costs, more flexible work
conditions, less environmentally rigorous legislation, and a certain level of
political stability with institutions that offfer confijidence and infrastruc-
ture” (Rosselet-McCauley, 2010).
The International Organization for Standardization (ISO), in response
to an agreement by the World Trade Organization, produces international
industrial and business standards (ISO standards), the purpose of which is
the coordination of national standards in order to facilitate trade and
information exchange: “in the context of competitiveness policy, the aim
is to adapt goods and services to international standards.”25 ISO 9000 and
9001 standards organize processes for “continuous improvement in the
customer and market relation focus… afffecting quality management of
products and services… establishes a comprehensive system by support-
ing competitiveness through quality management,” and it is expected that
they will be adopted not only by companies, but by government, educa-
tional and other institutions. Competitiveness thus becomes measurable
and assessable; the rules of “competitiveness,” the desires of the “cus-
tomer,” are specifijied exactly. External assessment becomes a mechanism
for the imposition of decisions, and the criteria and assessment scales
become instructions or public policy templates, the primary source from
which the policies of every state are drawn. But thanks to new information
technologies, the states of underdeveloped countries are subjected to a
level of supervision never seen before, placed on a network – on the inter-
national competitiveness network. But the process of international inter-
connection doesn’t stop there, as the external assessment criteria are
taken on as their own by the governments of the countries. In Latin
America, several diffferent governments have promoted the creation of
local replicas of the World Competitiveness Center in order to perform
their own internal evaluations applying the center’s criteria. Some exam-
ples are offfered below.
The Corporación Andina de Fomento26 for the development of what it
calls its strategic project, the Competitiveness Support Program, received
assistance from Harvard University’s Center for International Develop-
ment to set out the conceptual base for its activities and, “under the lead-
ership of Professors Michael Porter and Jefffrey Sachs, the center provided
25 The quotes in this paragraph have been taken from the ISO website (http://www.iso
.org/iso/en/ISOOnline.frontpage)
26 http://www.caf.com/view/index.asp
166 chapter seven
diffferent social groups share the same values and attitudes.”28 And, as a
fijitting reward for so much efffort, Latin America has its own Competitiveness
Report. In 2002, the fijirst Latin American Competitiveness Report was
published “in collaboration with Harvard University’s Center for
International Development,” with the purpose of “complementing the
World Competitiveness Report published by the World Economic Forum”
(Revista Inter-Forum, 2001).
All of these centers promoting competitiveness assert that it is “a task
involving everyone” (each and every one of us is human capital and, if we
take on the task appropriately, we constitute social capital), which means
that all of society is subordinated to the supreme goal of becoming attrac-
tive to transnational capital. For example, the Latin American Center for
Competitiveness and Sustainable Development (CLACDS) considers it
necessary “to promote changes in public policies, corporate strategies
and civil society initiatives” (Fernández Lagraña, 2006). And to promote
this “task involving everyone,” they establish what might be labeled Com-
petitiveness Promotion Brigades. In the suburbs, offfijices, schools, universi-
ties, government departments, political parties and unions, those most
prone to catching the Ah Q Syndrome virus are recruited, motivated by the
expectation of winning some reward, in imitation of the zeal and diligence
of Jehovah’s Witnesses, to preach the supreme command: be competitive.
In a quasi-religious ritual, which generally follows the same pattern, they
assert with fearful solemnity that “globalization is a risk” but, they add
with a smile from ear to ear, “it is also an opportunity.” They then go on to
explain in detail what to do to take full advantage of this wonderful
opportunity.
The task of the brigades (the due fulfijillment of which is periodically
subjected to external assessment to determine whether they are still wor-
thy of being rewarded) is to translate the needs of global capital, the
desires of the customer, into guidelines for organizing the daily activities
of their community and, in order to prevent any dissidence, to represent
the reality principle (‘this is what we need’), while promising some kind of
reward (‘if we develop ourselves as human capital and as social capital’).
The brigades constitute a social scafffolding which, supported by the net-
works of power deployed from the think tanks and global institutions
in an environment characterized by the destruction or absence of a
collective construction of alternatives, result in a relatively efffective social
leadership. In Gramsci’s terms, they form part of the civil society of neolib-
eralism; part of the downward network that disseminates the neoliberal
conception of the world and connects.
To complete the panorama of the submission to their interests that the
multinational corporations demand of nation-states, we should also con-
sider the concept of risk rating, defijined as “an opinion on the solvency and
security of a particular fijinancial instrument issued by a given institution”
(BBV, n.d.). Country risk is supposedly an objective measurement of the
capacity of a country to assume its fijinancial debt commitments at the
international level; the rating is issued by Risk Rating Companies – Dufff &
Phelps, Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s Investors Service, Goldman Sachs, and
Chase-JP Morgan being among the most important. The greater the risk,
the more expensive the credit for the country that assumes the commit-
ments. However, it is also a means of political positioning of international
fijinancial capital, and raising the risk rating can function as a warning or as
a reprisal from investors for some political behavior that disturbs them.29
And in the context of the panorama of submission and external assess-
ment, it should also be remembered that the U.S. government (the only
indispensable state in the world is the United States) implements unilat-
eral certifijication processes for the “good” or “bad” conduct of sovereign
nations, reports on the human rights situation in other countries, and
demands alignment with its policies regarding the “war on drugs,” the “war
on terrorism,” “preventive wars,” etc.
The offfijicial name for this whole process of submission to the interests
of transnational fijinancial capital and – in the case of Latin America –
submission to U.S. government supervision, is transition to democracy.
Around the world, neoliberalism proposes as a political model the estab-
lishment of formal democracy; although the institutions and processes of
liberal democracy continue to operate, “the essential political decisions
are disconnected from the democratic processes” (Hirsch, 1996: 100).
Neoliberal democracy is, in reality, “a new historical form of author-
itarian state” (Hirsch, 1996: 101), operating on the basis of one basic
29 Two brief examples illustrate this idea: Standard & Poor’s gave its customers a timely
warning and raised a yellow alert based on the possibility that if leftist candidate Andrés
Manuel López Obrador and the Party of the Democratic Revolution (PRD) won the
Mexican presidency, the country’s economic policies could sufffer dramatic changes
(Consuegra, 2006); and Goldman Sachs established a ‘Lula-meter’ tracing a connection
between country risk and the increasing likelihood of Lula Da Silva assuming the Brazilian
presidency, with the malicious intention of frightening part of the electorate (Dudley,
2002).
the neoliberal state 169
restriction: a drastic restriction of choice. The states cannot and must not
do anything other than ensure free mobility for capital, compete to attract
it and administrate the work force entrusted to them. A rigid conditioning
is imposed, as inescapable as if it were a divine law; according to neolib-
eral ideology, nobody controls globalization, it cannot be modifijied in any
way, everything must be adapted to its demands and there is no other pos-
sibility of progress. Neoliberal democracy is democracy that de-politicizes
and de-citizen-izes, if by politics we mean (in the theoretical tradition dat-
ing back to Rousseau) a collective efffort to defijine and construct a social
order that guarantees all individual rights, and by citizenship we mean the
right to participate in the defijinition of the social order. It produces democ-
racies that are sterile, unstable, and incapable of contributing to the con-
stitution of the social order.
In liberal democracy, citizens are legally defijined as the owners of the
means of production, and workers are excluded from this right. In what we
could call Keynesian democracy, the workers, through the construction of
a corporate forum of negotiation between the classes, acquire a certain
degree of citizenship. But neoliberal democracy establishes two types of
citizens; fijirst-class or real citizens, who make the decisions that defijine the
social order, and second-class or imaginary citizens, who merely vote to
choose the political personnel that will administrate the social order
defijined by the fijirst-class citizens.
The real citizens are hard to fijind because, being modest by nature, they
shy away from unnecessary publicity. But I have already examined how all
important political decisions aim at the creation of a system of organiza-
tions and political institutions beyond the scope of democratic control,
and how the states have become subordinate to the interests of transna-
tional capital and the institutionalized structures that it has created (the
World Trade Organization, International Monetary Fund, World Bank,
etc.), shaping a “hierarchically structured framework of states, interna-
tional organizations, multinational consortia and mafijia-type criminal
organizations,” (Hirsch, 2000), a “compact ruling elite that seeks to plan,
direct, structure and order all human activity on the planet, backed up by
their huge economic and fijinancial power. So vast is this power that these
elites no longer even think in terms of the planet, as they consider the
whole world to be their planet” (Salbuchi, 1999).
The imaginary citizens have a fleeting and cyclical existence. They
appear during each electoral period, vote and then disappear again.
But thanks to them, the rulers within the so-called political class are cho-
sen; those entrusted with the administration of the local governments,
170 chapter seven
30 “In the competition between party machines, the primary aim is to diffferentiate the
product using commercial propaganda industry techniques, and to organize and promote
show fijights with high viewer ratings, whose presentation and realization poorly conceal
the basic conspiracy between the opponents” (Hirsch, 2000).
31 Almeyra suggests that “merely institutional politics, when parliamentary institutions
don’t count, leads to the integration of the parties into the state machine and into the logic
of capital: corruption, seizing good positions, and unprincipled voting” Almeyra, 2004).
32 “They are transformed into apartheid regimes, which exhaust all their energy in the
militant repulsion of anyone who might threaten the privileges that still remain” (Hirsch,
2000).
the neoliberal state 171
33 “Political reforms have led the country to the creation of a political class that only
represents itself, distanced from the life of its society and of its voters. This political class
does not feel compelled to explain to society its view of the world and the future, or to
account for the empty promises made by its members when the time comes for them to
commit to the insipid hollowness of fijighting to the death for political seats and for posi-
tions and budgets” (Blanco, 2006).
34 “The law permits the creation and operation of political parties to turn into a busi-
ness with funds from the treasury and no relation to the public function that defijines them”
(Bendesky, 2003).
35 “Under ‘normal’ political conditions, the internal conflicts of the parties would
already have given rise to new formations, as they are irresolvable. But this doesn’t happen
because of the persistence of the monopoly on registration, the key to all prerogatives. The
result is that the diversity that actually exists is not expressed institutionally, but instead
has the efffect of paralyzing the internal organization of these parties, or is fabricated to
reflect the position of their candidates. Can a grouping of individuals with no ideology,
prepared to sell out to the highest bidder, be called a ‘national’ party?” (Sánchez Rebolledo,
2006, emphasis added).
36 “The parties and the sphere of politics are out of touch with the problems that con-
cern society, as their analyses and proposals have been reduced to campaign spots”
(Zermeño, 2003); “they see the democratic game as an exercise in image and marketing”
(Sánchez Rebolledo, 2003); “the television duopoly will receive close to 8 billion pesos from
the political class in payment for air-time to broadcast their campaign spots” (Rascón,
2005).
37 “Under the pretext of “‘democratizing’ Mexican public life, diffferent U.S. government
departments – and in particular the National Democratic Institute (NDI) and the
International Republican Institute (IRI), international arms of the two main parties in the
United States – have been advising Mexico’s three main parties for at least four years, and
for [the elections in] 2006, the U.S. Agency for International Development will provide
them with technical, political and fijinancial support” (Garrido, 2005).
38 “That Mexican democratic politics has turned into a circus says much about the
speed of adaptation of the local politicians to international trends, and much as well about
the surprising degree of disintegration of the ruling groups that command Mexico’s
longest-standing political formations” (Cordera Campos, 2006); “abundant use of unde-
clared income, derived from the treasury, but also from organized groups with illegal inter-
ests, open buying of the vote, shameless electoral mobilization and manipulation, and
forced abstention… what is worrying is the apparent apathy of the public toward extreme
displays of political immorality and, at the same time, the victorious reassertion that the
traditional mechanisms to prevent electoral fraud have a future.” (Hernández López, 2006).
39 The Editorial of the Mexican daily La Jornada on Thursday, January 19, 2006, offfered
a harsh examination of Mexican democracy, asserting that “democratic processes, when
they have existed, have not translated into responses to the serious social problems in the
country, which remain unresolved, if not exacerbated… the parties have made a great dis-
play of ineptitude, a lack of principles and the widespread deterioration of their internal
organization.”
172 chapter seven
has been very careful to keep social movements excluded from real access
to electoral contests, which is to be expected of the right or the center,
although somewhat surprising in the case of the left. Yet in spite of the
existence of a strong social opposition to neoliberalism, the priorities of
the leftist PRD do not go as far as the construction of a politically unifijied
anti-neoliberal front;40 rather, the party is highly susceptible to the Ah Q
Syndrome.41
Nevertheless, all evidence points to the fact that a majority of Mexicans
have voted in two presidential elections for candidates of the left, more
out of disgust with the center and the right than for the merits of the left
itself; the fijirst was Cuauhtémoc Cárdenas in 1988 and the second was
López Obrador in 2006. But in neither case did the left show either the
capacity or the willingness to oppose the frauds perpetrated by the other
members of the political class, being satisfijied simply to be members of
that class – second-class members – but members nevertheless.42 Under
these circumstances, elections are merely a source of discouragement and
will only serve either to roll back processes to construct collective alterna-
tives by promoting the individualist cry of “every man for himself” (in a
scream or a whimper) as the only option, or to push society forward in
search of new spaces for organization, resulting in an increased concen-
tration of politics in social movements.43 Nevertheless, according to the
U.S. government, Mexican democracy is worthy of praise.44 In other coun-
tries – Bolivia and Venezuela, for example – active social movements have
I will begin with a brief review of society under the conditions of neolib-
eral domination. To this end, it is worth highlighting two of the outcomes
of the processes examined previously: fijirst, the workers are ‘atomized’,
reduced to managing their relation with capital individually and to seek-
ing out individual options for subsistence; second, many workers sufffer a
severe decline in living and work conditions, both in developed and in
underdeveloped nations, although much worse in the case of the latter.
Neoliberal Individualism
The fijirst outcome is associated with the basis of the neoliberal pattern of
domination: while in the previous stage (the diffferent modalities of the
contained form of domination) capital organized workers corporately, in
this stage, capital disorganizes, atomizes and pulverizes in order to domi-
nate the workers, particularly in underdeveloped countries. In these coun-
tries, opening up to markets results in the collapse of the industry
established during the developmentalist period, replaced with the maqui-
ladora or offfshore assembly plant as a predominant form in industry, and
with unemployment on the one hand and casual employment without
labor rights on the other. This provokes the growth of the informal sector
and of exclusion and, as necessary correlates, chaos, anomie, and social
disorder.
Zermeño describes the situation created by neoliberalism as the spread
of “the assembly plant economy with its appalling implications for human,
working and living conditions, its broken and impoverished families, and
the state administration of criminal activity 177
production process. Between the labor-power system and company management there
must be established a cultural, existential continuity, a common perspective that allows no
fractures… ‘to build’ a totally new collective identity, rooted in the territory of the factory…
to secure loyalty and availability…. to subsume the existential dimension of labor-power
itself under capital… to identify the subjectivity of the work with the subjectivity of capi-
tal…. to make belonging to the company the only subjectivity possible” (Revelli, 2004).
3 Mokhiber and Weissman consider it necessary to remind us that corporations are not
individuals: “In spite of the fact that the law often treats corporations as if they were real
human beings, and in spite of the effforts of corporations to present themselves as part of
the community, corporations are essentially and fundamentally diffferent from real people
and should not be granted the same rights as people of flesh and blood… For example,
the state administration of criminal activity 179
free competition (i.e. not subject to any legal regulation) between workers
(between employed workers and other employed workers, between
employed and unemployed workers, and between workers in developed
countries and workers in underdeveloped countries). As it destroys the
social regulation of the class relation, neoliberalism hinders the construc-
tion of a collective order and promotes a wide range of particularities with
one basic purpose: to prevent any chance of structuring a class-based
political front by pushing class conflict out of view and rendering it harm-
less to neoliberal domination.
[in the United States] they have managed to evade a large number of reasonable regula-
tions related to advertising by claiming that they violate individual rights under the First
Amendment” (Mokhiber and Weissman, 2005b).
4 For a systematic exploration of this topic, see Chossudovsky, 2002.
5 Even as questionable as their criteria for measurement are, the fijigures provided by the
World Bank illustrate the enormous dimensions that poverty has reached in the world
today: in the year 2000, 1.1 billion people in the world were living on less than one U.S. dol-
lar a day, and 2.74 billion on less than 2 dollars; together this represents two thirds of
humanity (World Bank, 2003). According to data published by the FAO, 224 million people
in Latin America and the Caribbean live below the poverty line and more than 55 million
sufffer from malnutrition.
6 According to the International Labor Organization, “the number of unemployed
remained at an all time high of 195.2 million in 2006,” and “the ILO reported only modest
180 chapter eight
The issue of the dismantling of state institutions as viable spaces for work-
ers to coordinate some form of political defense against the voracity of
capital needs to be examined on two levels: fijirst, at the level of the nation-
state, especially those of underdeveloped nations; and second, at the
international level. In relation to the nation-state, again the evidence
speaks for itself. In chapters 6 and 7 of this work, I analyzed the process
that has led to the dismantling of the government forms of the previous
period and the establishment of the forms of the neoliberal state, and
I pointed out that the purpose of these transformations is, specifijically, to
destroy any space for capital to compromise with labor and to make the
state increasingly impervious to any democratic recourse whereby work-
ers might be able to express their interests and needs.
The result of this is what some authors have referred to as the “crisis of
the political”7: the breakdown of the system of public representation and
the rejection of the political class, made up of corrupt, servile, dishonest
and irremediable politicians who invariably go unpunished. Social prob-
lems increase while the “politicos” fijight for the popular vote by making
promises that nobody believes and playing their trump card of fijiltering
information to the media to create scandals that demonstrate that their
opponent is worse than they are.8 In terms of the second level, the lack of
gains in lifting some of the world’s 1.37 billion working poor – those working but living on
the equivalent of US$2 per person, per day – out of poverty… there weren’t enough decent
and productive jobs to raise them and their families above the US$2 poverty line” (ILO,
2007). This means that unemployment and casual employment that yields an utterly inad-
equate income for the worker afffects a total of more than 1.5 billion workers. Added to this
is child labor: 246 million children in the world work and some 171 million do so in hazard-
ous situations, subjected to various forms of slavery, prostitution and pornography, or in
armed conflicts, among other illegal activities. 1.2 million children are enlisted in forced
exploitation in the sex trade, which in Latin America is mostly aimed at tourists (UNICEF,
2005).
7 In Europe, Castells explains, “there is much talk of personal insecurity, crime, vio-
lence, loss of national identity (threatened by the invasion of immigrants and the suprana-
tional nature of the European Union), of jobs in danger and social security without a
future, of a world dominated by multinationals, of lives alienated by technology, of govern-
ments dominated by arrogant bureaucracies in Brussels or in Washington, of an American
superpower out of control, of a European Union that is faint-hearted globally and techno-
cratic in Europe, of fijinancial markets where our savings evaporate without explanation, of
media dominated by sensationalism, and of corrupt, servile and dishonest politicians”
(Castells, 2001).
8 The political class staggers from one scandal to the next, but nothing is ever corrected
or punished. They are simply scandals that are useful to the media: “the media has placed
itself at the very heart of politics, where the opinions and decisions of the public are
the state administration of criminal activity 181
formed… politics has to be adapted to a media language that has three rules: simplifijication
of the message, personalization of policy, and the predominance of negative messages dis-
crediting the opposition over positive messages with little credibility. All of this leads to
scandal politics as a basic weapon for gaining power by taking out the opponent… all the
parties have made the denunciation of corruption a favorite weapon” (Castells, 2001). In
Mexico, this institutional disablement has reached spectacular levels in the federal govern-
ment in cases such as the Savings Protection Banking Fund (FOBAPROA) and in state gov-
ernments in cases such as that of Mario Marín, the “gober precioso” (“dear governor”) of
Puebla, and Ulises Ruiz, governor of Oaxaca: “the large-scale disintegration of society, as
can be seen in the way in which political and economic power is exercised… moral decline
on public display… Impunity is what prevails, along with its counterpart, the increasingly
conspicuous absence of fijirm measures by the State to protect its citizens. In the face of the
evidence, practically all discourse rings hollow. The gobers preciosos are now a metaphor in
Puebla for the networks of complicity, abuse and arbitrariness that are rampant…. the out-
breaks of violence, the persistence of insecurity, the con artists and swindlers on every
corner and in every public offfijice” (Bendesky, 2006).
9 The spokesperson for these concepts par excellence is former Mexican president
Ernesto Zedillo, who, while a radical globalphile, proved profoundly globalphobic, arch-
nationalist and even xenophobic, on issues not related to the interests of big transnational
capital: outraged by the presence in Chiapas of an international human rights commit-
tee, Zedillo asserted that “these ‘progressives’ from abroad who consider Mexico a country
of ‘oppression, persecution, injustice and mistreatment of indigenous people’ need to
understand that it’s up to Mexicans to establish their own laws and resolve their internal
182 chapter eight
Even in the realm of the unions, where the capacity of the workers to com-
pel capital to negotiate once seemed an irreversible achievement, the
obstacles are enormous. Gallin explains that the incorporation of the
work force of the so-called “former socialist” and “former developing”
nations has added billions of workers to the global labor market con-
trolled by transnational capital, who have entered that market with their
own particular political backgrounds (“it would have taken a miracle
for the international union movement to rise above the weaknesses of
its members; it would have needed to wipe out forty years of history”),
some social democratic, others Stalinist, and the rest repressed and/or
corporatist: “the countries that play an important role in the global labor
market and that determine the conditions on the bottom of the scale
are countries where the people were severely repressed, such as China,
Vietnam or Indonesia, or where they are sufffering the consequences of
a tough repression in their recent historical past, as in Russia, Brazil
or Central America. Or they are ‘hard democracies’, countries where dem-
ocratic forms are observed but where social power relations are estab-
lished according to undemocratic rules, such as India, Mexico or Turkey”
(Gallin, 2000).10
On the level of civil rights, the construction of a framework of interna-
tional governability that would civilize neoliberal globalization, resolve its
“serious democratic defijicit” and give rise to the “social considerations”
that have so far been ignored, has been a constant proposal of the interna-
tional social movement, for example, at the World Social Forum, which
has identifijied “the need for a global governability to regulate the new
international economic powers… and to fijight for the globalization of
social rights,” (Díaz-Salazar, 2004), and has proposed “a diffferent globaliza-
tion that includes solidarity from the bottom up, the globalization of
human rights, the socialization of democracy as a universal value…
problems… “we Mexicans are quite right to be outraged and upset by this situation… the
solution to the problems in Chiapas will be internal… we Mexicans, without the need of
intervention, without the need of foreign interference, will resolve our own problems.’”
(Vargas, 1998; Urrutia, 1998). Thanks to this selective globalphilia, after completing his term
as president he joined the board of directors of three multinational corporations which
had benefijited during his presidency (Union Pacifijic Corp, Procter & Gamble and Grupo
Desc) as well as being appointed chairman of a UN committee (Villamil, 2010).
10 To this already complicated panorama should be added the fact that “the global rate
of unionization is below 13% (163 million union members out of 1.3 billion wage-laborers,
and this rate would drop to half as much or less if we also take workers in the informal sec-
tor into account)” (Gallin, 2000).
the state administration of criminal activity 183
the universalization of care for the Earth and its ecosystems” (Bofff, 2003).
But the inequity that plagues neoliberal globalization, both between
social classes and between developed and underdeveloped nations, is not
due to “defijiciencies in its governance”; on the contrary, its governance is
designed to make this inequity governable, denying workers not only
rights as citizens but even as laborers, while capital organizes its domina-
tion on a global scale.
It is a political design created by capital, personifijied by the big multina-
tionals and by the nations of developed capitalism, particularly the United
States (the “powerful countries and powerful players” to which the ILO
makes a vague reference), the result of a systematic and explicit efffort on
the part of what I have named the production workshop of domination
strategies. For example, in response to the social mobilization of the 1960s,
an analysis published in 1975 titled “The Crisis of Democracy: Report on
the Governability of Democracies” (Crozier et al, 1975), ordered by the
Trilateral Commission, an initiative of David Rockefeller that brought
together the big business leaders of the U.S., Europe and Japan, asserted
that “the social expectations of citizens and their demands on the state
have risen considerably, while the capacity and resources of the latter to
satisfy them have fallen, generating frustration and rejection. Therefore, to
propose greater participation by citizens in public life and demand greater
responsibility and involvement by the state, far from making our democra-
cies more governable, aggravates their defijiciencies… Thus the solution
consists in reducing civic participation, modernizing the management of
society and entrusting it to social players (companies, associations, inter-
est groups) and a few institutions which, by coordinating their interac-
tions, will be able more easily to reconcile their antagonisms and resolve
their conflicts” (Vidal-Beneyto, 2002).
Inequality and anti-democracy in neoliberal globalization cannot be
understood as a problem of “defijiciencies of governance,” as there is no
intention to correct this supposed defijiciency by strengthening democracy
and incorporating “social considerations” or the interests of “the workers
and the poor” as the ILO suggests. The question that preoccupies neolib-
eral capital is not how to incorporate the interests of the workers, but how
to pursue its effforts to satisfy its interminable hunger for surplus-value
without placing its domination at risk. Although this is a question that
admits varying responses (it is, after all, a work in progress), in the follow-
ing section I will examine how neoliberal domination has been structur-
ing its response so far.
184 chapter eight
Production of Criminals
11 Examining the rate of construction of new prisons in Great Britain, Bauman observes
that “it is higher than any other sector of the British economy,” and nevertheless “as impres-
sive as the prison construction boom may be in Great Britain, it is nothing compared to
that of the United States” (Bauman, 1999: 22).
the state administration of criminal activity 185
12 “Half of the workers of the world – close to 1.4 billion impoverished workers –
currently live on less than 2 U.S. dollars per day per person. They work in the vast informal
sector – from agricultural operations to fijishing, from farms to city streets – without bene-
fijits, social security or social assistance… Unemployment, in terms of people currently
without jobs, is at its highest levels and continues to rise. In the last ten years, offfijicial
unemployment grew by more than 25 per cent and now afffects close to 192 million people
in the world, or 6% of the total work force” (Rudnik and Goransky, 2007).
13 In its own way, even the World Bank recognizes the profound economic inequality
that currently prevails as a source of violence: “in its World Development Report for 2005,
the World Bank suggests that the growing economic inequality between the diffferent
regions of the world and within countries themselves is a decisive factor in violence and
the risk of [civil] war, and doubts that it would be possible even to come close to, much less
to reach, the goal for the millennium set by the 1995 World Summit in Copenhagen to cut
world poverty in half” (Krätke, 2007).
186 chapter eight
Illegal Migration
The more developed free trade and free capital mobility become,
particularly between developed and underdeveloped countries, the more
unemployment, casualization and marginality grow, especially in the
underdeveloped world14, and, as a necessary correlate, the greater the
numbers are of people migrating to the developed world in search of
employment and a means of existence.15 Faced with this wave of poverty
and migration, capital has positioned itself on both sides of the process to
close the pincer on the workers.
On the side of the underdeveloped countries, transnational capital and
its administrators (the United States, the IMF, the World Bank, etc.),
together with their local delegates (the local political class), promote
openness and competitiveness in the country in question to make it
attractive to transnational capital investment – the only possible way,
they claim, of generating the employment that the country so desper-
ately needs. In the discourse and in neoliberal practice, to oppose this
process, which subordinates everything to the supreme purpose of
being attractive to foreign capital, would be madness and, probably, a
criminal act.
On the side of the developed countries, the same capital represented by
the same global administrators accuses migrants of being the main cause
of the deterioration of the living conditions of local workers, and its politi-
cal class, particularly the segment on the right of the political spectrum,
coordinates the defense of their privileges while promoting hatred of
Individual Crime
As the basic challenge for a growing sector of the population in contempo-
rary capitalism is the challenge to survive, migration and integration into
the so-called “informal economy,” as well as organized or individual crime,
the state administration of criminal activity 189
constitute possible survival options21, although these last two are rein-
forced because neoliberalism produces not only unemployment but dete-
rioration of the whole social fabric. In a downward spiral aggravated by
migration, families and communities disintegrate, the fabric of mediation
and social and political cohesion is devastated22 and the social construc-
tion of ethical reference points is likewise destroyed. The need to survive
and the destruction of ethical reference points, promoted by the mass
media of big transnational capital, transform criminal activity into some-
thing that could be called a normal employment option for many unem-
ployed workers.
For the purposes of this analysis, further exploration of individual crime
is unnecessary, beyond the recognition that it is clearly a survival strategy
for homeless delinquents. What is of interest to this study is how this indi-
vidual crime establishes a social basis, a source of labor it might be said,
for organized crime.
Organized Crime
Between individual and organized crime there is a qualitative diffference.
The fijirst is a means of individual and family survival; the second is a capi-
tal accumulation strategy; organized crime constitutes a capitalist enter-
prise, necessarily tied in with the framework of the capitalist economy.23
Organized crime constitutes a successful cluster, the most profijitable and
dynamic production and commercial chain in the world economy today,
the jewel in the crown of neoliberal capitalism, covering a wide range of
21 “Hand in hand with unemployment and an unpromising future, crime, gangs and
drug addiction have grown among youth” (Hernández Navarro, 2006).
22 “Conflicts between the various communities tend to be resolved by violence, due to
the decreased possibility of mediation by offfijicial institutions, such as political parties, the
diffferent churches, the unions… Conflicts within families are also intensifijied due to the
obligation upon women, children and the elderly to look outside the family unit for
the supplementary income they need to survive… Violence against women and children
has become endemic, the bonds between neighbors and in small communities are broken,
crime grows, and so does fear, which in turn provokes violent reactions” (Almeyra, n.d.).
23 For example, between the women who sell drugs in the street as a means of income
to maintain their family because they do not have access to paid employment, or rural
workers who grow coca because they are unable to fijind any other reasonably profijitable
crop, and the gangster, there is a diffference similar to that which exists between the
employer (the entrepreneur) and his employees: the latter appropriates the profijit while the
former receive a relatively high wage (possible thanks to the high profijitability of the enter-
prise) for work subject to high professional risks. Of course, prisons are fijilled with the for-
mer, while the latter are much harder to catch, and even if imprisoned they maintain a
privileged status.
190 chapter eight
24 In the south of Mexico, as in many parts of the world, organized crime has discovered
how profijitable the poorest of the poor can be. Migrant women (“more than 20,000 Central
American women are currently working as prostitutes in brothels, hideaways and bars in
Mexico’s south-southeast”), especially the young and attractive ones, are kidnapped and
subjected to diffferent production processes involving a wide range of commodities charac-
teristic of the neoliberal free market: they are fijilmed while being raped to produce porno
fijilms which have high market demand; sold by kidnappers to bars and clandestine brothels
often owned by “local politicians, bankers and people with economic power, operating in
the shadows and earning a signifijicant income,” where “they are held against their will in a
situation of slavery, forced to take drugs, to cover their food and accommodation expenses”
and to work as prostitutes, thereby becoming part of the tourist package offfered to the
customer. In some cases, their captors will negotiate with their family members for their
release or to pay the cost of a pollero (smuggler) who will ultimately take them to the
United States. Others less fortunate are sold as slave labor to clandestine factories, thereby
closing their productive cycle (Hernández, 2009). According to the UN Offfijice on Drugs and
Crime (UNODC) human trafffijicking has become “a highly lucrative activity of transnational
organized crime, associated and/or competing with drug and arms trafffijicking” (UNODC,
2009b).
25 “[Tax havens] are micro-territories or States with loose or non-existent tax legisla-
tion, which engage in the anonymous receipt of capital through a kind of marketing of
their sovereignty. Numerous banks located in these places – Switzerland, Monaco, the
Cayman Islands, the Bahamas or Luxembourg, to name a few of the 60 to 90 that exist in
the world – receive money from anywhere on the planet, from any person or company,
without having to justify the origin of the funds. They are located on the peripheries of the
major economic centers of the world – the United States, Europe and Asia… They are efffec-
tively factories for laundering the money of mafijias, corrupt political leaders and corpora-
tions” (Sader, 2004.)
the state administration of criminal activity 191
26 The pernicious and degrading efffects of tax evasion on society as a whole are numer-
ous: “tax havens and harmful preferential tax regimes afffect the location of tax activities
and other services, erode the tax bases of other countries, distort trade and investment
patterns and undermine justice, neutrality and broad social acceptance of tax systems in
general…. they reduce global welfare and weaken the confijidence of tax payers in the integ-
rity of taxation systems… thereby contributing to the ‘normalization’ of a profoundly
unjust and regressive tax regime, which causes so much damage to the wellbeing and com-
munity of all the world’s citizens” (Jiménez, 2004).
27 “The OECD and the FATF, a body associated with the OECD, not only fail to launch
any concerted action against tax havens, but in fact tolerate and accept them… European
and international conventions continue to omit express reference to tax havens as spaces
outside the law where all kinds of undeclared income are hidden. All of this facilitates the
preservation of these territories outside the international legal framework with absolute
impunity… There is a global tendency toward formal and real tolerance, if not toward the
integration of tax havens into the international community” (Jiménez, 2004).
28 “The profijits derived from criminal activities such as drug or arms trafffijicking, terror-
ism, kidnapping, crimes against the fijinancial system, diversion of pubic funds or the result
of the activities of any illegal organization, before being used by the holders, must pass
through an operation that disassociates the funds from their illicit origin. This process is
commonly referred to as money laundering and involves 2% to 5% of the annual gross
domestic product of the world, which represents 600 billion to 1.5 trillion U.S. dollars per
year, according to data from the IMF” (ATTAC, 2004).
29 The literature that can be reviewed to document the interconnection between the
criminal and legal branches of the neoliberal economy is now quite extensive. For an oper-
ative, empirical and concrete view of the question, see Saviano, 2007.
192 chapter eight
Catherine Austin Fitts asserts that “the U.S. launders about $500 billion to
$1 trillion annually… this explains the importance that this money has on
the New York stock exchange, its interest in keeping it circulating in the
market and the threat to its interests represented by any attempt to
decriminalize narcotics trafffijicking” (Austin Fitts, 2001).
From this perspective, it is evident that the “war on drugs” launched by
the United States around the world has purposes distinct from those
ascribed to it in the offfijicial discourse. For example, Plan Colombia has,
among other objectives, the purpose of ensuring that narco-dollars con-
tinue circulating within the U.S. economy: “Plan Colombia is proceeding
apace to try to move narco-deposits out of FARC’s control and back to the
control of our traditional allies and, even if that does not work, to move
Citibank’s market share and that of the other large U.S. banks and fijinan-
cial institutions steadily up in Latin America” (Austin Fitts, 2001). The
criminal branch of the neoliberal economy, like any other industry, par-
ticularly those that are globalized, produces and/or acquires its basic
supplies, transforms them into fijinished products, transports them and
markets them, forming a chain running backwards to its suppliers (con-
struction, chemical and pharmaceutical, automotive industries, etc.) and
forwards to its transport, marketing and consumption networks; it gener-
ates employment and invests in the banking system and the stock market,
and engages with government authorities at national and international
levels. The interests associated with organized crime are many, and very
powerful, and it seems unlikely that within the top levels of neoliberal
political and economic power there exists any serious intention of putting
an end to it – in the United States much less than anywhere else – at least,
as made evident above, not in terms of control of money laundering. What
follows below is a brief overview of the arms trafffijicking sector of this
industry, at least in the case of the United States.
In the U.S., the opposition of the powerful National Rifle Association
(which unites the main arms producers in the country) against any
attempt to regulate arms sales is well known. Cason and Brooks explain
that at “arms fairs” the purchase of arms requires no customer record
check and that “critics of the weak gun control laws warn that the alleged
terrorists are also buying them in the United States to use them against
citizens of this country… For the terrorists of the world, the United
States is the great arms bazaar.”30 Nevertheless, Cason and Brooks add,
30 “When U.S. troops searched the Al Qaeda camps in Afghanistan, they found a train-
ing manual that informed its operatives that it is ‘perfectly legal’ to buy high-powered
the state administration of criminal activity 193
“Attorney General John Ashcroft has been a fijierce opponent against the
application of greater controls on sales and possession of fijirearms in this
country,” which is understandable, given that the election campaign of his
boss, President George W. Bush, had been fijinanced – at least in part – by
funds provided by none other than the National Rifle Association.31
Arms manufacturers, like bankers who launder money and any other
legal industry linked to the criminal branch, are interested in selling their
products and making profijits; their customers are anyone with money.
They don’t ask them who they are, or what they want them for; whether
they are thugs or terrorists is no business of theirs. The impact of the crim-
inal branch of the neoliberal economy is not only economic. Its politico-
electoral influence is also clear; its capacity to make “donations” and
fijinance political campaigns, particularly now that electoral processes are
increasingly a matter of political marketing and costly media publicity,
enables it to influence the critical moment of neoliberal democracy – the
electoral moment. As a result, it may influence the composition of the
stafff who administrate the government apparatus.
According to Catherine Austin Fitts, the four U.S. states with the largest
market share in drug trafffijicking and money laundering of narco-profijits
and other profijits of organized crime, well known as banking power strong-
holds, are New York, California, Texas and Florida. Austin Fitts then raises
the question: “Who were the governors of these four states in 1996? Well,
let’s see. Jeb Bush was the governor of Florida. Governor Jeb was the son of
George H.W. Bush, the former head of an oil company in Texas and Mexico,
the former head of the CIA and the former head of the various drug
enforcement effforts as vice president and president. Then George W. Bush,
also the son of George H. W. Bush, was the governor of Texas. So the gover-
nors of the two largest narco dollar market share states just happen to be
the sons of the former chief of the secret police” (Austin Fitts, 2001).
With so many economic and political interests articulated around the
criminal branch of the neoliberal economy, it is not surprising that this
fijirearms in the United States, and advised Osama bin Laden’s followers to ‘take advantage
of the weak U.S. fijirearms laws to acquire training as snipers and participate in military
exercises’” (Cason and Brooks, 2001). For the case of Mexico, the Washington Post published
a series of articles documenting the trafffijic of arms from the U.S. to the Mexican cartels (see
for example, Grimaldi and Horwitz, 2010).
31 During the 2004 election campaign, “Kerry accused Bush of giving into the National
Rifle Association, which supports the president’s election campaign,” while Bush “pro-
posed the granting of immunity in civil trials to arms manufacturers and… supported
moves by Congress to allow the expiration of the prohibition on assault weapons imposed
by Bill Clinton 10 years ago” (Clarín, 2004).
194 chapter eight
Examining the process in this way from the perspective of social relations
and relations, it is evident that criminal activity, which in a diverse and
complex array of modalities has been spreading throughout the social
framework of neoliberal capitalism, is a product wholly produced by
fijinancial capital, the dominant faction of contemporary capitalism. When
I examined neoliberal democracy (Chapter 7) from the perspective of
the state administration of criminal activity 195
nor has its consequences been as oppressive upon world society as a whole
as they are now. It is with good reason that the authors of the Rome Statute
of the International Criminal Court remark that “during this century”
(referring to the 20th century, not yet having witnessed the promising start
of the 21st, which looks certain to outdo its predecessor in the production
of barbarism), “millions of children, women and men have been victims of
atrocities that deeply shock the conscience of humanity” (ICRC, 1998).
Even within the legal branch of the neoliberal economy, it is not unusual
to fijind illegal activities. Although they may be disguised with an appear-
ance of legality, many of the activities in this branch in fact represent seri-
ous crimes; one need only compare many of the habitual practices of the
big multinational corporations and their states against the defijinitions of
genocide, crimes against humanity and war crimes provided by the Rome
Statute to appreciate the extraordinary dimensions of the problem. The
criminal activity of neoliberal capital and the impunity with which it
operates are reaching truly outrageous levels.32 Although tracing its devel-
opment is a task far beyond the intentions and possibilities of this work,
two cases are worth noting here.
During 2008, successive waves of speculation on food products, energy
and mortgage loans led to a profound global economic crisis and a process
of conversion of public resources into private hands at a rate without prec-
edent in history. In spite of the recurrence of these speculative surges –
which gravely afffect the living conditions of our society – no serious efffort
has been made to contain them. Even former senior offfijicials including
Jacques Delors acknowledge that “fijinancial markets have become increas-
ingly opaque… The size of the lightly or not-at-all regulated ‘shadow bank-
ing sector’ has constantly increased in the past twenty years… Inadequate
incentive schemes, short-termism and blatant conflicts of interest have
enhanced speculative trading… epitomizing the loss of business ethics!”
(Delors et al, 2008, emphasis added). Meanwhile, as a result of these spec-
ulative dealings in the context of a systematic efffort to destroy rural pro-
duction in favor of the agri-food multinationals, famine (a product of food
shortages and increased food prices) is devastating the most impoverished
regions of the world.33
32 According to the preamble of the Statute, it is necessary “to put an end to impunity
for the perpetrators of these crimes and thus to contribute to the prevention of such
crimes”; without doubt it is necessary, but the current correlation of forces between social
classes, far from reducing crime and impunity, actually increases them.
33 For a particularly enlightening view on this topic, see Bello, 2008.
the state administration of criminal activity 197
More or less simultaneously, the world has begun sufffering from a new
emerging threat, the so-called swine flu, a new product of the criminal
activity of neoliberal capital with the complicity of the state: “Authorities
knew of the pandemic threat, but gave no importance to the warnings of
scientifijic institutions and social organizations as they did not wish to inter-
fere with the economic interests of the huge farm and livestock industry and
the pharmaceutical and biotechnology multinationals that profijit from
diseases. To this end, fragmentary focuses that do not question the causes
of the problem are useful, such as taking emergency measures when the
dead and sick can no longer be overlooked, while asserting that the crisis
can be resolved with more technology controlled by the multinationals.
For any new viruses, new vaccines will be found – patented and sold by
corporations. Even if a vaccine is found against the latest virus, the indus-
trial breeding of animals continues to be a time bomb for the creation of
more new viruses… Instead of attacking the causes of the epidemic, those
who produced it are rewarded” (Ribeiro, 2009b, emphasis added). A threat
to the lives of an undetermined number of human beings is rendered sec-
ondary to the interests of big capital; there can be no clearer defijinition –
and this is but one among a thousand examples – of what matters to
neoliberal capital.
35 For example, keeping criminal activity restricted to the margins of what is functional
for capital accumulation and domination is problematic: organized crime, the product of
private initiative, like any normal business, seeks to expand the scale of its operations and
its markets and diversify its products, and it will not hesitate to levy charges, to kidnap for
ransom and even to kill other business leaders, especially those of small and medium busi-
nesses, terrorizing and virtually paralyzing whole cities and segments of economic activity.
But these are collateral damages – like the uncontrolled surge in the speculative activities
of big fijinancial capital which drain billions of dollars of public funds – which do not
threaten the basic principle of neoliberalism: freedom for private enterprise.
the state administration of criminal activity 199
36 This capacity of the criminal branch of the neoliberal economy to produce employment
and high wages is modifijied as the branch itself is transformed according to the general
logic of capitalist production; for example, the employment and remuneration opportuni-
ties for rural workers who participate in it shrink as drug production becomes more indus-
trialized and natural drugs are replaced with synthetic varieties.
200 chapter eight
37 It is common to hear among young males in excluded communities, or at least those
who still seek opportunities within the law, complain of “girls who prefer drug dealers.”
38 Consider, for example, the following news article on a conflict between youth gangs:
“The emos, whether we like it or not, are a new generation, but I don’t think that it will be
the anarcho-punks or the goths who attack them… the conscious objective is to divide
them [youth], because they can’t be offfered expectations for the future… The violence
between diffferent youth gangs is nothing new; it has always existed, but now it has
increased considerably. This campaign is dangerous and could grow… The government
prefers to have youth divided rather than critical and demanding… the levels of frustration
and rage keep growing in the country and suddenly they look around not to fijind ‘who did
this to me’, but ‘who will pay for it’. In Latin America there are nearly 30 million youth who
don’t have the chance to study or work, and their logic, viewing it more as survival than
crime, is inclined toward drug dealing, piracy or contraband. Unless the State addresses the
employment and education problem, there will be more conflict” (Vargas and Olivares,
2008). According to this logic, the Mara Salvatrucha (MS13) and skinheads are extreme
cases.
the state administration of criminal activity 201
39 That this strategy of constructing legitimacy can prove highly efffective is clearly
proven by the political strategy adopted by U.S. President George Bush following September
11, 2001. In Mexico, President Felipe Calderón’s strategy to legitimize his government has
been none other than the war on organized crime. However, it is also a strategy with a lim-
ited life, as indicated by the growing difffijiculties experienced by the U.S. government to
convince its citizens of the need to continue the war on terrorism.
202 chapter eight
International Terrorism
40 “Beyond the comparative theories, all the elements of the shock doctrine are present
in Mexico. This includes economic shock therapy, the words used last week in the United
States by Mexico’s treasurer, Agustín Carstens; the minister said that shock therapy worked
during the Mexican flu emergency, and that the government is preparing additional struc-
tural reforms for the second part of the year. After the elections in July – another fear
campaign – the worst will be unleashed, including, perhaps, another timely outbreak of
the H1N1 virus, our new Al Qaeda” (Fazio, 2009).
41 In reality, this article by Frédéric London makes fun of the idea, but the lack of con-
ceptual rigor in its discussion of “neoliberalism”, “socialism”, etc. does little to help clarify
the state administration of criminal activity 203
the issue. In the same edition and with the same flippancy, Ibrahim Warde speaks of
“a change of epoch.”
42 How useful the war on international terrorism has been in helping big U.S. capital to
appropriate strategic natural resources, such as Iraqi oil, should not be underestimated.
But more generally, while free trade has furnished the conditions for the spread of the new
technological revolution, the war on terrorism has furnished the conditions for the spread
of the U.S. military revolution, the most convincing of its arguments for establishing its
hegemony in “the new American century.”
43 It is clear that the consequences of the anti-terrorism strategies expressed, for exam-
ple, in the Patriot Act, Plan Mexico or the SPPNA (Security and Prosperity Partnership of
North America) represent a very real military and repressive framework.
44 Recommended reading on this topic includes Zibechi, 2008 and Davis, 2007.
45 This is the meaning behind the open debate at the core of military intelligence, par-
ticularly in the United States, regarding “the three dominant theories on the war of the
future that are currently being discussed in military magazines – the Fourth Generation
War, the Third Wave War and the Fourth Epoch War” (Bunker, 2006).
204 chapter eight
46 “Many big businesses promote crime and live offf crime. There has never before been
so much economic concentration and scientifijic and technological knowledge dedicated to
the production of death. The countries that sell the most arms are the same countries
responsible for world peace. Fortunately for them, the threat of peace is weakening, and its
dark clouds are rolling away, while the war market recovers and offfers promising prospects
of profijitable slaughter. The armaments factories are working as hard as the factories that
manufacture enemies tailored to their needs.” (Galeano, 2006, emphasis added).
the state administration of criminal activity 205
47 “Possible threats to the West are broadened to include phenomena such as terrorism,
drug trafffijicking, immigration and cultural conflicts… The potential sources of threats to
the global security system of the emerging New World Order were located in third world
countries as a consequence of the multiple causes of conflict existing in such countries
(economic disparity, nationalist interests, religious intolerance, racial hatred, demographic
pressure and extreme weather conditions), which might, if their problems spill beyond
their borders, threaten the security of the global community” (Contreras Natera, 2007).
206 chapter eight
can let other people, sort of lesser contractors, do the dirty work of actu-
ally making stufff. And that was the sort of revolution in outsourcing, and
that was the paradigm of the hollow corporation.” And, she adds, “Rumsfeld
very much comes out of that tradition. And when he came on board as
Defense Secretary, he rode in like a new economy CEO that was going to
do one of these radical restructures. But what he was doing is he was tak-
ing this philosophy of this revolution in the corporate world and applying
it to the military. And what he oversaw was the hollowing out of the
American military, where essentially the role of the army is branding, is
marketing, is projecting the image of strength and dominance on the
globe… but outsourcing every function” (Klein, 2007b).
Corresponding to the global fijinancial oligarchy, its governing group
(particularly the top-level political bureaucracy of the United States)
views itself as the administration of a global government, which it designs
in the image and semblance of the global company, as a network with stra-
tegic alliances, senior partners and junior partners, designs for relocation
and outsourcing, etc., in competition for world supremacy. These are the
global players of the world government.
Signifijicant among the points made in the quote above is the notion that
“the war of the future” is basically a war not between states, but between
states and what Lind calls a “wide variety of non-state actors.” If we con-
sider that wars between states have been the expression of conflicts
between national bourgeoisies, Lind’s suggestion means that the global
bourgeoisie sees itself as lacking signifijicant national rivals, and what it is
really concerned about is the opposition of the working class under its
domination, although this concern is obscured behind all manner of crim-
inals and terrorists. Thus, for big capital “there is nobody to talk to and
nothing to talk about”; in other words, it does not recognize the legitimacy
of any social interest in opposition to it. By this logic, the state administra-
tion of criminal activity will inevitably develop into the administration of
chaos and brutality.
Joxe, examining “the political consequences of the absolute militarism
of the United States” with reference to the cases of Iraq and Afghanistan,
raises the question: “Might it not in fact be a total chaos strategy? … The
quick victory will no doubt turn into a lasting source of hostility against
the ‘liberators’, condemned to the status of occupiers… The huge imperial
power appears to be committed to separating the military objective from
the political objective… This beginning of the ‘war without end’ declared
by the Bush administration is a war without victory and without peace,
and probably without reconstruction” (Joxe, 2003b). Although the “total
chaos strategy” is particularly visible in cases like Iraq and Afghanistan, in
reality it is the logical result of the development of the state administra-
tion of criminal activity, just as this itself is the result of the destruction of
the institutional spaces that defijined the contained form of capitalist dom-
ination (as explained at the beginning of this chapter). With the neoliberal
pattern of domination, which constitutes a return to the natural form of
capitalist domination, an increasing number of spaces for social organiza-
tion around the world are being fijilled by the logic of the state administra-
tion of criminal activity and the “total chaos strategy.”
The reason behind this “total chaos strategy,” in terms of immediate
interests, is identifijied by Joxe himself: “Whatever is necessary will be done
to ensure that both destruction and reconstruction are sources of corpo-
rate profijits, thereby saving corporate morale at the expense of political
morale and intelligence” (Joxe, 2003b). But Lind goes beyond immediate
interests and, as we saw above, makes it clear that at the core of what he
calls the Fourth Generation War “lies a crisis of legitimacy of the state.”
However, he expresses no interest in exploring the factors behind this
“universal crisis,” or what the solutions might be to remedy it. Instead, he
208 chapter eight
Earlier, I noted that, for Gramsci, the state is “political society plus civil
society,” connecting the conditions of political and economic domination
with those of ideological domination, and those of consensual domina-
tion with coercive domination. The state relates the conditions of domina-
tion to the conditions of exploitation and establishes an organic link
between structure and superstructure. Moreover, I remarked that the
dominant class produces its own ideology according to Gramsci’s analysis.
Its general conception of the world is a necessary condition for its homo-
geneity and consciousness of its own function in the economic and politi-
cal spheres and, therefore, for its cohesion as a class. This ideology is not
external either to the economics or the politics of the capitalist class, as
class practices (economic and political) are interconnected, and mutually
determined, with an awareness of class.
Ideology is constructed and performed, made visible and present,
within the economic and political practices of the dominant class and,
although it preserves its basic principles and its class-based nature
throughout the history of capitalism, it evolves and is transformed along
with the development of capitalism, with the emergence of new domi-
nant factions and new challenges that arise. But this ideological produc-
tion not only gives cohesion to the dominant class; it also constitutes
a level (along with the economic and political levels) of class-based
210 chapter nine
1 “Domination is a political relation which, on the one hand, is organized and repro-
duced as the State; but it is also something that is established through the organization of
the culture of a society or nation. Political power is produced in the process of organization
of the culture… ‘Common sense’ is a political production and part of the struggle for hege-
mony… Politics is a collection of practices instituting the shape of the social; that is, as a
process that occurs as organization of the culture, involving the organization and develop-
ment of the state as well as of a historical block” (Tapia, 2008).
2 The third section of this chapter explores the issue of the fethishization of social rela-
tions in capitalism and its connection to ideological domination.
ideological domination 211
3 This necessarily entails, under the conditions of capitalism, the representation of the
“real” social order as conflictive, “that is, combative by nature” (Tagarelli, 2009).
212 chapter nine
able to present its strategic initiatives as the solution to the evils of the
previous period, thereby winning public support for its new projects.
The transition of the Soviet bloc from state capitalism (self-acclaimed
“real socialism”) to neoliberal capitalism was presented as a response to a
“popular demand for democracy and universal prosperity.” In the devel-
oped capitalist states of the West, this process was argued to be a “victory
for democracy and the free world,” and “the end of history.”5 In Latin
America, the economic crisis aggravated the loss of prestige of the devel-
opmentalist state, thereby facilitating the presentation of the transition
from developmentalism to neoliberalism as the solution to its defijiciencies
and as a “transition to democracy and modernity.”
On the level of ideological domination, the key to the Latin American
transition lies in the vilifijication of the developmentalist state; on this
basis, neoliberalism launched an offfensive to “replace the predominantly
nationalist beliefs, through which the majority of the population orga-
nized its understanding of the country, the region and the political and
economic world,” with the goal of “making the privatizing content of the
new economic policies compatible with the cultural and political compo-
sition of the civil societies that would have to support the new confijigura-
tions of capitalism in Latin America,” and promoting a new common
sense, “which revolved around the idea of a global market, efffijiciency,
competitiveness and denationalization” (Tapia, 2008).6
5 “At the level of the conception of the world and of knowledge, neoliberalism articu-
lated a discourse as a strategy to explain the contemporary context… a normative eco-
nomic discourse – which, under the pretext of rationality, eliminates the possibility of
considering alternatives from among which the best way of satisfying social needs might
be chosen – and a political discourse that also argued for the superiority of the political
culture and competitive party system of liberalism as the synthesis of all political history”
(Tapia, 2008).
6 “To legitimize the privatization processes, it was necessary to create a new common
sense; that is, people needed to view the world as a dynamic of production, circulation and
consumption of commodities in highly depoliticized processes, and, therefore, to assess
the facts and the meaning of those facts according to this mercantile culture” (Tapia, 2008).
214 chapter nine
Thus, for example in Latin America, “the fijirst years were ones of public
and discursive resistance and confrontation. But as privatization pro-
cesses advanced, and the processes of deconstruction of the nation-states
dismantled the material conditions that enabled the maintenance of
nationalist beliefs, the people gradually began replacing their beliefs with
others that were liberal and neoliberal in nature, particularly in the urban
centers where the greatest economic modernization occurred.”7
The neoliberal ideology, with the conception of the era that it proposed
(its explanations of the past and of the problems of the present, as well
as its proposed solutions and promises for the future), played its role
throughout the period of transition. But once the structures of the previ-
ous forms of domination were dismantled, a new reality was imposed on
the relation between capital and labor, and new ideological content
emerged. The point of departure in the examination of the neoliberal pat-
tern of ideological domination is thus the new historical, economic and
political situation, which is confijigured in the relation between capital and
labor. In particular, it is worth recalling here the point made earlier that
while in the previous stage (the various modes of the contained form of
domination) capital organized corporately, in this stage capital disorga-
nizes, atomizes and pulverizes in order to dominate the workers, particu-
larly in underdeveloped countries. The neoliberal state abandoned the
state administration of concessions (which characterized the contained
form) as the core element of domination, thereby bringing about the col-
lapse of the old institutional framework constructed to organize and regu-
late bargaining between capital and labor – parties and unions.
This context of disorganization and reduction to individual isolation
engenders the ideological (and political) defenselessness of the working
class, allowing neoliberal capital, in spite of its unprecedented capacity
to generate inequality, injustice and savagery,8 to deregulate its relation
with labor, to impose submission to its needs and its logic, to promote
9 After reading various analyses on the topic, one might be tempted to classify it as
absolute defenselessness, but there are many initiatives in process, the germination of con-
siderable social resistance, which compel us to consider the ideological power of capital in
the contemporary world in relative terms.
10 The monopolization process underway afffects not only “traditional” media (the
press, television, etc.) but also new media: “Google is quickly turning into a megacorpora-
tion of the future, buying up the competition (Blogger, YouTube), making users dependent
on its advertising system, monopolizing the search for information, and becoming the larg-
est database in history, storing virtually everything… Users, without realizing, are being
gradually trapped in Google’s web…” (Colectivo Troyano, 2009a).
11 “Most people are guided by the information provided by the big mass media outlets,
but these outlets depend too much on the big economic powers, which in turn depend on
216 chapter nine
the politicians. Information passes through fijilters, corporate parameters and self-
censorship (direct threats or fear of losing their jobs), or comes so directly from govern-
ment sources that the fijinal product could be called ‘disinformation’… it is the mass media
communications system itself, so tied up with the interests of big corporations, that pre-
vents the transmission of genuine information, establishing a system of propaganda rather
than information – inculcating the world view of those who hold economic and political
power… the propaganda model dominates the media” (Colectivo Yachay Red Científijica
Peruana, 2002).
12 “The violence of information has made the real world disappear… the sense of reality
is disintegrated, creating a diffferent reality… the massive trade in images demonstrates a
huge indiffference toward the real world… it smothers Homo-Televisus, whose inhuman
passiveness supports the cruel aesthetic of the spectacle of the destruction of the most
sacred moral values… the formidable machine of propaganda, simulation, concealment
and rhetoric makes it impossible for people to feel anything” (Jean Baudrillard, as quoted
in Marelli, 2007).
13 The Keynesian period produced a wealth of experience in the fijield of ideological
domination; in Section 4.3.4, I pointed out that during this period the “production work-
shop of domination strategies,” in conjunction with the education system and the mass
media, organized the ideological and cultural messages that circulated in society, monopo-
lizing the spaces for public communication and adapting scientifijic applications to discern
and influence culture, ideology and the behavior of society: surveys, interviews, advertising,
propaganda, marketing, etc. From that time, capital and its ideological universe began
working out how to invade the daily world of the working class, although not to the degree
that it has today.
14 The literature on the topic is extraordinarily extensive, but, of the texts I’m familiar
with, I would recommend Chiesa, 2008; Valqui Cachi and Pastor Bastán, 2009; and Revuelta,
2008.
ideological domination 217
Competitiveness
In Chapter 7, I explained the increased importance given to the promo-
tion of competitiveness, i.e. skills, knowledge and feelings directed fully
and energetically at serving capital, in a world where capital reigns virtu-
ally unchallenged and where so many human beings are superfluous, all
are forced to compete, and all are subordinated to the supreme goal of
being useful and attractive to capital. In the same chapter, I explained how
the Competitiveness Promotion Brigades constitute a social framework
that forms part of the civil society of neoliberalism, part of the downward
network that disseminates the neoliberal conception of the world and
connects society to the intellectual and moral leadership of neoliberal
capital. With the transition from the Keynesian pattern of domination to
the neoliberal pattern, the core of the capital-labor relation has shifted
from collective bargaining to individual competitiveness.
Even as unemployment rises, as long as the state maintains minimal
regulations (in terms of wages, the work day and working conditions) and
the unions preserve some capacity for negotiation, some restrictions on
the voracity of capital remain. But if, as is the case under the conditions
that neoliberalism tends to establish, the state allows the regulations
restricting the behavior of capital to become increasingly lax and the bar-
gaining capacity of the unions continues to shrink, the workers will be
thrust, as isolated individuals, into the world of free competition, forced to
compete on two levels: fijirst, in an individual efffort to be useful to capital,
although the reward offfered – employment and a wage – is scarce and
generally poor in quality; second, to compete against all other workers,
both the employed and the unemployed (competing to keep their jobs if
they have them and to get one if they don’t), the integrated and the
excluded. The lack of socially constructed alternatives drives workers
toward a suicidal persistence to strive to serve capital, clinging to the
increasingly implausible illusion (for a growing number of superfluous
workers) promising that, ultimately, wellbeing and employment will be
17 “It was the media corporations, the big entertainment and communications compa-
nies, that assumed the huge task of generating a new ‘public opinion’ that could be identi-
fijied with the values arising from the neoliberal form assumed by contemporary capitalism”
(Forster, 2009).
ideological domination 219
Alienation
Criminal Activity
23 “The fact that many Latin American countries have now lived through two decades
of neoliberalism means that the new generations have been educated in an atmosphere of
liberal beliefs and liberal common sense; they have learned these beliefs in every sphere –
in their schools, their parents’ workplace, the media and the news” (Tapia, 2008). For a part
of today’s society – perhaps more among the young – life appears reduced to the individual
and the individual to the sexual, to “those few surviving enclaves… where a pleasure and
playfulness not wholly under the heel of power might still be relished,” so that “one would
accordingly anticipate an enormous inflation of interest in these matters,” although “some
thinkers would caution how discourse and sexuality were themselves policed, regulated,
heavy with power…” (Eagleton, 1996: 4).
24 In Chapter 6, I examined how the liberalization of the international movement of
fijinancial capital and the processes that it provokes have given rise to the construction of a
form of political discourse that promotes resignation among the dominated; no human
power could possibly oppose the omnipotence of market forces. I will return to this point
later.
25 “Domination is based on ignorance and on the socialization of intellectual patterns
that incorporate subordination, hierarchy and subalternity into the constitution of the
subjects… Domination involves disorganizing the conditions for recognition among social
subjects, especially in the world of workers. Disorganization produces unawareness – of
ideological domination 223
neoliberal pattern means that workers are forced into increasingly deregu-
lated submission to the ever greater demands of capital, and that the
search for options of employment and subsistence become increasingly
disordered and chaotic, as do the searches undertaken by capital for prof-
itable activities and the employment options that it offfers, including
unlawful and criminal activities.
Before, I pointed out that the extraordinary profijits yielded by organized
crime employers enables them, given the conditions of labor casualiza-
tion and rising unemployment, to provide privileged labor and wage
conditions to their employees, offfering them relatively high wages and
creating expectations of status for a segment of the excluded population
so that, as the commercial and production chain associated with criminal
activities expands, a genuine social framework is constructed in urban dis-
tricts and neighborhoods and in rural centers, constituting what I referred
to as Crime Promotion Brigades. In the world of neoliberal capital, crime
is a normal work option that attracts a growing number of applicants
and creates jobs26 with much more dynamism than any other branch of
the contemporary economy. Obviously, the problem is also one of ethics
and social cohesion; if large masses of the unemployed are turning to
crime, society is sufffering from a serious breakdown in the mechanisms of
social cohesion and the construction of ethical referents. Neoliberalism
does not construct any consistent form of social cohesion, but rather fos-
ters the destruction of all ethical referents as it promotes individualism,
competition and unscrupulousness, as much among workers as among
capitalists.27
themselves as individual and collective subjects, of other subjects, of the nation and of the
world” (Tapia, 2008).
26 For example, the National Drug Threat Assessment 2009, a report issued by the U.S.
Department of Justice’s National Drug Intelligence Center, asserts that drug trafffijicking
organizations (but one sector of the crime economy) generate 450,000 jobs in Mexico alone.
This information in fact aroused terrible indignation among Mexican political party lead-
ers, to such an extent that the national leader of the Democratic Revolutionary Party
(PRD), Jesús Ortega, accused the U.S. government of meddling (!), asserting that the U.S.
intelligence report was “a frankly rude declaration that meddles in the country’s afffairs”
and, in a forceful rejoinder (!), claimed that there are 50 times as many U.S. citizens living offf
drug trafffijicking (Bravo and Padilla, 2009).
27 “In the current neoliberal era, there is a clear breakdown in compliance with existing
legal frameworks, at both national and international levels… The violation of the rule of
law has a domino efffect… As federal, state and municipal authorities, the political and the
business class in general are the fijirst to violate the rule of law, citizens, professional groups
and unions also often assume unlawful practices, taking control of public spaces for
their own purposes, infringing basic administrative regulations for urban and rural coexis-
tence, stealing union fees, corrupting and being corrupted. Cynicism, arrogance and the
224 chapter nine
Fear
Neoliberal capital is also an enormous factory of fears. In addition to those
produced by health, ecological and environmental crises, its economics
generates fear because, as a threat or as a reality, it deprives many of access
to their means of subsistence, and its politics provokes fear by generating
defenselessness and a lack of forums in which solutions could be sought.29
supremacy of private over collective interests take the place of civil responsibility and col-
lective empowerment; a popular culture of corruption is constructed, in which honesty is
synonymous with stupidity” (López y Rivas, 2005).
28 “Crime spreads like a cancer… Impunity has created a vicious circle revolving around
the perception that in our society turning to crime is a low-risk business which, as such, is
increasingly attractive in a social stew seasoned with unemployment and poverty” (Iruegas,
2005.)
29 “The fears may be or appear irrational, but they are not unwarranted. There are fears
arising from the uncertainties generated by global processes, such as employment casual-
ization and unemployment, the depreciation of skills and specializations, the loss of limits
and referents in the territories inhabited, the absence or weakness of institutions or orga-
nizations of social integration, and the general crisis afffecting many services of the welfare
state” (Borja, 2007).
ideological domination 225
In the drive to be competitive there is a strong dose of fear, and the crimi-
nal activity fostered under neoliberalism produces fear among those out-
side the growing underworld of crime and feel threatened by it, but also
among the criminals themselves. All of these fears are produced by the
domination of neoliberal capital. But at the same time, with the state
administration of criminal activity, neoliberal capital creates fijields in
which these fears are condensed, which serve to perpetuate its domina-
tion; it creates culprits and solutions as well as new fears. Fears produced
by neoliberal economics and politics go much further than those directly
associated with criminal activity, but neoliberal domination condenses
them and disperses them, fijirstly because it constructs illusory culprits,
and secondly because it encapsulates society in an illusory solution: secu-
rity. The ideological defenselessness of the workers and the media ensure
that the true culprits and the real solutions remain outside the focus of
perception and social inquiry.
This construction of illusory culprits and solutions operates both in
developed and underdeveloped countries. Around the world, fear (of ter-
rorism, of violence, of crime, etc.) and the offfer of security has become the
discursive core of neoliberal politics. In developed countries, the focus is
on the threat of terrorism, while in underdeveloped countries it is the
threat of crime, although in both cases the pattern is flexible, allowing
variants, a multiplicity of threats, some of which emerge while others dis-
appear; what matters is that there must always be one on hand when
needed. Fortunately, to ensure the solid development of the ideological
domination of neoliberal capital, there are many threats, ranging from
criminal gangs like Mara Salvatrucha30 to the prospect of China and India
as emerging superpowers, the battle against terrorism and counterinsur-
gency, climate change and its potential geopolitical consequences, failed
or fractured states, cyberspace as a new terrain of conflict, the rise of new
powers, the growing influence of non-state actors, the spread of weapons
of mass-destruction and other destructive technologies.31 With such an
overabundance of threats we can comfort ourselves with the certainty
30 “The U.S. Attorney General, Alberto Gonzales, declared that the war against Central
American youth gangs in general, and against the Mara Salvatrucha (MS-13) in particular,
is second only in importance to the war against al-Qaeda… the evidence indicates that the
‘maras’… have become larger, meaner and better organized, raising the threat that they rep-
resent to Central America and the United States to an alarming level” (Díaz, 2007, emphasis
added).
31 The U.S. Defense Department, in its “Quadrennial Defense Review” presented in
February 2010, reports new supranational threats (see Brooks, 2010).
226 chapter nine
32 “The fears and consequent demands for public security have provoked offfijicial
responses, populist in character, which arouse the irrational dimension of fear, generically
designating social collectives as potentially dangerous, upon which fijirst falls public stigma,
and then preemptive repression. It goes without saying that these policies are aimed
at producing perverse efffects, helping to arouse the most irrational fears and provoking
growing demands for more security” (Borja, 2007).
33 Borja explains this dynamic with what he calls reactionary populism, “equivalent at
the local level to that used by the Bush government at the global level”; the fijirst step is to
make a political priority out of the fears of the people, integrated but worried about the
uncertainties and worked up by the campaigns of conservative politicians and some media
outlets; then, to construct a discourse that threatens anything that is bothersome, and
fijinally, to pass laws that impose penalties on anyone capable of offfending normal citizens
by their presence in the public space” (Borja, 2007).
34 The result of this is that “any behavior contrary to the established order” is deemed
“illegitimate and dangerous to coexistence”, thereby justifying “repressive action against
any unpleasant or disagreeable social groups, which are confused with criminal or violent
minorities” (Borja, 2007).
ideological domination 227
a segment of the public that is increasingly terrifijied and anxious for secu-
rity; “it is a long war,” they claim, “but we cannot abandon it and one day
we will win.”
In reality, the very nature of this war means it will never be won;35 but,
indeed, it cannot be abandoned. In the previous chapter, I examined the
state administration of criminal activity and its role in linking the
economics and politics of neoliberal capital, noting that on the level of
ideological domination it allows the promotion of a world view that exter-
nalizes its internal contradictions, criminalizing and dissolving the class
opposition against its domination, reducing society to powerlessness and
legitimizing36 its preventive positioning of police and military forces
against society. The ideological defenselessness of contemporary society is
such that the repression imposed on it is presented as a response to its
own demands.
In the state administration of criminal activity, neoliberal capital
encodes its most precious hopes – economic, political and ideological. It
had been waiting too long to waste the opportunity to bring them to frui-
tion when it fijinally came: “what the U.S. needed to be able to dominate
much of humanity and the world’s resources was ‘some catastrophic and
catalyzing event – like a new Pearl Harbor’. The attacks of 11 September
2001 provided the ‘new Pearl Harbor’ described as ‘the opportunity of
ages.’ The extremists who have since exploited 11 September come from
the era of Ronald Reagan, when far-right groups and ‘think tanks’ were
established to avenge the American ‘defeat’ in Vietnam. In the 1990s, there
was an added agenda: to justify the denial of a ‘peace dividend’ following
the Cold War. The Project for the New American Century was formed,
along with the American Enterprise Institute, the Hudson Institute and
others that have since merged the ambitions of the Reagan administration
35 These policies, explains Borja, are aimed at producing perverse efffects; the repressive
logic leads to preemptive repression of entire social collectives, turning a once innocent
populace into criminals, fostering greater injustice and aggravating the very problems of
coexistence that it is supposed to resolve, generating more violence than existed previ-
ously, contributing to the arousal of the most irrational fears and provoking increased
demands for more security (Borja, 2007).
36 Fear “is a way of postulating the future, perhaps the contemporary way of forging
consensus on the dictates of time… it has become a kind of metagram that organizes the
subjectivity of every aspect of life… Strictly speaking, the big modern States no longer
require political repression to ‘maintain order’, as we were accustomed to seeing up until
the 1980s. The society of fear established in the proliferation of trafffijicking seeks to introject
into each citizen the security guard of his own civil impotence… the exception turned into
the rule. How can we explain the origins of this new form that legitimizes order based on
the routine collapse of order itself?” (Semo, 2005).
228 chapter nine
with those of the current Bush regime” (Pilger, 2002).37 Thus, it is simply
too useful to be abandoned, at least not willingly. Only intense social pres-
sure could force it to do so.
Over the course of the historical development of the liberal pattern, the
workers were processing their ideological, political and organic separation
from the capitalist state, until they were forced to make the transition to
the contained form of domination. During the Keynesian period they
were closely connected to the state, organized under its hegemony through
their integration into civil society; capitalist domination organized a social
framework in which ideological creation and dissemination, that is, the
organization of civil society, were closely associated with bargaining for
and granting improved material conditions in the lives of the workers. In
the Keynesian pattern of domination the framework of the state adminis-
tration of concessions was established as the setting in which ideological
domination is organized. In the neoliberal pattern, this setting is occupied
by state administration of both competitiveness and criminal activity.
The Crime Promotion Brigades constitute, in the sub-world of criminal
activity, the equivalent of the Competitiveness Promotion Brigades in the
sub-world of legal activity. Both are internal to the ideology of neoliberal
capital, an expression of a dominated society incapable of making an ide-
ological break with capital. They complete the downward network which,
by promoting the life options offfered by neoliberal capital, disseminates
its conception of the world and binds society to its intellectual and moral
leadership. However, as the historical trajectory of the neoliberal pattern
advances, this framework organizing the structure of its civil society
becomes increasingly tied up with the state administration of criminal
activity, fijirstly because, although competition and alienation (and the dis-
content they provoke) are mutually connected and reinforced, they are
ultimately subsumed in crime and the fear it produces, and secondly,
because the future trajectory of neoliberal capital inevitably fosters
increasing criminal activity, as will be shown later in this chapter.
It hardly needs stating that the intellectual and moral leadership of
neoliberal capital is not of the same progressive nature that characterized
37 Others have compared September 11 with the Reichstag fijire (Kagarlitsky, 2001).
ideological domination 229
38 Bearing witness to the reality of criminal activity fostered by neoliberal capital are
the nearly 20,000 deaths in 5 years in Mexico (Sánchez, 2010), although these are related
only to the war on drugs, the soft version of criminal activity. In Iraq and Afghanistan,
where the war on terrorism is being waged (the hard version of criminal activity), the deaths
have surpassed 850,000, as well as more than 1.5 million injured (Dufour, 2008).
230 chapter nine
39 “The revolutionary element that constituted Modernity was the break from the theo-
logical world view of the social order and the constitution of a new world view in which
Reason, as an attribute of man, was an instrument of transformation of the world, through
which he could reflect on himself in his subjectivity… The individual became conscious
and objective, and things lost any quality of mystery. Man creates himself and becomes
self-referential… the notion of perfection lies ahead… For modernity, there are no limits.
It is Man who constructs the meaning of his own actions. There is no prior external orches-
tration. Individuals are lords of their own actions” (Aruj, 2000).
ideological domination 231
Even under the most oppressive conditions, human beings need to fijind
reasons for living that make life tolerable and livable. In the world of neo-
liberal capital, some of these reasons are provided by capital itself. It sells
these reasons (because it never gives anything away) and, therefore, they
are only accessible to people who are integrated (either through competi-
tiveness or criminal activity), who are able to function as consumers.
They are plastic flowers, which nevertheless give some color to the oppres-
sive bleakness of real life and help explain the continued success of
capital domination. There are also real flowers, grown by life itself, which
(although capital attempts to appropriate them and present them as
40 “Vattimo considers that the philosophies of Nietzsche and Heidegger are the founda-
tions for all future ideology. Using these authors, he constructs what he calls the philoso-
phies of diffference, which are based on fragmentation and multiplicity, in opposition to
the dialectic vision as a globalizing vision based on Hegel and Marx. This perspective is also
referred to as ‘weak thought’ or the post-modern condition, and is defijined as a distancing
from the basic ideals of modernity: progress, avant-gardism, critical thinking and sur-
mounting of obstacles. The crisis of modernity thus afffects all aesthetic, cultural and social
values” (Palenga, n.d.).
232 chapter nine
products of its garden, mixing the plastic flowers with the live ones, so that
the former might sap some of the life of the latter) grow not because of,
but in spite of capital.
Heading the list of flowers sold by capital is consumption itself41 and, in
particular, an increasingly spectacular array of electronic products, such
as the computer and Internet with their many possibilities, as well as a
diverse range of software and virtual games, capable of immersing their
many users in a matrix, an illusory, simulated world. The social world is
perceived through the virtual communities and replaced with video addic-
tions and second-life websites, to such an extent that normal life and vir-
tual existence become confused, and it almost seems possible to construct
one’s entire existence around the computer and its range of associated
products, provided that one has the real money to buy them and to satisfy
all the old necessities which are neither virtual nor admit virtual solutions,
such as food, housing and clothing.
Unlike the conventional media that previously monopolized public
entertainment and recreation (fijilm, radio and television), which are one-
way, admitting spectators only, these new media forms are interactive,
offfering a reasonably wide margin for users to participate in the creation
of their own virtual products within which they may weave something of
their own vitality: from on-line chat and making virtual friends and even
lovers (which, according to the experts, may potentially convert into real
ones) to creating their own spaces for information, reflection and amuse-
ment. This universe of electronics and its potential to produce a huge
quantity of virtual products is a complex, multifaceted phenomenon with
a vast range of open possibilities for the future. The Internet in particular
has even turned into a site of conflict between opposing perspectives,
from its conversion into a simple commodity at the service of the consoli-
dation and enrichment of the new giant monopolies (IBM, Microsoft,
Intel, Apple, Yahoo, Amazon and Google) or free access for the free
exchange of use value, music, books, images, etc., to its use as a resource
for the global connection of social movements42 or for the purposes of
41 “When night falls, when the lights of the shopping malls go out and the neon world
disappears, the individual takes refuge in his house, opens the shopping bags (the only
daily moment of pleasure) and feels a sense of fulfijillment of the consumer status awarded
by the market. As this pleasure is momentary – lasting only as long as the act itself – a few
minutes later, in solitude, he returns to his natural state of inaction: the passivity typical of
the democratic societies of the 21st century” (Toledano, 2008).
42 “The Internet allows the organization of local alternative projects through global pro-
tests, which ultimately take place in a particular place, for example, in Seattle, Washington,
ideological domination 233
Prague, etc., but which are established, organized and developed via the online connec-
tion, i.e. the global connection, of local movements and local experiences. The Internet is
the global-local connection, which is the new form of control and social mobilization in
our society” (Castells, 2003).
43 “To abolish religion as the illusory happiness of the people is to demand their real
happiness. The demand to give up illusions about the existing state of afffairs is the demand
to give up a state of afffairs which needs illusions” (Marx, 1844: Abstract).
44 “Reality has been masked under the blue veil of anti-depressants, and social cohe-
sion depends on the work calendar: holidays, long weekends and public entertainment
events” (Toledano, 2008).
45 “Más de cien palabras, más de cien motivos, para no cortarse de un tajo las venas, más
de cien pupilas donde vernos vivos, más de cien mentiras que valen la pena” (Joaquín Sabina,
“Mas de cien mentiras”, 1994).
234 chapter nine
46 “The fact that the laborer consumes his means of subsistence for his own purposes,
and not to please the capitalist, has no bearing on the matter. The consumption of food by
a beast of burden is none the less a necessary factor in the process of production because
the beast enjoys what it eats” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 23).
47 Consider, for example, this exemplary reasoning: “Marriage is an outdated institu-
tion, created by the nobility at a time when human life expectancy was 35 years; as such,
today in the 21st century, if we want a more just and equitable society, we need to transform
the conjugal bond and create a system that truly gives us greater freedom and dignity”
(Norandi, 2010). According to this line of reasoning, marriage is to blame for the problems
produced by neoliberalism and, of course, if that is where the cause is, the solution is to be
found there also.
48 “The battle, the open fijield, is the place where the multiple identities invented by
capitalism, the mermaid songs of plural subjectivity, disappear, and identity of class, of
ideological domination 235
51 “To call on them to give up their illusions about their condition is to call on them to
give up a condition that requires illusions. The criticism of religion is, therefore, in embryo,
the criticism of that vale of tears of which religion is the halo” (Marx, 1844).
ideological domination 237
The Spaceship
52 In the commodity form, the “social character of men’s labor appears to them as an
objective character stamped upon the product of that labor; properties pertaining to them
by nature, as objective determinations of the products of labor themselves… reflecting the
social relation which mediates between producers and global labor, as a social relation
between objects, existing outside the producers” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 1, Sect. 4).
53 “The category of ‘abstract labor’ is closely associated with the critical theory of fetish-
ism because it is the indirect sociability, performed a posteriori, of global social labor that
is reifijied in the products that take on lives of their own and ultimately take over in the capi-
talism of our times” (Kohan, 2007).
ideological domination 239
added). And in the chapter “The Trinity Formula,” Marx notes that “all
forms of society, in so far as they reach the stage of commodity-production
and money circulation, take part in this perversion. But under the capital-
ist mode of production and in the case of capital, which forms its domi-
nant category, its determining production relation, this enchanted and
perverted world develops still more” (Marx, 1894: Ch. 48). It is not only that
things (products) acquire social properties, but that they acquire autono-
mous action, independent of the will and the consciousness of their pro-
ducers. Thus, for example, quantities in commodity exchange relations
“vary continually, independently of the will, foresight and action of the
producers” (Marx, 1894: Ch. 48). And in this action, producers fall under
the command of their products; the social action of the producers “takes
the form of the action of objects, which rule the producers instead of being
ruled by them” (Marx, 1894: Ch. 48, emphasis added).
As the processes unfold, the more mediations intervene, the more the
internal connection – “the nexus, the link and the passage between two
moments of development and the action” (Kohan, 2009) – that joins them
is concealed, the more the action of things shifts beyond the control of the
producers and the more accentuated the command of these things over
their producers becomes. Marx traces a line that follows the general devel-
opment of this process. In “The Fetishism of Commodities and the Secret
Thereof” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 1), he examines the difffijiculties associated with
identifying the internal connection between value and the value form,
while in “The Trinity Formula” (Marx, 1894: Ch. 48) he takes the same
approach to identify the internal connection between the product of value
and its distribution in profijit, income and wages.
In the direct production process, he notes, the relation is still very sim-
ple, and “the actual connection impresses itself upon the bearers of this
process, the capitalists themselves, and remains in their consciousness.
The violent struggle over the limits of the working-day demonstrates this
strikingly. But even within this non-mediated sphere, the sphere of direct
action between labor and capital, matters do not rest in this simplicity.
With the development of relative surplus-value… whereby the productive
powers of social labor are developed, these productive powers and the
social interrelations of labor in the direct labor process seem transferred
from labor to capital. Capital thus becomes a very mystic being since all of
labor’s social productive forces appear to be due to capital, rather than
labor as such…” (Marx, 1894: Ch. 48). And he adds: “Then the process of
circulation intervenes, with its changes of substance and form, on which
all parts of capital, even agricultural capital, devolve… This is a sphere
240 chapter nine
where the relations under which value is originally produced are pushed
completely into the background… the surplus-value contained in the
commodities seem not merely to be realized in the circulation, but actu-
ally to arise from it… This sphere is the sphere of competition which, con-
sidered in each individual case, is dominated by chance; where, then, the
inner law, which prevails in these accidents and regulates them, is only
visible when these accidents are grouped together in large numbers,
where it remains therefore invisible and unintelligible to the individual
agents in production” (Marx, 1894: Ch. 48).
To sum up, “the actual process of production, as a unity of the direct
production process and the circulation process, gives rise to new forma-
tions, in which the vein of internal connections is increasingly lost, the
production relations are rendered independent of one another, and
the component values become ossifijied into forms independent of one
another… the inner connection [is] completely disrupted… precisely
because the relations of production, which are bound to the various mate-
rial elements of the production process, have been rendered mutually
independent… we have the complete mystifijication of the capitalist mode
of production, the conversion of social relations into things… it is an
enchanted, perverted, topsy-turvy world” (Marx, 1894: Ch. 48).
The concept of fetishism, which explains how things acquire social prop-
erties, autonomous action and command over human beings, reflects a
reality generated by the capitalist relations of production; it is an appear-
ance that necessarily corresponds to an essence, which is modifijied only
when that essence changes.54 This fetishized form of social relations,
according to Kosik’s analysis, shapes the world of the pseudo-concrete,
made up of the diffferent phenomena that crowd the everyday environ-
ment, which with their regularity, immediacy and self-evidence penetrate
54 “Whence, then,” asks Marx, “arises the enigmatical character of the product of labor,
so soon as it assumes the form of commodities? Clearly from this form itself… fetishism…
attaches itself to the products of labor so soon as they are produced as commodities, and…
is therefore inseparable from the production of commodities.” And he adds: “The recent
scientifijic discovery, that the products of labor, [in] so far as they are values, are but material
expressions of the human labor spent in their production, marks, indeed, an epoch in the
history of the development of the human race, but by no means dissipates the mist through
which the social character of labor appears to us to be an objective character of the prod-
ucts themselves” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 1).
ideological domination 241
55 On this basis, Marx contrasts classical political economics with vulgar economics:
.“..by Classical Political Economy, I understand that economy which, since the time of
William Petty, has investigated the real relations of production in bourgeois society, in
contradistinction to vulgar economy, which deals with appearances only…” (Marx, 1894:
Ch. 48, fn 33).
242 chapter nine
56 According to Kosik, “agents of social conditions feel at ease, as fijish do in water, in the
world of phenomenal forms that are alienated from their internal connections and are in
such isolation absolutely senseless” (Kosik, 1976: 2, emphasis added).
ideological domination 243
57 According to Ianni, the metaphor of the spaceship carries with it the idea of the
decline of the status of individuals, either singular or collective, as a subject of reason and
of history, now reduced to “producing the material and spiritual conditions of their subor-
dination and probable dissolution.” And he adds, quoting Robert Kurz: “Universal reason,
supposedly absolute, has been debased to mere functional rationality at the service of the
process of appreciation of money (which has no subject), even to the point of the contem-
porary unconditional capitulation of the so-called sciences of the spirit” (Ianni, 1996: 8).
58 “These formulae, which bear it stamped upon them in unmistakable letters that they
belong to a state of society in which the process of production has the mastery over man
instead of being controlled by him… appear to the bourgeois intellect to be as much a self-
evident necessity imposed by Nature as productive labor itself” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 1).
59 In contrast with this submission to the fetish, Marx asserts that “the life-process of
society, which is based on the material process or production, does not strip offf its mystical
veil until it is treated as production by freely associated men, and is consciously regulated
by them in accordance with a settled plan” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 1, Sect. 4).
244 chapter nine
which converts them into capital, and converts capital into wage-labor.
But fetishism identifijies the social relation with the thing itself, and the
latter thus appears just as eternal as the former.
Fetishism, as a support to the eternal nature of capitalism, is the ulti-
mate basis of bourgeois ideology: the social properties, autonomous action
and command over producers associated with things are not, to the
fetishizing mind, individual conditions of a moment in the history of
humanity, but their general, immutable and eternal conditions60 and, as
such, are insuperable: “The formal independence of these conditions of
labor in relation to labor, the unique form of this independence with
respect to wage-labor, is then a property inseparable from them as things,
as material conditions of production, an inherent, immanent, intrinsic
character of them as elements of production. Their defijinite social charac-
ter in the process of capitalist production bearing the stamp of a defijinite
historical epoch is a natural and intrinsic substantive character belonging
to them, as it were, from time immemorial, as elements of the production
process” (Marx, 1894: Ch. 48, emphasis added).
Thus, at least for those who are ideological prisoners of capitalist pro-
duction relations, against the power of the fetish there is nothing that can
be done. Consequently, the starting point for emancipation from the ideo-
logical domination of capital consists in social questioning of capitalist
ownership, the abandonment of the fetishist perception of its eternal
nature and of the need to submit to its command. Once we break free of
this fetishism, we fijind that both the competitiveness and criminal activity
that dominate the world today are at the service of the fetish, that their
needs are derived from the needs of the fetish. Thus, at least on the ideo-
logical level, we experience a radical liberation which is necessary,
although by no means sufffijicient, to give the working class the capacity to
oppose the power of capital (economic, political and ideological).61
60 “The changed form of the conditions of labor, i.e. alienated from labor and confront-
ing it independently, whereby the produced means of production are thus transformed
into capital, and the land into monopolized land, or landed property – this form belonging
to a defijinite historical period thereby coincides with the existence and function of the pro-
duced means of production and of the land in the process of production in general… [I]f
labor as wage-labor is taken as the point of departure, so that the identity of labor in gen-
eral with wage-labor appears to be self-evident, then capital and monopolized land must
also appear as the natural form of the conditions of labor in relation to labor in general”
(Marx, 1894: Ch. 48).
61 “The recent scientifijic discovery, that the products of labor, [in] so far as they are val-
ues, are but material expressions of the human labor spent in their production, marks,
indeed, an epoch in the history of the development of the human race, but, by no means
ideological domination 245
In the following chapter, I will examine the general conditions for this
process, but it is worth noting here that liberation from the ideological
domination of capital is associated with a general process of decline of
capitalism that makes it necessary to overcome it by transforming it into a
society of freely associated human beings who submit the material pro-
duction process to their planned and conscious control, “instead of being
ruled by it as by a blind power.” However, in the world today we are faced
with a paradox: the same conditions that are making it increasingly urgent
to break free of the domination of capital are also rendering that libera-
tion more difffijicult. The fetish is weakened but at the same time increas-
ingly fijierce and threatening, like an old man refusing to die, forcing
humanity to pay the heavy price of sufffering a long and destructive termi-
nal phase.
The defeat of capitalism as the fulfijillment of a historic need is an open
process, involving the conditions under which the transformation may
take place, that is, the degree to which the logic of the fetish will develop
before humanity frees itself from its command, and the possibility that
such liberation may be thwarted if the fetish and its personifijications end
up destroying humanity, as warn some of the more pessimistic assessors of
both the magnitude of the destructive capacity that capital has attained in
the contemporary world and the growing and increasingly radical con-
tempt it shows for life.
dissipates the mist through which the social character of labor appears to us to be an objective
character of the products themselves… The fact that in the particular form of production
with which we are dealing, viz., the production of commodities, the specifijic social charac-
ter of private labor carried on independently, consists in the equality of every kind of that
labor, by virtue of its being human labor, which character, therefore, assumes in the prod-
uct the form of value – this fact appears to the producers, notwithstanding the discovery
above referred to, to be… real and fijinal” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 1, Sect. 4, emphasis added).
246 chapter nine
Under these conditions problems are plentiful, and perusing any newspa-
per can reveal what daily life has turned into in this world dominated
by neoliberal capital: on almost any day in the last two years, in any of
the countries of the world, the menu of news includes competitiveness,
poverty, unemployment, terrorism, crime, and crises of various kinds
(economic, environmental, health crises, etc.). Opinions of the spokespeo-
ple for neoliberal capital abound, invariably focused on arguing for
62 “Freeing up trade and industry from any state protection or control is today the aim
openly stated by politicians and big industrialists” (Kurnitzky, 2000).
63 “Free competition of private economic interests is ultimately replacing all forms of
social coexistence” (Kurnitsky, 2000).
64 “The apparent ‘absolute objectivity’ of the social order ends up predominating over
the subjectivities subjugated to the fetishist order… The rules governing the life of this
objectivity, which are beyond all human control, assume absolute autonomy and take the
helm of the ship of society. They become independent of the collective conscience and
will” (Kohan, 2007).
ideological domination 247
But what is alarming is not only the magnitude of the problems but the
inability to resolve them: “in the near future, in the next ten years, we run
the risk of becoming victims of new economic crises, of an exacerbation of
the ecological hazard and of increasing political confusion… If we had to
say today what the most likely future is, the exacerbation of the crises or
the conception and construction of a new type of society based on respect
for human rights by the vast majority, we would have to respond honestly
that the pessimistic hypothesis is more probable than the optimistic
option, which places its confijidence in the capacity of human beings to
save their own future” (Touraine, 2010).
65 Consider, for example, the following from two articles published in the January 6,
2010 edition of the Spanish newspaper El País: “They didn’t need three hours to work out
that they were in agreement on the basic point: to strengthen the economic government of
Europe, because this is the only possibility that the Old Continent has to compete with the
United States and emerging powers like Brazil, China and India” (Aizpeolea, 2010); “the
unsuccessful attempt of the suicide bomber has prompted the introduction of a controver-
sial system of body scanning… In 30 seconds, the traveler is stripped naked… The White
House has been quick to remind us that the loss of privacy may be a minor necessary evil in
the great struggle against terrorism” (Oppenheimer and Alandete, 2010, emphasis added).
66 This quote is taken from an article published on the same day as the two quoted
above.
248 chapter nine
67 This obviously refers to the form of state capitalism that claimed the title of “real
socialism”, to which I referred in Chapters 4 and 5.
68 Science seeks “knowledge for its own sake… science obeys its own rules… Speculation
is here the name given the discourse on the legitimation of scientifijic discourse… that is to
say, philosophical. Philosophy must restore unity to learning, which has been scattered
into separate sciences… to realize this project of totalization” (Lyotard, 1984, 32, 33, 34).
69 “The subject… is humanity as the hero of liberty. All peoples have a right to science…
The State receives its legitimacy not from itself but from the people… the State… assumes
direct control over the training of the ‘people’ under the name of the ‘nation’ in order to
point them down the path to progress… knowledge fijinds its validity not within itself… but
in a practical subject – humanity… its epic is the story of its emancipation from everything
that prevents it from governing itself” (Lyotard, 1984: 31, 32, 35).
70 This is the title of Chapters 4 and 5 of Lyotard’s book.
250 chapter nine
71 According to Lyotard, the terms performance and performativity (of a system) refer to
“optimal performance and measurable efffijiciency in input/output relations” and he adds
that, unlike a denotative utterance (in which “the addressee is put in a position of having
to give or refuse his assent”), the distinctive feature of a performative utterance “is that its
efffect upon the referent coincides with its enunciation… [it] is not subject to discussion or
verifijication on the part of the addressee, who is immediately placed in the new context cre-
ated by the utterance” (Lyotard, 1984: 26, emphasis added).
72 “The ruling class is and will continue to be the class of the ‘decision makers’. It is no
longer composed of the traditional political class, but of a composite layer by corporate
leaders, high-level administrators, and the heads of the major professional, labor, political
and religious organizations” (Lyotard, 1984: 35).
ideological domination 251
Rejecting Humanism
73 Lyotard defijines terror as “the efffijiciency gained by the elimination or by the threat of
elimination of a ‘player’ from the language game one shares with him. He is silenced or
consents, not because he has been refuted, but because his ability to participate has been
threatened…” There are many ways in which he might be deprived of this ability. The threat
is essentially: “Adapt your aspirations to our ends, or else…” (Lyotard, 1984: 64).
74 The basic principle of humanism, according to Sader, is that “men make their own
history, even when they are not aware of the fact” (Sader, 2007). This allows criticism of
views that displace people as the center of the world, with its problems, but also with its
solutions, in favor of diverse fetishes (including capital, which is what concerns us here).
252 chapter nine
75 “While social ferocity always existed, it had imperative limits, because labor resulting
from human lives was indispensable to those who held power… Never has humanity as a
whole been so threatened in its survival… human beings until now were always given a
guarantee: they were essential to the function of the planet” (Forrester, 1999: 126).
ideological domination 253
Rejecting Politics
76 In Latin America, although the development of antagonisms has been less intense
than in the Arab world, there is no shortage of authors who offfer a more extreme descrip-
tion of the danger that humanism represents for neoliberalism: “the countries of ALBA
[Bolivarian Alliance for the Americas] are building an economic system without precedent,
with the human being at the heart, based on solidarity, cooperation, redistribution and
complementariness. In contrast, the government and legislature of the United States retain
only a few remnants of a humanist and humanitarian vision of political economics. It is
worth examining this contrast further, because it clarifijies the basic motive behind the
imperialist military aggression of the United States and its allies, which will probably lead
the region into war” (Solo, 2009, emphasis added).
254 chapter nine
the hierarchy of society’s goals; but then neither does the pariah, the crim-
inal, the informal worker, the illegal immigrant, or the racist, xenophobic
neo-Nazi.77
Let us return now to Lyotard to observe how dead wood like truth and
justice (although the same procedure can be extended to any uncomfort-
able narrative, such as humanism, democracy or the political theories of
the social contract or the common good) can be turned into input that
enhances the performativity of capital. But fijirst, to avoid any confusion, it
is worth reiterating where the absolute priority lies: “Having competence
in a performative-oriented skill does indeed seem saleable… and it is efffiji-
cient by defijinition. What no longer makes the grade is competence as defijined
by other criteria, such as true/false, just/unjust, etc.” (Lyotard, 1984: 51,
emphasis added). Nevertheless, in relation to truth, it is important to recall
a few salient points.
Firstly (as is obvious), that the aim is not to reject the production of
knowledge in general, but to encourage the production of relevant knowl-
edge. Those who have resources to fund research, even for the dissemina-
tion of the knowledge, are the state and the companies, but the funds are
allocated “in accordance with this logic of power growth. Research sectors
that are unable to argue that they contribute… to the optimization of the
system’s performance are abandoned… The criterion of performance is
explicitly invoked by the authorities to justify their refusal to subsidize
certain research centers… The desired goal becomes… the best performativ-
ity of the social system… The general efffect [of the performativity
principle] is to subordinate the institutions of higher learning to the
authorities” (Lyotard, 1984: 47–48, emphasis added).
Secondly, this truth, which is partial, biased and relevant only to the
logic of the development of the fetish, can be promoted to the category of
the socially prevailing truth: “No money, no proof – and that means… no
truth. The games of scientifijic language become the games of the rich, in
which whoever is wealthiest has the best chance of being right” (Lyotard,
1984: 45).
77 “Life is lived in immediate terms, never thinking in perspective; the world has no
future, [because] ‘the future is already here’. History has no meaning in relation to what lies
ahead” (Aruj, 2000).
256 chapter nine
Rejecting Criticism
Thus, the postmodern program does not reject truth, justice, humanism,
the common good, democracy, or the social contract in general. What it
explicitly posits is the concept of the relevant relationship between these
narratives and the performativity of capital. It is thus concerned with
78 “Whence its credibility: it has the means to become a reality, and that is all the proof
it needs. This is what Horkheimer called the ‘paranoia’ of reason” (Lyotard, 1984: 12).
79 “This procedure operates within the following framework: since ‘reality’ is what pro-
vides the evidence used as proof in scientifijic argumentation, and also provides prescrip-
tions and promises of a juridical, ethical and political nature with results, one can master
all of these games by mastering ‘reality’. That is precisely what technology can do. By rein-
forcing technology, one reinforces ‘reality’ and one’s chances of being just and right
increase accordingly” (Lyotard, 1984: 47).
ideological domination 257
turning them from dead wood into input that will enhance this performa-
tivity. In other words, it is concerned with eliminating criticism made from
these perspectives of the logic of the fetish, eliminating any construction
based on them that might be turned into a project of emancipation, in
order to make them relevant to the development of the logic of the fetish.
“[T]his realism of systematic self-regulation, and this perfectly sealed cir-
cle of facts and interpretations” Lyotard argues “can be judged paranoid
only if one has, or claims to have, at one’s disposal a viewpoint that is in
principle immune from their allure. This is the function of the principle of
class struggle in theories of society based on the work of Marx” (Lyotard,
1984: 12).
Thus, if this viewpoint is eliminated (i.e. if Marxism is eliminated80), we
will be happily settled in this paranoid realism of the systematic self-
regulation of the fetish: “This is how legitimation by power takes shape.
Power is not only good performativity, but also efffective verifijication and
good verdicts… It is self-legitimating, in the same way a system organized
around performance maximization seems to be” (Lyotard, 1984: 47). The
elimination of this viewpoint thus becomes the core purpose of the post-
modernist narrative.
This viewpoint, as I indicated in the fijirst chapters of this work, was
constructed by Marx from two intersecting perspectives: the fijirst refers to
necessary relations, independent of the will and consciousness of human
beings, relations which have a tendential development and which neces-
sarily lead to the end of the capitalist mode of production, while the sec-
ond relates to the struggle of the classes. Lyotard, as will be shown below,
does not commit the vulgarity of declaring the internal contradictions
of capitalism resolved, as do some other postmodernists, but positions
his argument that the critical model has been invalidated at the level of
the class struggle. The delegitimation of the emancipation narrative is
based on the retreat of Keynesianism and the defeat of “the communist
alternative.” According to his assessment of Marxism, “in the countries
with liberal or advanced liberal management,” the struggles inspired by
Marxism have been transformed into “regulators of the system,” while
“in communist countries, the totalizing model and its totalitarian efffect
80 Although the discourse of “the decline of the unifying and legitimating power of the
grand narratives” is targeted at any criticism of the logic of the fetish, its privileged target is
Marxism. According to Lyotard, “it would be easy to show that Marxism has wavered
between the two models of narrative legitimation [of speculation and emancipation]”
(Lyotard, 1984: 36).
258 chapter nine
have made a comeback in the name of Marxism itself, and the struggles
in question have simply been deprived of the right to exist” (Lyotard,
1984: 13).81
In this way – and this is his fijinal argument – “the social foundation of
the principle of division, or class struggle, was blurred to the point of los-
ing all of its radicality; we cannot conceal the fact that the critical model
in the end lost its theoretical standing and was reduced to the status of a
‘utopia’ or ‘hope’, a token protest raised in the name of man or reason or
creativity, or again of some social category – such as the Third World or the
students – on which is conferred in extremis the henceforth improbable
function of critical subject” (Lyotard, 1984: 13). In contrast with the post-
modernist position, over the course of these chapters I have explained
the historical trajectory taken by the diffferent eras of capitalist domina-
tion, and the conclusion that can be drawn from this examination
(particularly in the case of the neoliberal pattern) – the need to further
develop this criticism – is exactly the opposite of that put forward by the
postmodernists.
The domination pattern concept is useful for analysis, but also for polit-
ical purposes. It is useful for analysis because it links the history of domi-
nation to the tendencies that have directed the historical development of
capitalism and to the circumstances of the class struggle. It is useful for
political purposes because it reveals the subject of the process (class or a
faction thereof), helping to dismantle the most intrinsic tactic of bour-
geois ideology aimed at defusing any inquiry by the dominated classes
who seek the cause of and the solution to their woes: to present the order
of capitalist society as an expression of human nature, the needs of capital
as natural needs and the process of capital as natural, as a process without
a subject. If, as its ideologues take for granted, the laws governing the oper-
ation of capital are as natural and eternal as the law of gravity, the affflic-
tions of the workers are natural, eternal and irremediable and the only
rational response is resignation. But as capital is in fact a product of soci-
ety and history, resignation is not only irrational but impossible and,
although for Lyotard it is merely a “token protest raised in the name of
man,” the project of emancipation of humanity from the power of the
fetish – the incorrigible utopia referred to in a song by Spanish songwriter
81 “Everywhere the Critique of political economy (the subtitle of Marx’s Capital) and its
correlate, the critique of alienated society, are used in one way or another as aids in pro-
gramming the system” (Lyotard, 1984: 13).
ideological domination 259
Joan Manuel Serrat,82 which “is not satisfijied with the possible,” and “raises
hurricanes of rebellion” – is as inalienable a feature of the working class as
the will to live itself. “Without utopia, life would be a rehearsal for death”
sings Serrat, and he is right for two reasons.
First, because the class struggle in capitalism remains unaltered: the
weakness and defeat of those dispossessed of the means of production,
which under the current circumstances has resulted in their resistance
being “blurred to the point of losing all of its radicality,” has as a necessary
correlate the reinforcement and the fijierce radicalization of the struggle on
the side of capital. Second, because with its development, capital tends to
aggravate the social ills that it provokes, as Lyotard himself acknowledges:
“The logic of maximum performance is no doubt inconsistent in many
ways, particularly with respect to contradiction in the socioeconomic
fijield: it demands both less work (to lower production costs) and more (to
lessen the social burden of the idle population). But,” he adds, in keeping
with a discourse convinced of the eternal nature of the fetish, “our incre-
dulity is now such that we no longer expect salvation to rise from these
inconsistencies, as did Marx” (Lyotard, 1984: xxiv). He subsequently con-
fijirms this point of view: “Even when its rules are in the process of changing
and innovations are occurring, even when its dysfunctions (such as strikes,
crises, unemployment, or political revolutions) inspire hope and lead to
belief in an alternative, what is actually taking place is an internal read-
justment, and its result can be no more than an increase in the system’s
‘viability’. The only alternative to this kind of performance improvement is
entropy, or decline” (Lyotard, 1984: 11–12).
82 “¡Ay! Utopía incorregible que no tiene bastante con lo posible… que levanta hura-
canes de rebeldía… Sin utopía, la vida sería un ensayo para la muerte.” (Joan Manuel Serrat,
“Utopía”, 1992).
260 chapter nine
83 “The instances and segments that comprise the social framework become absolutely
‘autonomous’… The local fragment takes on a life of its own. The micro-unit began to
claim autonomy and turn its back on any logic of struggle at a global level. The specifijic
code of each rebellion (the code of the colonized, of ethnicity, of an oppressed community
or people, of gender, of a sexual or generational minority, etc.) no longer recognized
any level of connection with the others… Each instance of domination… could only be
challenged from its own particular context, turned into an isolated ghetto and into a ‘lan-
guage game’ disconnected from any global perspective or universal translation” (Kohan,
2007).
84 “The subject of Marxism is a collective subject that is constituted as such (incorpo-
rating the multiple individualities and group identities) in the struggle against its historic
enemy. It is the working class as a whole, and thus constitutes a subject that is not only
individual, but collective” (Kohan, 2007).
ideological domination 261
85 “If there is no longer a central power to fijight, if there no longer exists a privileged
space of confrontation where the diverse collective of exploiters and oppressors fijind a
common fortifijication to guarantee the reproduction of the social order, then there is no
way of forming a radical opposition to fijight for complete changes to the system” (Kohan,
2007).
86 “But with the condition that each one must remain confijined to its own issues and
that all maintain a mutual distance from one another” (Kohan, 2007).
87 “Instead of the universalist aspirations of socialism and the integrating politics of the
struggle against class exploitation, we have a plurality of essentially disconnected individ-
ual struggles, leading to submission to capitalism… an excuse for disintegrating the resis-
tance to capitalism” (Ellen Meiksins Wood, as quoted in Kohan, 2007).
262 chapter nine
88 “In opposition to reason, which proposes that individuals unite for a common proj-
ect that is reasonable and logical for all… in postmodernity we fijind a ‘being together’ that
is informed by a sensitive, erotic reason, that is, a ‘being together’ out of sentimental inter-
est, not common interest in a political or religious project… In opposition to a faith in the
future of modernity, there appears in postmodernity a special attention to the present, to
the experience of here and now… Tribes are junctions that form part of a network – a net-
work that connects them to each other. This network is the masses… an entity unto itself,
i.e. without a purpose… by which it may be diffferentiated from the notion of society, in
which it was understood that specifijic common purposes existed… the masses breaks up
constantly into tribes” (Cassián et al, 2006).
89 This line of interpretation can be found in works of authors such as Michel Mafffesoli
(see Mafffesoli, 1996) or the interviews he has given to the newspapers La Nación (Corradini,
2005) and El Clarín (Martiniuk, 2009).
90 “The term ‘identifijication’ implies a process of participation, somewhat magic or mys-
tical. You lose yourself; when I lose myself in a particular tribe, I experience ecstasy. I am no
longer myself – I am the group. Through the multiplicity of facets I will participate in a
multiplicity of tribes and the interlinking chain of these tribes makes up the masses”
(Mafffesoli, as quoted in Martiniuk, 2009).
ideological domination 263
91 Mafffesoli contrasts the myth of Dionysus, god of festivity, with the myth of
Prometheus, god of progress: “The citizens of the booming modern, progressive, hard-
working metropolis, dying of boredom, end up opening their doors to let in Dionysus”
(as quoted by Corradini, 2005).
264 chapter nine
92 More than 160 years ago, Marx wrote: “Economists have a singular method of proce-
dure. There are only two kinds of institutions for them: artifijicial and natural. The institu-
tions of feudalism are artifijicial institutions; those of the bourgeoisie are natural institutions.
In this they resemble the theologians, who likewise establish two kinds of religion. Every
religion which is not theirs is a religion of men, while their own is an emanation from
God… Thus there has been history, but there is no longer any” (Marx, 1847: Ch. 2, emphasis
added).
ideological domination 265
social relations of capitalism as eternal, and as we have seen how the shift
from the contained form to the natural form of its domination is cele-
brated as a great triumph – an eternal triumph over the working class.
93 Elsewhere, Lyotard quotes Claus Mueller: “In advanced industrial society, legal-
rational legitimation is replaced by a technocratic legitimation that does not accord any
importance to the beliefs of the citizen or to morality per se” (Lyotard, 1984: 97, emphasis
added).
266 chapter nine
Thus, in essence, the subject is the fetish and the capitalist is merely its
personifijication; its incarnation must be sought for elsewhere.
According to Marx, “it is only because his money constantly functions
as capital that the economic guise of a capitalist attaches to a man…
Except as personifijied capital, the capitalist has no historical value, and no
right to that historical existence… And so far only is the necessity for his
own transitory existence implied in the transitory necessity for the capi-
talist mode of production” (Marx, 1867: Ch. 23, 24). The right to existence
must be defended in competition with other capitalists to earn the right
to reach the fijinishing line; if the subject of the process of capitalist
development is the flourishing of the fetish, the last man is its fijinal incar-
nation, the incarnation of Absolute Monopoly of the means of production
and subsistence, i.e. the result of the full development of its internal
tendencies.
Following the thought of Heidegger, Roberto Aruj suggests that post-
modernism “eliminates the historic subject as the reconstructor of reality,
as reconstructor of history… Subjects do not exist; rather, there are beings
that become Being, in the sense of an entity involved in a transformation in
which the subject is the recipient of the dynamic” (emphasis added). And
these individuals turning into Being, that is, capitalists chosen by the
Being to be incarnated, “attempt to maintain their status through compe-
tition with no restrictions on its development… Their ultimate goal is to
stay in the game because only those who can integrate and adapt to the
dynamic established by the system will make it through the elimination
rounds. The rest will vanish… the lives of millions of people is worth noth-
ing.” (Aruj, 2000)95 According to Kurnitzky, neoliberalism proclaims that
“might is right,” and total competition under the precepts of laissez faire
turns society into a battleground of individual economic interests, with
no limit on the actions of “the ablest and the fijittest” (Kurnitzky, 2000).
Earlier on, I offfered an analysis of the global fijinancial oligarchy, the per-
sonifijication of global fijinancial capital, which aims to concentrate all the
world’s wealth, while in Chapter 7 I explained how its ruling group (par-
ticularly the high-level political bureaucracy of the United States) views
itself as the administration of a global government, responsible for bring-
ing all the nation-states into the network in its global administration of
competitivity and criminal activity, to compete in the provision of the
most profijitable conditions and to fijight everything that threatens the
unhindered development of the free market and the domination of fijinan-
cial capital and the global fijinancial oligarchy. The implementation of this
project of economic and political expansion of global fijinancial capital is
the project for the future that neoliberal capital offfers humanity and is
what explains why it bases its ideological domination on the promotion of
competitivity, alienation, criminal activity and fear, and why it is so radi-
cally hostile to any opposition to the logic of the fetish.
In this global oligarchy, still in fijierce competition with itself and in a
voracious pursuit of the means of production and subsistence that remain
outside its control, lies neoliberal capital’s last man, still seeking the full
implementation of his mission and vision, i.e. Absolute Monopoly. No
doubt, he will continue this pursuit to the extent that society and the proj-
ect’s own internal contradictions allow. Unless the power of the fetish is
contained, its logic, and the development of its internal tendencies, will
continue to grow.
In relation to this third goal, there is also little to add, except to note that
as the gestation of the last man progresses and the irreconcilable contra-
diction that exists between him and the rest of humanity becomes more
brutally evident, the use of the mass media to manipulate, control and
direct social behavior for political purposes, based on the argument of a
situation of a permanent global war on terrorism and organized crime,
becomes increasingly perverse and cynical.
We can fijind an example of this in the war on terrorism, although
it could also easily be found in the war on organized crime or, more
generally, in any situation in which neoliberal capital seeks to promote
its anti-popular or pernicious projects. Rouleau suggests that, “with
the pretext of ‘communicating’, all governments – to varying degrees –
practice disinformation,” but in times of war, “manipulation of informa-
tion becomes common currency, whether through the dissemination of
half-truths or lies, commission through omission or the spreading of
unverifijiable rumors.” Thus, in preparation for the war against Iraq and to
generate a climate of confijidence and support for the government’s anti-
terrorist policy among Americans, there flourished “in the White House
and in the Pentagon, in the CIA and in the Department of State” a multi-
tude of “communication departments” and “public relations” advisers
and, “in the greatest of secrecy,” the Pentagon created “an Offfijice of Strategic
Influence, whose mission was to misguide public opinion – a supreme
skill – through non-U.S. press agencies (chiefly, the Agence France Presse
and Reuters)” (Rouleau, 2003).
It is certainly not surprising that the Pentagon has “decided that even
lying is valid,” given that “these types of techniques have always been used
by the CIA in disinformation campaigns and operations to destabilize for-
eign governments, for example, in Cuba or Iraq” (Baron, 2002). But there is
one substantial diffference between past and present models: these cam-
paigns were once directed against foreign enemy governments; now they
are directed against the whole world. “According to an article published on
ideological domination 271
the front page of the New York Times, the newly created Offfijice of Strategic
Influence is planning to disseminate information to international agen-
cies and media outlets as part of an efffort aimed at influencing public opin-
ion in the heart not only of enemy countries but also of those considered to be
friends, with the aim that all the information broadcast by agencies such
as Reuters or Agence France Press ends up published in the American dai-
lies”97 (Baron, 2002, emphasis added).
In February 2002, a scandal broke out when the existence of the Offfijice
of Strategic Influence was made public: “in the face of the outrage gener-
ated in the Congress and in the press, Donald Rumsfeld, Secretary of
Defense, was compelled to offfer his apologies and announce the closure of
the department, which was quickly replaced by another bearing the more
discrete name of Offfijice of Special Plans” (Rouleau, 2003, emphasis added).
However (and this point is of particular signifijicance), “one of Washington’s
most notorious ‘hawks’ and a personal friend of Rumsfeld, Frank Gafffney,
published a virulent attack against a ‘left’ that sought to deprive the United
States of an indispensable instrument of war” (Rouleau, 2003, emphasis
added). In fact, as the gestation of the last man progresses, what is clear
above all else is the war that this last man has launched against the rest of
humanity; the outstanding feature of the state administration of criminal
activity is combat and its establishment as a situation of permanent war
(on organized crime and/or international terrorism and/or any useful
enemy), which means, as a logical correlate, that everything – from human
and civil rights to information and communication98 – is submitted to
the rules of war, thereby legitimating (at least for the personifijications
of capital) the planned use of propaganda aimed at social and political
control.99
97 “The main target would be the moderate Islamic Arabic nations, where the discon-
tent and unease provoked by the anti-terrorist war is on the rise and, according to the
Pentagon, threatens to destabilize the whole region. But the information, or rather, disin-
formation, would also be aimed at allied nations in Europe, Asia and Latin America”
(Baron, 2002), and at U.S. society itself.
98 Information and communication via all forms of media, including the Internet,
which has increasing priority: “For decades, the battle of ideas has been waged on radio
and television. Today, that battle has entered a new dimension. It is now being waged on
the World Wide Web, as demonstrated by two websites sponsored by the United States
European Command” (Coon, 2007).
99 When questioned about illegal spying on U.S. citizens, President Bush refused to
comment: “We don’t talk about ongoing intelligence operations to protect the country…
Any sources and methods of intelligence will remain guarded in secret,” and he explained
that the “reason” was that “there is an enemy stalking us who would like to know exactly
what we’re doing in order to stop it” (AFP, 2005).
272 chapter nine
The necessity for lies is itself grounded in lies100 and the circle is thus
closed; who, other than the enemy, would be opposed to misleading the
enemy? In a state of war, normal democratic conditions cannot be estab-
lished, as lying, misleading and concealing are necessities of war and true
information is only available to Chiefs of Stafff; troops and civilians must
simply place their trust in the commands, as inquiring into the truth is
equated with serving the enemy. And as the enemy also misleads, i.e. there
is no nor can there be any reliable, verifijiable information on the enemy,
about whom we only know what the authorities tell us,101 society is
trapped in a truly Orwellian “Ministry of Truth” (which, to reduce the obvi-
ousness of its fijilial association with Big Brother, might well be named the
Offfijice of Strategic Influence or Special Plans).
With a design that echoes the media manipulation presented in the
fijilm Wag the Dog or the story lines of comic strips like Batman and his
arch-criminal enemies, or the fijilms depicting James Bond’s struggle
against the diabolical organization SPECTRE led by the supervillain
Blofeld, mythical enemies of the free world can be created, like Goldstein
en 1984 or Bin Laden and Al Qaeda102 after 9/11, or any other enemy that
may appear in the future once the media efffectiveness of the existing
supervillains has been exhausted.
Having established the war on terrorism, the next natural, logical step is
to feed the fear, multiplying infijinitely the efffects of terrorism “through the
manipulation and spin of mass media presentation around the globe”
(Freytas, 2007).103 The use of “media terrorism” (media operations directed
100 “Covert propaganda… produces devastating results, given that the mass audiences
of television, radio and newspapers consume it unaware of the interests and political
objectives that drive it, believing that it has no other purpose than to inform” (Guevara,
2005).
101 “In the real world, there are no precise data on the existence or the death of Bin
Laden, and nobody has yet revealed how he was able to escape from the military siege and
missiles in Afghanistan. Nobody questions why the CIA, with its countless networks of
infijiltration into Islamic terrorism, has not been able to detect or assassinate him, nor even
why Osama has disappeared without a trace in spite of the fact that offfijicially every intelli-
gence service in the world is searching for him night and day” (Freytas, 2006a).
102 Chossudovsky reminds us that “the alleged mastermind behind 9/11, Saudi-born
Osama Bin Laden, was recruited during the Soviet-Afghan war, ironically under the aus-
pices of the CIA, to fijight Soviet invaders” (Chossudovsky, 2008a). See also Chossudovsky,
2001 and Tarpley, 2004.
103 “The ‘fear of terrorism’ process is in turn fed by the major international agencies and
networks responsible for the worldwide broadcasting (as if taken from the pages of a spy
novel) of stories, leaks, press releases, letters, videos with new threats, ‘secret information’
on terrorist groups, leads, etc… and keeping the ‘terrorism of Al Qaeda’ up their sleeve like
a trump card to be pulled out whenever the international (or local) situation so requires”
(Freytas, 2007).
ideological domination 273
104 For this reason, for example, Bin Laden makes periodical reappearances: “he threat-
ens Europe and the United States with a holy war, promises attacks and mass murders with
chemical and biological weapons, and then disappears as mysteriously as he came… Al
Jazeera shows the videos with his communiqués and threats, the U.S. and European net-
works broadcast them around the world, and the CIA – along with the rest of the intelli-
gence services of the central powers – announces all kinds of terrorist catastrophes
looming, mainly in the United States or Europe” (Freytas, 2006a).
274 chapter nine
105 It is not hard to see the similarity between the pattern followed by Russia in
Chechnya and that followed by the United States in Afghanistan: “The tactic that radically
tipped the balance in favor of the new war was the propaganda on the explosions in
Moscow. The presentation of these events had a dramatic efffect on public opinion. The
reports underlined the idea that Chechnya was a nation of bandits, with no law or order,
and that kidnappings were commonplace; therefore, the country was a direct threat to the
Russian population… and society would never be safe until the Chechen threat was elimi-
nated completely… The propaganda put the Chechen independence leader, Shamil
Basayev, in fijirst place among the men most hated by Russia’s urban population” (Pineda,
2003).
106 This shift occurs even more easily if blame is added to the mix: “The intolerable rise
of crime in Russian cities was associated with the image of ‘bandits’ attributed not only to
the guerrillas but to the whole Chechen population” (Pineda, 2003).
107 “What is wrong with the human race, that it can be moved to crying over 22 hired
men running behind a ball, and yet doesn’t shed a single tear over the mass murder of its
own species? How did we come to this aberration, this atrocious individualism, this dehu-
manization, this indiffference to life and death, where the only forces of collective mobili-
zation are sports idols and entertainment fijigures?” (Freytas, 2006b).
ideological domination 275
Degradation
108 It is not my purpose to explore the topic further here, but for more information see
the Washington Offfijice on Latin America, 2008, and Rojas Aravena, 2008, among many
others.
109 “Mass poverty is incompatible with social harmony and public stability. Latin
America has become a flagrant example of this. Added to organized crime, the illegal levies
of paramilitary groups and the practices or deviations of some guerrilla forces, the outra-
geous gap between rich and poor, the cynicism of the elite, the widespread corruption of
the police, or the disrepute of the justice system (due, among other factors, to the impunity
that has accompanied so many state crimes), have weakened civic values, undermined
social solidarity and fostered a wave of crime which, in some countries, is characterized by
the multiplication of sexually motivated kidnappings… symptomatic of societies in crisis,
and of an accelerated societal breakdown” (Prolongeau and Rampal, 1997).
278 chapter nine
lives (“our martyrs bear witness to it”), erodes their government structures
(“the temptation that the manna of trafffijicking must represent to a poorly
paid government employee”) and their productive and social structures:
“in Afghanistan, there is nothing but opium. What is needed is to pull this
country out of poverty and develop alternatives for rural workers… the
U.S. offfensive has only encouraged the option of poppy growing, which is
the means of subsistence for 3.3 million Afghans” (Gouverneur, 2002).
In Iraq, local corruption is entwined with corruption in the West110 and
they have been working together, even since before the war in 2003, to ruin
the country. The sanctions against Baghdad, in force since August 1990,
had a devastating efffect on Iraqi society: in addition to “problems in
obtaining food and medicine, the infrastructure began to deteriorate,111
essential services for the population, ministries, electrical power plants,
drinking water, all dropped to extremely precarious levels… Corruption,
which until then had been nonexistent, began to develop at every level.
Crime grew at a dizzying rate… Much of the middle class emigrated and
the country lost its professionals. The education system, which previously
covered all children, recorded a spike in student dropouts, as many had to
work to help their families survive, thereby producing a semi-illiterate
generation… The country took a fijifteen-year leap backwards, which will
take a lot of work to redress… they destabilized one of the most important
states in the region and increased its chances of fragmentation. Who will
be judged for these errors? What commission will assess these mistakes
for which the whole Middle East pays so dearly?” (Gresh, 2005).
Up to this point, the examples offfered have been taken from the
defenseless underdeveloped world (although always with the enthusiastic
collaboration of developed nations). Not included in this analysis are the
many other notable cases of social degradation in the contemporary
world, such as the recurring humanitarian crises that especially afffect the
110 “Between 1996 and 2003, the ‘Oil for Food’ program allowed Iraqi president Saddam
Hussein to divert hundreds of millions of dollars. At the same time, several high offfijicials in
the United Nations (UN) pocketed large commissions… Moreover, foreign political leaders,
chiefly French, have also taken advantage of the system” (Gresh, 2005).
111 “And, in the midst of this collapse, the desire of the United States to monopolize all
of the reconstruction contracts should not be underestimated. To be able to reestablish
electricity, it would have been necessary to turn to the corporations from Germany
(Siemens) and Switzerland (ABB) that had installed the modern electrical grid in place in
Iraq. To repair the phone lines, the best option was to call Alcatel (a French fijirm), which
had installed the existing system and was familiar with the terrain. But Washington wanted
to punish the governments of Old Europe, and at the same time guarantee the juicy con-
tracts to companies that funded the Republican Party” (Gresh, 2005).
ideological domination 279
countries of Southern Africa and the Horn of Africa, or the shocking work-
ing conditions sufffered by large numbers of workers in India and China.
However, examples can also be found in the developed world. In France,
while they expand the “law-free zones handed over to the parallel econ-
omy and the law of the gangs” and their suburbs appear to have become
their biggest threat,112 they are exploring the best responses to their prob-
lems: “We are witnessing a massive expansion of penalization of behaviors
which until now were not prosecuted under the law, as well as a toughen-
ing up of the penalties imposed for minor crimes… we have shifted from a
global approach to problems (social development of neighborhoods, con-
struction improvement and crime prevention), that is, from the idea that
these problems have social causes, to the idea of the individual responsi-
bility of offfenders and their capacity to choose rationally” (Bonelli, 2003).
Indeed, in France, as around the world, “they are working hard on the
task of social demolition,” eliminating 10,000 jobs in education while
simultaneously hiring 10,000 prison guards, and amending a range of laws
(related to dismissal, reduction of work hours and control of public funds
allocated to businesses), “all of which are considered detestable obstacles
to the ‘liberation of the forces that be’, i.e. employer arbitrariness” (de Brie,
2003).113 The French Right “is committed to the policy of the right to plun-
der, developed under the aegis of the World Trade Organization (WTO),
which negotiates – under the framework of the General Agreement of
Trade in Services (GATS) – for the progressive submission of all public ser-
vices, including health and education, to the law of the market.” De Brie
explains in detail the method used in these cases, whereby the “extrem-
ists” call for exaggerated reforms and the government, after sizing up
the terrain, offfers reasonable, moderate measures: “they use the proven
method of cutting the problem into slices; social demolition in stages”
(de Brie, 2003).
But this is not only happening in France. Throughout the European
Union social dumping is being legitimated in the common market, estab-
lishing “a clear hierarchy between the rights of companies and social
norms, in which the former prevail over the latter,” and although the Court
of Justice of the European Communities “admits that union action consti-
tutes a ‘fundamental right’ (which is indeed an advance in the social
wasteland of Europe) it immediately empties it of content by subjecting it
to the obligation of not ‘hindering’ the freedom of establishment or the
free provision of service of the companies in the common market… the
defense of the minimum wage thus proves incompatible with European
law if it is likely to make the conditions offfered to companies of another
member state ‘less attractive, or more difffijicult’” (Robert, 2010). And since
the EU is fijilled with “millions of voters who are victims of the brutalities
engendered by globalization in the postindustrial world… with multitudes
of disposable workers, suburban new poor, mileuristas, the excluded, retir-
ees in the prime of their lives, casualized youth, middle-class families on
the brink of poverty… the many common people who have fallen victim to
neoliberal shock treatment,” the social democratic parties, which in
2002 governed in 15 countries while in 2010, “in spite of the fact that
the fijinancial crisis has demonstrated the moral, social and ecological
impasse of ultra-liberalism, govern in only fijive nations (Spain, Greece,
Hungary, Portugal and the United Kingdom) because they have not
known how to take advantage of the failure of neoliberalism. And the
governments of three of these countries – Spain, Greece and Portugal,
attacked by the fijinancial markets and afffected by the ‘debt crisis’ – will
fall into discredit and lose their popular support when they begin, with
an iron hand, to implement the austerity programs and unpopular
policies demanded by the logic of the EU and its main gatekeepers”
(Ramonet, 2010).
“Some time ago,” adds Ramonet, “Europe’s social democrats decided to
encourage privatization, promote the reduction of government budgets at
the expense of the public, push up the retirement age and dismantle the
public sector, while spurring on the concentrations and mergers of mega-
corporations and allowing the banks to do as they pleased. For years they
have been accepting, without much regret, a shift toward social liberalism.
They no longer view as priorities any of the objectives that once formed
part of their ideological DNA, for example, full employment, the defense
of the social benefijits won in the past, the development of public services
or the eradication of poverty” (Ramonet, 2010). It is thus no surprise that,
in light of this vacuum of options, right, extreme right and even neo-Nazi
projects thrive.
The United States offfers a great deal of material for analysis in this
area, but I will limit myself to a brief overview drawn from a report issued
ideological domination 281
114 In preparing this report, the members of the commission reviewed “documentation
and listened to dozens of emblematic testimonies by poor, white and black, Latin and
Asian, young and old women and men, veterans of Iraq and mothers who had lost their
children in that war of occupation, homeless people, victims of the Katrina hurricane,
unemployed, migrants against whom walls are built and restrictions are implemented,
while their work and human exploitation is legitimized under neo-slavery conditions,
physically handicapped people, mothers whose children have been unjustly removed by
the State because of their poverty, and citizens with no healthcare, among various sectors
in American society” (Truth Commission, 2006).
282 chapter nine
next,115 its government has no qualms about arguing that it has the right to
deny the rights of others,116 including, of course, its own people: “The U.S.
government has responded to the evidence being arrayed against its out-
landish 9/11 conspiracy theory by redefijining the war on terror from exter-
nal to internal enemies. Homeland Security Secretary Janet Napolitano
said on February 21 that American extremists are now as big a concern as
international terrorists. Extremists, of course, are people who get in the
way of the government’s agenda” (Roberts, 2010, emphasis added).
It isn’t for nothing that the oligarchy of the United States is the one that
most openly promotes its own candidacy for the honor of last man as,
according to Samir Amín, “deprived of the tradition in which social demo-
cratic workers’ and communist parties marked the formation of modern
European political culture, U.S. society lacks the ideological instruments
that would enable it to resist the unchallenged dictatorship of capital…
and it is capital that shapes the society’s mode of thinking in all its dimen-
sions” (Amin, 2003a). But even under these conditions of the society’s
ideological and political weakness, the project of the U.S. oligarchy “can-
not for long be sustained without active repressions, or even tyranny, at
home” and without doing substantial damage to its internal democratic
institutions: “The popular tradition within the United States is anti-
colonial and anti-imperial and it has taken a very substantial conjuring
trick, if not outright deception, to mask the imperial role of the US in
world afffairs or at least to clothe it in grand humanitarian intentions over
the past few decades. It is not clear that the US population will generally
support an overt turn to any long-term militarized Empire (any more than
it ended up supporting the Vietnam War). Nor will it accept for long the
price, already substantial given the repressive clauses inserted into the
Patriot and Homeland Security Acts, that has to be paid at home in terms
of civil liberties, rights and general freedoms” (Harvey, 2004: 82).
In short, social degradation, which dislocates communities, affflicting
them with multiple conflicts and isolating them in contained fury and
impotence, acting like a cancer that gradually spreads throughout the
whole body of society, is not accidental or circumstantial, but rooted in
profound tendencies of neoliberal capital related to the gestation of the
last man and, more generally (as will be shown in the last chapter) to the
115 For a few examples of the scandals, see Brooks, 2005a and Brooks, 2006. U.S. Senator
John McCain, with an undeniable hint of humor, remarks of Washington that “this town
has become very corrupt, there’s no doubt about it” (as quoted in Brooks, 2006).
116 For an exploration of this question, see Chomsky, 2005.
ideological domination 283
Surveillance
The contenders for the title of last man monitor one another on a global
scale as a necessity of competition, but they also monitor their slaves in
order to prevent (or, when required, to repress) any outbreak of resistance
or rebellion. To address this point and take note of the trend (a growing
systematic efffort to enhance surveillance capacities, and the use of scien-
tifijic and technological research and development for espionage and soci-
etal control), highlighting its signifijicance and relevance and outlining
117 “Many of the country’s most successful entrepreneurs are using Israel’s status as a
fortressed state, surrounded by furious enemies, as a kind of twenty-four-hour-a-day show-
room – a living example of how to enjoy relative safety amid constant war” (Klein, 2007a).
Among other successful products and services, these salespeople offfer high-tech fences for
an apartheid planet, unmanned drones, biometric IDs, video and audio surveillance gear,
air passenger profijiling and prisoner interrogation systems. “Palestinians,” says Klein, “are
no longer just targets. They are guinea pigs….” in laboratories “where the terrifying tools of
our security states are being tested” (Klein, 2007a).
284 chapter nine
system that stretches around the world to form a targeting system on all of
the key Intelsat satellites used to convey most of the world’s satellite phone
calls, Internet, email, faxes and telexes” (STOA, 1998). According to the
report, this system works by indiscriminately intercepting huge quantities
of communications, and then picks out those of value using artifijicial intel-
ligence aids.
ECHELON routinely intercepts all telecommunications in the European
Union, is designed for primarily non-military purposes (governments,
organizations and businesses) and has been used to obtain privileged
information which – and this is what truly outraged European business
and political leaders118 – has benefijited U.S. companies involved in arms
deals and strengthened Washington’s position in crucial World Trade
Organization talks with Europe. But while ECHELON exhibits features
that tie in with the competitive strategies of the U.S. oligarchies119 in rela-
tion to their European counterparts, in the case of the EU-FBI the two
sides are in cooperation:
The EU-FBI Global Telecommunications Surveillance System: links the
diffferent police authorities of the European Union with the FBI. According
to a Statewatch report, the EU accepted the “requirements” established by
the FBI focusing on the systematic recording and storage of all informa-
tion trafffijic in telecommunications: “every phone call, every mobile phone
call, every fax, every e-mail, every website’s contents, all internet usage,
from anywhere, by everyone, to be recorded, archived and be accessible
for least seven years,” in addition to making it compulsory for network and
service providers to provide law enforcement agencies with data from
intercepted communications and real-time access to transmissions
(Statewatch, 2001).120 Included as part of this deployment of technological
resources to monitor and control society is direct intervention into per-
sonal computers: “it is now totally possible to gain remote access to any
121 “At the end of 2001, the American television network MSNBC leaked that the FBI was
using the Magic Lantern virus to spy on computers. This Trojan virus and others like Back
Orifijice, Netbus and Sub7 can be introduced into the computer via any online operation:
downloading a song, receiving an email, opening a picture… once installed, the computer
is accessible to the virus owner, who not only can see what is happening on it, but even
intervene and usurp the identity of its users, passwords included” (Ateneu, 2010).
122 For more information on this topic, see also Rodríguez, 2009 and Alandete, 2009.
123 “We understand video surveillance systems to refer to any systems equipped at least
with a camera connected to a screen where the image is viewed… All such cameras and
those who operate them come under social control, forming part of the para-policing infra-
structure” (Ateneu, 2010).
ideological domination 287
124 According to the UK’s Data Protection Commissioner, “the routine long-term preser-
vation of data by ISPs [Internet Service Providers] for law enforcement purposes would be
disproportionate general surveillance of communications.” Nevertheless, “the EU has
agreed in secret on the creation of an international phone tapping network through a
secret network of committees and the EU’s network and service providers will be required
to install ‘interceptable’ systems, and to put any person or group under surveillance when-
ever they receive an interception order… These plans have never been submitted for review
to a European government, nor to the European Parliament’s Committee on Civil Liberties,
in spite of the evident issues of public freedoms posed by such an uncontrolled system. The
decision to go ahead was simply adopted in secret” (Statewatch, 2001).
288 chapter nine
Murder
Throughout the neoliberal period so far, the pursuit of the goal has been
very intense in underdeveloped countries: “Countries are destroyed,
often transformed into territories, sovereignty is foregone, national
institutions collapse, the national economy is destroyed through the
imposition of ‘free market’ reforms, unemployment becomes rampant,
social services are dismantled, wages collapse, and people are impover-
ished… In turn, the nation’s assets and natural resources are transferred
into the hands of foreign investors through a privatization program
imposed by the invading forces” (Chossudovsky, 2007a). These processes
ideological domination 289
Cold War, the CIA continued to support Islamic brigades that served “as a
catalyst for the disintegration of the Soviet Union and the emergence of
six new Muslim republics in Central Asia,” but that would also operate in
Bosnia and Chechnya and promote secessionist Islamic insurgencies in
India’s Kashmir and on China’s western border with Afghanistan and
Pakistan, while at the same time separatist forces in Tibet have received
support from the United States.126
The fostering of conflicts, while aimed at debilitating the competitors,
also seeks to organize new economic benefijits by appropriating strate-
gic resources like oil,127 and creating highly profijitable business sectors
such as the drug trade.128 Chossudovksy explains that what he calls
“Washington’s hidden agenda,” which “consists in sustaining rather than
combating international terrorism, with a view to destabilizing national
societies and preventing the articulation of genuine secular social move-
ments directed against the American Empire… Washington continues to
support—through CIA covert operations—the development of Islamic
fundamentalism, throughout the Middle East, in the former Soviet Union
as well in China and India… Throughout the developing world, the growth
of sectarian, fundamentalist and other such organizations tends to serve
U.S. interests. These various organizations and armed insurgents have
been developed, particularly in countries where state institutions have
collapsed under the brunt of the IMF-sponsored economic reforms”
(Chossudovsky, 2008a).
126 In the case of China, “Washington is attempting to trigger a broader process of politi-
cal destabilization and fracturing of the People’s Republic of China. In addition to these
various covert operations, the U.S. has established military bases in Afghanistan and in
several of the former Soviet republics, directly on China’s Western border” (Chossudovsky,
2008a).
127 “Russia’s main pipeline route transits through Chechnya and Dagestan. Despite
Washington’s condemnation of ‘Islamic terrorism’, the indirect benefijiciaries of the wars in
Chechnya are the Anglo-American oil conglomerates which are vying for complete control
over oil resources and pipeline corridors out of the Caspian Sea basin” (Chossudovsky,
2008a).
128 Afghanistan “is a strategic hub in Central Asia… it is also strategic for its opium pro-
duction, which today, according to UN sources, supplies more than 90% of the world’s
heroin market, representing multi-billion dollar revenues for business syndicates, fijinancial
institutions, intelligence agencies and organized crime… Protected by the CIA, a new surge
in opium production unfolded in the post-Cold War era. Since the October 2001 US inva-
sion of Afghanistan, opium production has increased 33 fold… The Golden Crescent drug
trade was also being used to fijinance and equip the Bosnian Muslim Army (starting in the
early 1990s) and the Kosovo Liberation Army (KLA)… Albania and Kosovo lie at the heart
of the ‘Balkan Route’ that links the ‘Golden Crescent’ of Afghanistan and Pakistan to the
drug markets of Europe” (Chossudovsky, 2008a).
ideological domination 291
It is also important to note that the need for murder entailed in the gesta-
tion of the last man defijines the prospects for the future and the plans of
the personifijications of neoliberal capital in several senses:
First, as an extension of the “global war on terrorism” declared by the
United States; Chossudovksy explains that, according to U.S. military doc-
trine, “[a] terrorist attack on American soil of the size and nature of
September 11, would lead – according to former US Central Command
(USCENTCOM) Commander, General Tommy Franks, who led the inva-
sion of Iraq in 2003 – to the demise of Constitutional government.” Such
an event “would be used to galvanize U.S. public opinion in support of a
military government and police state. The resulting crisis, the social tur-
moil and public indignation would facilitate a major shift in US political,
social and institutional structures” (Chossudovsky, 2008a). Thus we fijind
that, while “supporting international terrorism,”129 U.S. government agen-
cies (according to the logic of the shock doctrine) are preparing their
preemptive plan for a terrorist attack: “General Franks was not giving
a personal opinion on this issue. His statement is consistent with the
dominant viewpoint both in the Pentagon and the Homeland Security
Department as to how events might unfold in the case of a national
emergency… The ‘massive casualty producing event’ is an integral part of
military doctrine” which is used to “create conditions of collective fear
and intimidation, which facilitate the derogation of civil liberties and
the introduction of police state measures” and allow the government to
“to galvanize public opinion in support of a global military agenda”
(Chossudovsky, 2008a).130
Second, as an extension of the notion of the “enemy” being anyone who
gets in the way: Chossudovksy explains that in March 2005, the Pentagon
released the summary of a document that outlines the U.S. government’s
agenda for global military domination, which “calls for a more ‘proactive’
approach to warfare, beyond the weaker notion of ‘preemptive’ and
defensive actions, where military operations are launched against a
129 And this is true, according to Chossudovsky, both before and after September 11: “the
‘Islamic terror network’ is a creation of the U.S. intelligence apparatus… There is ample
evidence that Al Qaeda remains a U.S. sponsored intelligence asset… [which] remains
fijirmly under the control of the U.S. intelligence apparatus” (Chossudovsky, 2008a).
130 In another article, Chossudovsky quotes David Rockefeller: “We are on the verge of
global transformation. All we need is the right major crisis and the nations will accept the
New World Order” (Chossudovsky, 2007a).
292 chapter nine
all with the exclusive aim of safeguarding the assets and increasing the
power of the richest people on the planet” (Dufour, 2009, emphasis added).
There is no doubt that (as Dufour points out) investments in education,
health and environmental conservation and recovery would be much
more profijitable and benefijicial for all, but this is not in the script of neolib-
eral capital, which is becoming increasingly necrophiliac and genocidal as
complements to its unbridled globalphilia. The UN millennium develop-
ment goals are not the goals of neoliberal capital.
Of course, this vocation for war and death, which goes hand in hand with
its voracious desire to concentrate control of the means of production and
subsistence, has never been foreign to the spirit of capitalism,132 but what
is signifijicant is the qualitative diffference between the development of this
general tendency of capital throughout its previous history and its current
level. This diffference does not consist in the current personifijications of
capital having a greater inclination toward killing to pursue their interests
than their predecessors had, but in the level of development of science
and technology and their use in the pursuit of the interests of capital.
To illustrate this point, it will be sufffijicient to cite a few brief examples
related to global warming, worldwide pollution, and the proposition of
geoengineering, i.e. technologies for restructuring the stratosphere and/or
the oceans, as a solution: “the manipulation of the planet as a whole, or of
large slabs of the planet or whole ecosystems in order to, theoretically,
slow down climate change” (Ribeiro, 2009a). The reports of the ETC Group
assert that geoengineering uses additional technology to counteract col-
lateral damage without eliminating the problem that causes it; its applica-
tion ensures that the industry will continue to pollute the planet and
makes the problem more complex by contributing massively to particle
pollution (ETC Group, 2007). According to the research, “all these projects
entail a hazard to the natural balance of ecosystems and further upset the
climate” (Ribeiro, 2009a) as they involve “experiments that tinker with the
132 Including during its golden era, the post-war boom: “What is referred euphemisti-
cally as the ‘post war era’ is in fact a period of continuous war and militarization. Since the
end of the Second World War, this ‘long war’ seeks to establish US hegemony worldwide…
This entire ‘post war period’ [1945 up to the present] is marked by extensive war crimes
resulting in the death of more than ten million people… This fijigure does not include those
who perished as a result of poverty, starvation and disease” (Chossudovsky, 2007a).
294 chapter nine
planet’s complex climate system” (ETC Group, 2010). Put simply, “its ben-
efijits are speculative and its risks are planetary… geoengineering is deadly
serious” (ETC Group, 2009, emphasis added).
Nevertheless, it is the solution preferred by the United States, which
didn’t care for the “focus on the negative efffects” of a report drafted by
the International Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), or for its “rejection
of voluntary agreements,” and pushed for “techno-fijix strategies to be
given a prominent place in the fijinal report’s recommendations” (ETC
Group, 2007). The reason for this, according to the ETC Group, is that the
large-scale nature of all geoengineering technologies means they are
highly centralized, and have commercial applications as well as a
strong potential for military application (ETC Group, 2009). In business
terms this technology is “incredibly lucrative,” so much so that “it’s
really more of a business experiment than a scientifijic experiment” (ETC
Group, 2007).
It is worth digressing briefly here to consider further the potential mili-
tary uses of this technology. The ETC Group explains that the potential
for using environmental modifijication technologies as a weapon against
other nations makes weather control “fascinating” to many of the
world’s military powers: “A US Air Force report entitled ‘Weather as a
Force Multiplier: Owning the Weather in 2025’ concluded that the weather
‘can provide battlespace dominance to a degree never before imagined,’
including the ability to thwart an enemy’s operations by enhancing
a storm or by inducing drought and making fresh water scarce” (ETC
Group, 2007).
According to Chossudovsky, “the US military has developed advanced
capabilities that enable it selectively to alter weather patterns. The tech-
nology, which is being perfected under the High-frequency Active Auroral
Research Program (HAARP), is an appendage of the Strategic Defense
Initiative – ‘Star Wars’. From a military standpoint, HAARP is a weapon of
mass destruction, operating from the outer atmosphere and capable of
destabilizing agricultural and ecological systems around the world…
Weather-modifijication, according to the US Air Force document AF 2025
Final Report, ‘offfers the war fijighter a wide range of possible options to
defeat or coerce an adversary’, capabilities, it says, [which] extend to the
triggering of floods, hurricanes, droughts and earthquakes: Weather modi-
fijication will become a part of domestic and international security and
could be done unilaterally… It could have offfensive and defensive applica-
tions and even be used for deterrence purposes. The ability to generate
precipitation, fog and storms on earth or to modify space weather… and
ideological domination 295
133 Clearly, U.S. oligarchs have not forgotten that, at least at one point during the
Vietnam War, “their” youth refused to go and kill and die for them, and they have been
implementing a range of schemes (which are not explored here) to ensure that it doesn’t
happen again.
296 chapter nine
than clear: risks, appropriately taken, are opportunities. “It is not a ques-
tion of identifying the causes of the problems in order to resolve them, but
to make use of the crises and the disasters as new sources of business, even
when the proposed ‘solutions’ pose even greater threats to the environ-
ment, ecosystems, health and life” (Ribeiro, 2009a).
For example, by combining geoengineering with genetic engineering,
an environmental crisis transformed into a food crisis could result in a
need to abandon all precautions and allow the proliferation of genetically
enhanced crops. “Claiming concern about contamination, companies will
insist on using ‘Terminator’ (sterile seed) technology. Global food security
will depend on a handful of agribusinesses” (ETC Group, 2007: 2).134
Promoting transgenics means handing food sovereignty over to a handful
of transnationals, as all GM products are patented and owned by six com-
panies: “to hand over seed sovereignty is to give these companies the key
to the entire food chain” (Ribeiro, 2009a). This would be a way of consoli-
dating the excessive power that transnationals have acquired in this sector
in recent decades: “they have increasing power to decide what is planted,
what we eat, what quality (or lack thereof) it will have, etc. Transgenic
crops are the greatest expression of this corporate control; all are patented
and inevitably contaminate other crops – which turns into a crime for the
victims, because they are accused of ‘unauthorized use’ of their patented
genes” (Ribeiro 2009a).135
In light of the above, we shouldn’t be surprised by the fijierceness with
which Monsanto attacks farmers around the world – including those of
the United States – to keep them “and everyone else from having any
access at all to buying, collecting, and saving of normal seeds” (Cohen-
Cole, 2009), or that “there is a large group of conservative think tanks with
strong links to big oil that have abandoned the old tactic of denying cli-
mate change and joined the chorus in favor of a techno-fijix… At any point
the climate engineers feel they’ve got a geoengineering scheme ready
to audition on the world stage, they’ve got ample data showing that the
climate emergency is already underway” (ETC Group, 2009).
134 Of course, “the world’s 1.4 billion people who depend on farmer-saved seed – most
of whom farm on marginal lands – will be left to fend for themselves,” (ETC Group, 2007: 2),
but this is insignifijicant “collateral damage.”
135 ”All agribusinesses… have enjoyed extremely high profijits since the food crisis was
announced in 2007, much higher than in previous years… The same companies that cre-
ated and benefijit from this debacle, which now with the food crisis have immorally
increased their profijits, promise us more of the same, or worse: further expansion of indus-
trial, transgenic, polluting agriculture, to continue raking in profijits… They are veritable
vultures of hunger” (Ribeiro, 2009a).
ideological domination 297
136 “Unlike transgenics, which take genes from existing organisms and insert them into
other existing organisms, synthetic biology aims at creating artifijicial genes and living
organisms, wholly created in a laboratory” (Ribeiro, 2009a).
298 chapter nine
governments need to tell the big transnationals that they do not have the
right to redesign the planet, but instead of doing so, they have “opted for
an ‘inverted’ principle of caution: as long as there are enormous scientifijic
uncertainties and a lack of public awareness, nothing should prevent cor-
porations from continuing to use everyone as their guinea pigs” (Ribeiro,
2009a, emphasis added). This means that “the scientifijic debate and the
government/commercial experimentation is taking place, once again, in
the absence of public discussion” (ETC Group, 2007: 1), while big corpora-
tions engage in “dangerous planet-tinkering schemes with minimal trans-
parency and even less public participation” (ETC Group, 2009: 1). As Silvia
Ribeiro points out, “there are no regulations applicable to nanotechnology
anywhere in the world, and governments continue to allow it to be mar-
keted ‘in the meantime’” (Ribeiro, 2009a).138
Worse still, capitalist governments, plagued by mutual distrust (as no
government believes that international negotiations will be able to halt
climate change) and trapped in a competitive dynamic, are part of the
problem rather than the solution: “one of the most dangerous aspects of
geoengineering is that it could be unilaterally deployed. A single country,
corporation or individual, or some coalition of the willing convened by
those who possess the technology, could conceivably attempt to geoengi-
neer the planet… It’s not hard to imagine diffferent countries wanting to
control the climate’s thermostat in conflicting ways. Multilateralism is the
only option here” (ETC Group, 2009: 6).
As for the second point (capital’s increasingly voracious push for
privatization), public resources continue to be sold offf regardless of how
hazardous this may be to the general conditions of human life.
Chossudovsky, for example, examines the effforts to privatize food, water
and fuel corporations: “These three essential goods or commodities, which
in a real sense determine the reproduction of economic and social life on
planet Earth, are under the control of a small number of global corpora-
tions and fijinancial institutions… The fate of millions of human beings is
138 This is why the recommendations of the ETC Group are so important: “There is an
urgent need to engage all sectors of society in a comprehensive debate about the future
that is being planned for them. The sweeping economic, social and political issues raised
by converging technologies range far beyond the boundaries of any single country and
must be debated worldwide through the United Nations. The international community
must have the capacity to monitor and regulate the public and private governance [i.e. to
control governments and participate in key decisions] as well as control and ownership of
technologies… Beyond governance, the international community must create the capacity
to track, evaluate and accept or reject new technologies and their products through an
International Convention on the Evaluation of New Technologies” (ETC Group, 2003: 6).
300 chapter nine
139 The report adds that “almost as soon as scientists fijigured out how to manipulate life
through genetic engineering, corporations fijigured out how to monopolize it” (ETC Group,
2005a: 6).
ideological domination 301
140 According to an advertising portal on the Internet, “cans of oxygen are sold in many
stores in Japan. Each can costs 600 yen. There are various flavors in case you get bored
with the taste of ‘regular oxygen’, and they come with a comfortable adapter to enable to
absorption without a problem. The business of the future!” “They shudder,” remarked
an anonymous source, “because our great grandparents say they never paid a single penny
for water…” (García, 2006). A search confijirms that this is now an emerging market with a
lot of potential in Latin America. “The experts at the service of the transnationals have
demonstrated an unlimited capacity for invention to better serve their employers. For
them, nothing is impossible, absurd, or immoral. Among their most recent achievements
is their success in putting nature itself on sale, disguised as so-called ‘environmental
services’. Expressions such as ‘oxygen sales’ and ‘carbon sink sales’ are now common cur-
rency, particularly in the countries of the South” (Movimiento Mundial por los Bosques
Tropicales, 2006).
302 chapter nine
141 Klare quotes here from a 2003 Pentagon Report “An Abrupt Climate Change Scenario
and Its Implications for United States National Security.” The full text of this report is avail-
able at: http://www.climate.org/PDF/clim_change_scenario.pdf
ideological domination 303
Capital’s Rights
In short, neoliberal capital has decided that it has rights of ownership over
life and death all over the planet. The project for the future which neolib-
eralism (i.e. capitalism in its gestation of the last man of the end of his-
tory) offfers humanity is expressed in widespread necrophilia and war as
its increasingly dominant form (war on what it identifijies as organized
crime or international terrorism, war for natural resources, etc.) because it
seeks not to solve the problems it creates, but to turn them into opportuni-
ties for profijit and the deployment of force.
Its mission and vision require a radical and increasing abandonment of
any commitment to life on the planet: it is dismantling the framework
constructed during the Keynesian period to attend to the most basic
needs of society, destroying the environment and privatizing nature. Its
intellectual and moral leadership consists in submerging humanity in
savagery, leading it into all kinds of sterile wars in order to keep it at the
service of the perverse and criminal logic of the fetish and its insane
personifijications.
But this insanity is anchored in a reality. Underlying the situation is a
crisis in the capital/wage-labor relation, a single crisis disguised as multi-
ple crises (health, economic and fijinancial, overproduction, realization,
underproduction, food, climate, environmental, etc.). The march toward
Absolute Monopoly is transforming the relation among capitalists them-
selves and between capitalists and the working class – it is the march
toward the Last Man. But it also confijirms that society has reached the end
of capitalism itself, its period of decline, as will be argued in the following
chapter. And here we fijind a great paradox: the conditions that indicate
that we have reached the end of the capitalist relation are defijined by capi-
tal as the end of life itself and, in an attempt to prolong its own life at the
142 And, as if that weren’t enough, the Pentagon report predicts: “In this world of war-
ring States… nuclear arms proliferation is inevitable” (as quoted in Klare, 2006).
304 chapter nine
143 A few decades ago, Spanish fijilmmaker Luis Buñuel found the bourgeoisie to possess
a discreet charm: cynical, perverse, drug-addicted, drug-dealing and criminal… Clearly,
their discretion has diminished and their charm has been somewhat refijined.
PART THREE
CONCLUSION
CHAPTER TEN
Although the main purpose of this work has been to elaborate a theoreti-
cal framework for the examination of the forms of capitalist domination
and an introduction to their historical analysis, with a special focus on the
neoliberal form of domination, it is fijitting to conclude by presenting a
note (as I proposed in the third chapter) on the relation between the his-
torical succession of patterns of domination and the long-term trends
they produce in the life cycle of capitalism.
To this end and remaining always at the level of abstraction on which
this work has been developed, as an intermediate theoretical fijield between
general theory – the analysis of the forces that generate, develop and pro-
duce the disintegration of capitalism – and its specifijic manifestations in
history, I will turn my attention again to the relation between capital and
wage-labor, the essential relation under capitalism, which has served as
the basis for everything discussed so far; the theoretical space that allows
us to link the pattern of domination to the long-term history of capitalism
derives from the capital relation.
In the fijirst chapter, I explained that the essential relation under capital-
ism, the underlying social relation of its social classes, consists in the
308 chapter ten
The development of the relation between capital and wage-labor, and the
development of the capital relation itself, depends on the development of
the productive force of labor. In Chapter 2, I noted that in Capital, Marx
demonstrates that the capital relation articulates tendencies of develop-
ment, general trends that organize the future of capitalist society: an
increase in the productivity of labor and an increase in the organic com-
position of capital; expulsion of the work force from the labor process,
expansion of the industrial reserve army and the creation of an absolute
surplus population; and concentration and centralization of capital.
Moreover, Marx shows how these tendencies are expressed in downward
pressure on the rate of profijit and that the same tendencies that provoke
the reduction of the rate of profijit generate counter-tendencies that slow
down the development of the tendency to its fullest, with a constant
reduction of capital and an increase in its technical composition that is
more intense than the increase in its value composition. Capital’s search
for counter-tendencies to prevent the drop in the rate of profijit includes a
wide range of possibilities, the examination of which reveals the particu-
lar features of each historical period, but the basic counter-tendency
sought, which ultimately supports all others, is to increase the rate of sur-
plus-value. These counter-tendencies, it should be noted, slow down but
do not stop the main tendency.
Capitalist development, the development of the capital relation, is thus
necessarily the development of the productive force of labor. Marx con-
structs the concept of the organic composition of capital and its tendency
toward growth as a synthetic expression of this process. From this per-
spective, the tendencies toward reduction of the rate of profijit and expul-
sion of the work force from the labor process become clearly visible. As
I had further pointed out in the second chapter, the development of the
capital/wage-labor relation can be investigated on diffferent analytical lev-
els, constructed on the basis of the examination of the development of its
tendencies over time; that is, the examination of the historical process of
capitalism and its articulation in the short, medium and long term.
I argued that it is necessary to begin with the most direct and immediate
features of the capital relation in the consciousness and the practice of
capitalists in order to identify the general forms of capitalist domination;
the forms which, in their specifijic historical manifestations, appear as
310 chapter ten
The general features of the medium term in the history of capitalism – and
the corresponding periodization – were also explained in the second
chapter. The historical development of capitalism appears as a series of
phases of economic expansion, the fundamental condition for which is
the existence of a historical set of economic, political and ideological cir-
cumstances that ensure a rate of profijit satisfactory for capital, and phases
of depression that express the exhaustion of the conditions that ensured
an increased rate of profijit during the period of expansion that preceded it
and the search for new counter-tendencies.
If we compare the periodization of the medium term in the history of
capitalism with what I proposed as the period of prevalence of each pat-
tern of domination, we will fijind that the liberal pattern covers the fijirst
three expansive periods (1770–1830, 1850–1873 and 1896–1914) followed
by two corresponding periods of depression (1830–1850 and 1873–1896)
and the decisive shift to the Keynesian pattern did not occur until the mid-
dle of the third period of depression from 1914 to 1945 (with the stimulus
of the crisis of 1929), although in Western Europe this shift had been devel-
oping since the second period of depression (1873–1896).
On the other hand, the Keynesian pattern, at least as a relatively general
form of capitalist domination, had a much shorter life, which, in the strict-
est sense, not including its prolonged and turbulent process of transition,
is limited to the period of expansion after World War II (1945–1967); with
the onset of the subsequent period of depression (from 1967 onward), the
shift began toward the currently prevailing neoliberal pattern.
It is worth reiterating here that between one stage and another in the
medium term there is a basic continuity in terms of the tendential laws of
capitalist development; each stage begins with the levels of labor produc-
tivity, organic composition and concentration of capital with which the
previous stage ended. The return to a phase of expansion after one of
depression is not circular but might better be described as a spiral: the
the pattern of domination and historical cycle 311
long term, the full historical duration of the capitalist mode of production,
develops over the course of the stages that make up its medium term. Thus
the analysis of the medium term offfers explanatory dimensions and pre-
cise historical meanings when placed in relation to the long term.
The long term of capitalism covers the period from its birth as a social
model for organizing production until its death. From the perspective of
this analysis there are only three periods to consider: infancy, maturity
and decline. And the delimitation of each of these periods should be
drawn from the decisive moments in the productive force of labor, i.e.
decisive moments in the development of the capital relation.
In the infancy of capitalism, formal subsumption and absolute surplus
value prevailed; the fijirst industrial revolution had just begun to make its
efffects felt in some countries and certain sectors, and ownership of capi-
tal, i.e. of the means of production and subsistence of the workers, was
spread out among many capitalists. The move toward its maturity began at
the end of the 19th century in Western Europe, culminating in the techno-
logical transformations fostered by Fordism. Real subsumption and rela-
tive surplus value dominated the scene; science became the decisive
productive force with the establishment of what Figueroa calls the work-
shop of technological progress, and general labor and immediate labor
were separated. The dispersed nature of the ownership of capital that
typifijied the previous period was transformed and replaced by a clear ten-
dency toward concentration and centralization, although the separation
between producers and the means of production and subsistence assumed
a wide variety of forms, from extreme nationalization of capital in real
socialism to a combination of state and private monopoly capital in the
rest of the world, with priority given to private monopolies in the devel-
oped nations and state capital in the underdeveloped world.
The decline of capitalism (which will be examined below) corresponds
to the current period, with its technological revolution and its extreme
concentration of capital in the hands of a handful of gigantic transna-
tional monopolies. A correspondence can thus be identifijied between the
long-term periods of the history of capitalism and the historical sequence
of patterns of domination.
The fijirst pattern of domination was the liberal pattern (the fijirst histori-
cal expression of the natural form of domination), which represented
the infancy of capitalism, characterized by the powerlessness of workers
faced with a capital that had yet to fully stabilize the forms of extraction
of relative surplus value and that unleashed its voracious appetite for
growth.
312 chapter ten
The second pattern of domination was the Keynesian pattern (the fijirst
and only historical expression of the contained form of domination),
which represented capitalism in maturity; a rise in productivity derived
from advances in scientifijic research and their conversion into technology
coupled with the developments of Fordism and Taylorism, under condi-
tions of a certain degree of development of the organic composition of
capital, allowed for the construction of a delicate balance that permitted
the granting of concessions to workers together with increases in the rate
of profijit.1
The neoliberal pattern of domination, the second historical expression
of the natural form of domination, represents the decline of capitalism.
I will not go any further here to argue for the correspondence between
historical periods and the liberal and Keynesian patterns. However, still
without leaving the level of abstraction on which this work is developed, it
is necessary to further explain the argument for the relationship between
the decline of capitalism and the neoliberal pattern, beginning on the logi-
cal plane and concluding on the historical plane.
1 In the second chapter, I indicated that the crucial condition for the consolidation of
the contained form of domination was that it was supported by advances in labor produc-
tivity, i.e. with the relevant mediation, by advances in the rate of exploitation and the rate
of profijit. If capital cannot fijind a form of compensation, it will maintain constant and inces-
sant opposition to any limitation upon “freedom” and “free enterprise” and will defend its
unrestricted right to exploit labor.
2 This is of course the explicit proposition that Marx sets forth in what he calls his “guid-
ing principle” (see Marx, 1859: Preface).
the pattern of domination and historical cycle 313
The fijirst of these two directions is associated with what might be called
the social limit of capitalism – the limit imposed on capital by the working
class – and this limit in turn has a relative and an absolute dimension. The
relative social limit of capitalism is the efffect of the working class struggle
and operates in direct relation with the efffectiveness of workers in oppos-
ing and destroying the domination of capital. The absolute social limit lies
in the growing inability of the bourgeoisie to ensure the reproduction of
life of its slaves: “in order to oppress a class, certain conditions must be
assured to it under which it can, at least, continue its slavish existence…
the bourgeoisie is unfijit any longer to be the ruling class in society… It is
unfijit to rule because it is incompetent to assure an existence to its slave
within his slavery… Society can no longer live under this bourgeoisie, in
other words, its existence is no longer compatible with society” (Marx and
Engels, 1848: I). The absolute social limit is reached when the relative
social limit proves incapable of converting the decline of capitalism into
the transition to socialism. In this case, the bourgeoisie “cannot help let-
ting [its slave] sink into such a state, that it has to feed him, instead of
being fed by him” (Marx and Engels, 1848: I) and/or leave an increasing
percentage of the excess slaves to die or simply kill them offf.
It would not be possible to overstate the current dimensions or the
worsening trends of the diverse phenomena characteristic of the period:
unemployment, the billions of people lacking the most basic elements of
life, the famines affflicting growing masses of people, the huge dimensions
of the migratory movements of human beings who wander the world in a
desperate search for a place to survive, along with the increasing necro-
philia of the neoliberal bourgeoisie. As Joachim Hirsh notes:
“Viewed globally, ever greater numbers of human beings are no longer useful
to capital, even as objects of exploitation, and are left to their fate by govern-
ments and, in the worst cases, are treated only as objects to be monitored,
controlled and attacked with counter-insurgency strategies involving police
intervention… The fact that an increasing number of human beings are mar-
ginalized and excluded from the formal context of appreciation at the same
time means a new context of socio-political crisis: the less assured the rela-
tion between capital, labor and sustenance is, the more superfluous capital
becomes” (Hirsch, 2000).
And according to Samir Amin:
“The new organization of labor (the so-called ‘network society’) entails a
dramatic reduction in total labor, made possible thanks to the use of new
technologies or, to put it another way, to their increased productivity. But
in the actual operation of the system this economy of the labor factor is
accompanied, through exclusion, by a brutal reduction in the number of
workers used by capital… The theory of the supporters of capitalism is that
those excluded today could be working tomorrow, thanks to the expansion
318 chapter ten
4 According to Katz, the declining trend in the rate of profijit is a necessary process that
is not a contingent occurrence or a passing phase, but an internal result of the process of
accumulation, whose evolution responds to a predictable pattern of development (Katz,
2002).
the pattern of domination and historical cycle 319
5 “All these contradictions, which have acquired explosive characteristics, are a mea-
surement of the capitalist impasse. The excess of unsaleable products that flood the mar-
kets, whatever the sector or activity considered, and of surplus capital unable to fijind
profijitable employment, is an indicator of the current relevance of the law formulated by
Marx that makes his work truly exploratory, in spite of what his detractors may say” (Heller,
2003).
320 chapter ten
debt management practices” (Harvey, 2004: 70).7 Harvey argues that these
raids form part of the strategy of accumulation by dispossession, “a ‘vul-
ture capitalism’ dedicated to the appropriation and devaluation of assets,
rather than to building them up through productive investments” (Harvey,
2004: 72), which is characterized by violence, swindling, oppression, pil-
laging and fraud. He adds that “wholly new mechanisms of accumulation
by dispossession have also opened up,” among which he notes biopiracy
and the pillaging of the world’s stockpile of genetic resources by a few
large multinational companies, the depletion of the global environmental
commons (land, air, water) and the proliferation of environmental degra-
dation, the privatization of water and other public services (constituting a
new wave of “enclosing the commons”), and the reversion to the private
domain of common property rights won through past class struggles (the
right to a state pension, to welfare, to education or to national health care)
(Harvey, 2004: 75).
As far as unlawful forms of accumulation are concerned, the excellent
business represented by diverse modes of “organized crime” has already
been explored. Jorge Beinstein suggests that the rise of “gangster capital-
ism” needs to be viewed in connection with widespread deregulation and
the complicity of the state in forms of accumulation that encourage social
pillaging in its broadest sense: “we could identify a kind of ‘logical
sequence’ based on the diversion of funds originating in the productive
sector (with decreasing profijitability) towards ‘classical’ fijinancial opera-
tions (purchase of public deeds, shares, etc.) and from there (once these
operations were saturated) towards new, increasingly fast and complex
forms of speculation (‘derivative’ products, etc.), ultimately leading to ille-
gal businesses, plundering, etc. (from dismantling public companies in the
periphery to drug trafffijicking)” (Beinstein, 2000).
7 Harvey suggests that the structured destruction of assets by means of inflation, the
promotion of indebtedness levels which even in the advanced capitalist countries reduce
whole populations to servitude through debt, corporate fraud and dispossession of assets
like pension funds constitute “central features of what contemporary capitalism is about”
(Harvey, 2004: 75). But above all, he says, “we have to look at the speculative raiding carried
out by hedge funds and other major institutions of fijinance capital as the cutting edge of
accumulation by dispossession in recent times.” He illustrates this point with the case of
Southeast Asia: “by creating a liquidity crisis throughout Southeast Asia, the hedge funds
forced profijitable businesses into bankruptcy. These businesses could be purchased at fijire-
sale prices by surplus capitals in the core countries, thus engineering what Wade and
Veneroso refer to as ‘the biggest peacetime transfer of assets from domestic (i.e. Southeast
Asian) to foreign (i.e. U.S. and Japanese) owners in the past few years anywhere in the
world’” (Harvey, 2004: 75).
322 chapter ten
From the above we may conclude that the absolute priority of neoliberal-
ism has been to ensure that, even in the midst of economic stagnation,
transnational capital thrives8, regardless of the social consequences that
such a priority entails. All these barbaric forms of accumulation to which
neoliberal capital resorts to compensate for the drop in the rate of profijit
increase the damage to the lives and wellbeing of virtually every sector of
the people dispossessed of the means of production and subsistence.
But as long as these forms aid accumulation, capital will continue to
use them, will intensify them if it can9 and will have no qualms about
resorting to other even more barbarous measures. In the decline of capi-
talism, a perverse logic is taking root: the harder it becomes to maintain
capital accumulation, the more brutal its compensatory strategies become,
and the more destructive these strategies are, the more problematic a
reasonably sustainable accumulation becomes. István Mészáros describes
it as a “structural crisis of the system,” which is spreading everywhere,
undermining the basic conditions for the survival of the human species
(Mészáros, 2010).10
However, the move toward what I have called the absolute social limit
of capitalism by leaving a growing number of its slaves to die, fostering
homicide among them and/or killing them is not something that will
cause much concern for a genocidal capital, in the embryonic phase of
Absolute Monopoly, which is preoccupied only with effforts to raise the
relative social limit. Although I have systematically excluded an analysis of
the inter-imperialist contradictions from this reflection in order to con-
centrate on the analysis of the capital-labor relation, it is essential to bear
in mind that “a distribution of global income in decline only aggravates
the global recession… With a low rate of profijit in the sphere of production,
capital does not seek to accumulate through economic growth but through
8 “We have therefore witnessed for the last dozen years or so the extraordinary specta-
cle of a world economy in which the continuation of capital accumulation has come liter-
ally to depend upon historic waves of speculation, carefully nurtured and rationalized by
state policy makers” (Brenner, 2009b).
9 “In the absence of any strong revival of sustained accumulation through expanded
reproduction, this will entail a deepening politics of accumulation by dispossession
throughout the world in order to keep the motor of accumulation from stalling entirely”
(Harvey, 2004: 81).
10 “The enormous expansion of fijinancial adventurism… is by its nature inseparable
from the deepening of the crisis in the productive branches of industry as well as from the
ensuing troubles arising from the utterly sluggish capital accumulation” (Mészáros, 2010).
the pattern of domination and historical cycle 323
11 “The medium term strategic objective is to target Iran and neutralize Iran’s allies,
through gunboat diplomacy. The longer term military objective is to directly target China
and Russia” (Chossudovsky, 2010).
324 chapter ten
12 “The basic contradiction in the existing rationale is that capitalism has reached the
historic moment where it is impossible to return to linking investment with production in
a profijitable way. A greater development of productive forces, in other words, is no longer
possible under the existing economic rationale and social relations. This contradiction will
become visible in the thwarted attempts to solve it” (Dierckxsens, 2002).
13 “The weapons already available for waging the war or wars of the twenty-fijirst century
are capable of exterminating not only the adversary but the whole of humanity, for the fijirst
time ever in history. Nor should we have the illusion that the existing weaponry marks the
very end of the road. Others, even more instantly lethal ones, might appear tomorrow or
the day after tomorrow” (Mészáros, 2003).
the pattern of domination and historical cycle 325
It is worth reiterating here that the period of decline does not represent
the sudden collapse of capitalism, but a course toward its end. The neolib-
eral form of organizing the capital-labor relation admits variants, and in
capitalism today a signifijicant section of humankind still fijinds a place
within the social relations organized by capital. It is what we might call a
“flexible” domination; in contrast to previous periods, with a basically
homogeneous design in class relations, capital now fosters competitive-
ness and criminal activity and “flexibilizes” its design according to its eco-
nomic and political needs and strategies.
Some workers, particularly illegal immigrants, are radically deprived of
any kind of rights (labor, social or political), while labor and wage conces-
sions are granted to a constantly shrinking segment of highly qualifijied
workers, and division and conflict within the working class is fostered to
the extreme of assigning certain segments the explicit task of exterminat-
ing others by cultivating racism, xenophobia and the whole framework of
the state administration of criminal activity. Within the general design to
disable nation-states as spaces for the regulation of class relations, vari-
ants are also admitted; the most radical diffferences are found between
developed and developing nations, although even in the latter case the
so-called “transition to democracy” allows for political tinkering and
diverse margins of negotiation between diffferent national and class
interests.
However, from the perspective of the long-term trends and the current
historical period of capital, the world of the worker surplus population,
the waves of illegal migration, the underworld of criminal activity and its
professional sector (torturers, hired killers, human trafffijickers, etc.) and the
assault on the living conditions of the whole class dispossessed of the
326 chapter ten
means of production and subsistence, must all inevitably grow: “The anxi-
ety shared by the vast masses in virtually every part of the world arises
from the discovery made by the working class, the youth and the oppressed
masses of the rapid degradation of the conditions of their existence: a
return to or continued unemployment, the precarious nature of their
basic living conditions, destruction of social welfare, a return to hunger or,
even where hunger is absent, a return to both individual and social decay,
and the arrogance of the property owner classes and of a society that once
again shamelessly exposes the wealth of the few before the eyes of the
many who have none” (Chesnais, 1996).14
Such is the logical result of the renewed eagerness of capital to increase
the rate of surplus-value – in the current combinations of dealings with
workers, capital embraces any means of producing surplus-value, whether
relative or absolute15 – and to concentrate its production and appropria-
tion in the hands of a few huge and insatiable monopolies that dominate
production and the global market. Under these conditions, the develop-
ment of the period of decline must be marked by a growing rebellion of
those dispossessed of their means of production and subsistence, and by
the increasing fragility of the hegemony of capital: “what is new in this
phase of globalization directed by fijinancial capital is the appearance,
among vast sectors of the world’s population, of cracks in the domination,
in the absorption by the dominated classes of capitalist ideas and values
and in the fatalistic notion that there is no alternative to neoliberal poli-
tics since it is the only possible option” (Almeyra, 2007).
14 According to Raúl Zibechi, “a UN study estimates that 1 billion people live in periph-
eral slum districts of third-world cities, and that the poor in the world’s big cities have hit
two billion, one third of humankind. These fijigures will double in the next 15 to 20 years, as
the growth of the world’s population will occur entirely in the cities and 95% will be seen
in the suburbs of the cities of the South” (Zibechi, 2008).
15 “This consists in the bloodthirstiness with which employers oppose the reduction of
working hours and seek to dismantle the legal frameworks of labor: employers want to
overturn what for them represent hindrances to the appropriation of absolute surplus-
value” (Chesnais, 1997).
the pattern of domination and historical cycle 327
create more favorable ground for the dissemination of certain ways of think-
ing, of proposing and resolving the questions that inform all subsequent gov-
ernment activity… By defijinition, it is a long process that should not be
confused with its episodic manifestations… The crisis consists precisely in
the death of the old and the birth of the new; on these grounds the most
diverse gruesome phenomena are tested” (Portantiero, 1981: 51, 52, empha-
sis added). The development of science at the service of capital, in its pro-
ductive, political and military applications, elaborated in what I have
called the production workshop of domination strategies, provides capital
with new mechanisms for domination and new motivations for competi-
tion and division of workers, hindering the construction of viable alterna-
tives to capital domination.16
It thus turns out that the very thing that makes the destruction of the
capital relation increasingly necessary also makes that destruction difffiji-
cult: advances in science and technology, being conditions for deepening
the exploitation process and enforcing its tendential laws, pushing capital
toward its end, are also advances in the domination of the capitalist class
over the working class. Capital can thus prolong its domination and, the
more its period of decline is prolonged, the more threatening its capacity
for brutality and genocide becomes.17
To turn into a revolution, it is necessary for rebellion to give rise to the
construction of a counterhegemonic project – with economic, political
and cultural dimensions – which can coordinate an efffort to distance the
working class from capital domination, challenge the appropriation of sci-
entifijic and technological developments and allow the creation of a united
political front with its own blueprint for the future that will lead to the
social appropriation of the material means of production and scientifijic
and technological knowledge to be used to meet the needs of humanity
and care for the environment.
16 “What continues to stabilize and ideologically legitimate it are not the promises,
exposed long ago in practice, of a better, more peaceful ‘world society’, but the difffijiculty
associated with developing specifijic socio-political alternatives under the changed condi-
tions of globalized capitalism, and in the face of the failure of traditional state-socialist and
social democratic concepts” (Hirsch, 2000).
17 Iraq, since the U.S. army invaded it to “bring democracy” in 2003, is a good example of
the capacity for brutality displayed by contemporary capitalism; more than a million
deaths (IraqSolidaridad, 2008), without the Christian rulers of the United States losing any
sleep or registering in their consciousness any recollection of the old Mosaic command-
ment “thou shalt not kill.” Dante could scarcely have imagined more faithful and diligent
servers of Satan, the symbolic construction of evil, than neoliberal capital and its current
personifijications.
328 chapter ten
18 “It is not the dominator who has the right to ‘judge’ the Other, his victim. It is the
consensual and critical community, through its presence and exposure of the side of the
victims, that has the duty to judge the despotic dominating power.” Dussel also reminds us
that “there can be no representation or consensus without ‘living citizens’, and in the post-
colonial peripheral world this is not by any means guaranteed” (Dussel, 2002).
19 “The bourgeoisie keeps more and more doing away with the scattered state of the
population, of the means of production, and of property. It has agglomerated population,
centralized the means of production, and has concentrated property in a few hands. The
necessary consequence of this was political centralization. Independent, or but loosely
connected provinces, with separate interests, laws, governments, and systems of taxation,
became lumped together into one nation, with one government, one code of laws, one
national class-interest, one frontier, and one customs-tarifff” (Marx and Engels, 1848: I).
the pattern of domination and historical cycle 329
20 For example, we have seen how big transnational capital imposes “free trade” on
developing countries, thereby destroying the local economy while at the same time pro-
moting the solution to the problem: more concessions to big capital in order to attract
investment. This is also the case of the so-called “transition to democracy” that serves to
increase subordination of politico-electoral concerns to the interests and needs of big
transnational capital: the precarious nature of the transition to democracy is resolved with
new reforms to further the “transition.” Economic problems are explained as due to a lack of
competitivity, and political problems as due to insufffijicient implementation of the transition
to democracy. An agenda is thus organized and imposed on society, whereby, viewed in
terms of class relations, big capital is situated on both extremes: it produces the problem
and offfers the solution. Other cases have also been examined, such as the migration of
undocumented workers, climate change, food production, etc.
21 “The political institutionalization of class commitments and the guarantee of demo-
cratic freedoms have historically been achieved in the context of the national state…
Political universalism requires a redefijinition that can establish a new version of the tradi-
tional meaning, which was coined in the nation-state context, of freedom, equality, democ-
racy and human rights… to move beyond the historic relation between nation-state and
citizenry” (Hirsch, 1996: 44, 49).
330 chapter ten
will make the transition to socialism, although the form and duration of
this transition is no minor matter. In the 19th century, Marx believed that,
if it could identify the law that governs its development, a society could
shorten and lessen the birth pangs thereof.24 Perhaps the 21st century will
justify this optimism, shortening the period of decline and lessening the
birth pangs of socialism.
24 “And even when a society has got upon the right track for the discovery of the natural
laws of its movement – and it is the ultimate aim of this work, to lay bare the economic law
of motion of modern society – it can neither clear by bold leaps, nor remove by legal enact-
ments, the obstacles offfered by the successive phases of its normal development. But it can
shorten and lessen the birth pangs” (Marx, 1867: Preface to the First German Edition).
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Abu-Tarbush, José. 2005. “Los ‘think tanks’: información, poder y opinión pública.” Disenso
47. <http://www.pensamientocritico.org/josabub1105.html>
AFP, 2005. “Bush autorizó en 2002 espiar a miles de estadunidenses, denuncia el NY Times.”
La Jornada, December 17. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2005/12/17/022n1mun.php>
Aizpeolea, L.R. 2010. “Los ‘sabios’ recuerdan a Zapatero que Europe debe mejora su
competitividad.” El País, January 6. <http://www.elpais.com/articulo/espana/sabios/
recuerdan/Zapatero/Europa/debe/mejorar/competitividad/elpepinac/20100106 el
pepinac_6/Tes>
Alandete, David. 2009. “La CIA se enreda en la Red.” El País, November 5. <http://www
.elpais.com/articulo/tecnologia/CIA/enreda/Red/elpeputec/20091105elpeputec_10/
Tes>
Almeyra, Guillermo. n.d. “La violencia y la mundialización.”Unpublished Manuscript.
Almeyra, Guillermo. 2003. Revolucion, emancipacion, sujeto revolucionario. Paper pre-
sented at First International Conference on the Work of Karl Marx and the Challenges
of the Twenty-First Century, Havana, May 5–8, 2003. <http://www.nodo50.org/
cubasigloXXI/congreso/almeyra_10abr03.pdf>
Almeyra, Guillermo. 2003a. “¿Dónde se refugia ahora la política?” La Jornada,
July 13.
Almeyra, Guillermo. 2004. Política, partidos y poder en la mundialización. Paper presented
at Second International Conference on the Work of Karl Marx and the Challenges of the
Twenty-First Century, Havana, May 4–8, 2004. <http://www.nodo50.org/cubasigloXXI/
congreso04/almeyra_180404.pdf>
Almeyra, Guillermo. 2005. “Mundializacion, neoliberalismo y unidad de los explotados.”
Diálogo Nacional Website. <http://www.dialogonacional.org.mx/pon42.html>
Almeyra, Guillermo. 2007. “America Latina: el comienzo de una nueva fase.” Cuadernos del
Sur 36.
Amin, Samir. 1975. “Una crisis estructural” in S. Amin et al. (comp.) La crisis del imperial-
ismo. Barcelona: Fontanella, pp. 11–46.
Amin, Samir. 2003a. “Estados Unidos: el control militar del planeta.” La Jornada, March 3.
<http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2003/mar03/030305/per-control.html>
Amin, Samir. 2003b. “La economía política del siglo XX.” Tareas 113: 5–22. <http://www
.salacela.net/images/tareas/7_a.pdf>
Amin, Samir. 2009. “El capitalisrmo senil.” La Historia del Día, November 14. <http://
lahistoriadeldia.wordpress.com/2009/11/14/samir-amin-el-capitalismo-senil-descargar
-documento-2/>
Amnesty International. 2007. Report 2007. London: Amnesty International. <http://archive
.amnesty.org/report2007/eng/Homepage.html>
Anderson, Perry. 2004. The Role of Ideas in the Construction of Alternatives. Los Angeles:
UCLA. <http://bibliotecavirtual.clacso.org.ar/ar/libros/hegeing/Anderson.pdf>
Antunes, Ricardo. 2001. ¿Adiós al trabajo? Sao Paolo: Cortez.
Arceo, Enrique. 2002. Hegemonía estadounidense, internacionalización fijinanciera y produc-
tiva, y nuevo pacto colonial. Buenos Aires: Ceceña. <http://168.96.200.17/ar/libros/
cecena/arceo.pdf>
Aruj, Roberto. 2000. “El posmodernismo como sustento ideológico fijilosófijico del neoliber-
alismo a fijines del siglo XX.” La Onda Revista Digital 16. <http://www.laondadigital
.com/laonda/laonda/Documentos/El%20posmodernismo%20como%20sustento%20
ideologico%20fijilosofijico%20del%20neoliberalismo%20a%20fijines%20del%20
siglo%20XX.htm>
336 bibliography
Astarita, Rolando. 1997. “Sobre las tendencias actuales del capitalismo.” Herramienta 5.
<http://www.herramienta.com.ar/varios/5/5-8-3.html>
Ateneu Llibertari del Casc Antic. 2010. “Sonríe te están grabando: Cámaras, cámaras y
más cámaras.” Indymedia Madrid, February 18. <http://madrid.indymedia.org/
node/12868>
ATTAC. 2004. “La desregulación del sistema fijinanciero estimula el lavado de dinero.”
Rebelión, January 15. <http://www.rebelion.org/hemeroteca/economia/040115attac
.htm>
Austin Fitts, Catherine. 2001. “Narco-dollars for Beginners: How the Money Works in the
Illicit Drug Trade.” Drugwar.com, October 24. <http://www.drugwar.com/fijittsnarco1
.shtm>
Ayala, Roberto and Víctor Figueroa. 2001. “Imperialismo y globalización: ¿Es posible
humanizar el capitalismo?” Rebelión, June 6. <http://www.rebelion.org/hemeroteca/
izquierda/rayala060601.htm>
Baron, Ana. 2002. “EE.UU. crea una ofijicina para dar información falsa.” Clarin, February 20.
<http://www.clarin.com/diario/2002/02/20/i-02801.htm>
Bauman, Zygmunt. 1999. In Search of Politics. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
BBV. n.d. “La califación de riesgo, signifijicado y procedimientos.” Bolsa Boliviana de Valores,
S.A. <http://www.bbv.com.bo/aula.temario3.asp>
Beinstein, Jorge. 2000. “La gran mutación del capitalismo: Narcomafijias, centro y periferia.”
América Latina en Movimiento, December 13. <http://alainet.org/active/1099>
Bellinghausen, Hermann. 2003. “Noveno aniversario del alzamiento zapatista.” La Jornada,
January 2. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2003/01/03/006n1pol.php?origen=index
.html>
Bello, Walden. 2008. “Cómo fabricar una crisis global.” La Jornada, May 27 and 30. <http://
www.jornada.unam.mx/2008/05/27/index.php?section=opinion&article=018a1pol>
<http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2008/05/30/index.php?section=opinion&article=014a1
pol>
Bendesky, León. 2003. “El buque hace agua.” La Jornada, July 14. <http://www.jornada
.unam.mx/2003/07/14/019a1eco.php?origen=index.html&fly=2>
Bendesky, León. 2006. “Rubor.” La Jornada, February 20. <http://www.jornada.unam
.mx/2006/02/20/index.php?section=opinion&article=031a1eco>
Bihr, Alain and François Chesnais. 2003. “¿Aún es posible criticar la propiedad privada? Un
asunto tabú.” Le Monde Diplomatique, September. <http://www.pensamientocritico.org/
alabih1004.htm>
Blanco, José. 2006. “Turbio año electoral.” La Jornada, January 10. < http://www.jornada
.unam.mx/2006/01/10/index.php?section=opinion&article=020a1pol>
Bloch, Ernst. 1986. The Principle of Hope. Boston: MIT Press.
Bobbio, Norberto and Nicola Matteucci. 1981. Diccionario de Ciencia Política, Madrid:
Siglo XXI.
Bofff, Leonardo. 2003. “Porto Alegre, Davos y la globalización.” Rebelión, January 24. <http://
www.rebelion.org/sociales/bofff240103.htm>
Bonelli, Laurent. 2003. “Una visión policial de la sociedad.” Le Monde Diplomatique.
February. <http://monde-diplomatique.es/2003/02/bonelli.html>
Borja, Jordi. 2007. “Miedos urbanos, demandas de seguridad y represión preventiva.” La
Factoria 32. <http://www.lafactoriaweb.com/articulos/borja32.htm>
Boron, Atilio. 2000. Tras el búho de Minerva. Mercado contra democracia en el capitalismo de
fijin de siglo. Buenos Aires: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Boron, Atilio. 2001. “El nuevo orden imperial y cómo desmontarlo.” Rebelión, August 27.
<http://www.rebelion.org/hemeroteca/izquierda/boron270801.htm>
Bravo, Elba Mónica and Liliana Padilla. 2009. “EU debe informar cuántos de sus ciudadanos
viven de las drogas, exigen PAN y PRD.” Milenio Online, March 12. <http://impreso
.milenio.com/node/8543726>
Brenner, Robert. 2009a. The Economics of Global Turbulence, 2nd ed. New York: Verso.
bibliography 337
Brenner, Robert. 2009b. “Overproduction not Financial Collapse is the Heart of the Crisis:
the US, East Asia, and the World.” Asia Pacifijic Journal, February 7. <http://www
.japanfocus.org/-Robert_Brenner__S_J_Jeong/3043>
Brooks, David. 2005a. “El mayor escándalo de corrupción en un siglo sacude a la clase
política de EU.” La Jornada, December 28. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2005/12/28/
023n1mun.php>
Brooks, David. 2005b. “Por ley, será delincuente todo migrante indocumentado en
EU.” La Jornada, December 17. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2005/12/17/003n1pol
.php>
Brooks, David. 2006. “Más que a azufre, en Washington todo huele a corrupción; proliferan
los escándalos políticos.” La Jornada, September 30. <http://www.jornada.unam
.mx/2006/09/30/index.php?section=mundo&article=026n1mun>
Brooks, David. 2007. “Anuncia Washington nuevas medidas para “controlar” la inmigración
indocumentada.” La Jornada, August 11. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2007/08/11/
index.php?section=mundo&article=027n1mun>
Brooks, David. 2008. “Perciben estadounidenses recesión económica.” La Jornada, January
2. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2008/01/02/index.php?section=economia&article=01
7n1eco>
Brooks, David. 2010. “Presenta Obama el gasto militar para 2011; es el más grande de la his-
toria.” La Jornada, February 2. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2010/02/02/index.php
?section=mundo&article=024n1mun>
Brunhofff, Suzanne de. 1980. “La gestión estatal de la fuerza de trabajo,” in Moncayo Victor
Manuel and Fernando Rojas, eds., Estado y economía. Crisis permanente del Estado capi-
talista. Bogotá: Sociedad de Ediciones Internacionales.
Bunge, Mario. 2003. “La fijilosofía no ha muerto, pero está gravemente enferma.” Tendencias
21, April 26. <http://www.tendencias21.net/Mario-Bunge-la-fijilosofijia-no-ha-muerto,
-pero-esta-gravemente-enferma_a150.html>
Bunker, Robert J. 2006. “Guerra de Cuarta Época. Generaciones, modos y época. Formas de
guerra y el RPMA.” La Nueva Cuba, May 18. <http://www.lanuevacuba.com/archivo/
robert-bunker-1.htm>
Calvo Ospina, Hernando. 2003 “El paramilitarismo como estrategia contrainsurgente en
Colombia.” Le Monde Diplomatique, April. <http://monde-diplomatique.es/2003/04/
ospina.html>
Camil, Jorge. 2005. “Golpe de estado.” La Jornada, December 16. <http://www.jornada
.unam.mx/2005/12/16/021a1pol.php>
Campo Urbano, Salustiano del, Juan F. Marsal and José Antonio Garmendia. 1987.
Diccionario UNESCO de Ciencias Sociales. Barcelona: Planeta-Agostini.
Carlsen, Laura. 2006. “Bad Blood on the Border.” Counterpunch, February 4. <http://www
.counterpunch.org/carlsen02042006.html>
Carmagnani, Marcello. 1984. Estado y sociedad en América Latina (1859–1930). Barcelona:
Grijalbo.
Carmona, Ernesto. 2009. “Facebook ¿es de la CIA?” Rebelión, May 27. <http://www
.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=86035>
Carrillo, Jorge and Raúl Hinojosa. 2003. “Cableando a Norteamérica: la industria de los
arneses automotrices,” in Contreras, Oscar and Jorge Carrillo eds., Hecho en Norteamérica.
Mexico City: Cal y Arena.
Cassián Nizaiá, et al. 2006. “Imaginario Social: Una aproximación desde la obra de
Michel Mafffesoli.” Athenea Digital 9. <http://ddd.uab.cat/pub/athdig/15788946n9a11
.pdf>
Cason, Jim and David Brooks. 2001. “Frenética compra de armas en EE.UU.” La Jornada,
December 27.
Cason, Jim and David Brooks, 2004a. “Descubre el Pentagono una nueva amenaza en AL:
el populismo radical.” La Jornada, March 29. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2004/03/29/
030n1mun.php?origen=index.html&fly=1>
338 bibliography
Cason, Jim and David Brooks, 2004b. “El FMI recomienda a México acelerar reformas con
las hechas en el IMSS.” La Jornada, September 29. <http://www.jornada.unam
.mx/2004/09/30/017n1pol.php?origen=index.html&fly=1>
Castaingts Teillery, Juan. 2004. “Política mexicana: lenguaje y cultura del escándalo.” El
Financiero, October 21.
Castells, Manuel. 2001. “La crisis de lo político.” PoliticasNet. <http://usuarios.multimania
.es/politicasnet/articulos/crisisp.htm>
Castells, Manuel. 2003. “Lección inaugural del programa de doctorado sobre la sociedad de
la información y el conocimiento.” Educared. Buenos Aires: Fundación Telefónica.
<http://www.educared.org.ar/vicaria/adjuntos/lab-curr/leccion-inaugural-castells.pdf>
Castro, José Adalberto. Speech given at the opening of the seminar “El fenómeno de las
migraciones en nuestro tiempo. Perspectiva comparada entre México y la Unión
Europea,” Madrid, Spain, January 19, 2006. <http://www.senado.gob.mx/index.php?ver
=sp&mn=2&sm=2&id=9893&lg=59>
Chesnais, François. 1996. “Notas para una caracterización del capitalismo a fijines del siglo
XX.” Revista Herramienta 1. <http://www.herramienta.com.ar/revista-herramienta-n-1/
notas-para-una-caracterizacion-del-capitalismo-fijines-del-siglo-xx>
Chesnais, François. 1997. “La caracterización del capitalismo a fijines del siglo XX.” Revista
Herramienta 3. <http://www.herramienta.com.ar/revista-herramienta-n-3/
la-caracterizacion-del-capitalismo-fijines-del-siglo-xx>
Chiesa, Giulietto. 2008. “Guerra y Mentira. El control político y militar de nuestras socie-
dades.” VoltaireNet. January 15. <http://www.voltairenet.org/article154345.html>
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2001 “Who is Osama Bin Laden?” Global Research, September 12.
<http://www.globalresearch.ca/articles/CHO109C.html>
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2002a. War and Globalization: The Truth behind September 11.
Montreal: Centre for Research on Globalization.
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2002b. “Washington’s New World Order Weapons Have the Ability
to Trigger Climate Change.” Global Research, January 4. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/
articles/CHO201A.html>
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2002c. “United States War Machine: Revving the Engines of World
War III.” Third World Traveler. <http://www.thirdworldtraveler.com/War_Peace/US
_War_Machine.html>
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2002d. “Washington’s New World Order Weapons Have the Ability
to Trigger Climate Change.” Global Research, January 4. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/
articles/CHO201A.html>
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2003. Globalization of Poverty and the New World Order. Montreal:
Centre for Research on Globalization.
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2005. “New Undeclared Arms Race: America’s Agenda for Global
Military Domination.” Global Research, March 17. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/
articles/CHO503A.html>
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2007a. “The Criminalization of U.S. Foreign Policy: From the
Truman Doctrine to the Neoconservatives.” Global Research, February 5. <http://www
.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=4659>
Chossudovksy, Michel. 2007b. “La corrupción al asalto de los Estados. Como las mafijias
gangrenan la economía mundial.” Globalización, October. <http://www.rcci.net/
globalizacion/2007/fg707.htm>
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2007c. “Weather Warfare: Beware the U.S. Military’s Experiments
with Climatic Warfare.” Global Research, December 7. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/
index.php?context=va&aid=7561>
Chossudovksy, Michel. 2008a. “Al Qaeda and the ‘War on Terrorism’.” Global Research,
January 20. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=7718>
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2008b. “The Global Crisis: Food Water and Fuel. Three Fundamental
Necessities of Life in Jeopardy.” Global Research, June 5. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/
index.php?context=va&aid=9191>
bibliography 339
Chossudovsky, Michel. 2010. “Preparing for World War III, Targeting Iran.” Global Research,
August 1. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/index.php?aid=20403&context=va>
Chomsky, Noam. 2005. El terror como política exterior de Estados Unidos. Buenos Aires:
Libros del Zorzal.
Clarin. 2004. “Los diez principales temas de la batalla electoral en EE.UU.” Rebelión, October
24. <http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=6601>
Claudín, Fernando. 1976. Marx, Engels y la revolución de 1848. Madrid: Siglo XXI.
Colectivo Troyano. 2009a. “Corporaciones e implantes cerebrales, no están muy lejos.”
Rebelión, November 24. <http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=95811>
Colectivo Troyano. 2009b. “Reinventando la rueda: ¿‘redes sociales’ o control social?”
Rebelión, June 4. <http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=86432&titular=reinventa
ndo-la-rueda:-%BF%22redes-sociales%22-o-control-social?->
Cohen-Cole, Linn. 2009. “Genetically Modifijied Seeds: Monsanto is Putting Normal Seeds
Out of Reach.” Global Research, February 14. http://www.globalresearch.ca/index
.php?context=va&aid=12309
Colectivo Yachay Red Científijica Peruana. 2002. “El mundo de la desinformación.” Rebelión,
November 14. <http://www.rebelion.org/hemeroteca/medios/yachay141102.htm>
Committee of Santa Fe. 1980. “A New Inter-American Policy for the 1980s.” Washington:
Council for Inter-American Security.
Committee of Santa Fe. 1989. “Santa Fe II: A Strategy for Latin America in the Nineties.”
Washington: Council for Inter-American Security.
Consuegra, Renato. 2006. “Respingan inversores.” La Crítica. <http://www.lacritica.com
.mx/index.php?option=content&task=view&id=126&Itemid=25>
Contreras Natera, Miguel Ángel. 2007. “Imperio y fijin de sciécle. 11 de septiembre: una per-
spectiva crítica.” Sociologando, September 19. <http://www.sociologando.org.ve/pag/
index.php?id=33&idn=114>
Coon, Charlie. 2007. “El Departamento de Defensa se lanza a la Web para librar la batalla
informática.” Rebelión, June 22. <http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=52564>
Cordera Campos, Rolando. 2006. “El enredo.” La Jornada, March 19.
Córdova, Arnaldo. 1979. La política de masas y el futuro de la izquierda en México. Mexico
City: Serie Popular Era.
Coriat, Benjamín. 1992. El taller y el cronómetro. Ensayo sobre el taylorismo, el fordismo y la
producción en masa. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.
Corradini, Luisa. 2005. “‘Estamos en la era de los nómades y las tribus’ dice Mafffesoli.” La
Nación, August 31. <http://www.lanacion.com.ar/nota.asp?nota_id=734590>
Cortada, James and Thomas Hargraves. 1999. Into the Networked Age: How IBM and Other
Companies Are Getting There Now. New York: Oxford University Press.
Crozier, Michael, Samuel Huntington and Joji Watanuki. 1975. The Crisis of Democracy:
Report on Governability of Democracies to the Trilateral Commission. New York: NYU
Press.
Cueva, Agustín. 1993. El desarrollo del capitalismo en América Latina. Mexico City: Siglo
XXI.
Dabat, Alejandro. 1993. El mundo y las naciones. Mexico City: UNAM.
Dabat, Alejandro, Miguel Ángel Rivera and Estela Suárez. 2004. “Globalización, revolución
informática y países en desarrollo,” in Dabat Rivera and Wilkie, eds. Globalización y cam-
bio tecnológico. Mexico City: Juan Pablos Editor.
Davis, Mike. 2007. “Los suburbios de las ciudades del tercer mundo son el nuevo escenario
geopolítico decisivo.” Tortuga, Interview, March 10. <http://www.nodo50.org/tortuga/
article.php3?id_article=5228>
De Brie, Christian. 2000. “Gobiernos, mafijias y transnacionales, asociados,” Le Monde
Diplomatique, Southern Cone Edition, April.
De Brie, Christian. 2003. “La demolición social.” Le Monde Diplomatique, February. <http://
monde-diplomatique.es/2003/02/brie.html>
De Gortari, Eli. 1972. Introducción a la lógica dialéctica. Mexico City: FCE-UNAM.
340 bibliography
De la Garza, Enrique. 1988. Ascenso y crisis del Estado social autoritario. Mexico City:
Colegio de México.
Delors, Jacques, et al. 2008. “Financial Markets Can Not Govern Us!” Open letter of elder
statesmen on international fijinancial crisis endorsed by International Progress
Organization, May 19, 2008. <http://i-p-o.org/ipo-nr-10June08-fijinancial_crisis.htm>
Díaz, Miguel. 2007. “The Other War that Washington is not Winning.” Revista Ari 27. <http://
www.realinstitutoelcano.org/wps/portal/rielcano_eng/Content?WCM_GLOBAL
_CONTEXT=/elcano/Elcano_in/Zonas_in/ARI%2027-2007>
Díaz–Salazar Rafael. 2004. “De Porto Alegre a Bombay.” Rebelión, January 16. <http://www
.rebelion.org/hemeroteca/sociales/040116salazar.htm>
Dierckxsens, Wim. 2002. “Fin del neoliberalismo, fijin del capitalismo. Surge una nueva
utopía.” Alternativas, 23 (June): 13–28. <http://www.servicioskoinonia.org/relat/313
.htm>
Dimas, Eduardo. 2002. “Un jugoso botín: el Plan Puebla-Panamá.” Rebelión, September 30.
<http://www.rebelion.org/hemeroteca/economia/edimas300902.htm>
Dudley, Steven. “Lula Needs a Miracle.” The Progressive, October 1. <http://www.highbeam
.com/doc/1G1-93457090.html>
Dufour, Jules. 2007. “The Worldwide Network of US Military Bases: The Global Deployment
of US Military Personnel.” Global Research, July 1. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/index
.php?context=va&aid=5564>
Dufour, Jules. 2008. “Las guerras de ocupación de Afganistán e Iraq.” Global Research, July
31. <http://www.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=9719>
Dufour, Jules. 2009. “El gran rearme planetario.” Global Research, July 26. <http://www
.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=14539>
Dussel, Enrique. 2002. “Estado de guerra permanente y razón cínica.” Revista Herramienta,
21. <http://www.herramienta.com.ar/revista-herramienta-n-21/estado-de-guerra
-permanente-y-razon-cinica>
Eagleton, Terry. 1996. The Illusions of Postmodernism. Oxford: Blackwell.
Engels, Frederick. 1847. “Principles of Communism.” Marx/Engels Internet Archive. <http://
www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/11/prin-com.htm>
Engels, Frederick. 1877. “Karl Marx.” Marx/Engels Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists
.org/espanol/m-e/1870s/cmarx.htm>
Engels, Frederick. 1878. Anti-Dühring: Herr Eugen Dühring’s Revolution in Science.
Marx/Engels Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1877/
anti-duhring/index.htm>
Engels, Frederick. 1880. Socialism: Utopian and Scientifijic. Marx/Engels Internet Archive.
<http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/index.htm>
Engels, Frederick. 1884. “Origin of the Family, Private Property, and the State.” Marx/Engels
Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/download/pdf/
origin_family.pdf>
Engels, Frederick. 1895. Introduction to Karl Marx’s The Class Struggles in France.
Marx/Engels Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1850/
class-struggles-france/intro.htm>
Estay, Jaime. 2001. “Economía mundial y polarización económica y social,” in Caputo,
Orlando, Jaime Estay and José María Vidal Villa, Capital sin fronteras. Polarización crisis
y Estado-nación en el capitalismo global. Barcelona: Icaria.
Estay, Jaime. 2004. “ALCA: paraíso de inversionistas.” Red de Estudios de la Economía
Mundial. <http://www.redem.buap.mx/acrobat/jaime14.pdf>
ETC Group. 2003. “The Strategy for Converging Technologies: The Little BANG
Theory.” ETC Group Communique Issue #78. <http://www.etcgroup.org/upload/
publication/169/01/combang2003.pdf>
ETC Group. 2005a. A Tiny Primer on Nano-scale Technologies and the “Little Bang Theory.”
Ottawa: ETC Group. <http://www.etcgroup.org/upload/publication/55/01/tinyprimer
_english.pdf>
bibliography 341
ETC Group. 2005b. “Oligopoly, 2005: Concentration of World Power.” ETC Group
Communique Issue #91. <http://www.etcgroup.org/upload/publication/44/01/
oligopoly2005_16dec.05.pdf>
ETC Group. 2007. “Gambling with Gaia.” ETC Group Communique Issue #93. <http://www
.etcgroup.org/en/node/4913>
ETC Group. 2008. “Who Owns Nature?” ETC Group Communique Issue #100. <http://www
.etcgroup.org/upload/publication/707/01/etc_won_report_fijinal_color.pdf>
ETC Group. 2009. “The Emperor’s New Clothes: Geoengineering as 21st Century Fairy Tale.”
ETC Group Special Report, August 28. <http://www.etcgroup.org/upload/publication/
pdf_fijile/etcspecialreport_rsgeoeng28aug09.pdf>
ETC Group. 2010. “Top-down Planet Hackers call for Bottom-up Governance.” ETC Group
news release, February 11. <http://www.etcgroup.org/en/node/5073>
Fazio, Carlos. 2003. “ALCA y militarización, dos caras de un mismo proyecto hegemónico.”
Visiones Alternativas, May 7. <http://www.visionesalternativas.com.mx/militarizacion/
articulos/geoestrat/23.htm>
Fazio, Carlos. 2009. “Influenza, recesión y teoría del shock.” La Jornada, May 18. <http://
www.jornada.unam.mx/2009/05/18/index.php?section=opinion&article=022a1pol>
Feinmann, José Pablo. 2005. “Pornografía de la muerte,” in Bugani, Pedro, ed., La suma del
neoliberalismo y la postmodernidad en la globalización capitalista. Buenos Aires: Pensar
Libre. <http://www.psicoanalisis-s-p.com.ar/textos/modernidad015.doc>
Fernández Lagraña, Luis. 2006. “Centro Latinomericano para la competividad.” ABC
Digital, April 16. <http://archivo.abc.com.py/2006-04-16/articulos/246092/centro-latino
americano-para-la-competitividad>
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor. 1986. Reinterpretando el subdesarrollo. Mexico City: Siglo
XXI.
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor. 1989. La identidad perdida del socialismo. Mexico City: Ancien
Régime (UAZ-UAM).
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor. 1992. “El librecambio y la gestión estatal de la crisis en los
Estados Unidos: primera parte.” Vínculo Jurídico 11–12. <http://www.uaz.edu.mx/
vinculo/webrvj/rev11-12-5.htm>
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor. 1993. “El librecambio y la gestión estatal de la crisis en los
Estados Unidos: segunda parte.” Vínculo Jurídico 13. <http://www.uaz.edu.mx/vinculo/
webrvj/rev13-3.htm>
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor. 1995. “La gestión estatal del desarrollo en América Latina.”
Revista Problemas del Desarrollo, Vol. 26: 103.
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor. 2001. “América Latina: el nuevo patrón de colonialismo indus-
trial.” Revista Problemas del Desarrollo Vol. 32: 126.
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor. 2003. “La actualidad del imperialismo, la actualidad de la
crítica,” in Figueroa, Víctor, ed., América Latina en la crisis del patrón neoliberal de creci-
miento. Zacatecas: Political Science Unit, Universidad Autónoma de Zacatecas.
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor. 2008. Excedentes de población. Mimeo, materials from
Doctorate in Political Science, Universidad Autónoma de Zacatecas.
Forrester, Viviane. 1999. The Economic Horror. Cambridge: Blackwell.
Forster, Ricardo. 2009. “Neoliberalismo, medios de comunicación y democracia.” El País,
September 8. <http://www.pagina12.com.ar/diario/elpais/1-131394-2009-09-08.html>
Fox, Vicente. 2004. “Reunión de presentación del Instituto Mexicano para la
Competitividad.” Mexican President’s Offfijice Online Archive. Feb. 17. <http://fox
.presidencia.gob.mx/actividades/discursos/?contenido=7501>
Freytas, Manuel. 2006a. “Bin Laden, el mejor amigo de Bush.” IAR Noticias, June 15. <http://
iarnoticias.com/secciones_2006/norteamerica/0049_bin_laden_imperio_15jun06
.html>
Freytas, Manuel. 2006b. “Control mental: Como las grandes cadenas televisivas manipulan
la masacre de Israel en Líbano y Gaza.” IAR Noticias, July 14. <http://www.iarnoticias
.com/secciones_2006/medio_oriente/0016_manip_medios_gaza_14jul06.html>
342 bibliography
Freytas, Manuel. 2006c. “Guerra de Cuarta Generación.” IAR Noticias, March 21. <http://
www.iarnoticias.com/secciones_2006/norteamerica/0019_guerra_cuarta
_generacion_21mar06.html>
Freytas, Manuel. 2007. “La trama funcional y mediática de los ataques terroristas.” IAR
Noticias, July 5. <http://www.iarnoticias.com/secciones_2007/norteamerica/0092_cia
_terrorismo_tercerizado_05jul07.html>
Fröbel, Folker, Juergen Heinrichs and Otto Kreye. 1981. La nueva división internacional del
trabajo. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.
Fromm, Erich. 1978. Marx y su concepto del hombre. Mexico: Fondo de Cultura
Económica.
Fukuyama, Francis. 1992. The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Free Press.
Galeano, Eduardo. 2006. “El gran negocio del crimen y el miedo sacrifijica la justicia.” La
Jornada, June 4.
Gallin, Dan. 2000. “Globalización y la política del sindicalismo.” <http://www.global-labor
.org/A%20la%20hora%20de%20la%20mondializacion%20que%20movimento%20
sindical.pdf>
García, Hector. 2006. “De aperitivo, ¿oxígeno a la menta o a la naranja?” Kirainet—Un Geek
en Japón (blog), November 6. <http://www.kirainet.com/de-aperitivo-¿oxigeno
-a-la-menta-o-a-la-naranja/>
Garrido, Luis Javier. 2005. “La otra.” La Jornada, December 30.
Gerefffiji, Gary. 2006. “Las cadenas productivas como marco analítico para la globalización.”
<http://www.cema.edu.ar/~eab/UCEMA/Bloques_Economicos_y_Agronegocios_2006/
Gerefffiji_Gary_Cadenas_productivas>
Gilly, Adolfo. 2004. “Populismo radical: un sujeto político no identifijicado.” La Jornada,
June 1. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/031a1mun.php?origen=index.html&fly=1>
Gómez E., Luis. 1993. “Una aproximación a la historia social de la tecnología posindustrial,”
in Micheli, Jordy, compiler, Tecnología y modernización económica. Mexico City:
Universidad Autónoma Metropolitana—Xochimilco, pp. 471–499.
González Casanova, Pablo. 2000. “¿A dónde va México?” América Latina en
Movimiento, July 4. <http://alainet.org/active/840&lang=eshttp://alainet.org/active/
840 &lang=es>
Gouverneur, Cédric. 2002. “Mundialización de la economía mafijiosa. Guerra del opio en las
fronteras de Irán.” Le Monde Diplomatique, March 11. <http://www.eldiplo.org/login
.php3?numero=102&semanal=34/S_B_1_38>
Gramsci, Antonio. 1999. Antología. Selección, traducción y notas de Manuel Sacristán.
Madrid: Siglo XXI.
Gresh, Alain. 2005. “‘Petróleo contra alimentos’. Un escándalo puede ocultar otros.” El
Monde Diplomatique, August 19. <http://www.eldiplo.org/login.php3?numero=102&
semanal=75/S_B_1_34>
Grimaldi, James and Sari Horwitz. 2010. “As Mexico’s drug violence runs rampant, U.S.
guns tied to crime south of the border.” Washington Post, December 15. <http://www
.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2010/12/12/AR2010121202663.html>
Guevara, Rodrigo. 2003. “Irak y el capitalismo militar de Estados Unidos.” IAR Noticias,
December 25. <http://iarnoticias.com/secciones/mediooriente/irak_y_el_capitalismo
_militar_de_estados_unidos.html>
Guevera, Rodrigo. 2005. “Los ‘contratistas’ de operaciones psicológicas con el Pentágono.”
IAR Noticias, December 19. <http://iarnoticias.com/secciones_2005/norteamerica/0117
_contratistas_privad_informacion_19dic05.html>
Harman, Chris. 2007. “The Rate of Profijit and the World Today.” International Socialism,
July 2. <http://www.isj.org.uk/?id=340>
Harvey, David. 2004. “‘The ‘New Imperialism’: Accumulation by Dispossession,” in Panitch,
Leo and Colin Leys, eds., The New Imperial Challenge: Socialist Register 2004. Winnipeg:
Fernwood, pp. 63–87.
Heller, Pablo. 2003. “Tasa de ganancia y descomposición capitalista.” En defensa del
Marxismo, 30 (May).
bibliography 343
Hernández, Evangelina. 2009. “Prostitución forzada, otra cara del yugo a migrantes.”
El Universal, December 2. <http://www.eluniversal.com.mx/primera/34025.html>
Hernández López, Julio. 2006. “Astillero, el mal (estado) del país.” La Jornada,
March 13.
Hernández López, Julio. 2007. “APPO, PRD y elecciones en Oaxaca.” La Jornada, May 22.
<http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2007/05/22/index.php?section=opinion&article=019a1
pol>
Hernández Navarro, Luis. 2005a. “El oso y el tigre.” La Jornada, October 11. <http://www
.jornada.unam.mx/2005/10/11/021a1pol.php>
Hernández Navarro, Luis. 2005b. “Migración y guerra contra el terrorismo.” La Jornada,
December 20. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2005/12/20/021a1pol.php>
Hernández Navarro, Luis. 2006. “Optimismo y cambio en América Latina.” La Jornada,
January 31. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2006/01/31/index.php?section=opinion
&article=027a1pol>
Herrera, Claudia and David Brooks. 2006. “En EU, Calderón se desmarca de la política
migratoria del actual gobierno.” La Jornada, November 10. <http://www.jornada.unam
.mx/2006/11/10/index.php?section=politica&article=003n1pol>
Hirsch, Joachim. 1979. “Elementos para una teoría materialista del Estado.” Críticas de la
economía política 12–13.
Hirsch, Joachim. 1996. Globalización, Capital y Estado. Mexico City: Universidad Autónoma
Metropolitana—Xochimilco.
Hirsch, Joachim. 2000. “¡Adiós a la política!” Revista Viento del Sur 17.
Huntington, Samuel. 1996. The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order.
New York: Simon & Schuster.
Ianni, Octavio. 1977a. “Clases subalternas y Estado oligárquico.” in Benitez Zenteno,
Raúl, ed., Clases sociales y crisis política en América Latina. Mexico City: Siglo
XXI-UNAM.
Ianni, Octavio. 1977b. El Estado capitalista en la época de Cárdenas. Mexico City: Serie
Popular Era.
Ianni, Octavio. 1984. La formación del Estado populista en América Latina. Mexico City:
Serie Popular Era.
Ianni, Octavio. 1996. Teorías de la globalización. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.
ICRC. 1998. Rome Statute of the International Criminal Court. Geneva: ICRC. <http://www
.icrc.org/ihl.nsf/FULL/585?OpenDocument>
ILO. 2007. Global Employment Trends 2007. Geneva: ILO. <http://www.ilo.org/global/
About_the_ILO/Media_and_public_information/Press_releases/lang–en/WCMS
_081866/index.htm>
Instituto Mexicano para la Competividad. 2003. Análisis de la competitividad en México,
September 2003. <http://www.queretaro.gob.mx/sedesu/deseco/esteco/perfeco/reveco/
Documentos/IMCO.htm>
IraqSolidaridad. 2008. “Más de un millón de iraquíes han muerto desde el inicio de la
ocupación.” Rebelión, Feb. 6. <http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=62888>
Iruegas, Gustavo. 2005. “En defensa propia.” La Jornada, December 16.
Iturriaga, Yuriria. 2006. “Francia: repudian millón y medio de personas la reforma laboral.”
La Jornada, March 19. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2006/03/19/index.php?section
=mundo&article=031n1mun>
Jafffe, Hosea. 1976. Del tribalismo al socialismo. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.
Jiménez Villarejo, Carlos. 2004. “Delincuencia fijinanciera y paraísos fijiscales.” Revista La
Factoria 24. <http://www.revistalafactoria.eu/articulo.php?id=267>
Joxe, Alain. 2003a. El imperio del caos. Buenos Aires: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Joxe, Alain. 2003b. “Una estrategia del desorden sin freno ni fijin.” El Monde Diplomatique
May. <http://www.monde-diplomatique.es/2003/05/joxe.html>
Kagarlitsky, Boris. 2001. “El incendio del Reichstag en Nueva York.” Herramienta Debate y
Crítica Marxista 17. <http://www.herramienta.com.ar/revista-herramienta-n-17/el
-incendio-del-reichstag-en-nueva-york>
344 bibliography
Marcos, Subcomandante. “Si nos equivocamos acerca del PRD, ofreceremos disculpas.” La
Jornada, August 11, 2005. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2005/08/11/014n1pol.php>
Marelli, Sergio. 2007. “La imaginación y el poder.” Etcétera, November 1. <http://www
.etcetera.com.mx/articulo.php?articulo=2297>
Martin, Hans-Peter and Harald Schumann. 1997. The Global Trap: Globalization and the
Assault on Prosperity and Democracy. London: Zed Books.
Martínez Peinado, Javier. 2000. “Periferia y fábrica mundial.” Aportes 15. <http://www
.redem.buap.mx/t3javier.htm>
Martiniuk, Claudio. 2009. “Nuestra marca de época es la tribu, lo arcaico, más el desarrollo
del Internet.” Clarín, December 27. <http://edant.clarin.com/diario/2009/12/27/um/
m-02108637.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1844. A Contribution to the Critique of Hegel’s Philosophy of Right. Marx-Engels
Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1843/critique-hpr/
intro.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1847. The Misery of Philosophy. Marx-Engels Internet Archive. <http://www
.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/poverty-philosophy/index.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1853. “The British Rule in India.” Marx-Engels Internet Archive. <http://www
.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1853/06/25.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1859. A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy. Marx-Engels Internet
Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1859/critique-pol-economy/
index.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1863. Formal and Real Subsumption of Labour under Capital: Transitional
Forms. Marx’s Economic Manuscripts of 1861–1863. Marx-Engels Internet Archive.
<http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1861/economic/ch37.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1867. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy. Vol. I. Marx-Engels Internet
Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/index.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1885. Capital, Vol II. Marx-Engels Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/
archive/marx/works/1885-c2/index.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1894. Capital, Vol III. Marx-Engels Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/
archive/marx/works/1894-c3/index.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1895. The Class Struggles in France, 1848–1850. Marx-Engels Internet Archive.
<http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1850/class-struggles-france/index.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1973. Outlines of the Critique of Political Economy. Marx-Engels Internet Archive.
<http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1857/grundrisse/index.htm>
Marx, Karl. 1981. El Capital. Libro I. Capítulo VI (Inédito). Mexico City: Siglo XXI.
Marx, Karl and Frederick Engels. 1848. Manifesto of the Communist Party. Marx-
Engels Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/
communist-manifesto/index.htm>
Marx, Karl and Frederick Engels. 1883. Communist Manifesto: Preface to the 1883 German
Edition. Marx-Engels Internet Archive. <http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/
works/1848/communist-manifesto/preface.htm>
Mathiesen, Thomas. 2000. “La Globalización de la Vigilancia.” One of a series of documents
on ENFOPOL published online by the Universidad de Granada. <http://www.ugr
.es/~aquiran/cripto/enfopol/enfo08.htm>
Memoria. 2002. “Echelon en la disputa por la hegemonía.” Memoria 157 (March), editorial.
<http://www.revistamemoria.com/vista.php?id=1286&path=718c4f0612e3d85fcbad>
Mendès France, Mireille and Hugo Ruiz Diaz. 2007. “Hacia una sociedad internacional
policial y represiva.” Rebelión, November 20. <http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id
=59017>
Messina, German. 2009. “Las sociedades latinoamericanas en las que (sobre)vivi(re)mos.”
Observatorio de la Economía Latinoamericana 116. <http://www.eumed.net/cursecon/
ecolat/la/09/mmf.htm>
Mészáros, István. 1970. Marx’s Theory of Alienation. Mészáros Internet Archive. <http://
www.marxists.org/archive/meszaros/works/alien/index.htm>
346 bibliography
Mészáros István. 2003. “Militarism and the Coming Wars.” Monthly Review, January. <http://
www.monthlyreview.org/0603meszaros.htm>
Mészáros, István. 2010. The Structural Crisis of Capital. New York: Monthly Review
Press.
Moeche, Erich. 1999. ENFOPOL: The Creation of a Global Surveillance Network. Paper pre-
sented at the Computers, Freedom and Privacy 99 Conference, Washington D.C., April
6–8.
Mokhiber, Russell and Robert Weissman. 2002a. “Cracking Down on Corporate Crime,
Really.” Focus on the Corporation, July 3. <http://lists.essential.org/pipermail/
corp-focus/2002/000120.html>
Mokhiber, Russell and Robert Weissman. 2002b. “La acción como respuesta.” Znet, October.
<http://www.zmag.org/Spanish/1002mokweiss.htm>
Mokhiber, Russell and Robert Weissman. 2005a. “Self Interview: On the Rampage.”
Z Space, Feb. 24. <www.zcommunications.org/self-interview-on-the-rampage-by-russell
-mokhiber.pdf>
Mokhiber, Russell and Robert Weissman. 2005b. “El crimen y la violencia de las corporacio-
nes infligen mucho más daño a la sociedad, tanto en dólares como en vidas, que la
delincuencia callejera.” Rebelión, April 6. <http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id
=13510>
Moore, Stanley. 1957. The Critique of Capitalist Democracy. New York: Paine-Whiteman.
Morin, Edgar. 1999. Sociología. Barcelona: Kairós.
Moseley, Fred. 2005. “Teoría marxista de las crisis y la economía de posguerra de los Estados
Unidos,” in Razón y Revolución, 14: Spring. <www.razonyrevolucion.org/textos/revryr/
RyR14/ryr14-moseley.pdf>
Moulian, Tomas. 2000. “El Neoliberalismo como Sistema de Dominación.” Alternativa 15.
Norandi, Mariana. 2010. “Matrimonio, institución vetusta y obsoleta, dice investigadora.” La
Jornada, February 8. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2010/02/08/index.php?section=so
ciedad&article=040n1soc>
Ogarrio, Gustavo. 2003. “Said: la radical actualidad de algún humanismo.” Rebelión,
November 18. <http://www.rebelion.org/hemeroteca/said/031118said.htm>
Ohmae, Kenichi. 1997. El fijin del Estado-nación. Santiago: Editorial Andrés Bello.
Oppenheimer, Walter and David Alandete. “Al Qaeda también nos desnuda.” El País,
January 6, 2010. <http://www.elpais.com/articulo/sociedad/Qaeda/nos/desnuda/
elpepisoc/20100106elpepisoc_1/Tes>
Ornelas Bernal, Raúl. 2000. “Un mundo nos espía. El escándalo ECHELON.” Revista Chiapas
9 <http://www.revistachiapas.org/No9/ch9ornelas.html>
Pacheco Benites, Alberto Renaun. 2008. “La muerte de la muerte.” Contratexto 6. <http://
www.ulima.edu.pe/Revistas/contratexto/v6/index.html>
Palenga, Mima. n.d. “Pensamiento débil.” Available from Free PDF E-Books. <http://www
.free-pdf-ebooks.com/ebook/vattimo-m%C3%A1s-all%C3%A1-de-la-interpretaci%
C3%B3n.html>
Pardo, Lisandro. 2009. “Redes sociales, bajo el interés de la CIA.” Rebelión, October 20.
<http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=93625>
Pérez, Carlota. 1986. “Las nuevas tecnologías: una visión de conjunto,” in Ominami, Carlos,
ed., La Tercera Revolución Industrial: Impactos Internacionales del Actual Viraje
Tecnológico. Buenos Aires: RIAL, Grupo Editor Latinoamericano, pp. 43–90. <http://
www.carlotaperez.org/Articulos/fijicha-lasnuevastecnologiasunavision.htm>
Perry, William. 1996. “La política de Estados Unidos hacia América Latina.” FASOC Vol. 11(1):
49–53. <http://www.fasoc.cl/fijiles/articulo/ART411926d0889da.pdf>
Petras, James. 2002. “La estrategia militar de EE.UU. en América Latina.” Visiones
Alternativas.
<http://www.visionesalternativas.com.mx/militarizacion/articulos/geoestrat/1.htm>
Petras, James. 2004. “The Politics of Imperialism: Neoliberalism and Class Politics in
Latin America.” Counterpunch, November 13–14. <http://www.counterpunch.org/
petras11132004.html>
bibliography 347
Petras, James. 2007. “Global Ruling Class: Billionaires and How They ‘Made It’.” The James
Petras Website. <http://petras.lahaine.org/articulo.php?p=1696&more=1&c=1>
Pilger, John. 2002. “Document Revealed: What America Needed was a New Pearl Harbor.”
Third World Traveler, December 12. <http://www.thirdworldtraveler.com/Pilger_John/
New_Pearl_Harbor.html>
Pineda, Francisco. 2003. “Irak, Afganistán, Chechenia: la guerra de desinformación en la
‘era de la información’.” Revista Rebeldía 7.
Piqueras, Andrés. 2005. “La mutua conformación del capital y el trabajo desde el capital-
ismo maduro al capitalismo senil y las formas sociales a que da lugar.” Revista Polis 12.
<http://www.revistapolis.cl/polis%20fijinal/12/pique.htm>
Plihon, Dominique. 2003. El nuevo capitalismo. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.
Portantiero, Juan Carlos. 1981. “Estado y crisis en el debate de entreguerras,” in Los usos de
Gramsci. Mexico City: Folios.
Portelli, Hugues. 1998. Gramsci y el bloque histórico. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.
Poulantzas, Nicos. 1973. Poder político y clases sociales en el Estado capitalista. Mexico City:
Siglo XXI.
Prolongeau, Hubert and Jean-Christophe Rampal. 1997. “En América latina, el secuestro se
convierte en una industria.” Le Monde Diplomatique, November.
Quijano, Aníbal. 1977. “Imperialismo, clases sociales y Estado en el Perú: 1895–1930,”
in Clases sociales y crisis política en América Latina. Mexico City: Siglo XXI-IIS-
UNAM.
Quintana, Victor. 2010. “Modelo juvenicida.” La Jornada, February 5. <http://www.jornada
.unam.mx/2010/02/05/index.php?section=opinion&article=017a2pol>
Ramonet, Ignacio. 2010. “Socialdemocracia, fijin de ciclo.” El Monde Diplomatique, February.
<http://www.eldiplo.com.pe/socialdemocracia-fijin-de-ciclo>
Rascon, Marco. 2005. “Emilio Azcárraga y don Osito Bimbo, se apropian de la moral
pública.” La Jornada, September 6.
Real Academia Española. 1992. Diccionario de la lengua española. 21st edition. Madrid: Real
Academia Española.
Regalado Álvarez, Roberto. 1999. “El manifijiesto comunista y la transnacionalización de la
dominación política,” in Caycedo Turriago, Jaime and Jario Estrada Álvarez, eds., Marx
vive: siglo y medio del manifijiesto comunista: ¿superación, vigencia o reactualización?
Bogotá: Universidad Nacional de Colombia, pp. 85–93. <http://www.espaciocritico
.com/sites/all/fijiles/libros/mrxvv1/mrxvv1a06p85a93.pdf>
Reina Rodríguez, Carlos Arturo. 2006. “Los Espectros Urbanos: En la era de las tribus, más
que pesado, es metal con historia.” Carlos Reina website, July 14. <http://carlosreina
.espacioblog.com/post/2006/07/14/los-espectros-urbanos-la-era-las-tribus-mas
-pesado->
Revelli, Marco. 2004. “8 tesis sobre el postfordismo.” Ediciones Simbióticas, Nov. 27. <http://
www.altediciones.com/t11.htm>
Revista Inter-Forum. 2002. “Reporte Latinoamericano de Competitividad.” Revista Inter-
Forum, December 23. <http://www.revistainterforum.com/espanol/articulos/122301
artprin.html>
Revuelta, María José. 2008. “El tratamiento mediático de la globalización.” Rebelión May 8.
<http://www.rebelion.org/docs/67138.pdf>
Ribeiro, Silvia. 2005. “Los dueños del planeta: corporaciones 2005.” La Jornada, December
31. <http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2005/12/31/019a1eco.php>
Ribeiro, Silvia. 2007. “El 2006 y la plutocracia.” América Latina en Movimiento, January 18.
<http://alainet.org/active/15154&lang=es>
Ribeiro, Silvia. 2009a. “Una red de poderosas trasnacionales juegan a romper las reglas de
la naturaleza.” Interview, Armas contra las guerras 262. <http://www.herbogeminis.com/
Entrevista_a_Silvia_Ribeiro.html>
Ribeiro, Silvia. 2009b. “Premiando a las transnacionales de la epidemia.” La Jornada, May 9.
<http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2009/05/09/index.php?section=opinion&article=029a1
eco>
348 bibliography
Robert, Anne-Cécile. 2010. “La polémica sobre una decisión demasiado favorable a las
empresas.” El Monde Diplomatique, July. <http://guasabaraeditor.blogspot.com/2010/07/
la-crisis-social-llega-al-parlamento.html>
Roberts, Paul Craig. 2010. “The Road to Armageddon: the Insane Drive for American
Hegemony Threatens Life on Earth.” Global Research, February 26. <http://www
.globalresearch.ca/index.php?context=va&aid=17821>
Rodero, Antón Emma. 2000. “Concepto y técnicas de la propaganda y su aplicación al
nazismo,” in Actas del III Congreso Internacional Cultura y Medios de Comunicación.
Salamanca: Publicaciones Universidad Pontifijicia. <http://www.bocc.ubi.pt/pag/
rodero-emma-propaganda-nazismo.pdf>
Rodríguez, Juan Carlos. 2009. “Facebook, de la CIA a la privacidad.” Eco Diario, June 25.
<http://ecodiario.eleconomista.es/internet/noticias/1354212/06/09/Facebook-de-la
-CIA-a-la-privacidad.html>
Rodríguez Derivet, Arleen. 2003. “La guerra del fijin de la historia.” La Jiribilla. <http://www
.lajiribilla.cu/2003/n097_03/paraimprimir/097_04_imp.html>
Rojas Aravena, Francisco. 2008. “Violencia en América Latina. Debilidad estatal, inequidad
y crimen organizado inhiben el desarrollo humano.” Pensamiento Iberoamericano 2.
<http://www.pensamientoiberoamericano.org/articulos/2/51/1/globalizacion-y-violen-
cia-en-america-latina-debilidad-estatal-inequidad-y-crimen-organizado-inhiben-el
-desarrollo-humano.html>
Román, Jose Antonio. 2005. “Derbez: migración sin freno por la incapacidad de crear
empleos.” La Jornada, October 4.
Romero, Aldo Andrés. 1998. “El Manifijiesto Comunista y la Globalización.” Revista
Herramienta 7. <http://www.herramienta.com.ar/varios/7/7-6.html>
Rossanda, Rossana. 2003. “La doctrina Bush borra los principios de la ONU y dicta las reglas
para imponer su ley donde sea.” Creatividad feminista http://www.rebelion.org/noticia
.php?id=77871
Rosselet-McCouley, Suzanne. 2010. “Appendix I: Methodology and Principles of Analysis,”
in World Competitiveness Yearbook 2010. Lausanne: IMD. <http://www.imd.ch/research/
publications/wcy/upload/methodology.pdf
Rouleau, Eric. 2003. “La propaganda de guerra y sus defijiciencias.” El Monde Diplomatique,
February. <http://monde-diplomatique.es/2003/02/rouleau.html>
Rudnik, Isaac and Jacob Goransky. 2007. “Propuestas alternativas y actores sociales en
América Latina.” Rebelión, February 27. <http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=47402>
Sader, Emir. 2004 “Paraísos fijiscales: Prostíbulos de la globalización.” Rebelión, July 1. <http://
www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=1329>
Sader, Emir. 2007. “Oda al humanismo.” Rebelión, May 18. <http://www.rebelion.org/
noticia.php?id=51044>
Said, Edward. 2003. “Worldly Humanism vs. the Empire Builders.” Counterpunch, August 4.
<http://www.counterpunch.org/said08052003.html>
Salbuchi, Adrian. 1999. El Cerebro del Mundo: La cara oculta de la Globalización. Cordoba:
Ediciones del Copista. <http://www.laeditorialvirtual.com.ar/>
Sánchez, Esther. 2010. “Narcoguerra 2009: Todos perdieron.” El Universal, January 10.
<http://www.eluniversal.com.mx/estados/74251.html>
Sánchez Rebolledo, Adolfo. 2003. “Contrastes de 6 de julio.” La Jornada, July 10. <http://
www.jornada.unam.mx/2003/07/10/021a1pol.php?origen=opinion.php&fly=1>
Sánchez Rebolledo, Adolfo. 2006. “Otro régimen de partidos.” La Jornada, January 12.
Sánchez Vázquez, Adolfo. 1999. Entre la realidad y la utopía. Ensayos sobre política, moral y
socialismo. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Saviano, Roberto. 2007. Gomorra. Mexico City: Debate.
Saxe-Fernández, John. 2006. Terror e imperio. La hegemonía política y económica de Estados
Unidos. Mexico City: Debate.
Saxe-Fernández, John. 2007. “Agenda secreta: anexión y ocupación.” La Jornada. April 26.
<http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2007/04/26/index.php?section=opinion&article=032a1
eco>
bibliography 349
Mexico 5, 18, 50, 81, 96, 100, 101, 121, 122, oppressed 2, 30, 74, 260, 326, 328
136, 143, 144, 147, 148, 157, 160–163, 166, organized crime 8, 12, 67, 173, 185, 189, 190,
170–172, 177, 181, 182, 186, 187, 190, 193, 192, 193, 197–199, 201, 203–205, 212, 223,
201–203, 205, 223, 229, 235, 274, 275, 277 224, 270, 271, 273, 277, 283, 290, 303, 321
middle term of capitalism 40
modern state 28, 128, 227 period of decline 12, 283, 303, 313, 316,
modes of domination and resistance 42 325–327, 331, 334
money-capital 128–130, 133, 136, 148 periodization 4, 40, 53, 55, 56, 69, 70, 310
monopolies 8, 20, 66, 68, 110, 120, 127, 128, political
139, 150–152, 154, 215, 232, 300, 311, 313, 326 class 91, 169–172, 180, 186, 250, 275, 281
multinational monopolies 8, 150, 154 domination 29, 35, 100, 308
multiple crises 10, 303 society 35, 50, 209, 275
mystifijications 27, 240 postmodern 231, 247–252, 254–263, 266,
267, 269
narratives 1, 250, 251, 256, 257, 260, 266 postmodernist 257, 258, 261, 269
National Industrial Recovery Act 94 private sphere 75, 76
National Manufacturers Association 94 production workshop of domination
national monopolies 8, 128, 150, 154, strategies 65–67, 102, 111, 159, 160, 183,
311, 313 210, 216, 327
nationalism 96, 97, 100, 101, 121 productive capital 69, 79, 81, 123, 128–130,
nationalization 89, 90, 95 133–137, 140, 142, 146–148, 150, 151, 154,
nation-state 4, 6–8, 10, 55, 57, 58, 62, 67, 160, 179
69, 80, 86, 95, 98, 115, 116, 123, 126, 127, proletariat 20, 21, 24, 25, 42, 52, 84, 87, 89,
132, 137, 142, 154, 156, 157, 159, 162, 168, 91, 96, 100, 104, 109
180, 205, 212, 214, 221, 229, 245, 246, 253, public sphere 76, 214, 254
268, 274, 288, 289, 325, 328, 329, 330
Nazi 94, 145, 187, 229, 255, 280 rationality 46, 88, 103, 104, 131, 213, 242,
Neoliberal 4–11, 13, 50, 66, 67, 70, 71, 91, 98, 243, 252–254, 261, 274, 324
101, 102, 113, 116, 117, 119, 121–123, 125–129, rebellion 84, 85, 95, 158, 259, 260, 264, 283,
131–133, 137, 138, 142, 143, 145, 149–152, 326, 327, 330, 331
154–156, 159, 162, 164, 168–170, 172, 173, and revolution 330, 331
175–180, 182–186, 189–203, 206, 207, 209, relative growth (internal growth) 61,
211–215, 218–231, 234–237, 243, 245, 246, 98, 99
248, 252–254, 256, 258, 263, 264, 265, repression 9, 115, 182, 226, 227, 230, 276,
267–270, 273, 274, 277, 280–282, 288, 282, 287
289, 291, 293, 295, 297, 303, 304, 307, 310, resistance 3, 5, 8, 31, 38, 41–43, 45, 47, 63,
312, 314, 317, 319, 320, 322, 323, 325–328, 65, 78, 92, 105, 118, 128, 135, 138, 142, 143,
330, 332 146, 147, 151, 160, 172, 173, 184, 203, 212,
democracy 168–170, 193, 194, 256 214, 215, 230, 234, 245, 251, 259, 261, 273,
economy 5, 6, 125, 127, 129, 131, 133, 135, 283, 287, 289, 308, 323, 330
137, 139, 141, 143, 145, 147, 149, 151, 153, revolution 6, 10, 12, 29, 34, 44, 49, 50, 66,
155, 175, 190–193, 196, 198, 199, 289 70, 71, 73, 74, 81, 83, 84, 86–91, 95, 97, 103,
ideology 169, 214, 252 110, 115, 117, 118, 123, 125, 130, 133, 140, 142,
state 5, 6, 50, 128, 131, 155–157, 159, 161, 146, 151, 168, 172, 203, 206, 217, 223, 230,
163–165, 167, 169, 171, 173, 175, 180, 184, 253, 259, 273, 298, 311, 313, 315, 326, 327,
202, 203, 212, 214, 229, 289 330, 331
neo-Nazi 145, 187, 255, 280 revolutionary class 84
networked States 8
North American Free Trade Agreement science of capital 107
(NAFTA) 121, 147, 160, 163, 186 security alliances 8, 204, 205
slavery 18, 47, 71, 79–81, 128, 180, 190, 281,
obedience 2, 13, 17, 19, 25, 31–34, 43, 78, 158, 292, 317
160, 163, 273 social
oligarchic pattern 5, 70, 73, 78, 79, 81, 82, class 1, 9, 11, 13, 19, 24, 25, 38, 41, 51, 61, 62,
96, 98, 99, 102 75, 78, 93, 100, 103, 118, 119, 156, 159, 162,
subject index 355
177, 178, 183, 195, 196, 202, 220, 254, transition to democracy 121, 158, 159, 168,
260, 262, 307, 313, 316 212, 213, 325, 329
governance 8, 245 transnationalized capital 10, 253
limit of capitalism 316, 317, 322, 323 tribalize 263
movements 170, 172, 188, 232, 261, 290 tribes 200, 217, 261–263
relation 2, 9, 18, 19, 21, 25, 30, 33, 35, Tsarist Russia 89, 329
38, 41, 42, 46, 71, 79, 110, 131, 132, 178,
194, 210, 220, 231, 235, 238, 240–244, underdeveloped capitalism 58, 59, 63, 71,
260, 261, 265, 307, 308, 324, 325, 72, 95, 103, 123
332, 333 underdeveloped nation 6, 7, 96, 119, 120,
socialism 1, 12, 20, 45, 52, 77, 83, 87, 89–91, 122, 134, 141–143, 146, 148, 150, 157, 158,
95, 115, 116, 119–121, 202, 212, 213, 249, 259, 175, 176, 180, 183, 187, 289, 315
261, 311, 317, 334 unemployment 6, 7, 23, 47, 59–61, 93,
Soviet Union 90, 119, 136, 273, 289, 290 104–106, 122, 133, 135, 144, 151, 155, 176,
state administration 5, 7, 9, 12, 102, 103, 123, 177, 179, 180, 185–187, 189, 199, 218, 221,
125, 175176, 184, 185, 199–201, 203, 223, 224, 233, 237, 246, 259, 263, 288,
205–207, 212, 214, 215, 219, 225–229, 235, 317, 326
271, 289, 325 unions 66, 78, 82, 88, 94, 103–105, 109–111,
of concessions 103, 123, 214, 215, 228 118, 135, 136, 143, 144, 167, 177, 182, 189, 214,
of crime 123 218, 219, 223, 269, 275
of criminal activity 5, 7, 9, 12, 176, 184, United States 5, 18, 66, 67, 83, 91, 92, 94,
185, 198–201, 203, 205–207, 212, 214, 97, 119, 121, 122, 125–128, 131, 132, 136, 144,
215, 225–229, 235, 271, 289, 325 153, 157–160, 168, 171, 172, 178, 179, 183,
state capitalism 12, 20, 52, 83, 89, 91, 119, 184, 186–188, 190–193, 202, 203, 205–207,
213, 249 225, 235, 236, 247, 253, 268, 271, 273, 274,
subsistence 3, 9, 12, 13, 19–21, 23–25, 28, 29, 278, 280–282, 285, 288–292, 294, 296,
33, 34, 37, 52, 65, 74, 76, 95, 101, 149, 151, 302, 327
176, 178, 185, 195, 223, 224, 234, 238, 262, use value 3, 40, 41, 232
263, 267, 268, 278, 288, 293, 300, 308, 311, USSR 1, 119, 289
313, 316, 322, 326, 333
superstructure 35, 51, 209 Venezuela 158, 172
surplus 21, 24, 34, 38, 44, 46, 59, 71, 137, 142,
143, 146, 151, 155, 156, 187, 199, 219, 309, war crimes 196, 281, 293
316, 318, 319, 321, 325, 332 war on drugs 168, 192, 205, 229, 274, 277
surplus-value 3, 5–7, 11, 39, 40, 45, 48, 49, Western capitalism 4, 70, 91
62, 73, 85, 97, 99, 109, 116–118, 123, 126, Western Europe 51, 71, 72, 83, 85, 87, 89,
129–131, 133, 138, 141, 146, 151, 152, 155, 175, 310, 311
183, 203, 239, 240, 313, 319, 326 worker movement 84, 89, 99, 115, 135, 143
surveillance 268, 269, 283–287 worker organization 47, 78, 84, 88, 91, 103,
synthetic analysis 4, 56 104, 111
systemic crisis 7 working class 2, 3, 5, 11, 18–21, 24, 25, 28, 38,
40–44, 46, 49, 75, 78, 84–93, 96, 101, 105,
Taylorism 92, 109, 134, 141, 142, 312, 315 106, 109, 111, 115, 116, 118, 126, 129, 131, 137,
technological revolution 6, 10, 12, 44, 117, 138, 155, 156, 185, 187, 206, 207, 214–217,
123, 125, 130, 133, 140, 142, 146, 151, 203, 219–221, 229, 233–235, 244, 259, 260, 263,
311, 313 265, 274, 303, 304, 308, 313, 316, 317, 323,
terrorism 1, 7, 8, 12, 168, 173, 185, 188, 191, 325–329, 333
201–205, 212, 225, 229, 246, 247, 270–274, World Bank 67, 121, 128, 157, 158, 160–162,
277, 283, 290, 291, 303 166, 169, 179, 185, 186, 301
Thanatophilia 231, 234, 235, 236, 274 World Competitiveness Center 164, 165
The Factory Acts 47 World Economic Forum 164, 167
The New Deal 93 World Trade Organization (WTO) 6, 132,
Third International 89, 91, 94 158, 160, 165, 169, 279, 285
third-generation monopolies 8 World War I 84, 92
trade unionism, 42, 88 World War II 83, 89, 93, 95, 101, 310
INDEX OF AUTHORITIES
Amin, Samir 40, 96, 127, 282, 317, 318 Lenin, Vladimir 30, 31, 42, 50, 52, 55, 68, 69,
Arceo, Enrique 102, 121, 127–130, 132, 138, 85, 115, 116, 329
146, 147, 149, 154, 163, 186 Lipietz, Alain 109, 138, 141, 144, 149
Lyotard, Jean-Francois 1, 10, 248–251,
Bauman, Zygmunt 184, 209 255–259, 265, 266, 269, 270
Bloch, Ernst 2
Mao 91
Carmagnani, Marcello 80, 82 Marx, Karl 3, 10, 17, 19, 21–23, 25–31, 37, 38,
Chossudovksy, Michel 288–291, 295 41–48, 50, 52, 55, 56, 69, 71–73, 75, 77, 78,
Córdova, Arnaldo 101 81, 84, 86, 115, 133, 231, 233, 234, 236,
Coriat, Benjamín 91–94, 104, 105, 108, 109 238–245, 257–260, 264, 267, 307, 309, 312,
316, 317, 319, 328, 330–334
Figueroa Sepúlveda, Víctor 19, 20, 25–27, 49, Mexico 5, 18, 50, 81, 96, 100, 101, 121, 122,
58–61, 63, 65, 66, 79, 80, 81, 85, 89, 96, 99, 136, 143, 144, 147, 148, 157, 160–163,
102, 120, 121, 125, 148, 149, 162, 163, 312, 313, 166, 170–172, 177, 181, 182, 186, 187, 190,
316, 332 193, 201–203, 205, 223, 229, 235, 274,
Fukuyama, Francis 1, 264–266 275, 277
Morin, Edgar 1
Gramsci, Antonio 1, 32, 35, 50–53, 55, 60, 67,
90, 106, 107, 108, 110, 168, 209, 211, 326, 331 Portantiero, Juan Carlos 66–68, 88, 102,
103, 106–108, 110, 327
Hirsch, Joachim 39, 106, 110, 116, 118, 119,
127, 135, 138, 155–157, 162, 163, 168–170, Roosevelt, Franklin 31, 94
187, 198, 317, 327, 329
Huntington, Samuel 1 Sánchez Vázquez 19, 29–32, 34, 35