Rural Livelihoods - Importance and Definitions
Rural Livelihoods - Importance and Definitions
Rural Livelihoods - Importance and Definitions
Definitions
Unit Information 2
Unit Overview 2
Unit Aims 2
Unit Learning Outcomes 2
Key Readings 3
Further Readings 5
References 5
Section Overview 7
Section Learning Outcome 7
1.1 Setting the scene 7
1.2 The importance of rural livelihoods 8
1.3 Structural characteristics of rural livelihoods 9
Section 1 Self Assessment Questions 13
Section Overview 14
Section Learning Outcomes 14
2.1 Livelihoods 14
2.2 Livelihoods: multiple linkages and multipliers 21
Section 2 Self Assessment Questions 26
Unit Summary 27
UNIT INFORMATION
Unit Overview
This unit discusses the importance of rural livelihoods in the world economy and their
distinctive features. Two aspects of this are, first, their dependence on both
agriculture and natural resources on the one hand, and non-agricultural activities on
the other and, second, the importance of activities which are not directly linked in to
the formal markets that form the context of much conventional economic analysis.
These differences lead to recognition of the need for different analytical techniques in
describing and understanding their activities and achievements and the opportunities
and constraints they face.
The unit describes the use of sustainable livelihoods frameworks in analysing rural
livelihoods and outlines some weaknesses of representation which omit market
interactions, institutional failings, and technological changes from its
conceptualisation.
The unit emphasises the complexity of studying rural livelihoods and the need to
assess interactions within livelihood systems and between them and their wider
economic, social, and political environments.
Unit Aims
To assess the importance of rural livelihoods in national and global economies
and communities.
outline the characteristics which define peasant livelihoods and discuss their
relevance to rural livelihood analysis
explain the livelihoods concept and critically appraise the use of sustainable
livelihoods frameworks for rural livelihood analysis
© SOAS CeDEP 2
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
KEY READINGS
Now read Section 2, review of African evidence. Note down the main points that the authors
draw from the literature. How do these compare with the points made in the study guide? (You
should note that Bigsten and Tengstam use the term ‘distress diversification’ to describe
diversification driven by ‘push’ incentives.)
You may want to skip the next two sections. These contain interesting and valuable information
on the study, but are not essential to drawing out the main points from the paper.
Now spend some time looking at Section 5. Look at Table 2 and note how income structure
changes between quintiles (quintile 1 is the poorest 20% of people, quintile 5 is the richest 20%
of people, ranked by income). What are the main differences you note between quintiles? Do
these agree with the authors’ comments in the text? Note down the main conclusions from the
description of the pattern of income diversification. The authors then classify households by
their combinations of source of income, to identify livelihood strategies. Tables 3 and 4 look
interesting — but beware that for livelihood strategies with a very low frequency the small
number of observations makes estimates of total income unreliable. This is one consideration
driving the authors’ use of econometric analysis to go beyond the use of tables and descriptive
statistics. Section 6 is largely taken up describing this analysis and you do not need to read it as
its conclusions are summarised in the last section, on policy conclusions. As you read this
section, in the context of the whole paper, do you agree with the policy recommendations? How
far are they supported by the empirical findings from the paper, and how far do they take
account of different linkage effects discussed in the study guide?
© SOAS CeDEP 3
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Turin C, Valdivia C (2012) Off-farm work in the Peruvian altiplano. In: Devereux
S, Sabates-Wheeler R (eds) Seasonality, Rural Livelihoods and Development.
Earthscan, pp. 145–162.
This chapter analyses the importance and nature of off-farm work in two different communities
in the Peruvian altiplano, with a particular emphasis on how this is affected by seasonal issues,
and how the nature and timing of off-farm work is affected by people’s other activities and by
different aspects of their environment. Use this chapter as a case study to examine some of the
points made in the study guide regarding the nature of rural livelihoods:
Which of the structural characteristics of rural livelihoods listed in Section 1.3 of the study
guide are found in the descriptions of the livelihoods of people in the two communities?
How far does discussion of rural off-farm work in this chapter match discussion of the RNFE
in Section 2.1 of the study guide and the patterns reported by Haggblade et al (2007)?
© SOAS CeDEP 4
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
FURTHER READINGS
Haggblade S, Hazell P, Reardon T (2005) The rural nonfarm economy: pathway out of
poverty or pathway in? In: The Future of Small Farms. Proceedings of a research
workshop, Wye, UK, June 26–29, 2005. International Food Policy Research Institute,
Washington, DC, pp. 151–178.
Reardon T (1998) Rural non-farm income in developing countries. In: The state of
food and agriculture 1998. FAO. Food and Agriculture Organisation, Rome.
World Bank (2007) World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development.
pp. 30–35, 84–89, 90–92.
Available from:
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWDR2008/Resources/WDR_00_book.pdf
pp. 30—35 provide an overview of agriculture’s role and potential for development and
highlights the important mixture of production for own consumption and for sale in developing
countries.
pp. 84—89 discuss and emphasise the way that farmers’ options are determined by their assets.
This also introduces wider issues relevant to development opportunities and constraints.
pp. 90—93 introduce the particular features and issues of small farmers.
REFERENCES
© SOAS CeDEP 5
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Dorward (2006) Markets and pro-poor agricultural growth: insights from livelihood
and informal rural economy models in Malawi. Agricultural Economics 35(2) 157–169.
Ellis F (1993) Peasant economics: farm household and agrarian development, 2nd
edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 3–15.
IFAD (2010) Rural Poverty Report 2011. International Fund for Agricultural
Development.
Poulton CD, Dorward AR (2003) The Role of Market Based Economic Development in
Strengthening Food Security. Paper prepared for the ODI Southern Africa Forum on
Food Security, June 2003. Overseas Development Institute, London.
Swift J (1993) Understanding and preventing famine and famine mortality. IDS
Bulletin 24(4) 1–15.
World Bank (2007) World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development.
pp. 30–35; 84–89; 90–93.
Available from:
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWDR2008/Resources/WDR_00_book.pdf
[Accessed 1 July 2013]
World Bank (2011) Improving the Odds of Achieving the MDGs: Heterogeneity, Gaps,
and Challenges. Global Monitoring Report 2011. The World Bank, Washington DC.
© SOAS CeDEP 6
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Section Overview
This unit discusses the importance of rural livelihoods in the world economy and their
distinctive features. It defines peasant livelihoods and examines the reasons why
their characteristics present a need for the use of different analytical techniques to
those used in conventional economic analysis.
The first Millennium Development Goal (MDG) is to eradicate extreme poverty and
hunger with its two targets being, by 2015, to
reduce by half the proportion of people living on less than a dollar a day
(compared with the 1990 figures). It is clear that achieving this goal requires special
emphasis on reducing rural poverty.
Other MDGs concern reducing infant mortality and improving health care and
educational provision. Rural people tend to be dispersed and remote, and these
features, among many, present particular challenges for progress towards many of
the MDGs.
© SOAS CeDEP 7
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
We are already using words that may have different meanings for different people.
We therefore need to discuss what we mean by ‘peasants’ and what we mean by
‘livelihoods’. We also need to decide what it is about the livelihoods of rural people
which demands a different socioeconomic analysis from that we would use to analyse
other more commercially based livelihoods.
Many of the rural poor depend directly or indirectly upon peasant livelihoods.
Poor rural people’s livelihoods are significant in national economies and the
world economy in terms of
– the potential market for increased demand for consumer goods and
services if rural people become more wealthy
© SOAS CeDEP 8
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Understanding these livelihoods is therefore important for our understanding of, and
action to address, rural poverty, the resulting human suffering, and the pressures it
then places on urban areas (through rural–urban migration, national, regional, and
global economies, and the environment).
These points are illustrated by the impact of recent economic growth in China on the
world economy. Until the mid-1970s China’s economy was dominated by a largely
stagnant peasant agriculture, but then technical, institutional, and economic policy
change allowed rapid growth in peasant agriculture in large areas of China, and these
in turn led to a transformation of the economy with global economic, social and
environmental implications. National and rural poverty rates have fallen dramatically.
However, peasant incomes and growth (particularly in more remote areas and in
areas with lower agricultural potential) now lag behind incomes and growth in the
rest of the Chinese economy. Conversely, in many parts of sub-Saharan Africa, per
capita agricultural growth was low and even negative for much of the second half of
the 20th century with increases in both the incidence and severity of rural and
national poverty, very poor national economic performance, and in many areas
increasing pressure on limited natural resources.
For those of us who are not peasants or poor rural people there are, then, compelling
arguments of compassion and self-interest urging us to work with rural people to
improve their quality of life and to extend their control over their environments,
resources, and destinies. However, if we are to assist them (as policy-makers,
researchers or community development workers, for example), we must understand
as far as possible both their environments and their behaviour within those
environments. This is necessary for communication and partnership. It is also needed
for analysis of what they are doing and why, for identification of strategies for
improvement, and for prediction of their responses to change.
We have said that rural, and particularly peasant, livelihoods have certain
distinguishing features. In this section we want to try to define these in terms of
particular structural characteristics and, although it is difficult, reach a definition of
peasants which would satisfy most people and is both operationally useful and
theoretically valid. This involves making generalisations which are widely applicable,
although, owing to the heterogeneity of peasant livelihoods, they will not be
applicable in all cases. It is important that we recognise, however, that we are
looking for a broad definition of peasants that identifies the principal features that we
need to understand: we are not trying to compile a very precise definition that allows
us to classify particular people or households as peasants or not peasants.
© SOAS CeDEP 9
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Peasants are part of larger societies but retain their own distinctive cultural
identities. In a similar way to their partial integration in the economy, they are
partially integrated in society, engaging with larger groups in some ways whilst
maintaining their own social norms and customs. This leads to another widely
stressed characteristic, that of transition.
Transition
Peasants are seen as representing some intermediate state between dispersed, self-
sufficient families and fully integrated members of society and the economy.
Transition implies change over time: it emphasises that peasant livelihoods are
neither static nor fixed, they are dynamic, adapting to changes in their environment.
It should be noted, though, that the direction and timescale of this change is not
defined nor does it mean that peasants are necessarily becoming something else, ie
‘non-peasants’.
Subordination
Partial integration (both economically and socially) means that peasants are
dominated by larger more powerful groups. They are subject to the decisions made
by and the behaviour of others and have limited ability to influence the nature and
impact of these decisions. This places them in positions of risk where they may be
exploited by more powerful groups.
Most peasants are engaged in agricultural activities. This does not mean that
peasants are purely subsistence farmers: most produce at least some food for their
own consumption but peasants also hire out their labour to other farms and engage
in other forms of employment, and they also often buy and sell staple and other
foods. Thus in Eastern and Southern Africa net buyers of staple foods commonly
make up more than 50% of smallholder farmers (and these tend to be poorer
farmers), while the majority of other smallholders are net sellers of food: very few
African farmers are strictly autarchic subsistence farmers (relying purely on their own
food production and not engaging with markets at all) (Barrett 2008). Similarly, the
use of family labour does not exclude the hiring in and out of labour to assist with
own farm production and to supplement income – again poorer households tend to
hire labour out and less poor households to hire labour in.
© SOAS CeDEP 10
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Multi-activity livelihoods
Peasant agricultural production is both for sale and for family needs. The peasant
household is simultaneously the producer and the consumer.
Heterogeneity
We now have a working characterisation of peasants that we shall use with very
minor modification. This is
This characterisation uses the ‘household’ as the unit of analysis. There are
significant difficulties with using the ‘household’ in this way but nevertheless, in
practice, much livelihood analysis does start from an analysis of households. There
are important practical reasons for this, but understanding differences and the
relationships between people within households is another important feature of rural
livelihood analysis.
© SOAS CeDEP 11
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
We see from our examination of the characteristics of peasant livelihoods that many
of the assumptions of neo-classical economics do not apply to the analysis of
peasants’ economic systems. This leads us to the conclusion that in order to
understand many rural people’s behaviour and management of their livelihoods we
will need to adapt more conventional analytical techniques developed for commercial
enterprises and derived from neo-classical principles to take account of the special
features found in peasant livelihoods.
© SOAS CeDEP 12
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Q uestion 1
Q uestion 2
True or false?
Urban and rural poverty are equally important in addressing the Millennium
Development Goal to reduce by half the proportion of people living on less than a
dollar a day.
Q uestion 3
(b) The markets with which peasants engage are often imperfect.
© SOAS CeDEP 13
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Section Overview
This section describes the use of sustainable livelihoods frameworks in analysing
rural livelihoods and outlines some of their weaknesses if they omit market
interactions, institutional failings, and technological changes from their design.
The section emphasises the complexity of studying rural livelihoods and the need to
assess interactions within livelihood systems and between them and their wider
economic, social, and political environments.
2.1 Livelihoods
‘Livelihoods’ is a term that we use in everyday life, and we probably all have differing
ideas about its meaning.
The term ‘livelihoods’ has become increasingly important in development theory and
practice, as it is seen to encompass a wide range of concerns, and to allow inclusion
of the broad range of people’s activities and assets in considering how they support
themselves, rather than focusing more narrowly on economic, income-generating or
formal activities. One way in which this concept has been developed has been
through the formulation of sustainable livelihood frameworks. Many different
frameworks have been developed by many different actors and organisations, each
with their own particular emphases, strengths, and weaknesses.
© SOAS CeDEP 14
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Transforming
Livelihood
Structures & Outcomes
Livelihood
Processes
Assets • More income
Vulnerability Structures
• Increased
Context H • Levels of In well-being
government order • Reduced
• Shocks S Influence Livelihood
N • Laws.. vulnerability
& Access • Private Strategies to
• Policies
• Trends sector achieve • Improved food
• Culture…
P F security
• Seasonality • Institutions
• More
sustainable
Processes
use of NR base
Frameworks such as this aim to represent the main factors affecting people’s
livelihoods and the relationships between these factors. They are not definitive and
should be seen as tools highlighting the complexities involved in thinking about and
interacting with livelihoods.
One of the key features of DFID’s framework is its emphasis on livelihoods assets
and on the different types of capital that make up the ‘assets pentagon’. The
framework stresses first that even poor people have assets (and development
interventions should work from people’s strengths, their assets, rather than promote
dependency by emphasising their weaknesses and problems), and second that
people have many different kinds of asset (or capital) and of livelihood strategy and
income.
Famine
There is a rich and substantial literature concerned with exploring and explaining the
causes of famine and the vulnerability of poor people to these causes. In general
terms, famine is where people do not have enough food, leading to a major deficit in
consumption of basic food and nutrition requirements. This lack of food may be due
to environmental causes reducing crop yields, eg pest or disease attack or too little
or too much water. It may also be due to economic constraints such as having too
little money to purchase inputs or a shortage of land or labour to cultivate sufficient
crops. These may be termed production failures, where, for whatever reason, not
enough food has been grown.
© SOAS CeDEP 15
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Following seminal work by Amartya Sen (Sen 1981), however, much of the literature
has been concerned with other, perhaps less obvious but more ubiquitous, causes of
famine: this is where there is sufficient food in a locality or market system to meet
people’s needs, but other factors present a barrier or constraint on people’s abilities
to access that food. Such inability to access otherwise available food is termed
exchange failure. Such constraints or barriers include civil unrest or poor
infrastructure preventing or limiting transportation of food to certain areas or at
particular times. A particularly important form of exchange failure is where food
prices are too high in relation to the income and financial resources of poor people
for them to be able to buy food. Sen uses the term entitlements failure to describe
the inability of people to obtain food because they lack resources with which to buy
or otherwise obtain it from others.
Investments in
Use of stores
directly of food
Claims on
the government
As in the DFID framework the ability of people to access food therefore depends on
their assets. Assets act as a buffer between production, exchange and consumption.
Assets are built up in times of surplus and can be converted into food or production
inputs in times of need. Peasants, and, more generally, poor people tend to have
fewer assets than other groups and may be constrained in the utilisation of those
assets they do possess due to their partial integration in (imperfect) markets and
society. Different assets have different roles in production, exchange and
entitlements.
How would you compare the classification of assets in the DFID sustainable
livelihoods framework and that in Swift’s analysis of assets which people use to
obtain food?
© SOAS CeDEP 16
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Each approach has its relative strengths and weaknesses. The livelihoods
categorisation in the asset pentagon is certainly simpler to understand and
represent, and it places greater emphasis on the particular characteristics of natural
capital, in particular. However, it seems to place less importance on the role of
assets as stores for buffering consumption against fluctuations in production and
exchange activities. Swift’s approach also gives more categorisations of different
types of claims or social capital. Although not explained earlier, Swift also makes an
explicit distinction between private and collective assets.
In the past there was an almost unconscious assumption that the term ‘rural’ more
or less equated to agriculture and that agricultural earnings were the most important
sources of revenue for rural people. There is now a large body of literature
demonstrating that rural non-farm employment (RNFE) activities are very significant
© SOAS CeDEP 17
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
for rural livelihoods. Evidence suggests that RNF activities provide an increasing
percentage of household incomes: examination of the available data indicates that
rural non-farm income (RNFY) comprises around 35% of household incomes in Africa
and 50% of household incomes in Latin America and Asia. It should be noted that
whilst the motives and opportunities for RNF activities vary considerably across time,
location and demographic group, a large percentage of households engage in some
form of RNF employment in addition to undertaking own farm and off-farm activities.
Reasons for participating in RNF employment tend to be categorised into push and
pull incentives, distinguishing between movements out of agriculture because of
improved opportunities in the RNFE (pull) and movements out of agriculture because
of worsening or limited opportunities in agriculture (push).
Pull incentives are dominated by the fact that RNF income tends to be higher
than income from agricultural employment
Push factors vary considerably with location and circumstance but include
RNF activities (particularly the more remunerative activities) often have entry
barriers and require assets which the poor do not have (for example, financial
capital, education, social networks, and links) and hence development of RNF
activities may not benefit the poor.
RNF activities affect agriculture in terms of factor supply, demand, and prices
(particularly for labour and finance).
© SOAS CeDEP 18
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
The implications of this analysis are very important: although the direct share of
agricultural income in rural livelihoods may be smaller than was previously thought,
the development of the agricultural sector remains fundamentally important to the
livelihoods of the poor.
Despite the need for integrated and complementary investments in both agricultural
and non-farm development, there is a tendency for development ‘fashions’ to lead to
policy swings between over- and under-emphasis in agriculture and in non-
agricultural activities. Thus mixed and changing emphases on urban industry and
rural agriculture up to the 1980s gave way to greater emphasis on rural non-farm
activities in the 1990s, with much less investment in agriculture. A number of
agencies and governments began to re-emphasise the need for agricultural
investment prior to the global food price rises in 2007 and 2008, and this gathered
momentum when the 2008 food crisis led to the next turn in the fashion cycle, with
agriculture coming right back to the forefront of development thinking.
Thus far we have looked at rural livelihoods as systems to analyse, with an emphasis
on the different components of the system (assets, activities, etc). At its simplest,
the livelihoods analysis approach provides a checklist of components to consider in
analysing peasant livelihoods. However, it can also be used as the basis for a
framework to think about relationships between different components – for example,
between the different roles and types of assets, between farm and non-farm income,
or between vulnerability, assets, and institutions.
Another way of looking at rural livelihoods is from the point of their management.
One way of looking at management is as a set of related decision-making activities
involving the design, choice, and implementation of strategies which allocate scarce
resources to different activities in order to achieve particular objectives. Some of the
key elements of this definition are illustrated and expanded in the figure in 2.1.3.
© SOAS CeDEP 19
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Objectives
final or intermediate
Resources
The Environment
physical, economic,
social, political etc
What about the time factor? Do all the elements in the figure in 2.1.3
take place simultaneously?
Answer
The cycle presented in the figure does not explicitly show the role of time.
However, decision-making, implementation, resource use, and the
production of outputs all occur at different times. During the season the
environment changes, the elements of a system may change and the
information available changes. Change also takes place between seasons. If
one is studying the behaviour and livelihood management of peasants one
must always keep in mind the dynamic aspects of the management process.
© SOAS CeDEP 20
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
What would be the main effects on people’s livelihoods if a disease epidemic caused
the incidence of sickness to increase in an area?
Although fully addressing this question requires a wide range of information, here we
want to highlight the need for any livelihood analysis to examine the relationship
between direct ‘individual livelihood’ effects and indirect effects through the market
(sometimes these are referred to as first order and second order effects).
Households in which someone becomes ill will be directly affected, as they will lose
labour and income, causing them to become poorer. In households which normally
hire out their labour to others then sickness may reduce their hiring out of labour –
or it may be that other members of the household will try to maintain the same
income and hire out more labour, so that the household still hires out the same total
amount of labour. In households which normally hire in labour from other households
then sickness may reduce the amount of labour they hire in (because the sickness
means they cannot afford to hire in so much labour) or increase the amount of
labour they hire in (to replace the work of the sick family member or of other family
members caring for the sick person).
In these situations we see that sickness might increase or decrease the supply of
labour into the labour market, and decrease or increase the demand for labour. On
© SOAS CeDEP 21
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
the one hand, if there are sufficiently large numbers of people becoming sick, and
the supply of labour were to decrease significantly and/or the demand significantly
increase, then wage rates would be expected to rise. This would mitigate the effects
of sickness on sick households hiring out their labour, but worsen the effects of
sickness on sick households hiring labour in. On the other hand, if sickness caused
the supply of labour to increase significantly and/or demand to fall, then we would
expect labour hiring opportunities and wages to fall, worsening the effects of
sickness on sick households hiring out their labour, but mitigating its effects on sick
households hiring labour in.
The impact of sickness on the labour market may therefore affect sick peoples’
responses to sickness and its impacts on them. However, we must also recognise
that if increased sickness in a community leads to changes in wages then this will
also affect households where no-one is sick – for example, if wages fall then poor
people who hire out their labour will be adversely affected by the epidemic even if
they do not fall sick themselves.
The important principle from this discussion is always to examine effects of, and
people’s responses to, change, taking account of market interactions by asking the
following questions.
(a) How may different people be affected by the direct effects of the change, and
how may they respond?
(b) How may these responses affect supply and demand to and from different
markets?
(c) How may changes in market supply and demand affect prices and wages?
(d) How may these changes in prices and wages affect the responses of people
directly affected by the original change, how may it affect others not directly
affected by the original change, and how may they respond?
Of course these new changes then lead back Question 2! The processes are dynamic
and feed into, and out from, intra- and inter-market interactions.
The insights above emphasise the importance of demand, supply, and prices in
exchanges of labour and products between livelihoods within a rural economy. These
are explored further below. It is important to note, however, that consideration of
demand, supply and prices in such exchanges does not depend upon neo-classical
economic assumptions regarding competitive markets: there are other schools of
economics which emphasise the importance of other forms of exchange and
interactions of importance to rural livelihoods. We highlight one approach, termed
new institutional economics, which is particularly relevant to the analysis of
situations where economic agents are ‘partially integrated into imperfect markets’.
New Institutional Economics (NIE) is a broad school which examines and
highlights the importance of transaction costs, institutional arrangements, and
collective action for economic opportunities and operation. Without needing to go
into detailed analysis it is important to realise that where economic activity is low,
markets are imperfect and transaction risks high (as is the case in rural people’s
economic environments) transaction costs tend to be high and institutional
arrangements tend to be incomplete, missing or ill-structured for poor people’s
livelihoods opportunities.
Such economic environments can result in the existence of a ‘low level equilibrium
trap’ for rural people, where poverty, low levels of economic activity, and constraints
© SOAS CeDEP 22
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
to market and technical development all reinforce each other, as shown in the figure
in 2.2.1.
The main points here are that market imperfections and both the types and
processes of institutions play an important role in determining rural people’s abilities
to access and utilise economic and livelihood opportunities.
Multipliers
In understanding the importance of markets for rural livelihoods we also need to
recognise that markets are not just important in setting prices and allowing people to
exchange goods and services, they also play an important role in economic growth
by multiplying benefits of change in an economy. This aspect of market linkages
between rural livelihoods is critical for rural livelihoods analysis.
How does this work? Consider what happens if one person or household gains an
extra unit of disposable income, and extra $1.00 say. This $1.00 will normally be
used and circulated within the economy: if spent or loaned then it will provide an
income or loan to someone else, who will then also have an extra $1.00 to loan or
spend, and so the benefits of that initial extra $1.00 will be ‘multiplied’ through the
© SOAS CeDEP 23
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
economy, prompting changes in demand and supply and generating wider returns.
These effects of expenditure, leading to a greater economic benefit than the face
value of the initial income and expenditure change, are known as multipliers. They
do not go on forever because some extra income is spent outside the economy on
imports, savings or remittances (and so escapes), some leads to inflation, and some
may just be stored away as cash.
Calculation of multiplier values is complex and multiplier values vary with location
and situation. However our consideration of multipliers highlights the need to
consider a wide range of other ‘linkages’ whereby income or other changes in some
livelihoods or parts of the economy affect other livelihoods or parts of the economy.
Thus, for example, the effects of increased disposable income in poor rural areas
may include:
Direct effects
– Increased local business incomes (in turn, feeding back into increased
demand for local raw materials)
– Changes in local labour markets with reduced supply and increased demand
for labour leading to a ‘tightening’ of labour markets, reduced local
unemployment and increased wages – unless there is investment in labour-
saving technology or equipment or the local economy draws upon a large
pool of migrant labour
The general picture is of benefits to a local economy exceeding the face value of the
initial income changes, but it is important to note that effects vary (for example, with
the openness of a local economy and its connection to other areas through different
imports, exports and flows of labour and capital) and to think carefully about how
livelihood opportunities interact with and through markets and how the wider socio-
economic environment may respond to, and feedback into, such changes.
Using the list of direct and indirect effects above, try to trace through
the impacts of either an increase food prices or reduced staple food crop
yields due to climate change. Share and discuss your ideas on the on
line environment. How may consideration of diversity between
households affect these linkages?
© SOAS CeDEP 24
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
© SOAS CeDEP 25
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Q uestion 4
Q uestion 5
Rural non-farm activities are _______ for many rural households. The rural non-farm
economy is _______ on agriculture through direct and indirect _______ and also
affects agriculture in terms of _______, demand and prices.
Q uestion 6
Distinguish between ‘human capital’ and ‘social capital’ as used in the asset
pentagon.
© SOAS CeDEP 26
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
UNIT SUMMARY
The importance of poor rural people’s livelihoods in the world economy derives from
the number of people involved and their poverty.
Growth in poor rural people’s livelihoods provides the potential for increased
markets.
Rural poverty accounts for a major part of global poverty and of national
poverty in poor countries.
Many poor rural people may be considered as peasants, and others which do not fit
into a strict definition of ‘peasant’ nevertheless share many of their structural
characteristics and are directly or indirectly dependent upon peasant agriculture for
their livelihoods.
Livelihoods are defined as ‘the capabilities, assets, and activities required for a
means of living.’
Peasants are partially integrated into their wider economic, political and social
environments and these features affect, and are affected by their livelihood
opportunities and choices. There are many linkages and interactions between
peasants and their environments.
The Rural Non-farm Economy (RNFE) is important for many rural households and
may provide a significant proportion of their income. The links between agriculture
and the RNFE are also very important, especially in the early stages of economic
growth where agriculture is a major economic sector and many RNFEs are dependent
on or directly related to agriculture.
© SOAS CeDEP 27
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
Q uestion 1
(a)
(c)
(f)
Activities
Livelihood decision-making
Objectives
Outputs
Resources
The environment
Q uestion 2
How might a local shock cause labour wage prices to increase or decrease?
Q uestion 3
© SOAS CeDEP 28
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
© SOAS CeDEP 29
P535 Socioeconomics of Rural Livelihoods Unit 1
social capital denotes the social resources which can be drawn upon to
assist with pursuing livelihood activities and strategies. It
includes networks of acquaintances and friends,
relationships with patrons, and memberships of wider
groups
sustainable livelihoods are conceptual models used to represent factors affecting
frameworks people’s livelihoods and the relationships between them.
They can be used as a checklist of components to
consider in analysing peasant livelihoods and also as a
basis for thinking about relationships between different
components
transaction costs are the costs incurred in obtaining information about
potential contracts, negotiating contracts, and enforcing
them
© SOAS CeDEP 30