Fred Halliday (Auth.) - Rethinking International Relations-Macmillan Education UK (1994)
Fred Halliday (Auth.) - Rethinking International Relations-Macmillan Education UK (1994)
Fred Halliday (Auth.) - Rethinking International Relations-Macmillan Education UK (1994)
Fred Halliday
M
MACMILLAN
Fred Halliday 1994
All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of
this publication may be made without written permission.
Acknowledgements viii
Preface IX
2 Theories in Contention 23
Traditional Empiricism: History and the English School 24
'Scientific Empiricism': the Siren of Behaviouralism 27
Neo-Realism: 'System' without Content 31
The Tallest Story: Post-modernism and the International 37
Conclusion: Another Path 46
Notes 245
viii
Preface
IX
x Preface
1
2 Rethinking International Relations
Formative Influences
upon it, and in particular of the external factors affecting it- if, in
effect, it evolves an acceptance of its own sociology of knowledge.
A body of thought can relate to the 'real' world in an effective and
critical way not by suppressing these connections, but by establish-
ing a distance from them, in both the priorities set and the
consciousness of how external factors have affected it. The history
of IR provides many examples of how this external constraint was
not adequately recognised, as does the history of social science in
general, and indeed of natural science. The priorities of the
subject have, in the main, been the priorities of elites and of states,
when not directly framed by the demands of state-related funding
agencies. This is true, however, not just for the explicit content of
work itself, but also for two other dimensions of this work: the
issues avoided and not discussed, and the underlying, apparently
neutral, methodologies used. The power of determining outcomes
depends as much on determining what questions are not raised,
and on excluding 'unacceptable' methods, as on imposing a
particular analysis. The extraordinary misrepresentation by IR of
the dominant conflict of the latter half of the twentieth century,
the Cold War, a subject discussed in Chapters 8 to 10, is a
remarkable case of ideological occlusion, the erection of a body of
knowledge serving not to illumine but to obscure a historical
process.
Equally, the dominance of inflatedly 'scientistic' methodologies,
or of their conventional opposite, ahistorical concepts of the
international 'system', have served to preclude other forms of
discussions within the discipline, notably on the role of values, and
on the linkage between domestic and international politics. As
Chapter 4 indicates, the flight from what is, in both domestic and
international politics, the central actor and concept, the state,
serves analogous ideological functions. If the recovery of IR's
history involves recuperation on all three levels- discipline, social
science, history itself- a reconstitution or rethinking of the subject
will simultaneously have to be aware of its significance in all three
of these dimensions.
The chapters that follow are one attempt to 'rethink' Inter-
national Relations along these lines. The next chapter is an
attempt to provide a critique of four major trends in the literature
from within the first circle, that of the discipline itself; the five
chapters that follow seek to broaden the discussion to relate
22 Rethinking International Relations
23
24 Rethinking International Relations
All social sciences face, from within and without their particular
disciplines, the argument that the 'facts' are enough, and that
theories, concepts, specialist language are unnecessary, examples
of 'jargon' and of academic pretension. This is particularly true of
International Relations: as a result of its 'invisibility' most of those
concerned with international issues, or having an opinion on them,
seem unaware that any specialist, conceptually specific, literature
on the subject exists. From within the discipline too, there are
pressures in this direction: the diplomatic historians for one have
long been wary of concepts and models and are quick to point to
what they regard as aberrations in this regard; robust and practical
dismissal of the need for such work recurs again and again in the
literature. 3 For students, coming to the subject for the first time,
the idea that there needs to be theoretical work often comes as a
surprise: Surely the facts are sufficient? And knowledge of the
Theories in Contention 25
Indeed, for all its concern with international process, and, more
recently with international economic processes, the literature on
international relations seems remarkably shy of using the term
'capitalism' at all. One of the consequences of this neglect is that
realist theory, and the history it implies, has a distinctive account
of how states and the international system interrelate. According
to this myth, states emerged as individual entities and then began,
gradually, to have relations with each other. Thus Waltz:
'Structures emerge from the coexistence of states' .24 This ignores
one of the central lessons of historical sociology and its account of
the development of states, which is that states, in the sense of
administrative-coercive entities, develop as a result of inter-
national processes, and not the other way around. Military
competition and the expansion of a market, together with the
existence of a shared culture, were not the results of, but the
preconditions for, the emergence of the state system. The
orthodox view that states arose first and then began to interrelate
to constitute an international system bears about as much relation
to reality as the myth of the social contract, or the stork.
The confusion about the history and definition of states is
evident in the second major difficulty with Waltz's analysis,
namely the claim that international relations can and should be
studied at a purely systemic level. The arguments Waltz advances
for this are rudimentary: that there is sufficient regularity in inter-
state relations to enable us to dispense with examinations of the
internal workings of states, and the, more general, claim that
'elegance' of theory is desirable. Waltz's formulations on this are,
again, revealing. His argument that systemic factors must be taken
into account in analysing international relations, i.e. that states are
not simply free to do what they want and are constrained by the
system as a whole, is unexceptionable. Thus he plausibly states: 'It
is not possible to understand world politics simply by looking
inside of states' (my italics). 25 This is, however, quite different
from arguing that the internal processes of states can be excluded
altogether from a theorisation of international relations: the move
from saying international relations cannot be studied 'simply' by
looking at the internal workings of states to saying that the internal
workings can be ignored is an important, and invalid, one.
Perhaps under the influence of other uses of the term 'structure',
su:;h as those in anthropology or linguistics, Waltz is drawn to a
36 Rethinking International Relations
considerations: first, that the role of these movements was far less
than often claimed, and that they were, as often or not, riven by
their own dissensions and factionalisms as much as any party of the
old sort; secondly, that while some movements were of a benign
and emancipatory kind, many others were not - mass movements
of a racist kind, in Germany and France, for example, Hindu and
Islamic fundamentalism, or the multiple expressions of the US
right, were just as much 'social movements' as the left and green
trends invoked by post-modernists. Their ability to meet two of
the main challenges they claimed to confront - explanation and
identification of an emancipatory subject - was, therefore, rather
limited: like the behaviouralists before them, they issued many a
promissory note.
A Necessary Encounter:
Historical Materialism and
International Relations
A Challenge Evaded
The fate of Marxism within the social sciences has, throughout the
past century, been profoundly uncertain, an ambivalence that has
in some respects been accentuated by the collapse of the
communist movements, and of communist regimes, since the late
1980s. On the one hand, the challenge of Marxism to established
patterns of thought, and to the existing state system, has led to its
exclusion from the academic domain, an exclusion compounded
by the dogmatisms, polemics and simplifications of Marxists
seeking or holding political power. On the other hand, Marxism,
itself part of the radical liberal tradition inherited from the
Enlightenment, and a response, along with the recognisable
academic disciplines of sociology and economics, to the rise of
industrial society, has shared many areas of common ground with
more strictly academic concerns and has in a variety of ways
influenced their evolution. If in some areas this has led to the
emergence of an identifiable 'Marxist' current within the social
sciences, it has a broader influence, one of diffusion,. so that
approaches originally associated with Marxism have become more
generally accepted. In this sense, in Gramsci's phrase, Marxism
has become 'the common sense of our epoch'.
If the ambivalence was accentuated by the communist challenge
and the Cold War, it was certainly made all the greater by the end
of that conflict and of the official challenge that communism
posed. It is now easy to say that Marxism has been discredited and,
47
48 Rethinking International Relations
implicit contrast with the 'national' is not one that they readily
accept: from the cosmopolitan assertion of the Communist
Manifesto onwards, as fine a statement of liberal transnationalism
as one would want to find with its invocations of 'interdependence'
Marxism has seen world affairs confidently in terms of a single
world process: the result was that the very need for a study of
inter-state and international relations might appear to be ir-
relevant, a diversion from analysis of the real, universal, forces
shaping world politics. Marx's view of nationalism, while less
hostile than later critics have suggested, was also one that denied
any necessary contrast or contradiction between the formation of
nations and the growing interlocking of states and societies, the
former being but a precursor to the latter, and part of a broader,
teleological, historical process. 7
issues, IR may now admit the extent to which specific political and
social interests determined its agenda, and the foreign policy of
states: in such a context, historical materialism, itself freed from
dogmatism and conformity, may become more, not less, significant
within the study of the international.
4
State and Society in
International Relations
74
State and Society in International Relations 75
State Back In, 5 which resumes this debate and contains articles by
many of its leading practitioners, suggests a contrary but crucially
relevant development in a cognate discipline to International
Relations which has considerable implications for IR's, often
unwarrantedly solipsistic, discussion on this issue. Equally, the
Marxist debate cuts through any counterposing of states and non-
state actors. What these developments suggest is that one way to
reassess the debate on the state within International Relations is to
study these parallel discussions and in so doing to question the
exclusive definition of the state around which much of the
International Relations debate has implicitly revolved. The argu-
ment is not about whether we are or are not 'state-centric', but
what we mean by the state.
This revival of state theory is particularly relevant to those who
have claimed the term should be abandoned. In a succession of
books and articles published from the mid-1980s onwards Yale
Ferguson and Richard Mansbach have argued that so confused
and inappropriate is the concept of the 'state', that it cannot
provide a basis for theoretical work on international relations. Yet
while they are right to draw attention to the multiplicity of
meanings attached to the state, they are not justified in many of
their other arguments or their conclusions. On the one hand, there
is nothing inherent in the concept of the state, as defined below, to
preclude discussion of the varieties of state power and value
allocation that they draw attention to. On the other hand, they
skirt around, indeed fail seriously to engage with, the literature on
the state that has developed within the sociological literature and
which indeed produced a range of work just at the time when they
were pronouncing the concept unusable. The claim that the term
'state' necessarily has normative connotations is quite unfounded.
Their attempt to relate the uselessness of the concept 'state' to the
broader crisis in IR theory is equally mistaken, based as it is on an
electicism of method and an indeterminacy of concept. The
conclusion that their work leads to is not so much that,
emancipated from the concept of 'state', a new International
Relations is possible, but rather that, if this concept is abandoned,
further confusion ensues. 6
78 Rethinking International Relations
Definitions Contrasted
International Society as
Homogeneity
94
International Society as Homogeneity 95
Men are not tied to one another by papers and seals. They are
led to associate by resemblances, by conformities, by
sympathies. It is with nations as with individuals. Nothing is so
strong a tie of amity between nation and nation as correspond-
ence in laws, customs, manners, and habits of life. They have
more than the forces of treaties in themselves. They are
obligations written in the heart.
At bottom, these are all the same. The writers on public law
have often called this aggregate of nations a commonwealth.
They had reasons. It is virtually one great state having the same
basis of general law, with some diversity of provincial customs
and local establishments. From this resemblance in the modes
of intercourse, and in the whole form and fashion of life, no
citizen of Europe could be altogether an exile in any part of it.
110 Rethinking International Relations
this creates for the organisation of labour, the state and education:
124
Revolutions and the International System 125
milieu of the twentieth century. The least that can be said here is
that the role of revolutions, a Ia Hannah Arendt, has been
systematically understated.
The second area of enquiry is descriptive, the examination of
the international dimensions of revolutions themselves, to ascertain
how far any regularities of political behaviour can be identified.
The existing, mainly realist, account of the international system
assumes that it has already ascertained what these regularities are,
and finds them confirmatory of realism's assumptions: there may,
however, be more to the story than that.
The third, most fundamental, area of enquiry concerns theory,
that is, what theoretical issues the study of revolutions poses for
IR. This leads to an examination of how far each of the established
paradigms can, and cannot, cope with a proportionate
acknowledgement of the importance of revolutions, and how far
apparently central assumptions of the discipline may need re-
examination in the light of such an investigation. This theoretical
probing, however, takes us beyond the domain of IR: it involves a
two-way process, one that should examine not only how revolutions
affect IR, but how far proper consideration of the international
context can pose questions for established sociological or political
explanations of revolution.
Historical Patterns
such commitments are tempered, but this should not detract from
the recurrence of the internationalist commitment in modern
revolutions, from the Girondins, through the Comintern, Lin Piao
and Che Guevara, to the pan-Islamic appeals of Khomeini, and his
espousal of sudur-i inqilab, or 'export of revolution': indeed in
this, as in many other respects, it is striking how true to form, how
conventional, Iranian revolution has been, beyond its particular
religious form. 23
The argument as to which provokes which, international
revolution or international counter-revolution, is in historical
perspective misplaced: both processes can begin autonomously,
for internal and systemic reasons, and, feeding on each other, lead
to confrontation. If revolutionary internationalism is an almost
universal result of revolutions, so is its opposite, counter-
revolutionary internationalism, the attempt by status quo powers
to prevent the spread of revolutions and reform and, where
possible, overthrow revolutions.
Two more issues that this interaction poses are perhaps more
rewarding and take us to the heart of the international system.
One is the issue raised by Richard Rosecrance and Raymond
Aron, and further developed by Stanley Hoffmann (and discussed
in Chapters 5 and 8), of the tendency of the international system to
homogeneity, that is, towards a similar organisation not just of
relations between states, but of the internal political and social
systems of states. 24 Both revolutionary and counter-revolutionary
internationalism derive from this tendency to homogeneity, which
goes beyond any specific international security considerations
about the military threat posed by one state to another (the point
is not whether the Sandinista regime in Nicaragua in the 1980s,
did, or could ever, pose a military threat to the USA).
The second issue which the record of both forms of inter-
nationalism points to, despite the claims of intervention, is the
durability of the states system. All revolutionary states have tried
to promote revolution abroad to 'export' it; in the straightforward
sense of the term, none has ever succeeded. Khomeini's failure to
promote revolution in Iraq in the early 1980s, or the Sandinistas to
ensure a guerrilla victory in El Salvador in the same period, were
true to form: there can be few images of international relations
more inaccurate than that of the 'domino theory'. The creation of
comparable regimes in neighbouring states has come only through
138 Rethinking International Relations
War. The First World War led to the Bolshevik Revolution which
determined Russia's role in the Second World War and beyond.
Inter-state conflict, and more broadly inter-societal conflict, led to
the collapse of communism in the late 1980s. By focusing only on
the 'systemic', Waltz's model paradoxically downplays the force of
the international. Following inter-state competition and its impact
within society, changes occur that then lead to further inter-state
conflict. As discussed in more detail in Chapter 5, this is the
formative interaction that has shaped so much of international
history.
Chapter 4 has already outlined an argument on differing
implications of the concept 'state' for international relations: here
it is possible only to summarise the implications for the study of
revolution. Revolutions are about states, and yet IR operates with
a problematic, increasingly contested, concept of the state itself.
As much as other developments in IR and elsewhere in the social
sciences, revolutions compel introduction of the new, second,
concept of the state, a sociological category of the state as an
administrative-coercive entity, in addition to the legal-political one
normally used in IR.
The concept of the state conventionally used (if rarely defined)
in IR precludes examination of precisely those processes that
make revolutions international: the effects of inter-state competi-
tion on state-society relations, the weakening of state-society
links by the impact of revolutions in other states, the determina-
tion of revolutionary foreign policy by the state-society conflicts of
post-revolutionary periods.
The second, more restricted concept of the state enables us to
see states in their Janus-like character, as the two-faced entities
that look both inwards, towards the society they seek to dominate,
and externally, towards other states and/or societies with which
they interact with the goal of strengthening their own internal
positions. With this two-faced concept of the state it also becomes
possible to re-examine a feature of the international system that
conventional theory takes for granted but to which it supplies
tautological or axiomatic replies, namely, why states compete; in
particular one can ask why, as the realists themselves often note,
competition between ideologically antagonistic, i.e. hetero-
geneous, states is more enduring and comprehensive than those
between states of similar orientation. The conventional answers,
Revolutions and the International System 141
able to come to power in Poland, the fate of the other regimes was
sealed.
The problem of homogeneity goes, however, beyond this issue
of alternative examples, in that it obscures what is perhaps a more
fundamental issue: namely, the role of homogeneity in a positive
sense in reinforcing states, that is, in reinforcing the 'normal'
interaction of stability of states. States are not isolated units: they
exist in an international context, and their practices, constitutions,
social and economic orders derive reinforcement from the fact that
other states behave like them. Nor is this a recent development, as
the literature on 'interdependence' too easily implies. Capitalism
and the modern state arose in an international context, not the
other way around.
This points to the idea that the international dimension is central
to explanation not only of the destabilisation of states when there
is heterogeneity, but also to the stability of political and social
orders when there is homogeneity. Most of the sociological
literature on this underplays the international dimension: whether
in the Durkheimian debate on common culture and its role in
social cohesion, or in the Marxist debate on the dominant
ideology, there is inadequate recognition of how the force of
international example through similarity and reinforcement serves
to consolidate specific social orders. 27 Yet the most important
underpinning of any ideology, the claim that what exists in a given
social and political order is eternal, natural and immutable,
derives confirmation from such a reinforcement. Once it becomes
evident that there can be different orders in other states - that
there can be republics, or countries where women have the vote,
or where houses can be properly insulated- then the 'naturalness'
of any given order collapses.
In other words, the key to understanding the ideological
challenge of heterogeneity lies in identifying the pre-existing
ideological role of homogeneity and reinforcement. If nothing
else, this serves to bring out the importance of the 'international'
in analysing any one social or political order: the 'international'
does not just become relevant when things break down - when
there is a political menace from outside, an invasion, a rival
economic power- but is equally important in the constitution and
reproduction of stable, apparently self-standing and autonomous,
states. The 'international' (like health) matters when things 'go
Revolutions and the International System 143
Over the last two and a half decades questions of gender, and
particularly those concerning the place and role of women, have
acquired much greater importance within the social sciences as a
whole. In response to the rise of a women's movement in some
Western societies, and to the production of a growing body of
analytic literature pertaining to women's position, there has been a
marked development in the agenda and concepts studied in a
range of academic disciplines. If this has been especially noticeable
in history and sociology, it has also been evident in political
science, economics and anthropology, and has acquired great
importance in the most ideologically constitutive of the humanities,
literature. 1 Until the very end of the 1980s there was, however,
one outstanding exception to this growing awareness of gender
issues, namely International Relations.
A survey of the articles published in, and books reviewed by,
the main British and American journals of international relations
during the 1970s and 1980s will reveal little if anything on gender
questions, and little that reflects an awareness of the expansion of
interest in related areas of the social sciences. 2 If one looked at the
contents of standard introductory courses on international
relations, at the major textbooks, at the relevant shelves of
academic bookshops, a similar absence was evident. In the flood
of books published on nuclear strategy, terrorism, third world debt
and the other preoccupations of the 1980s, there appeared to be
147
148 Rethinking International Relations
energy, nor ever did its genius soar with a prouder preeminence
over France, than at the time when frivolity and effeminacy had
been at least tacitly acknowledged as their national character,
by the good people of this kingdom.
Transnational Processes
They left the studio and, with a huge press contingent fighting
to get their tape recorders in between the two men, they
stepped into a model American kitchen. The argument
continued as Nixon pointed to all the latest gadgets. 'Anything
that makes women work less is good.' Khrushchev shook his
head, 'We don't think of women in terms of capitalism. We
think of them better.' Nixon said that a prefabricated home like
this one cost only $14,000 in America, well within reach of the
average worker ...
All you need for tea is a couple of drops of lemon juice. I think
it would take a housewife longer to use this gadget than it would
for her to do what our housewives do, which is to slice a piece of
lemon, drop it into a glass of tea, then squeeze a few drops out
with a spoon. That's the way we always did it when I was a
child, and I don't think this appliance of yours is an improve-
ment in any way. 26
Whatever their other differences, of course, both assumed that it
would be women who would make the tea.
160 Rethinking International Relations
To sum up, there are at least four distinct ways in which issues
pertaining to women and the international arena have, through a
variety of processes, received greater recognition in recent years:
through the encounter of feminism with International Relations
theory; through growing recognition of the gender-specific
consequences of a range of transnational processes; through the
emergence of women as distinct actors on the international scene;
and through an increased awareness of the gender component of
foreign policy issues.
She will find that she has no good reason to ask her brother to
fight on her behalf to protect 'our' country. ' "Our country" ',
162 Rethinking International Relations
she will say, 'throughout the greater part of its history has
treated me as a slave; it has denied me education or any share in
its possessions. "Our" country still ceases to be mine if I marry a
foreigner. "Our" country denies me that means of protecting
myself, forces me to pay others a very large sum annually to
protect me, and is so little able, even so, to protect me that Air
Raid precautions are written on my wall. Therefore if you insist
upon fighting to protect me, or "our" country, let it be
understood, soberly and rationally between us, that you are
fighting to gratify a sex instinct which I cannot share; to procure
benefits which I have not shared and probably will not share;
but not to gratify my instincts, or to protect either myself or my
country. For', the outsider will say, 'in fact, as a woman, I have
no country. As a woman I want no country. As a woman my
country is the whole world. ' 29
Inter-Systemic Conflict:
The Case of Cold War
170
Inter-Systemic Conflict: Cold War 171
avoided if only each side had been better informed about the other
(a 'different' policy towards Russia after 1917, China after 1949,
Cuba after 1959, or, for that matter, France after 1789). 5 Such
arguments tended to downplay the necessity of ideological
commitments on either side (to world revolution, solidarity/
rollback, intervention and so forth) and to stress the need for
better information and contact between states supposedly, but not
really, committed to each other's transformation.
The term 'internalist' denotes those approaches that locate the
dynamic of Cold War within rather than between the contending
blocs. This approach has several variants: it can locate the source
of conflict either within the domestic politics and socio-economic
structure of the two major states themselves, and, by extension,
within the other constituent states; or it can do so within the
internationally constituted bloc itself, seen as an ensemble where
Cold War is functional to the maintenance of bloc cohesion and
the hegemony of the dominant states within it.
The most straightforward version of this is Chomsky's 'two
dungeons' thesis, according to which the USA and the USSR
pursued the Cold War in order to discipline their own societies and
their respective junior partners: 'The Cold War is a highly functional
system by which the superpowers control their own domains. That
is why it continues and will continue'. 6 Mary Kaldor's work has a
similar thrust to it. Arguments such as those of Alan Wolfe, which
attribute Cold War to the workings of US domestic politics, are an
alternative version. 7 Michael Cox has, in several articles,
developed an analysis that is rich in diplomatic detail but which,
equally, denies that the Cold War is 'about' anything, other than
the conventional rivalry of two broadly similar, blocs. 8
Many expositions of the 'internalist' thesis focus on the pressure
for confrontation from economic sectors, characteristically the
'military-industrial' complex. E.P. Thompson's theory of
'exterminism' is one of the more elaborate variants of this thesis,
since it sees the arms race not just as the product of what arms
manufacturers themselves want, but of a dynamic that has come to
characterise the societies in question as a whole. 'Internalist'
arguments tend to deny the efficacy of East-West conflict as such
and to imply a degree of homology between the foreign policies
and internal structures of the two blocs. 9
Although mainly formulated in the 1980s, this work had
174 Rethinking International Relations
which the ravens of the Red Square have been predicting with
such complacent confidence since hostilities ceased would have
deep and important repercussions throughout the Communist
world ... no mystical, Messianic, movement- and particularly
not that of the Kremlin - can face frustration indefinitely
without eventually adjusting itself in .one way or another to the
logic of that state of affairs.
Thus the decision will really fall in large measure in this
country itself. The issue of Soviet-American relations is in
essence a test of the overall worth of the United States as a
nation among nations. To avoid destruction the United States
need only measure up to its own best traditions and prove itself
worthy of preservation as a great nation (italics added). 12
Implications
were both ones in which Soviet allies survived, and in the latter
won outright victory.
In the late 1970s and early 1980s US strategists did begin to talk
of 'eroding Soviet power at the margin', i.e. of encouraging revolt
in Soviet third world allies, notably, Cambodia, Afghanistan,
Nicaragua and Angola. But, draining as these contests were, it was
not here that the cracks later appeared, at the end of the 1980s. In
military-technological terms, the contest was equally different:
here, to a greater extent than in any sphere of competition, the
contest was in some respects an equal one, even as the USA was
able at almost every point to attain technical superiority over the
Soviet Union.
What is most relevant here is that, in economic terms, the
contrasts between the Ottoman-Manchu model and that of the
USSR were substantial. In addition to losing territory outright to
their strategic rivals, the position of the Manchu and Ottoman
empires, even in the territory over which they retained control,
was eroded by the intrusion of goods from the outside world,
which undermined existing social groups and economic systems; in
time, both empires accumulated foreign debt which they had to
meet by allowing concessions and the supervision of their customs
duties by Western officials.
No such processes occurred in the Soviet context. Given the
control by the state of economic activity in these countries, the
introduction of external goods was mediated by the state and had
virtually no impact on employment and status of social groups
within the countries. The role of foreign trade in the Soviet system
and the manner in which it affected that system were fundament-
ally different from that seen in the Ottoman and Manchu cases.
The provision of Western credit and technology, far from eroding
the power of the communist leadership, served to strengthen it
and, so the West at least believed, enhance its military capability.
Such was the control exerted by communist parties that there was
no question of external officials monitoring or affecting its
revenue-collecting and other functions. As far as export earnings
themselves were concerned, they were boosted in the 1970s by
increased prices for oil and gas, the main Soviet exports, whose
prices in the world market multiplied in that decade. If economic
interaction with, and competition from, the West played a part in
undermining the communist system it was not through weakening
190 Rethinking International Relations
191
192 Rethinking International Relations
(i) From the late 1940s onwards the USSR and the USA were
engaged in an arms race, conventional and nuclear, involving
growing expenditures, and a technological race, in which, for all
major dimensions except space in the late 1950s, tne USA was in
the lead, in the technological field, and remained, in most
dimensions, in the lead in the quantitative domain. 12
(ii) Despite this US lead, the relative burden on the USA was
significantly less, representing between 5 per cent and 10 per cent
of GNP (Gross National Product), whereas for the USSR arms
expenditure represented between 10 per cent and 20 per cent
throughout this period - some Russian officials now say it was as
high as 25 per cent.
(iii) Despite the lack of a direct US-Soviet military confronta-
tion, conventional or nuclear, this arms race represented, in a
Clausewitzian sense, a continuation of politics by other means: it
reflected a search for an elusive but strategically meaningful
measure of 'superiority' over the other, it embodied a pursuit by
both sides of prestige and status in the international arena, and it
constituted a means of pressure on the budget and hence on the
state-society relationship within the other. 13
Given the burden on the USSR, its inability to compete with the
USA, and the evident Clausewitzian rationales of the arms race, it
is frequently argued that it was this race which forced the USSR
into strategic retreat in the mid-1980s.
At least three variants of this argument can be noted: an
economic one, that the level of expenditure on arms and the
diversion of resources to the military sector were such that the
USSR could not continue to compete, and needed a drastic
reduction in military expenditure in order to divert resources for
domestic economic reorganisation; a technological argument, that
it was the continued US lead, acutely represented in the early
1980s by two developments, SDI (Strategic Defense Initiative) and
the cruise missile, which forced the Soviet leadership to realise
that it could not continue to compete; and a political argument,
that the dangers of nuclear war and the costs involved forced the
CPSU to abandon the idea of the world as one divided between
two camps, locked in social conflict, in favour of a stress on
universal human values and the common interests of human
kind.
All three of these are, in varying degrees, found in the writings
200 Rethinking International Relations
of Soviet and Western writers and each must certainly have played
a role. Gorbachev himself consistently evoked the third, political,
argument: while the appeal to 'universal' values has a long history
in Soviet- and before that- Russian thought, the power of nuclear
weapons and the accident at Chernobyl in 1986 certainly served to
reinforce this awareness of the dangers of nuclear energy and, by
extension, nuclear weapons.
Important as it is, there are significant reasons for qualifying the
import of the arms race explanation as the major factor behind the
Soviet collapse. Certainly, the economic argument must have
considerable force: indeed the very quantitative figure of 10 per
cent or 20 per cent of GNP being spent on defence understates the
qualitative and distorting impact, with the allocation of the best
administrative and scientific personnel and of key material
resources to this sector.
On the other hand, military expenditure as 10 per cent or more
of GNP is far from being an adequate explanation for the failings
of the Soviet economy. Israel and Taiwan had comparable defence
allocations in the same time period, but enjoyed higher standards
of living and greater rates of growth. 14 Moreover, the very high
rate of military expenditure as a percentage of GNP is but another
way of saying that GNP itself was rather low - the figures for
overall expenditure as between the US and USSR show that in
absolute terms the USA was outspending the USSR. 15
The focus must, therefore, be as much on the efficiency and
allocative mechanisms of the civilian sector as on the claim of the
military on GNP: had the Soviet GNP been rather higher and had
the remaining 80 per cent of the Soviet economy been more
effidenify organised, the 'burden' of military expenditure would
have been less and would, given reasonable efficiency and growth
rates, have represented a lower percentage of GNP anyway.
Similar problems arise with the technological argument: the
assumption of much analysis of the arms race, and of the
conventional Soviet approach prior to this, was that, more or less,
the USSR was compelled by the necessities of inter-state competi-
tion to match the USA in qualitative and quantitative terms.
Previously, the USSR had imitated US advances - as in the
development of multiple-warhead missiles after 1972 and of a
submarine-launched intercontinental capacity: the challenge of
SDI and of cruise missiles were that the USSR had no comparable
The Soviet Union and Inter-State Competition 201
riposte and that there was no evident antidote which it was capable
of producing.
Yet the USSR could have, without a mimetic rivalry, produced
counter-measures to these US challenges - low-flying strategic
missiles plus a system of decoys would have done much to in-
validate SDI, even had it proved viable. A policy of what was
termed 'minimum deterrence' would have made a substantial
difference and enabled the USSR to escape from its self-defeating
pursuit of 'rough parity'.
The third argument relevant to the arms race, the political
argument about the threat to humanity of nuclear weapons, had
great validity in itself and it is to the credit of Gorbachev that he
articulated it more clearly than anyone else: but it does not entail
the overall process of political and social change within the USSR
that accompanied the adoption of /these universal values
associated with 'new thinking'. It is conceivable that the USSR
would have opted out of the nuclear arms race as previously
pursued but insisted on preserving its distinctive political and
socio-economic system. To explain the latter involves looking
beyond the realm of the arms race and its economic, technical and
political costs.
Economic Pressures
benefits to the USSR- getting sugar and nickel that could be paid
for in rubles, rather than having to pay in hard currency; in other
cases, the third world ally was able to provide the USSR with
valuable imports- Afghan gas being one example. Secondly, and
despite current Soviet overstatement of their aid record, the
amount of aid, even on an extended definition, was in comparative
terms very low- 0.25 per cent of GNP, roughly equivalent to the
US record. 19 Politically convenient within the USSR as it may
have become to blame third world allies, who certainly were
mismanaging their economies, for the economic woes of the
USSR, this was hardly a major factor in the economic crisis of the
Soviet system.
As with military expenditure within the USSR itself, the focus of
criticism must go back to the overall system of planning and
production and the inefficiencies it contained, and which were,
incidentally, reproduced by Soviet aid programmes within third
world states themselves. The strategic cost of sustaining third
world allies in the 1980s was certainly rising, as a result of the
'Reagan Doctrine': but if the purpose of the anti-communist
movements was to weaken the USSR at its most vulnerable point
this turned out not to be the case. One of the major reasons for
Soviet and Western involvement in Afghanistan was the
demonstration effect of a ruling communist party being over-
thrown: the impact on Eastern Europe of Kabul falling would,
both sides believed, be potentially enormous. Yet in the end it was
not in Nicaragua nor Afghanistan that Soviet allies were first
overthrown, but in Eastern Europe itself. It was what happened in
Warsaw, Berlin and Prague that did so much to affect develop-
ments in Managua, Aden and Kabul, and not the other way
around.
A Comparative Failure
many ways the vital factor in forcing the Soviet leadership, faced
with this trend, to introduce change, namely the awareness of the
system's comparative failure vis-a-vis the West. It is here, above
all, in the perceived inability of the Soviet system to catch up, let
alone overtake, the West that the central aspect of the Soviet
collapse may be seen. It was a failure to compete internationally
that led to the post-1985 changes in the USSR: once begun, an
attempt to reform the system the better to survive and compete
quickly capsized into the failure to save the state as such.
The awareness of the system's inability to compete in the 1980s
was the final in several stages of such loss of hope. The first,
historical, disappointment was that immediately after 1917 when
the Bolsheviks realised that their revolution would not be
reproduced in Germany. This realisation led to a double redefini-
tion of strategy - temporary abandonment of the idea of world
revolution, proclamation of the idea that a socialist regime could
be built in the USSR. With the victories in the Second World War
and the increase in the number of third world pro-Soviet allies it
appeared for the 1950s and 1960s as if the initial encirclement of
the USSR could be overcome concomitant with the development
of socialism within the USSR itself. The successes of post-war
reconstruction and space technology in the 1950s seemed to
confirm this: hence the new, secularly optimistic, programme of
Khrushchev which combined continued rivalry with the West in
the third world with a policy of socio-economic development
designed to 'catch up with and overtake' the West in two decades.
It would seem, difficult as it is to believe now, that this
perspective, modified by Brezhnev, dominated Soviet thinking
until the early 1980s: there were continued advances in the third
world, the USSR attained 'rough parity' with the USA in the arms
race, and at home it was official policy to state that the USSR was
now at a new state, a stage of 'developed socialism'.
The reality was, however, rather different, as each of the major
areas of inter-state and inter-bloc competition showed. In the most
public and privileged area of competition, the military, the USSR
was, as we have seen, always inferior, in numbers and quality,
except for its conventional strength in Eastern Europe. In the
early 1980s it faced new challenges which it was both forced to
accept and constitutionally unable to respond to, and it lacked
anything like the global deployment capabilities of the USA and
208 Rethinking International Relations
its allies. If this was the area where the Soviet Union was to
compete the most, it was evidently not doing anything like well
enough.
In the second place, the international system created by the
USSR was markedly weaker quantitatively and qualitatively than
that created by the West. Not only was the international capitalist
market far stronger in terms of economic output, technological
change, and numbers of countries included within it, but its degree
of integration was greater: one of the paradoxes of planning within
the USSR and the Soviet international system more generally was
its inability to integrate sectors beyond giving them separate, if
supposedly co-ordinated, production targets. In the military
sphere a similar disparity and qualitative inferiority prevailed in
the comparison between NATO and the Warsaw Pact. For all the
talk of constituting a new world order, the Soviet one was less
integrated and much weaker overall. 21 In many respects, not least
innovation and pricing, it remained dependent on the capitalist
system, and ineffectually imitative of it.
This failure to compete in international terms would, in itself,
have been a major problem, given the fact that underlying East-
West rivalry and Cold War was an attempt by both sides to provide
a new basis for an international order and to demonstrate the
superiority of the one over the other. But this external blockage,
one going right back to 1917 and only obscured by subsequent
international triumphs, was compounded by the internal limits of
the system in many spheres: the failure to match levels of output in
the West, the growing gap in living standards between developed
socialist and developed capitalist states and, obscured by rhetoric
about 'socialist' democracy, the contrast between a substantial
degree of democratic success in the West and centralised political
control in the East. Had the USSR been able to rival the West
successfully in other spheres these internal deficiencies, those
denoted by 'stagnation', might have been concealed the longer,
but it was the failure at the international level that forced the
leadership to face up to them.
Here we come to a central feature of the collapse: almost
impossible to believe as it may now be, it would seem that up to
the early 1980s this contrast in internal achievement was hidden
from, or at least not recognised by, most Soviet observers, in the
leadership or elsewhere. The underlying self-confidence of the
The Soviet Union and Inter-State Competition 209
that of social and economic entities, most notably firms, and that
of ideology and culture - inter-state, inter-socio-economic, inter-
ideological. In addressing the question of 'how' the West put
pressure on the East this tripartite distinction may be helpful.
Operating on the first level, Western state action had effects,
but it was not the only story. The ability of Western states directly
to put such pressure became greater than ever before as the linking
of economic assistance to socio-economic change within the USSR
and Eastern Europe showed: perestroika created the conditions
for, not resulted from, such a socio-economic intervention by
the Group of 7. In the case of Eastern Europe, Western firms-
industrial enterprises, banks - also played a role, especially in
dealings with Poland in the early 1970s and in the handling of the
Soviet oil output. In the opening up that took place from late 1989
onwards, West German business enterprises have taken a role and
a lead, somewhat co-ordinated with, but separate from, that of the
Bonn Government itself. Once the wall had come down it was the
pressure of the West German state, plus the impact of West
German firms, and particularly banks, that combined to render
impossible any reformed regime in the East. It would be
analytically misleading either to reduce state policy in East-West
relations to the wishes of multinational corporations, or to see the
latter as acting simply within parameters laid down by or at the
behest of Western states. Their actions were parallel and usually-
though not always - convergent: the response of sectors of the
business community to political embargoes on communist states
was evidence enough of divergence in this regard.
The ideological and cultural dimension was, however, of even
greater importance: its role in the collapse of communism and in
the East-West rivalry that preceded it was in some ways decisive.
What above all forced the leadership of the CPSU to change
course, and what destroyed the support or acquiescence of the
peoples of Eastern Europe and the USSR to communism, was the
perceived contrast in living standards and in living conditions
between East and West. This ideological dimension is certainly
something that states help to promote and regulate, and which
their information and propaganda organs disseminate, and it is
something which rests upon economic performance, on the output
and sales policies of business corporations. During the Cold War
Western radio stations broadcasting to the East were, in a general
214 Rethinking International Relations
The preceding two chapters have examined the Cold War and its
outcome in the light of two of the themes that run through this
book: the role of 'heterogeneity' of values in international conflict,
and the contribution of socio-economic and ideological factors to
the collapse of the Soviet model. This chapter takes a broader look
at the evolution of the international system, including the collapse
of communism, in order to suggest some ways in which these
events may cast light on the questions raised in preceding chapters
and the degree to which new issues, and priorities, are raised by
them.
In the late 1980s &nd early 1990s the world underwent a strategic
and intellectual earthquake, comparable in effects- though not, at
least initially, in the human suffering - caused by the First and
Second World Wars. A hegemonic system, and its attendant
distribution of power, collapsed. The map of states was redrawn,
and around twenty new sovereign states were created. A degr~e of
uncertainty unparalleled since the 1930s prevailed in the inter-
national arena. The world created by this set of changes
corresponded to no easy model, and rightly provoked considerable
bewilderment. The following chapter, after some general observa-
tions on what it is that occurred in this period, examines different
interpretations of these events, and some contemporary responses
to them. If it avoids prediction, it does, none the less, hope to offer
some analysis of where the international system is going, and of
some possibilities for the future.
216
International Relations and the 'End of History' 217
that was much idealised by intellectuals at the time, but one which
was in the end to collapse almost without trace. 7
Some explanation involving different elements of the candidates
listed above may be most appropriate: it is easy, in retrospect, to
say that it 'never worked', but this attempt to escape the
conventional path of capitalist development was for a time
remarkably successful, not least in the ideological and military
challenge it posed to the West, even if it was in the end forced to
capitulate, and to do so almost without resistance. Although now
seen as inevitable, this was not how the communist experiment
appeared for many decades: both amongst those who supported it,
and those who feared it, there was a belief in the efficacy of
socialist state intervention that subsequent events have belied. If
nothing else, as suggested in Chapter 9, the communist collapse
deservescareful study from the perspective of those who believe in
elite-led or state-dictated social and economic development.
The third element in the end of the Cold War was the break-up
of the USSR, and of its attendant alliance system. Here it was not
at all clear if the process was complete by the end of 1991, not only
with regard to Eastern Europe but also to Russia itself: the
Russian Federation was subject to substantial centrifugal forces
and could yet break up into three parts under international and
internal pressure. Yet even if the process of fragmentation was
complete already, it had unleashed powerful changes in the
international arena. It had created a situation in which, with the
break-up of the pre-existing order, new regional alliances and new
potential hegemons have emerged: in Europe, Germany; in the
Caucasus, Black Sea and Central Asia, Turkey. In the Far East the
realignments were less major, because Soviet power was weaker,
but it encouraged, and coincided with, an increase in both Chinese
and Japanese power. The Far East was indeed the area with the
greatest political and economic range, and promised to be the
fulcrum of the twentieth-first century: whether it could contain
these changes without major military conflict was as yet not
evident. The impact on Indo-China, with the removal of the Soviet
role in Cambodia and Vietnam, and in the North-East Asian
region, was none the less substantial and continuous.
Some of these regional changes took the world back to a
situation before 1914- the pattern of alliances in the Balkans and
in the Baltic were cases in point. Others were new - the Turkish-
International Relations and the 'End of History' 221
suggest, for better or worse, and usually worse, that the power of
states has been eroded by these transnational forces and that there
is less and less that elected governments, or indeed unelected
ones, can do to manage the affairs of their countries. Here, there
has to be considerable caution. First, as discussed in Chapter 4,
globalisation is itself to a considerable extent the work of states,
who direct, stimulate, assist companies to do what they want to do:
no one believes that Japanese or German business operates
independently of the state, nor is it true of their French or Anglo-
Saxon competitors. Moreover, there is much that states can do to
stimulate competition on the internal plane, even if they have lost
some of their control of capital flows and interest rates.
We may, indeed, have to distinguish between two questions: the
first, whether any form of human agency- state-based, or other-
can cope with the problems we face; the second, whether, given
that some purposive strategic response to these questions is
possible, this should be based on the state or an international
body. The concept of 'global governance' has gained currency in
recent years and, shorn of unrealistic aspirations, can be seen as
having several components: the strengthening of existing global
and regional institutions, the evolution of law and norms prevail-
ing to international behaviour, the protection and promotion of
international 'public goods', be these the environment, space,
minerals, or the high seas. Yet however far we go, and can go,
down that road, the components of that governance structure will,
in the main be states, and the considerations that move politicians
or publics to accept them will have to encompass a state-based
('national') interest as much as a global one. 14
The same applies to the domain of legitimate international
competition, and of the major global trends threatening society
which Paul Kennedy has surveyed. If we take the three factors that
Paul Kennedy considers to be the keys to a state's long-run
international competitiveness- the quality of education, the status
of women, the quality of political leadership - then states, and
societies, retain a large measure of freedom in all of these and
have only themselves to blame if they fail to act, or blame
everything on external pressures. The same applies to the great
ecological and demographic threats which Kennedy rightly points
out as hanging over the next century: these are not going to be
addressed, contained or solved, by a global community, or by
228 Rethinking International Relations
one every year from Table 1 of the World Bank Report, namely
that while few countries outside Africa are getting poorer, the gap
between rich and poor states is widening. Moreover, as Giovanni
Arrighi has so well pointed out, 21 the membership of the club of
rich states has remained constant for over a century- no one has
left, although the members have changed places in the pecking
order, and only one state has joined, namely Japan.
The belief in liberal democracy understates the degree to which
capitalist democracy is precarious: it needs to last for a generation
at least before it can be assumed it will endure. One only has to
think about the Weimar Republic, or about such states as Sri Lanka,
Liberia, Argentina, Lebanon in the 1960s to see how dictatorship
can be re-established. In this, historically more cautious, perspect-
ive, there are only about two dozen established liberal democracies
in the world today, out of what are now over 180 independent
states.
This historically superficial view of democracy is linked to an
idealist and most misleading account of how democracy came
about. The dates he gives for the establishment of liberal
democracy -1790 for the USA, 1848 for Britain ~tc.- are those of
constitutional myth. The reality, which Goran Therborn has so
well shown, is that full democracy, including, among other
criteria, one person, one vote, and only one vote per person, came
to these two states in the 1960s, and, as a result not of the
evolution of the system in some idealist manner, but of political
action, of struggle. 22
Here we come to the central theoretical problem of Fukuyama's
work which is not about whether history has come to an end, but
of what constitutes history and, more specifically, historical
agency. Behind all theories of the end of history there lies a theory
of agency. That most people have some working answer to this
question is evident if we just list some of the candidates for motor
of history that have occurred in recent centuries: God, gods, the
stars, Reason, the balance of power, the working class, the
bourgeoisie, the peasantry- indeed virtually every class except the
one that may have done more than any other to shape the
twentieth century, the petty bourgeoisie - the intelligentsia,
conspiracy theories of all shapes and sizes, the economy, and, as
we have recently seen, the market. No doubt more are to come.
Fukuyama's answer is idealist, it being economic scientific
234 Rethinking International Relations
236
Conclusion 237
saw quite a lot of this in 1991-4: one can doubt if they would
recommend it to the world as a whole.
These two questions, of nationalism and intervention, and the
related issues of the great powers, touch upon what is perhaps the
most pervasive and difficult of all the normative issues confronting
the world at the moment, namely that of universal versus
particular values. Since the eighteenth century there has been a
current in Western thought that has asserted the validity of certain
universal, rationally based, moral principles of relevance to
political life- the rights of the individual, secularism, democracy
in some form or another. It has been amplified in recent times to
include more explicit recognition of the equality of gender and of
race. These values are by no means universally supported, nor do
they permit of unequivocal interpretation. But they are now
enshrined in political documents, national and international, and it
is very much part of the optimistic post-Cold-War view of the
world that they are now set to prevail. It has already been
suggested in Chapter 10, that, in any immediate sense, they are
not set to prevail, because the conditions under which, say,
democracy can sustain itself are not given in most countries in the
world.
But there has increasingly been another challenge, to the effect
that these values are in themselves questionable, and that other
value systems, of other provenances, have equal or even greater
value. The proponents of religious fundamentalism are front-
runners in this regard, but there is a broader current, evident in
East Asia, of contesting what is said to be a Western and
ethnocentric value system. Out of sympathy, or support for a
position loosely termed post-modernist, many in the West have
also subscribed to this relativistic challenge to any single grand
normative code.
There is, historically, much validity in this critique: these codes
were produced in particular countries, reflecting their background
and values, and it was not accident that these were in large
measure the same countries who occupied and dominated much of
the rest of the world. 6 Increasing liberty at home coincided with
spoliation abroad. There has also been a great degree of hypocrisy
in the claims made for normative rectitude on the part of the
dominant Western powers: they did more than any others to
violate sovereignty over the past century or two; the greatest
Conclusion 241
Alternatives in Research
more alert and awake. We shall hear, and indeed are already
hearing, much reflection on the end of the century, and the start of
a new millennium. All of this may be portentous irrelevancy, not
least because for much of the world the millennium corresponds to
another chronological system: there are at least six other systems
of counting the years to be found in the world to date - the
Judaic, the Muslim, the Zoroastrian Persian, the Ethiopian, the
Chinese and the Japanese- and their millennia come and go at
different times. There is nothing more ethnocentric than the year
2000. But if the idea of millennium, like that of examinations,
helps to focus minds, so much the better.
Political leaders, elected and unelected, have had a pretty poor
record over the past hundred years, but the scientists, natural or
social, have also had mixed reports. The danger has been not that
social scientists have been too removed from the concerns of
power, political or entrepreneurial, but that they have not had
enough distance from them, have not exerted themselves force-
fully enough to rise above the supposed common sense of their
epoch, and have consoled themselves with the vacuous and the
insignificant: hence, on the part of the natural sciences, the effort
devoted to weapons of mass destruction and the failure, till very
late in the day, to predict the impact of mankind on the
environment, distortions amply reproduced by the social scientists,
including those in International Relations. Here, above all, the
social scientists have often failed to display independence and
intellectual enterprise. For all, politicians and academics, natural
scientists and social scientists, the least that can be said is that the
record of the past hundred years has not been a very good one and
that the enormous suffering visited on humanity can teach us the
better to address the questions we face. Many of the forces that
will shape the next century, and the next millennium, and which
will shape the agenda of politicians and social scientists alike, have
already been unleashed: they had better take stock of them now.
Perhaps it would not be too unrealistic to hope that a better job
can be done in the next century than was made of it in the last.
Notes
245
246 Notes
2 Theories in Contention
Capitalism, and Nigel Harris, The End of the Third World (London;
Penguin, 1985).
17. For an illuminating interpretation see Georg Lukacs, Lenin: A Study
in the Unity of his Thought (London: NLB, 1970), ch. 4.
18. For the original statement see Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern
World System (London: Academic, 1974). See Historical Capitalism
(London: Verso, 1983) for a more succinct statement of his view.
19. Peter Worsley, 'One World or Three: A Critique of the World System
of Immanuel Wallerstein' Socialist Register, 1980; Ernest Laclau,
Politics and Ideology in Marxist Theory (London: NLB, 1977); Theda
Skocpol, 'Wallerstein's world capitalist system: A theoretical and
historical critique', American Journal of Sociology, vol. 82, no. 5,
1977.
20. E.P. Thompson, Fred Halliday and Rudolf Bahro, Exterminism and
Cold War (London: NLB, 1982).
21. Kees van der Pijl, The Making of an Atlantic Ruling Class (London:
Vers9, 1984). Another influential body of work in parallel here is that
of the French 'regulation' school of Alan Lipiers and Michel Aglietta.
For a powerful critique of this school see Alice Amsden 'Third World
Industrialisation: "Global Fordism" or a New Model', New Left
Review, no. 182, July-August 1990).
22. Eric Wolf, Europe and The People Without History (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1982).
23. Perry Anderson, Lineages of the Absolutist State (London: NLB/
Verso, 1974).
24. The Age of Revolutions 1789-1848 (London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson,
1962); The Age of Capital 1848-1875 (London: Weidenfeld &
Nicolson, 1975); The Age of Imperialism 1875-1914 (London:
Weidenfeld & Nicolson, 1987).
25. For the best surveys see Molnar, Marx, Engels et la Politique
lnternationale; on war see Bernard Semmel (ed.) Marxism and the
Science of War (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1981); on nations
and nationalism, see Benner, Marx and Engels on Nationalism and
National Identity.
26. Derek Sayer, The Violence of Abstraction (Oxford: Blackwell, 1987)
for a non-reductionist interpretation of Marx.
27. It is this argument which, in addition to forming the central theme of
the works of Wolf, Anderson and Hobsbawm mentioned above,
forms the basis of Justin Rosenberg's analysis of the origins and
development of the international system: The Empire of Civil Society:
A Critique of The Realist Theory of International Relations (London:
Verso, 1994). I am extremely grateful to Justin Rosenberg for the
many helpful suggestions he has made on the material in this chapter.
28. Eric Hobsbawm, 'Marx and History', New Left Review, no. 143,
January-February 1984.
29. The question of the impact of the Vietnam War on IR, and
specifically on the writing produced in the USA, might appear to be
unanswerable, since its main apparent consequence was to render
Notes 253
some subjects, such as the study of revolutions and social conflict, less
attractive. One answer is, however, that the impact is to be found in
the interest in 'interdependence', since the conflict in South-East Asia
was seen to be provoking major conflict within the USA.
30. Tom Bottomore, Classes in Modern Society (London: Allen &
Unwin, 1965). For one application to IR see Cox 'Social forces, states
and world orders'.
31. One obvious example of this interaction is the oil industry, where, for
a century or more, major corporations have influenced and utilised
states, in producer and consumer countries, to further their interests:
Simon Bromley, American Hegemony and World Oil (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1991). For an outstanding account ofthe
interaction of US banks and the US state see Jeffery Frieden,
Banking on The World (New York: Harper and Row, 1987). For
another revealing study of US foreign policy in terms of the influence
of business see David Gibbs, The Political Economy of Third World
Intervention.
32. This is discussed at greater length in Chapter 6.
33. For one illuminating example of the application of Marxist method to
a major historical event see Ernest Mandel, The Meaning of World
War I/ (London: Verso, 1986).
34. Arno Mayer, Politics and Diplomacy of Peace-Making: Containment
and Counter-Revolution at Versailles, 1918-1919 (New York: Knopf,
1967).
35. See Rosenberg, The Empire of Civil Society, ch. 5.
36. Julian Lider, Correlation of Forces: An Analysis of Marxist-Leninist
Concepts (Aidershot: Gower, 1988); Margot Light, The Soviet Theory
of International Relations (Brighton: Wheatsheaf, 1988).
1. See Harry Eckstein, Internal War (New York: Free Press, 1964), and
James Rosenau, 'Internal War as an International Event' in Rosenau
(ed.) note 9 below.
2. This is a core tenet of realism and nco-realism, despite concessions by
many realists that the exclusion of internal factors is merely an
analytic convenience. Waltz's argument is clearly spelt out in Theory
of International Politics, ch. 4: I have discussed this assumption and
the shifts in argument involved in Chapter 2, above. Examples of
conventional IR suppression of the question of the international
dimensions of revolution are legion. For example, Jack Plano and
Roy Olton's The International Relations Dictionary, 4th edn (Santa
Barbara: Longman, 1988) has no discussion of the general inter-
relationship of the two subjects: an (unindexed)item on revolution
and war discusses only internal aspects. IR literature is replete with
discussion of alliances, yet rarely is it made clear that (a) many
alliances have as their original purpose the suppression of revolution
within member states and (b) that one of the main reasons for the
collapse or ending of alliances is that revolutions occur within some of
the constituents: the fates of SEATO, CENTO and the Warsaw Pact
should make this latter point evident enough- victims, respectively,
of the Vietnamese, Iranian and Eastern European upheavals. Indeed
CENTO fell victim to revolution twice over: its initial form, the
Baghdad Pact, had to be abandoned in favour of CENTO after the
Iraqi Revolution of 1958.
3. See for example the overview of the sociological literature in Stan
Taylor, Social Science and Revolutions (London: Macmillan, 1984).
4. Jack Goldstone, Ted Robert Gurr and Farrokh Moshiri (eds)
Revolutions of the Late Twentieth Century (Boulder and Oxford:
Westview, 1991) p. 41. See also Jack Goldstone, Revolution and
Rebellion in the Early Modern World (Berkeley and Oxford:
California University Press, 1991; Jack Goldstone (ed.) Revolutions:
Theoretical, Comparative and Historical Studies (London: Harcourt,
Brace, Jovanovitch, 1986). For extensive discussion of, and by,
Goldstone see Contention: Debates in Society, Culture, and Science
Winter 1993, no. 5, particularly the article by John Foran, 'Revolu-
tionising theory/Theorising revolutions', which assesses Goldstone's
Revolution and Rebellion. Foran (p. 73) poses the intriguing question
of how far demographic growth can be treated as an independent (by
which he means externally determined) variable, and how far it is the
result of different, national, processes.
5. Fred Northedge. The International Political System (London, Faber &
Faber, 1976), pp. 28-30; Waltz, Theory of International Politics, pp.
127-8. Despite non-conformity on other matters James Der Derian
comes to similar conclusions: On Diplomacy: The Revolutionary State
Notes 261
women for a second hour, and feeling freer with these strangers than
in all my twenty-five years ... maybe the taproot where my greed
was stored was pouring out at last into the American Century, and I,
too, was out there copulating for the flag. Greed having transmuted
itself into a more noble emotion, I felt a glow of inner power as if I
were finally attached to the great wheeling scheme of things.'
8. On Machiavelli, Hanna Fenickel Pitkin, Fortune is a Woman: Gender
and Politics in the Thought of Niccolo Machiavelli, (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1984). On Western theory more
generally, Susan Moeller Okin, Women in Western Political Thought
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1979); Diana Coole, Women
in Political Theory (Brighton: Wheatsheaf, 1988).
9. 'Letters on a Regicide Peace', Letter I, in The Works and
Correspondence of Edmund Burke, vol. 5, p. 257.
10. The classic, and very funny, account of this is Carol Cohn, 'Sex and
death in the rational world of defense intellectuals', Signs, vol. 12, no.
4, summer 1987. The voyeurism suggested by Pentagon videos of
cruise missiles hitting their targets in the Kuwait war may not have
escaped viewers.
11. For general work on political theory and gender see Anne Phillips
Engendering Democracy (Cambridge, Polity, 19??) and Carol
Pateman, The Sexual Contract (Cambridge: Polity, 1988); and Okin
and Coole, note 7. For a critical overview of feminist-IR writing see
Marysia Zalewski, 'Feminist theory and international relations' in
From Cold War to Collapse: Theory and World Politics in the I980s
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993). On international
political theory see the chapter by J. Ann Tickner in Rebecca Grant
and Kathleen Newland Gender and International Relations (Milton
Keynes: Open University Press, 1991) and her Gender in Inter-
national Relations (Oxford: Columbia University Press, 1992).
12. On this see the reports Dame Anne Warburton, EC Investigative
Mission into the Treatment of Muslim Women in the Former
Yugoslavia, Report to the EC Foreign Ministers, February 1993;
Amnesty International, Bosnia-Herzegovina: Rape and Sexual Abuse
by Armed Forces, January 1993.
13. On the Red Army see the symptomatic exchange between Stalin and
his Yugoslav interlocutors on the subject in Milovan Djilas,
Conversations With Stalin (London: Penguin, 1962) p. 87-8. Later (p.
132) we learn that Marshal Zhukov had been dismissed from his post
as commander of the Soviet forces for stealing jewellery in occupied
Berlin: 'You know, Comrade Stalin cannot stand immorality', one of
his advisers confides in the author.
14. For an overview of literature on this see Ruth Pearson, 'Latin
American women and the new international division of labour: a
reassessment', Bulletin of Latin American Research, vol. 5, no. 2,
1986, and, for an earlier analysis, Diane Elson and Ruth Pearson,
'The subordination of women and the internationalisation of factory
production' in Kate Young, Carol Wolkowitz and Rosalyn
266 Notes
Morgenthau, Waltz, etc.- did likewise. For realists, there was not a
conceptual problem.
5. As discussed in Chapter 6, the argument that the conflict between
revolutionary and status quo powers was in some sense avoidable is
found, inter alia, with regard to the French revolution in Kim Kyong-
won, Revolution and International System (New York: New York
University Press, 1970), and with regard to Iran in James Bill, The
Eagle and the Lion.
6. As quoted in Cox, 'Radical theory and the new Cold War', p. 44. For
an attempt to engage with Chomsky on these issues see my discussion
with him in Bill Bourne, Udi Eichler and David Herman (eds) Writers
and Politics (Nottingham: Russell Press, 1987).
7. Mary Kaldor, The Disintegrating West (London: Penguin, 1978) and
The Imaginary War: Understanding East-West Conflict (Oxford:
Basil Blackwell, 1990); Alan Wolfe, The Rise and Fall of The 'Soviet
Threat' (Washington: Institute for Policy Studies, 1979).
8. 'Western capitalism and the Cold War Aystem' in Martin Shaw (ed.)
War, State and Society (London: Macmillan, 1984); 'The Cold War as
a System', Critique, no. 17, 1986.
9. E.P. Thompson, Fred Halliday and Rudolf Bahro, Exterminism and
Cold War (London: Verso, 1982).
10. For one recognition of this inter-systemic dimension see Oyrind
Osterud, 'Intersystemic rivalry and international order: Under-
standing the end of the Cold War' in Pierre Allan and Kjell
Goldmann (eds) The End of The Cold War (London: Martinus
Nijhoff, 1992).
11. 'The sources of Soviet conduct', Foreign Affairs, July 1947.
12. In Evan Luard (ed.) Basic Texts in International Relations
(Macmillan, 1992) pp. 478-9.
13. Two classic discussions of heterogeneity within mainstream IR
literature are Richard Rosecrance, Action and Reaction in Inter-
national Politics (Boston: Little, Brown, 1963) and Raymond Aron,
Peace and War (London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson, 1966).
14. Vendulka Kubalkova and Albert A. Cruickshank, 'The new Cold
War' in 'Critical international relations studies', Review of Inter-
national Studies, vol. 12, no. 3, July 1986, and Fred Haliday,
'Vigilantism in International Relations: Kubalkova, Cruikshank and
Marxist Theory' Review of International Studies vol. 13, no. 2, April
1987.
15. Carl Schmitt, The Concept of The Political (New Brunswick: Rutgers
University Press, 1976); Paul Hirst, 'Carl Schmitt's decisionism',
Telos, no. 72, summer 1987.
16. A powerful historical account of the universalising drive of capitalism
can be found in Eric Hobsbawm, The Age of Empire (London:
Weidenfeld & Nicolson, 1987). What is striking is that this generally
accepted historical thesis, and one eloquently stated in the
Communist Manifesto, should have had so little impact on much left-
wing writing on Cold War in the 1980s: assertions that capitalism did
Notes 271
1. It is striking that the end of the Cold War provoked rather more
theoretical reflection than did the Cold War itself. See Pierre Allan
and Kjell Goldmann (eds) The End of The Cold War (London:
Martinus Nijhoff, 1992); J.L. Gaddis, 'International relations theory
and the end of the Cold War', International Security, vol. 17, no. 3,
1992-3; Lynn Eden, 'The end of U.S. Cold War history? A review
essay', International Security, vol. 18, no. 2, 1993. See also my 'The
ends of Cold War', New Left Review, no. 180, March-April 1990;
George Schopflin, 'Why communism collapsed', International
Affairs, January 1990; Gale Stokes, 'The lessons of 1989', Problems
of Communism, vol. XL, no. 5, September-October 1991; Daniel
Deudney and John Ikenberry 'Soviet Reform and the end of the Cold
War: Explaining large-scale historical change', Review of Inter-
national Studies, vol. 17, no. 3, July 1991.
272 Notes
billions. All data from SIPRI Yearbook 1981, figures in constant 1978
prices. US expenditure was conventionally understated by a number
of accounting devices: one calculation was that the 1980 figure of $127
billions should be adjusted upwards to $223 billions, i.e. from 5.2 per
cent to 9.5 per cent of GNP: James Cypher in Monthly Review,
November 1981.
16. See Brus and Laski, From Marx to Market.
17. For a Soviet view of the western embargo see Igor Artemiev
'International economic security' in International Economic Security:
Soviet and British Approaches, Chatham House Discussion Paper
no.7, 1988.
18. Galia Golan, The Soviet Union and National Liberation Movements in
the Third World (London: Unwin Hyman, 1988); Jerry Hough, The
Struggle For The Third World: Soviet Debate and American Options
(Washington: Brookings Institution, 1986); Fred Halliday, Cold War,
Third World, ch. 4, for the rethinking of Soviet policy towards the
third world.
19. According to OECD DAC figures.
20. On 'stagnation' see Mikhail Gorbachev Perestroika: New Thinking
for Our Country and the World (London: Collins, 1987) ch. 1.
21. On the NATO-WTO comparison see Note 15, above. The degree of
economic integration between the Eastern European Comecon
members was far less than that within the EEC: most trade was on a
bilateral, Soviet-East European, basis.
22. Hedrick Smith, The Russians (London: Sphere Books, 1976) gives a
powerful evocation of this attitude in the period prior to the collapse
of Soviet confidence.
23. Gorbachev's Perestroika is replete with calls for the Soviet economy
to rise to 'world standards' i.e. those of the West.
24. On Kohl's calculations in this period see the diary of his political
adviser, Horst Teltschik, 329 Tage: Innenansichten der Einigung
(Berlin: Siedler Verlag, 1991).
25. Teltschik, 329 Tage, pp. 54-6.
26. Seminar by Gerald Mansell, former head of BBC Overseas Broad-
casting, LSE, November 1992.
1. For overviews see Mike Bowker and Robin Brown (eds) From Cold
War To Collapse: Theory and World Politics in the 1980s (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1993); Robin Blackburn (ed.) After the
Fall: The Failure of Communism (London: Verso, 1991); Michael
Hogan (ed.) The End of The Cold War, its Meaning and Implications
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992); Gabriel Partos, The
World That Came in from the Cold (London: BBC World Service/
274 Notes
3. For further discussion see Fred Halliday, 'The Gulf War and the study
of international relations', Review of International Studies, vol. 20,
no. 1, January 1994.
4. On the uprising and its aftermath see Kanan Makiya, Cruelty and
Silence (London: Century Hutchinson, 1993).
5. James Mayall, 'Non-intervention, self-determination and the "new
world order"', International Affairs, vol. 67, no. 3, July 1991;
Christopher Greenwood, 'Is there a right of humanitarian inter-
vention?' The World To-day, vol. 49, no. 2, February 1993; Adam
Roberts, 'Humanitarian war: Military intervention and human
rights', International Affairs, Vol. 69, No. 3, July 1993; Hedley Bull
(ed.) Intervention in World Politics (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984).
6. For the debate in the Arab world see Kevin Dwyer, Arab Voices
(London: Routledge, 1991) and Anne Mayer, Islam and Human
Rights: Tradition and Politics (London:. Pinter, 1991). Mayer is
particularly interesting on the manipulation of the third world critique
by interested parties within Islamic states.
Name Index
278
Name Index 279
281
282 Subject Index