Trading The Volatility Skew of The Options On The SP Index PDF
Trading The Volatility Skew of The Options On The SP Index PDF
Trading The Volatility Skew of The Options On The SP Index PDF
2 Basic concepts 4
2.2 Payoff . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
2.5 Decomposition of a portfolio profits and losses (P&L) in its greeks components . 7
3 Vertical spreads 9
4.1.1 Delta . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
4.1.2 Gamma . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
4.1.3 Vega . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
4.1.5 Graphs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
4.3.1 Delta . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
4.3.2 Gamma . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
4.3.3 Vega . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
4.3.5 Graphs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
2
5.1.1 Volatility are steepest for small expirations as a function of strike, shal-
lower for longer expirations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
5.1.3 Low strike volatilities are usually higher than high-strike volatilities . . 21
5.1.4 After large sudden market declines, the implied volatility of out of the
money calls may be greater than for ATM calls, reflecting an expectation
that the market will rebound . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
6.4 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
6.5 Strategy C . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
3
1 Introduction and objectives of the work
An option is a financial instrument whose price is derived from another asset, namely the
underlying, that has become very popular over the last 30 years. In many situations, both
hedgers and speculators find it more attractive to trade a derivative on an asset than to trade
the asset itself.
Options prices are generally calculated using the so called Black-Scholes model. Under this model
the price of an option depends (among other things) in a estimation of the future standard
deviation of the underlying (volatility) . Hence each price has an implied volatility. In this
document we propose a trading strategy using certain combination of options called vertical
spreads. The aim of the strategy is to monetize changes in the value of the implied volatility
of the options prices. To do so we first studied the greeks (see section 2 for an explanation)
components of each type of spread, in order to understand the nature of the risks involved in the
spreads trading, and specially how changes in implied volatility affect prices (section 3). Before
trading any kind of option it is mandatory to analyze the behavior of the volatility estimations,
model it, and compare it with the results obtained by other authors, which it is shown in section
4. According to this previous work, in section 5 we propose a trading strategy, which we back
tested using historical data. The features of the strategy and the conclusions are discussed in
section 6.
In section 2 the concepts related to finance needed to follow the document are briefly described.
2 Basic concepts
An option is a contract between two parties: The buyer and the seller. Once the contract is
signed the buyer acquires the right (not the obligation) to buy or sell the underlying for a certain
strike price K to the seller at a certain date in the future namely the expiry date or maturity.
The buyer is said to be long in the contract, whereas the seller is said to be short in the contract.
There are two basic types of options:
Call option: the holder has the right to buy the underlying asset by a certain date for a
certain price.
Put option: the holder has the right to sell the underlying asset by a certain date for a certain
price.
There are four different positions when entering an options contract: Long call, short call,
long put and short put (see section 2.2).
In this work we study combination of options whose underlying is the S&P 500 mini futures con-
tract. This is a futures contract depending on the S&P 500, which is a capitalization-weighted
index of the prices of 500 large-cap common stocks actively traded in the United States. The
stocks included in the S&P 500 are those of large publicly held companies that trade on either
of the two largest American stock market exchanges: the New York Stock Exchange and the
NASDAQ.
Options terminology:
Strike price K, is the price at which currencies are exchanged if the option is exercised.
4
Time to expiration T, is the time remaining before the option can be exercised, is expressed
in days until delivery/360.
Let us imaging that today the futures price of the index is 1200 units, and we buy a call option
(long call), expiring in 10 days, for a strike price of 1300. If the futures price of the index in ten
days is 1350, the buyer would exercise his right to buy the future contract at 1300 units, receiving
from the seller (short call) (1350-1300)*N dollars, where N is the nominal value specified in the
contract. If at expiration the futures price is below 1300, the buyer does not exercise his right.
In this case the sellers earn the price of the option, payed by the buyer when the contract was
signed. The position of the options holder depending on where the spot price is can be:
In the money: strike is more favorable to the holder than the current spot price.
Out of the money: strike is less favorable to the holder than the current spot price.
2.2 Payoff
The payoff is the pay that we will receive when the option is exercised, it depends on the position
we have on the option and the type of option we have:
Call option payoff : If we have a long position (Figure 1), is the maximum between 0 and
the difference between the price of underlying minus the exercise price (max(0, S K)).
Otherwise, if we have a short position (Figure 2), is the minimum between 0 and the
difference between the exercise price minus the price of underlying (min(0, K S)).
Figure 1: Payoff from long position in Figure 2: Payoff from short position in
a Call option for a strike price K = 1.4. a Call option for a strike price K = 1.4.
Put option payoff : If we have a long position (Figure 3), is the maximum between 0 and
the difference between the exercise price minus the price of underlying (max(0, K S)).
Otherwise, if we have a short position (Figure 4), is the minimum between 0 and the
difference between the price of underlying minus the exercise price (min(0, S K)).
5
Figure 3: Payoff from long position in Figure 4: Payoff from short position in
a Put option for a strike price K = 1.4. a Put option for a strike price K = 1.4.
The option value is composed by the intrinsic value and the time value. The intrinsic value of
an in-the-money option is S K for calls, and K S for puts, and the intrinsic value of out of
the money options is always 0. The difference between the option value and the intrinsic value
is the time value of the option, time value represents the additional value of an option due to
the opportunity for the intrinsic value of the option to increase. Figure 5 shows a decomposition
of call option value.
According to the Black-Scholes model, there is a fair value for options, for which no arbitrage
conditions through replication can be met. This price can be analytically calculated.
Fisher Black and Myron Scholes received the noble price for developing their scheme. The
Black-Scholes model works if the following assumptions are fulfilled:
The stock price follows a geometric Brownian motion with constant and drift.
6
There are no restrictions short selling.
The risk-free rate of interest is constant and the same for all maturities.
Being c a Call options, and p a put option, their prices according to the Black-Scholes model
are [3]:
c = S0 erT (N (d1 ) KN (d2 )) (1)
p = KerT (N (d2 ) S0 N (d1 )) (2)
where
2
S0
ln K
+ r+ 2 T
d1 =
T
d2 = d1 T
The price of an option depends on the price of the underlying, the strike price, the risk free
rate, and the implied volatility.
2.5 Decomposition of a portfolio profits and losses (P&L) in its greeks com-
ponents
Suppose that at t0 we build a portfolio V0 made of one option, whose price P (S, t, , r) is obtained
using the back scholes model.
When time passes from t0 to t1 (4t = t1 t0 ) the portfolio s P&L is 4V = V1 V0 , the
underlying would have moved 4S = S1 S0 , and the implied volatility 4 = 1imp 0imp . We
can decompose the P&L using a first order Taylor expansion:
1
4P = S + 4 imp + 4t + (4S)2 (3)
2
Where Delta () is the first derivative of the price with respect to the underlying, Vega () is
the first derivative of the price with respect to the implied volatility, Theta () the first deriva-
tive of the price with respect to the time to expiration, and Gamma () the second derivative of
the price with respect to the underlying. It can be easily shown that for a geometrical brownian
motion (4S)2 4t [3], therefore all the terms are first order.
,, and are the so called Greek letters, and they represent the sensitivity of the option price
to a single-unit change in the value of either a state variable or a parameter. Such sensitivities
can represent the different dimensions to the risk in an option. The greeks of the combination
of options are the sum of the individual greeks, and each combination has its own risk profile.
Delta can be interpreted as the probability that an option will end up in the money.
7
The Theta of an option is defined as the rate of change of the value of the option with respect
to the passage of time with all else remaining the same. Theta is sometimes referred to as the
time decay of the option, the change in the price of the option for a 1-day decrease in the time
remaining to expiration.
The Vega of an option is defined as the rate of change of the value of the option with respect to
the implied volatility of the price.
From equation 1, for a call option, the greeks can be obtained straightforwardly [3].:
= erT N (d1 ),
S0 N 0 (d1 )
= rKerT N (d2 )
T
= S0 T N 0 (d1 )erf T
N 0 (d1 )
= .
S0 T
= {O S} (4)
is said to be delta hedged, since the delta component of the option price is offset by the
underlying. This is true as long as the linear approximation implied in equation 3 holds. Usually
delta hedged portfolios have to be adjusted one or two time a day, to remain hedged.
8
3 Vertical spreads
A vertical spread can be defined as the linear combination of long calls and short calls or short
puts and long puts, having the long options the same strike price K (long leg) and the short
options a different strike price K(short leg). The expiration time is the same for all the options
that conform the spread. If a vertical spread is conformed by the same number of long and
short options, it is called a pure vertical spread, otherwise it is a ratio vertical spread. In
this document we will study pure vertical spreads, and we will refer to them simply as vertical
spreads.
As defined before, a vertical spread has always a long leg and a short leg. At expiration, a
vertical spread will have a minimum value of zero, when both options are out of the money
(OTM) and a maximum value of the amount between strike prices, when both options are in
the money (ITM).According to the strike of each leg, we can classify the vertical spreads into
4 types: bullish call spread, bullish put spread, bearish call spread and bearish put spread [1].
The payoff of every diferent type of spread is obtained by adding the the payoff of its constituent
options, and are represented in (Figure6) and (Figure7)
Being K and K the strikes (K > K ), and Pl and Ps the absolute value of the prices of
the long and the short leg respectively, the classification can be summarized in Table 1.
9
Table 1: Different kind of spreads that can be built with the strike prices K and K being
K > K , together with their maximum profits and losses.
Bullish call spread Bullish put spread Bearish call Bearish put
spread spread
Long leg strike K K K K
Short leg strike K K K K
Maximum prof K K (Pl Ps ) Ps Pl Ps Pl K K (Pl Ps )
Maximum loss Pl Ps K K (Ps Pl ) K K (Ps Pl ) Pl Ps
Other authors [2] classify vertical spreads according to wether you get money o give money
when you enter in the spread. For example, for a call option, price decreases with strike [3]
therefore, entering a bullish call spread costs Pl Ps whereas entering a bearish call spread gives
Ps Pl . In general, regular traders use vertical spreads when they have a directional view on
the market and they dont want volatility to be there primary concern [1].
In this section, we show the analytical expressions of the greeks for each type of vertical spread,
and we analyze their implications. We assume two general strike prices, K1 and K2, where
K2 > K1, a spot price S, an implied volatility , and time to expiration t.
We also show graphically (Figures 8,9,10 and 11) the evolution of the price and the greeks as
a function of time and spot price, corresponding to all the different vertical spreads that can
be built using the strikes K1 = 1000 and K2 = 1100. All the calculations were done assuming
= 30%, a risk free interest rate r = 2.8% and time to expiration 30 days t = 30/360 = 0.0833
in agreement with previously recorded market data.
10
4.1 Bullish call spread.
4.1.1 Delta
4.1.2 Gamma
4.1.3 Vega
= Sert t(n(d1) n(d2)) (7)
1 2
Like in the gamma case, vega is zero when n(d1) = n(d2) and K1K2 = Se 2 t . Vega is also
1 2
maximum for K1 = Se 2 t and setting K2 as higher as possible minimizes n(d2). The further
the expiration date, the higher is vega.
11
4.1.5 Graphs
Figure 8: Evolution with time and spot of the price and the greeks of a bullish call spread with short
leg strike K2 = 1100, long leg strike K1 = 1000, vol = 30% and r = 2.8
12
4.2 Bullish put spread.
The greeks of the bullish put spread are equal to the greeks of the bullish call spread.
Figure 9: Evolution with time and spot of the price and the greeks of a bullish put spread with short
leg strike K2 = 1100, long leg strike K1 = 1000, vol = 30% and r = 2.8.
13
4.3 Bearish call spread.
4.3.1 Delta
Since K1 < K2 then d1 > d2 and N (d1) > N (d2), therefore delta is always negative, and
the spread always has a bearish perspective.
For n(d2)/n(d1) = K2/K1, delta is minimized (this expression can be derived by making the
partial derivatives of with respect to K1 and K2, and matching both expressions, since at the
maximum they are equal to 0)).
4.3.2 Gamma
4.3.3 Vega
= Sert t(n(d2) n(d1)) (10)
1 2
. Like in the gamma case, Vega is zero when n(d1) = n(d2) and K1K2 = Se 2 t . Vega is
1 2
also maximum for K2 = Se 2 t and setting K1 as lower as possible minimizes n(d1). Also the
further from the exprying date, the higher is gamma.
14
4.3.5 Graphs
Figure 10: Evolution with time and spot of the price and the greeks of a bearish call spread with short
leg strike K1 = 1000, long leg strike K2 = 1100, vol = 30% and r = 2.8.
15
4.4 Bearish put spread.
The greeks of a bearish put spread are equivalent to the greeks of bearish call spread.
Figure 11: Evolution with time and spot of the price and the greeks of a bearish put spread with short
leg strike K1 = 1000, long leg strike K2 = 1100, vol = 30% and r = 2.8.
Lets assume that at t0 we want to enter into a bearish call vertical spread and that the implied
volatility of the options is low. We expect that at t1 the implied volatility suffers an upwards
shift of 300 basis points. We have taken the data of two bearish spreads from the data base
Bloomberg, and we have calculated how the shift of the implied volatility affect their prices (table
2). Since the aim of the section is to compare the sensibility to changes in implied volatility of
2 similar spreads, we set aside the effects of delta, theta and gamma, by keeping constant t, and
S. The days to expiration at t0 are 18, t1 = t0 + 1 day, the interest rate is 0.219%, and the spot
price is S = 1187.00 (S&P 500 mini futures).
16
Table 2: Evolution of the price of to bearish calls (the price is given in units of the underlying
(u), to calculate the price in dollars, the number must be multiplied by the nominal value of the
contract), when there is a downwards shift of 3 % of the implied volatility level. For the bearish
call 1 the short leg is initially ATM and the long leg is OTM, whereas for the bearish call 2 the
short leg is initially ITM and the long leg is ATM
Short leg strike (K1) Long leg strike (K2) Price at t0 Price at t1 P&L
and implied vol at t0 and implied vol at t0 4 = 3%
Bearish call 1 K1=ATM K2=4.21% OTM -20.75u -21.31u -0.56u
i = 29.496% i = 26.727%
Bearish call 2 K1=5%ITM K2= ATM -32.83u -32.33u 0.5u
i = 33.565% i = 30.710%
As we have seen in section 2.3.3, for a bearish call spread, the maximum sensitivity to vega
1 2 1 2
is achieved when the higher strike (long leg) is at K2 = Se 2 t . In this case: e 2 t = 1.0002 1
hence, the closest is the long leg to the ATM position, the longer in implied volatility is the
spread. For these reason, the spread 2 earns money under an hypothetical 3% increment in
volatility while the spread 1 does not.
Using the same parameters as in section 3.6, lets assume that at t1 the volatility will suffer a
downwards shifts of 300 basis points (table 3).
Table 3: Evolution of the price of to bearish calls, when there is a downwards shift of 3 % of the
implied volatility level(the price is given in units of the underlying (u), to calculate the price in
dollars, the number must be multiplied by the nominal value of the contract). For the bearish
call 1 the short leg is initially ATM and the long leg is OTM, whereas for the bearish call 2 the
short leg is initially ITM and the long leg is ATM
Short leg strike (K1) Long leg strike (K2) Price at t0 Price at t1 P&L
and implied vol at t0 and implied vol at t0 4 = 3%
Bearish call 1 K1=ATM K2=4.21% OTM -20.75u -20.05u 0.7u
i = 29.496% i = 26.727%
Bearish call 2 K1=5%ITM K2=ATM -32.83u -33.10u -0.27u
i = 33.565% i = 30.710%
As we have seen in section 2.3.3, for a bearish call spread, the maximum sensitivity to vega
1 2 1 2
is achieved when the higher strike (long leg) is at K2 = Se 2 t . In this case: e 2 t = 1.0002 1,
the closest is the long leg to the ATM position, the longer in implied volatility is the spread.
For these reason, the spread 1 earns money under an hypothetical 3% decreasing in volatility
while the spread 2 does not.
17
5 The volatility smile
One of the main assumptions of the Black Scholes options pricing model is that the mechanics
of the underlying of an option are ruled by a geometrical brownian motion, hence with volatility
independent of strike prices, spot prices, or time to expiry (variance goes with t in this kind
of motion).
The implied volatility in the prices of options prior to October 1987 was in agreement with the
former assumption. Until then a plot of the implied vol vs the strike price, or the spot price,
showed a straight horizontal line, or a straight horizontal plane in the case of plotting the implied
vol vs the strike prices and the time to expiry.
In october 1987 the stock market drop by 20 % or more in two days. This kind of extreme
movements conform what is usually called the heavy tails, and are not taken into account in
a geometrical brownian motion model. After this, the markets reacted making more expensive
low strike puts than high strike or ATM calls. By doing this, a speculator pays more for a deep
OTM strike put, since a extreme favorable movement, with neglige probability in the BSM, is
indeed possible. Since then the plot of the implied volatility vs strike prices, resembles a skew
or even a smile, depending also on the time to expiration (Figure 12).
Figure 12: The implied volatility values of the calls on the S&P Index expiring on December 2011 are
plot vs the moneynes.We define the moneyness of an option as m = K/S expressed in points per cent,
where K is the strike price of the option and S the underlying Spot price. The expiration time is 6 months
and two weeks. It is said that the shape is a skew
Each market has developed its own idiosincratic volatility smile. Until the advent of and
alternative model to the BSM, options are priced using BlackScholes, but the implied volatility
of the price is adjusted to the volatility smile of the particular option market.
In this section we show the specific properties of the volatility skew associated to the options
that we use to make the strategy. To do this we used a set of historical data taken from the
database Bloomberg, with the following characteristics: Calls on the S&P 500 mini futures that
expire in December 2011. The first sample corresponds to the 1st of june, and the sampling
frecuency is 20 min
18
5.1 Features of the volatility smile of equity index options
In this section we enumerate the general features of the volatility smile according to [7], and we
test them using our historical data.
5.1.1 Volatility are steepest for small expirations as a function of strike, shallower
for longer expirations
95 (ti ) 90 (ti )
(ti ) = (11)
(95 90)
Figure 13: Evolution of the slope (), calculated according to the equation (7) as function of time to
expiry. In the same graph the moving average, the moving average+moving standard deviation and the
moving average - moving standard deviation can be found. This statistics were calculated according to
equation 12 and equation 13
Pn=i
n=(i31) (tn )
M A(ti ) = (12)
30
19
v
u n=i
u1 X
M S(ti ) = t ((tn ) M A(ti ))2 (13)
30
n=(i31)
The graph of figure 13 also shows another feature: The volatility of the volatility is
higher the closer is the option to expiration
In figure 14 we show the ATM volatility vs time graph together with the underlying vs time
graph for our historical data.The negative correlation can be clearly seen.
Figure 14: Up:Implied volatility of the ATM options, as a function of the time to expiry. Down: Spot
price of the underlying, as a function of the time to expiry
= 0.9170 (14)
Since index is formed by the sum of n stocks Xi , the variance of the index is given by the
expression:
n
X n
X n X
X n
var( Xi ) = var(Xi ) + 2 cov(Xi , Xj) (15)
i=1 i=1 i=1 j=i+1
20
When the market drops, the correlation between the stocks increases, increasing also the
volatility of the index. For this reason, the implied volatility of the ATM options has a negative
correlation with the behavior of the stock.
5.1.3 Low strike volatilities are usually higher than high-strike volatilities
In figure 15 we show the implied vols of the Calls expirying on December for different strikes
as function of days to expiration. This data is daily data, and was taken from bloomberg. The
ITM and OTM labels correspond to Calls, therefore the low strikes correspond to ITM and the
high strikes to OTM. For example, if the spot price is 1000, a 5 % ITM strike price would be of
950.
Figure 15: Evolution of the implied volatilities as function of time for different strike prices
The graph clearly shows that the low strikes have higher implied volatilities than the higher
strikes.
5.1.4 After large sudden market declines, the implied volatility of out of the
money calls may be greater than for ATM calls, reflecting an expectation
that the market will rebound
We could not see in our high frequency data this behavior. However, the skew showed convexity
after large market declines. Although the curvature was not enough for the OTM calls to be
higher than the ATM calls, the cause of the curvature is the same: OTM calls get more expensive
due to the fact that the market expects a sudden increase in the underlying level (Figure 16).
21
Figure 16: Left Plot of the futures price of the S&P 500 mini index, as function of the days to expiry
of its associated option. Right Plot of the volatility skew of the options at certain time point, that
correspond to the last point of the left graph. The point of the skew corresponding to the underlying is
highlighted
The sticky delta rule assumes that the implied volatility of an option with a certain time to
maturity, depends on the moneyness (mt = SKt )of the option. Mathematically this can be
expressed as:
t = f (mt , T t) (16)
Where T is the expiration date, t the present date and therefore T-t the time to maturity.The
following expression is one of the most used models.
(St ; K, T t)(St , St , T t) = 0 +1 ln(mt )+2 [ln(mt )]2 +3 (T t)+4 (T t)2 +5 ln(mt )(T t)+t (K, T t)
(17)
Where (St , St , T t) is the ATM volatility and (St ; K, T t) the volatility for the option
with strike price K.
After applying the model to our historical using linear regression we get the following statistics:
22
In figure 17 we show the surface formed by all the skews along the time given by the model
and given by the real data.
Figure 17: Left Actual implied volatility- ATM implied volatility as function of strike prices and days to
maturity.Rightimplied volatility- ATM implied volatility as function of strike prices and days to maturity,
given by the sticky delta rule
Table 4: Coefficients given by the linear regression corresponding to equation 17,together with
their standard error
The sticky strike rule assumes that the implied volatility of an option with a certain strike
remains constant when the asset price moves. Mathematically this can be expressed as:
23
t = f (K, T t) (20)
After applying the model to our historical data, using a linear regression we get the following
statistics:
In figure 18 we show the surface formed by all the skews along the time given by the model
and given by the real data.
Figure 18: Left Actual volatility surface Right Volatility surface given by the sticky strike rule
24
Table 5: Coefficients given by the linear regression corresponding to equation 17,together with
their standard error
In the following table we show the results found in [5] and [6] together with ours.
Clearly our results resemble the ones presented in other studies. Obviously, the underlyng
and the options are the same in the 3 studies. The difference is in the samples. The sample
period of the study presented in [5] is February 2004 to October 2007, and the number of
observations: 1575). The sample period presented in [6]is from June 1998 to April 2002, and
the total number of observations is 1974. In our case the sample period is from June 2011 to
November 2011, and the total number of observations is 100.
In [5] we found, R2 = 0.9769, whereas in [6]is R2 = 0.9493, being R2 = 0.9901 our result.
25
5.3.2 Sticky strike rule
The result found in [6] cannot be compared with the ones of [5] and ours, since his model
does not use logarithm. The sticky strike model in this case is :
R2 = 0.9493
26
6 Trading the slope
In figure 19 we show the volatility skew of the calls on the S&P 500 mini Futures at a certain
time point. The graph sketches the implied volatility vs moneyness. (We define the moneyness
of an option as m = K/S expressed in points per cent, where K is the strike price of the option
and S the underlying Spot price).
Figure 19: Volatility skew for the calls expiring on December 2011. The expiration time is 6 months
and two weeks. The strike price closest to the at the money value is 1300, being 1301.50 the underlying
price.
m1 (ti ) m2 (ti )
(ti ) = (25)
m1 m2
In figure 13 we showed the evolution of calculated from the intraday historical data together
witgh the moving average and the moving standar deviation
The change in the slope during one day can be expressed as:
In figure 20 we can see that the evolution of 4(ti ), using the the data presented in figure
13, is mean reverting, therefore, we could build a trading strategy based on trading changes in
the slope of the skew.
27
Figure 20: Plot of the one day difference in slope (calculated using equation 1), as a function of the days
to expiry
Let us focus in two points of the volatility skew, with implied volatility 1 and 2 , corresponding
to the strike prices K1 and K2 at t0 , and t1 . Let us assume that the moneyness of the options
remains constant. Let us assume also that we will deal always with ITM calls. This is done for
two reasons: The ITM calls are actively traded and the ITM part of the skew is the part that
best fulfills the heuristic models.
At t0 , the slope is: (t0 ) = 1 (tm01)2 (t0 )
m2 . Lets make the naive assumption that since 4(t) is
mean reverting, we can find a time point t1 where the slope raises ((t1 ) (t0 ) > 0).If this
happens, the following inequality must be fulfilled:
In other words, the distance between the two implied volatility values should increase. In fig-
ure 21 we show this graphically (we assume that there is not a big change in the level of the skew)
28
Figure 21: Representation of a change in slope between t0 and t1 . In this case there is not a big change
in the level of the skew
In other to monetize this movement, we can build a portfolio made of a long call with
strike price K1, and short call with strike price K2, being K2 > K1. The long call is long
in implied volatility whereas the short call is short in implied volatility, monetizing the slope
movement. This portfolio is a bullish call. If we expect the slope of the skew to decrease, the
monetization would come from building a portfolio consisting in a short call at K1, and a long
call at K2, ending up with a bullish call. This positions have the usual risks related to options:
Delta risk: The portfolio has an overall exposure to delta that has to be taken into account.
Delta hedging the portfolio can overcame this risk. The deeper ITM are both options the
lowest delta exposure (see section 4).
Gamma risk: The portfolio has an overall exposure to gamma that has to be taken into
account.Provided that the options are ITM calls, gamma is positive for the bearish call,
not representing a risk. For the bullish call, gamma is negative, however, choosing the
options sufficiently far away from expiration, and holding the positon for a short period of
time can overcome this risk (see section 4)
Theta risk: The portfolio has an overall exposure to theta that has to be taken into
account. The behavior of theta is antisimetrical to the behaviour of gamma. Choosing the
options sufficiently far away from expiration (see section 4), can overcome this risk.
Vega risk: Big changes in the level of the skew can lead to a negative P&L of the portfolio,
even though the expected change in slope happens (see figure 22). This is due to the fact
that the option closer to the ATM point has a bigger vega sensitivity. This risk could be
hedged building a ratio vertical spread, instead of a pure vertical spread. The proportion
of each leg has to be set to make the vega of the hole portfolio zero. By doing this, changes
in the distance between the implied volatility of each strike (i.e changes in slope), are still
monetize, and huge level variation does not a affect the price.
29
Figure 22: Representation of a change in slope between t0 and t1 . In this case there is a big change
in the level of the skew. A portfolio long in 0 and short in 1 would monetize the slope movement.
However, if the vega of the option corresponding to 1 is higher than the vega of he option corresponding
to 0, the whole portfolio may loose money
In this subsection we show an example of the trade that will be repeated while doing the strategy,
taken from real market data. In this case we monetize a decreasing of the slope. In figure 23 we
show the volatility skew at t0 and at t1 .
Figure 23: Volatility skew at two different times, corresponding to the calls expiring on December 2011.
At t0 we can see that near to m=90 there is a jump in the skew, which implies the the slope
30
is locally high. After time passes, the price of the option is corrected and so the slope.
The bearish call described in Table 6 can monetize the eventual move of the skew. (All the
prices and P&L are given in units of the underlying. To obtain its value in dollar, it must be
multiplied by the nominal value of the contract )
The 160 basis points decreasing of the implied volatility of the short leg, generates enough
earnings to overcome the losses due to the 42 basis points decreasing of the implied volatility of
the long leg. 118 volatility basis points have been converted in nearly 4 units.
31
6.2.2 Greeks decomposition of the P&L
Table 8: Greeks decompostions of P&L of the portfolio used to monetize he change in implied volatility
between t0 and t1
Due to the long distance to expiry (half year), the vega contribution is much higher than the
gamma or the theta contributions.
Also, the underlying barely moves 4S = 2.75 therefore the contribution of gamma is nearly
zero. Table 9 shows the greeks P&L decomposition if the trade would have been done, non delta
hedge
Table 9: Greeks decompostions of P&L of the portfolio used to monetize he change in implied volatility
between t0 and t1
Let us systematize the trading strategy, trying to monetize increments in the slope using similar
trades as the one presented in section 6.2.
We calculate the slope applying equation 25 on the historical data for three cases:
Strategy A m1 90 and m2 95
Strategy B m1 85 and m2 90
Strategy C m1 80 and m2 85
For every case we entry a trade at every time point i where the following inequality is fulfilled:
32
Therefore we expect the slope to raise. To monetize the eventual move we build the following
portfolio:
The positions remains open while tj ti < 1day. If equation 34 is not fulfilled after one day,
we exit the trade assuming the eventual losses.
6.4 Results
In figure 24 we show the P&L of each of the built portfolios, together with the greeks approxi-
mation .
Figure 24: Total P&L, together with the summed greeks components, for every traded day. The P&L
is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal of the
contract
The total number of trades performed were 165, from which 124 were winners.
33
Figure 25: The P&L is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied
by the nominal of the contract. The x axis corresponds to every day where a position is opened and
closed
For each trade, we have calculated the contribution of each greek. This is shown in figure
26.
Figure 26: Contribution of each greek to the P&L of the portfolio, together with the total P&L. The
P&L is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal
of the contract
In figure 27 we show the P&L of each of the built portfolios, together with the greeks approxi-
mation .
34
Figure 27: Total P&L, together with the summed greeks components, for every traded day. The P&L
is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal of the
contract
The total number of trades performed were 165, from which 153 were winners.
Figure 28: The P&L is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied
by the nominal of the contract. The x axis corresponds to every day where a position is opened and
closed
For each trade, we have calculated the contribution of each greek. This is shown in figure
29.
35
Figure 29: Contribution of each greek to the P&L of the portfolio, together with the total P&L. The
P&L is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal
of the contract
In figure 30 we show the P&L of each of the built portfolios, together with the greeks approxi-
mation .
Figure 30: Total P&L, together with the summed greeks components, for every traded day. The P&L
is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal of the
contract
The total number of trades performed were 57 , from which 53 were winners.
36
Figure 31: The P&L is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied
by the nominal of the contract. The x axis corresponds to every day where a position is opened and
closed
For each trade, we have calculated the contribution of each greek. This is shown in figure
32.
Figure 32: Contribution of each greek to the P&L of the portfolio, together with the total P&L. The
P&L is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal
of the contract
In figure 33 we show the P&L of each of the built portfolios, together with the greeks approxi-
mation .
37
Figure 33: Total P&L, together with the summed greeks components, for every traded day. The P&L
is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal of the
contract
The total number of trades performed were 57 , from which 53 were winners.
Figure 34: Contribution of each greek to the P&L of the portfolio, together with the total P&L. The
P&L is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal
of the contract
For each trade, we have calculated the contribution of each greek. This is shown in figure
35.
38
Figure 35: Contribution of each greek to the P&L of the portfolio, together with the total P&L. The
P&L is given in units of the underlying, to obtain its actual value, it must be multiplied by the nominal
of the contract
6.5 Strategy C
Our data did not show calls with m = 80. Therefore the performance of trade C could not be
tested.
According to figures 25, 28, 31, 34, the strategy is succesfull in all its versions. For the strategy
A, perfoming delta hedging lead to a higher percentage of winning trades that the non delta
hedge strategy (92.73% vs 75%). This is because the influence of delta is not neglige, compared
to influence of vega (see figure 20). On the other hand, delta can contribute to losses, but also
to earnings. For this reason, the strategy A delta hedged, has a lower accrued P&L than the
non delta hedged. By non delta hedging the strategy, a non trivial amount of risk is added,
which can lead to higher profits or losses.
Strategy B, can be performed less times than A, which means deep ITM calls are available in
the market only when the time to expiration is large (more than 140 days, according to our data
set). For the short period where this calls are available, Strategy B profits are higher than A
profits. This is due to the fact that the vega sensitivity for large times to expiration is greater
the deeper ITM are the call, for a wide range of strike prices (see figure 30)
39
Figure 36: Vega sensitivity of a bearish call spread (strike prices: 1160, 1210. implied volatility: 30%)
for three diferent times to expiry, 200, 80 and 20 days. For t=200, the deeper ITM are both calls, the
greater vega, for abig range of strike prices)
Further studies should include the bid-ask spread in order to measure the real impact of the
trading strategy.
40
References
[3] John C. Hull. Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, Pearson Education Ltd.,
2010.
[5] Jacinto Marabel. Dynamics of the Implied Volatility Surface. Theory and Empirical
Evidence, ENCUENTRO DE ECONOMIA APLICADA, Murcia, 2005.
[6] Toby Daglish, John Hull, Wulin Suo. Volatility surfaces: theory, rules of thumb, and
empirical evidence, Volume 7, Issue 5, 2007.
41