THIRD PARTY LITIGATION Funding Economic and Legal Approach
THIRD PARTY LITIGATION Funding Economic and Legal Approach
THIRD PARTY LITIGATION Funding Economic and Legal Approach
Marco de Morpurgo *
ABSTRACT
* Associate, Covington & Burling; Ph.D. candidate (Milan); LL.M. (Harvard); M.Sc.
(IUC Turin). Thanks to Professors Steve Shavell, Anthony J. Sebok, Mauro Bussani,
David Wilkins, Mitt Regan, Ugo Mattei, Duncan Kennedy.
343
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
TABLE OF CONTENTS
I. INTRODUCTION
New trends in civil litigation financing are transforming the
way in which we conceive the civil justice system. If, on the one
hand, academic and political discourses directly concerning the
substance of legal rights are of fundamental importance, equally
significant are the discourses about how those rights are then to be
enforced in practice. Litigation is an expensive process and its
costs are often prohibitive. Hence, questions on the ways in which
people and other economic actors can finance litigation to obtain
the fulfillment of their rights are perhaps as important as the
questions on the content of those rights themselves.
The traditional view of the litigation processat least in the
Western legal tradition 1contemplates the opposition of two
parties, plaintiff and defendant, each assisted by respective
lawyers, in front of an adjudicating authority. In the traditional
view, the resources for financing the litigation come from the
parties personal assets orin some jurisdictionsfrom their
lawyers assets.
Recent trends in civil litigation financing are breaking from
the traditional way of looking at the litigation process.
Increasingly, interrelationships between the civil justice system
1 This includes both the Roman and the common law traditions. See DIEGO E.
LPEZ MEDINA, TEORA IMPURA DEL DERECHO: LA TRANSFORMACIN DE LA
CULTURA JURDICA LATINOAMERICANA 12 (3d ed. 2004).
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
2 Dewey & LeBoeuf LLPa New York-based, 1,200-attorney law firmraised $125
million in a bond offering in April 2010. Carlyn Kolker, Dewey & LeBoeuf Issues Bonds
to Refinance Debt, as Law Firms Seek Capital, BLOOMBERG, Apr. 17, 2010, http://www.
bloomberg.com/news/2010-04-16/dewey-leboeuf-sells-125-million-of-debt-as-law-firms-
search-for-capital.html.
3 An Australian law firm, Slater & Gordon, held the worlds first I.P.O. for a law firm
in May 2007. Anthony Notaras, Law firms: to list or not to list?, INTERNATIONAL BAR
ASSOCIATION, http://www.ibanet.org/Article/Detail.aspx?ArticleUid=e2d1bfa3-e5c7-49e
5-8e4f-7171c31c119e (last visited Apr. 8, 2011).
4 Ugo Mattei, Access to Justice. A Renewed Global Issue? 11.3 ELECTRONIC J. COMP.
L. 1, 2-4 (2007).
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
8 On the benefits derived from the interaction between the two strongest
nonpositivistic approaches to legal analysis, namely comparative law and law and
economics, see UGO MATTEI, COMPARATIVE LAW AND ECONOMICS ix. (1997).
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
9 See ROBERT COOTER & THOMAS ULEN, LAW & ECONOMICS 74-118 (5th ed. 2008);
STEVEN SHAVELL, FOUNDATIONS OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 7-176 (2004).
10 COOTER & ULEN, supra note 9, at 78.
11 Anthony J. Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, 64 VAND. L. REV. 61, 63-67 (2011).
12 Id.
13 Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and
Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089, 1090 (1972).
14 See generally SAMUEL BOWLES, MICROECONOMICS: BEHAVIOR, INSTITUTIONS
AND EVOLUTION (2004); 1 ALFRED E. KAHN, THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION:
PRINCIPLES AND INSTITUTIONS (1988);
John O. Ledyard, Market Failure, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS
(S.N. Durlauf & L.E. Blume eds., 2d ed. 2008); Kenneth J. Arrow & Gerard Debreu,
Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy, 22 ECONOMETRICA 265 (1954);
Francis M. Bator, The Anatomy of Market Failure, 72 Q. J. ECON. 351 (1958); Ronald H.
Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J. L. & ECON. 1 (1960); Bruce C. Greenwald &
Joseph E. Stiglitz, Externalities in Economies with Imperfect Information and Incomplete
Markets, 101 Q. J. ECON. 229 (1986).
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
15 On the use of the term property rights in the law & economics literature, see
SHAVELL, supra note 9, at 9-11.
16 See infra Sections IV.A.1.b and 2.b.
17 See SHAVELL, supra note 9, at 258-259, 406-407, 430. See generally Anthony Heyes,
Neil Rickman & Dionisia Tzavara, Legal Expenses Insurance, Risk Aversion and
Litigation, 24 INTL REV. L. & ECON. 107 (2004); W. Kip Viscusi, Product Liability
Litigation with Risk Aversion, 17 J. LEGAL STUD. 101 (1988).
18 See generally ROBERT B. CALIHAN, JOHN R. DENT & MARC B. VICTOR,
AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, THE ROLE OF RISK ANALYSIS IN DISPUTE AND
LITIGATION MANAGEMENT (2004); Gretchen A. Bender, Uncertainty and
Unpredictability in Patent Litigation: The Time is Ripe for a Consistent Claim Construction
Methodology, 8 J. INTELL. PROP. L. 175 (2001); Joseph A. Grundfest & Peter H. Huang,
The Unexpected Value of Litigation: A Real Options Perspective, 58 STAN. L. REV. 1267
(2006); Evan Osborne, Courts as Casinos? An Empirical Investigation of Randomness and
Efficiency in Civil Litigation, 28 J. LEGAL STUD. 187 (1999).
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
1. Self-funding
If no form of external capital is available, the plaintiff must
use his or her own assets to finance the lawsuit. This is the default
situation in any jurisdiction. Depending on the jurisdiction, legal
costs can be either borne by each party respectively (American
rule) 20 or by the losing party (loser-pays-all or English rule). 21
The legal and economic logic of this basic situation has been
19 For a survey of recent research on empirical analysis of various ways for funding
civil litigation, see Paul Fenn & Neil Rickman, The Empirical Analysis of Litigation
Funding, in NEW TRENDS IN FINANCING CIVIL LITIGATION IN EUROPE 131 (Mark Tuil &
Louis Visscher eds., 2010).
20 See Kathryn E. Spier, Litigation, in THE HANDBOOK OF LAW & ECONOMICS 262
(A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell eds., 2007). See also SHAVELL, supra note 9, at
387-418.
21 See Ronald R. Braeutigam, Bruce Owen & John Panzar, An Economic Analysis of
Alternative Fee Shifting Systems, 47 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 173, 174 (1984); John C.
Hause, Indemnity, Settlement, and Litigation, or Ill Be Suing You, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 157,
157 (1989); Avery Katz, Measuring the Demand for Litigation: Is the English Rule Really
Cheaper?, 3 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 143, 144 (1987); SHAVELL, supra note 9, at 428-432; Spier,
supra note 20, at 300-303.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
2. Lawyer Funding
Some countries permit lawyers to take clients on a no-win-
no-fee basis, which enables lawyers to invest in their clients
lawsuits. In the American contingency fee system, introduced in
the United States (U.S.) at the turn of the twentieth century and
now accepted in all U.S. states, 23 the plaintiff pays the lawyer a
fraction of any positive recovery from settlement or judgment, and
nothing otherwise. 24 Under the UK conditional fee scheme,
introduced in England and Wales after the drastic reduction of
legal aid at the end of the 1990s, 25 the plaintiff pays the lawyers
cost plus an upscale premium, unrelated to the adjudicated
amount, if the case is successful, and nothing otherwise. 26 In both
the contingency and the conditional fee schemes, the plaintiff
essentially gives up a portion of his award (either a percentage or
an unrelated upscale premium) in exchange for the elimination of
the risk connected to an unfavorable outcome of the litigation.
5. Assignment of Claims
Especially in the common law world, legal and economic
scholarship has recently supported liberalization in favor of the
formation of markets in legal claims. 32 The idea of such markets
is based on the mechanism known as assignment. Assignment
places the third party acquiring the claim in the shoes of the
party who originally had the right to bring the lawsuit.
33 See Marc J. Shukaitis, A Market in Personal Injury Tort Claims, 16 J. LEGAL STUD.
329 (1987).
34 See WAYE, supra note 25; Andrea Pinna, Financing Civil Litigation: The Case for the
Assignment and Securitization of Liability Claims, in NEW TRENDS IN FINANCING CIVIL
LITIGATION IN EUROPE 109 (Mark Tuil & Louis Visscher eds., 2010); Michael
Abramowicz, On The Alienability of Legal Claims, 114 YALE L.J. 697 (2004); Isaac M.
Marcushamer, Selling Your Torts: Creating a Market for Tort Claims and Liability, 33
HOFSTRA L. REV. 1543 (2005); Molot, supra note 5; Sebok, supra note 11.
35 See Shukaitis, supra note 33, at 329.
36 This is the (simple model) definition of expected gains from trial in the basic
economic theory of litigation. See SHAVELL, supra note 9, at 401-02.
37 Pinna, supra note 34, at 17.
38 As suggested by A. Pinna, two problems would arise immediately under such an
outlined system. The first has to do with prescription: indeed, as known, a claim has to be
brought to court before it is time barred; however, the legal claim could be traded even
once the action is brought. The other problem has to do with the date at which damages
would be assessed, i.e., either at the date of the judgment (France) or at the date of the
harm (England). Id. at 17-18.
39 Id. at 17.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
6. Litigation Loans
A market that presents very close similarities and connections
to TPLF, particularly well-developed in the United States, is one
in which private companies provide litigation loans to (needy)
plaintiffs for covering their expenses (mainly living and medical) 42
any financial assistance to their clients to meet their day-to-day living expenses. Julia H.
McLaughlin, Litigation Funding: Charting a Legal and Ethical Course, 31 VT. L. REV. 615,
646-647 (2007).
43 See Susan L. Martin, The Litigation Financing Industry: The Wild West of Finance
Should Be Tamed Not Outlawed, 10 FORDHAM J. CORP. & FIN. L. 55, 55 (2004); Douglas
R. Richmond, Other Peoples Money: The Ethics of Litigation Funding, 56 MERCER L.
REV. 649, 650 (2005).
44 See Echeverria v. Estate of Lindner, No. 018666/2002, 2005 WL 1083704, at *6 (N.Y.
Sup. Ct. Mar. 2, 2005), where Judge Warshawsky wrongfully considered a litigation
funding agreement a loan based on the fact that a positive outcome of the suit was a
sure thing, given that the plaintiff was suing under a statute that imposed strict liability.
That judgment has to be considered wrong because it cannot be said that all civil cases
based on strict liability can be said to be sure things. See Anthony J. Sebok, A New
York Decision That May Imperil Plaintiffs Ability to Finance Their Lawsuits: Why It
Should Be Repudiated, or Limited to Its Facts, FINDLAW, Apr. 18, 2005, http://writ.news.
findlaw.com/sebok/20050418.html.
45 For a synthetic survey of the dialogue between proponents and critics of litigation
loans, see Mariel Rodak, Its About Time: A Systems Thinking Analysis of the Litigation
Finance Industry and Its Effects on Settlement, 155 U. PA. L. REV. 503 (2006).
46 Courtney R. Barksdale, All that Glitters Isnt Gold: Analyzing the Costs and Benefits
of Litigation Finance, 26 REV. LITIG. 707, 735 (2007); Martin, supra note 43, at 68;
McLaughlin, supra note 42, at 655.
47 McLaughlin, supra note 42, at 627.
48 WAYE, supra note 25, at 5.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
49 George S. Swan, Economics and the Litigation Funding Industry: How Much Justice
Can You Afford?, 35 NEW ENG. L. REV. 805, 824 (2001).
50 WAYE, supra note 25, at 5.
51 Terry Carter, Cash Up Front: New Funding Sources Ease Financial Strains on
Plaintiffs Lawyers, 90 A.B.A. J. 34, 34 (2004).
52 Model Rules of Professional Conduct, Rule 1.8(e) reads as follows:
A lawyer shall not provide financial assistance to a client in connection with
pending or contemplated litigation, except that: (1) a lawyer may advance
court costs and expenses of litigation, the repayment of which may be
contingent on the outcome of the matter; and (2) a lawyer representing an
indigent client may pay court costs and expenses of litigation on behalf of the
client.
MODEL RULES OF PROFL CONDUCT R. 1.8 (2010). See James T. Moliterno, Broad
Prohibition, Thin Rationale: The Acquisition of an Interest and Financial Assistance in
Litigation Rules, 16 GEO. J. LEGAL ETHICS 223 (2003).
53 AMERICAN LEGAL FINANCE ASSOCIATION, http://americanlegalfin.com (last
visited Apr. 3, 2011).
54 Among the firms is The Lions Group, which lends money to individuals who
would like to maintain their lawsuits but need money immediately. Their typical client
would be an auto accident victim who needs cash to pay for medical expenses and cannot
wait years to receive a jury verdict or a deferred settlement. Anthony J. Sebok, Venture
Capitalism for Lawsuits? Why It Doesnt Exist, and What Alternatives for Financing Exist
Instead, FINDLAW, Feb. 12, 2001, http://writ.news.findlaw.com/sebok/20010212.html.
Others include: Interim Settlement Funding Corporation (Rancman v. Interim Settlement
Funding Corp., 99 Ohio St.3d 121 (2003)); Future Settlement Funding Corporation
(Rancman v. Interim Settlement Funding Corp., 99 Ohio St.3d 121 (2003)); Lawcash
(Echeverria v Estate of Linder, No. 018666/2002, 2005 WL 1083704, at *6 (N.Y. Sup. Ct.
Mar. 2, 2005)); Juris Capital; Magnolia Funding; Lawsuit Cash Advance; Plaintiff Support;
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
Preferred Capital Funding; Plaintiff Investment Funding LLC; PS Finance; Golden Pear
Funding; Case Funding; Allied Legal Funding; The Law Funder; and Oliver Street
Finance.
55 See infra Sections IV.A.1.a and 2.a.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
A. Definition
The conceptual and practical interconnections between the
various markets for property rights in litigation outlined above are
extremely interesting and the boundaries that separate them are
sometimes highly faded. A few of the authors that have devoted
interest to alternative methods for financing civil litigation
(including TPLF) have engaged in the discussion concerning
conceptual and practical definitions of such boundaries. 56
However, the purpose of this article is not to explore the
interconnections and draw lines between TPLF and other similar
practices, but rather to conceptually isolate TPLF and analyze it
from a comparative legal and economic perspective. For the
purpose of this article, therefore, TPLF is to be intended as a
specific financial service, which consists of third parties providing
funds to plaintiffs to cover their litigation expenses. These funds
are provided on a non-recourse basis and are advanced by funders
who maintain a passive role, in exchange for the promise by the
plaintiff to pay the funder a determined percentage of the award in
the case of a favorable settlement or judgment.
56 In particular, for a discussion of the boundaries between assignment and TPLF, see
Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, supra note 11. See also WAYE, supra note 25.
57 Roughly speaking, maintenance indicates the action of one who assists a litigant in
prosecuting or defending a claim. Champerty is a particular form of maintenance,
namely one made for the purpose of gain. The prohibitions of maintenance and
champerty are embodied in two ancient common law doctrines, which will be discussed in
Section V.A.1.
58 LITIGATION FUNDING IN AUSTRALIA, Discussion Paper, Standing Committee of
Attorneys General (May 2006), http://www.lawlink.nsw.gov.au/lawlink/legislation_policy/
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
ll_lpd.nsf/vwFiles/LitigationFundingDiscussionpaperMay06.pdf/$file/LitigationFundingDi
scussionpaperMay06.pdf. See WAYE, supra note 25, at 55. For an example of an
insolvency matter for which TPLF was provided, see Anstella Nominees Pty Ltd v. St
George Motor Finance Ltd. [2003] FCA 466 (Austl.).
59 See WAYE, supra note 25, at 5, 18, 133; LITIGATION FUNDING IN AUSTRALIA, supra
note 58, at 4-6. For two examples, see QPSX Ltd. v. Ericsson Australia Pty. Ltd. (2005)
F.C.A. 933 (Austl.) and Fostif v. Campbell Cash and Carry (2005) N.S.W.C.A. 83 (Austl.).
60 See QPSX Ltd. v. Ericsson Australia Pty. Ltd. (2005) 219 A.L.R. 1 (Austl.);
Campbells Cash & Carry P/L v. Fostif P/L (2006) 299 A.L.R. 200 (Austl.).
61 IMF, which provides funding of legal claims and other related services where the
claim size is over $2 million, is the largest litigation funder in Australia and the first to be
listed on the Australian Stock Exchange. See IMF, http://www.imf.com.au (last visited
Mar. 28, 2011).
62 Litigation Lending Services Ltd., set up in Sydney in 1999, has traditionally focused
on the provision of litigation funding for insolvency market actions typically ranging from
claims of between $200,000 and $10 million, though extending their services beyond
insolvency to general commercial litigation, class actions and representative proceedings.
See Litigation Lending Services, http://www.litigationlending.com.au (last visited Mar. 28,
2011).
63 LCM Litigation Fund Pty Ltd (LCM) has been in business since 1998 and was
previously known as Australian Litigation Fund Pty Ltd (until April 2008). LCM
primarily provides litigation funding to insolvency practitioners. However, LCM also
provides funding to solvent companies and individuals with worthwhile commercial legal
claims. . . . LCM prefers to undertake projects in which the relevant legal claim is for at
least $2.5 million. LCM Litigation Fund, http://www.lcmlitigation.com.au (last visited
Mar. 28, 2011).
64 As of 2006, five companies operated in the business of commercial litigation
funding. LITIGATION FUNDING IN AUSTRALIA, supra note 58, at 4. As of May 2010,
about six active funders operated in the market. Charlie Gollow, Inv. Manager, IMF
(Austl.) Ltd., Trends and Developments in Australian Litigation Funding, Presentation at
the RAND ICJ Conference: Alternative Litigation Finance in the U.S.: Where Are We
and Where Are We Headed with Practice and Policy?, Washington, D.C. (May 21, 2010).
65 See infra Section V.A.2.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
77 ACCESS TO JUSTICE WITH CONDITIONAL FEES, supra note 25, at 3.3. However,
third party funding was introduced as a result of an amendment sought in the House of
Lords. See infra Section V.A.4.
78 WAYE, supra note 25, at 82.
79 Norglen Ltd. (in liq) v. Reeds Rains Prudential Ltd. [1999] 2 A.C. 1 (Eng.); Ramsey
v. Hartley [1977] 1 W.L.R. 686 (Eng.); Guy v. Churchill [1888] 40 Ch. 481 (Eng.); In re
Park Gate Waggon Works Co. [1881] 17 Ch. 234 (Eng.); Seear v. Lawson [1880] 15 Ch. 729
(Eng.).
80 A famous case is that of Harbour Litigation Funding . . . financing the legal battle
of Michelle Young, wife of the property tycoon Scot Young, [claiming] to have lost most
of what was once a 400m fortune. Elena Moya, Hedge Funds, Investors and Divorce
Lawyers Its a Match Made in Heaven, GUARDIAN.CO.UK (Oct. 16, 2009), http://www.
guardian.co.uk/business/2009/oct/16/hedge-funds-divorce-litigation-funding.
81 For the most recent and exhaustive report on the costs of the UK civil justice
system, see HON. LORD JUSTICE JACKSON, REVIEW OF CIVIL LITIGATION COSTS: FINAL
REPORT (2010).
82 Harbour Litigation funds claims with a claim value in excess of 3,000,000.
Harbour Litigation Funding Ltd., http://www.harbourlitigationfunding.com (last visited
Mar. 28, 2011).
83 Juridica predominantly invests in the United States, the United Kingdom, and in
international arbitrations cases. Juridica Investments Ltd., http://www.juridicainvestments
.com (last visited Apr. 3, 2011).
84 Juridica Investment Limited, for example, with over $200 million of assets under
management, is listed on the London Stock Exchanges Alternative Investment Market
(AIM: JIL). Juridica Investments Ltd., http://www.juridicainvestments.com (last visited
Apr. 3, 2011).
85 Allianz Litigation Funding is the UK branch of Munich-based Allianz ProzessFinanz
GmbH. Allianz Litigation Funding, http://www.allianz-litigationfunding.co.uk (last visited
Apr. 3, 2011).
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
86 Michael Herman, Allianz to Fund UK Court Cases, TIMES ONLINE, Oct. 18, 2007,
http://business.timesonline.co.uk/tol/business/law/article2688587.ece.
87 Jane Croft, Litigation Finance Follows Credit Crunch, FINANCIAL TIMES, Jan. 27,
2010, http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/7c98c38a-0ab1-11df-b35f-00144feabdc0.html.
88 CLAIMS FUNDING INTERNATIONAL, http://www.claimsfunding.eu (last visited Mar.
28, 2011).
89 Allianz entered the UK market in 2007. Allianz Litigation Funding, http://www.
allianz-litigationfunding.co.uk (last visited Apr. 3, 2011).
90 Allianz Prozessfinanzierung, http://www.allianz-profi.com (last visited Mar 28, 2011).
91 Allianz Prozessfinanzierung, http://www.allianz-profi.de (last visited Mar. 28, 2011).
92 Roland Prozessfinanzierung, http://www.roland-prozessfinanz.de/de/roland_prozess
finanz (last visited Mar. 28, 2011).
93 Foris AG, http://www.foris.de (last visited Mar. 28, 2011).
94 Roland Kirstein & Neil Rickman, FORIS Contracts: Litigation Cost Shifting and
Contingent Fees in Germany, CSLE Discussion Paper 2001-04 (2001), available at
http://econpapers.repec.org/paper/zbwcsledp/200104.htm; Michael Coester & Dagobert
Nitzsche, Alternative Ways to Finance a Lawsuit in Germany, 24 CIV. JUST. Q. 83, 84
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
(2005).
95 D.A.S. Prozessfinanzierung AG, http://www.das-profi.de (last visited Mar. 18, 2011).
96 Juragent Prozessfinanzierung, http://www.juragent.de (last visited Mar. 28, 2011).
97 ExActor, http://www.exactor.de (last visited Mar. 28, 2011).
98 Kirstein & Rickman, supra note 94, at 3-4.
99 See Schffel, Survey, Prozefinanzierung durch Dritte, BERLINER ANWALTSBLATT,
at 82 (2001).
100 Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 88.
101 For example, in Austria, AdvoFin Prozessfinanzierung AG, or Lexdroit. AdvoFin
Prozessfinanzierung AG, http://www.advofin.at (last visited Mar. 28, 2011); LEXDROIT,
http://www.lexdroit.at. (last visited Mar. 28, 2011). The first Swiss litigation financing
company was Prozessfinanz. Prozessfinanz, http://www.prozessfinanz.ch (last visited Mar.
28, 2011). See Christian Toggenburger, Financing Private Litigation A European
Alternative to Contingency Fees, 4 EUR. J. LAW REFORM 603 (2002).
102 See infra Section V.A.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
114 See Law, Finance, and Capital Markets A Rand Institute for Civil Justice Program,
http://www.rand.org/icj/programs/law-finance (last visited Mar. 28, 2011).
115 See Conference: Collective Redress & Litigation Funding, Sydney, Dec. 11 2009,
Canberra, Dec. 12-13, 2009, law.anu.edu.au/cle/CRLF_Conf09/flyer.pdf.
116 See Conference: New Trends in Financing Civil Litigation in Europe: A Legal,
Empirical and Economic Analysis, Erasmus Univ. Rotterdam, Apr. 24, 2009,
http://www.frg.eur.nl/home/research/research_programmes/behavioural_approaches_to_c
ontract_and_tort_relevance_for_policymaking/financing_civil_litigation (last visited Apr.
8, 2011).
117 Geoffrey McGovern, Neil Rickman, Joseph Doherty, Fred Kipperman, Jamie
Morikawa, & Kate Giglio, Trends and Implications for the Civil Justice System,
Presentation at Conference: Third-Party Litigation Funding and Claim Transfer, June
2009, http://www.rand.org/content/dam/rand/pubs/conf_proceedings/2010/RAND_CF272
.pdf.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
118 At the center of the debate was the recent RAND paper. See STEVEN GARBER,
ALTERNATIVE LITIGATION FINANCING IN THE UNITED STATES: ISSUES, KNOWNS AND
UNKNOWNS (RAND Corp. 2010), http://www.rand.org/pubs/occasional_papers/2010/
RAND_OP306.pdf.
119 See SHAVELL, supra note 9, at 387-443.
120 Under the American rule, each party pays for its own costs of litigation. See supra
note 20.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
Under the given conditions, because E(R) > E(C), the funder will
invest.
b. The Plaintiff
Assuming that the plaintiff is also a profit maximizer and that
he is bringing suit to receive the highest amount of money
possibleand not, for example, personal vindication, which he
may even be willing to pay forwe know from the basic
economics of litigation that, in absence of third-party funding, the
plaintiff will bring suit if his expected return from suit is higher
than his expected costs. 122 In other words, the plaintiff tries to
maximize his E(S), where E(S) = E(R) E(C).
In the presence of the availability of TPLF, we have two
possible scenarios. In the first scenario, one with no TPLF,
plaintiffs E(S) = E(R) E(C) = OR E(C). In the second
scenario, where the plaintiff receives TPLF, we indicate the
121 On applying risk analysis to litigation, see R.B. CALIHAN ET AL., supra note 18, at 5-
33.
122 SHAVELL, supra note 9, at 390.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
Or
123 In addition to poor people, this category includes creditors in the insolvency context,
where it would be impossible to pursue wrongdoers due to lack of funds.
124 Here the comparison is only between the condition of poor people with or without
TPLF. I am not discussing other alternatives for financing poor peoples litigation.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
Thus,
125 Under the English rule, the losing party pays for all litigation costs. See supra note
21.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
E(S) = 2000
b. The Plaintiff
From the viewpoint of the plaintiff, the decision to turn to
TPLF depends on whether the E(S) with TPLF is higher than the
E(S) without TPLF. That is to say, recalling that the apostrophe
() is used to make reference to the scenario with TPLF, the
plaintiff will turn to TPLF when:
the case, and are equally risk neutral, there is no room for gains
from the financing contractthere is no possible V that can be
agreed upon to benefit both parties. As is demonstrated in the
following subsections, this is true under both the American rule
and the English rule for allocation of legal expenses.
a. American Rule
Assume that both the funder and the plaintiff believe that the
outcome of the case will be favorable by a certain percentage O,
the value of the claim is of a certain amount R and that each
partys litigation costs are $20,000. Under these conditions of
perfectly symmetric information, there is no possible V that the
parties will agree upon. Unless their respective expected profit
under the financing contract is equal to that without the contract,
there will always be a V by which one party gains and the other
loses.
In fact, consider the following table, using apostrophe () to
indicate the situation with the funding agreement:
Funder Plaintiff
No TPLF E(R) = 0 E(C) = 0 E(R) = OR E(C) =
20,000
Yes TPLF E(R) = E(C) = E(R) = (1 E(C) = 0
V(OR) 20,000 V)OR
Funder Plaintiff
No TPLF E(S) = 0 E(S) = OR 20,000
Yes TPLF E(S) = V(OR) 20,000 E(S) = (1 V)OR
Because the funder and the plaintiff will only enter into contract if
their respective E(S) > E(S), the following can be said of the two
parties as to whether they will enter into contract:
Or,
b. English Rule
In this subsection I conduct the same test under the English
rule and I reach the same conclusion. Assume that both the
funder and the plaintiff believe that the claim is of a certain value
R, the probability of winning O is 60%, and the total litigation costs
(C = (Cp + Cd)) are 40,000. Now consider the following table,
which shows the expected payoffs of alternative scenarios (with
and without TPLF) for the funder and the plaintiff respectively:
Funder Plaintiff
No TPLF E(S) = 0 E(S) = OR (1 O) C
Yes TPLF E(S) = OVR (1 O) C E(S) = OR (1 V)
Because both the funder and the plaintiff will only be willing to
contract if their respective E(S) > E(S), then the following can be
said with respect to their willingness to contract:
Or,
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
2. Efficiency of TPLF
It has been demonstrated and explained why, under the right
conditions, both parties are made better off by TPLF, which
consequently has demonstrated itself to be efficient with respect to
the funder and the plaintiff.
From the point of view of the funder, a TPLF contract is
essentially an investment. Some concerns have been raised with
respect to the fact that third parties can profit from other peoples
litigation in which they have no interest other than financial.
However, as it has been shown earlier, investing in litigation is
something that already happensmore or less directlyin other
129 Compared to the individual plaintiff, litigation financing firms are likely to have
greater expertise and thus a higher ability to evaluate the probability of the success of a
claim.
130 In fact, a $20,000 loss is likely to negatively affect an individual plaintiff more than a
well-financed litigation funding company, for which such a loss might not be as significant.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
C. Externalities
We have learnt from the economic model that TPLF is in
principle efficient. At this point, the following question comes up:
if TPLF is efficient, why has it received judicial and institutional
resistance? And why is the question of its desirability receiving
1. Access to Justice
Access to justice is a vague concept. Both terms access and
justice can be interpreted in various ways, which can then
combine into a variety of meanings of the concept. 139 In broad
terms, access to justice is defined as the set of conditions that
allows those who wish to enforce or defend their legal rights the
reasonable opportunity to do so. 140 In particular, access to justice
has been framed in terms of access to the legal process and access
to the courts. 141 Furthermore, access to justice has been defined as
access to due redress. 142 This article does not address the question
of what should be meant by access to justice, and it will limit itself
to consider access to justice in the general sense, referring to ones
opportunities to defend his legal rights and to obtain due redress
for the wrongs received.
I mentioned earlier that TPLF increases the chances that a
claimholder will act for the protection of his rights. In fact, both
the poor plaintiff and the non-poor plaintiff benefit from
TPLF. 143 On the one hand, the claimholder who cannot afford to
2. Deterrence
The possibility for a claimholder and an investor to bargain
over property rights in litigation and to come to a TPLF
agreement, apart from making both parties better off, produces an
external effect on potential defendants that the law and economics
literature refers to as the deterrence effect. 146 If potential
defendants know in advance or reasonably expect that individuals,
who might potentially sue them, will not do so because of lack of
funds or risk aversion, then the former will have either no or at
least a lesser incentive to avoid the occurrence of those events
which would entitle the latter to a legal claim against the former.
Optimal deterrence requires potential injurers to be aware of
the fact that they will bear full costs of the harm they produce. 147
If potential injurers are aware of that, they will optimally
claims, resulting in a more costly civil justice system. 160 It has been
asserted that [e]ven if this were true, why would this be a bad
thing? 161 If the funded claims are not fraudulent and are based
on valid law, then it would not be a bad thing for these cases to
increase in number, because it would mean that more legal wrongs
are repaired and more wrongdoers are held accountable. 162
Perhaps society should devote more resources to the civil justice
system.
The question regarding the volume of litigation can also be
addressed from a different perspective, namely, the social versus
the private incentive to bring suit in a costly legal system. 163 This
perspective does not focus on the costs of the court system that are
borne by taxpayers. Instead, it focuses on the relationships
between, on the one hand, the private and social costs of litigation,
respectively (Cp) and (Cp + Cd), and, on the other, the private and
social benefits of litigation, respectively OR, and the external effect
on the behavior of potential defendants generally. 164 Assuming
that the overall level of litigation increases due to TPLF, the
question to address is whether the absolute value of the increasing
social costs (Cp + Cd)determined by the amount of litigation that
depends on the private incentive to litigate under TPLF (which in
turn depends on the private costs and benefits)outweighs the
absolute value of the social benefits of litigation, which can be
defined as the decrease of social costs due to the precautionary
activities of defendants which decreases the probability of loss to
victims from p to q, where p > q. If the absolute value of litigation
costs outweighs the absolute value of the deterrence benefits, then
TPLF is socially undesirable; in the opposite case, TPLF is
desirable. This is true under a perspective where the criterion for
desirability is assumed to be the minimization of total social costs,
which equals the sum of expected losses, prevention costs and
expected legal expenses. 165
The following model depicts the social desirability of TPLF
160 For the first attempt of empirical investigation in this direction, considering the
experience of Australia, see ABRAMS & CHEN, supra note 111.
161 Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, supra note 11, at 68.
162 Id. See New Hampshire Ins. Co. v. McCann, 707 N.E.2d 332, 337 (Mass. 1999);
Kevin Pennell, On the Assignment of Legal Malpractice Claims: A Contractual Solution to
a Contractual Problem, 82 TEX. L. REV. 481, 494-96 (2003).
163 See Steven Shavell, The Social Versus the Private Incentive to Bring Suit in a Costly
Legal System, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 333, 333-339 (1982).
164 Id. at 334.
165 Id. at 335.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
x + ql < pl
x + q(l + a + b)
pl
x + q(l + a + b) < pl
1. Traditional Prohibitions
TPLF has been growing throughout the common law world
during the past fifteen years. 168 However, the pace of its
development has not yet been determined by free market forces as
the industry has encountered resistance from courts of law which
have long been debating the legal status of TPLF. On the one
hand, in general termsthe range of which is broader than TPLF
as narrowly considered in this article 169third-party financing of
litigation has encountered its biggest obstacles in the common law
2. Australia
Maintenance and champerty were once torts and crimes in all
Australian jurisdictions. 188 However, courts allowed TPLF
184 A.L.G., The Effect of Champerty in Contractual Liability, 79 L. Q. REV. 493, 494
(1963).
185 See Susan L. Martin, Financing Litigation On-Line: Usury and Other Obstacles, 1
DEPAUL BUS. & COM. L.J. 85, 89-94 (2002). Other opinions that consider the relevance of
usury for TPLF include: McLaughlin, supra note 42; Rodak, supra note 45; Barksdale,
supra note 46; Richmond, supra note 43; Martin, supra note 43; WAYE, supra note 25.
186 The worlds first recorded usury law was part of the Babylonian Code of
Hammurabi, circa 1700 B.C.
187 In Echeverria v. Estate of Lindner, No. 018666/2002, 2005 WL 1083704, at *6 (N.Y.
Sup. Ct. Mar. 2, 2005), Judge Warshawsky wrongfully considered a litigation funding
agreement a loan based on the fact that a positive outcome of the suit was a sure
thing, because the plaintiff was suing under a statute that imposed strict liability. That
judgment has to be considered wrong because recovery in civil cases is not a sure thing
just for the fact of being based on strict liability. See supra note 44.
188 In Australia, the common law prohibition of litigation funding was justified in part
by the concern that the judicial system should not be the site of speculative business
ventures. However, the primary aim was to prevent abuses of court process (vexatious or
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
3. United States
The doctrines of maintenance and champerty traditionally are
also found in U.S. state common law, where they typically relate
back to the English common law doctrines which were previously
received and maintained following the American Revolution. 206
The two doctrines are very much interrelated or, more precisely,
champerty is a form of maintenancenamely an illegal form of
maintenance. 207 Restrictions to maintenance exist in varying
degrees across U.S. states. All states now permit at least one form
of maintenancelawyers contingency fees 208while, conversely,
all states prohibit at least what is referred to as malice
maintenance, i.e., when a third party supports a stranger litigant
for pure spite of malevolence toward the target of the person aided
by the maintainer. 209 As it appears from these two examples,
many conceptions of maintenance exist that are prohibited in
varying degrees across U.S. states. 210 What is of interest here is
what is referred to as profit maintenance, or champerty.
The legal status of champerty in the United States is not
uniform and its picture is quite complex. 211 For the purpose of this
section of the articlethat of providing an overview of the status
of TPLF in the common law worldI will use the following
paragraphs to summarize the evolution of the legal status of TPLF
in the United States, referring to the existing literature for more
detailed observations. 212
As in Australia, champerty is neither a tort nor a crime in
205 Charlie Gollow, Inv. Manager, IMF (Austl.) Ltd., Trends and Developments in
Australian Litigation Funding, Presentation at the RAND ICJ Conference: Alternative
Litigation Finance in the U.S.: Where Are We and Where Are We Headed with Practice
and Policy?, Washington, D.C. (May 21, 2010).
206 Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, supra note 11, at 98.
207 See supra Section V.A.1.
208 Lawyers contingency fees have also been defined as an exception to the prohibition
of champerty. See Martin, supra note 43, at 57; Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, supra note
11, at 100.
209 Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, supra note 11, at 102.
210 For a detailed discussion, see id. at 94.
211 For an in-depth analysis, see id. at 107. According to Sebok, restriction on
champerty can be classified under three categories: (1) restrictions on what lawsuits may
be maintained for profit; (2) restrictions on how lawsuits may be maintained for profit; and
(3) restrictions on the cause of the maintenance for profit. See id. at 108.
212 See id. at 74; Bond, supra note 171, at 1333-41 (who offers an overview of champerty
law in all fifty-two states).
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
213 As such, its visibility in case law is somehow proportional to the amount of
champertous agreements. Id. at 1304.
214 See supra Section III.B.
215 Hardick v. Homol, 795 So. 2d 1107 (Fla. 5th Dist. Ct. App. 2001); Osprey, Inc. v.
Cabana Ltd. Pship, 532 S.E.2d 269 (S.C. 2000); Saladini v. Righellis, 687 N.E.2d 1224
(Mass. 1997).
216 WAYE, supra note 25, at 111.
217 Rancman v. Interim Settlement Funding Corp., 99 Ohio St.3d 121 (Ohio 2003).
218 See, e.g., the position of the lower courts then reversed by the Ohio Supreme Court
in Rancman, 99 Ohio St.3d 121 (Ohio 2003).
219 See, e.g., GA. CODE ANN. 13-8-2 (West 2009); KY. REV. STAT. ANN. 372.060
(West 1942); LA. CIV. CODE ANN. art. 2447 (1995) (but only applies to purchases by
attorneys and officers of the court); MISS. CODE ANN. 97-9-11 (West 1976); N.Y.
JUDICIARY LAW 489 (McKinney 2004).
220 See, e.g., Midtown Chiropractic v. Illinois Farmers Ins. Co., 812 N.E. 2d 851 (Ind. Ct.
App. 2004); Johnson v. Wright, 682 N.W.2d 671 (Minn. Ct. App. 2004); Fleetwood Area
School Dist. v. Berks Cnty Bd. of Assessment Appeals, 821 A.2d 1268 (Pa. Commw. Ct.
2003); Toste Farm Corp. v. Hadbury, Inc., 798 A.2d 901 (R.I. 2002). The examples are
among those reported by WAYE, supra note 25, at 112.
221 Based upon the survey offered by Bond, supra note 171 (Appendix), reported and
updated by Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, supra note 11, twenty-eight U.S. states
permitted champerty as of 2002: ME. REV. STAT. tit. 9A, 12-101 (2007) (partially
amending ME. REV. STAT. tit. 17A, 516(1) (1975)); OHIO REV. CODE ANN. 1349.55
(West 2008) (reversing Rancman v. Interim Settlement Funding Corp., 99 Ohio St.3d 121
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
(Ohio 2003)); Landi v. Arkules, 835 P.2d 458 (Ariz. Ct. App. 1992); Abbott Ford, Inc. v.
Superior Court, 741 P.2d 124 (Cal. 1987); Fastenau v. Engel, 240 P.2d 1173 (Colo. 1952);
Robertson v. Town of Stonington, 750 A.2d 460 (Conn. 2000); Kraft v. Mason, 668 So.2d
679 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1996); TMJ Hawaii, Inc. v. Nippon Trust Bank, 153 P.3d 444
(Haw. 2007); Wright v. Meek, 3 Greene 472 (Iowa 1852); Boettcher v. Criscione, 299 P.2d
806 (Kan. 1956); Martin v. Morgan Drive Away, Inc., 665 F.2d 598 (5th Cir. 1982); Son v.
Margolius, Mallios, Davis, Rider & Tomar, 709 A.2d 112 (Md. 1998); Saladini v. Righellis,
687 N.E.2d 1224 (M.A. 1997); Smith v. Childs, 497 N.W.2d 538 (Mich. Ct. App. 1993);
Schnabel v. Taft Broad Inc., 525 S.W.2d 819 (Mo. Ct. App. 1975); Green v. Gremaux, 945
P.2d 903 (Mont. 1997); Adkin Plumbing & Heating Supply Co. v. Harwell, 606 A.2d 802
(N.H. 1992); Polo v. Gotchel, 542 A.2d 947 (N.J. Super. Ct. Law Div. 1987); Leon v.
Martinez, 638 N.E.2d 511 (N.Y. 1994); Odell v. Legal Bucks, LLC, 665 S.E.2d 767 (N.C.
Ct. App. 2008); Interstate Collection Agency, Inc. v. Kuntz, 181 N.W.2d 234 (N.D. 1970);
Mitchell v. Amerada Hess Corp., 638 P.2d 441 (Okla. 1981); Brown v. Bigne, 28 P. 11 (Or.
1891); Osprey v. Cabana Ltd. Pship, Inc., 532 S.E.2d 269 (S.C. 2000); Record v. Ins. Co. of
N. Am., 438 S.W.2d 743 (Tenn. 1969); Anglo-Dutch Petroleum Intl, Inc. v. Haskell, 193
S.W.3d 87 (Tex. App. 2006); Giambattista v. Natl Bank of Commerce of Seattle, 586 P.2d
1180 (Wash. Ct. App. 1978); and Currence v. Ralphsnyder, 151 S.E. 700 (W. Va. 1929).
222 As reported by A. Sebok, sixteen U.S. states now explicitly permit champerty as a
form of maintenance for profit: CO: Fastenau v. Engel, 240 P.2d 1173 (Colo. 1952); CT:
Robertson v. Town of Stonington, 750 A.2d 460 (Conn. 2000); FL: Kraft v. Mason, 668 So.
2d 679 (Fla. 1996); IA: Wright v. Meek, 3 Greene 472 (Iowa 1852); KS: Boettcher v.
Criscione, 299 P.2d 806 (Kan. 1956); ME: ME. REV. STAT. tit. 9A 12- 101 (2009) (partially
amending ME. REV. STAT. 17A 516(1) (2009)); MD: Son v. Margolius, Mallios, Davis,
Rider & Tomar, 709 A.2d 112 (Md. 1998); MA: Saladini v. Righellis, 687 N.E.2d 1224
(M.A, 1997); MO: Schnabel v. Taft Broad. Co., 525 S.W.2d 819 (Mo. App. 1975); NH:
Adkin Plumbing & Heating Supply Co. v. Harwell, 606 A.2d 802 (N.H. 1992); NC: Odell v.
Legal Bucks, LLC, 665 S.E.2d 767 (N.C. App. 2008); OH: ORC ANN. 1349.55 (2009)
(reversing Rancman, 99 Ohio St.3d 121(2003)); OK: Mitchell v. Amerada Hess Corp., 638
P.2d 441 (Okla. 1981); OR: Brown v. Bigne, 28 P. 11 (Or. 1891); WA: Giambattista v. Natl
Bank of Commerce of Seattle, 586 P.2d 1180 (Wash. App. 1978); and WV: Currence v.
Ralphsnyder, 151 S.E. 700 (W. Va. 1929). Sebok, The Inauthentic Claim, supra note 11, at
99.
223 WAYE, supra note 25, at 113.
224 For examples and cases, see id. at 113.
225 Id. at 114.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
4. United Kingdom
The experience of the United Kingdom is similar to the
Australian one to the extent that TPLF first developed in the
context of insolvency before expanding to the whole realm of
commercial litigation. Furthermore, unlike Australia (and the
United States), the UK experience has demonstrated that TPLF
need not to be so confined, but it can expand outside the
commercial context into what is commonly referred to as the
personal injury sphere. 231
Apart from the development of case law on litigation funding,
232 See ACCESS TO JUSTICE WITH CONDITIONAL FEES, supra note 25.
233 See Access to Justice Bill, 1998-9, H.L. Bill [58B] cl. 38 (Eng.), available at http://
www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm199899/cmstand/e/st990513/am/90513s01.htm.
234 WAYE, supra note 25, at 87.
235 Traditionally the common interest had to derive from the subject matter of the
claim, rather than being a commercial interest coincidental to the claim (Alabaster v.
Harness, [1895] 1 Q.B. 339 (Eng.)). However, in the 1990s, that requirement was relaxed
allowing for any genuine commercial interest to be the basis for an exception to the
common law position (see comments in Giles v. Thompson, [1993] 3 All E.R. 321, 333
(Eng.)).
236 As noted by WAYE, supra note 25, at 106-07, in England, the general position in
relation to insolvency office holders such as liquidators or trustees in bankruptcy is that
those office holders are exempt from prohibitions arising in champerty and maintenance
preventing the assignment of legal claims. Norglen Ltd. (in liq) v. Reeds Rains Prudential
Ltd., [1999] 2 A.C. 1 (Eng.); Ramsey v. Hartley, [1977] 1 W.L.R. 686 (Eng.); Guy v.
Churchill, [1888] 40 Ch. D. 481 (Eng.); In re Park Gate Waggon Works Co., [1881] 17 Ch.
D. 234 (Eng.); Seear v. Lawson, [1880] 15 Ch. D. 729 (Eng.).
237 Giles v. Thompson, [1994] 1 A.C. 142 (Eng.).
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
238 Ahmed v. Powell, [2003] P.N.L.R. 22 (Eng.); Factortame & Ors v. Secy of State for
Transport, Local Government and the Regions (No. 8) [2003] Q.B. 381 (Eng.).
239 Trendtex Trading Corp. v. Credit Suisse, [1982] A.C. 679, 683 (Eng.).
240 WAYE, supra note 25, at 104.
241 Ahmed v. Powell, [2003] P.N.L.R. 22 (Eng.).
242 This approach is confirmed by the recently proposed Code of Conduct for the
Funding by Third Parties of Litigation in England and Wales, proposed for consultation by
the Civil Justice Council to civil justice stakeholders in the summer of 2010. See CIVIL
JUSTICE COUNCIL, supra note 135.
243 If a conditional fee regime applies, funding agreements must conform to its
requirements. See Factortame & Ors v. Secy of State for Transport, Local Government
and the Regions (No. 8) [2003] Q.B. 381 (Eng.); Awwad v. Geraghty & Co., [2001] Q.B.
570 (Eng.).
244 See supra Section III.B.
245 Arkin v. Borchard Lines Ltd., [2005] 2 Lloyds Rep. 187 (Eng.).
246 WAYE, supra note 25, at 105.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
1. Traditional Prohibitions?
In the civil law world no specific legislative or judicial
prohibitions seem to apply to TPLF. However, the industry is not
developed. According to a recent report in the civil law world: 250
in Argentina there is no regulation on this issue; in Brazil third
party funding is not prohibited; in Bulgaria neither special
regulation nor restrictions on third party funding are provided; in
Estonia third party funding of claims is permitted based on the
general rules governing the performance of obligation by third
party; in Finland generally speaking, third party funding of
claims is not restricted but not very common; in France third-
party funding is not forbidden per se. As French lawyers can only
be paid by their clients or the clients agent (article 11.3 of the
National Bar Association Rules), third-party funding appears
possible under French law provided that the private party
concludes a contract with the plaintiff governing the funding and
apportioning of the damages obtained, and does not directly pay
the lawyers fees. In Italy, third party funding is possible but not
frequent; in Latvia there are no restrictions on third party
funding of claims; however, it is not common practice in Latvia;
in Mexico there is no express prohibition about third party
funding neither on the Federal Bill nor in the Mexico City Bill; in
2. Germany
TPLF in Germany operates in the framework of the following
context: as a rule, legal costs are borne by the losing party (or
apportioned between the parties); 255 costs are often high, are fixed
by law 256 and include court fees 257 and attorney fees; 258 additional
diminishing marginal rate. See Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 84.
258 INTRODUCTION TO GERMAN LAW 377 (Mathias Reimann & Joachim Zekoll eds.,
2d ed. 2005).
259 Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 84.
260 See supra Section III.B.
261 For an in-depth analysis of the contractual agreement regulating the relationship
between a plaintiff and a funder, see Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 87-94.
262 See id. at 95; N. Dethloff, Vertrge zur Prozessfinanzierung gegen Erfolgsbeteiligung,
NEUE JURISTISCHE WOCHENSCHRIFT 2225, 2227 (2000) (F.R.G.). See also DIRK
BTTGER, GEWERBLICHE PROZESSFINANZIERUNG UND STAATLICHE
PROZESSKOSTENHILFE: AM BEISPIEL DER PROZESSFHRUNG DURCH
INSOLVENZVERWALTER (2008) (F.R.G.).
263 It is interesting to notice here the typical civil lawyers attitude toward trying to
bring back innovative contractual agreements within the pre-determined contractual
types designed in the civil code. See MAURO BUSSANI, LIBERT CONTRATTUALE E
DIRITTO EUROPEO 28-35 (2005) (Italy).
264 Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 94.
265 A loan exists only where the borrower is obliged to pay back the received amounts
under no contingency. In TPLF contracts, the plaintiff is only obliged to repay if he is
successful and receives from the defendant the amount advanced by the funder. The same
argument has been made in the context of U.S. law. Echeverria v. Estate of Lindner, 2005
WL 1083704, at *6. See supra note 44 and comments therein.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
266 An insurance contract requires that the insurance coverage be provided in return for
a premium. See M. HENSSLER, RISIKO ALS VERTRAGSGEGENSTAND 373 (1994)
(F.R.G.); Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 95.
267 Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 95.
268 Vicki Waye, Conflicts of Interests Between Claimholders, Lawyers and Litigation
Entrepreneurs, 19 BOND L. REV. 225, 249 (2007) (discussing the existence of possible
conflicts of interest between the funder and the plaintiff in common law); Toggenburger,
supra note 101, at 627 (discussing the existence of possible conflicts of interest between the
funder and the plaintiff in civil law).
269 Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 95.
270 Id.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
271 Id.
272 Id.
273 Id. at 95.
274 For a description of other minor problems, see Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at
98-101.
275 Bundesrechtsanwaltsordnung [BRAO] [Federal Lawyers Act ], Aug. 1, 1959,
49(b) no. 2 (F.R.G.).
276 As reported by Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 95-98.
277 Toggenburger, supra note 101.
278 See Dethloff, supra note 262, at 2228; Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 96.
279 Coester & Nitzsche, supra note 94, at 96.
280 See id. at 96-97.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
obligation under this contract; (2) TPLF does not interfere with
the independence of the legal profession, the safeguard of which is
the aim of prohibition against contingency fees; and (3) a clients
financing contract does not create a conflict of interest between
the lawyer and the client.
The three conditions above clearly do not matter in their
descriptive dimension, but rather in their normative dimension. In
other words, the point is not that TPLF is permissible because that
is what happens in fact, but rather that TPLF contracts, in order to
be valid, must respect the above conditions. Once again, the
transfer of control of the litigation is what creates problems for the
validity of TPLF. If control is transferred from the claimholder to
the funder, then it is not true that the financing contract does not
have an impact on the lawyer. The lawyer will follow instructions
from the funder, will further the funders interest and not the
plaintiffs interest (when they diverge); he will have obligations to
the funder (e.g., duties to inform and provide documents), and
conflicts of interest will exist when the plaintiff and the funder
have different interests. 287 Once again, transfer of control in third-
party litigation financing contracts is a very delicate aspect. For
our purposes, however, which are limited to narrowly
considering the TPLF, TPLF contracts are to be considered valid
under German law.
287 It is truein principlethat both the plaintiffs and the funders interest is to
achieve the maximum possible award. However, their interests may diverge with respect
to timing andeventuallyalso to the amount of the award. While a plaintiff is usually a
one-shot player, who will then try to maximize the awards, a financing company is a
repeated player. The amount of awards it is interested in is a function of the investment,
not at all related to the merit of the claim. Possibly, if things get complicated during the
course of the litigation, the funder will be willing to accept any amount that is superior to
the costs he incurred, and will prefer to bring that case to conclusion soon instead of
investing further resources.
288 See supra note 242.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
that TPLF has not yet developed in the civil law world. On the
one hand, structural differences include the costs of the legal
system and the civil justice system, alternative methods of
compensation of attorneys and procedural rules. 289 That is to say
that not just positive rules, but rather all formants of legal system
should be considered in analyzing TPLF.290 On the other hand,
cultural differences include deep cultural models that are rooted in
a legal system, sometimes even in a way that is unconscious
not realized by the people within that legal system, but play a
significant role in the evolution of the law and legal culture. 291
First, litigation in common law jurisdictions is much more
expensive than in civil law countries. The very structure of the
American judicial process decentralizes power and activity: a large
variety of activities within litigation which are labeled official in
European legal systems, such as service of process, discovery, 292
and questioning of witnesses, are private matters in American law
and are therefore paid for by the parties. 293 Furthermore, punitive
damages are not contemplated in civil law countries thus reducing
the margin of profit from funding litigation. 294
Second, from a broader viewpoint, within the civil law-
common law divide, the civil law culture is considered to be less
litigious compared to its common law counterpart. 295 Third,
289 Some skepticism has been expressed with respect to the economical viability of the
TPLF industry in Europe. Toggenburger, supra note 101, at 621-627.
290 Sacco, after dwelling on the different formative elements of a systemnamely the
legal formantschallenges the traditional standpoint adopted by domestic jurists in
analysing their systems. In particular, he rejects the traditional static approach whereby
the legal rule is considered uniform and all the legal formants of one legal system are
regarded as being coherent with each other (thus giving the same answer to a question of
law). To the contrary, he argues that only through a dynamic and anti-formalistic
approach, whereby legal formants are in a competitive relation with each other, is it
possible to unveil the analogies and differences between different legal systems and to fill
the hiatus between operative rules and declamations. See Rodolfo Sacco, Legal Formants:
A Dynamic Approach to Comparative Law, Inst. 1 & 2, 39 AM. J. COMP. L. 1, 343 (1991);
P.G. Monateri & Rodolfo Sacco, Legal Formants, in 1 THE NEW PALGRAVE
DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW 531 (P. Newman ed., 1998).
291 In the comparative law literature, these are known as crittotipi. See ROFOLFO
SACCO, INTRODUZIONE AL DIRITTO COMPARATO, in TRATTATO DI DIRITTO
COMPARATO 125 (5th ed. 2005).
292 FED. R. CIV. P. 26.
293 See RUDOLF B. SCHLESINGER ET AL., COMPARATIVE LAW: CASES, TEXTS,
MATERIALS 428, 448 (6th ed. 1998); Ugo Mattei, A Theory of Imperial Law: A Study on
U.S. Hegemony and the Latin Resistance, 3 GLOBAL JURIST FRONTIERS, Art. 1, 9, 36
(2003), available at http://www.bepress.com/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1088&context=gj.
294 Toggenburger, supra note 101, at 620.
295 According to the data offered by Marc Galanter in 1983, the only countries, out of a
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
group of fifteen, that presented more than 40 yearly civil cases per 1000 people were
Australia, Canada (Ontario only), Denmark, England/Wales, New Zealand and the
United States. Among them, Denmark was the only civil law country (according to the
classification of legal systems provided by the University of Ottawa, supra note 250).
Among the others, Belgium, France, Japan, Norway, Sweden and West Germany were
between 20 and 31 per 1000 people; while Italy, The Netherlands, and Spain were below
10. See Marc Galanter, Reading the Landscape of Disputes: What we Know and Dont
Know (and Think we Know) about our Allegedly Contentious and Litigious Society, 31
UCLA L. REV. 4, 54 tbl. 3 (1983). On the litigiousness of the United States, see WALTER
K. OLSON, THE LITIGATION EXPLOSION: WHAT HAPPENED WHEN AMERICA
UNLEASHED THE LAWSUIT (1991); Macklin Fleming, Court Survival in the Litigation
Explosion, 54 JUDICATURE 109 (1970); B. Manning, Hyperlexis: Our National Disease, 71
NW. U. L. REV. 767 (1977). See also THOMAS F. BURKE, LAWYERS, LAWSUITS AND
LEGAL RIGHTS: THE BATTLE OVER LITIGATION IN AMERICAN SOCIETY (2002). For a
more recent view on the level of litigation in a comparative perspective, see STEPHEN C.
YEAZELL, CONTEMPORARY CIVIL LITIGATION 39-64 (2009).
296 See RICHARD SUSSKIND, THE END OF LAWYERS? RETHINKING THE NATURE OF
LEGAL SERVICES 27 (2008).
297 This approach is also visible in other fields of the law and perhaps it mirrors a
general attitude. Consider, for example, breach of contract: while in the United States the
primary remedy for breach of contract is compensatory monetary damages and specific
performance being the exception; in the civil law world, it is the other way around.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
298 For an early, comprehensive work discussing the success of the economic analysis of
law in civil law countries, see 11 INTL REV. L. & ECON. (1991), containing: R. Cooter &
J.R. Gordley, Economic Analysis in Civil Law Countries: Past, Present, Future, 261; U.
Mattei & R. Pardolesi, Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: A Comparative
Approach, 265; C. Kirchner, The Difficult Reception of Law and Economics in Germany,
277; G. Hertig, Switzerland, 293; S. Ota, Law and Economics in Japan: Hatching Stage,
301; S. Pastor, Law and Economics in Spain, 309; G. Skogh, Law and Economics in
Sweden, 319; W. Weigel, Prospects for Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries:
Austria, 325; and G. Hertig, The European Community, 331. For later works, see MATTEI,
COMPARATIVE LAW, supra note 8; LAW AND ECONOMICS IN CIVIL LAW COUNTRIES
(Bruno Deffains & Thierry Kirat eds., 2001); EDGARDO BUSCAGLIA & WILLIAM
RATLIFF, LAW AND ECONOMICS IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES (2000); Richard A. Posner,
Law and Economics in Common-Law, Civil-Law, and Developing Nations, 17 RATIO
JURIS 66 (2004); Aristides N. Hatzis, Civil Contract Law and Economic Reasoning: An
Unlikely Pair?, THE ARCHITECTURE OF EUROPEAN CODES AND CONTRACT LAW 159
(Stefan Grundmann & Martin Schauer eds., 2006).
299 Radin, supra note 180, at 48.
300 WAYE, supra note 25, at 12.
301 As mentioned earlier, in Asia, China and Japan are considering introducing legal-
expenses insurance. See Qiao, supra note 128, at 1.
302 Russia, for example, is showing interest in learning about best practices in (and
alternatives to) legal aid. See, e.g., INST. OF L. AND PUB. POLY, Project, Strengthening
Access to Justice for the Poor in the Russian Federation 2008-2012, http://ilpp.ru/page_pid_
578_lang_2.aspx (last visited Mar. 28, 2011).
303 See supra Section IV.A.2.
deMORPURGO_Article 11/1/2011 9:05 AM
VI. CONCLUSION
The ability of claimholders and third parties to bargain over
property rights in litigation enables interactions between the civil
justice system and the world of finance, which break with the
traditional conception of the litigation process. This approach
addresses a major problem traditionally considered inevitable: the
costs and risks of litigation. Third-party litigation fundingone of
the most innovative trends in civil litigation financing todayis
based on the existence of gains from trade in property rights in
litigation, and permits claimholders to eliminate the risk connected
to litigation. In exchange for the elimination of risk, the
claimholder pays a price, which is represented by the share of
awards that he promises to give to the funder in case of a favorable
outcome of the litigation.
The legal status of TPLF is currently at the center of a heated