Oecd Actiune 11
Oecd Actiune 11
Oecd Actiune 11
Project
Measuring
and Monitoring BEPS,
Action 11 - 2015 Final
Report
This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or
sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries
and to the name of any territory, city or area.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use
of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli
settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
References to "countries" should be read as including all jurisdictions.
OECD 2015
You can copy, download or print OECD content for your own use, and you can include excerpts from OECD publications, databases and
multimedia products in your own documents, presentations, blogs, websites and teaching materials, provided that suitable
acknowledgement of OECD as source and copyright owner is given. All requests for public or commercial use and translation rights should
be submitted to [email protected]. Requests for permission to photocopy portions of this material for public or commercial use shall be
addressed directly to the Copyright Clearance Center (CCC) at [email protected] or the Centre franais dexploitation du droit de copie (CFC)
at [email protected].
Foreword 3
Foreword
International tax issues have never been as high on the political agenda as they are
today. The integration of national economies and markets has increased substantially in
recent years, putting a strain on the international tax rules, which were designed more than a
century ago. Weaknesses in the current rules create opportunities for base erosion and profit
shifting (BEPS), requiring bold moves by policy makers to restore confidence in the system
and ensure that profits are taxed where economic activities take place and value is created.
Following the release of the report Addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting in
February 2013, OECD and G20countries adopted a 15-point Action Plan to address
BEPS in September 2013. The Action Plan identified 15actions along three key pillars:
introducing coherence in the domestic rules that affect cross-border activities, reinforcing
substance requirements in the existing international standards, and improving transparency
as well as certainty.
Since then, all G20 and OECD countries have worked on an equal footing and the
European Commission also provided its views throughout the BEPS project. Developing
countries have been engaged extensively via a number of different mechanisms, including
direct participation in the Committee on Fiscal Affairs. In addition, regional tax organisations
such as the African Tax Administration Forum, the Centre de rencontre des administrations
fiscales and the Centro Interamericano de Administraciones Tributarias, joined international
organisations such as the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank and the United
Nations, in contributing to the work. Stakeholders have been consulted at length: in total,
the BEPS project received more than 1400submissions from industry, advisers, NGOs and
academics. Fourteen public consultations were held, streamed live on line, as were webcasts
where the OECD Secretariat periodically updated the public and answered questions.
After two years of work, the 15actions have now been completed. All the different
outputs, including those delivered in an interim form in 2014, have been consolidated into
a comprehensive package. The BEPS package of measures represents the first substantial
renovation of the international tax rules in almost a century. Once the new measures become
applicable, it is expected that profits will be reported where the economic activities that
generate them are carried out and where value is created. BEPS planning strategies that rely
on outdated rules or on poorly co-ordinated domestic measures will be rendered ineffective.
Implementation therefore becomes key at this stage. The BEPS package is designed
to be implemented via changes in domestic law and practices, and via treaty provisions,
with negotiations for a multilateral instrument under way and expected to be finalised in
2016. OECD and G20countries have also agreed to continue to work together to ensure a
consistent and co-ordinated implementation of the BEPS recommendations. Globalisation
requires that global solutions and a global dialogue be established which go beyond
OECD and G20countries. To further this objective, in 2016 OECD and G20countries will
conceive an inclusive framework for monitoring, with all interested countries participating
on an equal footing.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
4 Foreword
A better understanding of how the BEPS recommendations are implemented in
practice could reduce misunderstandings and disputes between governments. Greater
focus on implementation and tax administration should therefore be mutually beneficial to
governments and business. Proposed improvements to data and analysis will help support
ongoing evaluation of the quantitative impact of BEPS, as well as evaluating the impact of
the countermeasures developed under the BEPS Project.
TABLE OF CONTENTS 5
Table of contents
Abbreviations and acronyms .......................................................................................... 11
Executive summary ......................................................................................................... 15
Chapter 1. Assessment of existing data sources relevant for BEPS analysis ........... 17
1.1 Introduction............................................................................................................ 18
1.2 Potential criteria for evaluating available data for BEPS research ........................ 18
1.3 Currently available data for BEPS analysis ........................................................... 24
1.4 Initial assessment of currently available data for analysing BEPS ........................ 26
Chapter 2. Indicators of base erosion and profit shifting ............................................ 41
2.1 Introduction............................................................................................................ 42
2.2 Indicator concept.................................................................................................... 42
2.3 Indicators as a component of Action 11................................................................. 43
2.4 Guidelines for indicators ........................................................................................ 44
2.5 A significant caution .............................................................................................. 45
2.6 Six indicators of BEPS .......................................................................................... 46
2.7 General structure of the indicators ......................................................................... 47
2.8 Disconnect between financial and real economic activities................................... 48
2.9 Profit rate differentials within top global MNEs ................................................... 52
2.10 MNE vs. comparable non-MNE effective tax rate differentials....................... 57
2.11 Profit shifting through intangibles ....................................................................... 60
2.12 Profit shifting through interest ............................................................................. 63
2.13 Possible future BEPS indicators with new data ................................................... 65
2.14 Indicators considered but not included ................................................................ 67
2.15 Summary .............................................................................................................. 68
Annex 2.A1. Formulas for calculating indicators ........................................................ 71
Chapter 3. Towards measuring the scale and economic impact of BEPS
and countermeasures....................................................................................................... 79
3.1 Overview ................................................................................................................ 81
3.2 Key issues in measuring and analysing BEPS ....................................................... 82
3.2.1 Defining BEPS ......................................................................................... 82
3.2.2 The counterfactual for BEPS analysis .................................................. 83
3.2.3 Separating BEPS from real economic activity ......................................... 84
3.2.4 Separating BEPS from non-BEPS preferences ........................................ 86
3.2.5 Measuring the appropriate tax rate for BEPS analysis ............................. 86
3.3 What we know about BEPS and the effect of countermeasures ............................ 88
3.3.1 General profit shifting analysis ................................................................ 88
3.3.2 Incentives for BEPS ................................................................................. 96
3.3.3 BEPS and developing countries ............................................................... 98
3.3.4 Estimating the scale (fiscal effects) of BEPS ........................................... 99
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
6 TABLE OF CONTENTS
3.3.5
3.3.6
3.3.7
Table 2.1.
Table 2.2.
Table 2.3.
Table 2.4.
Table 3.1.
Table 3.2.
Table 3.3.
Table 3.4.
Table 3.5.
TABLE OF CONTENTS 7
Table 3.A1.1.
Table 3.A1.2.
Table 3.A1.3.
Table 3.A2.1.
Table 3.A2.2.
Table 3.A2.3.
Table 3.A2.4.
Figures
Figure 1.1.
Figure 2.1.
Figure 2.2.
Figure 2.3.
Figure 2.4.
Figure 2.5.
Figure 2.6.
Figure 3.1.
Figure 3.2.
Figure 3.A1.1.
Figure 3.A1.2.
Figure 3.A1.3.
Figure 3.A1.4.
Figure 3.A1.5.
Figure 3.A1.6.
Figure 3.A1.7
Figure 3.A1.8.
Figure 3.A1.9.
Figure 3.A1.10.
Figure 3.A1.11.
Figure 3.A1.12.
Figure 3.A1.13.
Figure 3.A1.14.
8 TABLE OF CONTENTS
Figure 3.A1.15 Tax planning reduces the effect of corporate taxes on tax
planning MNEs investment................................................................ 178
Figure 3.A2.1. Potential approach to undertaking a fiscal estimate ............................ 196
Figure 3.A2.2. Intra-firm transactions as a percent of selected trade statistics ........... 204
Figure 3.A2.3. Potential steps to follow once data availability has been
determined ........................................................................................... 213
Figure 4.1.
Future path of BEPS measurement ..................................................... 252
Figure 4.2.
Data important for analysis of BEPS and countermeasures ................ 258
Boxes
Box 1.1.
Box 1.2.
Box 1.3.
Box 2.1.
Box 2.2.
Box 2.3.
Box 2.4.
Box 2.5.
Box 2.6.
Box 2.7.
Box 2.8.
Box 2.9.
Box 3.1.
Box 3.2.
Box 3.3.
Box 3.4.
Box 3.A1.1.
Box 3.A1.2.
Box 3.A1.3.
Box 3.A1.4.
Box 3.A1.5.
Box 3.A1.6.
Box 3.A1.7.
Box 3.A1.8.
Box 3.A1.9.
TABLE OF CONTENTS 9
Box 3.A1.10.
Box 3.A1.11.
Box 3.A1.12.
Box 4.1.
Box 4.2.
ACE
AETR
AMNE
AMTR
ATAF
B2C
Business-to-consumer
BEA
BEPS
BMD3
BMD4
BOP
Balance of payments
BvD
CbCR
Country-by-Country Reporting
CDIS
CFA
CFC
CIAT
CIT
CTJ
EBIT
EBITDA
ECJ
EITI
ETR
EPO
EU
European Union
FDI
FISIM
FL-METR
G20
Group of Twenty
GAAP
GAAR
GIE
GDP
GOS
HMRC
ICTD
IFRS
IMF
IP
Intellectual property
IRS
JCT
KBC
LOB
Limitation-on-benefits
MAP
MiDi
MNE
Multinational enterprise
MTR
NA
National Accounts
NGO
Non-government organisation
NIE
NOS
NSO
OECD
PCT
PE
Permanent establishment
PPT
R&D
SAAR
SOI
SPE
STAN
STR
TFDE
UNCTAD
USTPO
VAT
Value-added tax
WHT
Withholding tax
WIOD
WP
Working Party
WTO
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 15
Executive summary
The adverse fiscal and economic impacts of base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS)
have been the focus of the OECD/G20 BEPS Project since its inception. While anecdotal
evidence has shown that tax planning activities of some multinational enterprises (MNEs)
take advantage of the mismatches and gaps in the international tax rules, separating
taxable profits from the underlying value-creating activity, the Addressing Base Erosion
and Profit Shifting report (OECD, 2013) recognised that the scale of the negative global
impacts on economic activity and government revenues have been uncertain.
Although measuring the scale of BEPS proves challenging given the complexity of
BEPS and the serious data limitations, today we know that the fiscal effects of BEPS are
significant. The findings of the work performed since 2013 highlight the magnitude of the
issue, with global corporate income tax (CIT) revenue losses estimated between 4% and
10% of global CIT revenues, i.e. USD 100 to 240 billion annually. Given developing
countries greater reliance on CIT revenues, estimates of the impact on developing
countries, as a percentage of GDP, are higher than for developed countries.
In addition to significant tax revenue losses, BEPS causes other adverse economic
effects, including tilting the playing field in favour of tax-aggressive MNEs, exacerbating
the corporate debt bias, misdirecting foreign direct investment, and reducing the financing
of needed public infrastructure.
Six indicators of BEPS activity highlight BEPS behaviours using different sources of
data, employing different metrics, and examining different BEPS channels. When
combined and presented as a dashboard of indicators, they confirm the existence of
BEPS, and its continued increase in scale in recent years.
The profit rates of MNE affiliates located in lower-tax countries are higher than
their groups average worldwide profit rate. For example, the profit rates reported
by MNE affiliates located in lower-tax countries are twice as high as their groups
worldwide profit rate on average.
The effective tax rates paid by large MNE entities are estimated to be 4 to 8
percentage points lower than similar enterprises with domestic-only operations,
tilting the playing-field against local businesses and non-tax aggressive MNEs,
although some of this may be due to MNEs greater utilisation of available country
tax preferences.
Foreign direct investment (FDI) is increasingly concentrated. FDI in countries
with net FDI to GDP ratios of more than 200% increased from 38 times higher than
all other countries in 2005 to 99 times higher in 2012.
The separation of taxable profits from the location of the value creating activity
is particularly clear with respect to intangible assets, and the phenomenon has
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
16 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
grown rapidly. For example, the ratio of the value of royalties received to spending
on research and development in a group of low-tax countries was six times higher
than the average ratio for all other countries, and has increased three-fold between
2009 and 2012. Royalties received by entities located in these low-tax countries
accounted for 3% of total royalties, providing evidence of the existence of BEPS,
though not a direct measurement of the scale of BEPS.
Debt from both related and third-parties is more concentrated in MNE affiliates
in higher statutory tax-rate countries. The interest-to-income ratio for affiliates of
the largest global MNEs in higher-tax rate countries is almost three times higher
than their MNEs worldwide third-party interest-to-income ratio.
Along with new empirical analysis of the fiscal and economic effects of BEPS and
hundreds of existing empirical studies that find the existence of profit shifting through
transfer mispricing, strategic location of intangibles and debt, as well as treaty abuse,
these BEPS indicators confirm that profit shifting is occurring, is significant in scale and
likely to be increasing, and creates adverse economic distortions. Furthermore, empirical
analysis indicates that BEPS adversely affects competition between businesses, levels and
location of debt, the location of intangible investments, and causes fiscal spillovers
between countries and wasteful and inefficient expenditure of resources on tax
engineering. The empirical analysis in this report, along with several academic studies,
confirms that strong anti-avoidance rules reduce profit shifting in countries that have
implemented them.
However, these indicators and all analyses of BEPS are severely constrained by the
limitations of the currently available data. The available data is not comprehensive across
countries or companies, and often does not include actual taxes paid. In addition to this,
the analyses of profit shifting to date have found it difficult to separate the effects of
BEPS from real economic factors and the effects of deliberate government tax policy
choices. Improving the tools and data available to measure BEPS will be critical for
measuring and monitoring BEPS in the future, as well as evaluating the impact of the
countermeasures developed under the BEPS Action Plan.
While recognising the need to maintain appropriate safeguards to protect the
confidentiality of taxpayer information, this report makes a number of recommendations
that will improve the analysis of available data. Some of the information needed to
improve the measurement and monitoring of BEPS is already collected by tax
administrations, but not analysed or made available for analysis. The focus of the reports
recommendations in this area is on improved access to and enhanced analysis of existing
data, and new data proposed to be collected under Actions 5, 13 and, where implemented,
Action 12 of the BEPS Project.
The report recommends that the OECD work with governments to report and analyse
more corporate tax statistics and to present them in an internationally consistent way. For
example, statistical analyses based upon Country-by-Country Reporting data have the
potential to significantly enhance the economic analysis of BEPS. These improvements in
the availability of data will ensure that governments and researchers will, in the future, be
better able to measure and monitor BEPS and the actions taken to address BEPS.
Chapter 1
Assessment of existing data sources relevant for BEPS analysis
Key points:
This chapter assesses a range of existing data sources with specific reference to the
availability and usefulness of existing data for the purposes of developing indicators
and undertaking an economic analysis of the scale and impact of BEPS and BEPS
countermeasures.
This chapter concludes that the significant limitations of existing data sources mean
that, at present, attempts to construct indicators or undertake an economic analysis of
the scale and impact of BEPS are severely constrained and, as such, should be heavily
qualified.
While there are several different private data sources and aggregated official sources
currently available to researchers, they are all affected by various limitations that
affect their usefulness for the purposes of analysing the scale and impact of BEPS and
BEPS countermeasures.
One of the key challenges with currently available data sources is that it is difficult for
researchers to disentangle real economic effects from the effects of BEPS-related
behaviours.
Private firm-level financial account databases are useful, but are not comprehensive in
their coverage, have significant limitations in their representativeness in some
countries, do not include all MNE entities and/or all of their associated financial
information, and do not have information about taxes actually paid.
Some of the limitations of the currently available data also affect the ability of
individual governments to analyse how BEPS impacts their economies and tax
revenues.
While tax return data covering all subsidiaries of MNEs are potentially the most
useful form of data, most countries do not have or make such data available for the
purposes of economic and statistical analysis, even on an anonymised or confidential
basis. For example, it is difficult to determine the share of total corporate income tax
paid by MNEs, relative to purely domestic companies, as currently very few countries
make such data available.
Recent parliamentary and government enquiries have shed new light on the tax affairs
of some high profile MNEs. While this information represents a rich and emerging
source of evidence of the existence of BEPS, such information relates to the activities
of a small number of MNEs and is of limited use in undertaking a broader analysis. In
some cases, this information is not included in the available firm-level financial
account databases, which highlights the inadequacy of relying exclusively upon them.
Separating real economic effects from tax effects requires both data and estimation
methodologies, since even with good data, BEPS is not observable and must be
estimated. Nevertheless, more comprehensive and more detailed data regarding MNEs
is needed to provide more accurate assessments of the scale and impact of BEPS.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
1.1 Introduction
1.
Assessing currently available data is an important part of BEPS Action 11.
Having a proper understanding of the available data and its limitations is a fundamental
issue for the development of indicators showing the scale and economic impact of BEPS,
as well as for the development of economic analyses of the scale and impact of BEPS and
BEPS countermeasures.
2.
It cannot be overemphasised that the results obtained from any analysis are only
as robust as the data and methodology underpinning them. This is particularly true in the
case of analysing BEPS, since BEPS involves multinational enterprises (MNEs) that can
establish intra-group arrangements that achieve no or low taxation by shifting profits
away from jurisdictions where the activities creating the profits are taking place. These
intra-group cross-border arrangements are often very complex, involving multiple related
entities, and related party transactions are typically not separately identifiable (and
available) in tax or financial account databases.
3.
Hence, it is crucial to establish an understanding of the currently available data
what is available; the coverage and representativeness of that data; whether it is tax return
or financial account data; whether it is macro or micro-level data; its reliability and
robustness (what quality control measures are in place for the data collection); whether it
is comparable across jurisdictions; and who has access to it.
4.
This chapter provides an initial assessment of the data currently available for
analysing BEPS and BEPS countermeasures, which is relevant to both the development
of potential indicators and the undertaking of refined economic and statistical analyses. It
is important to note that most analyses, including government policy analyses and
decisions, are made with partial information. For policymakers, using available data to
conduct some analysis is better than working without empirical-based evidence at all, but
such analyses must also recognise the limitations of currently available data and how
those limitations may affect the reported results.
5.
The purpose of the assessment undertaken in this chapter is to describe what is
available, as well as outline the benefits and limitations of the different types of data.
Based on this assessment, Action 11 also involves the identification of new types of tools
and data that should be collected in the future. New data could include capitalising on
existing data that is currently unavailable, either due to confidentiality reasons or because
it is not currently processed or analysed, as well as additional information needed for
monitoring BEPS in the future, taking into account ways to reduce administrative costs
for tax administrations and businesses. A detailed discussion of potential new tools and
data is set out in Chapter 4.
1.2 Potential criteria for evaluating available data for BEPS research
6.
An assessment requires establishing a set of criteria to be used for evaluating the
different types of data with respect to their usefulness for analysing BEPS. Having a
thorough understanding of the available data will provide a solid base for working
towards best practices in future data collection to 'fill the gaps' and strive for more
comprehensive data and comparability across countries, recognising the trade-offs
between the objectives of improved tax policy analysis and the need to minimise
administrative costs for tax administrations and businesses.
7.
8.
Coverage/Representativeness: BEPS is a global issue so comprehensive coverage
across all countries would be ideal. Many macro-level aggregate data are available for
most countries. Coverage of the entities that form part of MNEs is an important issue. A
number of firm-level databases are available for individual countries, and the few private
global databases are increasing coverage across multiple countries.
9.
Even where data for a particular country exists, coverage issues may continue to
complicate a rigorous assessment of BEPS. One aspect concerns the coverage of financial
information for the entities included in the firm-level databases. Missing financial
information may have an equally detrimental effect on an analysis as if the entity were
not included in the database. Aggregation of financial information in respect of entities
within MNE groups can also distort and limit the analysis.
10.
Incomplete coverage of firms for any number of reasons means that the data
collected may be from a non-random sample and so, potentially, a non-representative
sample of firms. Extrapolating results beyond a non-random sample has limitations which
main reasons for bilateral asymmetries. Bilateral data on transactions other than FDI are
also important for analysing BEPS, for example trade in goods and services, royalty
payments and payments/receipts for services (e.g. legal, management and accounting
services). Coverage of bilateral flows between non-OECD/G20 countries and countries
with low corporate tax rates is often missing.2 Bilateral information does not provide
analysts with a view of the full chain of a transaction including the origin, transit points
and the final destination.3 Being able to see more than the first destination is important
given that many flows are routed via special purpose entities (SPEs) for tax-motivated
reasons.
16.
The 4th edition of the OECD Benchmark Definition of Foreign Direct Investment
(BMD4) recommends that countries explicitly separate FDI statistics on SPEs and nonSPEs for reporting purposes, which will result in more meaningful measures of real FDI.
Separate reporting of flows through SPEs also identifies particular financial flows, which
in some cases have facilitated BEPS behaviours. With the implementation of the latest
standards, nine countries (in addition to the four that have done so for several years) have
now reported data separating resident SPEs. More data will become available as more
countries are included in the new OECD database of FDI statistics later in 2015.4
17.
Micro-level data makes separating real and BEPS-related effects more likely,
since individual firm data allows adjustment for industry, size of company, situation in
the MNE group, and other non-BEPS tainted variables. In other words, analysis with
micro-level data makes it possible to identify and control for more, but not necessarily all,
non-tax characteristics of both affiliated firms and MNE groups that could affect BEPS.
18.
Ability to focus on specific BEPS activity: Differences between tax return and
financial account data represent an important limitation affecting the use of non-tax
financial account information for analysis of tax policy issues generally and BEPS
specifically. This is likely to be amplified in instances where an entitys financial profile
reported for accounting purposes does not correlate with its economic value-add in the
jurisdiction in which it resides (particularly for subsidiaries of foreign headquartered
MNEs and unlisted domestically headquartered MNEs). There are three main examples
of such book/tax differences. Firstly, book/tax income differences can include permanent
exemption of intragroup dividends and timing differences such as accelerated tax
depreciation. Companies in a MNE group report financial profits that include exempt
intragroup dividends. Differences between the tax consolidation rules and the statutory
accounting consolidation rules can affect consolidated accounts.
19.
A second book/tax difference relevant to BEPS analysis is the tax residence of the
company compared to the country of incorporation, where financial reporting is required.5
Due to differences in international tax rules, some companies have tax residence in a
country other than the country of incorporation, or in some cases companies have been
able to exploit mismatches between the tax laws of different countries with the result
being that they are not tax residents of any country. Also, financial accounts generally do
not show the sales or income of an entity across different countries, so analyses generally
assign all of the sales and income to the country of incorporation. For example, a branch
of a company could be earning income in a low-tax rate country, yet it is reported as
income of the company incorporated in a high-tax country, thus distorting both the
location of profits and the measure of the tax rate.
20.
A third book/tax difference is the actual tax variable. Financial statement accounts
under International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) or Generally Accepted
Accounting Principles (GAAP) include tax expense, which is an accrual measure of tax
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
than for policy action purposes. Financial statement information is publicly available
annually, often 2-4 months after the firms fiscal year has closed. Tax return information
is often not filed until late the following year, and the processing of the tax return
information for analysis purposes is often two years after the calendar year.
25.
Access to the information: MNEs file tax and regulatory reports with
governments, and those tax reports are available to the tax administration agency. In
many countries, the confidentiality of the tax return data prevents any sharing of the
information beyond the tax administration agency. Thus government tax policy analysis
outside of the tax administration may be limited to specific requests for anonymised
records or aggregate statistics. Non-government access to corporate tax return records is
typically not permitted, except for a few countries and only for strictly controlled research
projects with strict confidentiality rules. Aggregate corporate tax return data is published
by a number of countries, including information by industry and for certain taxpayer
attributes such as total assets or total revenue. Based on information collected in a recent
OECD Committee on Fiscal Affairs (CFA) WP2 on Tax Policy Analysis and Tax
Statistics (WP2) survey, only eight of the 37 respondent countries were able to provide
data on MNEs share of corporate income tax revenues.
26.
Other data issues: There are many other data issues that reduce the signal-tonoise ratio (real information content) of any empirical tax policy analysis. Analysis must
be undertaken with available data, but the analysts and users of the analysis should be
aware of the data limitations. A few of the additional data issues related to BEPS analysis
include:
Balance sheets typically reflect purchased intangibles only, since for both tax and
financial accounting most expenditures for intangible investments are deducted
immediately (expensed) rather than capitalised;
Intangibles are not limited to intellectual property, such as patents, trademarks and
copyrights, but may also include other important items, such as trade names,
brands, assembled workforce, and managerial systems, that are important to take
into account when considering the sources of real economic activity and value
creation;
Headline statutory tax rates are often not the tax rate applicable at the margin of
BEPS behaviour, due to specific country tax rules or administrative practices;
Effective tax rates, both tax paid and financial tax expense, can also reflect specific
non-BEPS related incentives, such as R&D tax credits;
Available data may be collected through a sampling process to reduce the burden
on respondents and the processing costs, but this raises issues of appropriate
weighting;
Existing data collection and processing may capture previous profit shifting
structures and transactions, but may not capture recent and new structures and
transactions to shift profits; and
Recent data may be impacted by the financial crisis and changing macroeconomic
conditions and may not be directly comparable to previous conditions.
Balance of
Payments (BOP)
MACRO
Foreign Direct
Investment (FDI)
Trade
MICRO
Customs (trade)
data
Company financial
information from
public / proprietary
databases
MICRO (continued)
Company financial
information from
government
databases
Tax return CIT
information
Tax audit
information
Detailed specific
company tax
information
33.
More complete information about global MNE activity is needed to analyse
BEPS. The analysis of BEPS would benefit from seeing the complete picture of the
activities of the MNE and its related entities. In particular, the ability to identify the
financial and taxation impacts of the activities of related entities relative to the economic
contributions made to the global value chain by the entities in each jurisdiction. Many tax
administrations currently only receive tax returns for the MNE entities required to file
taxes in their country. They might not have access to information about related party
affiliates undertaking transactions with the taxpayer in their country. The incomplete
picture can often result in BEPS behaviours not being transparent for identification and
quantification. Similarly, an incomplete picture of a MNEs financial arrangements can
obscure BEPS behaviours from researchers using financial accounts.
34.
Incomplete coverage of a MNEs economic activity across countries is
particularly problematic for analysis of BEPS if the coverage is non-random. In that case,
the sample of business entities may not be representative of the overall population. The
potential for non-representativeness in analysing BEPS is likely to occur in two particular
situations.
35.
First, if the missing businesses or activities are in either high-tax rate or low-tax
rate countries. Since BEPS typically involves profit shifting from high-tax to low-tax or
no-tax rate countries, arrangements to segregate profits from real economic activity
would be most likely to show up in those entities. For example, large reported profits in
no-tax countries, where there is little if any real economic activity or value creation would
be a result of BEPS.
36.
Second, entities engaged in BEPS behaviours may be less likely to report any
corporate holdings, offshore structures or activity that could highlight their BEPS actions
to tax authorities or publicly available sources, where their activities may become subject
to media and public attention. This may be because there is often discretion in some of
the public reporting (e.g. materiality exceptions), or the penalties for non-reporting may
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
be small relative to the benefits of avoiding disclosure of tax and financial information
that may include evidence of BEPS behaviours. Hoopes (2015) summarises academic
research on issues of disclosure and transparency, including several studies12 with regard
to geographic/segment reporting, which have found selective disclosure particularly by
tax aggressive MNEs.
37.
It should also be noted that some MNEs are voluntarily becoming more
transparent in their tax reporting. The driving forces behind this include the Extractive
Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI), requirements by the European Commission,
increasing public and government scrutiny that may affect reputation, and good
governance motives.
38.
An additional concern about incomplete coverage and lack of representation
arises if BEPS behaviours differ across countries (e.g. R&D intensive countries may be
more susceptible to BEPS behaviours involving intangibles while other countries may be
more affected by financial restructuring13), but the available data is not sufficiently
representative of the population such that it can capture the differences. Lack of
representation has been noted by Cobham and Loretz (2014)14 with respect to tax policy
analysis of developing countries. A recent IMF analysis concluded that developing
countries are likely to have significantly higher BEPS concerns than developed countries
due to lower tax administrative capacity to stop BEPS behaviours. Also, many studies of
profit shifting are based on the Amadeus database, which includes only European
countries, so the results may not be applicable to non-European countries.
39.
The most comprehensive (and widely-used by researchers) global database is the
proprietary BvD ORBIS database. It is an extensive database of almost 100 million
financial accounts from many countries, and is being continually updated, expanded and
improved. Although a useful global database, it has limitations,15 and is based upon
financial account rather than tax return data. With respect to its representativeness for the
purposes of BEPS empirical analysis, Cobham and Loretz (2014) note the Eurocentric
nature of the sample and its weakness in coverage of low-income countries. Table 1.2 is a
summary of the Cobham and Loretz data analysis, plus a comparison to the geographic
distribution of both the Fortune Global 500 MNE groups and GDP.
Europe
208,048
28,901
9,303
3,910
2,349
252,511
Location of Subsidiary
Latin &
Central
North
America & Middle East
America Australasia Caribbean
& Africa
9,933
3,451
1,465
835
23,095
2,363
803
125
4,624
20,318
276
84
556
432
672
11
297
75
32
567
38,505
26,639
3,248
1,622
Total
223,732
55,287
34,605
5,581
3,320
322,525
78%
12%
8%
1%
1%
100%
29%
28%
41%
3%
0%
100%
%
Representation
by location of
group
headquarter
69%
17%
11%
2%
1%
100%
GDP
27%
24%
34%
8%
7%
100%
Notes:
1. Regional distribution of top 500 companies in 2014 (Fortune Magazine)
2. GDP from IMF (current 2011 prices; 2011 used to compare with latest year used by Cobham and Loretz from Orbis)
Source: Cobham, A. & Loretz, S. 2014. International distribution of the corporate tax base: Implications of
different apportionment factors under unitary taxation
40.
For example, Table 1.2 shows that MNEs headquartered in Europe accounted for
69% of the affiliates in the ORBIS database; in comparison, MNEs from the rest of the
world accounted for only 31%. Of the total affiliates with key financial information
included, 78% were in Europe, while 22% were located in the rest of the world. This is
only a summary of the number of firms, and does not indicate how representative the
database is in terms of economic activity or taxes. The lack of representative data is likely
to be worse for developing countries. Furthermore, it does not indicate whether actual
data is available for all the firms included.
41.
Many academic studies have observed and estimated the existence of profit
shifting (including profit shifting from specific BEPS channels) with limited financial
account data, and in a few cases using tax return data, as described in Chapter 3.
Importantly, these studies find that BEPS is occurring and the extent of BEPS is large and
statistically significant. The limitations of the currently available data are problematic in
estimating the global scale and economic impact of BEPS. There is concern that sample
selection may result in underestimation of findings on aggregate profit shifting.16 Other
studies include both BEPS and individual tax evasion in their analyses of BEPS and are
thus likely to overstate the scale of BEPS.
42.
Recent public enquiries by legislative and/or parliamentary committees, such as in
the United Kingdom, the United States, and more recently Australia, into the tax
strategies of some high profile MNEs, have shed significant light on the tax affairs of the
affected parent companies and their affiliates.17 In addition, The European Commission
has launched a series of in-depth investigations into specific tax regimes that could be
considered as EU State Aid to MNEs.18 Investigative journalism has also brought much
useful information into the public domain.
43.
What is striking is that when one looks into the micro data available, much of this
newly revealed information does not appear to be visible either because certain
affiliates are not included or, where they are included, the financial information is
missing. This reveals a clear disconnect between the information revealed through
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
targeted public enquiries of some MNEs and the limited available tax information for
those same MNEs from consolidated financial statements. Box 1.2 explains this further.
Box 1.2. Public enquiries reveal data missing from many academic studies
Evidence emerging from several recent public enquiries into the tax affairs of a number of high
profile MNEs reveals clear deficiencies in the available data sources used by researchers in
analysing BEPS. The public enquiries revealed new information on the earnings, structure and
tax affairs of parent companies and their affiliates. The table below shows an example of one of
the MNEs reported pre-tax income.
The parent company, X, located in a high-tax jurisdiction, reported between 29 and 43 percent of
pre-tax earnings for the years 2009 to 2011. Xs affiliate, Y, located in a low-tax jurisdiction,
earned nearly two-thirds of the groups total pre-tax income in 2010 and 2011, and half of the
total in 2009.
Global Distribution of Specific MNE reported Earnings:
Pre-tax income
Entity
X (Parent)
Location
High tax
country
Low tax
country
2011
2010
2009
31
29
43
64
65
50
Other
Total
100
100
100
Y (Affiliate)
While Affiliate Y earned the majority of the pre-tax income, it paid virtually no taxes to any
government for these three years. Due to different rules for determining tax residence, a key
entity incorporated in the low-tax country was not taxable in any country. Thus, several tens of
billions of the parents local currency were only taxed at a 0.06% tax rate over three years.
In a micro database used by many researchers to analyse BEPS, the financial information for the
key affiliate (Y) in the low tax country was missing. This reveals a clear disconnect between the
information revealed through targeted public enquiries of some MNEs and the incomplete
available financial information for those same MNEs from financial accounts. Much of the
important information for tax analysis is simply absent. The fact that such observed instances of
BEPS are not visible in firm-level financial account databases highlights concerns regarding the
reliability and representativeness of one of the most frequently used existing data sources.
44.
Additional analysis of tax return information is needed. As noted above,
significant differences exist between tax return information and financial accounts, which
make financial account information problematic as a sole source for analysing BEPS,
even if it was comprehensive.
45.
Tax return information submitted to individual countries is also not
comprehensive in terms of the full picture of the MNE group, but it is less likely to be
subject to underreporting due to the significant financial penalties for tax noncompliance. Tax return data will have accurate information about the country of tax
residence, taxable income, tax paid, tax credits, and tax consolidation, which reduces
significant noise present in financial accounts. Information obtained from tax audits can
identify new types of BEPS behaviours, and could potentially be used if compiled and
analysed systematically to monitor BEPS behaviours in the future.19
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
Box 1.3. Some current best practices in using available data for BEPS analysis
Germany The Deutsche Bundesbank houses the Micro database on Direct Investment (MiDi),
which is a full census of foreign firms affiliates in Germany. It covers directly or indirectly
owned foreign affiliates of German parent companies above a certain size and ownership
threshold, including affiliates in developing countries. It contains unconsolidated (sometimes
consolidated) balance sheet data at the firm level, ownership variables (links between affiliates
and parent company), as well as other useful information such as liabilities to shareholders and
(or) affiliates; total balance sheet of affiliates and parent company; and shares in the assets and
liability positions of non-residents. The data includes profit after tax, but does not include other
income statement information, such as taxes or income/expense information for analysing
specific BEPS channels. The MiDi data is confidential and available only on site at the Research
Centre at the Central Office of the Deutsche Bundesbank in Frankfurt for approved research
projects and under strict confidentiality rules.
Sweden Government analysts in Sweden have access to detailed, anonymised taxpayer
information from filed tax returns. The firm-level information also includes balance sheet
information, the number of domestic employees, employee compensation, and the value of
tangible and intangible assets. The data distinguishes between MNEs and purely domestic firms,
with a further breakdown available by sectors. Information on foreign source income and related
party transactions (e.g. controlled foreign corporations), and the amount of R&D expenditures
undertaken in the country is not captured in tax returns. A useful practice that could be replicated
in other countries is using information available from other sources, such as commercial sources
to supplement the governments database. However, the Swedish data lacks detailed income
information on foreign subsidiaries.
Latin America Some tax authorities, such as in Argentina, request companies to present
special forms with information relating to transactions with related parties as well as with
entities located in non-cooperative jurisdictions, and non-related parties. The information covers
trade in goods and specifies prices, volumes and trading partners. Some Latin American
countries share data extracted from these forms (e.g. effective tax rates, intragroup transactions,
and transactions with parties located in tax havens) with international organisations, such as the
Inter-American Centre of Tax Administrations (CIAT), upon request, even if they are not shared
with the public. This suggests that there are opportunities for international organisations to
construct comparable data for developing countries20.
United States The United States Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) surveys both UNITED
STATES headquartered firms (and their affiliates abroad) and subsidiaries in the United States
of foreign headquartered firms. Both surveys are done on an annual basis with more detailed
benchmark surveys done every five years. MNE firms operating in the United States are required
by law to respond to these surveys, but the survey information is not shared with tax or financial
reporting authorities to enable verification, and confidentiality is assured. The aggregated data
are publicly available, and the micro data can be accessed by non-government researchers under
strict confidentiality rules. The current data does not enable full consolidation, can include some
double counting of affiliated entities, and does not identify hybrid securities that can be used for
shifting income. The data for each affiliate includes the country of location of its physical assets
as well as its country of incorporation, though neither of these are necessarily its country of tax
residence.
Box 1.3. Some current best practices in using available data for BEPS analysis
(continued)
The United States Internal Revenue Service (IRS) collects tax return information on controlled
foreign corporations (CFCs) of United States parents, plus tax return information on United
States subsidiaries of foreign parents. Some of the tax return data is compiled and tabulated for
published aggregate tables, and compiled micro data is available for certain government analysts
as well as certain approved non-government researchers. While most corporate micro data for
analysis are stratified random samples, in the international area micro data is more likely to be
for the population of multinational corporations. This enables a relatively complete picture of all
the CFCs of United States parents though some information on lower tiers may be missing. Data
are reported by country of incorporation and therefore the country of reporting for some entities,
particularly hybrid or stateless entities, does not necessarily reflect the country of tax residence.
For United States subsidiaries with foreign parents, data are generally limited to United States
activity. The CFC data is important in tax policy analysis particularly because it includes
linkages with affiliated entities.
50.
In 2011, the OECD Expert Group for International Collaboration on Microdata
Access was formed to examine the challenges for cross-border collaboration with micro
data. The resulting 2014 report21 notes: The challenge in the 21st Century is to change
practices in access to micro data so that the access services can cross borders and
support trans-national analysis and policy making. This is necessary to reflect the
increasingly international (global) reach and impact of comparative analysis and shared
policy making.
51.
Instead of suggesting new legislation, substantial new infrastructure, or new
technology for doing so, the report seeks smarter deployment of what already exists in
most OECD countries. Of course, in the micro-level tax return data context for BEPS,
data collection, dissemination and access is still not ideal. The report highlights the
importance of comparability and thus working towards homogeneity in data collection
across countries. It states that regional and international shared policy making needs the
support of evidence drawn from comparative analysis and/or the combined data of the
national parties to the collaboration. Working with available firm/group-level financial
statements, for example, reveals the heterogeneity across reporting standards for
accounting purposes worldwide. The level of detail (and whether this is provided
geographically or by segment) in which groups choose to report certain items like sales,
assets, profits and employees differs widely. There are also vast differences in the
mandatory information required by different tax authorities.
52.
It is important to emphasise that in most cases BEPS must be estimated rather
than directly observed from tax returns, financial accounts or customs records. For
example, identifying deviations from arms length pricing is a highly fact-intensive
analysis. Analysis of customs data for individual product pricing must distinguish
between sales to related parties and third-parties, and analysis of relatively unique
transfers of intangible assets requires analysis of comparable transactions. Comparisons
of profits and effective tax rates across thousands of companies require sophisticated
statistical analysis to truly separate tax aspects from real economic activity. Simple
descriptive statistics can only provide indications, rather than correlation or causation, of
potential BEPS behaviours, and statistical analysis of large databases may also only be
able to provide rough measures or indications of BEPS due to current data limitations.
Nonetheless, analysis of available data by statistical and economic analysis will provide
additional insights beyond descriptive statistics.
53.
Processed corporate tax return information for MNEs and their foreign affiliates
have been analysed by governments and, in some countries, academic researchers.
Linkage of tax return information with other business administrative records within
governments could increase the insights from existing data. However, access to existing
tax return information for tax analysis purposes is not always possible. In addition, many
government tax policy agencies and tax administrations have limited resources to conduct
empirical statistical and economic analysis. Some countries provide good examples of
what can be achieved as there are co-operative research programmes between government
and academics for analysis of data under strictly controlled and confidential
circumstances by academics with specific research programmes. This promotes robust
economic and statistical analysis based on access to firm-level data.
54.
Although having a large database with many observations is helpful for statistical
analysis, such a database may exclude important available information. Sometimes the
quality and depth of an analysis is more insightful than the quantity of observations
providing a non-random and/or less in-depth analysis. Thus, although examples of BEPS
behaviours by some major MNEs should not be extrapolated to all MNEs, detailed
information from public enquiries should be considered. Existing databases used for
economic analysis of BEPS should be checked to see if identified cases of BEPS are
included in the data. Finally, this assessment of the currently available data for economic
analysis of BEPS and potential countermeasures has identified significant data
limitations, data issues, and in some cases data gaps in the various data sources currently
available for analysing BEPS and BEPS countermeasures.
Bibliography
Akamah, H.T., O.-K. Hope and W.B. Thomas (2014), Tax havens and disclosure
aggregation, Rotman School of Management Working Paper, No. 2419573.
Australia (2014), Parliament of Australia: Inquiry into tax disputes,
www.aph.gov.au/Parliamentary_Business/Committees/House/Tax_and_Revenue/Inqu
iry_into_Tax_Disputes (accessed 19 December 2014).
Beer, S. and J. Loeprick (2013), Profit shifting: Drivers and potential countermeasures,
WU
International
Taxation
Research
Paper
Series,
No.
2013-03,
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2271539.
Buettner, T and G. Wamser, G. (2007), Intercompany loans and profit shifting: Evidence
from company-level data, CEsifo Working Paper Series, No. 1959.
Bureau Van Dijk, ORBIS Database, Bureau Van Dijk Electronic Publishing.
Cederwall, E. (2015), Making sense of profit shifting: Jack Mintz, Tax Foundation
interview, http://taxfoundation.org/blog/making-sense-profit-shifting-jack-mintz.
Cobham, A. and S. Loretz (2014), International distribution of the corporate tax base:
Impact of different apportionment factors under unitary taxation, ICTD Working
Paper, No. 32.
Dharmapala, D. (2014), What do we know about base erosion and profit shifting? A
review of the empirical literature, Fiscal Studies, Vol. 35, pp. 421448.
European Commission (2014), State aid: Commission extends information enquiry on tax
rulings practice to all member states, http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-142742_en.htm (accessed 8 January 2014).
Hanlon, M. (2003), What can we infer about a firms taxable income from its financial
statement?, National Tax Journal, Vol. 56, Issue 4, pp. 831-863.
Hoopes, J. 2015, Taxes and disclosure: A brief summary of the research, (mimeo).
Hope, O.K., M. Ma and W.B. Thomas (2013), Tax avoidance and geographic earnings
disclosure, Journal of Accounting & Economics, Vol. 56(2-3), pp. 170-189.
House of Lords Select Committee on Economic Affairs (2013), Tackling corporate tax
avoidance in a global economy: is a new approach needed?, First Report of Session
201314, www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201314/ldselect/ldeconaf/48/48.pdf
(accessed 14 October 2014).
Huizinga, H., L. Laeven and G. Nicodeme (2008), Capital structure and international
debt shifting, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 88, pp. 80-118.
IMF (2014), Co-ordinated Direct Investment Survey: Project on bilateral asymmetries,
IMF Policy paper,
http://data.imf.org/?sk=D732FC6E-D8C3-44D1-BFEB-F70BA9E13211.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
Notes
1.
2.
3.
Cederwall, E. (2015), Making Sense of Profit Shifting: Jack Mintz. Tax Foundation.
4.
OECD 2015. Implementing the latest international standards for compiling foreign
direct investment statistics: How multinational enterprises channel investments
through multiple countries.
5.
6.
For financial accounting purposes, the objective is to record both current-year and
future-year tax liabilities (tax expense) associated with the current-year economic
activities of a firm. This differs from actual, current-year tax payments that may have
been generated by prior-year economic activities and do not include the future tax
payments from current-year economic activities. See Hanlon (2003) and Lisowsky
(2010).
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
E.g. Weyzig (2014), Buettner and Wamser (2007), Huizinga et al. (2008).
12.
Hope et al. (2013) examined firms responses to a United States accounting rule
change in 1998, which allowed firms to stop providing segment reporting at the
geographic level. The analysis found that firms that discontinued geographic segment
reporting were those that had lower effective tax rates, consistent with firms interest
in not reporting information that would potentially reveal tax avoidance behaviour. In
a similar paper, Akamah et al. (2014) find that firms with operations in tax havens are
more likely to aggregate their geographic segment disclosures.
13.
Cederwall, E. (2015), Making Sense of Profit Shifting: Jack Mintz. Tax Foundation.
14.
Cobham and Loretz (2014) use the largest commercially available database of
company balance sheets, ORBIS. Using a dataset of over 200,000 individual
companies in over 25,000 corporate, they state coverage is severely limited among
developing countries, and increasingly so for lower-income countries, and where
there are non-random reasons for information to be missing (e.g. accounts in low-tax
jurisdictions are less likely to be included in the dataset), this will result in systematic
biases to the results.2014
15.
In response to the OECD (2014) BEPS Action 11 Request for Input, Reinald Koch
and Andreas Oestreicher list some of the limitations: there is no distinction between
interest and dividend income, or between intra-group and third party transactions; the
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
publishers of the data rely on extent to which companies publish reports; there are
missing companies in the data as well as missing financial information from
companies that are included; it is not a random sample as it depends on information
released by business sector; and it can be assumed that information is lacking in
particular for entities that are used for tax planning purposes.
16.
Beer and Loeprick (2013) estimate profit shifting, and find significant effects, but
note the selection criterion reduced their sample by more than 60%, possibly
resulting in a bias as incomplete accounting information may be correlated to less
transparent corporate governance and more aggressive tax optimization. Such a bias
would likely result in an underestimation of findings on aggregate profit shifting.
17.
Commons Select Committee on Tax avoidance and evasion in the United Kingdom
(2015); House of Lords Select Committee on Economic Affairs (2013); The
Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations in the United States (2013); Inquiry into
Tax Disputes in Australia (2014).
18.
19.
20.
BEPS Monitoring Group, submission to Action 11 Request for Input, September 2014
21.
Chapter 2
Indicators of base erosion and profit shifting
Key points:
While there is a large and growing body of evidence of the existence of BEPS,
through empirical analysis and specific information relating to the affairs of certain
MNEs that has emerged from numerous legislative and parliamentary enquiries, the
scale of BEPS and changes in BEPS over time are difficult to measure.
This chapter presents six indicators to assist in tracking the scale and economic impact
of BEPS over time, while noting the strengths and limitations of each indicator. The
six indicators point to a disconnect between financial and real economic activities,
profit rate differentials within top global MNEs, tax rate differentials between MNEs
and comparable non-MNEs and profit shifting through intangibles and interest.
The use of any indicators to identify the scale and economic impact of BEPS can only
provide general indications and the interpretation of any such indicators must be
heavily qualified by numerous caveats.
While no single indicator is capable of providing a complete picture of the existence
and scale of BEPS, a collection of indicators or a dashboard of indicators can
provide broad insights into the scale and economic impact of BEPS and provide
assistance to policymakers in monitoring changes in BEPS over time.
This chapter also provides calculations for the indicators, using samples of existing
available data. The data used to produce these calculations are affected by the
considerable limitations of existing available data sources described in detail in
Chapter 1. As a result, the indicators are illustrative rather than definitive, as the
insights that can be discerned from these indicators are greatly affected by the
limitations of the existing available data.
Future access to more comprehensive and improved data would allow much greater
insight to be obtained from the use of these indicators as well as two potential
indicators that could be constructed with improved future data.
The six BEPS indicators show strong indications of BEPS behaviours using different
sources of data, employing different metrics, and examining different BEPS channels.
When combined and presented as a dashboard of indicators, they provide evidence of
the existence of BEPS, and its continued increase in scale. Improved data availability
can provide better insights in the future.
2.1 Introduction
55.
One of the key components of Action 11 is the development of indicators that
can be used to identify the scale and economic impact of BEPS, to track changes in BEPS
over time and to monitor the effectiveness of measures implemented to reduce BEPS.
56.
The first step in developing useful indicators of BEPS is defining the concept.
BEPS relates to arrangements that achieve no or low taxation by shifting profits away
from the jurisdictions where the activities creating those profits take place or by
exploiting gaps in the interaction of domestic tax rules where corporate income is not
taxed at all. No or low taxation is not per se a cause of BEPS, but becomes so when it is
associated with practices that artificially segregate taxable income from the activities that
generate it. The important distinguishing characteristic of BEPS is tax planning strategies
that result in a disconnect between the geographic assignment of taxable profits and the
location of the underlying real economic activities that generate these profits. As a result
of this disconnect, MNEs may be able to shift profits from higher-taxed countries to
lower-taxed countries without a corresponding material change in the way the taxpayer
operates, including where products and services are produced, sales and distribution
occur, research and development is undertaken, and how the taxpayers capital and labour
are used. In some cases, BEPS involves placing just enough economic activity in a
jurisdiction to attempt to justify the tax planning strategy.
57.
An overriding objective in the construction and analysis of BEPS indicators in
Action 11 is to develop metrics that help portray the extent of practices that artificially
segregate taxable income from the activities that generate it.
59.
As with any gauge, the degree of precision depends on the available information
and the accuracy of the measurement tools. Given currently available data and distortions
caused in that data by BEPS which is being measured, at this stage BEPS indicators can
only provide some general insights into the scale and economic impact of BEPS, but will
necessarily lack the precision that may become possible if more comprehensive and
improved data sources were to be used in the future (see Chapter 1 for a detailed
assessment of the limitations of currently available data). More refined analysis and
estimates of BEPS, based on multi-variate statistical estimation, are possible with
currently available data, but also involve significant uncertainties and limitations (see
Chapter 3 for a detailed examination of the approaches to undertaking such estimation).
Over time, the proposed indicators will provide a general sense of the trend in a number
of key metrics associated with BEPS behaviours.
60.
The concept followed in developing the BEPS indicators has been to create a
dashboard of indicators that provides an indication of the scale of BEPS and help
policymakers monitor changes in the scale of BEPS over time. The indicators are crude
proxies for a more refined and sophisticated estimate of the dimensions of BEPS. Given
currently available data, indicators are probably the appropriate approach to showing
consistent trends on the general scale of BEPS. Multiple indicators can help identify
trends regarding the scale of BEPS and changes in BEPS and specific BEPS behaviours.
An important requirement of an indicator is that it provides more signal than noise in
measuring the scale of BEPS. To the extent that various potential indicators provide the
same signal (i.e. a high correlation) on the same dimension, then only the clearest
indicator should be used.
61.
While no single indicator can be used to provide a complete picture of the scale or
economic impact of BEPS, if a number of separate indicators referring to different
dimensions are pointing in the same direction, they may provide more solid information
on the presence of and trends in BEPS.
Current State
Indicators of
BEPS with
available data
Analyses of
economic
impact of BEPS
and countermeasures with
available data
Future State
New and
refined
indicators with
better data
Refined
analyses of
economic
impact of BEPS
and countermeasures with
better data
Ideal
True measures of
BEPS and
countermeasures
BEPS, not real economic responses to tax rate differences that reflect the impact of
current-law provisions adopted by legislators, including incentives to expand business
operations in their country. Legislated or discretionary tax incentives can have an
important impact on reported corporate income tax payments that reflect the location of
real economic activity. The challenge in developing indicators is distinguishing between
the economic effects and BEPS. However, artificial cross-border arrangements to exploit
legislated differences in tax structures, including statutory tax rate differences, are
considered BEPS.
70.
The BEPS indicators should be able to be refined with potential new data
sources. The initial indicators are based on currently available data for a large number of
countries. New methodologies and data sources will be identified going forward to
analyse the scale of BEPS and the effectiveness of countermeasures to reduce BEPS. In
some cases the initial indicators could be calculated from new data sources which could
provide more targeted and accurate information for estimating BEPS.
71.
Bad indicators should be avoided; caveats should be highlighted. Almost as
important as developing effective indicators of BEPS is the need to avoid using poor,
imprecise and misleading indicators. Indicators should have a high signal-to-noise ratio.
In other words, indicators should provide a high ratio of information about BEPS
behaviours relative to real economic effects and other non-BEPS factors. Any indicator
will have limitations which should be highlighted. All indicators will require careful
interpretation in analysing BEPS.
72.
Indicators should be simple, clear and timely. Indicators will be used by
policymakers, so they should be simple, clear and well-described. However, their caveats
and limitations should also be clearly noted. Where possible, indicators should not have
significant time lags.
73.
Indicators should be adaptable to extended uses. The initial indicators focus on
the global perspective, but some indicators should have the potential to be extended to be
used by individual countries or for specific industries. The development of disaggregated
indicators should be considered for future analysis.
This chapter presents six specific indicators in the following five categories:
Profit rate differentials within top (e.g. top 250) global MNEs
2. Differential profit rates compared to effective tax rates
3. Differential profit rates between low-tax locations and worldwide MNE
operations
C.
80.
In addition, two possible additional indicators are discussed that could be
estimated from improved future data when it becomes available.
81.
Indicators 1 and 5 are based on macro-level data on a country-by-country basis.
Indicators 2-4 and 6 are calculated from MNE, firm-level financial information from the
ORBIS database2 for unconsolidated affiliates and/or worldwide consolidated groups.
82.
In order to partly distinguish between BEPS and real economic impacts, most of
the indicators are constructed using various comparison groups, such as different groups
of countries, different groups of MNE affiliates or worldwide MNE measures vs. affiliate
measures. The objective is to compare measures where BEPS is likely to be relatively
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
important to measures that are more likely to reflect real economic activities. The use of
these comparison groups is designed to increase the signal-to-noise ratio of the indicators.
2.8.1.2 Limitations
FDI information includes financial stocks, as well as stocks related to real
economic activities. The indicator has to be carefully evaluated in reaching
conclusions about the presence of BEPS. In addition, not all BEPS behaviours
are captured by FDI statistics.
Countries report transactions related to BEPS, such as transactions with special
purpose entities, in different ways. This introduces cross-country variations in
FDI based on reporting differences.
2.8.1.3 Issues
FDI is measured relative to GDP. However, other measures of real economic
activity, such as trade flows (both imports and exports), and annual capital
formation could be used in constructing the indicator.
Indicator 1: Concentration of foreign direct investment relative to GDP
Description: This macro-economic indicator is the ratio of the stock of FDI to a
countrys GDP, a measure of real economic activity. The indicator compares the FDI
ratio in countries with relatively high values of FDI to GDP ratios to the same ratio in the
rest of the included countries. Two versions of the FDI measure are presented.
The first is net FDI equal to the FDI stock in a country owned by foreign investors from
OECD countries minus the domestically-owned FDI stock invested in OECD countries.
Countries with high ratios of net FDI to GDP could be characterised as countries that are
the ultimate destination of the inward FDI that are significantly above the average.
The second FDI measure is gross inward FDI. Countries with high ratios of gross FDI to
GDP include both ultimate destinations (countries with high ratios of net FDI to GDP)
and conduits (countries with low ratios of net FDI to GDP) with the inward or flowthrough FDI that are significantly above the average.
Both versions of the indicator are presented below and show similar differences between
the high-ratio countries and the remaining countries and similar trends.
Rationale: FDI measures cross-border investments among related enterprises. The stock
of FDI includes investment related to both BEPS and real economic activity. Significantly
high concentrations of FDI to GDP in a country or group of countries may provide an
indication of BEPS.
Data source: OECD Foreign Direct Investment Statistics. The data is the inward and
outward FDI stock from and to OECD countries. The FDI stock data is available for 214
countries identified in the OECD database.
High-ratio countries
250%
500%
200%
400%
Gross FDI to GDP ratio
High-ratio countries
B. Gross FDI
150%
100%
99 times higher
50%
0%
2005
2006
2007
300%
200%
100%
38 times higher
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Remaining countries
0%
2005
27 times higher
13 times higher
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Table 2.1 presents the values for both versions of Indicator 1 for 2005-2012.
Table 2.1. Indicator 1: Concentration of foreign direct investment relative to GDP
Year
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Caveats:
FDI positions include both real investment and purely financial transactions, including
mergers and acquisitions, unrelated to current economic activity. Only a portion of the
financial transactions may be related to BEPS. The indicator cannot distinguish
between BEPS and other transactions related to real economic activity, but a high
indicator may flag potential BEPS.
The mixture of BEPS and real economic activity may vary between developing and
developed countries. For example, developing countries with attractive investment
climates may have relatively high FDI stock/GDP ratios. This needs to be taken into
consideration in interpreting variations in the indicator across countries.
FDI stock is not as closely related to BEPS as FDI income, but the FDI income to GDP
ratio is much more volatile than the FDI stock to GDP ratio and it is also more affected
by the economic cycle.
The indicator can be refined as new information becomes available, such as the separate
reporting of FDI for special purpose entities and mergers and acquisitions.
Availability of data on bilateral FDI flows is not constant over time.
95.
The indicators in this category differ primarily in the groups of firms used to
compare profit rates. The different groups used in the two indicators are: 1) MNE
affiliates in higher-tax and lower-tax countries, and 2) combined affiliates in lower-tax
countries vs. the MNEs worldwide operations. For each indicator, tax variables are used
to either identify groups or to compare profit rates directly to effective tax rates (ETRs) in
the calculation of the indicators.
2.9.2.2 Limitations
Measures are dependent on available financial reporting data, so may not have
information for all affiliates and may have limited geographic coverage.
Financial statement data is primarily limited to public corporations, not
privately-held corporations or partnerships.
The profit rate is calculated based only on assets, and is not adjusted for
functions and risks.
The calculations of profit rates require information on tax expense, pre-tax
income and assets. The availability of this information may vary for MNE
affiliates within a single country, as well as across countries due to variations in
reporting requirements.
Information on the economic factors has data issues (e.g. most intangibles are
not in total assets).
The tax variable (average effective tax rates) is calculated from reported
financial statement income tax expense (current tax expense plus deferred tax
expense), not actual taxes paid or tax liability on current-year income.
These indicators provide only indirect evidence of BEPS. Reported tax expense
(or actual taxes paid, if available) already includes the effects of BEPS and nonBEPS, resulting in lower reported taxes in higher-tax countries and higher
reported taxes in lower-tax countries. The net reduction in worldwide taxes of
MNEs, either from shifting income among countries with different tax rates or
from the net reduction of reported worldwide taxable income, is not directly
measured in the indicator.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
2.9.2.3 Issues
Averages may obscure the behaviour of a subset of companies that are
undertaking BEPS. Where available, the distribution of the indicator values
could be examined for the influence of significant outliers. Comments on the
discussion draft suggested evaluating the databases on a case-by-case basis to
remove outliers that have relatively large values that distort the indicator
measures, but cautioned removing outliers given the somewhat arbitrary
methods used to identify and remove outliers.
ETR differential will be negative, where BEPS is occurring, because the affiliates ETR
will be less than the MNEs worldwide ETR.
Data source: Unconsolidated affiliate and worldwide consolidated group financial
statement information for the top 250 global MNEs reporting information is used to
calculate the indicator.
Box 2.3. Indicator 2: High profit rates of low-taxed affiliates of top global MNEs
Background: BEPS involves shifting profits from affiliates in high-tax countries to affiliates in
low-tax countries.
Description: This indicator summarises the relationship between the profitability of MNE
affiliates in a country and their ETRs. The indicator is equal to the share of total pre-tax income
in the sample reported by affiliates in higher-profit, lower-tax countries. In Figure 2.3, the
affiliates that are in the lower-tax, higher-profit category are represented by the shaded area in
the southeast quadrant of the graph.
Data used: The calculation uses unconsolidated affiliate and worldwide consolidated group
financial information on tax expense, pre-tax profits, and assets from financial reports for 250 of
the top global MNEs (by sales) and their affiliates. The calculations are done for over 2,300
country-level affiliate groups that include over 10,000 affiliates. Financial groups are not
included.
Results:
In 2011, lower-tax, higher-profit affiliates accounted for 45% of the total income
reported by all affiliates in the sample. 45% is the value of the indicator. These affiliates
accounted for 33% of total affiliates.
The affiliate groups in the northwest quadrant, higher ETRs and lower profit rates,
accounted for only 7% of the total income. If BEPS is occurring, a portion of the
income in this quadrant and in the northeast quadrant may have been shifted to the
southeast quadrant (lower-tax, higher-profit affiliates).
The value of the indicator increased by 32% between 2007 and 2011.
Figure 2.3 explains the indicator in terms of the four quadrants in the diagram. The lower-right
quadrant is the area indicating potential BEPS. This is the quadrant that includes affiliate groups
with lower ETRs and higher profits, relative to the worldwide MNE measures. The figure also
identifies the percentage of total affiliate pre-tax income reported in each quadrant. For example,
affiliate groups in the southeast quadrant account for 45% of the total income in 2011.
Box 2.3. Indicator 2: High profit rates of low-taxed affiliates of top global MNEs
(continued)
7% of total income
profit rate = 6%
Negative
Positive
Figure 2.3. Indicator 2: High profit rates of low-taxed affiliates of top global MNEs
Negative
Positive
Caveats:
While the indicator partially controls for differences in the profitability of affiliates,
by comparing them to their MNEs worldwide profitability, it cannot differentiate
between higher profit rates due to BEPS and higher profit rates possibly needed to
ensure competitive after-tax rates of return on investments.
The indicator does not control for or hold constant other factors that influence BEPS,
including variation in affiliate characteristics, such as size and industry.
Box 2.4. Indicator 3: High profit rates of MNE affiliates in lower-tax locations
Background: The presence of BEPS is expected to result in relatively high profit rates in
relatively low-tax locations. Indicator 3 defines relatively low-tax locations in terms of the
country-by-country distribution of a MNE groups worldwide assets.
Description: This indicator compares the profitability of a MNEs affiliates in lower-tax
countries to the profitability of the MNEs worldwide operations. Affiliates ETRs (weighted by
assets) are calculated for each country where a MNE has affiliates; countries are ranked by ETR
for each MNE. Profit rates are calculated for lower-tax locations, defined as countries with the
lowest ETRs that account for 20% of the MNE groups worldwide assets. The relative
profitability of a MNEs affiliates in lower-tax countries is the profit rate in these countries
divided by the MNEs worldwide profit rate. The indicator is the weighted (by assets) average
profit rate ratio over all MNEs in the sample.
Data used: The calculation uses financial information on tax expense, pre-tax profits, and assets
from financial reports for 250 of the top global MNEs and their affiliates. The calculations are
done for over 170 MNE groups and their 10 000 affiliates.
Results:
In 2011 profit rates of affiliates in lower-tax countries of 171 of the largest MNEs
were on average almost twice as high as their worldwide MNE groups profit rates
(ratio of 2.0).
For the same year, the top 25% of the MNE affiliates, ranked by relative profit rates,
had ratios exceeding 2.4; the ratio exceeded 4.4 for the top 10% of the MNE affiliates.
The indicator increased by 3% between 2007 and 2011.
Table 2.2 summarises descriptive statistics for 2007 and 2011.
Table 2.2. Indicator 3: High profit rates of MNE affiliates in lower-tax locations
2007
2011
Indicator 3
1.9
2.0
1.9
2.4
3.2
4.4
Caveats:
Relatively high profit rates in lower-tax countries may reflect differences in real
economic activity for affiliates in lower-tax countries relative to the MNEs
worldwide operations, but a significantly higher profit rate in lower-tax countries is a
potential indication of BEPS.
There are MNEs in the database that may have relatively low indicator values because
of missing affiliates with relatively high profit rates. In these cases, the potential for
BEPS may be understated.
Box 2.5. Indicator 4: Effective tax rates of MNE affiliates compared to non-MNE
entities with similar characteristics (continued)
Results:
The value of the indicator in 2010 was -3.3. This indicates that, on average, large
MNE affiliates had ETRs that were 3.3 percentage points lower than comparable nonMNE entities. The indicator is statistically significant from 0.
Since 2003, the indicator has shown that, on average, a large MNE affiliate ETR
differential over domestic firms with similar characteristics fluctuating around the
level of -3 percentage points, with these fluctuations not being significant from a
statistical point of view.
Table 2.3 presents the estimates of the indicator for 2000 through to 2010. Figure 2.4 provides a
graph of the indicator value over the 2000-2010 period.
Table 2.3. Indicator 4: Effective tax rates of MNE affiliates compared to non-MNE entities
with similar characteristics (in percentage points)
Year
Indicator 4
2000
-3.9
2001
-4.5
2002
-3.6
2003
-2.7
2004
-3.2
2005
-3.0
2006
-2.9
2007
-3.2
2008
-3.3
2009
-2.8
2010
-3.3
Box 2.5. Indicator 4: Effective tax rates of MNE affiliates compared to non-MNE
entities with similar characteristics (continued)
Figure 2.4. Indicator 4: Effective tax rates of MNE affiliates relative to non-MNE entities
with similar characteristics (in percentage points)
-1
-2
-3
-4
-5
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
Caveats:
Unobserved and inherent differences between MNE affiliates and domestic entities
that are not related to tax planning (e.g. capital intensity, productivity) may also
influence their relative ETRs. In some countries, entities with similar characteristics
may not exist to compare to large MNE affiliates operating in the country.
The indicator includes some non-BEPS behaviours, such as the decision to carry out
substantial activity in a country to benefit from certain preferential tax treatments (e.g.
R&D tax subsidies, investment tax credits).
As discussed in Chapter 1, the available firm-level financial data has limitations in
terms of country representativeness, the use of financial, rather than actual, tax
payment data, and some missing entities and observations with incomplete financial
information. The results are dependent on the specific individual firm database used
as well as the regression specification.
Rationale: Transferring intellectual property from a higher-tax country where R&D takes
place to a lower-tax country is one channel facilitating BEPS. A high value of the
indicator suggests that the income stream from intellectual property received in the highratio countries is significantly higher, relative to other countries, than would be expected
given the actual R&D expenditures in these countries, which may indicate BEPS.
Data source: Balance of payments and R&D expenditures from the World Bank, World
Development Indicators.
Box 2.6. Indicator 5: Concentration of royalty receipts relative to R&D spending
Background: The transfer of intellectual property (IP) from high-tax countries where it is
developed to low-tax countries after development may facilitate BEPS. It results in lower royalty
receipts per euro of R&D spending in the country where the IP was developed and higher
receipts per euro of R&D spending in the country to which the IP was transferred.
Description: This indicator compares royalties received to R&D spending in the countries with
ratios in excess of 50% to the average ratio in the remaining countries. The composition of the
high-ratio countries is based on the 2011 values and kept constant in the other years.
Significantly above average royalty/R&D spending values may indicate BEPS.
Data used: Balance of payments and R&D expenditures from the World Bank, World
Development Indicators. The data includes 59 countries in 2011 with 4 countries having ratios
above 50%.
Results:
In 2011, the high-ratio countries received EUR 1.04 of royalties per EUR 1 of R&D
spending. The remaining countries received only EUR 0.18 of royalties per EUR 1 of
R&D spending.
As a result, the royalties/R&D spending ratio for the top group of countries was
almost six times larger than the same figure for the remaining countries included in
the sample.
The indicator value doubled between 2005 and 2012, due to the increase in royalty
receipts of the high-ratio countries.
In 2011, high-ratio country royalties accounted for 3% of royalties for the 59
countries examined. The indicator evidences the existence of BEPS, but is not a
measure of the scale of BEPS. Even with the low share of high-ratio countries the
indicator still provides evidence of the existence of BEPS.
Figure 2.5 shows Indicator 5 over the 2005-2012 period. The diagram compares the values of the
royalties to R&D spending ratios for the countries with the highest royalty/R&D ratios to the
same ratio for the remaining countries for which data is available.
Remaining countries
1.2
1.0
0.8
6 times higher
0.6
0.4
3 times higher
0.2
0.0
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Indicator 5
2.8
2.5
2.6
2.5
2.7
4.3
5.8
5.8
Caveats:
The composition of the group of remaining countries varies as data availability varies
over time. The number of countries with data available to calculate this indicator
ranged from 32 to 69. However, the value of the indicator does not change
significantly if it is calculated only for countries for which data is available in all
years in the 2005-2011 period.
Countries vary in whether they report royalties based on country of incorporation or
tax residence. For example, countries with many conduit companies typically do not
consider such companies to be part of the domestic economy and do not include data
on these companies in their reporting.
A limitation of this indicator is that current income from intellectual property could be
the result of R&D expenditures in prior years. The indicator currently does not
High STR / low interest-to-income ratio High STR / high interest-to-income ratio
18% of total interest
interest-to-income ratio = 5%
excess ratio = -5 percentage points
Average
Below average
Above average
Figure 2.6. Indicator 6: Interest to income ratios of MNE affiliates in locations with
above average statutory tax rates
Low STR / low interest-to-income ratio Low STR / high interest-to-income ratio
Below average
Average
Above average
Box 2.8. Future Indicator A: Profit rates relative to ETRs, MNE domestic vs.
global operations
Example: Illustrative calculations for this indicator have not been made due to current data
limitations.
Caveats:
This indicator requires worldwide financial reporting data for both domestic and
foreign MNE operations. Publicly available MNE financial reports vary significantly
in how, and if, the worldwide information is reported separately for domestic and
foreign operations. This limits the number of MNEs that can be included in this
indicator using currently available public financial reports.
The profitability of domestic and foreign operations will vary by the composition of
activities that may involve different degrees and types of capital and labour intensity.
Box 2.9. Future Indicator B: Differential rates of return on FDI related to SPEs
Example: Illustrative calculations for this indicator have not been made due to data limitations.
Caveats:
FDI statistics for SPEs will be reported for an increasing number of countries
beginning with data published in 2015. The impact of expanded coverage will affect
changes in the value of the indicator unrelated to changes in BEPS. This needs to be
recognised in the interpretation of this indicator as a measure of changes in BEPS
over time.
While investment related to BEPS is expected to be a significant portion of SPE
investment, there will also be non-BEPS related SPE investment.
Additional analysis will be needed to determine the criteria for including countries in
the top group of home countries that is characterised as investing countries with
relatively high ratios of SPE-related FDI.
The indicator only measures profit shifting that is facilitated by direct investment
relationships.
2.15 Summary
102. This chapter presents six indicators and a further two potential indicators to assist
with the measurement and monitoring of BEPS. These indicators are intended to be
viewed like a meter or a gauge, capable of measuring trends and variations over time and
acting as warning lights that might point to the existence of BEPS. No single indicator
is capable of providing the complete picture, but by presenting a dashboard of BEPS
indicators this report provides new insights regarding the presence and scale of BEPS.
103. As with any gauge, the degree of precision depends on the available information
and the accuracy of the measurement tools. Given the state of currently available data, the
indicators presented can only provide some general insights into the scale and economic
impact of BEPS, but lack the precision that may become possible if more comprehensive
and improved data sources, supported by sophisticated statistical analysis, become
available in the future.
104. As a dashboard, the indicators provide a signal that BEPS exists, is likely to be
increasing in scale, and that better data availability is needed to refine economic analysis
of BEPS and the BEPS Action Plans countermeasures in the future. While the indicators
are high-level rather than refined economic analyses, and have significant data limitations
and caveats, all six indicators presented in this chapter show the expected sign or trend
indicative of the presence of BEPS.
105.
average profit rates. These affiliates represented only 33% of total affiliates in
the MNE. The value of the indicator increased 32% between 2007 and 2011.
Indicator 3 shows that reported profit rates of MNE affiliates in lower-tax
countries were, on average, almost twice as high as their groups worldwide
profit rate.
Indicator 4 estimates the ETRs, by calculating the reported tax expense as a
percentage of reported profits, of large MNE affiliates relative to non-MNE
entities with similar characteristics. Between 2000 and 2010, the ETRs for large
MNE entities (with more than 250 employees) was estimated to be between 2.7
to 4.5 percentage points lower than similar non-MNE ETRs.
Indicator 5 shows that royalties received relative to R&D expenditures in a
group of countries with ratios above 50% are six times higher than for the
average of all other countries, up from three times higher in 2009.
Indicator 6 shows the concentration of high interest-to-income ratios in higher
statutory tax rate countries. It shows that the largest global MNEs affiliates
with high interest-to-EBITDA ratios, located in high-tax countries have an
interest-to-EBITDA ratio almost three times higher than their groups
worldwide unrelated-party interest-to-EBITDA ratio.
106. Two additional indicators are also described that could be calculated when new
data become available: a comparison of profit rates and ETRs of MNE domestic
(headquarter) and foreign operations, and differential rates of return on FDI investment
from special purpose entities.
107. Economic analysis of the scale and economic impact of BEPS and the
effectiveness of potential BEPS countermeasures are presented in the next chapter, which
complement the high level indications of the six BEPS Indicators.
Notes
1.
References to the future state and ideal state are not presented as proposed or
inevitable stages, but are designed to highlight that improvements in the data sources
available would also lead to improvements in the accuracy of BEPS indicators and
economic analyses.
2.
The firm-level financial information is for a sample of the 250 largest global nonfinancial MNEs, as measured by sales. It includes financial information in 2007 and
2011 from both the MNE consolidated and affiliates unconsolidated financial
statements.
3.
The tax expense measure includes taxes that are based on income, including corporate
income taxes and withholding taxes based on income.
4.
Indicators 2 and 3 measure potential profit shifting in different ways. Indicator 2 uses
individual affiliate observations in the calculations; Indicator 3 aggregates all of a
MNEs affiliates at the country level. The two indicators also differ in how low-tax
locations are defined. Indicator 2 defines low-tax as locations of affiliates with ETRs
less than the MNE groups worldwide ETR; Indicator 3 defines low-tax as countries
with the lowest ETRs accounting for 20% of assets.
5.
6.
EBITDA is pre-tax income before any deductions for interest paid, corporate income
taxes, depreciation and amortization. Net interest expense (interest expense minus
interest income) could not be calculated from the available affiliate-level data.
7.
Domestic operations include the parent company and its affiliates operating in the
same country as the parent.
8.
9.
Annex 2.A1
Formulas for calculating indicators
Indicator 1A:
1.
Year 2012 was chosen as a base year for Indicator 1. OECD FDI Statistics was
the source of data on FDI.
2.
An inward FDI position of partner country i (iFDIi) is calculated as the sum of
outward FDI positions from all available OECD countries to partner country i in 2012
where oFDIpi,j is the outward FDI position reported by OECD country j to partner
country i and N is the number of OECD countries1.
3.
An outward FDI position of partner country i (oFDIi) is calculated as the sum of
inward FDI positions from all available OECD countries to partner country i in 2012
where iFDIpi,j is the outward FDI position reported by OECD country j to partner country
i and N is the number of OECD countries.
4.
A net FDI position of partner country i (net FDIi) is calculated as the difference
between its inward FDI position and its outward FDI position.
5.
The net FDI to GDP ratio is calculated for each partner country i.
6.
A group of high-ratio partner countries with a net FDI to GDP ratio above 50%
are selected. The weighted average net FDI to GDP ratio for the high-ratio countries (net
FDI to GDP ratiohigh) is calculated. The weighted average net FDI to GDP ratio for the
remaining partner countries (net FDI to GDP ratiorest) is calculated where n is the total
number of partner countries reported by OECD countries and m is the number of highratio countries.
8.
Steps 2 to 7 are repeated for other years with the same high-ratio countries
identified in 2012.
Indicator 1B:
1.
Year 2012 was chosen as a base year for Indicator 1. OECD FDI Statistics was
the source of data on FDI.
2.
An inward FDI position of partner country i (iFDIi) is calculated as the sum of
outward FDI positions from all available OECD countries to partner country i in 2012
where oFDIpi,j is the outward FDI position reported by OECD country j to partner
country i and N is the number of OECD countries2.
3.
The gross FDI to GDP ratio is calculated for each partner country i.
4.
A group of high-ratio partner countries with a gross FDI to GDP ratio above
200% are selected. The weighted average gross FDI to GDP ratio for the high-ratio
countries (gross FDI to GDP ratiohigh) is calculated. The weighted average gross FDI to
GDP ratio for the remaining partner countries (gross FDI to GDP ratiorest) is calculated
where n is the total number of partner countries reported by OECD countries and m is the
number of high-ratio countries.
5.
The indicator for 2012 is calculated as the ratio of the gross FDI to GDP ratio of
the high-ratio countries to the gross FDI to GDP ratio of the remaining countries.
6.
Steps 2 to 5 are repeated for other years with the same high-ratio countries
identified in 2012.
Indicator 2:
A.
For all affiliates of MNE 1 and a given year, profit rate differentials are calculated as
follows.
1.
For affiliate i, the profit rate (profit ratei,MNE1) is calculated as pre-tax income of
affiliate i divided by assets of affiliate i.
2.
The global profit rate for MNE 1 (profit rateg,MNE1) is calculated as MNEs
consolidated pre-tax income divided by MNEs consolidated assets.
3.
The profit rate differential of affiliate i (profit rate diffi,MNE1) is calculated as the
difference between the affiliate is profit rate and MNE 1s global profit rate.
B.
For all affiliates of MNE 1 and the given year, effective tax rate differentials are
calculated as follows.
1.
For affiliate i, the effective tax rate (ETRi,MNE1) is calculated as affiliate is tax
expense divided by affiliates is pre-tax income.
2.
The global effective tax rate for MNE 1 (ETRg,MNE1) is calculated as MNE 1s
consolidated tax expense divided by MNE 1s consolidated pre-tax income.
3.
The effective rate differential of affiliate i (ETR diffi,MNE1) is calculated as the
difference between the affiliate is ETR and MNE 1s global ETR.
C
D.
Affiliates with profit rates differentials greater than zero and ETR differentials
less than zero are selected.
E.
The indicator for the given year is calculated as the sum of pre-tax income of
affiliates selected in step D divided by the sum of pre-tax income of all affiliates where k
is the number of all MNEs in the sample, ni is the number of affiliates of MNEi and mi is
the number of affiliates of MNEi selected in step D.
Indicator 3:
A.
For MNE 1 and a given year, the profit rate differential is calculated as follows.
1.
For country i where MNE 1 has affiliates, the sum of assets (assetsi,MNE1), the sum
of pre-tax income (pre-tax incomei,MNE1), and the sum of tax expenses (tax expensei,MNE1)
of all MNE 1s affiliates in country i are calculated where assetsj,i,MNE1 is assets of MNE
1s affiliate j in country i (similarly for pre-tax income and tax expense) and ni is the
number of MNE 1s affiliates in country i.
2.
The profit rate of MNE 1 country group of affiliates in country i (profit ratei,MNE1)
is calculated as the sum of pre-tax income of MNE 1s affiliates in country i divided by
the sum of assets in MNE 1s affiliates in country i.
3.
MNE 1s global profit rate (profit rateg,MNE1) is calculated as MNE 1s
consolidated pre-tax income divided by MNE 1s consolidated assets.
4.
The effective tax rate of MNE 1s country group of affiliates in country i
(ETRi,MNE1) is calculated as the sum of tax expenses of MNE 1s affiliates in country i
divided by the sum of pre-tax income of MNE 1s affiliates in country i.
5.
The countries where MNE 1 has affiliates are ranked by their effective tax rate.
Low-tax countries are defined as countries with the lowest ETRs that account for 20% of
the assets of the MNE. The average profit rate (weighted by assets) of low-tax countries
is then calculated; m is the number of low-tax countries and n is the number of all
countries where MNE 1 has affiliates.3
6.
MNE 1s profit rate differential (profit rate diffMNE1) is then calculated as the ratio
of MNE 1s profit rate in low tax countries divided by MNE 1s global profit rate.
B.
C.
The indicator for the given year is the average profit rate differential (weighted by
assets) for all MNEs in the sample where k is the number of MNEs in the sample and
assetsg,MNEi is consolidated assets of MNE i.
Indicator 4:
Indicator 4 uses firm-level unconsolidated financial data and ownership information from
the ORBIS database compiled by Bureau Van Dijk and processed by the OECD Statistics
Directorate.
The sample consists of entities in both multinational and non-multinational groups in 46
countries (all OECD and G20 countries, OECD accession countries Colombia and Latvia
as well as Malaysia and Singapore) over 2000-2010. Micro-firms (less than 10
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
employees), loss-making firms and standalone firms (i.e. firms that are not part of a
corporate group) are excluded. The sample has 2 046 838 observations.
Indicator 4 is the regression coefficient
individual entities in the sample:
,
is the effective tax rate of entity f (operating in country c and industry i
where
and member of a MNE or domestic group) in year t, measured as tax expenses over
is a dummy equal to one when firm f has more than
reported profit.
is a dummy equal to one when firm f has up to
250 employees.
is a dummy equal to one when a company is part of a
250 employees.
is a vector of firm characteristics, including the position of the
multinational group.
firm in the group and a dummy for patenting groups.
The regression analysis based on the whole sample shows that the estimated difference
between the ETR of large MNE entities and the ETR of comparable domestic (i.e. nonmultinational) groups is 3.3 percentage points (i.e. 3 = -0.033) and was estimated for
each individual year. The adjusted R-squared is 0.186.
Indicator 5:
1.
Year 2011 was chosen as a base year for Indicator 6. World Bankss World
Development Indicators was the source of data on royalty receipts (charges for the use of
intellectual property) and R&D expenditures.
2.
For each country i, the ratio of royalty receipts to domestic R&D expenditure was
calculated.
3.
A group of high-ratio countries with a royalty to R&D ratio above 50% are
selected. The weighted average royalty to R&D ratio for the high-ratio countries (royalty
to R&D ratiohigh) is calculated. The weighted average royalty to R&D ratio for the
remaining countries (royalty to R&D ratiorest) is calculated where n is the total number of
countries for which data is available and m is the number of high-ratio countries.
4.
The indicator for 2011 is calculated as the ratio of royalty to R&D ratio of the
high-ratio countries to the royalty to R&D ratio of the remaining countries.
5.
Steps 2 to 4 are repeated for other years with the same high-ratio countries
identified in 2011.
2.
MNE 1s global interest-to-income ratio (interest-to-income ratiog,MNE1) is
calculated as MNE 1s interest expense divided by MNE 1s EBITDA from consolidated
accounts.
3.
Affiliate 1s interest-to-income ratio differential (interest-to-income ratio
diff1,MNE1) is calculated as affiliate 1s interest-to-income ratio minus MNE 1s global
interest-to-income ratio.
B.
For MNE 1s affiliate 1 and the given year, a combined CIT rate differential is
calculated as follows.
1.
The worldwide average combined CIT rate (weighted by EBITDA) of all
affiliates of all MNEs (CIT ratew) is calculated where CIT rate1,MNE1 is the combined CIT
rate in the country of affiliate 1 of MNE 1, k is the number of MNEs in the sample and ni
is the number of affiliates of MNE i.
2.
The combined CIT rate differential of MNE 1s affiliate 1 (CIT rate diff1,MNE1) is
calculated as the difference between the combined CIT rate in the country of MNE 1s
affiliate 1 and the worldwide average combined CIT rate.
C.
Steps A and B are repeated for all affiliates and all MNEs in the sample.
D.
Affiliates with both the interest-to-income ratio differential and the combined CIT
rate differential greater than zero are selected.
E.
The indicator for the given year is calculated as the difference between the
weighted average interest-to-income ratio of affiliates selected in step D and the weighted
average interest-to-income ratio of all affiliates in the sample (both averages weighted by
EBITDA) where k is the number of all MNEs in the sample, ni is the number of affiliates
of MNEi and mi is the number of affiliates of MNEi selected in step D.
Notes
1.
If the partner country is an OECD country, only FDI positions from the other 33
OECD countries are taken into account.
2.
If the partner country is an OECD country, only FDI positions from the other 33
OECD are taken into account.
3.
The total assets accounted for by low-tax countries, will not be exactly 20%. In that
case, the last country to be included in the low-tax countries would cause the sum of
low-tax countries assets exceed 20% of total MNEs assets. The last country is then
not assigned a weight equal to its assets. Instead, it is assigned a lower weight. This
weight is set such that the sum of assets of all low-tax countries is equal to exactly
20% of the sum of total MNEs assets. For example, the two low-tax countries are A
and B. A has an ETR of 11% and assets equal to 15% of total MNEs assets; B has an
ETR of 12% and assets equal to 10% of total MNEs assets. In that case, B is
assigned a weight of half of its assets equal to 5% of total MNEs assets (15% + 5% =
20%).
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 79
Chapter 3
Towards measuring the scale and economic impact of BEPS and
countermeasures
Key points:
There is a large and growing body of evidence of the existence of BEPS, stemming
from hundreds of empirical analyses and specific information relating to the tax
affairs of certain MNEs that has emerged from numerous legislative and
parliamentary enquiries. However, measuring the scale and economic impact of BEPS
proves challenging given the complexity of BEPS and the serious data limitations.
This chapter summarises the available empirical analyses of profit shifting and the
effects of previously implemented anti-avoidance countermeasures. Recent research
has focused on specific types of BEPS behaviours, mostly on transfer mispricing and
debt shifting, but also on treaty abuse, controlled foreign corporation rules, hybrid
mismatch arrangements, and disclosure rules, but more empirical analysis is needed in
all of these areas.
No empirical studies comprehensively cover global MNE activity. In particular, most
studies are constrained by a lack of data relating to MNE entities in many countries,
and where information regarding MNE entities is available it is often incomplete.
Statistical analyses based upon data collected under the Action 13 Country-byCountry Reports have the potential to significantly enhance the economic analysis of
BEPS. However, even with additional data and sophisticated estimation
methodologies, researchers of the scale, prevalence and intensity of BEPS will still
have difficulty in fully separating BEPS from real economic activity and from nonBEPS tax preferences.
Several recent studies have presented estimates of the scale of BEPS globally or for
individual countries. All of these studies show significant fiscal effects using different
types of data and different estimation methodologies. An OECD analysis of financial
accounts from a cross-country database estimates the global corporate income tax
revenue losses to be in the range of 4% to 10% of corporate income tax revenues, i.e.
USD 100 to 240 billion annually at 2014 levels. The studies estimating the fiscal
effects on developing countries, as a percentage of their GDP, find that these effects
are higher than in developed countries, given the greater reliance on CIT revenues and
often weaker tax enforcement capabilities of developing countries, but in some cases
these studies also include revenue lost from non-BEPS behaviours.
BEPS anti-avoidance measures previously implemented by countries have been found
to be effective, in countries fiscal estimates, in academic studies, and in OECD
research, to reduce tax planning. Thus, countries with higher statutory corporate tax
rates do not necessarily have higher fiscal losses from BEPS if they have strict antiavoidance rules. International co-ordination of those rules will increase the
effectiveness of BEPS countermeasures while reducing the cost of compliance for
businesses.
80 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
BEPS causes significant economic distortions. Empirical analyses, including OECD
research, find that BEPS involves MNEs manipulating the location of external and
internal debt; reduces the effective tax rate on intangible investments, thereby
distorting the types of investments made; affects the location of patent registrations,
and to a lesser extent actual R&D activity; affects the location of different types and
forms of foreign direct investment; and creates tax base and policy spillovers between
countries.
OECD research finds that BEPS reduces the effective tax rate of large MNE entities
by 4 to 8 percentage points on average compared to similarly-situated domestic-only
affiliates, providing a competitive advantage in product and capital markets. The
reduction in effective tax rates is larger for very large firms and firms with patents.
This research also finds that MNE tax planning may allow certain MNEs to increase
their market power, resulting in more concentrated markets.
Analyses of BEPS make comparisons of current business activity with some
alternative or counterfactual. The counterfactual could be a hypothetical world
without BEPS or a hypothetical world without co-ordinated multilateral action.
When evaluating BEPS countermeasures, the estimated counterfactual of the effects
of implementing countermeasures can be compared with current law rules and
revenues.
The extent of BEPS-induced distortions will depend on who currently benefits from
BEPS: whether the tax savings from BEPS are passed along in lower consumer prices,
higher wages to workers, or to higher returns to capital owners. The reduction in
corporate tax liabilities enjoyed by MNEs engaging in BEPS is unlikely to have the
same economic effects as a general reduction in corporate income taxes.
BEPS countermeasures will increase taxes paid by MNEs engaging in BEPS, but
other businesses and households will benefit from lower taxes or increased public
infrastructure or increased government services, and indirectly through a more levelplaying field. The effects on all businesses and households need to be included in
analyses of countermeasures. Analysis needs to consider who benefits from BEPS,
since if BEPS increases the after-tax economic rents of MNEs engaging in BEPS,
countermeasures may not affect some of their investment decisions.
Additional research on MNEs investment decisions, determinants of profitability,
business tax preferences, and total business taxes is needed to enhance the economic
analysis of BEPS and BEPS countermeasures.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 81
3.1 Overview
108. A survey of the academic and empirical literature reveals over one hundred
studies have found the presence of BEPS. A recent review of the empirical literature by
Dharmapala (2015) does not report a single empirical study not finding some evidence of
BEPS. Another review of the academic literature by Riedel (2015) concludes: Existing
studies unanimously report evidence in line with tax-motivated profit shifting (despite
using different data sources and estimation strategies).1
109. A common theme of these studies has been the finding that profits are being
shifted from high-tax countries to low-tax countries and that there is substantial evidence
of a disconnect between the jurisdictions where MNEs are recording their taxable
profits and the locations where the economic activities that generate these profits are
taking place. The studies find empirical evidence of BEPS through various channels,
including through: transfer pricing, the strategic location of debt and intangible assets,
treaty abuse, and the use of hybrid mismatch arrangements. Government analyses,
academic studies, and OECD research presented in Annex 3.A1 have all found that
certain measures enacted to address BEPS activity have been effective in protecting the
revenue bases of the countries implementing these measures.2
110. While the various academic, government and empirical studies undertaken find
BEPS is occurring, there is less certainty over the scale or extent to which it is occurring.
Scale is defined as the magnitude of the change in overall tax receipts due to BEPS. To
date, most studies have focused on individual countries or individual BEPS channels
rather than attempt to achieve a comprehensive global estimate of the scale of BEPS
activity. Riedel (2015) reports that the estimates of profit shifting range from less than 5%
to more than 30% of the income earned by MNEs in high-tax countries being shifted to
lower-tax countries. While most of the studies focus on shifting financial profits (not
taxable income) and do not include instances of stateless income,3 such a large range
shows the significant uncertainty surrounding the estimation of the magnitude of BEPS.
Due to differences in pre-tax profits reported in financial statements and taxable income,
plus tax credits, the percentage change in corporate tax revenues could be even higher
than the percentage change in pre-tax reported profits.
111. The two key challenges facing any attempt to undertake an economic analysis of
BEPS that arrives at credible estimates relate to the availability of data and the
methodology employed for estimating the scale of BEPS. While Chapter 1 discusses the
significant limitations of currently available data, this chapter focuses on the
methodological issues involved in undertaking economic analyses of the scale and
economic impact of BEPS and BEPS countermeasures. It should be noted that few of the
academic estimates of profit shifting attempt to estimate the total tax benefits to MNEs or
revenues lost to governments from BEPS.
112. Even with the Action 13 Country-by-Country Reports of MNE global taxes and
economic activity, measures of the scale of BEPS will require sophisticated estimation
techniques to separate BEPS from real economic activity and from non-BEPS tax
incentives. Measurement of BEPS and countermeasures will not be available from
extracting a single line from a tax return or Country-by-Country Report, but will need to
be estimated, and such estimation not only requires better tax and non-tax information,
but also requires further refinement of the methodologies applied to future economic
analyses.
82 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
113. This chapter starts with a discussion of the key issues in measuring BEPS, its
economic effects, and the effectiveness of BEPS countermeasures. Significant progress
has been made in the last few years in the analysis of BEPS, but given the complexity of
BEPS and the serious data limitation, more progress is needed to provide a more precise
and a more complete understanding of BEPS behaviours. The chapter outlines what we
do know from the empirical studies including some new OECD research, as well as what
we do not currently know about the scale and economic impacts of BEPS. The chapter
concludes with a number of areas where future economic research with better data will be
important in enhancing our understanding of the scale and impact of BEPS and the
effectiveness of BEPS countermeasures.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 83
84 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 85
where to recognize it, i.e. which jurisdiction.5 This lack of agreement and empirical
evidence over where such activity is located is an important source of uncertainty in
terms of measuring BEPS.
127. What activities generate profits? One difficulty that arises from a review of the
empirical economic literature is that there is no agreement on what economic activities
generate profits, which is critical to measuring BEPS. Some analysts argue that profits are
generated where the factors of production (labour and capital) are located, whereas other
analysts argue that profits are generated where sales occur. Some other analysts argue that
profits are generated based on a combination of labour, capital and sales. Current tax
rules generally use a fact specific approach based on a companys functions, assets and
risks.
128. The conceptual problem is exacerbated by how capital, sales and labour are
typically measured. The value of total assets generally does not include the value of
intangible capital assets, which are important generators of value especially in todays
economy, but are also highly mobile. Investments in intangible assets, such as R&D
expenditures, are generally deducted or expensed in the year of the investment for
financial statement accounting, and thus are not included in the value of total assets,
except for certain intangibles acquired in an acquisition or purchase. Sales are often
measured in the countries where the sales have originated (i.e. origin or production
location) rather than where the final consumers are located (i.e. destination or
consumption location). Labour is often measured by the number of employees, but this
measure may not distinguish between full-time and part-time employees, or differences in
productivity or value added per labour hour. A MNEs labour presence may be measured
by total employee compensation, but similar to sales, employees often work in multiple
jurisdictions during a year, not just in the jurisdiction of incorporation.
129. Where are profits generated? Just as there is no agreement on the specification of
the activities that generate profit, there is considerable disagreement over the key question
of where profits are generated. Many of the existing economic studies implicitly define
the location where the activities creating profits take place in the methodologies
employed in their empirical analyses. For example, some economic studies use a profit
rate (measured as profit-to-sales, profit-to-employees or profits-to-assets) to test whether
financial statement profit is shifted between affiliates based on tax rate differentials.
130. Most of these economic studies use regression analyses to measure BEPS due to
tax rate differentials, with other non-tax variables as explanatory variables to explain the
creation of real economic profits. The economic studies define real economic profits by
reference to the measure used in the profit ratio (e.g. sales or assets) and by the
explanatory variables (e.g. tangible capital, size, headquarters location, industry, presence
of patents, etc.).
131. To estimate where economic value creation takes place, one has to construct a
specification of the production function for the entity. In the case of transfer pricing,
consideration of the production function is usually referred to as the functions, risks and
capital of the MNE. A production function would not only take into account the usual
factors of production: low-skill labour, high-skill labour and physical capital; but research
and development (R&D) and other intangible capital, public infrastructure; industry
agglomeration effects; and synergies with other entities in the MNE. Thus, the typical
empirical specification of profits does not take into account all relevant components of
the production function. Omitted variables in the analyses will have at least two effects:
86 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
the explanatory power of the regression will be weaker and the estimates of tax shifting
responsiveness may be affected by the omitted variables.
132. Additional research is needed in the area of estimating the contributions to real
economic contributions to profits, since it is essential to the separation of BEPS from real
economic activity. Recent research by Corrado et al. (2012) finds that investment in
intangible assets is a significant percentage of companies total capital expenditures, and
a significant contribution to labour productivity. Intangible investments between 1995
and 2009 were 118% of tangible investments in the United States and 62% of tangible
investments in the EU15.6 Better incorporation of intangibles assets (and not just patents
or R&D) and also risk management is needed.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 87
Box 3.2. Different tax variables used in BEPS and tax policy analyses (continued)
Marginal tax rates (MTR) applicable to the shifted income would be the ideal measure for BEPS
analysis, but are often not known. In some cases the MTR is the same as the headline statutory
tax rate or a special statutory tax rate, but in others it may be a negotiated rate as part of an
administrative ruling.
Effective tax rates (ETRs) come in a number of variations and are useful for different types of
analyses.
Backward-looking average effective tax rates (AETR) are also used to measure the effects of
BEPS, but often are inexact measures of the incentives to shift taxable income. AETRs may be
closer to what companies actually pay in tax and reflect all aspects of the corporate tax system.
However, they are a backward-looking metric, reflecting historical tax effects (e.g. depreciation
from prior investments, loss deductions from prior years taken against current year taxable
income, etc.) and non-BEPS tax provisions (e.g. R&D and energy tax credits). AETRs are often
computed from financial statement data, and thus identify the country of incorporation not tax
residence, and computed from accounting tax expense, rather than tax liability or cash taxes
paid, and which can include taxes paid in other countries, as described in Chapter 1.
Forward-looking marginal and average effective tax rates (FL-METRs and FL-ATRs) are
calculated using hypothetical companies to illustrate the tax on a future investment. FL-METRs
are used to analyse domestic investment incentives at the margin, but are increasingly recognised
as inappropriate for measuring MNEs decisions on the location of high-return intangible assets.7
FL-ATRs illustrate the tax on the total return or economic profit of an investment, particularly
for investments earning above a competitive return, for purposes of considering the location of
that investment across different countries. Hypothetical companies are fact-specific and difficult
to weight to be representative of the whole economy, plus they do not capture all of the
important tax aspects of the corporate tax structure, particularly international tax rules.
Other tax rates. In evaluating the level of taxes paid by selected groups of taxpayers or specific
taxpayers, some analyses and press articles report a ratio of taxes paid to sales, and may even
call it an effective tax rate. Sometimes a low ratio is the basis for concluding that a MNE is
artificially shifting profits out of a country. This interpretation illustrates the confusion caused by
mixing tax base concepts. The corporate income tax is a tax on a companys equity income, not
a tax on sales (consumption). The appropriate measure for evaluating the burden of an income
tax is taxes divided by income, not the ratio of taxes to sales. A low ratio of taxes to sales may
simply reflect the fact that a firm operates in a low profit margin industry, where sales are high
relative to profits. In contrast to net income, the amount of sales has to cover payments to labour
and lenders, as well as intermediate purchases from other firms.
Tax policy analysts are still grappling with which tax rate(s) should be used to empirically
estimate the effects of BEPS. Sensitivity analysis, such as running regressions with different tax
rate measures, can be used to determine if the choice of tax rate makes a significant difference.
136. In addition to the tax rate used in the analysis, another methodological issue
relates to the question of determining the appropriate way to calculate the tax rate
differential (i.e. the differential between one MNE entitys tax rate compared to the
average tax rate of other entities in the MNE group). A number of empirical studies
compare affiliates tax rate to the MNE parents tax rate. That captures shifting between
parents and affiliates. Other studies compare an affiliates tax rate to the tax rate of the
group. That captures inter-affiliate shifting but in some cases does not include shifting
with the parent. Some of the studies compare the entitys tax rate to the other related
entities average tax rate, either a simple unweighted average or weighted by revenue, but
shifting may be disproportionately undertaken with the lowest tax rate affiliates. In fact,
all of the shifting may be undertaken with one entity based in a zero tax rate country. This
88 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
issue requires additional exploration to improve the measurement of BEPS tax rate
differentials.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 89
some analysing profit shifting from parents to affiliates and others analysing profit
shifting between unconsolidated affiliated entities.
143. While academic studies have increasingly focused on individual company data,
several international organisations have used macroeconomic data to estimate the effects
of BEPS. These studies focus on the effects of tax haven countries and FDI through
special purpose entities. Although macroeconomic data cannot capture detailed firm-level
behaviour, it can capture some dimensions of BEPS which may not be reflected in microdata due to its incomplete coverage. One limitation with using macro data, such as
foreign direct investment data, is it includes the impact of taxes on both real economic
activity and BEPS.
144. Most academic studies have not applied their estimates of profit shifting based on
the sample data to provide an estimate of the fiscal effects. Fiscal estimates require
significantly more information than just the average responsiveness of financial profits to
a change in tax rates. Financial statement profits generally differ from taxable income due
to differences in accounting and tax rules. Companies with negative taxable income in a
given year generally cannot receive a tax refund in that year, but must carry forward any
tax losses to future years. Further, the relationship between income and tax liability is not
proportional due to the extensive use of tax credits in many countries.
145. Two recent studies provide useful summaries of the empirical analysis of BEPS.
Dharmapala (2014) summarises the empirical literature of profit shifting analyses and
reports that the more recent empirical literature finds the estimated magnitude of BEPS to
be smaller than that found in earlier studies. The change seems mainly due to the
increasing recent use of micro firm level data, which is able to hold more non-tax factors
constant, compared to aggregate data across countries. Riedel (2015) reports that existing
studies unanimously report evidence in line with tax-motivated profit shifting, but there is
a wide range of profit shifting estimates from 5-30% of MNE profits.
146. Notable examples of general analyses of profit shifting using firm-specific data
are Grubert (2012), Huizinga and Laeven (2008), Heckmeyer and Overesch (2013),
OECD Annex 1, and Dowd, Landefeld and Moore of the United States Congressional
Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) (2015). Grubert (2012) uses a sample of United
States corporate tax return data of large non-financial United States-based MNEs to
investigate the role of taxation in the large increase in the foreign share of total income of
United States MNEs between 1996 and 2002. The paper finds that companies with lower
foreign effective tax rates have higher foreign profit margins and lower domestic profit
margins. The analysis finds that introduction of the check-the-box regulation in 1997
accounted for a significant fraction of the reduction in the foreign effective tax rates. The
analysis shows that R&D intensity reduces foreign effective tax rates, indirectly
indicating that the strategic location of intangible assets can facilitate BEPS.
147. Huizinga and Laeven (2008) analyse the Amadeus database of European MNEs
unconsolidated affiliate financial account information to investigate profit shifting
incentives due to international tax differences. They were the first to take a portfolio
approach to MNE behaviour, using as a tax variable the average of bilateral differences in
statutory tax rates between companies in the same group. The analysis uses earnings
before interest and taxes as the dependent variable. Considering both tax differentials
among foreign affiliates and tax differentials between parents and foreign affiliates, they
find evidence of profit shifting, both among foreign subsidiaries and between parent
companies and their affiliates abroad. Finally, they estimate the associated revenue
implications for each country by comparing the actual profit shifting outcome to a
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
90 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
theoretical benchmark without profit shifting. They find a semi-elasticity of reported
profits with respect to the top statutory tax rate of -1.3.
148. Heckemeyer and Overesch (2013) conduct a meta-analysis of available profit
shifting analyses and report a tax semi-elasticity of subsidiary pre-tax profits of -0.8,
where a 10 percentage point increase in the tax variable reduces financial statement
profits by 8 percent. The analysis uses multiple estimates from individual studies and is
heavily weighted to studies of European companies. The analysis does not separately
estimate the effects of the different types of data, such as financial account, investment
survey, and tax return data.
149. New research in Annex 3.A1 uses the ORBIS database of unconsolidated
affiliates financial accounts to analyse profit shifting and differences between MNE
affiliates and similarly-situated domestic companies. The analysis finds that between
2000 and 2010 an affiliates statutory headline tax rate that is one percentage point above
its MNE group average is associated with a lower reported profit by about 1 percent on
average, a semi-elasticity around -1.0. A second analysis finds that large MNE entities
(with more than 250 employees) have an estimated 2 to 5 percentage points lower
effective tax rate on average than comparable domestic-only companies, which reflects
the exploitation of mismatches between tax systems and the relative use of domestic tax
preferences. Combining the two estimates, BEPS is found to reduce the ETR of large
MNEs entities by a range of 4 to 8 percentage points. The analysis also finds that
existing tax anti-avoidance rules have a positive effect on reducing profit shifting.
150. Dowd, Landefeld, and Moore (2015), three economists of the United States Joint
Committee on Taxation, analyse United States tax return data for foreign controlled
corporations of United States parent MNEs and find significant non-linear effects of
profit-shifting. They find a linear estimate of the semi-elasticity is -1.3, but the study also
finds 4 to 7 times higher elasticities for profit shifting to low-tax affiliates. Despite
working with actual tax return data, missing data8 and consolidation issues (e.g. affiliates
in zero tax rate countries report some taxes paid to other countries) could affect the
results.
151. Dharmapala (2014) has noted that the estimates of tax responsiveness from
academic studies often seem small relative to the large fraction of net income in tax
havens. These are not necessarily contradictory, since the former measure the effects of
small marginal changes (i.e. in tax rate differentials) rather than the absolute levels of tax
rate differences of 20% or 30% compared to 0%.9 Thus, econometric estimates of
marginal changes may understate the actual effects of large tax rate differentials.
152. Table 3.1 presents a number of profit shifting economic analyses using individual
company information. All of these empirical studies are attempting to measure the effect
of profit shifting due to tax rate differentials, separating profit shifting from the effects of
real economic activity. Differences in the data, variables used, and methodology used
(Box 3.3) explain why good empirical analyses yield different results, but all show strong
evidence of profit shifting. The median elasticity among the 20 studies is -1.0.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 91
92 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Box 3.3. Different approaches used to estimate profit shifting (continued)
Explanatory economic variables: Separating profit shifting from real economic activity
contributions to reported profits is important. Most studies include a variety of measures of real
economic activity to isolate the tax effect. Most studies use available metrics of capital and/or
labour, additional variables such as population, unemployment, inflation, trade and corruption
indices, and GDP related measures to account for macroeconomic differences in the countries in
which the MNE entities are operating. The capital measure only includes reported total assets or
tangible/fixed assets, and thus does not include other potential contributors to firm profit, such as
intangible assets of the MNE group, public infrastructure, social capital, etc. It should be noted
that the explanatory economic variables used are quite different from the arms length pricing
measures based on functions, risks and assets of the MNE entities or uncontrolled comparable
prices. No studies to date have used both affiliate and group data to estimate the entities shares
of the MNE group profit due to data limitations.
Fixed effects (dummy) variables: Most of the empirical studies use fixed effects variables to
hold constant factors unique to the individual entity, individual year, industry or country. Ideally,
the regressions would include specific economic measures for these dimensions, but due to data
or conceptual limitations, simple one-zero dummy variables are often used to capture those
important effects.
Linear vs. non-linear tax effects: Analysts must choose a specification of the regression equation
of how tax rates affect profit shifting. Most analysts choose a semi-log elasticity measure where
the percentage change in profits is a function of a percentage point change in the chosen tax rate
variable. Alternatively, the estimate can be calculated with a simple elasticity, where the
percentage change in profits is a function of the percentage change in the chosen tax rate. The
two types of estimates can be presented as equivalents by calculating the semi-log elasticity
equivalent for the simple elasticity at the average of the tax rate. The Hines/Rice analysis
suggested that a non-linear specification could be used, but most empirical analyses have
conducted linear specifications. The United States JCT economists analysis cites a -1.3 linear
semi-elasticity, but their preferred speciation is non-linear and ranges from -0.8 to -9.5
depending on the level of the effective tax rate faced by the affiliate.
Semi-elasticity vs. elasticity: Most analyses use a semi-elasticity measure (based on a log-linear
specification) where the percentage change in profits is a function of a percentage point change
in the chosen tax rate variable. Alternatively, the estimate can be calculated with a standard
elasticity (based on a log-log specification), where the percentage change in profits is a function
of the percentage change in the chosen tax rate. The main advantage of the semi-elasticity is that
it is straightforward to interpret; an x percent change in profits for a one percentage point change
in the tax rate. Elasticity specifications can capture a changing responsiveness depending on the
absolute level of the tax variable. A semi-elasticity equivalent can be calculated for the elasticity
specification at the average of the tax rate.
Cost of tax planning / Linear vs. non-linear tax effects: Economic theory suggests two reasons
for a non-linear relation between tax rates and profit shifting: fixed cost of tax planning and
convex concealment costs. These effects are not mutually exclusive. Convex concealment costs
arise when the cost of shifting increases with the absolute amount of profits shifted. This implies
that the effect on pre-tax profits will be smaller at higher absolute levels of the tax rate
differential. If tax planning is associated with fixed costs, higher tax semi-elasticities would be
expected at higher absolute levels of the tax rate differential. Although Hines and Rice (1994)
found evidence of a non-linear relationship, most subsequent empirical analyses have reported
only linear specifications. Grubert and Mutti (1991) found evidence of fixed tax planning costs.
Dowd, Landefeld and Moore (2015) find a strong non-linear relationship with semi-elasticities
ranging from -0.8 to -9.5 depending on the level of the effective tax rate faced by the affiliate,
which provides empirical support of fixed costs of tax planning and for testing non-linear
specifications.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 93
94 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Table 3.1 Data sources, estimation strategies and results from recent profit shifting studies
Authors
Year
Semielasticity
Dischinger
2007
-0.7
2008
-1.3
Dependent
Variable
pre-tax
profit
pre-tax
profit
GDP
ADD
Fixed Effects
Firm
Time
x
x
Azemar
2010
-1.0
pre-tax
profit
2012
-0.7
pre-tax
profit
2012
-0.5
pre-tax
profit
2013
-0.5
2013
-1.1
pre-tax
profit
pre-tax
profit
Markle
2015
-0.9
pre-tax
profit
2015
-1.3
pre-tax
profit
Clausing
2015
-2.4
pre-tax
profit
Schwarz
2009
-3.5
Grubert
2012
-1.6
OECD
2015
-1.0
2011
-1.1
pre-tax
profit to
sales
pre-tax
profit to
sales
pre-tax
profit to
assets
post-tax
profit
x
x
Ind.
Rsquared
Time
Period
STR
affiliate to parent
0.76
19952005
STR
affiliate to parent
0.68
1999
US-STR
and
foreign
ETR
no
0.81
19922000
STR
affiliate to parent
N/A
19952006
STR
foreign aff. to
US parent
0.60
19822005
STR
affiliate to parent
0.14
STR
no
0.21
affiliate to group
Coverage
EU
entities
EU
entities
foreign
aff. of US
parents
19952005
19952005
EU
entities
foreign
aff. of US
parents
EU
entities
EU
entities
0.83
20042008
worldwide
entities
Data
FS
FS
TR
FS
IS
FS
FS
composite
var. based
on STR
STR and
ETR
no
0.46
20022010
ETR
foreign aff. to
US parent
0.64
19832011
ETR
no
0.28
19992001
change in
foreign
ETR
no
N/A
1996,
2004
STR
affiliate to group
0.03
20002010
worldwide
entities
FS
STR
no
0.01
20022009
EU
entities
FS
Tax rate
differential
Tax
variable
x
x
Ctry.
x
x
foreign
aff. of US
parents
foreign
aff. of US
parents
foreign
aff. of US
parents
foreign
aff. of US
parents
FS
TR
IS
IS
TR
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 95
Table 3.1 Data sources, estimation strategies and results from recent profit shifting studies (continued)
Authors
Year
Semielasticity
Dependent
Variable
GDP
ADD
2013
-0.4
EBIT
2013
-1.0
EBIT
2014
-1.6
EBIT
2011
-1.0
total factor
prod.
Weichenrieder
2009
-0.5
return on
assets
Heckemeyer and
Overesch
2013
-0.8
pre-tax
profit and
EBIT
Fixed Effects
Tax
variable
Tax rate
differential
Rsquared
STR
affiliate to parent
0.16
STR
affiliate to group
0.06
composite
var. based
on STR
affiliate to parent
STR
Firm
Time
Ind.
x
x
Ctry.
Time
Period
Coverage
19992009
20032011
EU
entities
worldwide
entities
0.71
19982009
EU
entities
no
0.10
19982004
STR
German affiliate
to parent
0.52
19962003
worldwide
entities
German
aff. of
foreign
par.
STR and
ETR
various
N/A
various
various
Data
FS
FS
FS
FS
IS
meta
Note: Studies estimating tax semi-elasticities of profit shifting published after 2006. In case of no preferred estimate, the baseline specification was used. C stands for tangible
capital, L for employee compensation, ADD for additional variables; a x indicates that corresponding control variables have been included. In the last column FS
indicates financial statement data, IS investment survey, and TR tax return data.
96 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
10
40
35
30
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
25
Weighted by the average inward and outward FDI position. Source: OECD Tax Database, OECD FDI
Statistics.
155. Most empirical studies analyse the effects of statutory headline tax rates. The
incentives for BEPS are based not only on headline statutory CIT rate differentials. Many
countries have preferential tax treatment for certain types of income. For example, the
strategic location of intangibles is a significant BEPS strategy, and the incentives to
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 97
engage in BEPS behaviour are increased when there are preferential tax rates on patent
income without economic nexus requirements. Figure 3.2. shows the average CIT rate on
patent income and the standard deviation in OECD countries. In 2013, eight OECD
countries had patent boxes. The remaining OECD countries applied their headline CIT
rates on patent income. Again, the tax rates are weighted by FDI to narrow the focus
towards MNE cross-border activity and BEPS.
156. The average CIT rate on patent income is lower and declined more than the
average headline CIT rate. The standard deviation of CIT rates on patent income is higher
and increased more than that of CIT headline rates. The standard deviation increased
sharply in 2007 when Belgium and the Netherlands introduced their patent boxes. The
weighted standard deviation of CIT rates on patent income in OECD countries increased
from 8.6 in 2003 to 11.8 in 2013, i.e. by 38%.
Figure 3.2. Incentive to engage in BEPS: Corporate income tax rate on patent income
variation within OECD countries
FDI weighted standard deviation (left axis)
16
40
12
30
20
10
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
157. Further refinement of these measures is possible, but they clearly show the
incentives for engaging in BEPS behaviours, such as the strategic location of intangibles,
has been increasing over the past 11 years. Finally, the incentive to shift profits to
countries with zero tax rates still remains strong even with lower average tax rates.
Reducing taxes to zero from 10% or 20% still creates a large tax rate differential effect,
which is why there is BEPS shifting to zero rate countries from all positive tax rate
countries.
158. When analysing BEPS it is important to refine the measurement as closely as
possible to the affected economic activity. Table 3.2 shows that a simple unweighted
standard deviation of statutory tax rates in OECD countries does not show an increase in
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
98 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
the incentive for BEPS. However, when the tax rate differentials are weighted by GDP
they show a significant increase. When they are weighted by FDI and trade, both
measures of MNE activity, they are even higher and the percentage change over the past
eleven years is also higher.10 The standard deviation of CIT rates on patent income is
much higher than simply using the statutory headline tax rate.
Table 3.2. Standard deviation of OECD tax rates, 2003 and 2013
Unweighted
GDP weighted
FDI weighted
Trade weighted
6.5
2013
5.8
4.7
5.6
5.6
6.6
7.0
6.6
8.5
7.2
8.6
8.3
2013
8.4
10.0
11.8
10.7
159. A similar analysis using bilateral tax rate differentials shows a similar large
incentive effect to undertake BEPS. Using FDI positions as weights11, there is a wide
variation ranging from 11% for the United States to -18% for Ireland between OECD
countries in 2012. Since 2000, the differentials have increased from 3% in the United
States and -13% in Ireland. Germanys FDI-weighted bilateral tax rate difference
declined from 16% in 2000 to 0% in 2014. Using shares of each trading countrys total
exports of goods accounted for by a trading partner as weights, there is a wide range of
tax rate differentials between OECD countries, ranging from 14% for the United States to
-16% for Ireland.
160. This type of information on tax rate differentials, the key explanatory variable in
empirical studies of BEPS, should be reported in empirical studies of profit shifting. The
tax rate differentials are as important as the elasticity estimate in the studies if the results
are used to estimate the fiscal impact of BEPS. It should also be noted that incomplete
coverage of countries in the underlying databases, whether using macroeconomic or firmlevel data, will affect the weighted average of the STRs in the comparison countries. If
countries (or firms in countries) with relatively high positive tax rate differentials are
underrepresented, the implicit global tax rate differential will be understated.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 99
162. Many studies focusing on developing countries do not separate the revenue lost
from BEPS behaviours from individual tax evasion and illicit financial flows. Developing
countries have higher ratios of CIT to GDP, so their revenue base is potentially more at
risk from BEPS behaviours than developed countries, and loss of CIT revenue could lead
to critical underfunding of public investment that could help promote economic growth.
In a report by the African Tax Administration Forum, African tax administrations find
that transfer-pricing abuse is a major obstacle not only to effective revenue mobilisation,
but also to development and poverty alleviation, and that most countries lack the
necessary skills to identify and analyse complex cases.12 Better understanding of the
economic effects of BEPS on developing countries is important for the design of tax
policies that account for country differences in tax systems and levels of enforcement
capabilities.
163. A recent working paper by UNCTAD13 provides a tax and investment perspective
on the tax consequences of FDI for developing economies. Investment is important to
sustainable growth of developing countries, which must be considered when reducing
profit shifting out of those economies. Again, how the potential additional tax revenues
from reducing BEPS behaviours are used by developing counties will be important to the
future effects of countermeasures on their inbound FDI.
164. The UNCTAD empirical analysis investigates the role of investment as one of the
enablers of tax avoidance, highlighting the use of special purpose entities (SPEs), tax
havens and the role of offshore investment hubs as major players in foreign direct
investment in developing countries. It states: The root-cause of the outsized role of
offshore hubs in global corporate investments is tax planning. The analysis is based on
an approach which maps aggregate corporate international investments between direct
investor and recipient jurisdictions based on bilateral flows in or coming from SPEs and
tax havens. It finds a relatively larger effect of SPE and tax haven investment in
developing countries.
100 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
the activity that generates it) will have a tendency to overestimate the scale of BEPS. This
is because BEPS is not due to tax differentials per se, but rather to specific taxpayer
strategies segregating taxable income from the activities that create that value. Tax rate
differentials using AETRs reflect non-BEPS tax reductions, such as from R&D tax credits
or accelerated depreciation, thus resulting in an overestimate of the scale of BEPS.
Implementation of transfer pricing rules allows a range (acceptable within inter-quartiles)
within which acceptable prices can be set, which are not reflected in tax rate differentials.
Due to other factors, particularly data limitations and incomplete specification of the
underlying production function, estimates from tax rate differences may underestimate
the scale of BEPS.14
168. Another approach uses aggregate macroeconomic country measures to take into
account tax rate differences or institutional differences. These studies take advantage of
country-specific details, such as the amount of country FDI from SPEs or tax havens, or
the statutory tax rates of tax havens and other countries. These studies are unlikely to
fully separate BEPS from real economic activity and non-BEPS tax preferences.
169. Another approach measures specific BEPS behaviours. A recent survey of the
academic literature by Riedel (2015) states: The most convincing empirical evidence has
been presented by academic studies that investigate specific profit shifting channels as
their empirical tests are more direct and offer less room for results being driven by
mechanisms unrelated to income shifting.15 Examples include quantifying the effects of
non-arms length transfer pricing, excessive interest deductions, and treaty abuse.
Measuring specific BEPS behaviours enables researchers to use different types of data
sources, such as trade data to analyse transfer pricing, leverage rates of affiliated
companies to analyse excessive interest, or bilateral investment flows to analyse treaty
abuse. BEPS behaviours are driven by differences in tax rates and/or differences between
tax systems that can be exploited to reduce taxation through artificial schemes.
170. While measuring specific BEPS Actions is a more direct approach, many of the
same data and methodological issues arise. Estimating the revenue effects of specific
BEPS Actions requires consideration of the interactions between different BEPS channels
(e.g. possible overlap or complementarities) in producing a total BEPS estimate. For
example, the tax challenges of the digital economy (Action 1) are being addressed
through the other Actions, in particular the work on artificial avoidance of permanent
establishment, transfer pricing and CFC rules.
171. At the individual country level, the BEPS Actions approach may be estimated by
governments using their own administrative databases, which will often include tax return
data. Proposed BEPS countermeasures are not expected to eliminate 100% of the impact
of BEPS behaviours out of consideration of administrative costs for tax administrations
and businesses. See Annex 3.B1 for a description of how governments could use this
approach to measure individual BEPS Actions.
172. There are a limited number of other estimates of global fiscal effects of BEPS or
the fiscal effects of BEPS for developing countries. A recent study16 uses aggregate
country data on investment through offshore investment centres and tax havens to
estimate the fiscal effects for developing countries and globally. Several non-government
organisations (NGOs) have published figures which are often multi-year estimates based
on trade or total corporate tax numbers, but do not attempt to separate real economic
activity from BEPS behaviours, and often include estimates of individual income tax
evasion or non-compliance.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 101
173. Given the many uncertainties associated with global estimates of the scale and
economic impacts of BEPS, no single empirical estimate will be definitive, but such
estimates are generally of more value for policymakers than extrapolating from more
narrow studies involving a limited number of companies or countries. By laying out the
approaches taken, the research can be further refined as improvements in available data
and methodologies become available.
174. Table 3.3 shows the range of global estimates from a new OECD estimate of the
global revenue loss from BEPS (described below), as well as from two other analyses.
The estimates range from 4% to 10% of global CIT revenue for the global revenue loss,
and from 7.5-14% of developing countries CIT revenue. It should be noted that the
UNCTAD estimates do not include the full effects of trade mispricing.17
Table 3.3. Estimates of global and developing country fiscal effects from BEPS
Fiscal estimate approach
Scope
Year (level)
2014
5% of CIT
200 (8% of CIT)*
13% of CIT
66-120 (7.5-14% of
CIT)*
2012
2012
102 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
investment by MNEs. The analysis is based on 2.0 million records between 2000 and
2010. As a result of both profit shifting, mismatches between tax systems and relative use
of domestic tax preferences, the ETR of large MNE entities is estimated to be lower on
average by 4 to 8 percentage points compared to similarly-situated domestic-only
affiliates. This differential is even higher among very large firms and MNEs with patents.
178. A revenue loss estimate requires a number of important parameters and
assumptions to extrapolate from one database to a global estimate. As the available data
have limitations in representativeness and coverage in a number of countries, only a
global estimate based on global parameters was produced. The revenue loss arises from
two effects: profit shifting due to tax rate differentials and differences in average effective
tax rates for large affiliates due to mismatches between tax systems and tax preferences.
The combination of the two effects results in estimates of the net18 global corporate tax
revenues lost from BEPS at 4-10% of corporate tax revenues, or USD 100-240 billion at
2014 levels. These estimates are based on the specific database, methodology and
assumptions used as described below and in more detail in Annex 3.A1.
179.
180. The key parameters used are the responsiveness of the profit-to-asset ratio to tax
rate differentials estimated from the ORBIS database with a particular regression
specification for profitable entities (-0.1); the average profit-to-asset ratio (6.2%) from
ORBIS data; an average tax rate differential between affiliates (3.6%) from ORBIS data;
MNEs share of profits (59%) with the ORBIS data and supplemented with aggregate tax
return tabulations for several countries; tax credits as percent of before-credit corporate
tax collections (19%) from an OECD survey19; and an estimate of USD 2.3 trillion of
after-credit corporate tax collections in 2014, adjusted for expected growth from 2011.
181. The estimate is based on a number of assumptions. The estimated semi-elasticities
of reported profits to tax rate differentials of -1.0 for all MNE entities and -1.6 for
profitable MNE entities is assumed to be the same for the MNEs outside the ORBIS
sample as the MNEs in the sample; the tax variable is assumed to accurately capture
profit shifting, based on the specification of the regression and the variables used; tax
revenue changes are assumed to be proportional to the amount of profit shifting; noncorporate businesses are assumed not to be engaged in BEPS; ORBIS relationships for
tax rate differentials and asset/profit ratio are assumed to be the same for MNEs outside
the ORBIS sample as the MNEs in the sample; differences in any of these relationships
across countries are assumed to not significantly affect the global estimate; and the
average profit shifting response to tax rate differentials between 2000 and 2010 is
assumed to be the same for 2014.
182. The estimate of the mismatches between tax systems and the relative use of
domestic tax preferences is calculated by the following equation:
CIT revenue lost from MNE mismatches between tax systems and preferential tax
treatment = Average ETR difference between large MNE entities and comparable
domestic entities MNEs share of total profits Share of large MNEs estimated
global CIT revenues
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 103
183. The key variables different from the profit shifting equation are the average ETR
difference between large MNE entities and comparable domestic entities estimated from
the ORBIS database with a particular regression specification (3.25%) and the share of
large MNEs as a percentage of all MNEs in the ORBIS sample (93%).
184. The estimate is based on some additional assumptions. The estimate of a ETR
differential between large MNEs and comparable domestic entities is assumed to be the
same for the MNEs outside the ORBIS sample as the MNEs in the sample; the
differential tax rate variable is assumed to not include non-BEPS tax preferences
available to both MNEs and domestic companies; tax revenue changes are assumed to be
proportional to the amount of the estimated ETR differential; and the average ETR
difference between 2000 and 2010 is assumed to be the same for 2014.
185. Some factors may lead to an underestimation of the revenue loss (e.g. missing
entities engaged in significant BEPS, different weighting in estimation20), while other
factors may lead to an overestimate (e.g. not controlling for country-fixed effects21).
Recognising these uncertainties, a range of the global revenue estimates is presented. The
range from 4% to 10% of CIT revenues takes into account a 95% confidence interval
around the tax sensitivity estimates22 and the upper bound assumes that firms outside the
sample have a 50% higher tax planning intensity than firms in the sample. The coverage
rate of ORBIS with the OECD STAN Business Demography Statistics was an average
32%, weighted by corporate tax collections.
104 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 105
106 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
3.3.7 The extent of BEPS behaviours and possible dynamic effects if not
curtailed
190. Another dimension to the scale of BEPS is the question of How widespread is
BEPS activity among corporations? A number of studies have found evidence that profit
shifting is widespread across the corporate MNE sector, but several recent papers (Davies
et al., 2014; Egger et al., 2014) report significant BEPS behaviours by a limited number
of large MNEs with affiliates in a small number of jurisdictions. The answer to this
question has implications for the design of BEPS countermeasures. More research is
needed in this area.
191. Another aspect is the dynamic nature of BEPS. Even if BEPS is not widespread
now, it could become much more widespread if nothing is done on an internationally-coordinated basis. Competitive pressures through pricing and acquisitions give MNEs using
BEPS an advantage in lower costs to take market share from companies or acquire
companies that do not use BEPS to lower their costs. As seen recently in the case of
corporate inversions, a significant change in corporate tax behaviour minimising taxes
can occur suddenly even when legal arrangements under current law had existed for
years.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 107
108 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
internal borrowing being particularly sensitive to taxes. Using German firm-level data,
Moen et al. (2011) find evidence of both internal and external debt shifting and estimate
that they are of about equal relevance.
200. Huizinga, Laeven and Nicodme (2008) use the European Amadeus database to
test whether differences in taxation among countries have a statistically significant effect
on the firms capital structure and on internal debt. They include both marginal effective
tax rates and an indicator of the tax incentive to shift debt (calculated as the sum of
international tax differences weighted by local assets), and find a statistically significant
effect on firms leverage, indicating that debt shifting might occur, not only between
parent and subsidiaries, but also among foreign subsidiaries. They find an increase of the
effective tax rate by 0.06 in the subsidiary country has a positive international effect on
leverage in the subsidiary country of 0.4%.
201. Weichenrieder (2015) describes the growing literature on rules limiting the
deductibility of interest, including studies of German inbound FDI (Weichenrieder &
Windischbauer (2008) and Overesch & Wamser (2010)); German outbound FDI
(Buettner et al. (2012)), and United States outbound FDI (Blouin et al. (2014)). Two
papers evaluated the German interest barrier rule introduced in 2008, which limits the
deductibility of interest generally to 30% of EBITDA. Using the DAFNE database for
German companies, Buslei and Simmler (2012) consider how the rule affected firms
capital structure, investment and profitability. The results show a strong behavioural
response by firms to avoid the limited deductibility of interest expenses, successfully
broadening the tax base in the short-term. Affected firms decreased their debt-to-assets
ratios and there was no evidence of a negative (short-term) effect on investment. Dreler
and Scheuering (2012) analysed how German firms subject to the interest barrier rule
adjusted their debt-to-assets ratios and their net interest payments compared to a control
group. Their analysis shows that the interest barrier resulted in firms lowering their debtto-assets ratios and their net interest payments, but principally by reducing external debt
rather than related party debt.
202. The OECD analysis in Annex 3.A1 finds evidence of strategic placement of
external (third-party) debt in MNE consolidated groups due to tax rate differentials within
the group. A one percentage point higher statutory corporate tax rate of an affiliate than
the average in the MNE group is associated with a 1.3% higher external debt/equity ratio
for that affiliate. The analysis does not include the location of intra-group debt.
Prevent treaty abuse (Action 6)
203. Empirical analyses of tax treaty issues are limited and often are included with
other BEPS behaviours or are specific to particular countries. One recent simulation
analysis, Vant Reit and Lejour (2014), shows the potential reduction in withholding
taxes due to treaty shopping, but the analysis is not based on actual taxpayer behaviour.
204. The analysis examines bilateral tax rates on cross-border dividends between 108
countries (3,244 country pairs) and shows that indirect routes (treaty shopping) are
cheaper than direct routes for 67% of the country pairs. 21% of the country pairs have a
zero effective tax rate without treaty shopping, but 54% when treaty shopping is possible.
Treaty shopping is estimated to reduce the withholding effective tax rate by more than 5
percentage points from nearly 8% to 3%. A simulated removal of tax havens from any
double tax relief (other than foreign tax credit) shows an increase in the world average
effective withholding tax rate by 0.14 percentage points.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 109
Assure that transfer pricing outcomes are in line with value creation (Actions 8-10)
205. Transfer pricing has been identified as a major BEPS issue with four actions
identified in the BEPS Action Plan specifically dedicated to addressing BEPS through
this channel. Transfer pricing, particularly through the shifting of intangible assets, is
discussed in the general BEPS analyses. Four key studies focus specifically on transfer
pricing.
206. Clausing (2003) investigates the effect of host country statutory and effective tax
rates on inter-company trade in goods. Using data on intra-firm transactions from the
United States Bureau of Labor Statistics, the analysis finds that low foreign statutory tax
rates are correlated with lower export prices and higher import prices relative to thirdparty transactions. The analysis finds a tax rate 1% lower in the country of
destination/origin is associated with intra-firm export prices that are 1.8% lower and
intra-firm import prices that are 2.0% higher, relative to non-intra-firm goods. Several
other studies using price-based comparisons of related-party and third-party imports and
exports show significant tax effects, including a recent study of French 1999 trade data by
Davies et al. (2014).
207. Grubert (2003) analysing data from United States MNEs tax returns for United
States MNEs finds that United States controlled foreign corporations (CFCs) located in
countries with relatively low and relatively high statutory CIT rates engage in
significantly greater volumes of inter-affiliate transactions. This is consistent with BEPS
related activity. The analysis finds that R&D intensive companies engage in greater
volumes of such intra-company trade.
208. Mutti and Grubert (2009) analyse United States MNEs tax return data to
investigate whether the United States check-the-box regulation has encouraged the
relocation of intangible assets abroad. They provide evidence of a substantial migration of
intangible assets abroad, in particular to low tax countries through hybrid entities and
cost-sharing agreements. Moreover, descriptive statistics show that royalty payments
among foreign affiliates increased sharply in the period considered, from entities in hightax countries to entities in low-tax countries.
209. Karkinsky and Riedel (2012) focus on the effect of statutory tax rates and other
tax-related variables (such as binding CFC rules and withholding tax on royalties) on the
number of MNEs patent applications. They build a unique dataset of European firms
merging Amadeus financial statement database with PATSTAT information. They find
that low tax rates increase the probability that the firm applies for a patent in low-tax
locations. This result is similar to a study by Griffith, Miller and OConnell (2011).
210. The OECD analysis in Annex 3.A1 finds that the tax sensitivity of profit shifting
is almost twice as large among MNE groups with patents as for non-patenting MNE
groups, controlling for a number of factors affecting firms profitability. A separate
analysis, which uses combination of data on patents from PATSTAT and firm
characteristics from ORBIS financial account data, suggests that preferential tax
treatment of patents increases both patents invested in other countries as well as R&D
activities.
Benefits of better disclosure (Actions 5, 11, 12 and 13)
211. Hoopes (2015) provides a survey of a number of studies that have analysed the
effects of disclosure issues. A paper by Dyreng, Hoopes and Wilde (2014) finds empirical
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
110 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
evidence suggesting that U.K. public companies decreased tax avoidance and reduced the
use of subsidiaries in tax haven countries when there was increased public disclosure.
Several studies (Lohse et al., 2012; Lohse and Riedel, 2012; Annex 3.A1) find empirical
evidence of reduced profit shifting from tougher transfer pricing documentation rules.
Increased transparency of government tax rules (Action 5) will reduce a non-tax rate
competition, with greater disclosure of government rulings involving potential base
erosion.
212. Announcements of future legislative changes can affect corporate taxpayer
behaviours even before specific legislative measures have been enacted. Some
corporations are already changing their international tax structures due to the progress of
the BEPS Project and expected changes by governments.34
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 111
112 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
221. Fifth, economic analyses and estimates of BEPS and BEPS countermeasures are
subject to significant uncertainty, given the difficulty of disentangling BEPS activity from
MNEs real economic activity and non-BEPS tax preferences, plus the significant
limitations of currently available data. Multiple approaches finding large magnitudes
provide greater certainty of the general scale of BEPS than individual studies using one
methodology and relying upon a single data source. Any statistical estimate has a range of
error given the sample used and the unexplained variance of the underlying economic
activity. Extrapolation beyond the sample from which an analysis is conducted is a
further source of bias since it is not known whether the missing companies have the same
behaviours as the included companies.
222. Sixth, although the incidence of corporate taxes is still widely debated, most
analyses conclude that corporate income tax falls on both capital and labour, varying in
the degree of capital mobility, openness of the economy, and the extent to which the
corporations are earning competitive returns or economic rents.38 Since BEPS is not a
general CIT rate reduction, but a self-selected tax reduction of some MNEs, the burden of
BEPS countermeasures would not be the same as the burden of a general corporate tax
policy change. Not all of the corporate tax increase on MNEs engaging in BEPS will
affect their investment decisions, since some could fall on economic rents or be passed
forward or backward to other economic actors.
223. Seventh, it is important to account for taxpayer behaviours. If the BEPS
countermeasures are not adopted by most countries or if there are other tax avoidance
mechanisms not addressed by the BEPS countermeasures with which MNEs could avail
themselves, then the positive gains from the BEPS Project would be reduced. If BEPS is
reduced, tax rate differentials for some MNEs could increase resulting in shifts of real
economic activity, plus tax competition affecting real economic activity could increase.
Additional economic research on the mobility of real economic activity (research and
expenditure, physical investment, employees) is needed, since current measures of
mobility are often on the mobility of income, which reflects significant BEPS behaviours.
224. Finally, a comprehensive analysis of the economic impacts of BEPS
countermeasures would also include an evaluation of the net change in the taxpayer
compliance costs, the effectiveness of tax administration enforcement. The analysis
would identify any unintended double taxation from inconsistent implementation of tax
treaties and improvements in dispute resolution through the mutual agreement procedure.
225. The global fiscal and economic impacts of BEPS and BEPS countermeasures are
important, and initial estimates based on currently available data, tools and methodologies
are helpful to policymakers. While current modelling of BEPS and countermeasures is
not done comprehensively or with a full general-equilibrium model due to data and
conceptual limitations, the economic impact analyses show BEPS distorts many business
decisions. Analyses by each countrys tax policy and statistical offices using more
detailed information about their economies and tax systems will be necessary to fully
assess the effects of the BEPS Action Plan on individual countries.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 113
227. Tax incidence analysis is designed to determine who bears the burden of a tax.
The burden of a tax is defined to be the ultimate resting point of the tax after recognising
any tax shifting that might occur after the tax is imposed. Tax shifting is the process by
which taxpayers bearing the legal responsibility for paying the tax (legal incidence)
alter their behaviour and, as a result, shift the burden of the tax to other parties (e.g.
consumers, workers and capital owners) through changes in output or input prices. The
final resting point for a tax is the economic incidence of the tax. Thus, the economic
incidence or burden of a tax can be very different than the initial legal incidence of the
tax.39
228. The extent of tax shifting from BEPS countermeasures will depend on a number
of factors, including how the additional tax revenues from the BEPS countermeasures are
used by the government: which taxes are changed, what type of spending is changed,
and/or the extent to which governments budget balances are changed. The extent of tax
shifting also depends on the market conditions faced by MNEs engaging in BEPS: how
sensitive consumers are to price changes, the presence of competition, and how
responsive the supply of labour and capital are to changes in compensation and the return
on investment.40
229. There are several assumptions used in this analysis to identify the economic
incidence of changes in global corporate income taxes as a result of the implementation
of the BEPS countermeasures. Any analysis of the economic incidence of BEPS
countermeasures requires making assumptions about these issues.
All countries adopt the recommended BEPS countermeasure. If a significant
amount of economic activity is not subject to the countermeasure, then the
conclusions would be different. This is consistent with a longer-run perspective
on the incidence of the tax changes.
Capital is mobile across industries within a country and between countries in the
medium term (3-10 years), while labour is less mobile.
The impact on global economic activity from the implementation of the BEPS
countermeasures will depend primarily upon the average worldwide change in
total CIT collections and the global after-tax rate of return on capital
investment.
The impact on economic activity in any single country will depend on how the
after-tax rate of return in the country initially changes relative to the worldwide
after-tax rate of return as a result of the BEPS countermeasures.
Countries CIT rates remain constant.
230. Based on the fiscal impact estimates of the impact of the BEPS countermeasures,
there will be a net worldwide increase in corporate income tax collections. However,
while most countries will have higher corporate tax collections from the BEPS
countermeasures, some countries could experience decreases in CIT collections as a
result of BEPS countermeasures that align taxable income with the location where the
economic activity generating that income is located. Given the global net CIT tax
increase, the following discussion describes the tax shifting process in terms of where the
burden of any additional taxes collected will fall.
231. In the short run, the net increase in CIT revenues will lower the after-tax rate of
return on capital investments of the firms currently engaging in BEPS behaviours. An
important question relates to the extent to which capital would be reallocated in response
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
114 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
to reducing BEPS and its effect on the after-tax rate of return of companies that have been
engaging in BEPS. The answer depends upon the extent to which BEPS behaviours have
increased their after-tax rates of return (relative to what they would be without BEPS), as
well as the market conditions in which they operate.
232. MNEs that have used BEPS to reduce their CIT revenues have been able to
reduce, on average, effective tax rates in those countries (most often in countries with
weak anti-avoidance rules and above-average statutory or effective tax rates). While
MNEs take these ETRs into consideration when making initial location investment
decisions, BEPS can result in increases in the after-tax rates of return of those companies
without necessarily increasing the level of their existing capital investments. OECD
research presented in Annex 3.A1 finds in industries with a high concentration of MNEs
with affiliates in no-tax countries the responsiveness of investment to tax rates is less than
other firms investments. This is because tax-planning MNEs can achieve lower taxes
through artificial arrangements without changing the location of the value-creation and
real economic activity. With BEPS countermeasures, the availability of this form of doit-yourself tax relief will be substantially reduced. As a result, the after-tax rates of
return of those companies will be reduced.
233. If after-tax rates of return are reduced of companies engaging in BEPS in some
countries as a result of the BEPS countermeasures, what will be the impact on real
investment and economic activities in those industries and those countries? The answer to
this question is complicated, and depends, to a significant degree, on whether the affected
MNEs are operating in competitive or imperfect markets and on the time horizon for the
analysis.
234. If the MNEs paying higher taxes are operating in competitive markets (i.e.
earning just the required rate of return on their capital at the margin, which means zero
economic rent), the standard CIT incidence analysis would predict that in the long run
they will reallocate capital from the high-tax industries and countries with lower after-tax
rates of return to other industries and countries that now offer higher after-tax rates of
return. In the process there will be less real economic activity in the relatively high-tax
industries and countries and more real economic activity in the lower-tax industries and
countries. The shifting process will end when the after-tax rate of return is equalized at
the new, lower after-tax rate of return on all worldwide capital that reflects the higher
global CIT tax wedge due to the net increase in global CIT taxes from implementing
the BEPS countermeasures.
235. In the competitive market case, in the long run after sufficient time for real capital
to be reallocated, the expected impact of the higher global CIT is:
Capital owners will bear most of the burden of the average global net tax
increase due to the adoption of BEPS countermeasures. In the adjustment
process, capital may be reallocated across industries and countries with
associated impacts on consumer prices and labour compensation. However, the
burden of the overall net increase will be borne by capital owners located in all
countries and all industries because reallocations of capital cannot avoid this
incremental burden.41 To the extent the increase in corporate tax reduces the
after-tax rate of return to all capital, a lower return to saving and investment in
the long run could reduce overall global capital investment and thus the
productivity of labour with some proportion shifted to labour in the form of
lower wages.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 115
116 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
economic rents over a long period of time and there would be no significant
reallocation of capital among countries.
237. Economic incidence, particularly of the CIT in a global economy, is still an
unresolved issue for economists. The economic incidence of unilateral measures
increasing the cost of capital for business in one country relative to other countries with
mobile capital in competitive markets would fall on the fixed factors. The economic
incidence analysis of co-ordinated, multilateral BEPS countermeasures in the presence of
imperfect competition, however, may lead to significantly different conclusions compared
to the analysis of unilateral measures in competitive markets.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 117
tax rules which are used more by certain industries, such as accelerated depreciation or
research and development tax credits, or which have special industry tax rules. Tax
revenue reductions from BEPS are also likely to vary from industry to industry. For
example, the ability to move intangible assets and the income associated with intangible
assets without changing the location of where the value was created is a significant source
of BEPS and is likely to occur in some industries more than others. This can create
economic distortions across industries from varying ETRs. Many of the empirical
analyses find stronger profit shifting responses to taxes for companies that have patents,
where the MNE has intangibles, or are in industries with extensive intangibles.
Annex 3.A1 shows that the ETR differential is higher among MNEs with patents, since
they have a higher profit-shifting intensity and can take greater advantage of tax
preferences, such as for R&D, than domestic firms by the strategic placement of R&D
and patents.
243. MNEs can take advantage of both domestic tax planning and BEPS to lower their
effective tax rates below the rates of domestic competitors, providing them with an
advantage in gaining market share through lower consumer prices or their ability to
acquire domestic companies. Egger, Eggert and Winner (2010) and Annex 3.A1 find
effective tax rates of MNEs or their affiliates are lower than comparable domestic
corporations or their affiliates. Annex 3.A1 estimates that BEPS reduces the effective tax
rate of large affiliates of MNEs by 4 to 8 percentage points on average compared to
similarly-situated domestic-only affiliates, due to both profit shifting, mismatches
between tax systems and domestic tax preferences.47 The differential is larger for MNEs
affiliates with more than 1,000 employees and MNEs with patents. Identifying
comparable MNE and domestic-only companies may not be possible given inherent
differences between companies operating multi-nationally and those operating only
domestically.48 Identifying even somewhat comparable companies is a challenge,
particularly for smaller countries, but statistical techniques, such as propensity score
matching and regression analysis, have been used.
244. Academic studies have generally not analysed the economic implications of tax
planning on competition between companies. The OECD analysis in Annex 3.A1 assesses
if industries with a strong presence of tax-planning MNEs are more concentrated and if
MNE groups engaged in tax planning obtain different price mark-ups as compared to
other firms with similar characteristics. The empirical analysis suggests that industries
with a strong presence of MNEs are more concentrated. The empirical analysis also finds
that MNE groups with an affiliate in a no-corporate-tax-country are associated with
higher price mark-ups (pre-tax operating profit divided by turnover), controlling for other
factors affecting mark-ups such as size, productivity, leverage, presence of patents and
exposure to foreign competition. Sikes and Verrecchia (2014) find a negative effect on
firms cost of capital in economies where a significant proportion of firms engage in tax
avoidance, with the most burdensome effect on firms that do not engage in tax avoidance.
245. BEPS-induced distortions in the location of corporate debt. Economic efficiency
is also affected by BEPS effects on MNEs capital structure. A number of studies show
BEPS occurring through excessive interest deductions, with both related-party and
external debt. As interest deductions are taken in high-tax rate countries, and interest
income is attributed to in low or no-tax countries, the after-tax cost of debt is reduced.
Differences in the tax treatment of debt and equity can be exploited in the cross-border
context. Thus, debt shifting exacerbates the existing tax bias towards corporate debt
financing.
118 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
246. A bias toward corporate debt and a bias against corporate equity already exist in
most corporate tax systems. Corporate interest is deductible and generally taxed at the
interest recipient level. Corporate equity income in the form of retained earnings and
dividends are taxed at the entity level and generally again at the investor level, although a
number of countries provide reliefs to dividends and capital gains. Debt shifting by
MNEs exacerbates the corporate tax bias by effectively increasing the tax benefit from
interest deductions through the strategic location of both external and internal debt to
high-tax countries. Use of hybrid mismatch arrangements can result in multiple layers of
borrowing within a MNE group with multiple interest deductions, or deductions of
interest in one country but the payment is treated as an exempt dividend in another
country. Increased external and internal debt shifting thus increases the overall level of
debt bias.
247. Proposals to reduce the debt bias through notional allowances for corporate equity
(ACE) have been implemented in several countries. MNEs can shift their capital structure
to maximise tax benefits from external and internal debt in high tax countries without
interest limitations, while increasing their equity contributions in countries with an ACE
system.
248. BEPS-induced distortions in the location of patents. Numerous studies show that
BEPS affects the location of FDI and patents, since taxable income can be segregated
from where the value is created. This can affect the location of some employment and
physical capital to justify claims for the desired tax treatment. This varies depending on
the tax treatment, generally in the form of a preferential IP regime, on offer, and the
activity requirement needed to qualify for such treatment. The analysis in Annex 3.A1
which uses a combination of data on patents from PATSTAT and firm characteristics
from the ORBIS database, finds tax rate differences affect the location of patent
registrations. A recent European Commission study finds that lower tax rates on certain
intangible income encourages greater connection between residence of inventors and the
location of registration of patents if the rules require such connection. Otherwise the
lower tax rate encourages shifting of patent registrations and taxable income without a
significant shift in real economic activity.49
249. Future studies of the effects of taxes on the location of real R&D investment
expenditures and research engineers and scientists are needed. Studies examining R&D
effects have looked at the location of the registration of patents and whether an investor
associated with the patent resides in the country, but have not analysed actual R&D
activity.50 Such studies would need to account for existing R&D tax credits and
deductions of more than 100% of R&D expenditures, plus personal income taxes on the
inventors as well as non-tax factors such as agglomeration effects and countries public
R&D investments.
250. Effects on the location of real economic activity. Taxes matter in location
decisions as shown in a number of empirical analyses. De Mooij (2008) did a metaanalysis of which finds that effective marginal tax rates and average marginal tax rates,
rather than statutory tax rates, have significant effects on FDI. He reports a -0.4 semielasticity of effective marginal tax rate effect on the intensive margin of FDI (increases
within an individual country), while finding a -0.65 semi-elasticity of the effective
average tax rate on the extensive margin of FDI (changes between countries). It should be
noted that FDI includes more than just greenfield investments and business expansions,
but also reinvested earnings and merger and acquisitions. Estimates of the responsiveness
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 119
of real economic activity could be understated if companies can currently achieve tax
benefits without moving real economic activity.
251. Linking real economic activity to tax benefits for patent income or for any type of
income or economic activity will more closely align taxable income with actual economic
activity. Providing tax benefits associated with a type of income or behaviour without any
such requirement that real or substantial activity occur is likely to achieve a countrys
policy goal of generating significantly more of the economic activity in their country, but
is likely to result in MNEs engaging in BEPS. Increasing the link through measures to
counter harmful tax practices and through assuring transfer pricing outcomes are in line
with value creation will result in higher taxes on companies currently doing profit
shifting. Aligning taxable income with real economic activity will result in more taxable
income being reported by companies currently engaging in profit shifting in the
jurisdictions where the economic activity giving rise to that income actually occurs.
Aligning taxable income with real economic activity will not mean that companies will
pay less attention to countries statutory tax rates, but instead tax rates will be taken into
account when decisions about the actual location or relocation of the real activities and
function that generate income are being made. The analysis in Annex 3.A1 finds support
for the hypothesis that tax planning MNEs investment is currently less sensitive to tax
rates than other firms investment since tax planning MNEs can reduce their ETRs
through artificial arrangements without changing the location of their real economic
activity.
252. While taxes affect location and investment decisions, they are not the only factor
MNEs take into account. It is important for researchers to estimate the effects of all
business taxes, not just corporate income taxes, and taking into account the effects of
non-tax factors. Table 3.4 summarises key factors determining the location of MNE
operations from two business surveys. The right column shows the ranking from a World
Bank survey of almost 200 decision makers of the largest MNEs. The left column shows
the ranking from a recent EY report of European decision-makers.
Table 3.4. Ranking of key location factors of MNE operations
Europe 2014
Worldwide 2002
Access to customers
Cost of labour
10
Level of corruption
National taxes
11
Local taxes
17
Telecommunications infrastructure
10
19
Note: The ranking for Europe comes from the EY Attractiveness Survey 2014 and the worldwide from the
Foreign Direct Investment Survey by the World Bank 2002. Local labour skill level was number 6 and
corporate taxation number 8 in the EY survey. Factors that could not be matched are marked with a minus
sign.
120 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
165. The table shows similar rankings about key location factors of MNE operations in
Europe and worldwide. A stable social and political environment and access to
customers rank at the top of both lists. The cost of labour and the qualification of
potential employees are also very important. National and local taxation are ranked 8th or
lower, and do not appear to be as important as many other factors.51 Nonetheless, when
tax differences are large or when other factors are fairly similar across locations, taxes
will affect business location decisions, as reflected in the empirical studies.
166. BEPS-induced distortions of types of investment. BEPS distorts the allocation of
investment and capital resources, favouring types of capital that are most conducive to
BEPS behaviours.52 Table 3.5 shows an illustrative marginal effective tax rate calculation
for knowledge based capital (KBC) from the OECD Supporting Investment in Knowledge
Capital, Growth and Innovation (2013). The analysis calculated a tax wedge, difference
between the pre-tax required hurdle rate of return on R&D at the margin and the aftertax required rate of return to the investor. The R&D tax wedge for domestic licensing and
production, or for a companys own-use in production, is 16 percentage points. The R&D
tax wedge becomes a negative 32 percentage points with the transfer of the KBC to an
offshore holding company with a substantially lower effective tax rate. Instead of the
income from the KBC investment bearing some tax, albeit much lower than the statutory
tax rate, the tax treatment of the income from the KBC becomes a significant subsidy as a
result of BEPS behaviours.
Table 3.5. Summary R&D tax wedge with MNE tax planning
R&D tax wedge
No R&D tax credit
(percentage points)
16.2
6.1
11.7
2.0
-3.0
-11.5
-32.4
-38.4
-14.5
-17.3
167. Another economic distortion and economic efficiency effect occurs when the tax
system favours one type of company over another. This results when MNEs engaging in
BEPS are able to reduce their ETR due to BEPS compared to MNEs not engaging in
BEPS and compared to domestic-only companies. MNEs have an inherent advantage
over domestic-only companies in being able to strategically place activity in jurisdictions
that offer special domestic tax incentives, such as R&D investment expenditures. Those
differences, which can result in differential effective tax rates, are not BEPS behaviours.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 121
168. MNEs can take advantage of BEPS behaviours to artificially segregate taxable
income from the activity creating that income to reduce the MNE groups overall
effective tax rate (i.e. the affiliate in a country will face the same statutory tax rate as a
domestic only group, but will have less or more taxable income in that country due to
profit shifting).53 The overall groups effective tax rate can be lowered, which can provide
a potential competitive advantage in terms of cost savings compared to less aggressive tax
planning MNEs or domestic only companies without multinational tax planning
opportunities. The tax savings from BEPS behaviours can enable tax planning MNEs to
have a competitive advantage in obtaining favourable financing, in making acquisitions,
and in lowering product prices.
122 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
rates. While the estimates based on effective tax rates do not provide statistically
significant results, strategic setting of statutory tax rates is supported by the evidence. The
analysis confirms the negative effect of foreign CIT statutory rates on domestic tax bases.
Specifically, a one percentage point reduction in CIT statutory rates in all other countries
yields a 6.5 percent decrease in the CIT base of the average country and a simultaneous
reduction in the domestic CIT rate by 0.5 percentage points. This strategic decrease of the
CIT rate leads to an increase in the CIT base by 4 percent and a net base loss of
2.5 percent.
174. The presence of fiscal externalities implies that unilateral approaches to
international tax policy issues are likely to lead to inefficient outcomes at the global level.
Countries enacting unilateral countermeasures may protect their tax bases, while shifting
base erosion activity to other countries.56 Countries that encourage tax base shifting with
BEPS-facilitation attributes, such as lack of transparency, combined with a low or no
corporate tax,57 can reduce tax revenues in other countries and overall through both direct
and strategic spillover effects.
3.4 Future areas for economic research to better measure the scale and economic
impact of BEPS with better data
175. The mandate for Action 11 included developing an economic analysis of the scale
and impact of BEPS (including spillover effects across countries) and actions to address
it. This chapter summarises the current understanding of the scale and impact of BEPS
based on academic studies, other international organisations analyses, as well as some
new OECD research. Progress is being made in better understanding BEPS and
countermeasures, and the economic analysis show that BEPS is significant and affects
many economic decisions of both taxpayers and governments. The issue of BEPS and
appropriate geographic allocation of income and expenses relative to measures of value
creating activities is important not only to the current corporate income tax, but also
would affect other taxes proposed by some academics such as a business cash-flow tax or
a comprehensive business income tax.
176. The current body of empirical research into the fiscal and economic impacts of
BEPS demonstrates that the stakes are high, but there is still much further research
needed to be undertaken. Chapter 1 has illustrated how currently available data is affected
by many limitations, and this chapter outlined many methodological challenges
confronted by BEPS researchers. Chapter 2 includes BEPS Indicators that can be refined
with better data and more sophisticated analysis of that data. Annex 3.A1 provides
empirical estimates of the economic effects of tax planning based on financial account
data, which could be refined with better data. Annex 3.A2 provides a toolkit for analysing
the fiscal effects of specific BEPS countermeasures, which is often a strong starting point
for analysis of other economic effects. Chapter 4 makes recommendations on how better
use could be made of current and future data and recommends tools to monitor and
evaluate the effectiveness and economic impact of the actions taken to address BEPS in
the future. This chapter identified a number of areas for future BEPS analysis that have
not been undertaken or that are limited by current data. A number of areas for future
research beyond the Action 11 mandate but which will add to the understanding of BEPS
and MNEs are highlighted, since better data alone will not be sufficient for the best
possible analysis of BEPS.
177.
The following are some of the areas where additional analysis is needed:
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 123
The prevalence and intensity of BEPS. How pervasive are BEPS behaviours? Is
BEPS limited to a small number of MNEs or more widespread? Are some
MNEs more intensively exploiting BEPS than other MNEs, and if so why (e.g.
costs of tax planning, corporate governance, risk profile)?58 Would largely
unrestricted BEPS encourage smaller MNEs to start engaging in BEPS and
encourage domestic companies to go global for the BEPS tax benefits?
Differences in the profitability of MNEs vs. comparable domestic entities. Are
there inherent economic differences between MNEs and domestic entities which
make comparisons of ETR difficult? If so, how can competitiveness between
MNEs and domestic entities be evaluated?
Factors contributing to group profitability. What contributes to the profitability
of a global consolidated MNE? How much can be explained by tangible capital,
labour and/or sales compared to other factors such as different types of
intangible assets, public infrastructure, country risk diversification, etc.
Factors contributing to affiliate profitability. What contributes to the
profitability of individual MNE entities? How can functions, assets and risks be
incorporated in future analyses of BEPS, since they are the basis of arms length
pricing? How much can be explained simply by tangible capital, labour and/or
sales compared to other factors such as the intangible assets of their global
MNE, public infrastructure, labour force qualities and stability in a country,
etc.? How can these other factors which may change over time be incorporated
more fully than just dummy variables?
Other tax factors in location decisions. Corporate taxes are only one sourcebased tax affecting location decisions. How do these other business taxes affect
MNEs tax decisions? How can measures of profit shifting separate the effects
of non-BEPS tax preferences from BEPS?
Effects of uncertainty, reputation and compliance costs, and disclosure.
Companies face the equivalent of implicit taxes from uncertainty, reputation59
and compliance costs. Can these be measured and included in the economic
analysis of taxes and BEPS? What effects do disclosures to tax administrations
have?60
Mobility of different types of labour and capital. How mobile are different
forms of real economic activity, such as top level executives, R&D scientists,
production workers, back-office workers, buildings, equipment, different types
of intangible assets, etc.?
Governments strategic behaviours. How do different institutional settings
affect countries co-operative versus competitive behaviours? How multilateral
do agreements need to be to achieve effective co-operative outcomes?
178. The analysis of BEPS and countermeasures has advanced since 2013, providing
more evidence of BEPS and insights into specific BEPS channels and potential effects of
BEPS countermeasures. As analysts can only observe the current world with BEPS, any
analysis of BEPS and countermeasures must estimate a comparison point, whether it be a
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
124 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
world without BEPS, a future world without co-ordinated multilateral action, or a future
world with proposed countermeasures. Future analysis of BEPS, MNEs BEPS
behaviours, and tax competition with improved estimation methodologies are needed to
complement improvements in the available data relevant for analysing BEPS and BEPS
countermeasures.
Bibliography
Acciari, P., F. Tomarelli, L. Limosani, and L. Benedetti (2015), Measurement of Base
Erosion and Profit Shifting Phenomena through the Analysis of FDI Stocks, Italian
Ministry of Economy and Finance Department of the Treasury Working Papers.
www.dt.mef.gov.it/export/sites/sitodt/modules/documenti_en/analisi_progammazione/
working_papers/WP_3.pdf
Akcigit, U., S. Baslandze, and S. Stantcheva (2015), Taxation and the International
Mobility of Inventors, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 21024.
African Economic Outlook (2010), Direct taxation in Africa, Public Resource
Mobilisation & Aid. www.africaneconomicoutlook.org/en/theme/public-resourcemobilisation-and-aid/the-state-of-public-resource-mobilisation-in-africa/directtaxation-in-africa/.
Armstrong, C. S., J. L. Blouin, A. D. Jagolinzer and D. F. Larcker (2015), Corporate
governance, incentives and tax avoidance, Journal of Accounting and Economics,
Vol. 60, Issue 1, pp. 1-17. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2015.02.003.
Australia (2014), Parliament of Australia: Inquiry into Tax Disputes,
www.aph.gov.au/Parliamentary_Business/Committees/House/Tax_and_Revenue/Inqu
iry_into_Tax_Disputes (accessed 19 December 2014).
Azmar, C. (2010), International corporate taxation and U.S. multinationals behaviour:
An integrated approach, Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 43, No. 1, pp. 232
253.
Bach, S. (2013), Has German business income taxation raised too little revenue over the
last decades? DIW Berlin.
Becker, J. and N. Riedel (2012), Cross-border tax effects on affiliate investment
Evidence from European multinationals, European Economic Review, Vol. 56, pp.
436450.
Beer, S. and J. Loeprick (2013), Profit shifting: Drivers and potential countermeasures,
WU International Taxation Research Paper Series, No. 2013-03, DOI:
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2271539.
Beuselinck, C., M. Deloof, and A. Vanstraelen (2014), Cross-jurisdictional income
shifting and tax enforcement: Evidence from public versus private multinationals,
Review of Accounting Studies, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 710-746.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 125
126 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
De Mooij, R. A. and S. Ederveen (2008), Corporate tax elasticities: a readers guide to
empirical findings, Working Paper 8/22, Oxford University Centre for Business
Taxation.
Desai, M.A., F. Foley and J.R. Hines (2004), A multinational perspective on capital
structure choice and internal capital markets, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 59, No. 6.
Devereux, M. and R. Griffith (1998), Taxes and the location of production: evidence
from a panel of US multinationals, Journal of Public Economics, 68(3), pp. 335-367.
Devereux, M., B. Lockwood and M. Redoano (2008), Do countries compete over
corporate tax rates? Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 92, pp. 121035.
Dharmapala, D. and N. Riedel (2013), Earnings shocks and tax-motivated incomeshifting: Evidence from European multinationals, Journal of Public Economics,
Elsevier, vol. 97(C), pp. 95-107.
Dharmapala, D. (2014), What do we know about base erosion and profit shifting? A
review of the empirical literature, Fiscal Studies, Vol. 35, pp. 421448.
Dharmapala, D. (2015), Base erosion and profit shifting: A simple conceptual
framework, CESifo DICE Report, Vol. 12, Issue 4, pp. 8-14.
Dischinger, M., B. Knoll and N. Riedel (2014), The role of headquarters in multinational
profit shifting strategies, International Tax Public Finance, Vol. 21, No. 2, pp. 248271. DOI: 10.1007/s10797-012-9265-5.
Dowd, T. P. Landesfeld and A. Moore (2015), Profit shifting of U.S. multinationals,
Joint Committee on Taxation working paper.
Dreler, D. and U. Scheuering (2012), Empirical evaluation of interest barrier effects,
ZEW Discussion Paper, No. 12-046.
Dyreng, S., J. L. Hoopes and J. H. Wilde, (2014), Public pressure and corporate tax
behaviour, Working Paper available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2474346 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2474346.
Dyreng, S. and K. Markle (2014), The effect of financial constraints on tax-motivated
income shifting by U.S. multinationals, Working paper, Duke University.
Egger, P., Eggert, W. and Winner, H. (2010), Saving taxes through foreign plant
ownership, Journal of International Economics, 81, S. 99-108.
Egger, P. et al. (2014), Corporate taxes and internal borrowing within multinational
firms, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 6 (2), 54-93.
Ernst and Young (2014), European attractiveness survey 2014 - Back in the game,
www.ey.com/GL/en/Issues/Business-environment/european-attractiveness-survey.
European Commission (2014), A study on R&D tax incentives, Working Paper No. 522014.
European Commission (2015), Patent boxes design, patents location and local R&D,
IPTS Working Papers on Corporate R&D and Innovation, No. 6/2015.
Fryt, M. D., A. Lyon, W. McBride, D. Shackelford and T. Treichel (2015), Session 3:
Evaluating the U.S. corporate income tax, The Tax Magazine, June 2015.
Fuest, C. (2015), Who bears the burden of corporate income taxation?, mimeo for the
European Tax Policy Forum, www.etpf.org/papers/PP001CorpTax.pdf.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 127
Fuest, C. and N. Riedel (2010), Tax evasion, tax avoidance and tax expenditures in
developing countries: A review of the literature, Report prepared for the U.K.
Department for International Development (DFID), Oxford University Centre for
Business Taxation.
Fuest, C., S. Hebous and N. Riedel (2011), International debt shifting and multinational
firms in developing economies, Economics Letters, pp. 135-138.
Fullerton, D. and G. E. Metcalf (2002), Tax incidence, Handbook of Public Economics,
A.J. Auerback and M. Feldstein (ed.), Elsevier, Edition 1, Vol. 4, Chapter 26, pp.
17871872.
Gravelle, J. C. (2010), Corporate tax incidence: Review of general equilibrium estimates
and analysis, Working Paper 2010-03, United States Congressional Budget Office,
pp. 30-33.
Genschel, P. and P. Schwarz (2011), Tax competition: A literature review, SocioEconomic Review, No. 9, pp. 339-370.
Griffith, R., H. Miller and M. OConnell (2011), Corporate taxes and the location of
intellectual property, CEPR Discussion Papers 8424.
Grubert H. (2003), Intangible income, intercompany transactions, income shifting, and
the choice of location, National Tax Journal, Vol. 56, No. 1, Part 2, pp. 221-242.
Grubert, H. (2012), Foreign taxes and the growing share of U.S. multinational company
income abroad: profits, not sales, are being globalized, National Tax Journal 65(2):
247-282.
Grubert, H. and J. Mutti (1991), Taxes, Tariffs and Transfer Pricing in Multinational
Corporate Decision Making, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 73, No. 2,
pp. 285-293.
Hanlon, M. and S. Heitzman (2010), A review of tax research, DOI:
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1476561.
Harberger, A. C. (1995), The ABCs of corporation tax incidence: Insights into the openeconomy case, Chapter 2, American Council for Capital Formation, Policy and
Economic Growth.
Harberger, A. C. (2006), Corporate tax incidence: reflections on what is known,
unknown and unknowable, www.econ.ucla.edu/harberger/ah-corptax4-06.pdf.
Hebous, S. and M. Ruf (2015), Evaluating the effects of ACE systems on multinational
debt financing and investment, CESIFO Working Paper No. 5360.
Heckemeyer, J. H. and M. Overesch (2013), Multinationals profit response to tax
differentials: Effect size and shifting channels, ZEW Discussion Paper No. 13-045.
Hines, J.R, and E.M. Rice (1994), Fiscal paradise: Foreign tax havens and American
business, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, MIT Press, 109(1), pp. 149-82.
Hoopes, J. (2015), Taxes and disclosure: A brief summary of the research.
Huizinga, H. and L. Laeven (2008), International profit shifting within multinationals: A
multi-country perspective, Journal of Public Economics, 88(6), pp. 1149-1168.
Huizinga, H., L. Laeven and G. Nicodme (2008), Capital structure and international
debt shifting, Journal of Financial Economics, 88, pp. 80118.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
128 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
IMF (2014), Spillovers in International Corporate Taxation, IMF Policy paper.
Karkinsky, T. and N. Riedel (2012), Corporate taxation and the choice of patent location
within multinational firms, Journal of International Economics, 88, 176-185.
Keen, M. and K. Konrad (2012), The theory of international tax competition and coordination, Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Public Finance, Working paper
No. 2012-06. DOI: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2111895.
Kleinbard, E. (2011), Stateless Income, Florida Tax Review, Vol. 11, No. 9. DOI:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1791769.
Liu, L. and R. Altshuler (2013), Measuring the burden of the corporate income tax under
imperfect competition, National Tax Journal, Vol. 66, No. 1, pp. 215-237.
Lohse, T., N. Riedel and C. Spengel (2012), The increasing importance of transfer
pricing regulations: A worldwide overview, Oxford Center for Business Taxation
Working Paper, No. 12/27.
Lohse, T. and N. Riedel (2012), The impact of transfer pricing regulations on profit
shifting within European multinationals, FZID Discussion Paper, No. 61-2012,
https://fzid.uni-hohenheim.de/71978.html.
Lohse, T. and N. Riedel (2013), Do transfer pricing laws limit international income
shifting? Evidence from European multinationals, Oxford University Centre for
Business Taxation Working Paper, No. 13/07.
Loretz, S. and S. Mokkas (2011), Evidence for profit shifting with tax sensitive capital
stocks, Working papers 1116, Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation.
McDonald, M. (2008), Income shifting from transfer pricing: Further evidence from tax
return data, United States Department of the Treasury, Office of Tax Analysis, OTA
Technical Working Paper 2.
Maffini, G. and S. Mokkas (2011), Profit shifting and measured productivity of
multinational firms, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 73, Issue 1,
pp. 120.
Markle, K.S. (2015), A comparison of the tax-motivated income shifting of
multinationals in territorial and worldwide countries,
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1764031.
Markle, K. S. and L. Robinson (2012), Tax haven use across international tax regimes.
Markle, K. S. and D. Shackelford (2012), Cross-country comparison of corporate
income tax, National Tax Journal 65:3, pp. 493-527.
Mieszkowski, P. and G.R. Zodrow (1986), The new view of the property tax: A
reformulation, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 16 (3), pp. 309327.
Mintz, J. M. and V. B. Venkatachalam (2015), The problem with the low-tax backlash:
Rethinking corporate tax policies to adjust for uneven reputational risks, University
of Calgary School of Public Policy Research Paper, Vol. 8, Issue 24.
Men, J., D. Schindler, G. Schjelderup and J. Tropina (2011), International debt shifting:
Do multinationals shift internal or external debt? CESIFO Working Paper, No. 3519.
Monkam, N. (2012), ATAF Regional studies on reform priorities of African tax
administrations: Africa-wide report, African Tax Administration Forum. DOI:
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 129
http://10.100.15.87:15871/cgi-bin/blockpage.cgi?wssession=18446744072250628799.
MSCI (2015), Re-examining the tax gap, www.msci.com/documents/10199/4043da8b4d49-4449-ac0e-28b09df3b220.
Mutti, J. and H. Grubert (2009), The effect of taxes on royalties and the migration of
intangible assets abroad, in M. Reinsdorf and M. Slaughter (ed.) International Trade
in Services and Intangibles in the Era of Globalization, University of Chicago Press.
Nicodme, G. (2008), Corporate income tax and economic distortions, CEB Working
Paper, No. 08-033.
OECD (2010), Tax policy reform and economic growth, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264091085-en.
OECD (2013), Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264202719-en.
OECD (2013), Supporting investment in knowledge capital, growth and innovation,
OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264193307-en.
OECD (2014), Part 1 of a report to G20 Development Working Group on the impact of
BEPS in low income countries, OECD, Paris, www.oecd.org/tax/part-1-of-report-tog20-dwg-on-the-impact-of-beps-in-low-income-countries.pdf.
Overesch and Wamser (2010), The effects of company taxation in EU accession
countries on German FDI, Economics of Transition 18, pp. 429-457.
Oxfam (2015), Africa: Rising for the few,
www.oxfam.org/sites/www.oxfam.org/files/world_economic_forum_wef.africa_rising
_for_the_few.pdf.
Randolph, W. C. (2006), International Burdens of the Corporate Income Tax,
Congressional Budget Office, Washington, D.C.
Riedel, N. (2015), Quantifying international tax avoidance: A review of academic
literature,
European
Tax
Policy
Forum
Policy
Paper
No.
2,
www.etpf.org/papers/PP002QuantAvoid.pdf.
Ruf, M. and A. J. Weichenrieder (2013), CFC legislation, passive assets and the impact
of the ECJs Cadbury-Schweppes decision, CESifo Working Paper, No. 4461.
Schwarz (2009), Tax-avoidance strategies of American multinationals: An empirical
analysis, Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 30, pp. 539549,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/mde.1471.
Scottmay, M., Amazon to stop funnelling European sales through low-tax haven, The
New York Times, 24 May 2015.
Sikes, S. and R. Verrecchia (2014), Externalities of corporate tax avoidance, University
of Pennsylvania working paper,
www.mccombs.utexas.edu/~/media/Files/MSB/Departments/Accounting/TARC/2014/
Sikes%20Verrecchia%20Paper.pdf.
Slemrod (2010), Location, (real) location, (tax) location: An essay on mobilitys place in
optimal taxation, National Tax Journal, Vol. 63 (4, Part 2), pp. 843-864.
130 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Slemrod and Wilson (2009), "Tax competition with parasitic tax havens," Journal of
Public Economics, Elsevier, Vol. 93(11-12), pp. 1261-1270.
UNCTAD (2015), FDI, tax and development, UNCTAD Investment and Enterprise
Division Working Paper.
UNCTAD (2015), World Investment Report 2015: Reforming international investment
governance, UN Reference: UNCTAD/WIR/2015.
United States Joint Committee on Taxation (2014), Technical explanation, estimated
revenue effects, distributional analysis, and macroeconomic analysis of the Tax
Reform Act of 2014: A discussion draft of the Chairman of the House Committee on
Ways and Means to reform the Internal Revenue Code, United States Government
Printing Office, Reference No. JCS-1-14.
Vant Riet, M. and A. Lejour, (2014), Ranking the stars: Network analysis of bilateral
tax treaties, CPB Discussion Paper, No. 290.
Vicard, Vincent (2015), Profit shifting through transfer pricing: Evidence from French
firm level trade data, Banque de France Working Paper No. 555,
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2614864.
Voget, J. (2015), The effect of taxes on foreign direct investment: A survey of the
empirical evidence, European Tax Policy Forum, Policy Paper No. 3,
www.etpf.org/papers/PP003FDI.pdf.
Weichenrieder, A.J. (2009), Profit shifting in the EU: Evidence from Germany,
International Tax Public Finance, Vol. 16, pp. 281297,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-008-9068-x.
Weichenrieder, A.J. (2015), Does exchange of information between tax authorities
influence multinationals' use of tax havens?, ZEW Discussion Paper, No. 15-015.
Weichenrieder, A.J. and H. Windischbauer (2008), Thin-capitalization rules and
company responses: Experience from German legislation, CESifo Working Paper,
No. 2456.
World Bank, (2002), Foreign direct investment survey, Washington, DC: World Bank.
http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2002/01/2524561/foreign-directinvestment-survey.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 131
Notes
1.
2.
Several of the studies referred to later in the chapter describe the effects of some
existing BEPS counter-measures, including interest limitations. Several countries
reported in the survey by the OECD CFA Working Party No.2 revenue from interest
limitations ranging from 3-9% of corporate income tax revenues.
3.
Kleinbard (2011).
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
A number of tax returns are not included in the analysis because the compilation of
the database did not distinguish between zeros and not reported. Thus, some cash
boxes with no employees or tangible assets could have been excluded from the
analysis due to missing data.
9.
10.
The FDI weighted standard deviation presented has the FDI weights changing each
year as FDI changes. Using the 2003-2013 average FDI positions as a constant weight
for all years shows the same trend.
11.
FDI includes both real economic activity and BEPS, so is not an ideal measure, but
information about special purpose entities and other conduit financing and the
ultimate destination of some FDI is not available.
12.
Monkam, N. (2012).
13.
14.
Different methodologies, variable used and data sources can explain different
estimates. Some microdata profit shifting studies explain a very small amount of the
variation in profitability across affiliates.
15.
Riedel (2015).
16.
UNCTAD (2015).
17.
UNCTAD (2015), World Investment Report (pp. 201): The profit shifting and tax
revenue losses estimated here are mostly confined to those associated with tax
avoidance schemes that exploit a direct investment relationship through equity or
debt. Trade mispricing does not require a direct investment link: MNEs can shift
profits between any two affiliates based in jurisdictions with different tax rates.
132 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
18.
Tax rate differentials are both positive and negative so BEPS involves some
redistribution of revenue across countries. Because BEPS involves shifting of profits
from entities subject to marginal tax rates higher than to the entities receiving the
shifted income, profit shifting is not a zero-sum game: it involves significant global
revenue losses. Individual country estimates are not done due to data limitations and
the complexity of individual countries tax rules.
19.
Averages are weighted by share of corporate tax collections after tax credits in 20052010 among the countries included in the analysis. For the final profit shifting fiscal
estimate, actual corporate tax collections after tax credits are adjusted upward by 23%
to more accurately reflect the taxable income base affected by profit shifting, based
on a CFA/WP2 survey of corporate tax credits, principally at 2011 levels.
20.
A sensitivity test shows the effect of an alternative tax rate differential and weighting
factor. The tax rate differential calculated for the MNE entities in the ORBIS database
could be changed to the tax rate differential between countries weighted by their
macro-level goods export trade. Bilateral trade in goods exports is an important area
of transfer mispricing, although comparable data for related party exports are not
available for many countries. Services including royalties have larger tax rate
differentials, but service export data are not comprehensive. A second adjustment
could weight country tax rate differentials by corporate taxes before credits, rather
than corporate taxes after credits. Those two adjustments result in the global corporate
tax revenue loss ranging from 6% to 14% of CIT. Leaving the revenue loss from
mismatches and tax preferences aside, the two changes produce an estimate of
corporate revenue loss just from profit shifting in the same range as the base case.
21.
The analysis in Annex 3.A1 tested the sensitivity of the profit shifting tax
responsiveness for country fixed effects. The regression coefficient was one-third
lower than the baseline estimate. Country fixed effects are used to hold non-tax
factors constant across counties, but the estimates of the tax relationship is then based
only on variation in tax rates within countries over time, since between country
variation in tax rates are captured by the country fixed effects. When using the profit
shifting estimate with country fixed effects, the global corporate tax revenue loss
ranges from 3% to 8% of CIT. Country fixed effects are already used in the
mismatches and tax preferences regression estimate.
22.
The 95% confidence interval is roughly two standard deviations from the mean. The
profit shifting estimates standard error is 0.0164 and the ETR differential estimates
standard error is 0.0026.
23.
24.
UNCTAD, World Investment Report (2015), pp. 201-204 and Annex II pp. 24-26.
25.
26.
27.
MSCI (2015).
28.
29.
Oxfam (2015).
30.
Bach (2013).
31.
Clausing (2011).
32.
Vicard (2015).
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 133
33.
Annex 3.A1.
34.
Scottmay (2015).
35.
36.
Cederwall (2015).
37.
Slemrod (2010).
38.
39.
See Clausing (2012), Gravelle (2010), Harberger (1995) and Harberger (2006).
40.
The standard corporate income tax incidence analysis is based on the Harberger
Model of the incidence of changes in a general corporate income tax. For a fairly
easy-to-follow explanation of the model, see Harberger (1995). In this article,
Harberger explains how his original closed-economy model has to be modified to
analyse CIT incidence in the international setting. Randolph (2006) provides a more
detailed analysis of the expected incidence of the general corporate income tax.
41.
It has been noted that the incidence effects outlined in this section are similar in
nature to the new view of the incidence of a property in open-border local
economies. See Mieszkowski and Zodrow (1986). In this view, property owners bear
the burden of an average tax rate across jurisdictions with above and below-average
tax rates creating excise tax effects in different jurisdictions that shift the remaining
portion of the burden to households. See Gravelle (2010).
42.
This result under perfect competition is fundamentally the same result that would be
expected from an increase in the CIT in a closed-border economy, except that the
reallocations of capital occur between the corporate and non-corporate sectors only,
not across borders. Harberger (2006) made this point, noting: if all countries (or a
set of big countries making up most of the world economy) choose to move their CIT
rates in more-or-less parallel fashion, then the appropriate [incidence] model is one of
a closed economy. (p.7).
43.
44.
Cronin et al. (2012) estimate that 63% of the total returns to capital is excess profits,
while only 37% is a normal return.
45.
Clausing (2012) discusses how the presence of economic rents would increase the
burden of CIT on owners of capital. She also notes empirical studies of the incidence
of the CIT in the international setting are tainted by the presence of BEPS as MNEs
can reduce effective tax rates through the shifting of profits unrelated to changes in
the international allocation of capital. In this case, there may be a minimal tax burden
on capital to be shifted. Voget (2015) cites some empirical studies that could imply
that some of the multinationals rents are location specific and relatively immobile.
46.
Devereux and Griffith (1998) note that MNEs facing discrete investment choices with
finite capital will choose location decisions based on the average effective tax rate,
rather than the marginal effective tax rate on investment. This incidence analysis
assumes companies have access to capital when earning excess returns, and thus
would still be earning more than the next-best alternative investment.
47.
The estimated range includes two effects: 1) a range of -2.5% to -5.0% around the
estimated average -3.25% lower effective tax rates due to mismatches between tax
systems and domestic tax preferences, and 2) a range of -1.5% to -3.5%% due to
profit shifting of all MNEs. The latter estimate multiples the estimated -2.8% to -7.5%
134 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
reduction in global CIT revenue from profit shifting alone times the estimated 59% of
MNEs share of profits divided by the average weighted effective tax rate of 30% in
the countries included in the analysis.
48.
Several studies do not report finding statistical differences, although the studies differ
in the companies analysed and have different methodologies. See Markle and
Shackelford (2012), Dyreng and Markle (2014) and UNCTAD (2015). The Annex 1
estimate finds a statistically significant difference between large MNEs and similarly
situated domestic-only large affiliates. It does not find a statistically-significant
difference between large MNEs, small MNEs and small domestic-only affiliates.
49.
50.
Akcigit et al. (2015) analyse the international mobility of inventors and personal
income taxation, and report inventors who are employed by MNEs are more likely to
take advantage of personal income tax differentials.
51.
It is possible that company officials place less importance on national taxes currently
due to the availability of BEPS.
52.
53.
Hanlon and Heitzman (2010) discusses how many tax planning activities reduce both
financial reported profits and taxable income (conforming planning), and thus do
not affected measured ETRs. Only non-conforming planning where taxable income
or taxes are reduced but reported profits are not results in lower ETRs. For instance,
increased interest deductions reduce both reported profits and taxable income, while
exempt dividends do not affect reported profits, but reduce taxable income.
54.
55.
See Genschel and Schwarz (2011) and Keen and Konrad (2014).
56.
De Mooij (2011).
57.
58.
The tax accounting literature has begun work in this area but limited by available
financial statement information. For example, see Armstrong et al. (2015).
59.
60.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 135
Annex 3.A1
Economic implications of multinational tax planning
Box 3.A1.1. Summary of main findings
This annex provides robust evidence of tax planning by multinational enterprises (MNEs). The
analysis is based on a sample of data that are considered to be the best available cross-country
firm-level information. Yet, the data have significant limitations in their representativeness in
some countries, do not include all MNE entities and are based upon financial accounts rather
than tax returns.
The focus of this annex is broader than the OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS)
Project.1 The BEPS Project focuses on instances where the interaction of different tax rules
leads to double non-taxation or less than single taxation and it also relates to arrangements that
achieve no or low taxation by shifting profits away from the jurisdictions where the activities
creating those profits take place. The analysis contained in this study assesses the fiscal and
economic implications of international differences in statutory and effective corporate tax rates
and as such it also covers domestic tax incentives.
Tax planning is widespread among MNEs and entails tax revenue losses.
Robust empirical evidence shows that MNEs engage in international tax
planning. MNEs shift profit from higher to lower-tax rate countries. Large MNEs also
exploit mismatches between tax systems (e.g. differences in the tax treatment of
certain entities, instruments or transactions) and preferential tax treatment for certain
activities or incomes to reduce their tax burden.
Transfer price manipulation, strategic allocation of intangible assets and
manipulation of internal and external debt levels are important profit shifting
channels.
The empirical patent analysis suggests that preferential tax treatment of
intellectual property (IP) influences the location of intangible assets. Preferential
IP regimes attract research activities and the ownership of patents invented in other
countries. Preferential regimes may also encourage the relabeling of certain incomes to
benefit from the regime.
Tax planning reduces the effective tax rate of large MNEs by 4-8 percentage
points on average. The reduction is even greater for very large firms and firms
intensive in the use of intangible assets. Small MNEs also engage in tax planning but
to a lesser extent.
The net tax revenue loss from tax planning is estimated at 4-10% of global
corporate tax revenues. These estimates based on 2000-10 data are surrounded by
uncertainty and should be interpreted with caution.
136 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Box 3.A1.1. Summary of main findings (continued)
Strict anti-avoidance rules reduce tax planning. Strict anti-avoidance rules, such as
transfer pricing, interest deductibility, GAARs and CFCs rules, are found to reduce
profit shifting. However, complex rules generate compliance costs for all firms,
hampering profitability, as well as administrative and enforcement costs for tax
authorities. These costs could be reduced by international co-ordination.
Tax planning effects on economic efficiency are unclear.
Tax planning may allow certain MNEs to increase their market power, resulting in
more concentrated markets. The reduced competitive pressure may entail welfare losses.
However, these losses may be partially offset by the associated reallocation of resources
to high-productivity MNEs.
The possibility to manipulate the location of internal and external debt lowers the
cost of debt for MNE groups and can compound the debt-bias present in most
tax systems. Even so, domestic firms have on average higher external leverage than
MNE groups. Information on internal debt is not available.
International tax planning reduces effective tax rates and the effect of crosscountry corporate tax differences on the location of investment by tax planning
MNEs. However, this is achieved at the cost of additional distortions (e.g. uneven
playing field between tax-planning MNEs and other firms) as compared with a situation
in which corporate tax rates were cut across the board.
Introduction
The design of corporate tax systems influences the behaviour of multinational enterprises
(MNEs). International differences in taxation can lead MNEs to locate a larger share of
their economic activity in lower-tax countries. In addition, it can lead to international tax
planning by MNEs to reduce their tax burden. MNEs may locate profits in lower-tax
countries, independently of where the profit-generating activity takes place, for example
by manipulating the price of intra-group transactions or the location of external and
related-party debt. They may also exploit differences in the tax treatment of certain
entities or instruments (henceforth called mismatches between tax systems) or
preferential tax treatment for certain activities or incomes to reduce their tax burden. In
some cases, MNEs may also defer repatriation of profits from abroad indefinitely to avoid
taxes. This raises a number of fiscal, redistributive and economic efficiency concerns,
which are discussed in this study (see Figure 3.A1.1 for an overview).
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 137
This annex provides an estimate of tax planning based on financial account data from the
largest commercially-available firm-level database (ORBIS).2 The study estimates the
relationship between tax rate differentials and profit shifting using financial account data.
It is well known that the legal accounting standards for firms differ between public
financial accounting and confidential tax accounting (e.g. Lisowsky, 2010) and improved
access to data, especially tax return data, would enable refined estimates of the effects of
tax planning. In the absence of such data, this study relies on the best cross-country firmlevel financial account data currently available.
The study looks at both fiscal and efficiency issues related to tax planning behaviour by
MNEs. Tax planning affects the distribution of tax bases and revenues among countries,
thereby entailing fiscal considerations. By reducing the effective corporate tax rate of
certain MNEs relatively to other MNEs and domestic firms, tax planning may also distort
competition and lead to efficiency losses (e.g. if domestic firms are hindered from
growing). Tax planning opportunities may also be one factor altering firms financing
decisions by reinforcing the debt bias present in most countries tax system at the expense
of equity financing, with potential effects on firms investment choices and bankruptcy
risks at the MNE group level.
The location of MNE investments in tangible and intangible assets depends, among other
factors (e.g. labour taxation, regulations, access to market, agglomeration effects, labour
force skills, quality of infrastructure, etc.), on corporate taxation. All else equal, countries
with lower tax rates or preferential tax regimes for certain investments attract more
foreign investment including R&D investments than higher-tax countries. These
investments can create technological spillovers, with positive effects for productivity and
growth (and in turn reduce such positive spillovers in higher-tax countries) (e.g.
Blomstrm and Kokko, 1998; Markusen and Venables, 1999). They can also influence
trade patterns (Dahlby, 2011).
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
138 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Globalisation and the ongoing integration of world capital markets may further increase
the mobility of corporate tax bases and the sensitivity of investment to international tax
differences (Braconier et al., 2014). This may intensify tax competition. Indeed,
evidence suggests that an increasing mobility of capital is associated with lower statutory
corporate tax rates (Devereux et al., 2008; OECD, 2009; Arnold et al., 2011; IMF, 2014),
which is consistent with the reduction in corporate tax rates that occurred over the past
decades (Figure 3.A1.3, Panel A). Even so, corporate tax revenues of OECD countries
have remained fairly stable on average as a share of GDP, suggesting that in many
countries a broadening of the base has accompanied the cuts in the rate (Figure 3.A1.2,
Panel B). In some countries, the corporate tax base was supported by an increase in the
profit rate and also possibly by substitution effects between personal and corporate
income tax.
Figure 3.A1.2 Corporate tax rates and tax revenues
Panel A: Statutory corporate tax rate, %3
2014
2000
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
5
4.5
4
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 139
140 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
statutory tax rates. MNEs may also be able to reduce their tax burden via preferential
tax treatment and negotiated firm-specific reduced tax rates.
Hybrid instruments and transfers: Instruments which are treated differently
in two countries, for example as debt in one country and as equity in another
country. This can result in an interest deduction in the first country and nontaxable income in the second country (as the income is treated as a tax-exempt
dividend).
Hybrid entities: The same entity can be treated differently in two countries for
tax purpose. For instance, an entity may be considered as tax resident by no
country (so called stateless entities) and in this way achieve double nontaxation of profit. Alternatively, an entity can be treated as a non-taxable entity
such as a partnership (where the partners are taxed instead of the entity itself) in
one country and a taxable entity in another. This can result in a deduction in the
first country and non-inclusion of the income in the second country.
Preferential tax treatment: MNEs may shift certain incomes to benefit from
special tax treatment offered by some countries (or areas within them), such as
for intellectual property (e.g. patent boxes) or financial services. Domestic firms
can also benefit from preferential tax treatment, but to a lesser extent than
MNEs since they cannot shift incomes across borders to enjoy these treatments
on a larger scale.6
Negotiated tax rates: Firm-specific reduced tax rates for individual MNEs
through negotiation between the MNE and the tax authority.
Tax planning schemes are often complex and can involve several of these channels in
combination. To take this complexity into account, this study relies on a systematic topdown approach. It first focuses on where profits of MNEs are reported (profit shifting),
and second it assesses the effective taxation of reported profits in each country
(mismatches between tax systems, including preferential tax regimes). This ensures
consistency and that there is no double-counting between the two. The exploitation of
preferential tax regimes and negotiated tax rates are included in the mismatches analysis
since they cannot be disentangled from them with the available data.
The approach also takes into account potential interactions between profit shifting and
mismatches between tax systems. For instance, if profits are shifted to a country to enjoy
a preferential tax treatment, the ETR differential resulting from this treatment is applied
to the complete tax base (i.e. including the shifted profits) when assessing the fiscal
implications of tax planning.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 141
142 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Box 3.A1.2. Disclaimer on the data used in the empirical analysis (continued)
Distribution of firms in the sample, by firm type9,10,11
Panel A: As a share of total number of firms (only firms with more than 250 employees)
%
100
MNEs
Domestics groups
Standalone firms
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
MNEs
Domestics groups
Standalone firms
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 143
Box 3.A1.2. Disclaimer on the data used in the empirical analysis (continued)
Quality of the sample and of the MNE group identification
The coverage of firms with available financial account data varies across countries. Compared
with the actual population of firms (when data on the actual population is available), the
coverage is above 50% in most European countries and less than 10% in most non-European
countries. However, it is limited in some countries, including the United States, New Zealand
and Chile (see Figure below). The distribution of observations across industries is somewhat
higher in manufacturing than in services.
Representativeness of the final sample
Number of firms in the final ORBIS sample, as a share of the total in STAN business demography
statistics, 200612
Panel A: by country
Percent
100
All firms
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Note: The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli
authorities. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East
Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
144 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Panel B: by industry
Percent
All firms
60
50
40
30
20
Finance and
insurance
Transport and
communications
Hotels and
restaurants
Wholesale and
retail trade
Construction
Utilities
Manufacturing
(other)
Motor vehicles
Electrical and
optical equipment
Machinery and
other equipment
Metallic products
Other non-metallic
mineral products
Petroleum
products
Wood
Leather
Textiles
Mining
10
Source: OECD calculations based on the ORBIS database and OECD STAN business demography
statistics.
For an average MNE group, more than 50% of the worldwide activity is covered, which is a
higher share that in other recent studies (e.g. Huizinga and Laeven, 2008). An issue is the lack of
financial data in certain no-corporate-tax countries. This is mitigated by the methodological
approach, which only relies on links to these countries being identified, not on the availability of
financial accounts in these countries. Still not all links are identified in ORBIS. It is difficult to
assess the magnitude and importance of the missing links due to general lack of data on actual
links. Nevertheless, an important number of links to no-corporate tax countries is identified (see
Figure below). For example, among the top-500 United States firms (Fortune 500 list for 2013),
Citizens for Tax Justice (CTJ, 2014) identify 362 firms having links to tax havens. Of these
362 firms, 266 (i.e. 72%) are in the ORBIS sample. Among these 266 firms, at least one tax
haven link is identified in ORBIS in 184 cases, i.e. 69% of the times (this represents just over
half of top United States firms with tax haven links).
Given that financial reporting requirements are usually stricter for large firms, the coverage of
the data is generally better for these firms. This would suggest that the coverage of MNE entities
is better than average as they are generally large entities, although entities in large MNE groups
can be small. It is possible that MNEs heavily involved in tax planning or using complex
schemes (e.g. stateless entities for tax purposes) opt not to disclose their financial accounts to
business registers if the repercussion of not complying with reporting is limited. This may result
in under-sampling of such firms, which may bias the results when there are non-random
reasons for information to be missing (e.g. accounts in low-tax jurisdictions are less likely to be
included in the dataset) (Cobham and Loretz, 2014). This issue is addressed in the sensitivity
analysis.
Finally, the current OECD-ORBIS database includes data up to 2010 and the analysis is based
on the 2000-10 period. Since then, tax planning behaviours may have changed reflecting factors
such as the growing importance of the digital economy and changes in anti-avoidance rules
against tax planning and in global value chains. In addition, corporate tax rates have been cut in
some countries.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 145
Box 3.A1.2. Disclaimer on the data used in the empirical analysis (continued)
Identified links to no-corporate-tax countries of entities in the sample
Share of large MNE entities in the sample having links to countries not taxing corporate
income13,14
Panel A: by country of headquarters
As a share of total number of large MNE entities, %
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Panel B: by industry
As a share of total number of large MNEs entities, %
60
50
40
30
20
Finance and
insurance
Transport and
communications
Hotels and
restaurants
Construction
Wholesale and
retail trade
Utilities
Manufacturing
(other)
Motor vehicles
Electrical and
optical equipment
Machinery and
other equipment
Metallic products
Other non-metallic
mineral products
Petroleum products
and chemicals
Wood
Leather
Textiles
Mining
10
146 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Profit shifting
The empirical strategy to identify profit shifting is to compare the profitability (measured
as the ratio of pre-tax profit to total assets or employment) of MNE entities with similar
characteristics (e.g. size, industry, etc.), but different opportunities to shift profits (see
Box 3.A1.3 for details and Figure 3.A1.3, Panel A). These opportunities depend on the
location of the other entities in the corporate group. Entities with links to lower-tax rate
countries have opportunities to shift profits abroad, while entities with links to higher-tax
rate countries may receive profits from abroad. In this study, the profit shifting
opportunity of a MNE entity is measured by the difference between the statutory
corporate tax rate in the country of this entity and the average (unweighted) statutory tax
rate in the countries where its corporate group operates.15,16,17 Links to countries outside
the sample, including no-corporate-tax countries, are taken into account even in cases of
missing financial information of the particular entity.
The estimated profit shifting elasticity implies that a one percentage point (or about 3%)
higher statutory corporate tax rate than the average in the corporate group is associated
with a reduction in reported profits of about 1% (Figure 3.A1.3, Panel B). This sensitivity
is slightly higher than the estimate of a 0.8% reduction in corporate profits based on a
meta-analysis of existing firm-level studies (Heckemeyer and Overesch, 2013). The two
different measures of profitability (pre-tax profits to total assets or employment) yield
similar results.
In addition, results are robust to a number of variants: (i) using different fixed-effects
structures (e.g. country and country-interacted-with-time fixed-effects); (ii) restricting the
sample to EU countries; (iii) restricting the sample to manufacturing firms; (iv) restricting
the sample to sub-periods; (v) re-sampling observations to adjust for the relatively low
representation of certain countries in the analysis; (vi) dropping all entities having at least
one subsidiary, i.e. keeping the lowest tier in the corporate structure, (to avoid any
potential bias involving dividends paid by subsidiaries); (vii) using forward-looking
effective tax rates instead of statutory rates; (viii) excluding from the tax variable links to
countries with below-average score on rule of law or regulatory quality indicators;
(ix) using a 90% ownership threshold (instead of 50%) in the identification of corporate
groups.18 Robustness of the results to extrapolation beyond the sample is an issue that is
addressed via sensitivity analysis (see below).
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 147
Box 3.A1.3. Empirical approach: Assessing tax planning based on firm-level data
The strategy to assess profit shifting is to compare the profitability of MNE entities with similar
characteristics except for their links to countries with different tax rates. The hypothesis is that
MNEs with links to lower-tax rate countries would report relatively low profits in entities
located in higher-tax countries compared with similar firms that have no such links. In practice,
the estimated equation is as follows:
,
where
is the profitability (the ratio of reported pre-tax profits to total assets
or employment) of firm f (operating in MNE group g, country c and industry i) in year t.
is a vector of determinants of true profitability, which includes both firm-specific characteristics
(size, position in the group, presence of patents in the group) and macroeconomic variables
(GDP growth, exchange rate, inflation, GDP per capita).
is
the difference between the statutory tax rate in country c and year t and the unweighted average
of the statutory tax rates in the countries where the multinational group g operates. Statutory
rates are national averages (i.e. they do not reflect regional differences in rates) and do not take
into account tax holidays. The tax sensitivity of profits is measured by the coefficient , which is
expected to be negative if profits are shifted to lower-tax rate countries. , are respectively
time and industry fixed-effects to control for unobserved (non-tax) factors affecting
profitability.*
Excluding country fixed-effects in the baseline estimation may bias the estimated tax sensitivity
(upwards or downwards) since some unobserved country-specific factors may be captured by the
tax sensitivity. However, such fixed-effects may also capture some profit shifting, which would
result in underestimating profit shifting (Clausing, 2009; Buettner and Wamser, 2013). The
results are qualitatively robust to including both country and country-interacted-with-time fixedeffects, although the tax sensitivity would be reduced by about 30%.
The strategy to assess (jointly) mismatches between tax systems and preferential tax treatment is
to compare the effective tax rate (ETR) of a multinational entity in a given country to the ETR of
a domestic (i.e. non-MNE) entity with similar characteristics. The ETR considered is the ratio of
tax expenses over the profit reported in the financial statements of the firm, at an unconsolidated
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
148 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
level (i.e. for each entity in the group). One caveat is that tax expenses reported in financial
accounts are likely to differ from tax liabilities in tax data, for example due to differences in the
inclusion of deferred tax expenses, other book/tax differences and differences in the tax
residence of the affiliate.
The hypothesis is that if a multinational entity exploits mismatches to reduce its tax burden, it
may report a high profit in its financial statements, but its taxable profit (and thus its tax burden)
would be lower, for example because of the use of a hybrid instrument or entity. A hybrid
instrument can result in an interest deduction in one country as it is treated as debt in this country
and a non-taxable income in another country where it is treated as equity. As compared to a
standard debt instrument, this would lead to a lower ETR (as measured with financial account
data) in the receiving country. However, there would be no visible difference in financial
accounts as compared to a standard equity instrument. The use of a hybrid entity will generally
result in a lower ETR, as it can allow a MNE entity to report profits in a higher-tax rate country
while paying the tax rate of a lower-rate (or no-tax) country. Another example is a dual resident
entity which may claim more than one tax deduction for the same interest expense, thereby
reducing its ETR. The effective tax rate of MNE entities can also be reduced by the exploitation
of preferential tax treatment for certain activities or incomes (e.g. shifting patents to a patent-box
country), to the extent that they benefit more than domestic firms, or because of negotiated tax
rates. One caveat is that unobserved and inherent differences between MNE and domestic
entities that are not related to tax planning (e.g. capital intensity) may also influence their
relative ETRs.
Exploiting mismatches between tax systems may involve complex schemes with important fixed
costs, suggesting that only large MNEs may engage in it. To account for this, the empirical
approach is to compare the effective tax rate of multinational and domestic entities among
different size classes. The estimated equation is as follows:
,
where
is the effective tax rate of firm f (operating in country c and industry i) in year t,
measured as tax expenses over reported profit.
and
are
respectively dummies for large (over 250 employees, in line with the EU definition) and small
entities.
is a dummy equal to one when a company is part of a multinational group.
is a vector of firm-specific controls (position in the group, presence of patents,
profitability). The coefficients
and
measure the ETR differential between small
(respectively large) MNEs and comparable domestic firms. The hypothesis is that these
coefficients should be negative if MNEs exploit mismatches between tax systems and
preferential tax treatment to reduce their tax burden. and
are dummies for industry and for
country-interacted-with-time, which capture the effect of countries having different (and timevarying) tax rates.
________________________________________
*
Estimating profitability of individual affiliates is very difficult with available data, as reflected
in only 1.5% of the variance across affiliates being actually explained. This is common among
cross-sectional firm-level studies with many observations (see for example Beer and Loeprick,
2014). It reflects the intrinsic volatility of the profit rate, which is largely driven by (unobserved)
firm-specific factors. If profitability is not captured by the non-tax variables, the estimated tax
responsiveness could be affected.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 149
150 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Figure 3.A1.4 Trends in international tax planning, 2000-2010
Panel A: Profit shifting
Point estimate: profit shifting
Profit shifting elasticity (impact on profit of a one percentage point tax rate differential)
3%
2%
1%
0%
-1%
-2%
-3%
-4%
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
Note: Panel A shows that in 2000 a one percentage point higher statutory corporate tax rate than the average
in the corporate group is associated with a reduction in reported profits of about 1.9%. Panel B shows that in
2000 the ETR of large MNE entities is on average close to 4 percentage points lower than that of comparable
large domestic groups. The year estimates are obtained by interacting the tax planning sensitivities described
in Box 3.A1.3 with a year dummy.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 151
45%
40%
35%
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
United States
Japan
Germany
France
United
Kingdom
Netherlands Switzerland
Korea
Canada
Italy
Other
countries
Note: The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The
use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli
settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
* Peoples Republic of China.
Source: PATSTAT Database.
152 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
An increasing number of countries have preferential tax treatment of the income from
intellectual activities (so-called patent boxes or IP-boxes) (see Table 3.A1.1). In
some countries, but not all, the preferential tax treatment is conditional on activity
requirements and does not apply to acquired intellectual property unless it is further
developed in the buying country (Evers et al. 2013; PWC, 2013).23
Table 3.A1.1 Tax treatment of intellectual property in selected OECD and G20 countries,
201424
Country
Acquired intellectual
Year of
property
introduction
Belgium
34
6.8
Yes, if further
developed
2007
China1
33
0-12.5
na
2008
France
34.4
15.5
2001
Hungary
19
9.5
Yes
2003
Luxembourg
29.2
5.84
Yes
2008
Netherlands
25
Yes, if further
developed
2007
2014
2008
Portugal
Spain2
Sw itzerland
(Niedw alden)
31.5
30
50% of
gross
income
exempted
60% of
patent
income
exempted
21.1
8.8
Yes
2011
Turkey (Technology
development zones)
20
20
No
2001
United Kingdom
21
10
Yes, if further
developed
2013
Notes:
1. Peoples Republic of China.
2. The corporate rate is reduced to 28% in 2015 and 25% in 2016 and onwards.
Source: Evers et al. (2013) and PWC (2013).
The empirical strategy to assess the tax sensitivity of the location of patents is to compare
patent applications of MNE entities with similar characteristics except for their links to
countries with different tax rates (Box 3.A1.4).25 The hypothesis is that MNEs with links
to countries with a lower effective tax rate on patent income (statutory rate or reduced
rate for patents) would apply for fewer patents in entities located in higher-tax countries
as compared to similar firms that have no such links. Similarly to the profit shifting
analysis, taxes are measured by the difference between the corporate tax rate or the
preferential tax rate on intellectual property income in the country of an entity and the
average (unweighted) tax rate in the countries where the group operates. The analysis
considers the impact of taxes on both shifted and non-shifted patents. Non-shifted patents
are used as a proxy for R&D activities.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 153
The empirical analysis suggests that preferential tax treatment attracts both patents
invented in other countries and R&D activities. For instance, a 5 percentage point cut in
the preferential tax rate on patent income is associated with an increase of 17% in the
number of shifted patents, which represents a 2% increase in the total (shifted and nonshifted) number of patents. The same tax rate cut is also associated with an increase of
5% in the number of non-shifted patents, corresponding to a 4% increase in the total
number of patents (Figure 3.A1.6). The relative importance of these two effects is likely
to vary with the design of the preferential tax treatment, such as activity requirements.
Figure 3.A1.6 The effect of preferential tax treatment on the number of patent applications
Change in patent applications induced by a 5 percentage point cut in the preferential tax rate on patent income
Percent
20
18
16
14
12
10
8
% of
shifted
patents
% of total
number of
patents
4
2
0
% of nonshifted
patents
% of total
number of
patents
1. Shifted (non-shifted) patents are patents where the inventor is located in a different (the same) country
than the MNE entity applying for the patent protection. A 5 percentage point cut in the preferential tax
rate on patent income is associated with an increase of 17% in the number of shifted patents, which
corresponds to 2% of all (shifted and non-shifted) patents. The effect is evaluated for an average country
where the share of shifted patents is 11% (weighted average of available countries).
154 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
where
world of firm
is the number of patent applications to the three main patent offices in the
(belonging to group g operating in country
and industry ) in year .
is the difference
between the effective tax rate on patent income in the home country and the average effective
tax rate on patent income in the group. The effective tax rate on patent income is the patent-box
tax rate if a patent box exists; otherwise it is the statutory tax rate.
are
vectors of control variables, including: the entitys lagged depreciated stock of patent
applications, the concentration of researchers and statutory corporate tax rates (both defined in
differential terms relatively to the MNE group average, in the same way as the tax variable),
entity size dummies, headquarter dummy, parent dummy, MNE group size, R&D subsidies at
home and on average in the countries where the group operates.
and
are industry,
country and time fixed-effects. In a second step, the effect of preferential tax treatment is
separated from the effect of statutory corporate tax rates by interacting the effective tax rate with
a dummy variable identifying whether the country has a patent box or not. The model is
estimated successively for all, shifted and non-shifted patents.
The patent data is sourced from the OECD PATSTAT data matched with ORBIS data for firm
characteristics. The sample consists of entities in 25 countries covering the years 2004-10. The
equation is estimated using a negative binomial model, which is a non-linear model suited for
high-variance count data, such as patent numbers.
Consistent with this, the profit shifting analysis confirms that profit shifting is
significantly stronger the tax sensitivity is about twice as large among MNE groups
with patents than for non-patenting MNE groups. Moreover, all else equal, patenting
firms are found to have a lower ETR than non-patenting firms, which reflects the
existence of preferential treatment for intellectual property and R&D tax credits in some
countries. This difference is larger for MNEs than for domestic firms, suggesting that
MNEs benefit more from these tax incentives by shifting patents and R&D investments to
countries with preferential treatment for patent income and R&D investments.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 155
An in-depth analysis of MNEs allocation of external debt (i.e. third-party debt to credit
institutions), relying on a similar approach as the profit shifting analysis, confirms that
MNEs tend to locate external debt in higher-tax rate countries (see Box 3.A1.5).
Specifically, the estimated debt-manipulation elasticity implies that a one percentage
point higher statutory corporate tax rate of an entity than the average in the MNE group is
associated with a 1.3% higher external debt for this entity. For the average entity, this
would translate into a reduction in profit by about 0.2% (as compared to an overall
reduction of 1% for profit shifting as a whole), accounting for 20% of overall estimated
profit shifting. This is a lower-bound estimate, as the analysis only focuses on third-party
debt and does not include the location of intra-group debt, which has been shown to be a
significant tax planning channel (Buettner et al., 2012). In the financial account data used
in this study, intra-group debt cannot be isolated.
Box 3.A1.5. Empirical approach: Manipulation of the location of external debt
The strategy to assess manipulation of the location of debt draws on Huizinga et al. (2008) and is
similar to the profit shifting analysis. The idea is that the observed debt of an entity is the sum of
a true and a manipulated debt. Manipulated debt would generally be positive in higher-tax rate
countries and negative in lower-tax rate countries. The strategy is to compare the leverage of
MNE entities with different opportunities to manipulate (i.e. shift or receive) debt, controlling
for other characteristics influencing true debt. Manipulation opportunities are assessed based
on the location of the other firms in the group and the statutory tax rate in these locations. A
lower tax rate than the group average is assumed to be associated with shifting of debt to highertax rate countries, while a higher tax rate would be associated with receiving debt. Reflecting
this strategy, the baseline equation is:
where
part of MNE group g and operates in country c and industry i, in year t. Debt refers to debt owed
to financial institutions, as reported in an entitys financial accounts sourced from the ORBIS
database. Importantly, it does not include intra-group debt, reflecting data limitations.
is the difference between the statutory tax rate in country
c and the unweighted average of the statutory tax rates in the countries where the multinational
group of f operates. A positive
would indicate that debt is located in higher-tax countries.
is a vector of determinants of true debt including firm-specific controls such as size,
position in the group (headquarters, other parent entity or non-parent entity) and the number of
countries where its MNE group operates. Country or industry-specific controls are: GDP growth,
value-added growth in the industry, development level (GDP per capita) and size of the credit
sector (measured by private credit as a share of GDP and the share of employment in the finance
industry). and are respectively time and industry fixed-effects.
Another way to assess the relative importance of profit shifting channels is to compare
the tax sensitivity of pre-tax profit with the sensitivity of operating profit (i.e. profit
before interest expenses and financial income). The tax sensitivity of pre-tax profit
captures all profit shifting channels (transfer pricing, location of intangibles, location of
debt, interest rate manipulation, etc.), while the tax sensitivity of operating profit does not
include the location of debt and interest rate manipulation. For example, if the tax
sensitivity of pre-tax profit were twice as large as the one of operating profit, debt
manipulation would represent half of overall profit shifting. The empirical analysis does
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
156 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
not find a statistically significant difference between the tax sensitivity of operating profit
and that of total pre-tax profit. One caveat is that pre-tax profit includes financial income,
i.e. interest income and dividends received. However, results are robust to dropping all
entities with at least one identified subsidiary, which are the principal ones receiving
dividends.
Summing up, the analysis suggests that transfer price manipulation, artificial allocation of
legal ownership of intangible assets and manipulation of debt levels are important profit
shifting channels. This is in line with recent literature findings (Heckemeyer and
Overesch 2013; Buettner and Wamser, 2013).27
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 157
Table 3.A1.2 Profit shifting and mismatches reduce the effective tax rate of MNEs1
Average differential in the effective tax rate between MNEs and domestic groups with similar characteristics
Percentage point
Induced by:
Profit shifting
Small MNE entity (<250
employees)
as compared to a small non-MNE
(domestic) entity
Large MNE entity (250+
employees)
as compared to a large non-MNE
(domestic) entity
Mismatches between
tax systems and
preferential tax
treatment
Total
-2.0
[-1 to -3]
0.0
-2.0
[-1 to -3]
-2.0
[-1 to -3]
-3.3
[-2 to -5]
-5.3
[-4 to -8]
1.
The ranges around the average differential are computed using the sensitivity assumptions described in
section 3.1.
158 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Box 3.A1.6. Anti-avoidance rules
Some of the main anti-avoidance rules in domestic tax systems in OECD and G20 economies are
(OECD, 2013):
Transfer price rules require that cross-border transactions between related firms
should be valued at market price (so-called arms length principle). When no
comparable transaction exists, different valuation methods can be used, for instance
based on cost plus a fixed mark-up or using economic models to split the relevant
profit among entities.
Thin capitalisation rules and rules limiting interest deductibility disallow the
deduction of certain interest expenses when the debt-to-equity or the interest-toearnings ratio of the debtor is considered excessive. These rules apply either to total or
related-party debt.
Controlled foreign company (CFC) rules aim at eliminating the deferral of tax on
certain income by using lower-tax foreign affiliates or the exemption on certain
mobile foreign source income.
General or other specific anti-avoidance rules prohibit aggressive tax avoidance, for
instance, by denying tax benefits from a transaction that lacks economic substance.
Anti-hybrid rules link the domestic tax treatment of instruments or entities with the
tax treatment in the foreign country, thus eliminating the mismatch between tax
systems. For instance, they may deny the deduction of interest if treated as nontaxable dividend in the recipient country.
A number of academic studies have classified countries according to the degree of strictness on
specific anti-avoidance rules, such as transfer pricing regulations and rules against debt
manipulation (e.g. Lohse et al., 2012; Lohse and Riedel, 2012; Blouin et al., 2014). However,
there exists no classification of the overall strictness of the anti-avoidance stance.
Building upon these studies, a new, though limited, classification on the strictness of antiavoidance and withholding taxes among OECD and G20 countries is developed in this study.
Detailed tax rules vary significantly between countries and the classification aims at grouping
countries along the key dimensions of anti-avoidance that are relatively easy to quantify and
compare across countries, using simple and mechanical rules. The classification focuses on: (i)
requirements regarding transfer pricing documentation; (ii) rules that limit interest deductions
(i.e. thin capitalisation and interest-to-earnings rules); (iii) existence of a GAAR; and (iv)
existence of a CFC rule. The classification also considers the level of withholding taxes on
interests, dividends and royalties as they can influence MNEs incentives to shift profit. Within
the European Union, withholding taxes are set to zero by law.
On transfer pricing, interest deductibility and withholding taxes, the classification is based on a
0-1-2 scale, which captures the broad strictness of rules but may miss important country-specific
details. On GAAR and CFC rules, a simpler 0-1 scale based on the existence of a rule is used,
reflecting the difficulty to classify these country-specific rules in a harmonised way. The overall
classification sums the 5 components. As a result, the classification runs from 0 to 8.
A caveat to this classification is that some aspects of anti-avoidance rules that are more difficult
to compare across countries as well as country-specific details and enforcement practices (e.g.
frequency of tax audits, penalties in case of non-compliance) are not captured. In addition, the
classification does not distinguish between territorial and worldwide tax systems.
Information on some of the main anti-avoidance rules and withholding taxes among
OECD and G20 countries is the basis for a new, though limited, composite anti-avoidance
classification outlined in Box 3.A1.6 and presented in Figure 3.A1.7. This grouping
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 159
builds upon earlier classification efforts in the literature (Lohse et al., 2012; Lohse and
Riedel, 2012; Blouin et al., 2014). According to this grouping of countries, anti-avoidance
rules appear to be comparatively strict in countries with relatively high corporate tax
rates. This may reflect that, in countries with relatively high tax rates, firms have stronger
incentives to avoid taxes, prompting governments to introduce stricter regulations.
A few existing studies have assessed the role of specific anti-avoidance rules for firms
behaviour, such as the impact of transfer pricing regulations on profit shifting (e.g. Lohse
and Riedel, 2012) and the effect of thin capitalisation rules on firms capital structure
(e.g. Blouin et al., 2014). Generally, these studies find that individual anti-avoidance
measures can reduce tax planning. However, there is no evidence of the overall impact of
anti-avoidance rules and their implementation on tax planning.
Based on the slightly broader, but still limited, anti-avoidance classification presented in
Figure 3.A1.7, the estimates in this study suggest that relatively stricter anti-avoidance
rules are associated with lower profit shifting across OECD and G20 economies.28 For
instance, an increase in the strictness of anti-avoidance rules from moderate to relatively
strict is associated with a reduction in profit shifting from that country by about one half.
The empirical analysis also provides evidence that rules that limit base erosion via
interest deductions are associated with reduced debt manipulation.
Figure 3.A1.7 Illustrative classification of anti-avoidance rules
Distribution of countries by degree of strictness of anti-avoidance rules and withholding taxes
2005
2014
50%
45%
40%
35%
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
Weak
Moderate
Relatively strict
Very strict
Note: 15% of countries in the sample (which includes all OECD and G20 countries) had very strict antiavoidance rules in 2014. A very strict anti-avoidance rule corresponds to a score of 7-8 on the 0-8 indicator
of anti-avoidance and withholding taxes described in Box 3.A1.6. A score of 8 is defined as the combination
of strict documentation requirements on transfer pricing, a strict rule against debt manipulation, existence of a
GAAR and a CFC rule as well as relatively high withholding taxes on interest, dividends and royalties. A
relatively strict rule corresponds to a score of 5-6, a moderate to 3-4 and weak to 0-2. The indicator
does not reflect the enforcement of existing rules.
160 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Both tax planning and anti-avoidance entail compliance costs, reducing firms
profitability
Complex tax codes result in wasted resources for firms and tax administrations and can
contribute to deter foreign investment. International tax planning also involves a
collective waste of resources due to the costs associated with setting up complex tax
schemes (e.g. tax and legal advice). One indication of resources spent on tax planning is
the share of production of the tax consultancy industry in overall output
(Figure 3.A1.8). Still, this indication is rough as this production category also includes
non-tax-related activities, such as regular accounting and bookkeeping activities, the size
of which varies across countries, depending among other things on industry structure.
One reason for the complexity of the tax system is that governments react to tax planning
by some firms with anti-avoidance legislation that increases the administrative cost of all
firms. For instance, Slemrod et al. (2007) suggests that tax complexity in the United
Kingdom has increased mainly because of a significant volume of anti-avoidance
legislation was added to the tax code. Consistent with this, the empirical analysis shows
that anti-avoidance rules mitigate profit shifting, but are also associated with significantly
lower average (pre-tax) profitability. The lower profitability may reflect resources spent
on tax compliance. This adverse effect on average profitability is robust to controlling for
the income level of a country, burdensome regulations in other areas and the statutory
corporate tax rate. Compliance costs for firms as well as administration and enforcement
costs for tax authorities are important to the assessment of the overall cost-benefit of antiavoidance rules. Co-ordinating anti-avoidance rules across countries could reduce
compliance costs for MNEs.
Figure 3.A1.8 Production of the accounting, bookkeeping, auditing and tax consultancy
industry29
% of GDP, 2011
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
Note by Turkey: The information in this document with reference to Cyprus relates to the southern part of
the Island. There is no single authority representing both Turkish and Greek Cypriot people on the Island.
Turkey recognises the Turkish Republic of Northern Cyprus (TRNC). Until a lasting and equitable solution is
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 161
found within the context of the United Nations, Turkey shall preserve its position concerning the Cyprus
issue.
Note by all the European Union Member States of the OECD and the European Union: The Republic of
Cyprus is recognised by all members of the United Nations with the exception of Turkey. The information in
this document relates to the area under the effective control of the Government of the Republic of Cyprus.
Source: Eurostat, BEA, OECD calculations.
Fiscal implications
Profit shifting redistributes corporate tax bases across countries and results in global tax
revenue losses as shifted profits are taxed at a lower average rate than they would have
been in the absence of profit shifting. While profit shifting entails gains or losses at the
country level depending on the characteristics of tax systems, in the case of mismatches
between tax systems (including preferential tax treatment) there are generally no gains in
terms of tax revenues, but there can be ambiguity as to who has lost revenue. For
example, both parties concerned by a scheme involving a hybrid security may (or may
not) claim that they lost revenues. Another difficulty is to identify the most frequent
schemes and countries involved in these mismatches.
The revenue effects are presented for hypothetical combinations of tax bases and tax rate
differentials between tax rates faced by the average MNE entity in the home country and
the tax rate faced by this hypothetical MNE on average in the other countries where it
operates. They should be seen as illustrative and ranges reflecting the many uncertainties
of the analysis are provided. The revenue estimates are based on the average tax planning
propensity (both for profit shifting and mismatches) estimated over the full sample of
countries, in combination with different hypothetical tax rate differentials and tax bases
(i.e. the share of MNE profits in total corporate profits). It is important to note that the
average propensity leaves aside certain country-specific differences in tax planning
intensity, for example resulting from the strictness and enforcement of rules against tax
planning.
162 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
between 40% and 80% in most OECD and G20 countries. The revenue effects of tax
planning are also based on the assumption that corporate tax revenues change in
proportion with reported financial profits. This is an approximation because of potential
differences between reported and taxable profits due to, inter alia, book/tax differences
and tax credits. The effect of book/tax differences on the estimated revenue effects is
ambiguous (Box 3.A1.7). By contrast, taking into account tax credits would increase the
revenue effects where such tax credits are significant. Information on tax credits is
limited and the available data suggest that they can vary substantially across countries and
over time. The assumption in this hypothetical example is that tax credits represent 15%
of CIT revenues before tax credits. Another key assumption is that firms outside the
sample have similar structures and behave in a similar way as firms in the sample.
Sensitivity analysis to this assumption is presented below.
Box 3.A1.7. The impact of book/tax differences and tax credits on tax
revenue estimates
There exist few estimates of the difference between book and taxable profits. In the United
States, the difference was volatile over 2006-10. Excluding the crisis-year 2008, the difference
was relatively small on average over the period (Boynton et al., 2014; see Figure below). This
pattern would suggest that differences in the timing of recognition of income and expenses are
an important driver of book/tax differences (see Section 2.2 above on the sources of book/tax
differences). In Germany, financial profits were 10% lower than taxable profits in 2009, with the
difference being largest among firms engaged in corporate restructuring, but the corresponding
information is not available for other years (Zinn and Spengel, 2012).
Book/tax differences in the United States1
Taxable income
USD billion
1000
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
Book/tax differences can affect the estimation of the average tax planning propensity, which is
based on financial account rather than tax data. Book/tax differences that are independent of tax
planning (e.g. timing differences) likely create noise in the estimation, but are unlikely to bias
the estimated tax sensitivity in any direction. In contrast, certain book/tax differences result from
tax planning schemes (e.g. a dual residence scheme leading to the same interest expense being
deducted in more than one country). These schemes would reduce taxable income relatively to
book income (Lisowsky, 2010). Such schemes are not identified in the profit shifting analysis,
but they are captured in the empirical analysis of mismatches between tax systems, which
focuses on how reported profits are taxed.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 163
Box 3.A1.7. The impact of book/tax differences and tax credits on tax
revenue estimates (continued)
Book/tax differences can also affect tax revenue estimates for a given tax-sensitivity of reported
profits. Indeed, these differences imply that corporate tax revenues may not change
proportionately with profits reported in financial accounts. For example, if taxable profit is
systematically lower (respectively higher) than book profit, shifting 5% of book profit would
amount to shifting more (respectively less) than 5% of taxable profit and thus lead to a revenue
loss greater (respectively smaller) than 5% of revenues.
Similarly, the existence of tax credits, if they are unaffected by profit shifting, can influence
revenue estimates. Taking tax credits into account would increase estimated revenue effects (see
Table below).
Illustrative example of the effect of book/tax differences and tax credits
No tax
planning
Tax
planning
Share of tax
planning
105.0
100.0
5.0%
94.5
89.5
5.6%
Tax rate
30%
30%
28.4
26.9
4.0
4.0
24.3
22.8
5.6%
6.6%
Note: Profit shifting is assumed to reduce financial account (i.e. reported) profit by 5% (line 1). Assuming
that taxable profits are 10% lower than financial profits, then profit shifting represents 5.6% of taxable
profit (line 2). Assuming that tax credits represent 15% of tax before credits and are unaffected by profit
shifting, revenue losses from profit shifting, revenue losses would represent 6.2% of tax revenues rather
than 5% (line 5).
164 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Figure 3.A1.9 Illustrative tax revenue effects of international tax planning in hypothetical
cases
Panel A: As a share of corporate income tax revenues
%
25
20
Profit shifting
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
Profit shifting
0.4
0.2
0.0
-0.2
-0.4
-0.6
Note: For a country in which the average resident MNE would face a 10 percentage point higher tax rate than
the average tax rate in the other countries where this MNE group operates and with a 50% share of MNEs in
total corporate profits, the tax revenue loss from tax planning would represent on average about 11% of CIT
revenues (or about 0.3% of GDP), most of which from profit shifting. These averages are presented as an
illustration of the magnitude of tax planning. However, actual country-specific tax revenue effects can vary
widely around these averages for many reasons, including cross-country differences in the strictness of antiavoidance rules against tax planning and other country-specific tax rules.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 165
Figure 3.A1.10 Illustrative tax revenue effects depending on the strictness of anti-avoidance
rules
Example assuming a 6 percentage point tax rate differential between the resident rate and the average rate in
the countries where the MNE groups operate
%
10
Profit shifting
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
Note: For an average country with a 6 percentage point tax rate differential, a 50% share of MNEs in total
corporate profits and weak anti-avoidance rules, the tax revenue loss from tax planning would represent on
average about 12% of CIT revenues. The effect of anti-avoidance rules on the profit shifting intensity is
estimated by refining the equation presented in Box 3.A1.3. The refinement consists of interacting the tax rate
differential with the classification of anti-avoidance strictness. The resulting effect is positive, suggesting that
profit shifting is reduced when anti-avoidance rules are relatively strict. The potential effect of anti-avoidance
rules on mismatches between tax systems is not included since it could not be established empirically with the
available data.
The revenue effects are surrounded by a number of uncertainties (Box 3.A1.8). Some
factors may lead to an underestimation of revenue effects, such as the potential lack of
financial or ownership information on certain entities involved in the most complex tax
schemes. More generally, unknown tax planning schemes of MNEs may not be
captured, although the empirical approach (based on the location of activity, profits and
tax expenses) does not require knowing the details of schemes to estimate tax planning.
On the other hand, certain assumptions may lead to an overestimation, such as not
controlling for country fixed-effects in the estimation of the profit shifting sensitivity.
166 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Reflecting these uncertainties, the revenue effects incorporate sensitivity to the following
two sources of variation (Figure 3.A1.11): (i) taking a 95% confidence interval around the
tax sensitivity estimate; and (ii) assuming that firms outside the sample have a 50%
higher tax sensitivity than firms in the sample, where the sample coverage is assessed
against the population of firms from the OECD Business Demography Statistics database
(the weighted average of coverage is about 40%).32
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 167
% of CIT revenues
30
20
10
0
-10
-10 p.p.
-6 p.p.
-2 p.p.
2 p.p.
6 p.p.
10 p.p.
-10 p.p.
-6 p.p.
-2 p.p.
2 p.p.
6 p.p.
-30
10 p.p.
-20
Panel B: Sensitivity to the tax planning intensity of firms outside the sample34
Tax planning propensity of MNEs outside the sample:
100%-150% of propensity of firms in the sample
% of CIT revenues
30
20
10
0
-10
-10 p.p.
-6 p.p.
-2 p.p.
2 p.p.
6 p.p.
10 p.p.
-10 p.p.
-6 p.p.
-2 p.p.
2 p.p.
6 p.p.
-30
10 p.p.
-20
168 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Panel C: Combined sensitivity
Combined sensitivity (A+B)
% of CIT revenues
30
20
10
0
-10
1.
-10 p.p.
-6 p.p.
-2 p.p.
2 p.p.
6 p.p.
10 p.p.
-10 p.p.
-6 p.p.
-2 p.p.
2 p.p.
6 p.p.
-30
10 p.p.
-20
The revenue effect is based on the assumption that firms outside the sample have the same tax elasticity
(i.e. profit shifting elasticity and average tax differential) as firms in the sample. The sensitivity
analysis assumes a 50% higher tax elasticity of firms outside the sample relative to firms in the sample.
The assumption is that 50% of firms are covered in the hypothetical country.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 169
Competition implications
Tax planning can distort competition among firms and entail efficiency losses. Indeed, as
shown above, the effective corporate tax rate of large tax planning MNEs can be sizeably
lower than the rate of some other firms. This lower effective tax rate can give rise to an
unintended competitive advantage of MNEs compared to other firms as it reduces the
firms tax costs (Overesch, 2009; OECD, 2013). This cost advantage can allow the MNE
to gain market shares by reducing its price in line with its costs at least in the short term.
In the longer term, once the MNE has gained a dominant market position, it may
ultimately increase prices to raise profits. Alternatively, if the MNE is pursuing a strategy
of competing on attributes other than the price (e.g. quality, service and branding), it may
use the cost savings to further differentiate its products to achieve a larger market share
and eventually a higher price and profit than its competitors (Porter, 1980). Finally, as tax
planning reduces the cost of MNEs relative to other firms (entrants), MNEs can raise
entry barriers by, for example, using the tax savings on spending on advertising and R&D
(Sutton, 1991). Overall, the expected effect of tax planning is to increase the market share
and after-tax profitability of tax planning MNEs at the expense of other firms.
Assessing the potential distortion to competition is difficult and little empirical evidence
exists. This study uses a combination of firm and industry-level data to investigate if
industries with a large share of MNEs with tax planning opportunities are more
concentrated than other industries (see Box 3.A1.9). One way to assess the impact of tax
planning on industry concentration is to compare it across countries having different antiavoidance rules. The idea is that tax planning is more frequent when anti-avoidance is
less strict, resulting in more concentrated industries than elsewhere. Controlling for other
country and industry characteristics, this analysis suggests that industries with a strong
presence of MNEs are less concentrated when anti-avoidance rules are stricter. Industry
concentration is measured as the market share of the 10 largest entities divided by the
market share of the 100 largest entities in an industry and country. For example, in an
industry with a high share of MNEs among top-10 firms (the 75th percentile of the
distribution), increasing anti-avoidance strictness by two notches (see Figure 3.A1.7)
would reduce the combined market share of the ten largest firms in the industry by about
6 percentage points.
The study also investigates the implications of tax planning for price mark-ups of MNE
groups using firm-level data (see Box 3.A1.9). Mark-ups are proxied by pre-tax operating
profit divided by turnover, in line with Aghion et al. (2005). Along with the increased
market concentration, estimates show that engaging in tax planning is associated with
higher price mark-ups controlling for other factors affecting mark-ups such as size,
productivity, leverage, presence of patents and exposure to foreign competition. For
example, the mark-up of a MNE group is about 10% higher than that of a domestic firm,
while the mark-up of a tax-planning MNE is up to 23% higher (Figure 3.A1.12, left
panel). The effect is reduced in countries with stricter anti-avoidance rules against tax
planning (Figure 3.A1.12, right panel). One caveat to these analyses is that the causality
is unclear as more profitable firms may choose to set up affiliates in lower-tax countries
(leading them to be identified as tax planners), suggesting that the results should be
interpreted with caution.
170 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Figure 3.A1.12 Mark-up rate and international tax planning
Mark-up rate premium over a non-multinational corporate group with similar characteristics1
%
%
25
25
20
20
15
15
10
10
Average MNE
group
MNE group
operating in 20
countries
Average MNE
group
Notes:
1. The differences in mark-up between different types of firms are statistically significant at a 5% level.
2. The average MNE group operates in five countries. MNE groups operating in many countries have been
shown to engage more intensively in international tax planning.
Distortions of competition lead to welfare losses as consumers face higher prices in some
markets than otherwise. It can also, under certain circumstances, reduce innovation
(Aghion et al., 2005; Gilbert, 2006). Reduced competitive pressures can also curb
innovation incentives for MNEs themselves as it reduces the incentives to innovate to
stay ahead of competitors (Aghion et al., 2005). Differences in the effective tax rate
between MNEs and other firms may also contribute to a suboptimal allocation of capital
in the economy as, by providing rates of return artificially altered by tax distortions,
MNEs may crowd out investment by other (potentially more productive) MNEs and
domestic firms.
Yet, MNEs are in general more productive and exposed to competition than other firms
(e.g. Helpman et al., 2004; Bloom et al., 2012) and they can generate positive
technological and productivity spillovers to other firms. If tax planning MNEs are more
productive than the firms they crowd out, the overall effect on efficiency is unclear.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 171
where
is the market concentration of industry i in country c, measured as the
combined market share (based on turnover) of the 10 largest entities (based on unconsolidated
accounts) in industry i and country c, divided by the combined market share of the 100 largest
entities in the same industry and country. The analysis is based on 28 industries in 28 OECD and
G20 countries. Tax planning intensity (
is measured by the market
share of MNE entities among top-10 firms in the industry multiplied by the strictness of antiavoidance rules in country c. The idea is that tax planning is more intense in industries with a
large share of MNEs, but less so in countries with relatively strict anti-avoidance rules. and
are dummies for industry and country, which capture common characteristics of certain
industries and countries.
The estimated mark-up equation is:
where
is the mark-up rate of the MNE group g (consolidated accounts), which
operates in industry i, in year t with headquarters in country c. The mark-up rate is proxied by
the Lerner index or price-cost margin, measured as operating profit divided by turnover, in line
with Aghion et al. (2005). The tax planning propensity (
) is measured by
four proxy variables: (i) a dummy variable for multinational (as opposed to domestic) groups;
(ii) a dummy variable for MNE groups with links to no-corporate-tax countries; (iii) the number
of countries where a MNE group operates; (iv) the average anti-avoidance strictness (as
measured by the indicator defined in Box 3.A1.6) in the countries where the group operates. The
control vector
is a set of group-specific variables potentially influencing the mark-up rate,
including size, productivity, leverage, presence of patents (as a measure of innovative activities)
and exposure to foreign competition (proxied by the average import penetration in markets
where the group is active).
and
are industry, year and country of headquarters fixedeffects.
All four measures of tax planning intensity have advantages and disadvantages. Comparing
MNEs and domestic firms (option i) poses the issue of potential unobserved differences between
them, although the extensive set of control variables included should minimise this issue.
Comparing tax-planning MNEs (e.g. with links to no-tax countries, option ii) to other MNEs can
pose reverse causality issues since ex ante more profitable MNEs have more incentives then
other MNEs to set up affiliate in low-tax countries. The number of countries where a MNE
operates (option iii) is also subject to reverse causality, since profitable firms are more likely to
expand to other countries than other firms. Finally, MNE groups facing relatively strict antiavoidance rules against tax planning (option iv) may have lower mark-up than other groups
because of the compliance costs implied by these rules. Despite these limitations, the results are
consistent across the various specifications, which supports the initial hypothesis that tax
planning distorts competition.
172 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 173
Box 3.A1.10. Empirical approach: Tax planning and group external leverage
The idea is to assess the sensitivity of MNE groups overall external leverage to changes in tax
rates in the different countries where they operate. These changes can affect the location of
group debt, but also its overall level by altering the effective cost of debt for the group. Overall
group leverage is expected to be sensitive to the tax rate in the country of headquarters, where an
important share of group debts is generally located, and in the higher-tax rate countries in the
group, where MNE groups have been shown to shift debts.
The estimated equation is as follows:
,
where
is the external (i.e. consolidated) debt-to-equity ratio of the MNE group g, with
headquarters in country c, in year t. is the sensitivity of leverage to the statutory tax rate in the
headquarters country (
) and
the sensitivity to the average of the two highest tax rates
among the countries where the group operates (
). In alternative specifications, the
average tax rate among all countries where the group operates and the average of the two lowest
tax rates are also considered.
is a set of firm-specific and macroeconomic control variables
(e.g. profitability, GDP growth, interest rates).
and
are respectively time and group fixedeffects.
The source of data is consolidated financial accounts of MNE groups from the ORBIS database,
over 2000-2010. The number of observations is about 15 000 group-year pairs, covering most
OECD and G20 countries. Results are robust to: (i) replacing the average of the two highest tax
rates in the group by the highest tax rate, or the average of the three highest; (ii) restricting the
sample to EU countries; (iii) excluding financial firms.
For example, a MNE group with relatively high debt manipulation opportunities (e.g. the
average of the two highest tax rates in the group is 40%, as compared to 35% for the
average MNE) has 8% higher external leverage (Figure 3.A1.13, left panel). This finding
is robust to a number of variants, such as adding control variables for macroeconomic
developments or restricting the sample to only EU countries or non-financial firms. In
addition, relatively strict thin capitalisation and interest-to-earnings rules against debt
manipulation are found to lower the propensity of MNE groups to increase their external
leverage through debt manipulation.
174 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Figure 3.A1.13 MNE group external leverage and international tax planning
Leverage (external consolidated debt-to-equity) as compared to an average MNE group1
20
20
18
18
16
16
14
14
12
12
10
10
On average
All firms
The empirical evidence suggests that strategic location of debt (internal and external) can
increase the total debt of MNE groups. Yet, the external leverage of the average MNE
group is found to be lower than that of the average domestic firm with comparable
characteristics (Figure 3.A1.13, right panel), in line with most of the empirical literature
(e.g. Burgman, 1996). This suggests that manipulation of the location of debt is not
among the main determinants of MNE groups external debt level, as it does not increase
the average external leverage of MNEs above the average of domestic firms. Moreover,
MNEs tend to have more diversified income streams as compared to domestic firms,
making them less vulnerable to adverse income shocks (e.g. Baker and Riddick, 2013).
Despite the additional external leverage induced by debt manipulation, the average MNE
is therefore less likely than a domestic firm to have external debt levels that make it
vulnerable to income shocks.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 175
planning may affect the impact of these distortions on investment and its location by
reducing the effective cost of investing in high-tax countries.
176 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Figure 3.A1.14 Share of inward FDI stock explained by tax rate differences between
countries1,2
Average 2006-2011
Percent
50
Elasticity of -3
Elasticity of -1.5
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
15% - 20%
20% - 25%
25% - 30%
30% - 35%
> 35%
1. A positive figure indicates that the existing tax differences contribute positively to FDI. For example,
without tax differences with other countries the FDI stock in a country with a tax rate below 15% would
be about 20-40 percent lower (depending on the elasticity) than the actual stock.
2. The estimates are based on differences in statutory tax rates (the most widely available across countries).
The estimates are similar when based on forward-looking effective tax rates instead of statutory tax rates.
In addition to differences in statutory corporate tax rates, preferential tax regimes (e.g. for
intangible assets) and other characteristics of tax systems may influence the location of
FDI. A potentially important factor is whether the home country of a MNE exempts
foreign-source dividends from tax (i.e. territorial/source tax system) or subjects them to
domestic tax while giving a credit for taxes paid in the host country (i.e.
worldwide/residence taxation). Existing studies do not find a significant difference in the
tax sensitivity of FDI under alternative tax systems (e.g. Hajkova et al., 2006). This may
reflect tax deferrals and other tax planning strategies of MNEs as well as in practice that
most countries do not have a pure territorial or worldwide system. A pure territorial
system would tax all investments into a specific country in the same way regardless of
home country, but would tax investment of the same MNE differently across countries. A
pure worldwide system would do the opposite: it would tax investment of a MNE at home
or abroad similarly, while treating investment of different MNEs into one country
dissimilarly. Recently, there has been a trend towards territorial systems among OECD
and G20 countries.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 177
Bilateral gross FDI stocks are drawn from the OECD International Direct Investment database,
covering 34 reporting countries and more than 200 partner countries over the period 2006-2011.
In the statistics, foreign direct investment consists of capital shares and reserves, including
retained profits, as well as net positions of loans, trade credits and securities.
The location of R&D activity and intangible assets are also influenced by taxation. As
discussed, MNEs may locate income associated with patents and other intellectual
property to countries with lower tax rate or preferential tax treatment on such income.
However, MNEs do not locate the ownership of intellectual property only based on taxes.
They often co-locate the ownership of intellectual property with the associated R&D
activity (Griffith et al., 2014). Indeed, the empirical analysis suggests that R&D activities
(proxied by patents where the inventor is located in the same country as the firm applying
for the patent protection) are sensitive to tax rate differentials (see Box 3.A1.4).
Tax planning reduces the effect of tax rate differences on the location of
investment by tax planning MNEs
Existing evidence, including recent OECD work, shows that a higher effective corporate
tax rate in a country reduces firms investment in that country (e.g. OECD, 2009;
Djankov et al., 2010; Arnold et al., 2011). However, the possibility for MNEs with links
to low-tax countries to reduce their effective tax rates by tax planning may make the
location of their investment less sensitive to cross-country differences in tax rates. Thus,
testing if (controlling for other factors affecting investment) the effects of high corporate
tax rates on investment are weaker for such MNEs than for other similar firms without
links to low-tax countries is an indirect way to verify the existence of tax planning.44,45
International tax planning may reduce the effect of relatively high corporate taxation on
tangible and intangible investment of tax planning MNEs, but at the cost of introducing
distortions that are related to both the implied tax revenue losses and to the uneven
playing field generated by differential effective taxation of different types of firms. Thus,
across-the-board corporate rate reductions and base broadening would have more
beneficial effects on the economy than self-helped reductions in effective tax rates by
selected MNEs via tax planning behaviour.
Industry and firm-level evidence across a large set of OECD and G20 countries confirms
that, while increases in corporate taxes tend to reduce firms investment in a typical
industry, the reduction in investment is lower in industries with a large share of tax
planning MNEs (see Box 3.A1.12). For instance, a 5 percentage point increase in the
effective (forward-looking) marginal corporate tax rate46 would reduce investment on
average across industries by about 5% in the long term (Figure 3.A1.15, Panel A).
However, in industries with a high concentration of MNEs with profit shifting incentives,
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
178 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
this effect would be nearly halved. This supports the hypothesis that tax-planning MNEs
investment is less sensitive to tax rates than other firms investment. This is because taxplanning MNEs can achieve lower taxes through artificial arrangements without changing
the location of the value-creating real economic activity. Moreover, stricter antiavoidance rules against tax planning are found to raise the sensitivity of investment to tax
rate changes (Figure 3.A1.15, Panel B).
Figure 3.A1.15 Tax planning reduces the effect of corporate taxes on tax planning
MNEs investment
Estimated long-term change in investment after a 5 percentage point increase in the corporate tax
rate47
-1
-1
-2
-2
-3
-3
-4
-4
-5
-6
-5
Low
(25th percentile)
Median
High
(75th percentile)
-6
Moderate
strictness
Average effect
Relatively strict
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 179
where
is the investment rate (investment divided by lagged capital stock) in country
c, industry i and year t, sourced from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD).
is the
forward-looking effective marginal tax rate from the Oxford Centre for Business Taxation
(results with the average effective rate are consistent but less statistically significant).
is the number of MNE entities with profit shifting incentives
among the 100 largest firms in country c and in industry i sourced from the firm-level database
(ORBIS). An entity is considered as having profit shifting incentives if it faces a higher tax rate
in its home country than the average (unweighted) in its corporate group, in line with the profit
shifting analysis (Box 3.A1.3). The coefficient reflects the tax sensitivity of the average firm,
while reflects whether industries with a high concentration of profit-shifting MNEs are more
sensitive than other industries.
is the value-added growth of the industry a
high-growth industry is expected to have a higher investment rate.
and
are respectively
fixed-effects for country-interacted-with-industry and time.
The sample consists of 30 industries in 29 countries over 1997-2009. The equation is estimated
either with ordinary least squares or a generalised method of moments estimator that avoids the
potential bias induced by the simultaneous use of the lagged dependent variable and fixedeffects. Results are consistent between the two estimation methods.
At the firm-level, the estimated equation is as follows:
where
is the investment rate of firm f operating in country c, industry i and year t.
The investment rate is measured as the change in fixed assets (at book value), net of depreciation
(also at book value) and divided by lagged fixed assets, sourced from the ORBIS database. This
measure is similar to Gal (2013). The effective tax rate and value-added growth variables are
identical to the industry level analysis.
is the difference
between the statutory tax rate in country i and year t and the average (unweighted) among the
countries where the MNE group of f operates.
and
are firm and time fixed-effects. The
sample consists of about 50 000 observations of MNE entity accounts in 18 OECD countries
over ten years (2001-2010).
180 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
additional activity (e.g. employment opportunities, investment by intermediate suppliers,
etc.), which further adds to growth and tax revenues.
One clear prediction from the tax competition literature is a reduction in tax rates, with a
race to the bottom in the extreme case of a small open economy with perfect capital
mobility (Devereux and Lorentz, 2012; Keen and Konrad, 2012). To the extent that the
corporate tax is considered as more distortive than other taxes, a certain degree of tax
competition may enhance economic efficiency. However, tax competition may also lower
public spending and taxes below their efficient level and cause welfare losses, although
this depends on what is considered the optimal level of public service provision (e.g.
Wilson, 1999). Overall, in practice it is difficult to determine at what point tax
competition produces negative effects for growth and welfare.
The empirical literature confirms that tax competition took place in past decades, as
countries have responded to lower corporate tax rates elsewhere by reducing their own
rates (Devereux and Sorensen, 2006; IMF, 2014). Furthermore, tax competition over
corporate tax bases may have induced indirect spillovers on other tax bases. Pressures to
reduce the corporate rate may have created pressures to reduce the top personal income
tax rate because of the possibility to incorporate to reduce tax payments (OECD, 2009;
Arnold et al., 2011; IMF, 2014). One marked change in taxation over the past decades is a
reduction in top personal income tax rates and in progressivity in income taxes in OECD
countries (OECD, 2009).
Tax planning provides incentives for tax competition as countries compete to attract
profits generated by MNEs activities elsewhere. This form of tax competition is not
always transparent as it can occur through preferential regimes rather than on statutory
rates. However, in the absence of tax planning, tax competition may not necessarily be
less intensive. This is because the sensitivity of real investment to taxes may increase,
as shown earlier. For instance, the estimates obtained with the methodology presented in
Box 3.A1.12 suggest that the sensitivity of industry-level investment to the effective
corporate tax rate would increase by about 30% if tax planning would be halved. In the
absence of tax planning, higher-tax rate countries could become less attractive investment
destinations for certain MNEs and may ultimately compete more fiercely to attract
investment. At the same time, the additional tax revenues obtained in the short run by
tackling tax planning could be used to reduce tax rates across the board or finance public
spending, which could support private investment over the longer term.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 181
Fiscal implications
Competition
between firms
Debt
Investment
Tax competition
In any case, the welfare implications of tax planning go beyond economic efficiency. Tax
planning redistributes corporate tax bases across countries, leading to revenue losses in
higher-tax rate countries. These losses will either lead to lower government expenditures
(which may reduce welfare) or may need to be offset by raising other distortive taxes on
less mobile tax bases, which may entail a welfare loss. More broadly, tax planning may
undermine the legitimacy of the tax system and reduce tax compliance among a wider set
of taxpayers. This may hamper governments ability to mobilise fiscal revenues due to
lack of trust and perception of unfairness of the tax system. In turn, this can generate
large compliance and administrative costs.
182 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 183
Bibliography
Aghion, P., N. Bloom, R. Blundell, R. Griffith and P. Howitt (2005), Competition and
Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, MIT
Press, Vol. 120.
Atkinson, A. and J. Stiglitz (1976), The Design of Tax Structure: Direct Versus Indirect
Taxation, Journal of Public Economics 6.
Arnold, J., B. Brys, C. Heady, A. Johansson, C. Schwellnus and L. Vartia (2011), Tax
Policy for Economic Recovery and Growth, Economic Journal, Vol. 121.
Baker, H. and L. Ridick (2013), International Finance: A Survey, Oxford University
Press.
Beer, S. and J. Loeprick (2014), Profit shifting: drivers of transfer (mis)pricing and the
potential of countermeasures, International Tax and Public Finance, No. 1.
Blomstrm, M. and A. Kokko (1998), Multinational corporations and spillovers,
Journal of Economic Survey, 12(3).
Bloom, N., R. Sadun and J. Van Reenen (2012), Americans Do IT Better: US
Multinationals and the Productivity Miracle, American Economic Review, 102.
Blouin, J., H. Huizinga, L. Laeven, and G. Nicodme (2014), Thin Capitalization Rules
and Multinational Firm Capital Structure, IMF Working paper, WP/14/12.
Boynton, C., P. De Filippes, E. Legel, and T. Reum (2014), A First Look at 2010
Schedule M-3 Reporting and Schedule UTP, Special Report, Tax Notes, Internal
Revenue Service.
Braconier, H., G. Nicoletti and B. Westmore (2014), Policy Challenges for the Next 50
Years, OECD Economics Department Policy Papers, No 9, OECD Publishing.
Buettner, T., M. Overesch, U. Schreiber and G. Wamser (2012), The impact of thin
capitalisation rules on the capital structure of multinational firms, Journal of Public
Economics, Vol. 96, Issues 11-12.
Buettner, T. and G. Wamser (2013), Internal Debt and Multinational Profit Shifting:
Empirical Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data, National Tax Journal, 66 (1).
Burgman, T. (1996), An Empirical Examination of Multinational Corporate Capital
Structure, Journal of International Business Studies, No. 27.
Chamley, C. (1986), Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with
Infinite Lives, Econometrica 54(3).
Clausing, K. (2009), Multinational firm tax avoidance and tax policy, National Tax
Journal, Vol. 62, No 4.
184 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Cobham, A. and S. Loretz (2014), International distribution of the corporate tax base:
Impact of different apportionment factors under unitary taxation, Mimeo, 2014.
CTJ (2014), Offshore Shell Games, Citizens for Tax Justice.
Dahlby, B. (2011), Global Value Chains, Foreign Direct Investment, and Taxation,
mimeo, University of Alberta.
De Mooij, R. (2011), The Tax Elasticity of Corporate Debt: A Synthesis of Size and
Variations, IMF Working Paper WP/11/95, International Monetary Fund.
De Mooij, R. (2012), Tax Biases to Debt Finance: Assessing the Problem, Finding
Solutions, Fiscal Studies, Institute for Fiscal Studies, vol. 33(4).
Devereux, M. and P. Sorensen (2006), The Corporate Income Tax: International Trends
and Options for Fundamental Reform, European Commission, Economic Papers No.
264.
Devereux, M., B. Lockwood and M. Redoano (2008), Do countries compete over
corporate tax rates? Journal of Public Economics 92(5-6).
Devereux, M. and S. Loretz, (2012), What Do We Know about Corporate Tax
Competition?, Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation, October, Working
Paper 12/29.
Dharmapala, D. (2014), What do we know about base erosion and profit shifting? A
review of the empirical literature, CESifo Working Paper, No. 4612.
Dischinger, M., U. Glogowsky and M. Strobel (2010), Leverage, Coporate Taxes and
Debt Shifting of Multinationals: The Impact of Firm-specific Risk, Mimeo,
University of Munich.
Djankov, S., T. Ganser, C. McLiesh, R. Ramalho and A. Shleifer (2010), The Effect of
Corporate Taxes on Investment and Entrepreneurship, American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics, Vol. 2 No. 3.
Evers, L., H. Miller, C. Spengel (2013), Intellectual property box regimes: Effective tax
rates and tax policy considerations, ZEW Discussion Papers, No. 13-070.
Feld, L. and J. Heckemeyer (2011), FDI and Taxation: A Meta-Study, Journal of
Economic Surveys (2011) Vol. 25, No. 2.
Fuest, C. and N. Riedel (2010), Tax Evasion and Tax Avoidance in Developing
Countries: The Role of International Profit Shifting, Oxford University Centre for
Business Taxation Working Papers, 10/12.
Fuest, C. and N. Riedel (2012), Tax Evasion and Tax Avoidance: The Role of
International Profit Shifting, in Draining Development? editor P. Reuter, the World
Bank.
Gal, P. (2013), Measuring Total Factor Productivity at the Firm Level using OECDORBIS, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1049, OECD
Publishing.
Gilbert, R. (2006), Looking for Mr. Schumpeter: Where Are We in the CompetitionInnovation Debate?, Innovation Policy and the Economy, Vol. 6 (eds. A. Jaffe, J.
Lerner and S. Stern), National Bureau of Economic Research.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 185
Golosov, M., A. Tsyvinski and I, Werning (2006), New Dynamic Public Finance: A
User's Guide, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.
Gravelle, J. (2015), Tax Havens: International Tax Avoidance and Evasion,
Congressional Research Service, Washington D.C.
Gravelle, J. (2014), International Corporate Tax Rate Comparison and Public
Implications, Congressional Research Service, Washington D.C.
Griffith, R., H. Miller and M. OConnell (2014), Ownership of intellectual property and
corporate taxation, Journal of Public Economics 112.
Grubert, H. (2003), Intangible Income, Intercompany Transactions, Income Shifting, and
the Choice of Location, National Tax Journal 56 No. 1.
Grubert, H. (2012), Foreign Taxes and the Growing Share of U.S. Multinational
Company Income Abroad: Profits, Not Sales, are Being Globalized, Office of Tax
Analysis, Working Paper 103.
Hajkova, D., G. Nicoletti, L. Vartia and K. Yoo (2006), Taxation and Business
Environment as Drivers of Foreign Direct Investment in OECD Countries, OECD
Economic Studies No. 43/2 2006.
Hall, R. and D. Jorgenson (1967), Tax Policy and Investment Behavior, American
Economic Review, Vol. 57.
Hanlon, M. (2003), What can we infer about a firm's taxable income from its financial
statements? National Tax Journal, pages 831-863.
Heckemeyer, J. and M. Overesch (2013), Multinationals Profit Response to Tax
Differentials: Effect Size and Shifting Channels, ZEW Discussion Paper No. 13-045.
Helpman, E., M. Melitz, and S. Yeaple (2004), Export versus FDI with Heterogeneous
Firms, American Economic Review, 94.
Huizinga, H. and L. Laeven (2008), International profit shifting within multinationals: a
multi-country perspective, Journal of Public Economics, No 92.
Huizinga, H., L. Laeven and G. Nicodeme (2008), Capital structure and international
debt shifting, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 88.
IMF (2014), Spillovers in International Corporate Taxation, IMF Policy Paper,
International Monetary Fund.
Joint Committee on Taxation (2014), Technical Explanation, Estimated Revenue
Effects, Distributional Analysis, and Macroeconomic Analysis of the Tax Reform Act
of 2014, United States Government Printing Office, Washington.
Judd, K. (1985), Redistributive Taxation in a Simple Perfect Foresight Model, Journal
of Public Economics, 28(1).
Keen, M. and K. Konrad (2012), International Tax Competition and Co-ordination,
Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Public Finance Working Paper, N12/06.
Kydland, F. and E. Prescott (1977), Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of
Optimal Plans, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 85.
Lisowsky, P. (2010), Seeking shelter: Empirically modeling tax shelters using financial
statement information. The Accounting Review, Vol. 85, No. 5, pages 1693-1720.
186 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Lohse, T. and N. Riedel (2012), The impact of transfer pricing regulations on profit
shifting within European multinationals, FZID Discussion Papers, No. 61.
Lohse, T., N. Riedel and C. Spengel (2012), The Increasing Importance of Transfer
Pricing Regulations a Worldwide Overview, Oxford University Centre for Business
Taxation Working Paper, No. 12.
Maffini, G. and S. Mokkas (2011), Profit Shifting and Measured Productivity of
Multinational Firms, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 73, 1.
Markle, K. and D. Shackelford (2011), Cross-country comparisons of corporate income
taxes, NBER Working Paper, No 16839.
Markusen, J., and A. Venables (1999), Foreign direct investment as a catalyst for
industrial development, European Economic Review, 43(2).
Modigliani, F. and M. Miller (1958), The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the
Theory of Investment, The American Economic Review, Vol. 48, No. 3.
Men, J., D. Schindler, G. Schjelderup and J. Tropina (2011), International Debt
Shifting: Do Multinationals Shift Internal or External Debt?, CESifo Working Paper
Series, No. 3519.
OECD (2007a), Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investment: Recent Evidence and Policy
Analysis, OECD Tax Policy Studies No. 17, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264038387-en.
OECD (2007b), Fundamental Reform of Corporate Income Tax, OECD Tax Policy
Studies No. 16, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264038127en.
OECD (2008), Reforming Corporate Income Tax, Policy Briefs, OECD Publishing.
OECD (2009), Taxation and Economic Growth, Economic Policy Reforms, Going for
Growth, Chapter 5, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/growth-2009en.
OECD (2013), Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264202719-en.
OECD (2014a), Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digital Economy, OECD/G20 Base
Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264218789-en.
OECD (2014b), Neutralising the Effects of Hybrid Mismatch Arrangements, OECD/G20
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264218819-en.
OECD (2014c), Countering Harmful Tax Practices more Effectively, Taking into account
Transparency and Substance, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project,
OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264218970-en.
OECD (2014d), Standard for Automatic Exchange of Financial Information in Tax
Matters, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264216525-en.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 187
188 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Notes
1.
This annex was prepared by the OECD Economics Department in co-operation with
the Centre for Tax Policy and Administration and has been approved by the OECDs
Economic Policy Committee and the Committee on Fiscal Affairs.
2.
3.
The tax rate is the sum of the national and sub-national tax rate. For non-OECD
countries, data are sourced from KPMG and refer to 2000 (Russian Federation refers
to 2001 instead of 2000) and 2013.
4.
5.
In the case of e-commerce or the sale of online services, there can be an ambiguity
over where the profit of a firm is generated. For example, a firm may conduct
substantial sales of goods and services in a market from a remote location and with
minimal use of personnel (OECD, 2014a). As it is not possible to ring-fence the
digital economy from the rest of the economy, no separate analysis was conducted of
profit shifting associated with the digital economy. The assumption underlying the
empirical analysis is that the location of assets (including purchased intangible assets
reported in financial accounts) or employees represents a relevant proxy for the true
activity of a firm.
6.
MNEs may also shift certain activities (e.g. R&D activities) to benefit from
preferential tax treatment on the related income. This is not considered as BEPS, but
is included in the empirical analysis as it cannot be disentangled from BEPS channels
with the available data. It was agreed in the BEPS Project that the preferential
treatment of intellectual property should be coupled with substantial activity
requirements to prevent harmful tax competition (OECD, 2014c).
7.
In worldwide taxation systems, the location of headquarters determines the tax rate
applying to worldwide profits. Thus, MNEs have an incentive to locate their
headquarters in lower-tax countries (so-called tax inversion). However, the empirical
analysis found no conclusive evidence that MNE headquarters are predominantly
located in high or low-tax countries.
8.
In some cases, reported and taxable profits differ because a firm exploits mismatches
between tax systems to reduce its taxable profit (e.g. by deducting the same expense
in more than one country) and thus its tax burden (Lisowsky, 2010). Such tax
planning situations cannot be identified by analysing the location of profits using
financial account data, but they are captured in the empirical analysis of mismatches
between tax systems, which focuses on how reported profits are taxed.
9.
MNEs are firms belonging to corporate groups present in at least two countries.
Domestic groups are firms in corporate groups present in only one country.
Standalone firms are firms belonging to no group (i.e. with no affiliate and no
parent company). Not identified firms are assigned in different categories by the
identification algorithm depending on the ownership threshold (i.e. 50% or 90%)
chosen to link companies. All business forms (corporations, limited liability
partnerships, etc.) are included in ORBIS data.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 189
10.
The share of domestic groups and MNEs appears implausibly low in the Netherlands,
which probably reflects missing ownership links in the ORBIS database for this
country. This may also be the case for other countries.
11.
The data are based on the ORBIS sample used in the analysis and may not be
representative of the underlying population, particularly for specific countries.
12.
Only countries covered in the OECD STAN business demography statistics database
are presented. Large firms are firms with more than 250 employees. When the
number of employees is not available in ORBIS, turnover or total assets are used as
alternative size measures (with respective thresholds of EUR 50 million and EUR 43
million, in line with the EU definition). Brazil and Iceland refers to manufacturing,
Japan is 2012 in STAN as compared to 2009 in ORBIS (large firms is 50+
employees), Iceland 2005, Brazil 2008 and Switzerland 2009.
13.
A MNE entity is considered as having a link to a given country if at least one entity in
its corporate group is present in this country. A MNE entity is considered as large if it
has more than 250 employees. The figures presented are computed based on all
observations in the ORBIS sample used in this study over the period 2000-2010.
Countries with less than 1200 observations of large MNE entities are not presented.
14.
The data are based on the ORBIS sample used in the analysis and may not be
representative of the underlying population, particularly for specific countries.
15.
The statutory corporate tax is usually considered as the relevant tax rate on shifted
profits (Gravelle, 2014). Lower effective tax rates (for example because of
preferential tax treatment) are captured in the second part of the empirical analysis
(mismatches between tax systems).
16.
17.
18.
A 50% threshold is commonly used in the tax literature for defining corporate groups
(e.g. Huizinga and Laeven, 2008; Maffini and Mokkas, 2011). The rationale is that
profit shifting would generally not take place between two companies that are not
under the same control. By contrast, foreign direct investment statistics use a 10%
ownership threshold.
19.
190 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
20.
A few papers (e.g. Markle and Shackelford, 2011) include the effect of mismatches in
their estimates, but without disentangling them from profit shifting.
21.
Shifted (non-shifted) patents are patents where the inventor is located in a different
(the same) country than the MNE entity applying for the patent protection. For
example, the United States accounts for 42% of global patent applications, out of
which 35% are invented in the country and 7% are invented in another country.
Worldwide patent applications refer to the sum of patent applications (shifted and
non-shifted) made by the 38 countries included in the analysis (see Panel B). Patent
applications refer to applications to two major patent offices (i.e. the United States
Patent and Trademark Office (USTPO) and the European Patent Office (EPO)) and
patents filed under the Patent Co-Operation Treaty (PCT).
22.
23.
It was agreed in the BEPS Project that the preferential treatment of intellectual
property should be coupled with substantial activity requirements to prevent
harmful tax competition (OECD, 2014c).
24.
Existing intellectual property regimes in the OECD and G20 that do not meet the
agreed standard for substantial activity should close to new entrants in June 2016 and
stop operating in June 2021 (G20 communiqu, February 2015).
25.
The patent protection may cover different countries than the one where the applying
firm is located depending on the patent office where the patent is registered.
26.
MNEs also have incentives to deviate from market interest rates on internal debt in
order to shift profit. However, interest payments between related entities are generally
regulated by the arms length principle as other internal transactions.
27.
28.
The indicator is compiled for 2005 and 2014. In the empirical analysis, the value for
2005 is used, which corresponds to the middle of the sample period.
29.
The figure shows the percentage of GDP devoted to accounting, tax preparation,
bookkeeping and payroll services, as a proxy for tax consultancy industry. It includes
services unrelated to tax, but also excludes economic resources devoted to tax
including tax legal services and corporations in-house tax staffs.
30.
The effect of international tax planning on other taxes and social contributions goes
beyond the scope of this study. If international tax planning results from artificial
financial flows and does not affect the location of real economic activity, the impact
on other taxes and social contributions should be limited.
31.
Figures as a share of GDP assume that CIT revenues represent 3% of GDP, which is
close to the OECD average.
32.
33.
The range is based on sensitivity around the point estimate of the tax planning
sensitivity. The sensitivity analysis assumes a 95% confidence interval (i.e. about two
standard errors on each side) around the point estimate of the profit shifting and
mismatch estimates.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 191
34.
The revenue effect is based on the assumption that firms outside the sample have the
same tax elasticity (i.e. profit shifting elasticity and average tax differential) as firms
in the sample. The sensitivity analysis assumes a 50% higher tax elasticity of firms
outside the sample relative to firms in the sample. The assumption is that 50% of
firms are covered in the hypothetical country.
35.
36.
Data on tax credits is limited and the data used in this study were provided to the
OECD as part of the work on Action 11 and most often refer to the year 2011. A
caveat is that tax credits are volatile and that relying on data for only one year may
not to be representative of the general size of tax credits.
37.
The underlying assumption is that non-OECD and non-G20 countries lose on average
4-10% of corporate tax revenues, which is the same as the countries in the sample. On
average in non-OECD non-G20 countries, corporate tax revenues as a share of GDP
is about 50% higher than in countries in the sample (data on corporate tax revenues
for these countries is sourced from available national sources and the IMF).
38.
Other factors including the taxation of capital at the personal level can also affect
financing decisions.
39.
One option is to allow tax deductibility for the opportunity cost of equity finance (socalled allowance for corporate equity, ACE) as introduced in Belgium and Italy over
the past decade. Another option is to remove interest deductibility altogether (socalled comprehensive business income tax, CBIT). These options are discussed
extensively in the literature (e.g. OECD, 2007; de Mooij, 2012).
40.
41.
Manipulating the location of group debt may increase bankruptcy risks of the entities
where debt is located if there is no perfect risk sharing within the group. However,
MNE entities are generally thought to benefit from explicit or implicit guarantee from
their parents (see Huizinga et al., 2008, footnote 9).
42.
New international guidelines for compiling FDI statistics are currently being
implemented. These guidelines recommend, among other things, to identify capital
being channelled through special purpose entities, which are known to be used for tax
planning. Once these data are available, the effect of tax differentials on FDI can be
refined
by
excluding
activities
of
special
entities
(see
www.oecd.org/daf/inv/oecdimplementsnewinternationalstandardsforcompilingfdistati
stics.htm).
43.
In the case of location of investment, the relevant tax rate is the effective tax rate, as it
takes into account the generosity of tax depreciation allowance of the investment and
other tax provisions. The results presented in this study rely on statutory rates since
effective tax rates are only available for a limited set of countries. However, the
findings are robust to using effective rates for a smaller set of countries.
44.
Few studies exist on the role of international tax planning for investment and most of
the existing ones focus on one specific country, such as the United States or Germany
(Grubert 2003; Overesch, 2009).
192 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
45.
Using tax data for the United States, Grubert (2003) shows that R&D-intensive MNEs
are more likely than other MNEs to invest in countries with either very high or very
low tax rates. Investments in very-low-tax countries may serve in the setting up of
tax-planning schemes. Investment in very-high-tax countries are attractive for taxplanning MNEs, since tax-planning allows them to avoid most of the high tax burden
that non-tax-planning firms have to face in these countries.
46.
Forward looking marginal tax rates are sourced from the Centre for the Oxford Centre
for Business Taxation. They derive from modelling a hypothetical investment project
taking into account all relevant tax provisions. By construction, they do not include
the effect of international tax planning.
47.
The corporate tax rate considered is the marginal forward-looking effective tax rate.
All differences in the reaction of investment to tax rate changes are significant at a
5% level.
48.
49.
Another justification for capital income taxes is that they can provide insurance
against future poor labour market outcomes (see Golosov et al., 2006). In a setting
when there is uncertainty about individuals future skills (productivity) and leisure is
a normal good, more savings today, all else equal, will reduce work incentives later
on. Thus, discouraging savings through capital income taxation increase the
governments ability to provide insurance against future labour market risks.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 193
Annex 3.A2
A toolkit for estimating the country-specific fiscal effects of BEPS
countermeasures
Introduction
When countries consider introducing BEPS countermeasures, estimates of the fiscal and
economic effects may be needed. Tax policy analysts can provide government officials
and other stakeholders with evidence-based analysis of the fiscal and economic effects of
options to curtail BEPS behaviours.
The BEPS Action Plan states that It is important to identify the types of data that
taxpayers should provide to tax administrators, as well as the methodologies that can be
used to analyse these data and to assess the likely economic implications of BEPS
behaviours and actions taken to address BEPS. Action 11 also involves ensuring that
tools are available to monitor and evaluate the effectiveness and economic impact of the
actions taken to address BEPS on an ongoing basis.1
This annex is intended to provide government tax administration and tax policy offices,
as well as other stakeholders, with a toolkit of methodological approaches that could be
used to estimate the fiscal effects of BEPS countermeasures. The fiscal effects estimates,
which may incorporate taxpayer behaviour, are often an important starting point for
analysis of other economic effects of legislative changes. While the toolkit discusses each
of the BEPS Actions separately, the general estimation approach will be familiar to most
government policy analysts responsible for analysing proposed tax legislation.
In a recent survey of the academic literature, Riedel (2014) notes: The most convincing
empirical evidence has been presented by academic studies that investigate specific profit
shifting channels as their empirical tests are more direct and offer less room for results
being driven by mechanisms unrelated to income shifting. This is an important insight in
the discussion of the fiscal effects of BEPS countermeasures, and many of these empirical
studies analysing specific profit shifting channels have been drawn upon in constructing
the methodological approaches in this annex.
The toolkit presented in this annex focuses on practical approaches that tax policy
analysts could use to estimate the fiscal effects of BEPS countermeasures for their
country. Given that each country has different data and will begin from different starting
points, several alternative approaches are often suggested. Some countries may introduce
the full suite of BEPS countermeasures, while others may introduce selected BEPS
countermeasures. For this reason, the proposed methodologies are distinguished by
action. This is in line with the scope of Action 11 of the BEPS Action Plan.2
Government estimates of the fiscal effects of domestic tax law changes are not new, and
some countries have already estimated the fiscal effects of certain BEPS-related tax
policy measures. It is worth noting that individual country fiscal effects from unilateral
measures do not take into account spillover effects in other countries. For example,
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
194 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
implementing an interest limitation rule will reduce debt and interest deductions in the
implementing country, but affected MNEs could shift debt and interest deductions to
other countries with weaker rules. The effect on global BEPS and global revenue would
be very different in respect of multilateral BEPS countermeasures compared to unilateral
measures.
A number of governments view the closure of loopholes as base protection measures and,
as a result, do not estimate the associated fiscal effects. This is also the case for many of
the BEPS-related countermeasures, which may be treated as measures that protect
forecasted budget revenue, not as incremental new revenue to the current-law revenue
projections.3 Thus, while a number of BEPS-related countermeasures have been enacted
over the past ten years, they have sometimes been seen as measures to protect the tax
base, and have not been officially scored as raising revenue relative to current tax
projections.
Some countries have estimated the fiscal effects of BEPS-related countermeasures
enacted or proposed. Table 3.A2.1 provides a summary of the fiscal estimates of BEPSrelated countermeasures in selected countries as a percentage of their total corporate
income tax (CIT) revenue. The revenue effects are approximate because the total CIT
revenue does not always refer to the same year for which the revenue estimates were
computed. Moreover, some revenue estimates refer to a period, but the number of years
included is not always explicitly stated. Measures that were implemented in prior years
may yield different fiscal estimates if estimated today or in future where general
macroeconomic conditions may be different. For interest limitation rules in particular,
because some of the fiscal estimates were introduced during a period of higher interest
rates; introducing them in the current interest rate environment may result in a lower
estimate. The fiscal estimates also depend on whether a country has implemented other
policy measures simultaneously and how the estimates of these measures may have been
integrated to avoid overlapping. Also, if these countries had existing countermeasures in
place, then the fiscal estimate would only be for the incremental revenue effect of the new
interest limitation rule, not the effect of the countrys total interest limitation rule. The
estimate would also be sensitive to the macroeconomic conditions at the time of
introduction.
Table 3.A2.1. Government fiscal estimates of BEPS-related measures
Country
Measure
Denmark
France
Germany
Norway
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
Year of enactment
(unless stated
otherwise)
2007
2014
2008
8.6%
2014
2013
2010
3.4%
8.5%
0.6%
2014
0.3%
2017
0.2%
Proposal (2015)
for enactment 2016
4.0%
Proposal (2015)
for enactment 2016
1.1%
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 195
196 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
be important to determine the appropriate counterfactual and whether proposed
countermeasures will be revenue protecting or revenue raising in nature.
Figure 3.A2.1. Potential approach to undertaking a fiscal estimate
Understanding the proposed change
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 197
taxpayers will be necessary, especially given the missing data problems with available
databases. Macroeconomic data may help calibrate financial account data and assist in an
extrapolation. Caution must be exercised when interpreting the results from financial
accounts due to the differences between tax expense reported for accounting purposes and
the actual tax paid by a business. A good strategy would be to understand the potential
sources of discrepancy and make suitable adjustments.
In the absence of a database of financial account micro-data, an alternative would be to
analyse a statistical sample, or the financial statements of the top MNEs in the country. It
is important to note that a statistical sample would be preferable to focusing on a
concentrated group of MNEs. While focusing on the top MNEs may capture a significant
proportion of the total economic activity affected, extrapolating beyond this group may
result in an overestimate of the fiscal effect. Using a true statistical sample of taxpayers
that would be affected by a policy measure would provide a better representation of the
economy and thus a better sample from which to extrapolate. The number of groups
chosen for the sample will depend on domestic factors and should have a good
representation across sectors to adequately reflect sectorial contribution to GDP and
whether certain sectors are more affected than others by the countermeasure(s) proposed.
If no micro-data is available, macro-data can be used. It is possible to find data on many
of the transactions that are likely to be affected by BEPS, including imports/exports,
sales, interest receipts and payments, and dividends and royalties. These are often
available in national accounts and balance of payments (BOP) data. It is also possible that
the data is available for bilateral exports/imports and/or FDI with other countries.
If no macro-data relevant to the countermeasure is available for the country, analogous
data from similar economies could be sourced, as well as information from empirical
studies. Some empirical studies have useful information on issues that relate directly to
BEPS behaviours.
198 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
between key variables. In the BEPS context, it is also critical to understand the various
incentives to engage in BEPS behaviours as these will also affect the size of the affected
tax base. Combining the knowledge from the prior steps effectively will enable an
informed determination of the size of the tax base that is likely to be affected by the
policy measure.
Deciding on the applicable marginal tax rate for the type of income shifted
Once the affected tax base has been calculated, it will be necessary to determine the
applicable tax rate to apply to the estimated change in the tax base. This will depend on
the type of income stream, whether the expansion in the tax base will be taxed at the
margin, and the specific rules implemented. The simplest tax rate to use is the headline
statutory tax rate, but in many cases (particularly in the BEPS context) this may not be the
best choice given that many countries have special regimes that have substantially lower
statutory CIT rates on certain income. For example, patent box regimes reduce the CIT
rate on IP-related income and some countries have special arrangements with taxpayers
that result in negligible tax liabilities. Effective tax rates may not be appropriate either; if
an increase in the tax base should be taxed at the margin, an effective tax rate (ETR)
would understate the fiscal effect in situations where investment allowances and tax
credits reduce the ETR.
The starting point would be the applicable marginal tax rate (AMTR), which is the rate
applied to an increase in taxable income as it would be taxed at the margin. Downward
adjustments may be required for a variety of reasons. For example, businesses in an
assessed loss position for tax purposes would not have their current tax liability affected
by an incremental increase in taxable income. Having access to micro-data would not
require an adjustment as the exact AMTR would be applied in the micro-simulation
model. However, in recognition of the fact that a certain portion of firms would be in a
tax loss position, a fiscal estimate relying on macro-data would require a downward
adjustment in the statutory marginal tax rate. If no adjustment is made, it is likely to result
in an overestimate of the fiscal effect.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 199
macroeconomic effect. Since any business tax increase from reducing BEPS would result
in lower taxes to other actors, increased government spending, or a reduction in the
governments budget deficit, overall macroeconomic effects are unlikely to be significant
given the offsetting effects. If significant macroeconomic effects are anticipated, the tax
administration and tax policy offices would generally work with other government offices
to estimate the overall budget effect.
Including behavioural responses for unilateral measures is different to doing so for
multilateral action as discussed in the introduction. There are multiple empirical studies
on taxpayer responses to tax rate differentials and specific tax policy changes that have
been implemented, all of which can provide useful insights to analysts.
There are also factors outside of the legislated policy change that need to be factored into
a fiscal estimate. In the lead up to introducing new legislation announced, many countries
have processes in place that could include the release of a discussion document to seek
public comments; parliamentary sessions; and engagement with taxpayers. The time
taken for these processes can result in taxpayers changing their behaviour to avoid being
affected by the new legislation. This is something that could be factored into behavioural
responses.
The level of enforcement is also important. Weak enforcement could render a good policy
measure ineffective if taxpayers can easily avoid paying the taxes due. For this reason, it
may be appropriate to factor in a measure of expected effectiveness in terms of how
successful the revenue authority will be at enforcing the countermeasure.
200 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
accurately; stacking affects the size of the individual components, not the total, while
reducing potential double-counting.
Stacking is important in estimating the fiscal effect of multiple policy measures to
eliminate double counting. A few examples of potential overlaps in the BEPS context
include: (1) if transfer pricing changes are stacked first, taxable income will be more
appropriately taxed where the value is created based on the new transfer pricing rules, so
taxable income that might be affected by Action 3 or Action 7 if implemented in isolation
will have already been included in the Actions 8-10 transfer pricing fiscal estimates; (2)
As both Action 4 and transfer pricing rules affect interest payments, caution will need to
be exercised in terms of distinguishing between the correct pricing of interest (or
payments equivalent to interest) and interest resulting from excessive leverage; and (3)
while Action 2 would raise revenue by eliminating hybrid mismatch arrangements
relative to current law in isolation, Action 4 and Action 6s fiscal effects could pick up
most of the fiscal effects that Action 2 would otherwise have generated. Thus, stacking
and potentially treating some countermeasures as integrity measures, which increase the
effectiveness of other countermeasures, can significantly reduce the possibility of doublecounting.
Synergies between multiple countermeasures are expected to have a more powerful effect
on reducing BEPS behaviours than individual countermeasures in isolation. Thus, the
sum of the parts may be less than the effect of the combined package. Countries could
consider the likely effectiveness of the individual countermeasures as a specific parameter
to be used in the estimate, as highlighted in the discussion of behavioural effects. The
effectiveness parameter includes not only the coverage of the proposed legislation, but
also the expected enforcement of the legislation. This parameter can be adjusted for
certain countermeasures to incorporate potential synergistic effects, with possible
sensitivity analysis around that adjustment.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 201
Since empirical studies have focused more on transfer pricing and the tax-motivated debt
bias relative to other BEPS behaviours, the proposed methodologies for the individual
Actions are arranged accordingly. The most comprehensive methodologies are provided
for Actions 8-10 and 13 (transfer pricing) and Action 4 (interest limitation rules).
Approaches to estimating the fiscal effects of the other Actions will also discuss the fiscal
estimation issues involved in respect of those countermeasures and highlight potential
available data. These Actions will contribute to addressing BEPS more effectively
through increased disclosure, reducing harmful tax practices, improving dispute
resolution, and speeding up the implementation of the treaty changes. In some cases,
some of these Actions are designed as integrity measures complementing other Actions;
such Actions will often enhance the effectiveness of other Actions such as transfer pricing
rules and interest limitations.
Actions 8-10 and 13 (Transfer Pricing)
The overall objective of Actions 8-10 is the improved allocation of corporate taxable
income to the countries where the economic activity generating the profits occurs.
Specific objectives of the three Actions include developing rules that prevent BEPS
caused by moving intangibles among group members (Action 8); transferring risks
among, or allocating excessive capital to, group members (Action 9); and engaging in
transactions which would not, or would only very rarely, occur between third parties
(Action 10).
Understanding the proposed changes
The following changes or clarifications in the transfer pricing guidance will reduce the
size of BEPS related to transfer mispricing and are particularly relevant to a fiscal
estimate:
Increased specificity in delineating the actual transactions in the context of a MNE
groups economic activities and commercial and financial relations between the
associated enterprises. This includes ensuring that both contractual arrangements
and the actual conduct of the parties are taken into account in delineating the actual
transaction for which it needs to be determined whether the conditions, including
the price, are at arms length;
Providing for the possible non-recognition of transactions when they lack the
commercial rationality of arrangements between unrelated parties;
Strengthening the identification of risk in order to determine which associated
enterprise assumes the risk for transfer pricing purposes. This includes ensuring
that the assumption of risk by an entity is consistent with the exercising of control
over the risk and with the financial capacity to assume the risk and is not only
determined by the contractual assumption of risk;
Providing for a more detailed evaluation of the activities related to the
development, enhancement, maintenance, protection and exploitation of
intangibles, and the allocation of profits generated by these intangibles in line with
the importance of these functions;
Provisions requiring that synergistic benefits deriving from membership of a MNE
group are appropriately allocated through arms length prices to members of the
group contributing to the benefits;
202 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
More detailed guidance on the pricing of transactions, including pricing of low
value-adding services and commodities; and
Introduction of measures to address the asymmetry of information between
taxpayers and tax administrations, such as in the cases of hard-to-value intangibles
and the timing of commodity transactions, thus preventing mispricing of
transactions involving such intangibles and commodities.
In addition, Action 13 will enhance the relevance of transfer pricing documentation, and
provide information about the MNE groups global allocation of revenues and activities.
Mandatory Country-by-Country Reporting will provide more information to tax
administrations to conduct risk assessments.
Data and methodology
Estimating the scale of transfer pricing-related BEPS and the effect of Actions 8-10 and
13 involves two distinct steps. First, an estimate is required of the net impact (increase or
decrease) on CIT collections of BEPS relating to the mispricing of transactions. This
estimate has two significant components: (1) the mispricing of transactions that are
observed in a countrys trade in goods and services data, and (2) BEPS-related
transactions that are misallocated in the trade data for specific countries. An example of
the second category would be missing royalty payments to a country that creates IP from
in-country R&D expenditures, if BEPS attributes the value of the IP (and related income
streams) to another country through transfer prices that are not in line with the location of
activities that created the IP. Both aspects of the fiscal impact of BEPS should be
included in the revenue estimates.
Second, an estimate of the overall impact of the proposed changes in transfer pricing rules
and guidance presented in the Report on Actions 8-10 (Aligning Transfer Pricing
Outcomes with Value Creation, OECD, 2015a) can be applied to the estimated scale of
BEPS from mispricing to determine the expected changes in CIT revenues attributable to
the implementation of the BEPS Actions. The purpose of the second step is to prepare a
revenue estimate of the expected change in CIT revenues due to the adoption and
implementation of the revised transfer pricing guidance. The extent of the changes
adopted, as well as the timing of their implementation will vary from country to country.
The suggested methodology addresses: (a) mispricing of goods and services transactions
between MNE entities, and (b) mispricing of interest payments among MNE entities.5
The methodology described is based on country-specific, macroeconomic data on trade
and interest flows to estimate the scale of BEPS and the fiscal effects of the guidance in
the Report on Actions 8-10. Where other data, including firm-level micro-data or more
disaggregated macro-data, is available for the country, analysts should take advantage of
this. If information, such as that obtained from audits, is available, alternative
methodologies may be appropriate.
a.
The estimation exercise begins with data on trade in goods and services, which includes
the combined effects of mispricing of goods and services. In the presence of BEPS, it is
expected that trade among MNE entities results in underreporting of profits in countries
with marginal tax rates higher than the domestic countrys marginal tax rate and overreporting of profits in countries with lower marginal tax rates. This profit shifting occurs
through the mispricing of transfer prices on MNE intra-firm trade flows of both exports
and imports.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 203
Detailed macroeconomic data on the total amount of annual exports and imports by
country (for both goods and services, where available), as well as bilateral export and
import flows with countries trading partners, is available from the OECD International
Trade Account data and IMF Direction of Trade Statistics.6 To the extent that more
detailed information from a national statistics office is available for individual countries,
analysts should take advantage of such information.
The international trade data includes both goods and services for OECD and G20
countries, but data for service flows may be limited for other countries. Separate
estimates of mispricing should be prepared for goods and for services when the data is
available. International trade transactions in services include a number of components
that may be affected by BEPS.
Revenue estimators need to understand what is included in the trade data. For example,
recent changes to the international standards for reporting balance of payments statistics
currently being implemented will expand available information on a countrys trade in
services related to intangible property. The new standards call for the capitalisation of
R&D expenditures. This will provide a basis for reporting the value of transfers of the
ownership of intangibles produced by R&D expenditures as a component of trade in
R&D services. However, many intangible asset values are significantly greater than the
capitalised value of their inputs, so potential shifted income may need to be adjusted from
the reported trade value. This is in addition to the already included services data on the
payments for the use of intellectual property.7 In countries that have not yet adopted this
change, the transfer of ownership rights in intangible property is unlikely to be included
in the trade in services category.
Estimators must also consider potential transfer pricing adjustments to currently reported
bilateral trade data. An example would be the potential reallocation of royalties paid by
an operating affiliate in one country to a tax haven entity, which may not be fully
reflected in royalties paid by the tax haven entity to the entity in the country actually
conducting the R&D. In this triangular conduit trade example, actual trade data would not
accurately reflect the expected income distribution.
Adjusting trade data to reflect MNE intra-firm transactions
Because BEPS mispricing occurs between MNE entities, it is necessary to reduce total
trade flows to those that are potentially subject to mispricing among related companies.
This requires estimating several key parameters:
The percentage of international transactions accounted for by corporations subject
to the CIT;8
The percentage of the resulting trade flows accounted for by MNEs (i.e. the trade
flows excluding exports/imports by domestic companies to/from unrelated parties);
and
The share of MNE trade transactions that represent transactions among related
MNE entities.
There are several possible sources of information that could provide a basis for estimating
these ratios. The first is tax return information of taxpayers identified as MNEs. The
relative size of their taxable income or taxes paid, compared to other business taxpayers
in the country, is a possible starting point. In addition, specific countries may conduct
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
204 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
surveys of MNEs and other corporations that collect information on their activities, such
as data on Activities of Multinational Enterprises (AMNE) that identifies intra-firm
transactions.9 Customs data and other national statistics could be used. If this type of
information is not available for the country, reported ratios from other countries with
similar economies and trade patterns could be used for the estimates.
Figure 3.A2.2 provides examples of the values for the key trade-related parameters for the
limited number of countries that report this information.
The aggregate trade amounts can be multiplied by the above fractions to estimate the
percentage of total trade accounted for by transactions between MNE entities.10
Figure 3.A2.2. Intra-firm transactions as a percent of selected trade statistics
Intra-firm exports as % of total manufacturing exports
70%
60%
50%
65%
64%
57%
49%
48%
51%
50%
47%
43%
39%
40%
32%
30%
24%
22%
18%
20%
10%
10%
0%
Canada
Finland
Israel
Italy
Japan
Netherlands
Poland
Sweden
United States
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 205
distribution chain accumulates in the gross trade flows.11 A portion of the trade flows
represent MNE intra-firm sales. The question is how this pyramiding affects the
accuracy of BEPS mispricing estimates based on the trade data.
While it is true that the intermediate goods and services lead to gross trade flows that
overstate the value added contribution in each country in the supply chain, it does not
necessarily follow that mispricing would only apply to the new value added by each
country in the supply chain. Mispricing may still be based on the gross value of sales, not
the smaller amount of in-country value added.
If a country determines that the use of gross trade data overstates the potential base for
transfer mispricing, an adjustment could be made to reduce the trade figures to address
this issue. For example, a country could reduce gross exports of goods by an estimated
percentage of the export that is accounted for by imports of intermediate goods from
other countries. A possible source for this percentage is the OECD Trade in Value Added
database that includes an estimate of foreign value added as a percent of a countrys
exports.12 This percentage ranges from 14% to 59% for OECD countries with a simple
average of 30%. If a country is excluded from the OECD database, an estimate could be
based on the figures for other countries with similar economies and trade patterns.
206 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
the present value of taxes of the two related entities. The tax reduction could be a
permanent reduction in tax equal to the statutory tax rate if the entity with the net
operating loss would be unable to use those net operating losses in a future year due to
carry-forward limitations.
For reference, the global weighted (by exports for the OECD and G20 countries) average
tax rate differential, using 2014 statutory tax rates and 2012 trade flows, was
3.3 percentage points, implying a net shifting out of profits and thus decrease in corporate
tax revenues.17 Depending on the home countrys AMTR relative to its trading partners,
the AMTR differential could be negative, in which case the country could be benefitting
from taxable income being shifted into the country with a coincident increase in corporate
tax revenues. If the AMTR differential is positive, the country could be experiencing a
shifting out of taxable income with a coincident decrease in corporate tax revenues.
Countries with AMTRs in excess of the weighted average of their trading partners had a
weighted average differential of 4.6 percentage points. The average tax rate differential
for the group of countries with home country AMTRs less than their trading partners was
-1.3 percentage points.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 207
Table 3.A2.2. Elasticity estimates of the responsiveness of intra-firm exports and imports to
corporate income tax rate differentials
Time
Period
Tax
Variable
1993-2000
STR
-0.65 to -1.6
semi-elasticities
Clausing (2003)
1997-1999
STR
-1.8 to -2.0
elasticities
Clausing (2006)
1982-2000
STR
-1.3
semi-elasticity
Overesch (2006)
1996-2003
STR
-1.45
semi-elasticity
1999
EATR
-0.24 elasticity
Vicard (2015)
2000-2014
STR
-0.23
semi-elasticity
1999-2006
STR
-0.64 to -0.82
semi-elasticities
Study
Data
Elasticity
Notes: STR is statutory tax rate; EATR is the backward-looking average tax rate.
To calculate the percentage difference in the trade prices of exports and imports due to
BEPS mispricing, the appropriately determined semi-elasticity value could be multiplied
by the applicable differential tax rates in each country, before applying the resulting
percentage to an estimated value of exports and imports with related parties in each
country that are potentially subject to BEPS-related mispricing. The first part can be
represented as:
Percentage difference in trade prices = (semi-elasticity) x (AMTRhome weighted average
AMTRtrade partners)
For example, with a semi-elasticity of -1 and an AMTR differential of +5 percentage
points, there could be a 5 percent reduction in trade prices.
With the simplifying assumption that there is no change in quantities traded as a result of
the mispricing of exports and imports, the estimated percentage change in prices is equal
to the percentage change in the value of trade. This calculation provides an estimate of
the BEPS-related change in the value of imports and exports of goods and services due to
the mispricing of observed transactions. In other words, it is an estimate of the change in
value that would result if the BEPS incentive due to the tax rate differentials did not exist,
assuming the estimated elasticities reflect only BEPS after accounting for real economic
effects.
The final fiscal estimate assumption is that a one unit change in exports and imports
translates into a one unit change in the CIT base. The resulting estimated change in a
countrys CIT tax base can then be multiplied by the AMTR to derive an initial estimate
of the potential maximum annual CIT revenue impact of BEPS mispricing of reported
goods and services. An adjustment would be required to recognise that a portion of firms
may be in an assessed loss position for tax purposes.
208 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
BEPS can also result from overstating interest paid on intra-firm loans by entities in
higher-tax countries and understating interest paid by entities in lower-tax countries. The
trade flow data used to estimate the BEPS impacts of trade mispricing does not include
interest payments and receipts.22
The IMF Co-ordinated Direct Investment Survey (CDIS) database provides data on BOP
statistics for FDI payments and receipts of interest between related parties that could be
used for estimating the revenue impact of interest payment mispricing. The data is for the
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 209
Combining the fiscal estimates for the mispricing of goods, services and interest
payments provides an aggregate estimate of the net revenue impact of BEPS under the
current law (the scale of BEPS). This provides a starting point (or counterfactual) for
estimating the expected fiscal impact of the revised transfer pricing guidance in the
Report on Actions 8-10.
The first step in estimating the budget impacts of the combined guidance requires
specifying the proposed or adopted administrative and legal changes that will better
address transfer-pricing related BEPS. Each Action could have a different effect, or could
be estimated jointly. The next step requires determining what percentage of current BEPS
would be eliminated due to the revised transfer pricing guidance. In other words, what is
the change in tax revenues that can be expected from the revised guidance? The following
should be considered in estimating these fiscal impacts.
210 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
a range of estimates for arms length prices chosen to reflect comparable transactions
among unrelated parties. Tax administrations generally accept transfer pricing estimates
that fall within a range (e.g. inter-quartile) of the estimates. As a result, some of the
estimated transfer mispricing may still fall within the acceptable transfer pricing range
and not result in a change in taxable income. A second possibility is that audit resources
are targeted on cases involving large expected outcomes. An adjustment factor could be
applied to the estimate of collections from eliminating mispricing to account for such
institutional features of the transfer pricing compliance system.
Additional adjustments
The initial estimate of transactions at risk of mispricing could be reduced for
certain types of trade considered to be less subject to mispricing;
The extent to which existing anti-avoidance rules are already effective in the
country should be factored into the fiscal impact estimates. An adjustment should
be made to reflect the relative strength of the countrys rules compared to the rules
implicit in the elasticity estimate used and the revised guidance that is
implemented; and
The country-specific impacts of the revised guidance will also depend upon the
timing of its implementation. This will affect the change in revenues calculated on
an annual basis.
Possible sources of information to estimate the adjustments include:
Input from income tax auditors and tax administrators on the potential impacts of
the changes on both voluntary compliance and audit results;
Revenue estimates prepared by estimators in other countries, including early
adopters of the revised guidance;
Results from empirical studies of profit shifting with different levels of transfer
pricing rules and enforcement levels; and
The first Country-by-Country Reports (CbCRs) will be filed for 2016 calendar year
filers no later than 31 December 2017. Enhanced transfer pricing documentation,
including CbCR information for MNEs with entities in the country, will thus be
available for statistical analysis following the filing of these reports and will
provide increased information for transfer pricing risk assessment. CbCR
information will provide an additional resource for improving the marginal tax rate
differential estimate with individual group data and for assessing this key
percentage.
Similar to evaluating the scale of BEPS and the effects of other BEPS Actions, the fiscal
effects of Actions 8, 9, 10 and 13 will not show up in a line on a future tax return. They
will need to be estimated based on available evidence. The effects of the Actions will
result in reduced mispricing as reported on the filed tax return, with a secondary effect of
more effective enforcement against any remaining misreporting. Ex post evaluation of the
estimated fiscal effects can involve conducting further empirical studies or examining
future literature on estimated profit shifting and changes in transfer pricing assessments
and settlements adjusted for levels of enforcement and other changes.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 211
212 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Possible additional design features: allowing carry-forward of disallowed interest
expense and/or unused interest capacity for use in future periods, or carry-back of
disallowed interest expense into earlier periods.
Specific rules to address issues raised by the banking and insurance sectors will be
developed, with this work to be completed in 2016.
Since countries may opt for different fixed ratios and supplement the fixed ratio with
additional design features of the best practice approach, some of which are outlined
above, the design of the interest limitation rules introduced in each country will influence
the estimation approach. In addition, countries differ in the level of detailed taxpayer data
that government tax policy analysts have access to. The following section outlines a
methodology (key steps, parameters, and assumptions) that may assist in estimation. The
methodology is separated into two potential approaches one using micro-data from tax
returns or financial reports and the other using a macro-approach. The approaches can be
used to estimate the change in fiscal cash collections on a year-by-year basis.
Data and methodology
Estimating the fiscal effect of interest limitation rules requires calculating the extent to
which the CIT base will be broadened by limiting interest deductions, and applying the
appropriate marginal tax rate to the increase in the base.29 It is important to take into
account the countrys existing excessive interest deduction countermeasures to determine
the incremental effect of the new rule. Also, it is important to recognise that taxpayers
may change their behaviour in response to interest limitation rules, which would result in
an adjustment to the static estimate. The magnitude of the behavioural response will
depend on the design of the rule and the extent to which interest limitations are
implemented on a multilateral basis, as well as non-tax determinants of capital structure,
such as prevailing interest rates.
With regard to a counterfactual, some countries may have existing countermeasures to
address excessive interest deductions in place, while others may not. For purposes of this
analysis, the starting point assumes no existing interest limitation rules: asset-based rules
(thin capitalisation rules) or interest limitation rules. If there are such rules, the amount of
revenue currently collected from those rules should be determined if possible from tax
returns, and then can be subtracted from the estimate relative to no interest limitation, to
estimate the incremental effect of the new rules. Countries with existing countermeasures
could opt to use current-law as the counterfactual in the estimation exercise.
Figure 3.A2.3 outlines the basic steps for estimating the fiscal effects of Action 4,
depending on whether micro or macro-level data will be used. The steps for each
approach are explained subsequently.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 213
Figure 3.A2.3 Potential steps to follow once data availability has been determined
What data is available for tax policy analysis?
Only entities
forming part of a
MNE group?
(A) Micro-data
(B) Macro-data
Determine total
amount of NIE in
the country
Only entities
forming part of
MNE & Domestic
groups?
All entities
(including standalone)?
Considerations for
focusing on
affected entities
Determine NIE
subject to rule
Adjustments:
- de-minimis rule
(if applicable)
- positive EBITDA
Adjustments:
- Internal interest
- de-minimis rule
(if applicable)
- positive EBITDA
Determine EBITDA
for affected entities
Applying a MTR to
the change in the
estimated tax base
Applying a MTR to
the change in the
estimated tax base
Dynamic effects:
- carry-forward
(if applicable)
- behavioural
considerations
Dynamic effects:
- carry-forward
(if applicable)
- behavioural
considerations
214 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
a.
Micro-data approach
Ideally, government tax policy analysts in each country would have access to business tax
returns to simulate the effects of the proposed interest limitation rule to obtain a static
fiscal effect, taking into account the different provisions of the countermeasure and the
AMTR of the additional income for different taxpayers. Individual company information
with NIE, EBITDA, and taxable (or financial) income can be used to estimate the static
fiscal effect for different fixed ratios, different de minimis rules, and different types of
taxpayers affected. The effect of a group ratio rule, the effect of a carry-forward / carryback rule, and behavioural effects would have to be separately estimated as adjustments
to the static revenue effect.
If tax return information is not available, but individual company financial information is
available, detailed simulations are possible, although adjustments for differences between
financial account information and tax bases will need to be considered. Also, given
potential lack of complete information from public financial accounts, macro-data for
total interest receipts and payments recorded in the country could help extrapolate the
micro-data to a total estimate.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 215
Adjustments
Once affected entities and total NIE have been determined, certain adjustments may need
to be incorporated. If the country legislates a de minimis threshold, all entities falling
below the threshold that would benefit from the carve-out will need to be dropped from
the population in the micro-simulation model. As part of the Action 4 best practice, it is
recommended that such a threshold be based on the total NIE of all entities in the local
group to avoid the possibility of fragmentation by establishing multiple entities, each of
which falls below the threshold.
216 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Applying an AMTR to the estimated increase in the tax base to arrive at a static
estimate
A micro-simulation model allows an appropriate tax rate to be calculated for each entity,
which could be applied to the estimated increase in the CIT base. Since any increase in
the corporate tax base will be taxed at the margin, the marginal tax rate is the most
appropriate measure.33 Using the top statutory tax rate may not be appropriate if there are
lower tax rates on certain taxpayers and/or accumulated tax credits or offsetting losses
that would lower the effective tax rate applied. It would be most appropriate to use the
effective tax rate calculated from the micro-simulation and note that it may be a
conservative estimate.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 217
they may have central financing functions and the transaction costs associated with
shifting debt could be high.
Substituting equity for debt or shifting debt from the implementing country to another
country would result in a revenue increase for the implementing country. Only if the
shifting of debt is between entities within the same country, would the behavioural effect
reduce the implementing countrys revenue effect.
Since interest deduction limitations would result in an increase in the tax base, affected
entities would experience an increase in their effective tax rate. Empirical studies
showing behavioural responses to changes in tax rate differentials could provide some
insights into the potential behavioural effects that may arise due to the enactment of
countermeasures.
Ruf and Schindler (2012) summarise empirical evidence on the German interest
limitation rules introduced in 2008. Buslei and Simmler (2012) and Dreler and
Scheuering (2012) find that firms respond by reducing debt-to-asset ratios.
b.
Macro-data approach
If individual company tax return or financial information is not available for the analysis,
then a macro-level approach can be attempted. The steps set out below offer a potential
estimation strategy that countries could pursue.
218 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
the statistics in order to compare with the entities that will be affected by the rule.
Depending on the design of the interest limitation rule, the affected entities in the data
may be over or underrepresented.
If none of the abovementioned options is available, aggregate financial account data may
be available for the non-financial corporate sector in the National Accounts most likely
produced by the central bank or National Statistics Office. The firms included in the nonfinancial corporate sector differ across countries and it will be necessary to check the
approach taken in the country. Some countries, for example, include quasi-corporations
in this classification.34 In the European Union (EU), only 7 out of 28 member countries
(Cyprus35, France, Hungary, Luxembourg, Romania, Slovak Republic and Spain) do not
employ the concept of quasi-corporation in their national accounts and, among the
remaining 21 member countries, only the Netherlands allocates all quasi-corporations to a
single institutional sector (i.e. the household sector). Hence, 20 out 28 EU member
countries have quasi-corporations in both their household and corporate sectors. Outside
the EU, there are also differing approaches, for example the United States does not use
the quasi-corporation concept, while South Africa does.
The OECD publishes data on interest payments and receipts for most OECD member
countries, as well as two non-OECD countries, one of which is a G20 country.
Table 3.A2.3 provides the NIE figure for these countries in 2012.36 The data provided for
the majority of countries has been adjusted for financial services indirectly measured
(FISIM), which estimates the difference between the higher interest rate that borrowers
pay in return for the financial service and the reference rate.37 Where information is
available, it is indicated whether quasi-corporations are included in the non-financial
sector.
The NIE figures in Table 3.A2.3 could be an over or under-estimate of affected NIE,
depending on how the interest limitation rules are designed. This will depend on which
entities are included in the National Accounts data compared to those affected by the rule.
With respect to the former, there are two important considerations: whether quasicorporations are included in the non-financial corporate sector, and whether interest
payments and receipts are recorded on a legal entity or enterprise group basis. This will
determine whether the aggregate NIE figure includes / excludes related party interest
payments. If it is based on the legal entity, NIE would include intra-group interest
payments and it will not be necessary to make an adjustment.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 219
Table 3.A2.3. NIE by the non-financial corporate sector in billions of USD (2012)
Country
OECD
Austria
Belgium
Chile*
Czech Republic
Denmark*
Estonia
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Hungary
Ireland
Italy
Japan*
Korea*
Mexico*
Netherlands
New Zealand
Portugal
Slovak Republic*
Slovenia
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
United Kingdom
United States
Non-OECD
Colombia*
South Africa*
USD bn
Incl. quasi-corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Only corp
8
5
5
4
2
1
7
59
19
6
4
9
47
(9)
30
44
13
8
7
1
1
49
17
9
46
350
Incl. quasi-corp
7
4
Incl. quasi-corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Only corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Incl. quasi-corp
corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Only corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Only corp
Incl. quasi-corp
Only corp
Incl. quasi-corp
* Countries where the figure adjusted for FISIM was not available
Source: OECD National Accounts Database
An additional consideration in estimating total NIE is whether the available data includes
financial payments equivalent to interest. Interest expense may be capitalised into the cost
of goods sold, embedded in purchases from other businesses, lease payments, payments
under profit participating loans or under alternative financing arrangements, such as
Islamic finance; or imputed on instruments such as convertible bonds and zero coupon
bonds.38 Focusing purely on interest expense would likely yield a conservative estimate.
Depending on the definition of interest in the country, this could be mentioned as a likely
source of downward bias or if information is available, an upward adjustment could be
made to the change in the tax base.
220 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
There are a few scenarios which may require adjustments for affected entities. Examples
of where an adjustment would be necessary include:
The interest limitation rule could only apply to entities forming part of a MNE
group, but aggregate NIE data includes all non-financial corporations. This would
result in both an over and under-estimate of the change in tax base an overestimate in the sense that many corporations may not be part of a MNE group and an
under-estimate in the sense that non-corporate entities may be part of a MNE group.
The interest limitation rule would apply to entities forming part of a group (MNE
and domestic) and stand-alone entities; however only aggregate NIE data from
National Accounts is available which covers non-financial corporations, but
excludes quasi-corporations. This would result in an under-estimate of the change in
tax base.
While there may not be any micro-data to draw on, there are potential other sources that
could be used to gauge the share of MNEs operating in the economy. For example, if the
central bank or National Statistics Office produces data on net or gross operating surplus
(NOS/GOS), it may be possible to find out the share of this that is attributable to MNEs
and use this information to assist with applying a factor to aggregate NIE data
(recognising that the share of NOS or GOS may not be directly linked to the share of
NIE).
An additional strategy to find out more about MNE and domestic groups, as well as large
stand-alone corporates, is analysing the financial statements of the top 25/50/100
groups/companies operating in the domestic jurisdiction as the largest groups are likely to
have the biggest interest deductions, or alternatively a stratified statistical sample could
be used. Deciding on an appropriate number of firms/groups will depend on the size of
the economy and other domestic factors, such as whether there is an appropriate
representation of sectors in the sample chosen. This could provide an indication of the
total external NIE if considered on a consolidated basis, or total (internal and external)
NIE if financial statements are published on an unconsolidated basis. This would provide
a useful comparison to NIE published in National Accounts data.
Adjustments
If an adjustment is required to add internal interest, a parameter will be required that
extrapolates from external NIE to total NIE. This would be necessary, for example, if
relying on aggregate National Accounts data that collects information based on the
enterprise group as opposed to legal entity as it would only include external NIE.
Estimates of internal interest to total interest could be taken from empirical studies.
Although not ideal, basing an adjustment for internal interest on the academic literature
may be more accurate than implicitly assuming zero internal interest by MNE affiliates.
The current literature, based on two datasets the German Bundesbank MiDi dataset and
the United States Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) dataset, finds the internal/external
debt ratio averages around 0.4, while internal/total debt is approximately 0.3.39 It should
be noted that both Germany and the United States have higher than average statutory
corporate tax rates, and thus may have higher internal debt ratios than countries with
lower statutory corporate tax rates.
Implementing a de minimis rule to exclude entities from the rule requires a downward
adjustment to the total NIE estimate. There may be information on small and mediumsized enterprises that is based on employees or turnover, which could be useful in making
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 221
an adjustment.40 Smaller firms may have higher interest ratios than larger firms, and
academic studies find that domestic-only firms have higher interest ratios than similar
sized MNE firms. However, if domestic-only firms are smaller than MNEs on average,
the percentage of NIE above the de minimis threshold may be lower than the average for
all firms.
Given that a fixed ratio rule would only affect entities in a tax-paying position, a
downward adjustment could be made to reflect this. It is important to consider this in
conjunction with the de minimis threshold as many of those in an assessed loss position
may fall below the de minimis threshold. Even though micro-data may not be available,
the Revenue Authority may produce aggregate statistics showing the portion of
corporations in an assessed loss position. This could assist in deciding on a suitable factor
for adjusting downwards, and could be more refined if the statistics are done by taxable
income groups.
Applying an AMTR
Once the increase in the tax base (total NIE in excess of the NIE/EBITDA ratio) has been
estimated, it will be necessary to apply an AMTR to the increase in the tax base. Given
that the base broadening effect of interest limitation rules will result in more taxable
income being taxed at the margin, the statutory tax rates may be a suitable starting
point.41
222 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Other countries fiscal estimates of excess interest countermeasures
In addition to other countermeasures, Table 3.A2.1 provides the fiscal estimate of
unilateral interest countermeasures in selected countries as a percentage of their total
corporate tax revenue. Measures that were estimated or implemented in prior years would
likely yield higher fiscal estimates compared with estimates produced today as these prior
measures were introduced during a period of higher interest rates. The point in the
business cycle at which the measure was estimated (and implemented) is also important
as the revenue effects are shown as a percentage of CIT revenues, which are volatile
across the cycle. The fiscal estimate also depends on whether a country implemented
other policy measures simultaneously that may have influenced the fiscal estimate for
interest countermeasures (e.g. depending on the order in which the estimates were
stacked). Also, if these countries had existing interest limitations rules, then the fiscal
estimate would be for only the incremental revenue effect of the new interest limitation,
not the effect of the countrys total interest limitation.
Potential interactions with other countermeasures
If implementing more than one BEPS countermeasure simultaneously, revenue estimates
would need to take into account interactions of the various provisions. The Actions in
respect of transfer pricing address the mispricing of interest, while Action 4 is focused on
curbing interest deductions resulting from excessive leveraging. If both the transfer
pricing guidance and interest limitation countermeasures are adopted, care will need to be
taken to remove potential mispricing corrections from the Action 4 fiscal estimate.
Action 4 could also interact with the measures proposed under Action 2 (hybrid mismatch
arrangements). Hybrid mismatch arrangement countermeasures may lead to the
disallowance of certain interest expense deductions, which could reduce the interest-toEBITDA ratio of firms affected by hybrid countermeasures. If data becomes available
about reduced interest deductions from hybrid mismatch arrangements, or an estimate of
that is made for another proposal, then it could be factored into the total NIE affected.
Action 1 (Address the Tax Challenges of the Digital Economy)
The Report on Action 1 (Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digital Economy, OECD,
2015c) examines a number of tax policy issues specifically linked to the digital economy,
its business models, and its key features. It notes that because the digital economy is
increasingly becoming the economy itself, it would not be feasible to ring-fence the
digital economy from the rest of the economy for tax purposes. Although the digital
economy does not generate unique BEPS issues, some of its key features exacerbate
BEPS risks. These risks are addressed in the BEPS Action Plan in the context of the work
on Actions 3 (Strengthening CFC Rules), 7 (Preventing the Artificial Avoidance of PE
Status), and 8-10 (Ensure that Transfer Pricing Outcomes are in Line with Value
Creation).
Understanding the proposed change
The Task Force on the Digital Economy (TFDE) discussed and analysed several potential
options to address these broader tax challenges raised by the digital economy issues.
Specifically, they are considering three tax policy options for more effectively imposing
taxes on activities related to foreign sellers without a PE in the country. The three tax
policy options are:
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 223
Modifications to the PE threshold and associated profit attribution rules for the CIT
on the net income generated from remote sales of digital goods and services to incountry customers by a foreign producer without PE status under current law;
The introduction of an excise tax on certain types of digital transactions; and
The imposition of a WHT on the gross receipts from certain types of digital
transactions.
Recommendations for enabling the collection of value-added tax (VAT) in business-toconsumer (B2C) digital transactions is included as part of the OECD International
VAT/GST Guidelines, which will protect tax revenue.
Fiscal estimation issues
For estimating the direct tax fiscal effects of modifications to the permanent
establishment threshold that affects remote sellers of digital goods and services, the
approach will be the same as that described for the fiscal estimate of Action 7 below.
Estimating the fiscal effects of introducing an excise tax or the imposition of a WHT on
certain types of digital transactions would follow the revenue estimating procedures
outlined above in the section discussing the general approach to undertaking a fiscal
estimate. Both taxes would be based on gross receipts of the identified transactions;
therefore, the tax base should be similar under either proposal.
The first step in estimating the fiscal effects of adopting one of the alternative tax
proposals would be to estimate the amount of existing sales for each type of eligible
digital transactions that would be subject to the new excise or WHTs. Industry reports or
country-specific estimates from public databases, such as the Eurostat e-commerce
statistics, could be used to estimate the potential tax base, although the amount would
need to be separated between the sales of remote sellers without a current PE from sales
of remote sellers with a current PE.
It would be important to distinguish between sales to final customers (households) and
intermediate sales to businesses in estimating the base. Potential behavioural responses
should also be considered, such as reductions in the digital transactions in response to
higher tax-inclusive prices along with substitution away from digital transactions from
remote sellers without a current PE to alternative transactions (both digital and nondigital) from sellers with a PE. The resulting estimate of the change in the tax base would
be multiplied by the applicable tax rates to determine the expected fiscal effects.
Finally, estimates of the fiscal effects of indirect tax changes through the collection of
VAT in B2C transactions would be based on the expansion of the VAT tax base
multiplied by the applicable VAT rates. Substitution of non-digital transactions for digital
transactions would not affect the expected collections (except for scenarios where
different VAT rates would apply).
Action 2 (Hybrid Mismatch Arrangements)
Understanding the proposed change
Hybrid mismatch arrangements are transactions which exploit cross-border differences in
the treatment of instruments and entities to produce a mismatch in tax outcomes. A
mismatch is either two deductions of the same payment (i.e. a double deduction (DD)
outcome) or a deductible payment that is not included in the tax base by the recipient (i.e.
a deduction/no inclusion (D/NI) outcome). Part I of the Report on Action 2 (Neutralising
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
224 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
the Effects of Hybrid Mismatch Arrangements, OECD, 2015d) sets out recommendations
for domestic rules intended to neutralise DD and D/NI outcomes for hybrid financial
instruments (such as instruments which are considered debt in one country and equity in
another) and hybrid entities (such as entities and arrangements that are considered
fiscally transparent in one country and fiscally opaque in another). Part I of the Report on
Action 2 further contains an imported mismatch rule that applies to both structured and
intra-group arrangements and that can be applied to any payment that is directly or
indirectly set-off against any type of hybrid deduction.
In the case of direct and indirect D/NI outcomes, part I of the Report sets out
recommendations for rules to deny a deduction in the payer jurisdiction as a primary rule
and, in the case of DD outcomes, the primary recommended rule is to deny a deduction in
the parent jurisdiction. The hybrid mismatch rules also have secondary recommended
rules that apply in the counterparty jurisdiction in the event that the primary rule is not
applied.
Part II of the Report on Action 2 sets out recommended changes to the OECD Model Tax
Convention aimed at ensuring that hybrid instruments and entities, as well as dual
resident entities, are not used to obtain unduly the benefits of tax treaties and that tax
treaties to not prevent the application of the changes to domestic law recommended in
part I.
Potential data
An economic analysis of hybrid mismatch arrangements requires detailed company-level
data. It requires not only information on transactions between related parties but also on
their tax treatment in both the payer and recipient jurisdictions. Such data is rarely
available through public sources, and only available to tax administrations making extra
efforts to identify such arrangements, including requesting additional information from
taxpayers. Estimates by government analysis would require information from tax
administration audit teams about the number and scale of existing hybrid mismatch
arrangements in the country.
Other countries fiscal estimates
Several countries have introduced or proposed countermeasures intended to address DD
and D/NI outcomes for which annual fiscal estimates have been made:
France introduced in January 2014 measures limiting deductibility of interest if it is
subject to a low tax rate at the level of the beneficiary. The estimated revenue effect
is an increase in CIT revenue by 0.9%.
The United Kingdom proposed in December 2014 measures in line with the Action 2
recommendations. The estimated revenue effect is an increase in CIT revenue by
0.2%.
The United States proposed measures limiting deductibility of interest and royalties
if there is no corresponding inclusion at the level of the recipient in the foreign
jurisdiction. The estimated revenue effect is an increase in CIT revenue by 0.04%.42
These estimates assume a large behavioural response due to MNEs ability to restructure
their financial arrangements around unilateral countermeasures. For example, rules that
deny a deduction for payments under a particular cross-border financing arrangement that
give rise to a D/NI outcome may simply encourage taxpayer groups to enter into the same
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 225
arrangement under the laws of another jurisdiction and then use a back-to-back loan
structure to import the effect of the mismatch into domestic law, thus converting a direct
D/NI outcome into an indirect D/NI outcome that is outside the scope of the countrys
rules.
The expected behavioural response to unilateral action by one country is the main reason
for the low estimated revenue effects. The recommendations under Action 2 are intended
to prevent taxpayers from obtaining any advantage under any jurisdiction in respect of
these types of arrangements, making them more effective than unilateral and uncoordinated action. If hybrid mismatch recommendations are implemented in many
countries simultaneously with a rule to address indirect D/NI outcomes, there will be
significantly less opportunity for companies to restructure their financial affairs to avoid
the effect of the recommended rules. Thus, hybrid arrangements would be expected to
increase corporate revenues by more than that generated from unilateral actions, provided
multilateral co-ordinated implementation of Action 2 occurs. The revenue from
implementation of the Action 2 recommendations is not expected to come from
disallowed deductions or disallowed exemptions under the hybrid mismatch rules
themselves, but rather from MNEs ceasing to structure themselves and their transactions
in such a way as to exploit mismatches, and thus not claiming the deductions or
benefitting from exempt income.
Potential interactions with other countermeasures
Rules recommended under Action 9 on transfer pricing of risk and capital and Action 4
on interest deductibility would decrease the benefit of many hybrid mismatch
arrangements by limiting possibilities of achieving tax reduction via interest payments. In
addition, the combination of hybrid mismatch arrangement rules with treaty abuse rules
will reduce tax planning opportunities, and thus will have a greater effect together than
the sum of the individual effects.
Action 3 (Controlled Foreign Corporation Rules)
The Report on Action 3 (Designing Effective Controlled Foreign Company Rules, OECD,
2015e) provides guidance based on best practices for the building blocks of effective CFC
rules, while recognising that the policy objectives of these rules vary among jurisdictions.
It identifies the challenges to existing CFC rules posed by mobile income, such as that
from intellectual property, services and digital transactions, and allows jurisdictions to
reflect on appropriate policies in this regard. The report emphasises that CFC rules have a
continuing, important role in tackling BEPS, as a backstop to transfer pricing and other
rules.
CFC rules are designed to protect a countrys tax base by preventing shifting of mobile or
passive income to a CFC. In the case of parents in territorial tax countries, CFC rules
prevent the shifting of particular income to benefit from exempt foreign source income.
In the case of parents in the countries that have a worldwide tax system with deferral,
CFC rules prevent the shifting of particular income to benefit from deferral of such
income.
Understanding the proposed change
The Report on Action 3 recommends that, in addition to corporate entities, CFC rules
could also apply to partnerships, trusts and permanent establishments when those entities
raise BEPS concerns, which could occur if they are either owned by CFCs or treated in
the parent jurisdiction as taxable entities separate from their owners.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
226 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
A tax rate exemption is recommended, pursuant to which CFC rules would not apply if
the CFCs effective tax rate were higher than a set threshold.43 The Report on Action 3
notes that resident shareholders should only be taxed on income earned by a foreign
company if they appear to have had some input in how, when and where that income was
earned. The Report on Action 3 recommends that CFC rules should at least apply both a
legal and an economic control test so that satisfaction of either test results in control, and
a CFC should be treated as controlled where residents directly or indirectly hold 50% or
more of the voting rights, but the report allows the option for a lower control threshold if
countries want to achieve broader policy goals or prevent circumvention of CFC rules.
Once an entity has been identified as a CFC, it is necessary to determine which income
will be attributable to shareholders or controlling parties.44 The Report on Action 3
describes multiple approaches to determining CFC income. CFC rules generally define
attributable income in the context of income earned by CFCs raise BEPS concerns, which
may include, among other things, income earned by CFCs that are holding companies,
provide financial and banking services, engage in sales invoicing, as well as income from
IP assets, digital goods and services, and captive insurance and re-insurance. The report
describes three approaches: a categorical analysis, a substance analysis, and an excess
profits analysis. Regardless of which approach is followed, the country will also need to
decide whether the approach applies to entities or transactions. The Report on Action 3
notes that the transactional approach may be more consistent with both the goals of the
BEPS Project and European Union law.
Depending on the definition of CFC income used in the country, the following types of
income are often included in CFC rules:
Dividends paid out of passive income that is not actively managed by the CFC.
Interest and other financing income, unless the CFC had the required substance to
earn the income and was not overcapitalised.
Specific service income, unless the CFC had the required substance to earn the
income, including:
Insurance income that was earned from a related party or where the parties to
the insurance contract or the risks insured are located outside the CFC
jurisdiction
Sales and services income
Royalties and other IP income
Once the level of CFC income has been determined, a tax rate is applied. CFC income is
generally subject to the tax rate of the parent company in the parent jurisdiction. The
Report on Action 3 also describes an option referred to as a top-up tax, which would
only subject CFC income to the difference between the tax paid in the CFCs jurisdiction
and a threshold rate.
The fiscal analysis begins with the specific CFC rules adopted by a country. The Report
on Action 3 sets out recommendations in the form of building blocks, but acknowledges
that jurisdictions will have different policy objectives for their CFC rules. Therefore these
recommendations are not minimum standards, but they are designed to ensure that
jurisdictions that choose to implement them will have rules that effectively prevent
taxpayers from shifting income into foreign subsidiaries.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 227
228 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Table 3.A2.4. Potential data sources for CFC income
Potential CFC income
Description
Potential Source
Dividends
Insurance income
Data on the value of purchases and sales via the internet (and/or
networks other than the internet) of companies by country (EU,
2010-2014)
http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/informationsociety/data/database
United States data on measuring the electronic economy:
www.census.gov/econ/estats/
European Multi-Channel Online Trade Association:
www.emota.eu/#!statistics/ccor
Empirical literature
There are some empirical studies that examine the effect of CFC rules on MNE
behaviour. The results generally show that the presence of CFC rules dissuade MNEs
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 229
from using low-tax jurisdictions. Markle and Robinson (2012) investigate whether CFC
rules, bilateral tax treaties and WHTs affect the tax behaviour of MNEs. Using ORBIS
and COMPUSTAT data, the findings suggest that both the taxing of foreign profits
(through a credit or worldwide system) and the presence of CFC rules reduce the
likelihood of a MNE using a tax haven. In addition, the wider the scope of income that is
subject to CFC rules, the lower the likelihood that a MNE uses tax havens.
Ruf and Weichenrieder analysed the German CFC rules in two separate analyses. Both
analyses are based on the German Bundesbank Micro-database Direct Investment (MiDi)
data on German MNEs (outbound investment)47. The 2012 analysis investigates the effect
of German CFC rules on the location of passive assets within German multinationals. The
analysis investigates whether exceeding the tax rate threshold has an impact on the
allocation of passive investment and finds that German CFC rules have a significant and
predictable impact on multinational financing and are effective in limiting the shifting of
passive assets. While passive investments make up a significant fraction of German
outbound FDI, they found German CFC rules are effective in restricting investments in
low-tax jurisdictions.
Their 2013 study investigates the effect of the change of Germanys CFC legislation in
response to a decision by the European Court of Justice (ECJ), which ruled that German
CFC legislation infringed on the freedom of establishment within the European Union,
and thus could not be applied to CFCs in EU countries. The analysis found that after
liberalising CFC legislation in response to the ruling, passive investments in low-tax
European countries increased compared to low-tax non-European countries, signalling
that the prior CFC rules limited shifting of passive investments of German MNEs to other
EU countries.
Potential interactions with other countermeasures
There are interactions between CFC rules and transfer pricing rules. If, for example, CFC
rules apply a sufficiently high rate of tax, certain transfer pricing outcomes may become
irrelevant to the MNE as the benefit of engaging in transfer pricing manipulation would
be removed. If proposed at the same time, a careful assessment of the likely interactions
and overlap between the two countermeasures would be appropriate.
Action 5 (Harmful Tax Practices)
Current concerns on harmful tax practices are primarily about preferential regimes which
can be used for artificial profit shifting, and a lack of transparency in connection with
certain rulings. The Report on Action 5 (Countering Harmful Tax Practices More
Effectively, Taking into Account Transparency and Substance, OECD, 2015f) sets out an
agreed methodology to assess whether there is substantial activity in a preferential
regime. In the context of IP regimes, consensus was reached on the nexus approach.
The nexus approach uses expenditure as a proxy for activity and allows a taxpayer to
benefit from an IP regime only to the extent that the taxpayer incurred qualifying R&D
expenditures that gave rise to IP income. The same principle can also be applied to other
preferential regimes so that such regimes are found to require substantial activity where
the taxpayer undertook the core income-generating activities.
In the area of transparency, a framework has been agreed for the compulsory spontaneous
exchange of information on rulings that could give rise to BEPS concerns in the absence
of such exchange. The results of the application of the existing factors applied by the
Forum on Harmful Tax Practices (FHTP), and the elaborated substantial activity and
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
230 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
transparency factors, to a number of preferential regimes are included in the Report on
Action 5.
Understanding the proposed change
The work of the FHTP and the agreed approach on substantial activities will have
positive impacts on CIT collections as the use of preferential tax rate regimes will be
restricted to taxpayers with sufficient economic activities in the country. This will be
expected to lead to an increase in taxes in the country with such a regime, as well as other
countries.
In a country with a fiscal regime favouring geographically mobile income, Action 5 and
the application of the elaborated substantial activity factor will reduce harmful tax
practices and be expected to result in an increase in tax revenue, assuming no change in
the base, due to the application of a higher general tax rate to the income that no longer
qualifies for a preferential tax regime. Reduced harmful tax practices will help reduce
BEPS and will be expected to lead to an increase in corporate tax bases and tax
collections in other countries.
Empirical evidence
Several studies show that corporate tax rates are an important factor for patent location
decisions and IP boxes have a strong effect on attracting patent registrations; it is
recognised, however, that patent locations may not mirror the location of R&D activities.
The studies use the number of patent applications as the dependent variable and the
corporate tax rate as one of the explanatory variables. For example, Karkinsky and Riedel
(2012), based on data from the European Patent Office (EPO) for a number of European
countries over the 1978-2007 period, estimate a semi-elasticity of -3.8 to -3.5; that is, a 1
percentage point decrease in the rate of corporate tax translates into a 3.5 to 3.8% increase
in patent applications in that country.
Griffith, Miller and OConnell (2014), based on data from the EPO on patents located in
14 European countries, estimate semi-elasticities that range from -3.9 to -0.5. They also
simulated the impact of the enactment of a new IP box on tax revenue and found that they
result in losses in government revenues because they do not attract enough IP income to
offset the revenue loss from the preferential tax rate application on current IP income.
While empirical studies show high responsiveness of MNEs to shifting mobile income,
the responsiveness of shifting real economic activity is significantly smaller. DeMooij
and Ederveen (2008) use a meta-analysis of other empirical studies to estimate an
extensive FDI investment margin of -0.65, which is considerably smaller than the
elasticities estimated for patent registrations. Similarly, a European Commission (2015)
working paper reports relatively low estimates of the responsiveness of research and
development expenditures.
A nexus requirement will reduce the amount of mobile income shifted as a result of
preferential tax regimes, and will reduce BEPS associated with harmful tax practices.
Fiscal estimation issues
As a response to Action 5, countries will remove or amend certain preferential tax
regimes. The effect on the country with an existing harmful tax practice can be estimated
by the change in the tax base and the application of the higher general tax rate.
Revenue increases to other countries will more likely occur in the future as income
shifting is reduced due to the reduction of harmful tax practices. One possible approach to
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 231
estimating the fiscal effect would be to estimate the increase in the average AMTR,
compared to what the average AMTR would have been with harmful tax practices, and
use the methodology described in the transfer pricing Actions.48
The potential revenue gained from increased transparency due to the exchange of
information will also be difficult to estimate, partly because the fiscal effects will depend
upon the actions of other governments and the effect of reductions in harmful tax
practices on relative marginal tax rates that create profit shifting incentives.
To the extent that additional information is received by a country as a result of the
compulsory spontaneous exchange of information on rulings, tax administration auditors
could provide insights on the potential revenue effects in the country.
Potential interactions with other BEPS Actions
There are potential overlaps with other BEPS Actions. Rules recommended under Action
8 on transfer pricing of intangibles would require any transactions which result in the
shifting of income to take advantage of tax rate differentials are to be in accordance with
the arms length principle.
Action 6 (Prevent Treaty Abuse)
The Report on Action 6 (Preventing the Granting of Treaty Benefits in Inappropriate
Circumstances, OECD, 2015g) includes a minimum standard on preventing treaty abuse
including through treaty shopping and new rules that provide safeguards to prevent treaty
abuse and offer a certain degree of flexibility regarding how to do so. The new treaty
abuse rules address treaty shopping which involves strategies through which a person
who is not a resident of a country attempts to obtain the benefits of a treaty concluded by
that country e.g. WHT reductions, through an intermediary established in that state. More
targeted rules have been designed to address other forms of treaty abuse.
Tax treaties are intended to reduce or eliminate double taxation of international income
flows, including cross-border dividends, royalties and interest. In general, these income
flows can be subject to several levels of taxation: CIT in the host country on profits
realised in that country that are subsequently distributed as dividends, WHTs on
international income flows, or CIT to be paid in the recipient country subject to double
taxation relief, such as foreign tax credits or dividend participation exemptions.
Understanding the proposed change
The part of the Report on Action 6 that deals with treaty shopping provides that the
OECD Model Tax Convention will include:
A new preamble for tax treaties according to which tax treaties are not intended to
create opportunities for tax evasion and avoidance, in particular through treaty
shopping.
A limitation-on-benefits (LOB) rule or a principal purposes test (PPT).
While the LOB rule addresses treaty-shopping situations based on the legal nature,
ownership in, and general activities of, residents of a Contracting State, the PPT rule
focusses on transactions, denying treaty benefits where one of the principal purposes for a
transaction or arrangement was to obtain treaty benefits. Although the rules target treaty
shopping differently, they would both allow treaty benefits to be granted to intermediaries
in some cases, primarily where sufficient income-earning activities are exercised by these
232 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
entities. There is agreement that, in these cases, the establishment of intermediaries is not
motivated by treaty shopping considerations.
Data and methodology
Tax optimising MNEs make use of treaty networks to minimise their WHT payments by
establishing intermediaries in conduit countries. While the simplest case involves only
one intermediary, tax planning may involve the routing of international income flows via
a chain of several conduit entities located in different countries. The effects of treaty
shopping on country-level revenues, therefore, depend on the position of the country
(within which the entity is located) in the treaty network. In principle, estimation requires
not only information on statutory WHT rates, double taxation relief methods and existing
tax treaties, but also on possible interactions across the treaty network.
Tax avoidance induces a diversion of international income flows, for instance through
Special Purpose Entities (SPEs), which may not be captured by existing data sources. As
a result, revenue effects may differ by country depending on its position in the treaty
network and the routing of international investment flows.
An evaluation of the countrys existing treaty network could be an initial step in the
analysis of the fiscal effects of treaty shopping. Tax treaties are designed to reduce double
taxation and stimulate reciprocal investment. The number of tax treaties and the amount
of treaty-related tax reductions do not per se provide insights about the existence or the
fiscal effect of treaty shopping. However, an indication about a countrys exposure to
treaty shopping may be obtained by identifying, first, potential conduit countries within
its network and, second, total outbound payments to relevant entities. UNCTAD (2015)
developed such an approach based on the bilateral corporate (inward) investment stock
from the IMF CDIS. As a first step, conduit countries may be identified by a set of
observable characteristics such as, for instance, low WHT rates, generous relief methods,
preferential tax regimes and a large number of treaty links. Second, outbound payments to
these countries can be retrieved from the CDIS. If bilateral SPE data is available, flows to
SPEs in other countries may also be included. The sum of these outbound payments is an
upper-bound estimate of the flows affected by treaty shopping.
The estimation of the fiscal effects of Action 6 countermeasures is dependent on available
data sources. Countries where data on international income flows and WHT revenues are
available will have a better empirical basis for their estimate. This approach is described
in subsection (a). If this information is not available, estimation procedures will have to
rely on other, often much less specific, data sources and results will therefore be less
certain, as described in subsection (b).
a.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 233
and WHTs may, in some countries, be available from the Central Bank or other public
institutions.
Using this data, a fiscal estimate can be calculated by drawing upon of the following
elements:
Definition of the tax bases, accounting for exemptions and tax treaties;
Weighted average WHT rate under current law;
Outgoing dividend, royalty and interest payments affected by treaty shopping;
and
Weighted average WHT rate under the adoption of Action 6 countermeasures.
The first step in estimating the effects of treaty abuse countermeasures would be to derive
an estimate of the tax base for each of the income types. It may be necessary to make a
downward adjustment to the tax base to account for potential WHT exemptions, before
applying an appropriate tax rate. If the tax base is not affected by tax treaties, the
weighted average tax rate can be computed by weighting the bilateral tax rates (standard
or reduced) by the income flow associated with the respective country-pairs. This is
straightforward if outflows and tax rates are available by partner country. Otherwise,
additional information, for instance, FDI stocks, can be used to determine the weights. If
tax treaties affect the definition of the tax base, then a similar approach can be used.
Exempted income flows which may become subject to taxation due to the
countermeasures could be treated as zero-rated and included in the tax base.
To estimate the effect of the countermeasures an additional assumption about the
expected increases in the average WHT rate need to be made. While this will entail
estimation (i.e. with regard to the effectiveness of the countermeasures), available data on
bilateral income flows may be used to provide empirical guidance. It has been suggested,
for instance, that an initial evaluation of the treaty network may help identify potential
conduit countries. Provided data on income flows to these countries is available, the
magnitude of the affected outflows can be estimated. If bilateral income flows to conduit
countries are not observed, other variables, such as e.g. FDI stocks, may be used as an
approximation. Separate FDI data series on SPEs may also be drawn upon to obtain a
more comprehensive picture of the relevant outflows (see UNCTAD, 2015, for a detailed
description).
As treaty benefits will be denied for transactions motivated by treaty shopping under the
Action 6 recommendations, the respective income flows will be reallocated for tax
purposes. Outflows to conduit countries, for instance, may now be treated as if they were
payments to the ultimate counterparty. The increase in the average WHT rate can be
captured by an adjustment in the weights associated with each country pair. Since the
final destination of the income flow in the counterfactual scenario remains unknown, a
proportional increase in the weights of all non-conduit countries could be a reasonable
starting point. Possible feedback based on audit experiences may also be used at this step.
Based on this approach, the affected outbound payments as well as the weighted average
WHT rates under current law and Action 6 can be approximated. Since potential effects
of the countermeasures on exempted income flows have been accounted for, the
approximated tax base does not change in the Action 6 countermeasure fiscal estimate.
The estimated revenue change equals the change in the weighted average WHT rate times
the total outbound payments estimated to be affected by treaty shopping.
234 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
b.
The approach presented in this section provides an example of how results from recent
academic publications can be combined with publicly available data sources to derive an
initial estimate. The following information is required:
Outbound payments of dividends, royalties and interest from BOP statistics;
Reduced treaty tax rates on royalties and interest; and
Country-level tax revenue estimates from the network analysis by Vant Riet
and Lejour (2014)50
BOP statistics include outgoing flows between related parties for dividends and interest
(BOP, current account, primary income, direct investment income). However, royalty
flows are not reported in the section on direct investment income but as a part of the
goods and services section (BOP, current account, goods and services, charges for
intellectual property). These flows include royalty flows between related and unrelated
parties. While dividend and interest flows from portfolio investments are separated in the
BOP data, further adjustments are necessary to isolate royalty flows between related and
unrelated parties.
Publicly available data can be combined with results from a recent publication which
provides information on country-level tax revenue effects with and without treaty
shopping. Vant Riet and Lejour (2014) use a network approach to map the tax incentive
structure faced by MNEs. The analysis includes 108 jurisdictions and builds on country
level information on CIT, WHTs and double taxation relief methods. In addition,
information on treaty benefits from existing bilateral tax treaties are used to calculate the
tax minimising indirect payment route between all possible pairs of countries.
The analysis shows that the FDI-weighted world average tax rate on dividend flows,
taking unilateral double tax relief and bilateral tax treaties into account, is around 11%.51
Comparing taxation on indirect and direct routes shows that treaty shopping reduces the
FDI-weighted world average by an upper bound of 44% (i.e. to 4.8%). While the world
average effect may not be indicative for individual countries, the paper also includes a
more detailed table providing revenue effects from WHT by country. Potential countrylevel WHT revenues with and without treaty shopping are reported as a percent of total
outgoing dividend flows. Based on this information, a fiscal estimate of the maximum
effect that could be obtained by eliminating treaty shopping can be derived by
multiplying the results with corresponding outflows of FDI dividends. Information at the
country level may be helpful to scale the upper bound estimate to a realistic estimate of
the fiscal effects for the country.
Two sets of additional assumptions could be necessary for an analysis of the fiscal effects
of Action 6 countermeasures. First, the results from the network analysis only include the
effects from dividend payments between related parties. To account for the effects from
royalty and interest payments, the revenue results from dividends could be applied to
other income flows. This can be done by calculating the proportional reduction of
statutory WHT rates on dividends that result from bilateral treaties and treaty shopping
(i.e. indirect routing) respectively. Applying these proportions to statutory rates on
royalties and interest may give a first approximation of the corresponding tax reductions
on other outbound payments. In addition, the results may also be expanded to include
income flows from portfolio investment. Although the treatment of portfolio dividends in
tax treaties is typically different from the treatment of dividends between related parties, a
similar approximation may be feasible, depending on the specific country context.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 235
236 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Understanding the proposed change
The specific PE provisions being dealt with under Action 7 include the agency-PE rule
and the specific exceptions. The recommendations will also address the issue of profit
attribution once a PE is established, but these recommendations have not been finalised.
The specific Action 7 recommendations to reduce the artificial avoidance of PE status
include:
Changes to the agency-PE rule to ensure that where the activities that an
intermediary exercises in a country are intended to result in the regular
conclusion of contracts to be performed by a foreign enterprise, that enterprise
will be considered to have a PE in the country unless the intermediary is
performing these activities in the course of an independent business;
Restricting all the exceptions to the PE rules to activities which are otherwise of
a preparatory or auxiliary character;
A new anti-fragmentation rule; and
Changes dealing with the splitting-up of contracts.
Data and methodology
Estimating the fiscal effects of Action 7 countermeasures will be difficult because the
determination of a PE is fact-specific. It will be necessary to focus the analysis on MNEs
with activities likely affected by a redefinition, such as commissionaire arrangements, to
get a rough measure of the potential magnitude of the activity affected. One possible
route would be to work together with relevant staff, including auditors, at the revenue
authority, to understand the previous cases of PE audits and current investigations, as well
as how the revised definition would affect the PE status of those and other companies.
Once examples or a sample of potentially affected companies are identified, that sample
can be extrapolated to the potential total economic activity affected by the Action 7
countermeasures in the country.
If it is possible to estimate the magnitude of the economic activities by the PEs being
analysed, profits would need to be allocated between the PE and related parties. Further
guidance with regard to this step of the estimation procedure can be obtained from the
revised transfer pricing guidelines and the additional guidance on attribution of profits
that will be developed in 2016.
Lowering PE thresholds implies that MNEs may now be subject to tax in locations where
PE status was previously avoided. Economic activity previously subject to tax in another
jurisdiction will now be subject to tax in the PE jurisdiction such that tax revenues could
potentially decrease in one jurisdiction and increase in another.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 237
To monitor the fiscal effects of the BEPS countermeasure, audit results and new CIT
information could be tracked after a countrys adoption of Action 7s countermeasures. If
the information is available for specific taxpayers, a net figure for revenue changes
should be calculated, including tax increases for taxpayers where new measures give rise
to PE status and the tax increases from economic activities of other in-country firms with
a PE that would be increased when the artificial avoidance of PE status has been
eliminated. Similar monitoring could be done for the jurisdiction where the income was
previously reported.
Potential interactions with other countermeasures
Action 7 will have important linkages to Action 2 and 6, and the transfer pricing changes.
Together with changes to tax treaties proposed in the Reports on Actions 2 and 6, the
changes will lead to an increase in taxation in a number of cases where cross-border
income would otherwise have been untaxed or would be taxed at very low rates as a
result of the current provisions in tax treaties.
The BEPS countermeasures recommended by Action 7 are linked to the revised transfer
pricing guidance of Actions 8-10. With the revised guidelines in effect, transactions
between a company with newly established PE and related parties are to be priced at
arms length. Where some of the income from the operations of a newly established PE
may have been shifted to a tax haven in the past, the income will now be assigned to
where the economic activity generating that income is located.
Action 11 (Measuring and Monitoring BEPS)
The Report on Action 11 (Measuring and Monitoring BEPS, OECD, 2015i) includes an
assessment of existing data sources relevant for BEPS analysis; indicators of BEPS; an
initial economic analysis of BEPS and countermeasures (and the issues surrounding an
economic analysis in the BEPS context); as well as recommendations for future data and
tools necessary to better understand BEPS behaviours and monitor these behaviours and
BEPS countermeasures over time. The issues raised and findings from the analysis of the
scale and economic impact of BEPS and countermeasures will improve the understanding
and visibility of these issues with policymakers and media. In addition, Action 11
highlights best practices in data collection and dissemination that could assist
policymakers in more countries to have a better understanding of BEPS behaviours in
their countries over time.
The measuring and monitoring of BEPS, such as that in the Report on Action 11, will
provide increased transparency. Action 11 increases transparency with its macro analysis
of the scale of BEPS and countermeasures, which complements the increased
transparency of the individual company information of the other Actions. Action 11 will
complement the increased transparency of Actions 5, 12 and 13.While not having a direct
effect on corporate tax revenues, Action 11 will have an indirect effect through an
improved understanding of the fiscal effects of BEPS behaviours by tax policy makers,
tax administrations, taxpayers, the media and the public. The analysis of BEPS
behaviours could highlight particular areas for increased tax enforcement, as well as raise
the reputation costs of tax avoidance. With a better understanding of the BEPS
behaviours and their potential fiscal and economic effects, Action 11 could contribute to
prompting a more comprehensive implementation of BEPS countermeasures, which
would result in tighter rules to counter BEPS. While not feasible to estimate a separate
fiscal effect of Action 11, it may increase the willingness of policymakers to take action
and improve the effectiveness of audit enforcement.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
238 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
Action 12 (Disclosure of Aggressive Tax Planning Arrangements)
The Report on Action 12 (Mandatory Disclosure Rules, OECD, 2015j) includes
recommendations for the design and implementation of mandatory disclosure regimes for
potentially aggressive or abusive international tax planning strategies. The policy
objectives include providing tax administrations with early information on tax planning
strategies and deterring taxpayers from engaging in aggressive tax planning
arrangements. The elements of Action 12 include:
A modular design of mandatory disclosure rules;
A focus on international tax schemes; and
The design of enhanced models of information sharing among countries.
Fiscal estimation issues
Adoption of the Action 12 countermeasure will result in countries having the option to
adopt new mandatory disclosure regimes or expanding existing regimes. The disclosure
information will allow tax administrations to more effectively enforce existing domestic
tax rules, as well as other BEPS countermeasures. As one transparency component of the
BEPS project, Action 12s recommendations will increase the effectiveness of a countrys
enforcement efforts and will discourage taxpayers from taking aggressive tax positions in
the first place.
Although implementation of new or expanded disclosure of aggressive tax planning
arrangements would be expected to increase total corporate tax collections, it would be
difficult ex ante to estimate the incremental improvement given the uncertainty of the
behavioural effects of audit enforcement and taxpayer reactions. The empirical literature
has focused more on the effects on financial reporting rather than actual taxes paid. Ex
post, analysts could work with the audit teams to identify the increased effectiveness of
audits and settlements on transactions identified through the increased disclosure.
Action 14 (Dispute Resolution Mechanisms)
The recommendations developed as a result of the work on Action 14 are intended to
improve the effectiveness and efficiency of the mutual agreement procedure (MAP) in
resolving treaty-related disputes; it is an important complement to the BEPS
countermeasures, which could introduce elements of tax uncertainty, as well as the
potential for unintended double taxation. The Report on Action 14 (Making Dispute
Resolution Mechanisms More Effective, OECD, 2015k) specifically includes:
Adoption of a minimum standard with respect to the resolution of treaty-related
disputes, intended to ensure the full implementation of treaty obligations related
to MAP, the implementation of administrative processes to promote the
prevention and timely resolution of treaty-related disputes, and that taxpayers
that meet the requirements of the MAP article can access the MAP; and
A commitment by 20 countries (that accounted for 90% of outstanding MAP
cases at the end of 2013) to provide for mandatory binding MAP arbitration in
their bilateral tax treaties.
Fiscal estimation issues
If there is inconsistency in the implementation of the BEPS countermeasures there is the
possibility that an unintended increase in double taxation could result in higher income
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 239
tax collections than expected from the intended reduction in BEPS. This could be a
potential component of the net revenue effect of other BEPS countermeasures.
Action 14 is designed to mitigate such unintended tax increases. The fiscal effect of an
improved dispute resolution mechanism could be a decrease in the estimated net income
tax revenues from other countermeasures. To the extent that improvements to the MAP
and/or a MAP arbitration mechanism apply with respect to existing disputes, the disputes
may be settled more quickly and a change in revenue could result from additional tax
payments or refunds of previously collected amounts. A future change in tax collections
from existing disputes might depend on whether countries require corporations to pay
taxes on the disputed amounts.
It would be difficult to estimate the effect in advance of actual experience with
improvements to the MAP and MAP arbitration. The results of a strengthened dispute
resolution process, in terms of tax adjustments, could be tracked to provide an ex post
estimate of the reduction in revenues due to the decrease in potential double taxation.
Action 15 (Multilateral Instrument)
The Report on Action 15 (Developing a Multilateral Instrument to Modify Bilateral Tax
Treaties, OECD, 2015l) explores the feasibility of a multilateral instrument to modify tax
treaties so as to implement the treaty-related BEPS measures and amend bilateral tax
treaties. This is designed to significantly reduce the costs and time associated with
bilateral treaty renegotiations for countries that choose to sign the instrument. A mandate
has been developed for an ad-hoc group, open to the participation of all countries on an
equal footing, to develop the multilateral instrument and open it for signature in 2016. So
far, 88 countries are participating in the work on an equal footing.
Fiscal estimation issues
Where countries sign the multilateral instrument to modify their tax treaties, this could
lead to an acceleration in the implementation of countermeasures and bring forward the
fiscal effects. To the extent that the adoption of new countermeasures would require
amendments to treaties which could require many years, the multilateral instrument may
enable those amendments to take place quicker. If the multilateral instrument leads to the
faster implementation of countermeasures then this will lead to a commensurate
acceleration of the fiscal effects.
Summary
This annex provides potential approaches that could be used by government tax policy
analysts to estimate the fiscal effects of BEPS countermeasures for their respective
countries. A general approach is described before potential approaches are explained for
the individual BEPS Actions. The proposed methodologies are set out according to the
individual countermeasures of the BEPS Action Plan. Some methodologies are more
comprehensive than others given the variation in data availability; the extent of insights
from empirical studies; and depending on the design of the countermeasures. Countries
will have different datasets and some may be more useful for particular BEPS
countermeasures than others. It is recognised that estimating the fiscal effects of BEPS
countermeasures may rely on applicable tax return data, financial account micro-data,
macro-data (aggregated from tax return or financial accounts), a combination of micro
and macro-data sources, or in some cases to data analogous to the country. Where
possible, multiple approaches based on different sources of data are described.
240 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
As better data becomes available both as a result of CbCR and countries recognising the
need to draw on taxpayer micro-data to make more informed and evidence-based tax
policy decisions tax policy analysts will be in a better position to evaluate and monitor
trends in BEPS behaviours and the effect of countermeasures.
An important consideration is the evaluation of ex post estimates relative to ex ante
estimates. Separating the effects of unexpected macroeconomic changes from unexpected
taxpayer behaviours from technical estimation issues can provide valuable learning to tax
policy analysts as they assess the underlying causes in cases of large differences. Even
small differences do not necessarily mean that all assumptions ex ante were correct.
Evaluation of past estimates can improve understanding of key parameters, including
behavioural changes.
Bibliography
Beer, Sebastian, and Jan Loeprick (2015), Profit shifting: drivers of transfer (mis)pricing
and the potential of countermeasures, International Tax and Public Finance, Vol.
22(3), pp 426-451.
Bernard, Andrew B., J. Bradford Jensen and Pete K. Schott (2006), Transfer pricing by
U.S.-based multinational firms, NBER Working Paper, No. 12493.
Blouin, Jennifer, Harry Huizinga, Luc Laeven, Gaetan Nicodeme (2014), Thin
Capitalization Rules and Multinational Firm Capital Structure, IMF Working Papers,
No. 14/12.
Buslei, Hermann, and Martin Simmler (2012), The Impact of Introducing an Interest
Barrier: Evidence from the German Corporation Tax Reform 2008, DIW Discussion
Paper, No. 1215.
Clausing, K. A. (2003), Tax-motivated transfer pricing and US intrafirm trade, Journal of
Public Economics 87 (9-10), pp. 2207-2223.
Clausing, K. A. (2006), International tax avoidance and U.S. international trade,
National Tax Journal, Vol. LVIV, No. 2.
Cristea, Anca D. and Daniel X. Nguyen (2014), Transfer pricing by multinational firms:
New evidence from foreign firm ownerships, University of Copenhagen.
Davies, Ronald B., Julien Martin, Mathieu Parenti and Farid Toubal (2014), Knocking on
tax havens door: Multinational firms and transfer pricing, CEPII Working Paper, No.
2014-21.
DeMooij, Ruud A., and Sjef Ederveen (2008), Corporate Tax Elasticities A Readers
Guide to Empirical Findings, Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation,
Working Paper, No. 08/22.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 241
Dischinger, Matthias, and Nadine Riedel (2011), Corporate taxes and the location of
intangible assets within multinational firms, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 95(78), pp. 691-707.
Dreler, Daniel and Uwe Scheuering (2012), Empirical evaluation of interest barrier
effects, ZEW Discussion Papers, No. 12-046.
European Commission (2015), Patent Boxes Design, Patents Location and Local R&D,
Taxation Working Paper No. 57.
Griffith, Rachel, Helen Miller and Martin O'Connell (2011), Corporate Taxes and the
Location of Intellectual Property, CEPR Discussion Paper, No. DP8424.
Karkinsky, Tom, and Nadine Riedel (2012), Corporate taxation and the choice of patent
location within multinational firms, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 88(1),
pp. 176185.
Lanz, R. and S. Miroudot (2011), Intra-firm trade: Patterns, determinants and policy
implications, OECD Trade Policy Papers, No. 114,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5kg9p39lrwnn-en.
Markle, and L. Robinson (2012), Tax Haven Use Across International Tax Regimes,
www.sbs.ox.ac.uk/sites/default/files/Business_Taxation/Events/conferences/symposia/
2012/markle.
OECD, Activities of Multinational Enterprises (AMNE) database.
OECD (2008), Benchmark Definition of Foreign Direct Investment, 4th Edition.
OECD (2013), Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264202719-en
OECD (2015a), Aligning Transfer Pricing Outcomes with Value Creation, Actions 8-10 2015 Final Reports, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD
Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241244-en.
OECD (2015b), Limiting Base Erosion Involving Interest Deductions and Other
Financial Payments, Action 4 - 2015 Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and
Profit
Shifting
Project,
OECD
Publishing,
Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241176-en.
OECD (2015c), Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digital Economy, Action 1 - 2015
Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing,
Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241046-en.
OECD (2015d), Neutralising the Effects of Hybrid Mismatch Arrangements, Action 2 2015 Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD
Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241138-en.
OECD (2015e), Designing Effective Controlled Foreign Company Rules, Action 3 - 2015
Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing,
Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241152-en.
OECD (2015f), Countering Harmful Tax Practices More Effectively, Taking into Account
Transparency and Substance, Action 5 - 2015 Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion
and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241190-en.
242 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
OECD (2015g), Preventing the Granting of Treaty Benefits in Inappropriate
Circumstances, Action 6 - 2015 Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit
Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241695en.
OECD (2015h), Preventing the Artificial Avoidance of Permanent Establishment Status,
Action 7 - 2015 Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project,
OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241220-en.
OECD (2015i), Measuring and Monitoring BEPS, Action 11 - 2015 Final Report,
OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241343-en.
OECD (2015j), Mandatory Disclosure Rules, Action 12 - 2015 Final Report, OECD/G20
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing, Paris,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241442-en.
OECD (2015k), Making Dispute Resolution Mechanisms More Effective, Action 14 2015 Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD
Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241633-en.
OECD (2015l), Developing a Multilateral Instrument to Modify Bilateral Tax Treaties,
Action 15 -2015 Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project,
OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241688-en.
OECD, Trade in value-added: Concepts, methodologies, and challenges (Joint OECDWTO Note), www.oecd.org/sti/ind/49894138.pdf.
Overesch, Michael (2006), Transfer pricing of intrafirm sales as a profit shifting channel:
Evidence from German firm data, ZEW Discussion Papers, No. 06-84.
Riedel, N., (2014), Quantifying international tax avoidance: A review of the academic
literature, Paper prepared for the European Tax Policy Forum, mimeo.
Schindler, Dirk, and Martin Ruf, (2015), Debt Shifting and Thin-Capitalization Rules German Experiences and Alternative Approaches, Nordic Tax Journal, Vol. 1, 17-33.
Ruf, M. and A. J. Weichenrieder (2012), The taxation of passive foreign investment:
lessons from German experience, Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 45, No.4.
Ruf, M. and A. J. Weichenrieder (2013), CFC legislation, passive assets and the impact
of the ECJs Cadbury-Schweppes decision, CESifo Working Paper, No. 4461.
Schindler, Dirk, and Guttorm Schjelderup (2013), Transfer Pricing and Debt Shifting in
Multinationals, CESifo Working Paper Series, No. 4381.
Van t Riet, M. and A. Lejour, (2014), Ranking the stars: Network analysis of bilateral
tax treaties, CPB Discussion Paper, No. 290.
Vicard, Vincent (2015), Profit shifting through transfer pricing: Evidence from French
firm level trade data, Banque de France Working Paper No. 555. DOI:
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2614864.
Merlo, Valeria, and Georg Wamser (2015), Debt Shifting and Thin-capitalization Rules,
CESifo DICE Report, Vol. 12(4), pp. 27-31.
UNCTAD (2015), FDI, tax and development, UNCTAD Investment and Enterprise
Division Working Paper.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 243
Notes
1.
Page 21 of the OECD (2013) Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting.
2.
Page 21 of the OECD (2013) Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting:
further work needs to be done to monitor the impact of measures taken under the
Action Plan to address BEPS. This should include outcome-based techniques, which
look at measures of the allocation of income across jurisdictions relative to measures
of value creating activities, as well as techniques that can be used to monitor the
specific issues identified in the Action Plan.
3.
4.
5.
The reduction in the CIT tax base due to the location of debt in entities in higher-tax
countries is not included in the transfer pricing revenue impact estimating
methodology. It should be included in the revenue impact analysis for Action 4
dealing with the allowance of interest deductions related to third-party and relatedparty loans.
6.
The data includes detailed information on goods and services flows, by trade partner,
and is available for the OECD and G20 countries. Information on trade in goods is
available for additional countries from IMF data. Trade amounts would have to be
imputed for the missing services trade data for selected countries.
7.
For a detailed description of what is included in the trade in goods and services data,
see IMF, Sixth Edition of the Balance of Payments and International Investment
Position Manual (BPM6), available at
www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/bop/2007/bopman6.htm.
8.
Note that the methodology is described in terms of CIT revenue impacts. The BEPS
countermeasures would apply to all business income. To the extent that BEPS affects
business profits reported on individual income tax returns and information is
available, this additional revenue impact could be included in the BEPS impact
calculations.
9.
10.
The share of trade accounted for by transactions between MNE entities is available
for a limited number of countries. See Lanz and Miroudot (2011), as well as data on
MNE activities from specific countries, including the United States and Germany.
11.
The trade amounts may include round-trip transactions among entities. For
example, goods in process may be exported from an affiliate in country A to an
affiliate in country B for further processing. The finished product may then be
returned to the affiliate in country A as an import into country A. The full amounts of
244 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
both the export from country A and import into country A are included in the estimate
of mispricing. National account statisticians are addressing this issue of double
counting from the perspective of creating more accurate measures of trade flows that
affect a domestic economy. See the OECD, Trade in Value-Added: Concepts,
Methodologies, and Challenges (Joint OECD-WTO Note).
12.
13.
One method of reducing this incentive is to require a greater level of in-country real
activity (R&D, for example) to qualify for the special rates.
14.
In calculating the trade-weighted AMTR, the AMTR for each of a countrys trading
partners identified in the bilateral trade data is multiplied by the share of a countrys
total worldwide exports or imports accounted for by the trading partner.
15.
Alternatively, the calculations could be done at the level of trade flows between a
country and each of the countrys trading partners. In this case, it is not necessary to
calculate a weighted average STR for among all trading partners.
16.
The AMTRs would generally be the applicable tax rates for combined national and
sub-national CIT rates.
17.
These calculations use headline statutory tax rates except lower special tax rates that
apply to royalty income in selected countries.
18.
Although the value of the semi-elasticity is constant for all AMTR tax rate differential
calculations, it does result in variations in the elasticity of response to these tax rate
differentials. In other words, the larger the percentage change in tax rate differences,
the higher the percentage change in export and import prices. Elasticities of trade
pricing could be used for elasticities of net income to the extent that non-tax rate
factors are fully specified and accurately measured in a regression equation. The
percentage change in trade prices would affect net income due to tax rate differentials
in the same way that net income is affected by tax rate differentials, over and above
the estimated effect of non-tax factors. An extra dollar of revenue from trade
mispricing results in an extra dollar of net income, similar to an extra dollar of net
income from other profit shifting.
19.
Sebastian Beer and Jan Loeprick, Profit shifting: drivers of transfer mis(pricing) and
the potential of countermeasures, International Tax Public Finance, published online
17 May 2014, find that profit shifting responsiveness is higher for subsidiaries with
higher ratios of intangible to total assets. Matthias Dischinger and Nadine Riedel,
Corporate taxes and the location of intangible assets within multinational firms,
Journal of Public Economics 95 (2011) also find that an affiliates pre-tax income
response is more sensitive to tax rate differentials for groups with high ratios of
intangibles to sales. See also the results discussed in Annex 1.
20.
See for example, Andrew B. Bernard, J. Bradford Jensen, Peter K. Scott, Transfer
Pricing by U.S.-Based Multinational Firms, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Working Paper 12493, August 2006.
21.
While royalty payments for the use of intellectual property are included in the charges
for the use of intellectual property category, the value of sales of the outcome of R&D
are reported in the other business services category. These transactions, including the
sale of intangible property among MNE entities, are included in the trade in services
flows that are the beginning point for the transfer pricing revenue analysis.
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 245
22.
The financial services in the service trade data include brokerage, underwriting, credit
card and management and advisory services. Interest payments and receipts are
included in the primary income accounts.
23.
The data is captured for those entities where there is at least a 10% ownership link.
24.
25.
26.
27.
Countries which are European Union (EU) Member States would need to take into
account EU law considerations in designing their domestic rules, to ensure they are
compliant with EU law. The Report on Action 4 includes an annex detailing the
necessary considerations.
28.
29.
The interest limitation would apply to all business, irrespective of legal form. The
description will refer to CIT, but would be equally applicable to personal income tax
base changes of non-corporate businesses and their owners.
30.
31.
Please see the Report on Action 4 for a discussion on why tax exempt income, such as
exempt dividend income or foreign earnings that are tax exempt, should not form part
of the entitys EBITDA figure. The rationale behind excluding exempt dividend
income is to address concerns related to the outbound investment scenario as
described in Action Item 4.
32.
33.
See the discussion on applicable marginal tax rates in the transfer pricing section
(Actions 8-10 & 13).
246 3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES
34.
35.
36.
37.
Banks generate service income by lending at a higher rate of interest than they
borrow. This is considered a service for bringing the lenders and borrowers together.
Since depositors receive a lower rate of interest than the reference rate, the interest
received is increased by the amount of the difference between the reference rate and
the rate that depositors actually receive. Depositors immediately use this increase in
income to purchase the service. Conversely, borrowers pay a higher rate of interest
(than the reference rate), some of which reflects payments for a service. The National
Accounts subtract the difference between the higher rate that borrowers pay and the
reference rate. Again this difference is immediately used by borrowers to purchase
this service.
38.
39.
40.
The Business and Industry Advisory Committee to the OECD presented numbers in
the Action 4 Focus Group meetings showing the distribution of large public firms by
different external interest ratios.
41.
Please see the discussion on applicable marginal tax rates in the transfer pricing
section (Actions 8-10 & 13)
42.
This estimate is stacked after many other proposals such that some of the revenue
effects are reflected in other estimates.
43.
Action 3 notes that this method generally recognises that even in a situation where the
statutory tax rate is not considered a low tax rate, low taxation may occur as a result
of (1) reducing the tax base or (2) lowering the tax burden by subsequent rebates of
taxes paid or through non-enforcement of taxes.
44.
Determining attributable income would be unnecessary for countries that opt for a
full-inclusion system, i.e. once an entity is classified as a CFC, all income is treated as
CFC income, which is relevant in the context of worldwide tax systems.
45.
There are exceptions: United States intra-firm imports and exports are collected for
disaggregated service items, and both Canada and the United States break down
services trade by affiliation (Lanz & Miroudot, 2011).
46.
See discussion on the applicable marginal tax rate (AMTR) in the section on transfer
pricing (Actions 8-10 & 13).
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
3. TOWARDS MEASURING THE SCALE AND ECONOMIC IMPACT OF BEPS AND COUNTERMEASURES 247
47.
In the case of the 2012 study, the data was supplemented with information on national
characteristics from the World Bank Development Indicators and with tax rate
information from PWC, the Bureau of Tax Policy Research at the University of
Michigan, KPMG, and other sources.
48.
Please see the discussion on applicable marginal tax rates in the transfer pricing
section (Actions 8-10 & 13).
49.
The sources include the IMF Balance of Payments Statistics and the OECD
International Direct Investment Database. In compiling and presenting FDI statistics,
compilers in many countries may encounter the possibility of confidential data
occurring in the results to be disseminated. FDI information can be regarded as being
confidential in a primary sense for a number of reasons: (i) if a compiler declares it to
be confidential, (ii) if there is only one or at most two entities giving rise to the
information, or (iii) if the contribution of a particular enterprise (or even two
enterprises) dominate(s) the contributions of all other entities (OECD, 2008).
50.
51.
Note that this result refers to the combined remaining tax rate, potentially including
CIT in the recipient country, depending on the relief method.
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 249
Chapter 4
Towards better data and tools for monitoring BEPS in the future
Key points:
The limitations of currently available data and the complexity of BEPS mean that
improved data and tools are necessary if the global community is to obtain a clearer
picture of the scale and impact of BEPS and properly monitor the effectiveness of the
measures implemented under the BEPS project.
Given the large, and soon to be expanded, volume of data in the hands of tax
administrations, this reports recommendations focus on the need for governments to
work more closely together to make better use of data that is already (or has been
agreed, as part of the BEPS project, to be) collected. In particular, statistical analyses
based upon data collected under the Action 13 Country-by-Country Reports have the
potential to significantly enhance the economic analysis of BEPS.
This report makes the following recommendations:
The OECD should work with all OECD members and BEPS Associates (including
all G20 countries) and any country willing to participate to publish, on a regular
basis, a new Corporate Tax Statistics publication, which would compile a range of
data and statistical analyses relevant to the economic analysis of BEPS in an
internationally consistent format. Among other information, this publication would
include aggregated and anonymised statistical analyses prepared by governments
based on the data collected under the Action 13 Country-by-Country Reports.
The OECD should work with all OECD members, BEPS Associates and any
willing participating governments to produce periodic reports on the estimated
revenue impacts of proposed and enacted BEPS countermeasures.
The OECD should continue to produce and refine analytical tools and BEPS
Indicators to monitor the scale and economic impact of BEPS and to evaluate the
effectiveness and economic impact of BEPS countermeasures.
Governments should improve the public reporting of business tax revenue
statistics, particularly for MNEs.
Governments should continue to make improvements in non-tax data relevant to
BEPS with wider country coverage, such as for FDI associated with resident SPEs,
trade in services and intangible investments.
Governments should consider current best practices and explore new approaches to
collaborating on BEPS research with academics and other researchers.
Governments should encourage more research on MNE activity within tax
administrations, tax policy offices, national statistical offices (NSO), and by
academic researchers, to improve the understanding of BEPS, and to better
separate BEPS from real economic effects and non-BEPS tax preferences.
250 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
Monitoring BEPS in the future will require that governments make better use of the data
that is already (or has been agreed, as part of the BEPS project, to be) collected.
Additional and more in-depth analysis of BEPS and the publication of statistical results
and aggregate tabulations of MNE taxes and activities by individual countries will also
be important to evaluating the effectiveness of BEPS countermeasures.
4.1 Introduction
268. The limitations of currently available data and current estimation methodologies
mean that improved data and tools will be necessary if the global community is to obtain
a clearer picture of the scale and impact of BEPS and properly monitor the effectiveness
of the measures implemented under the BEPS project.
269. Chapter 1 included an assessment of currently available data, which concluded
that the significant limitations of existing data sources mean that, at present, attempts to
construct indicators or undertake economic analyses of the scale and impact of BEPS are
severely constrained and thus must be heavily qualified. More comprehensive and more
detailed data regarding MNEs is needed to provide a more accurate assessment of the
scale and impact of BEPS.
270. Chapters 2 and 3 noted the difficulties in constructing BEPS indicators as well as
undertaking economic analysis with the currently available data. At present, in addition to
the data limitations, there is also a lack of detailed information on countries tax rules and
aggregate tax bases, which are all needed for improved cross-country economic analyses
of BEPS and the effects of BEPS countermeasures. Economic analyses must separate
BEPS behaviours from both the effects of real economic factors as well as the effects of
non-BEPS tax preferences such as R&D tax incentives and other legislated special rates,
deductions and exemptions.
271. Governments, and in particular tax administrations, already collect an array of
information regarding the tax affairs of MNEs and their affiliates. The scope and value of
this information will be increased as a result of the work undertaken as part of Action 5
(spontaneous exchange of rulings), Action 13 (transfer pricing documentation), and
where implemented, Action 12 (disclosure of aggressive tax planning arrangements).
While the need to improve the economic and fiscal analysis of BEPS requires greater
access to this data, any recommendations around the availability of data in the future must
take into account the need to protect the confidentiality of taxpayer information and
minimise the administrative burden for governments and taxpayers.
272. Given the large, and soon to be expanded, volume of data in the hands of tax
administrations, this reports recommendations focus on the need for governments to
make better use of data that is already (or has been agreed, as part of the BEPS project, to
be) collected and share best practices. Tax administrations can maximise the benefits of
available information by increasing access to this data for research purposes under strict
confidentiality rules. In addition, as statisticians continue to improve National Accounts
with the measurement of foreign direct investment (FDI) through special purpose entities
(SPEs) and other conduits, more disaggregation of bilateral trade in services data
including payments for intellectual property and management services, and the
measurement of intangible investments, these changes will provide further assistance to
future economic analysis of BEPS.
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 251
273. The tools to be used to analyse and publish data in the future should be developed
in a consistent and co-ordinated way so that when better data becomes available in the
future it can be analysed and published in its most meaningful form. Increased analysis
and publication of statistical results, particularly in the form of aggregate tabulations of
taxes and activities of MNEs by individual countries will be important in better
understanding BEPS.
274. Analyses of BEPS countermeasures may be useful for individual countries as they
consider enactment and implementation, as well as monitoring the effects of
countermeasures on BEPS going forward. Countries will differ in terms of the specific
BEPS countermeasures adopted (some already have implemented certain BEPS
countermeasures) and in the timing of their implementation. Improvements in the data
and tools for analysis of BEPS and BEPS countermeasures are critical for policymakers,
and those improvements will need to be undertaken by individual countries as well as
international organisations.
4.2 Background
275. The future path of BEPS measurement is clearly dependent on increasing the
quality and relevance of data available to improve indicators and economic analyses of
BEPS, as shown in Figure 4.1. In the current state of BEPS analysis, analysts are
generally exploiting the available data, although some of the data already being collected
are not currently being compiled for analysis and access is often limited. While there are
some new and innovative types of analysis of BEPS being undertaken, all analyses are
constrained by significant data limitations. The academic community has demonstrated its
creativity in examining new dimensions of BEPS to explore with currently available data,
but there are diminishing returns to working with the current data, particularly non-tax
return data.
276. The objective is that, in the future, better data will allow new and more refined
indicators as well as refined economic analysis of BEPS and the effectiveness of BEPS
countermeasures. Better data has a number of different dimensions.
More relevant BEPS information (i.e. total MNE tax payments by country, tax
residence of the entity rather than simply country of incorporation, related party
transactions and structures).
More coverage of companies, countries, and MNE relationships.
More complete set of companies (e.g. fewer missing entities and groups
and better coverage across all countries).
More complete information from currently available company tax and nontax records (e.g. fewer missing financial variables).1
Clear identification of MNE companies on tax return forms, both domestic
companies of foreign MNE parents and domestic parents of foreign
affiliates. Improved linkages between related entities and the overall MNE
group information.
Expanded linkages between tax and other financial information.
Increased access to available data for government analysts and academic
researchers under strict confidentiality and access requirements.
Increased data consistency across countries.
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
252 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
More timely information with shorter time lags.
277. Initiatives could be taken in the areas described above that would improve the
available data, increase the signal-to-noise ratio in future BEPS analyses, and help
separate BEPS from other factors.
Figure 4.1. Future path of BEPS measurement
Current State
Indicators of
BEPS with
available data
Analyses of
economic
impact of BEPS
and countermeasures with
available data
Future State
New and
refined
indicators with
better data
Refined
analyses of
economic
impact of BEPS
and countermeasures with
better data
Ideal
True measures of
BEPS and
countermeasures
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 253
conditions of access, to conduct their own research or special studies of tax return
information for the purposes of tax policy or economic analysis.
282. Box 4.1 outlines some examples of best practices concerning data availability for
the purpose of tax analysis of corporate tax and MNEs. As can be seen from the examples
of best practices, an important factor in the availability of current data is whether data that
has been provided to tax administrations is compiled into an electronic database that is
easily accessible by government tax analysts. Increased electronic filing of corporate
income tax returns will make the compilation of more data less resource intensive for tax
administrations.
283. While electronic filing systems are helpful, where information is not collected in a
standardised format, compilation will involve searching for the specific data item (often
with different terminology across different datasets) and then sorting into standardised
categories. Unless there is a tax form which taxpayers are required to complete, it is likely
that the information will not be compiled for tax policy analysis without requiring
significant extra resources and effort.3 Additional information requested on tax returns
that may not be required for the calculation of tax liability, such as information on
balance sheets or specific income and expense items may not be completed by taxpayers
with the same degree of care and diligence.
Box 4.1. Some best practices in data availability for tax analysis of corporate tax
and MNEs
Published aggregated tables of MNE tax data: The United States Internal Revenue Service
publishes special tabulations every other year of information from foreign affiliates of United
States MNEs (information Form 5471 including Schedule M) and from domestic affiliates of
foreign MNEs (Form 5472). The tables present aggregated totals of the components of taxable
income and deductions by country and industry, including in the case of Form 5472 detailed
aggregated transactions with related parties.
Information on cross-border related party transactions: The Australian Taxation Office requires
certain taxpayers to complete an annual international dealings schedule, which contains a
specific section on international related party transactions.4 The specific section is required to be
completed where the total amount of their international related party transactions exceeds
AUD 2 million. In addition, for the countries with the three largest related party transaction
totals, the taxpayer is asked to specify the country and detail the activity type and the aggregate
transaction amount (expenses/losses plus revenue/gains). The schedule also requires notification
of restructures, dealings in intangibles, derivatives transactions and information on the number
of CFCs in each country and an explanation of thin capitalisation arrangements on the Australian
side.
Access to qualified academic researchers under strict confidentiality rules: 15 OECD countries5
currently have special programs that provide qualified academics with access to corporate tax
return data for analysis under strict confidentiality rules. These programs enable sophisticated
empirical analysis of tax return data, complementing analysis of non-tax return data, while
maximising the benefit of existing data. See case study box of these programs.
Quantifying corporate tax preferences: A number of countries regularly publish the fiscal cost of
special tax rates, deductions, exemptions and credits in their corporate income tax. Although
there can be conceptual and measurement issues with some preferences, most corporate tax
preferences are readily measurable such as corporate tax credits, special low tax rates, and
deductions in excess of 100% of expenditures.
254 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
Box 4.1. Some best practices in data availability for tax analysis of corporate tax
and MNEs (continued)
Analysis of MNE investments: The German Bundesbank, the Japan External Trade
Organisation, and the United States Bureau of Economic Analysis conduct special surveys of the
multinational affiliates operations. While not tax focused, the information from these surveys
has provided academic researchers operating under strict confidentiality rules with an important
source of data about MNE behaviours. Concerns about MNE response rates have limited any
matching of these investment surveys with tax return information.
Aggregate audit analyses: Several countries report on their corporate audit and enforcement
activities, including amounts assessed and assessments collected. These analyses have not
separated MNEs from other corporations, and generally do not separately report by type of
assessment, such as specific BEPS behaviours. Several commentators on the Action 11 Public
Discussion Document suggested aggregated data from audits and examinations would aid in the
analysis of BEPS.
International and regional tax statistics: Consistent, comparable, and quality-checked tax
statistics are extremely important for policymakers and other tax stakeholders. The OECD
Revenue Statistics and Tax Policy Database provide detailed information on a comparable basis
for OECD countries and an increasing number of non-OECD countries in its regional
publications.
Matching available databases: Separating BEPS behaviours from real economic effects will
require data on real economic variables. Several tax administrations, policy offices and other
researchers supplement corporate tax return information with other databases to maximise the
available information. The Australia Taxation Office compares and contrasts corporate tax return
data with the databases of external agencies and organisations in order to ensure compliance
with tax obligations.6
Better utilisation of technology in collection and compilation of taxpayer data: Access to and
compilation of taxpayer data could be eased by the use of a digital system to collect and store it.
Brazil has unified tax and book-keeping information through a digital system; the Sistema
Pblico de Escriturao Digital, at the federal, state and municipal levels. In addition, Japans
Kokuzei Sogo Kanri system links all regional tax information for analysis.
Focus on data quality: Data quality can be enhanced by dedicated personnel focused on
improving the accuracy and completeness of data obtained from tax forms. The Department of
Finance, the Canada Revenue Agency and Statistics Canada have established a joint committee
for data quality, supported by working groups with subject matter specialists in areas including:
corporation and individual reporting, partnership and trust reporting, international reporting, and
sales tax reporting. The working groups meet regularly to address issues that arise, discuss
information technology system and/or form changes that are necessary to reflect legislative
amendments, and develop ways to improve data quality.
Statistical sampling: Even with electronic records, statistical sampling can be a useful tool to
examine tax return data too voluminous to approach with other techniques, such as quality
assurance and imputations. Statistics compiled by the United States Internal Revenue Service
(IRS) Statistics of Income (SOI) Division are generally based on statistical sampling. Returns are
assigned to sampling classes (or strata) based on criteria including the form type filed, various
income factors or other measures of economic size, and industry. Statistical samples are then
selected from each stratum and can be extrapolated to population totals.
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 255
256 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 257
258 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
291. Advances in the use of analytical and monitoring tools are being made by
researchers alongside improvements in the available data. Academic researchers have
extended empirical analyses through meta-analyses of multiple empirical studies of the
same phenomena and by analysing BEPS through tax rate differentials between affiliates
or between parent entities. Continued improvement in analytical techniques and
approaches, such as analysing MNE entities share of profitability and economic activity
of the entire MNE group are promising approaches.
No confidentiality issues or
issues overcome
Non-Tax Data
Data not
already
collected [7]
Data already
(or to be)
collected
Data not
already
collected
Possible confidentiality
issues
Currently
compiled
Not currently
compiled [4]
Issues can be
overcome [5]
Currently
analysed
Not currently
analysed [3]
What
measures?
Currently
published [1]
Not currently
published [2]
Access: who?
Confidentiality
is a barrier [6]
Access: what
form?
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 259
295. Data already being collected can be divided between data that does not involve
any confidentiality issues (or where those issues have already been overcome) and data
that has potential confidentiality issues. If there are possible confidentiality issues, then
those data can be divided into those where confidentiality issues might be overcome and
those where confidentiality issues will continue to be a barrier to access. Where there are
current confidentiality issues that might be overcome, consideration must be given to
determining what types of measures (e.g. legislative, administrative, etc.) are necessary to
address those confidentiality concerns, and then who might gain access (e.g. other
government analysts, academic researchers) and in what form would that access be
granted. In response to a questionnaire circulated by WP2 of the Committee on Fiscal
Affairs in June 2015, 17 of the 38 country respondents indicated that their tax
administrations provide access to information on payments between related parties from
tax return data to other government tax policy analysts.9 In 16 of the 38 respondent
countries, tax administrations allow access to corporate tax data to qualified academic
researchers and national statistical offices under strict confidentiality rules.
296. If data is collected and does not have confidentiality issues, there are still issues of
whether the data is compiled such that it can be analysed without excessive resource
costs. New electronic search technologies can now help pull information from openended text, but these processes still remain labour intensive. Resource constraints may
prevent even compiled data from being analysed. Tax administrations may have many
other priorities that take precedence before tax policy analysis is undertaken. Finally,
when data is analysed, it may not be published for a wider audience, again due to
resource constraints or other limitations. A number of tax administrations compile,
analyse and publish aggregated tables of corporate tax data without confidentiality issues.
297. Figure 4.2 specifically identifies seven categories of tax data, where future actions
may be considered to improve the available data and analysis of BEPS. A number of
potential future actions are identified below for each of the seven data groups, ranging
from consideration of additional metrics and analyses for tax data already collected,
analysed and published to focusing efforts on other groups of data when tax or non-tax
data has confidentiality issues.
1) Tax data already collected without confidentiality issues, currently compiled,
analysed and published
Consider additional metrics and analyses (e.g. specific analyses of MNEs,
expanded access to researchers under confidentiality arrangements)
Consider standardised formats for international comparability
2) Tax data already collected without confidentiality issues, currently compiled and
analysed, but not published
Consider additional metrics and analyses (e.g. specific analyses of MNEs,
expanded access to research under confidentiality arrangements, merging
databases)
Consider publishing analyses, and in standardised formats for international
comparability
260 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
3) Tax data already collected without confidentiality issues, already compiled but not
analysed
Consider additional analyses of the compiled data, and publication (e.g. specific
analyses of MNEs, expanded access to research under confidentiality
arrangements, merging databases)
4) Tax data already collected without confidentiality issues, not currently compiled
Consider which data is most useful for analysis (e.g. their benefits) and the cost
of compilation (e.g. specific analyses of MNEs, merging databases)
Consider processes to reduce compilation costs (e.g. statistical sampling)
Consider how data may be compiled in standardised formats for international
comparability
5) Tax data already collected, but possible confidentiality issues which may be
overcome
Consider what measures need to be taken to overcome confidentiality barriers
Consider who could have access (e.g. government tax policy analysts)
Consider what form the access could take (e.g. aggregated anonymised
tabulations)
6) Tax data already collected, but confidentiality is a barrier
Consider available alternatives to maximise benefit of data within
confidentiality limits (e.g. aggregated anonymised tabulations, access to
qualified researchers under strict confidentiality rules)
7) Tax data not already (or not agreed to be) collected
Focus on maximising the analysis and publication of tax data already collected
298. Monitoring BEPS in the future will require taking better advantage of currently
available (and soon to be provided) data in the hands of tax administrations. Increased
analysis and publication of statistical results and aggregated tabulations of MNE taxes
and activities by individual countries will be important to evaluating the effectiveness and
economic impact of BEPS countermeasures and ensuring that BEPS is properly
monitored in the future.
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 261
states that CbCR may also be used by tax administrations in evaluating other BEPS
related risks and where appropriate for economic and statistical analysis.10 While the use
of CbCR data is restricted to governments, statistical analyses based on the data included in
the CbCR have the potential to greatly improve future BEPS analyses. The conventional
statistical and economic analyses examining profit rates of individual affiliates based on
economic factors as well as tax rate differentials could be improved. Unlike analyses of
financial statement data, the statistical analyses based on CbCR data will be able to use
actual income taxes paid to the tax jurisdiction of the entities, and will include all entities
of the MNE group.11 The CbCR will be required of MNE groups with annual
consolidated group revenue in the preceding year of EUR 750 million or more, which is
estimated to exclude 85-90% of MNE groups while still covering MNE groups
responsible for approximately 90% of global corporate revenues.
301.
One of the benefits of CbCR is that there is a standard reporting template for
filing which will maintain consistent reporting rules across countries as a means of
limiting taxpayer compliance costs. The standard reporting template and its conversion to
electronic files will also enable less costly compilation of the included data by tax
administrations. MNEs will also file a master file, which provides an overview of the
MNE group business and its overall transfer pricing policies, and a local file, which
provides more detailed information relating to specific intercompany transactions. The
local file will include important information about transactions between related parties,
such as interest and royalties.12 This information would be helpful to analyse BEPS, but
will not be provided in a standard template. Tax administrations will have access to the
data, but it will require more resources to extract and compile the information.
302. The first CbCR will be filed for 2016 calendar year filers no later than
31 December 2017. Thus, some CbCR data will be available for statistical analysis as
early as the end of 2017. However, more complete data for 2016 will not be available
until later. Tax administrations and government tax policy analysts will want to be ready
to quickly analyse the data when it becomes available.13
303. Statistical analysis in the form of aggregated and anonymised tabulations based
on CbCR data would provide governments with a complete view of the largest MNEs
global activities for the first time. These statistical analyses would not disclose individual
taxpayer specific information, and any publication would depend on the countrys
confidentiality rules. In addition, governments should consider other immediate
compilation, analysis, publication and access improvements in other MNE corporate data
for analysing BEPS and BEPS countermeasures in the meantime. Increased benefits
could be obtained from the publication of such data in aggregated and anonymised form,
especially if such analyses are tabulated using a format that is consistent across countries.
To achieve such consistency, greater co-ordination between governments would be
required.
304. Given confidentiality considerations, tax administrations and some government
offices are the only ones with access to tax return information of MNEs operating in their
countries.14 When the first CbCR become available to governments in 2017, access to the
reports will be limited to those government offices. During the public consultations on the
Action 11 discussion draft, a number of commenters suggested that a formal repository or
global database of MNE CbCR should be created. Given concerns around confidentiality,
there are no plans for such an approach,15 however, there would clearly be considerable
benefit for BEPS analysis in developing an internationally co-ordinated approach to
262 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
compiling the results of statistical analyses that are aggregated, anonymised, and based
upon global CbCR data.
4.6 Recommendations
305. It is clear from the assessment of current data that analyses of BEPS with non-tax
return information provide an incomplete picture. Using publicly available non-tax return
data has shown the presence and significance of BEPS, but has not provided clear
measures of the scale and scope of BEPS. Non-tax return information does not have
complete coverage, and those companies that are missing or not reporting financial
information may be undertaking significant BEPS. Non-tax return information does not
allow the separation of BEPS impacts from the impacts of non-BEPS tax preferences. For
example, ETRs could be reduced by enacted tax incentives and special tax rates, as well
as BEPS behaviours.
306. Thus, better analysis of BEPS in the future will require more analysis of tax return
data by individual countries tax administrations and/or their tax policy offices. Given the
large, and soon to be expanded, volume of data in the hands of tax administrations, this
reports recommendations focus on the need for governments to work more closely
together to make better use of data that is already (or has been agreed, as part of the BEPS
project, to be) collected. Consistent with this approach, this report makes the following
recommendations:16
Recommendation 1
The OECD should work with all OECD members, BEPS Associates and any country willing to
participate to publish, on a regular basis, a new Corporate Tax Statistics publication, which
would compile a range of data and statistical analyses relevant to the economic analysis of BEPS
in an internationally consistent format. Among other information, this publication would include
aggregated and anonymised statistical analyses prepared by governments based on the data
collected under the Action 13 Country-by-Country Reports.
307. The OECD, through WP2 of the Committee on Fiscal Affairs, should work with
OECD members, BEPS Associates and any willing participating countries to develop
appropriate data classification guidelines and a standardised reporting template and
process, which will allow for the compilation and publication on a regular basis of
internationally consistent and comparable corporate tax statistics, which could include the
following:
Total corporate/business tax revenues collected by governments
MNE share of corporate/business tax collected
Breakdown of business taxes by industry/sector
Summaries of countries statistical aggregated analyses based on data obtained
from CbCR
Key income and expense items of the corporate tax base
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 263
Identification and quantification of tax credits, special low tax rates, and other
tax preferences
Corporate withholding taxes
308. These statistics would be provided in an aggregated and anonymised form to
ensure that taxpayer confidentiality is strictly preserved.
309.
Current cross-country analyses of corporate tax systems often use a crude
measure of the corporate tax base, by dividing corporate tax collections by the headline
statutory tax rate. This significantly understates the corporate taxable income by ignoring
corporate tax credits and special low tax rates, and could be improved with additional
information on corporate tax preferences.
Recommendation 2
The OECD should work with all OECD members, BEPS Associates and any willing
participating governments to produce periodic reports on the estimated revenue impacts of
proposed and enacted BEPS countermeasures.
310. The OECD, through WP2 of the Committee on Fiscal Affairs, should work with
participating governments to develop a standardised reporting template and process,
which will support the publication of periodic reports on the estimated revenue impacts of
proposed and enacted countermeasures.
311. These reports could monitor the expected revenue impacts of proposed reforms
and the estimated revenue impact of enacted reforms. Improved metrics of existing and
future BEPS countermeasures could be developed for cross-country research by analysts.
Recommendation 3
The OECD should continue to produce and refine analytical tools and BEPS Indicators to
monitor the scale and economic impact of BEPS and to evaluate the effectiveness and economic
impact of BEPS countermeasures.
312. Chapter 2 presents a dashboard of BEPS Indicators. While these indicators are
not intended to precisely measure the scale of BEPS, they do provide clear indications of
the existence of BEPS and with improved data and further refinement over time may
prove useful in monitoring trends and changes in BEPS.
313. As further data becomes available, not only will this lead to refinements in the
indicators presented, but may also allow for new and enhanced indicators to be
constructed, including those indicators identified in Chapter 2 as possible future
indicators.
314. Annex 3.A2 presents a toolkit for analysing the fiscal effects of BEPS
countermeasures for governments to use in their consideration of estimating future
revenue effects. The toolkit could be expanded to include the availability of statistical
analyses based on data collected under Action 13s Country-by-Country Reports. The
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
264 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
toolkit could also be refined with the shared experience of government estimators and
analysts who have estimated the effects of countermeasures in different countries.
Recommendation 4
Governments should improve the public reporting of business tax statistics, particularly for
MNEs.
315. Many countries currently do not separately identify MNEs for statistical reporting
of business tax statistics. The Action 13 Country-by-Country Reports will identify large
MNEs present in a country. Separate business tax statistics for in-bound MNEs (domestic
affiliates of foreign parents), out-bound MNEs (domestic parents with foreign affiliates)
as well as domestic-only businesses may be able to be compiled. Special tabulations from
the local files of the Country-by-Country Reports may provide more detail about MNEs
tax situation beyond the information in the standardised reports.
316. In the case of a large number of countries, including many low-income and
developing countries, there is a need for the improved compilation and publication of
basic, and expanded, revenue statistics. Increased information about incentives provided
to MNEs may also provide a starting point for an evaluation of their effectiveness.
317. Research on BEPS has been hampered by the lack of basic, quality revenue
statistical data. This is a fact for all countries, but is especially the case for developing
countries, where studies by academic researchers have highlighted the importance of
being able to access more information on BEPS in developing countries. Increased
technical assistance and support from developed countries should be provided. The
OECD Revenue Statistics and Regional Revenue Statistical publications provide a
possible template for the collection of data for countries that do not currently publish
regular, comparable and internationally consistent revenue statistics.
Recommendation 5
Governments should continue to make improvements in non-tax data relevant to BEPS, such as
by broadening country coverage and improving data on FDI associated with resident SPEs, trade
in services and intangible investments.
318. While CbCR has the potential to greatly enhance micro-level tax data of MNEs,
continued improvement in non-tax macroeconomic data and micro-level data will assist
future analysis of BEPS. Recent analyses of trade data, investment and FDI data have
provided important insights to the analysis of BEPS. Wider coverage of countries
included in these international statistics would be beneficial.
319. The Benchmark Definition of Foreign Direct Investment, 4th edition (BMD4)
recommends that countries include transactions with Special Purpose Entities (SPEs) in
their FDI statistics to ensure comparability with other countries. It also provides guidance
on compiling FDI statistics that exclude transactions with SPEs, but does not recommend
specific identification of SPEs and other conduits. These statistics enable policymakers to
assess the impact of FDI into their economies because the statistics will better reflect FDI
MEASURING AND MONITORING BEPS OECD 2015
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 265
into businesses with a real presence in the economy. These statistics also better measure
outward investment from countries by removing funds that pass through their economy
but originate elsewhere. Additional countries reporting SPEs would enable improved
analyses.
320. Improvements in the measurement of intangibles investments, including the
capitalisation of investments in research and development, will enable researchers to
better identify the contributors to profitability and the scale of their contribution. Detailed
analyses of trade statistics and investment surveys have been used by researchers to
analyse BEPS, but have been limited to only a few countries.
Recommendation 6
Governments should consider current best practices and explore new approaches to collaborating
on BEPS research with academics and other researchers. Governments should encourage more
research on MNE activity within tax administrations, tax policy offices, national statistical
offices, and by academic researchers, to improve the understanding of BEPS, and to better
separate BEPS from real economic effects and non-BEPS tax preferences.
321. Research by academics, national statistical offices17 and other tax policy analysts
is important to advancing the progress of the economic analysis of MNEs, BEPS and any
BEPS countermeasures. There are numerous examples of best practices, many of which
have been set out earlier in this chapter, where governments have made tax return data
available
to
researchers
under
strict
confidentiality
and
access
requirements. Governments should look to existing best practices and consider options
for improving collaboration with academics and researchers in the future.
322. In many countries, the collection of business statistics data used in compiling
national accounts makes no distinction between whether the firms are foreign affiliates or
domestically owned. Where available, the data shows significant differences across these
categories of firms.
323. Since separating real economic effects from BEPS is important, non-tax research
is needed on a number of issues, including:
What contributes to value added by businesses and particularly MNEs
The measurement and contributions to value of intangible assets
Understanding sources of differences between MNEs and domestic-only
companies
Non-tax determinants of MNE location decisions
4.7 Conclusion
324. The recommendations made in this report, combined with new statistical analyses
possible based on data from Actions 5, 13, and, where implemented, Action 12 will
enable policymakers in the future to have stronger economic analyses of BEPS and the
effects of BEPS countermeasures.
325. More information about BEPS will be needed to monitor the effects of the BEPS
program in the future, since BEPS is a global problem and individual country tax
administrations have the best data. Better data and tools for analysing BEPS are critical to
266 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
separating the effects of BEPS from real economic activity and non-BEPS tax
preferences.
326. Better data and improved analyses should be a priority to ensure that all
stakeholders have a better understanding of the fiscal and economic effects of BEPS, and
the impact of BEPS countermeasures and their effectiveness over time. Improved data
and analysis will assist policy makers by underpinning future decisions with an even
stronger evidence base and will, over time; help build greater trust and confidence among
all taxpayers in the effectiveness of the international tax rules.
Bibliography
Keightley, M. P. and J. M. Stupak (2015), Corporate Tax Base Erosion and Profit
Shifting (BEPS): An Examination of the Data, United States Congressional Research
Report.
Mahoney, L. and R. Miller (2013), Controlled Foreign Corporations, United States
Internal Revenue Service Statistics of Income SOI Bulletin, Winter 2013.
McDonald, M. (2008), Income shifting from transfer pricing: Further evidence from tax
return data, United States Department of the Treasury, Office of Tax Analysis, OTA
Technical Working Paper 2.
OECD (2015), Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting,
Action 13 - 2015 Final Report, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project,
OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241480-en.
Sullivan, M. A. (2010), Transfer Pricing Issues in a Global Economy, Testimony before
the UNITED STATES House of Representatives Ways and Means Committee, July
22, 2010.
4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE 267
Notes
1.
Many financial statement databases include observations for companies but without
accompanying financial information. Several government tax policy analysts have
noted that tax return information that is not specifically required for the tax liability
calculation are not as complete as the tax return lines for the tax liability calculation,
such as balance sheet data on assets and liabilities or data on information returns.
2.
Based on June 2015 survey responses of 30 OECD countries, just over half of the
countries tax policy offices have access to individual company tax return
information.
3.
4.
www.ato.gov.au/uploadedFiles/Content/MEI/downloads/International-dealingsschedule-2015.pdf.
5.
The OECD countries that grant access to tax return data, under strict confidentiality
conditions, to qualified (non-government) researchers include: Belgium, Canada,
Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Korea, Netherlands, New Zealand, Sweden,
Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States. South Africa also grants
access to these data to researchers.
6.
Another example can be found in McDonald (2008), Income Shifting from Transfer
Pricing: Further Evidence from Tax Return Data, where Compustat data was merged
with tax return records in order to add financial information for United States parents
of CFCs.
7.
Lee Mahoney and Randy Miller, Controlled Foreign Corporations, United States
Internal Revenue Service Statistics of Income SOI Bulletin, Winter 2013.
8.
9.
268 4. TOWARDS BETTER DATA AND TOOLS FOR MONITORING BEPS IN THE FUTURE
10.
11.
12.
Other related party transactions that have been analysed for BEPS issues, include
dividends, cost sharing, property right, sales of stock in trade, and serve transactions.
13
When calculating effective tax rates (e.g. income tax paid as a percent of profit), it
will be important to separate firms with positive profits from firms with losses,
otherwise the aggregated effective tax rates will be overstated.
14.
15.
16.
It is noted that countries, especially those with a more decentralised tax system, will
need sufficient time to analyse and/or implement the recommendations set out in this
chapter.
17.
National statistical offices are making advances in the development and collection of
economic data that will assist researchers in measuring and monitoring BEPS. As
reported in the summary of a recent conference on national accounts organized by the
Conference of European Statisticians, national statistical offices are developing
additional data sources to measure economic activities of MNEs and global value
chains. Examples of new developments include integrating data from multiple
sources, both macro and micro, disaggregating FDI statistics, and extending trade
statistics, such as trade in value added, to more accurately measure the influence of
international trade on domestic economies.
isbn 978-92-64-24133-6
23 2015 36 1 P