Change of Measure For Brownian Motion

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 4

P10-1

Project 10

1.

Change of measure for Brownian motion


Let {Bt : 0 t 1} be a Brownian motion with respect to a (standard)
ltration {Ft } on (, F, P). Write U for its quadratic variation process, Ut = t.
For each R, the process


qt = exp Bt 12 2 t
for 0 t 1
is a nonnegative martingale, with Pqt = Pq0 = 1. Dene a new probability
measure Q on F1 by specifying q1 to be its density with respect to P. That is,
Q X = P(Xq1 )
at least for all bounded random variables X .
Show that Q is equivalent to P, in the sense that both measures have the
same collection N of negligible sets.
Show that Q X = P(Xqt ) if X is Ft -measurable. Explain why qt is a
Radon-Nikodym density for Q with respect to P when both measures are
restricted to Ft .
For xed s and t = s + , a xed F in Fs , and a bounded measurable f ,
show that



Q F f (Bt Bs ) = P(Fqs ) P f (Bt Bs ) exp (Bt Bs ) 12 2



1
= Q F
f (z) exp 12 (z )2 / dz

Deduce that, under Q , the process Bt t is a standard Brownian motion.

2.

The Black-Scholes formula


Stock prices (in units so that S0 1) are sometimes modeled by a continuous
process driven by a Brownian motion, B, on [0, 1];
St = exp(( 1/2 2 )t + Bt )
for 0 t 1
2

1
= exp( Bt /2 t)
where 
Bt = Bt + (/ )t
for constants > 0 (assumed known) and (unknown). That is,
St = (Bt , Ut )

I am ignoring ination. cf.


expression of value of stock as
a multiple of a bond price.

where (x, y) = exp( x + ( 1/2 2 )y).

Suppose Y = f (S), with f a C-measurable functional on C[0, 1]. How much


should one pay at time 0 in order to receive the amount Y at time 1?
Use the Ito formula to show that
<1>

St = 1 + S Bt + S Ut ,

In more traditional notation,


d St
= d Bt + dt.
St
Roughly speaking, the relative increments of S behave like the increments of
a Brownian motion with drift . The process S B is the locM20 [0, 1] part
of the semimartingale decomposition of S.
d St = St d Bt + St dt,

Statistics 603a: 11 November 2004

or

c David Pollard


P10-2

Similarly, show that St = 1 + S 


Bt .
Show that Y can be written as a C-measurable functional of the 
B sample
path.
Temporarily suppose that = 0, so that 
B is a standard Brownian motion.
(i) Use stochastic calculus to show that
1

B=
S
S
Hint: What do you know about the increments of the process that takes
a constant value?
(ii) Suppose PY 2 < . Invoke results from Project 9 to show that there
exists a predictable H such that
H
<2>
Y = PY + H 
B1 = PY + K S1
where K :=
.
S
(iii) Interpret the last equality as an assertion that there exists an (idealized?)
hedging stategy that returns Y PY . Deduce that the arbitrage price
for Y equals PY in the special case where = 0.
Now consider the case where is unknown, possibly nonzero. Let Q be
the probability measure with density exp( B1 12 2 ) with respect to P,
where = / . Show that 
B is a standard Brownian motion under Q .
2
Assume that Q Y < . Show that there exists some predictable
process K (in some apppropriate L2 space) for which
Y = Q Y + K S1

almost surely [Q ].

I believe that the threat of the trading scheme that delivers a return K S1
now forces Q Y to be the amount one should pay at time 0 to receive the
amount Y at time 1. What do you think? Should the fact that K seems
to depend on the unknown invalidate the arbitrage argument?
Suppose Y actually depends only on the stock price at time 1, that is,
Y = f 1 (S1 ) for some measurable function f 1 . Show that


where W N (0, 1) under Q.
Q Y = Q f 1 exp( W 12 2 )
Deduce that Q Y does not depend on .
Specialize even further, to the case where f 1 (x) = (x C)+ , for some
constant C, to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula for the price of a
European option.

3.

I should reread Harrison &


Pliska (1981).

Does K actually depend on ?


As I type this Project late at night, I nd myself in the embarrassing position of
not really understanding how the question is handled for a general Y . However,
when Y = f 1 (S1 ) there is another approach that avoids the difculty by
constructing an explicit strategy via the solution to a partial differental equation.
Look for a smooth function f (x, t) for which f (x, 1) = f 1 (x) and
2 x 2 f x x (x, t) + f t (x, t) = 0
Use Ito to show that
f (St , t) = f (1, 0) + Fx St

almost surely [P].

Show that, under Q , the stock price process is a martingale. Deduce that


f (St , t) = Q f (S1 , 1) | Ft = Q (Y | Ft )
Statistics 603a: 11 November 2004

c David Pollard


P10-3

and, in particular, f (1, 0) = Q (Y | F0 ) = Q Y .


I hope I can sort through my confusion before the lecture. I will reread
the nal section of Chung & Williams (1990).

4.

Change of measure for semimartingales


The key fact about the change from P to an equivalent measure Q is the
preservation of the semimartingale property. It is not at all an obvious fact.
For suppose that X is a P-semimartingale that has decomposition X 0 + M + A,
where M is a locally square integrable P-martingale and A FV0 . Under Q the
A process is still in FV0 , but we will have to subtract another FV0 process A
from M to make it a locally square integrable Q-martingale, leading to the
Q-semimartingale decomposition X = X 0 + (M A ) + (A + A ).
To establish these facts in the general case I would need some theory about
processes with jumpsthings like the Doob-Meyer decomposition. Using only
tools developed in the course, I can show you how to treat a special case.
Consider only a process M locM20 ([0, 1], P) with continuous sample paths.
Here I have added the P to emphasize that the martingale properties hold
under the P distribution. Suppose that P and Q are equivalent measures, with
q1 := dQ/dP and dP/dQ = p1 = 1/q1 . Assume that the cadlag versions
of the P-martingale qt := P(q1 | Ft ) and the Q-martingale pt := Q( p1 | Ft )
actually have continuous sample paths.
Show that p = Q( p1 | F ) for each [0, 1]-valued stopping time .
Explain why we can assume pt qt 1. More specically, explain why
pt can be thought of as the density of P with respect to Q when both
measures are restricted to Ft .

Dene
k := 1 inf{t : pt k or pt 1/k} inf{t : |Mt | k}.
Without loss of generality, we may also assume that Mk M20 ([0, 1], P) .
Show that pM locM20 ([0, 1], Q). Hint: For s < t and F Fs show that




QF ptk Mtk psk Msk = QF ptk Mtk psk Msk {k > s}

Argue that F{k > s} Fsk then deduce


 that the right-hand side of the
last equality equals PF Mtk Msk {k > s} = 0.
Use the fact that q and M are both in locM20 ([0, 1], P) to explain
why the process Y := q M V , where V := [q, M] FV0 , is also
in locM20 ([0, 1], P). Hint: First explain why Ytk = q Mtk + M qtk .
Explain why both Y and V have continuous sample paths.
Explain why pY locM20 ([0, 1], Q).
Explain why [ p, V ] 0. Hint: V is a FV0 process with continuous
sample paths.
Deduce that pt Vt = p Vt + V pt .
Deduce that M p V V p locM20 ([0, 1], Q).

Statistics 603a: 11 November 2004

c David Pollard


P10-4

Explain why V p locM20 ([0, 1], Q). Hint: p is a Q-martingale.


Explain why A := p V is in FV0 .
Conclude that M A locM20 ([0, 1], Q).
You should check that this recipe works for the Brownian motion example
in Section 1.

5.

Things I could show if I had more time


(Actually I would also need some facts about processes with jumps.)
(i) Every local-martingale is a semimartingale.
(ii) Suppose P and Q are equivalent probability measures. If X is a
P-semimartingale then it is also a Q-semimartingale. Moreover, for
H locHBdd , the stochastic integral H X when calculated using the
methods from Project 7 under P is the same as the stochastic integral
when calculated under Q. The last assertion can be proved using the
characterization of the stochastic integral given in Project 7.
References
Chung, K. L. & Williams, R. J. (1990), Introduction to Stochastic Integration,
Birkhauser, Boston.
Harrison, J. M. & Pliska, S. R. (1981), Martingales and stochastic integrals
in the theory of continuous trading, Stochastic Processes and their
Applications 11, 215260.

Statistics 603a: 11 November 2004

c David Pollard


You might also like