Architecture of Drug Regulation in India
Architecture of Drug Regulation in India
Architecture of Drug Regulation in India
University of Edinburgh
Santhosh M.R.
I
Introduction
Pratap Banu Mehta, social scientist, argued recently that governance reform is not so
much about implementing designs created by committees of technocrats. Rather, the
first order of business is to restore credibility to the state itself [Mehta, 2009]. But,
in the sphere of pharmaceuticals, this task is not straightforward. Even in (or perhaps,
especially in) developed industrial countries the pharmaceutical industry influences the
perspective of the regulatory agency-so it comes to adopt their interests over and above
those of patients, i.e. that the agency could be said to be captured. Regulatory capture
matters because the risk-benefit assessment of drugs has a high degree of technical
uncertainty, which is inherent in toxicology, clinical trials, and epidemiology and it
therefore matters whether regulators give the manufacturer the benefit of scientific
doubt about safety and efficacy of their product [Abraham, 2002: 1498]. Abraham
13
concludes that, in the case of the European and north American drug regulatory systems,
there is insufficient public accountability (inadequate rights of access to regulatory
information), a lack of independent tests and technical expertise, insufficiently clear and
independent funding (some regulatory agencies are funded at least in part by user fees),
and poor control over potential conflicts of interest for regulators.
But the debates that Abraham summarises are concerned largely with only one part of the
field of pharmaceuticals regulation relating to the approval of new drugs, and monitoring
their effects. If one takes a product-life approach to pharmaceuticals regulation, however,
one needs to look at what happens to such approved drugs once they are formulated,
distributed, marketed, prescribed and consumed. In Europe and north America, there
tends to be an assumption which may or may not be justified that issues of prescriber
and retailer regulation, ethical marketing and so on have been largely resolved. On the
other hand, there is considerable concern about issues such as post-approval tracking and
pharmacovigilance, to pick up adverse drug reactions (ADRs). But in the Indian system,
these contextual issues have not been resolved; and ADRs are unlikely to be discovered
nor acted upon. In India, and elsewhere, there are serious doubts over whether regulatory
bodies are able to build public health concerns especially those that affect the poor into
their deliberations.
In this paper we address these issues by using our research on Tracing Pharmaceuticals
in South Asia to consider issues of regulation and how far this constrains inappropriate
use at all stages, from the sourcing of raw materials (bulk drugs) to the final consumption
of the product. We consider the recent history of attempts to reform the Indian regulatory
system, and suggest that they illuminate two key features of the situation. The first is
that in contemporary India, issues of pharmaceutical regulation are rarely discussed in
a cradle-to-grave approach. The regulation of some parts of the process attracts far
more attention than others, and the links between these parts are poorly co-ordinated.
The second is that regulation takes place with two significant disconnects. The first is
between the assumptions underpinning regulatory measures on the one hand and the
everyday conditions of drug production, distribution and consumption on the other;
and second, that the local regulation of production, distribution and consumption is
inadequate to deal with the global context within which these processes take place.
II
Regulation of Pharmaceuticals in Contemporary India
Pharmaceuticals regulation in India with apparently strong regulations but weak
implementation is not a unique situation [Myrdal, 1968]. 1 Chibber has argued that state
intervention in India was not per se a mistake, rather its state-led development problems
must be put down to the poor quality of that intervention [Chibber, 2003]. In the rest of
Architecture of Drug Regulation in India / Jeffery
14
this paper we assess how this situation has arisen with respect to pharmaceuticals and
of attempts by the Government of India to prevent or ameliorate the inadequacies of its
regulation in the country. In what follows, the term pharmaceuticals regulation means
the regulation of any aspect of the production, distribution, prescription or consumption
of a pharmaceutical product or the raw materials that are used in its production.
Our research confirms the large gap between the regulations that exist on paper
and the everyday practice of pharmaceutical use. At the level of the final consumer,
there is considerable self-prescription of drugs: with or without a written prescription,
ill people or their representatives can purchase virtually any medicines they can
afford, without necessarily taking the advice of any kind of practitioner [Das and
Das, 2007]. This is so despite classifications of medicines into categories that require
the prescription of a qualified medical practitioner before they can be sold. Further,
individuals can make a living through prescribing and selling medicines, despite
regulations that restrict these activities to the holders of specified qualifications
(medical degrees or pharmacy training): a situation of jugr medicine: medicine
that is make-do-and-mend. Even though the ideal and symbolic appeal of real
medicine (provided by government and nongovernment health institutions) remains
strong, much everyday provision comes from practitioners who are neither quacks
nor legitimate doctors but who invent roles for themselves as medical authorities
[Pinto, 2004: 377].
Similar issues can be seen in terms of the licences needed to stock and distribute
medicines, or to manufacture them. Although an Indian version of current WHO-Good
Manufacturing Practice has been incorporated into the Drugs and Cosmetics Act (DCA)
through the amendment of Schedule M, there is considerable doubt whether the rules are
applied coherently or universally throughout the industry. Medicines cannot (in general)
be introduced into the Indian market without approval by the Drugs Controller General
of India (DGCI) whereas State Licensing Authorities (SLAs) issue manufacturing
licences: but there inefficiencies and varying standards allow producers to get their new
combinations of medicines approved for sale by the less strict SLAs (for a discussion
of these relationships, see http://www.assocham.org/events/recent/event_278/_dr._
surinder_singh.pdf). And, as we shall discuss later, the processes of removing dangerous
or inefficacious medicines is very hard to implement. Few formal regulations affect
marketing practices: although some of the producers associations have promulgated
their own guidelines [see, e.g., OPPI, 2007] there is little evidence that such guidelines
are followed, nor what action has been taken to discipline any infringements.
In independent India, pharmaceuticals regulation was divided between the Ministry of
Chemicals and Fertilisers, now through a separate Department of Pharmaceuticals (for
matters related to production quality and pricing) and the Ministry of Health (registration
15
16
2008a; US Food and Drug Administration, 2008b). It now plays crucial and detailed
roles in setting production and record-keeping standards at Indian factories roles
that are likely to become more common since it established a New Delhi office
(in January 2009) and will use it to monitor about 100 production plants in India
(Shankar, 2009). Site visits of the scale and intensity mounted by the FDA probably
far exceed those of the Government of Indias own regulators who are supposed to
carry out the same tasks and to protect Indian consumers. In other words, perhaps
without the general public being fully aware of what is going on, India is de facto
accepting the idea that developing countries should not duplicate approval processes
within country but should instead rely on the expertise of stringent foreign or global
regulatory authorities.
Commissions as a Means of Reform
One means of integrating cross-ministry and inter-state concerns is through ad hoc
commissions, committees and task forces. Here we describe only those established
since 1995, when the Government of India began to grapple with the new form of
globalisation ushered in by the Doha round of international trade negotiations and the
creation of the World Trade Organisation, TRIPS and the extension of patent protection
to pharmaceutical products in India. The issues considered by several of these reports
go to the heart of the regulation problems and their characteristics shed light on the
problems of moving towards a more effective regulatory regime.
In many of these committees, Dr R A Mashelkar played a central role. Those most
relevant to pharmaceuticals are the Committee on Research and Development in Drugs
and Pharmaceuticals (1999); the Expert Committee on a Comprehensive Examination
of Drug Regulatory Issues, including the Problem of Spurious Drugs (2003); the Task
Force on Recombinant Pharma (2005); and the Technical Expert Group on Patent Law
Issues (2006).
Mashelkar had a distinguished career as a polymer scientist and manager of science.
He was the Director General of Council of Scientific and Industrial Research (CSIR)
from 1995-2006, a member of the Scientific Advisory Council to the Prime Minister
and also of the Scientific Advisory Committee to the Cabinet. He came to public
notice for his vigorous attack on American firms attempting to patent turmeric and
basmati rice. He has a wide view of the role of science in Indian society, for example,
seeing the need for child-centred education, woman-centred families, human-centred
development, a knowledge-centred society and innovation-centred India [Mashelkar,
2000]. In the commissions he has chaired the interests that are always represented
are civil servants from some (but not always all) of the Ministries of the Government
of India that have an interest in the field: Health, Chemicals and Pharmaceuticals,
17
Home Affairs, Finance and Planning, for example (see Table). State governments
responsible for people such as drugs inspectors, or District Health Officers tasked
with implementing regulations are usually conspicuous by their absence, as are
representatives of rural medical practitioners, pharmacists and drug wholesalers and
consumers. Some committees, such as the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health,
do draw on a wider set of constituencies, including (for example) the Voluntary Health
Association of India, the Society for Education, Action and Research in Community
Health, a journalist, economists and doctors from the private sector, as well as various
Ministers and ex-Ministers. The 1999 Mashelkar Committee, however, leant heavily
on industry representatives, especially large Indian multinationals, such as Ranbaxys
and Dr Reddys. When new policy proposals are under consideration, the opinions
of representatives of producer interests can be canvassed in other ways as well. Ram
Vilas Paswan, as Minister for Chemicals and Fertilisers, called in 50 top executives
from large Indian companies for consultation on his proposals for a new regulatory
framework for clinical trials and the encouragement of innovation in research and
development [Anon., 2009b].
The voices of others could also be provided by those invited to give evidence to
the committees, or who came uninvited. For example, the deliberations of the 2003
Mashelkar Report had presentations by scientists, the Indian Medical Association
(IMA), the Delhi Pharmaceutical Trust, Ahmedabad-based Consumer Education and
Research Centre (CERC) as well as the Confederation of Indian Industry (CII).
Four main topics have dominated the committees that have reported since 1995:
1. Drug price controls
2. Controlling spurious or counterfeit medicines
3. Improving the chances of inventing and patenting new chemical entities
4. Establishing a centralised National Drug Authority
Four other concerns have been noticeable by the lack of attention they have attracted
[All-India Drugs Action Network, 2006: 1]:
5. Ethical promotion
6. Labelling and consumer information
7. Elimination of irrational drugs and combinations
8. Pharmacovigilance
We discuss these in turn, before considering the wider implications of these patterns
for the quality of pharmaceuticals regulation in India.
Drug Price Control
A major concern of regulation has been of prices, and (not surprisingly), the main tussles
have been between industry representatives (wanting to limit or remove price controls)
Architecture of Drug Regulation in India / Jeffery
18
(2)
(3)
(4)
(7)
CII (Industry)
FICCI (Industry)
IPAss
CCC (Consumers)
Police (Enforcement)
DGHS (GoI)
NPPA (GoI)
(6)
DCG(I) (GoI)
(5)
WHO (Donors/Technical)
Column 2: Mashelkar, R. A. (1999). Transforming India into a Knowledge Power: Report of the
Pharmaceutical Research and Development Committee. New Delhi: Department of Chemicals and
Petrochemicals, Ministry of Chemicals and Fertilisers, Government of India.
Column 3: Department of Chemicals and Petrochemicals. (1999). Memorandum. New Delhi: Ministry
of Chemicals and Fertilisers.
Column 5: National Commission on Macroeconomics and Health (2005). Report. New Delhi: Ministry
of Health and Family Welfare.
Column 6: Sen, P. (2005). Report of the Task Force to Explore Options other than Price Control for
Achieving the Objective of Making Available Life-saving Drugs at Reasonable Prices. New Delhi:
Department of Chemicals & Petrochemicals, Government of India.
Column 7: Mashelkar, R. A., Mehta, G., Datta, A., Menon, N. R. M., & Sharma, M. (2006). Report of the
Technical Expert Group on Patent Law Issues. New Delhi: Indian Patent Office.
19
Legends:
AIDAN:
IDMA:
AISSDMA:
IPAll:
AIOCD:
IPAss:
CCI:
NPPA:
CII:
OPPI:
Organisation of Pharmaceutical
Producers of India
CSIR
FICCI:
DCG(I)
DGHS:
DGHS:
and those championing consumer interests (calling for their extension and tightening).
In 1970, almost all bulk drugs and their formulations were under price control, but
the number was reduced to 347 bulk drugs in 1979, 142 in 1987 and then to 74 in
1995. A Drugs Price Control Review Committee (DPCRC) was set up in 1999: its
recommendations led to the 2002 Pharmaceutical Policy, which proposed that, in order
to reorient the domestic drugs and pharmaceuticals industry in the face of the challenges
and opportunities from the liberalised economy, Indias accession to TRIPS and the
impending advent of the product patent regime, the span of price control over drugs
and pharmaceuticals should be reduced substantially [Department of Chemicals and
Petrochemicals, 2002: section 11]. But in responding to the Supreme Courts demands
(see above) the Department of Chemicals had to consider and formulate appropriate
criteria for ensuring essential and life saving drugs not to fall out of price control and to
review the drugs which are essential and life saving in nature [Department of Chemicals
and Petrochemicals, 2005: 2]. In July, 2003, therefore, the Government prepared a
National List of Essential Medicines (NLEM) consisting of 354 drugs, of which only
50 were then under price control [Department of Chemicals and Petrochemicals, 2005:
3]. The relevant Lok Sabha Standing Committee in 2005 also strongly recommended
bringing more NLEM Drugs under price control (citing the examples of Canada,
Japan, and the UK) (Standing Committee on Chemicals & Fertilizers (2005-06),
2005: 49-50).
There are, thus, on-going pressures from civil society and political representatives
to maintain or even strengthen price controls: and considerable dispute about whether
the existing controls are successful. As elsewhere, of course, brand leaders are able
to reduce price competition by enhancing the reputation of their branded goods,
Architecture of Drug Regulation in India / Jeffery
20
and by offering inducements to prescribers to use their products even though they are
pharmacologically indistinct from those of their cheaper competitors. In some (but not
all) market segments, the brand leaders show both the highest prices and the largest
sales, suggesting that these strategies are successful. 2 Such companies usually avoid
the drugs that are under price control. The prices of most drugs in India are below
international comparator prices [see, for example, Keayla, 1996; Lanjouw, 1997]. But
some critics (including the Federation of Medical Representative Associations of India
(FMRAI) point to the myriad ways in which the drug price control orders can be evaded
[All-India Drugs Action Network, 2006; L. Taylor, 2007]. Certainly, the division of
responsibilities between the body responsible for approving drugs for marketing (the
Drug Controller General of India, attached to the health ministry) and that responsible
for price regulation (National Pharmaceutical Pricing Authority, or NPPA, under the
ministry of chemicals and fertilisers) does not help.
Around the time in 1995 when India signed up to TRIPS, many commentators
predicted that this would lead to massive price increases in India [see Lanjouw, 1997
for a critical response]. Since then, commentators have been more cautious [see, for
example, Grace, 2004]. The Ministry of Chemicals and Petrochemicals believes there
are no upward price pressures in the pharmaceuticals market [Department of Chemicals
and Petrochemicals, 2008: 17]. Nonetheless, the Ministry started a scheme in 2008 to
provide all 350 essential drugs through Jan Aushadhi stores at a claimed level of around
75 per cent of the price of branded medicines available in the market: it is as yet too
soon to see the impact of this scheme. Apart from this, following the recommendation
of Pronab Sen Committee, the Government of India also constituted a Committee
on Price Negotiations for Patented Drugs and Medical Devices to explore the
possibilities of introducing price negotiations before the grant of marketing approval of
patented drugs.
The prices situation can be read in several different ways. On the one hand, price
controls may have been successful; alternatively, the prices of drugs (and their
availability for the poor) are set by a highly competitive market, and the drug price
control orders play very little part in keeping prices low. In 2006, NIPER conducted a
study on the Impact of TRIPS on pharmaceutical prices, with specific focus on generics
in India which concluded that fears pertaining to TRIPS related increase in drug prices
in India are unfounded. Analysis of data on prices of selected drugs, following the
TRIPS agreement shows that prices of drugs in India have been by and large stable
... No sudden changes in prices have occurred even after implementation of TRIPS
(Post 1995) and are unlikely to occur even after introduction of the product patents
[NIPER, 2006].
Recently, NPPA has launched a grievance redressal cell (Complaint Submission and
Redressal System, or CSRS) with a senior officer to hear grievances from the general
21
22
so the responsibility is divided between the Central Government and the State and
Union Territories Governments. Unlike the movements to decentralise aspects of
governance in India, since at least the 1970s the central Governments has tried to
reduce states autonomy and centralise control in this field. The Hathi Committee of
1975 first proposed a national pharmaceuticals agency, to provide uniform standards
and a single authority to register drugs, to ensure uniform standards across the country
[Hathi, 1975: para. 33].
Although the 1978 National Drug Policy made no mention of this, the 1986 and 1994
Drug Policies proposed National Drug Authorities to monitor drug quality according
to standard procedures. The 1999 Mashelkar Committee proposed establishing a
Monitoring Authority to oversee Good Manufacturing, Good Laboratory and Good
Clinical Practice but this, too, was not implemented. The 2003 Mashelkar Committee
proposed to strengthen the existing Central Drugs Standard Control Organisation
(CDSCO) and the State Drug Controllers and create a Central Drug Authority (CDA) a
line also followed in the 2002 Drug Policy. Apparently, 15 state governments supported
this idea [Ramachandran, 2003]. Nonetheless, in 2005 the Pronab Sen Committee
returned to a centralising proposal, to integrate the offices of the Drugs Controller
General of India, the Central Drugs Standard Control Organisation (CDSCO) and the
National Pharmaceutical Pricing Authority (NPPA), along with all the powers and
functions of these bodies [Sen, 2005: 55-56]. A Bill was introduced in Parliament to
establish a CDA, and Mashelkars views on this were regarded as so significant by the
Parliamentary panel charged with investigating the Bill that it delayed its report until
he had been consulted [Shankar, 2008]. The draft Bill was heavily criticised by the
committee [Alexander, 2008b] and the need for redrafting led to its being abandoned
before the Lok Sabha elections of 2009 [Alexander, 2008a].
Despite these repeated proposals, by 2009 the Government of India had made little
progress towards creating a National Drug Authority, perhaps partly because, health
being constitutionally on the concurrent list, centralisation of drug control may pose
additional legal hurdles. Opposition was strongest in Maharashtra, where the state Drug
Controllers Association opposed any dilution of the rights of state Drug Controllers.
A test case for centralised versus local autonomy has been the struggle to ban 294
fixed dose combination drugs declared irrational by the then-DCG(I) Venkateshwarlus
directive of October, 2007. Drug companies whose licences are still valid can
continue to manufacture these fixed dose combinations, whereas the State Licensing
Authorities (SLAs) were refusing, in early 2009, to renew the licenses that had expired
[Anon., 2009a].
In general, however, it seems likely that the proposals for an NDA emerge from
frustration at the inability to solve two problems. The first is varying procedures and
Architecture of Drug Regulation in India / Jeffery
24
standards imposed by SLAs, a situation which has seen some producers apply for
licenses from compliant SLAs if their own State is unwilling to grant a license quickly
or on reasonable terms. Individual States have the right to refuse to licence production,
but once a drug is approved in one State it can be sold throughout the country.
The second is the severe shortage of resources for testing drugs and licensing
producers on the basis of the quality of facilities. Thus, despite repeated proposals
from committees for the creation of new posts and investment in laboratory equipment,
the current infrastructure is completely inadequate to cope with the numbers of drugs,
producers, pharmacies and prescribers. According to Venkateshwarlu, DCG(I) (200608), there is now a six to nine month backlog at each of the plants which results in less
then [sic] 1 per cent of drugs being tested [Taylor N., 2008a].
What is Left Out?
Among the issues that are not given the same degree of attention are the following.
Ethical promotion and the restriction of incentives to prescribers and pharmacists
Major issues arise with the possibility that drugs are prescribed or dispensed more for
the financial interests of the prescribers and dispensers than the needs of the patient. One
example is the substitution of drugs by the pharmacist: as Hazra, CDMU, told us in an
interview if you write the generic name the retailer interprets it like he has the license to
give any medicines. So he gives that one that will fetch him the maximum commission
(December 29, 2006).
Evidence for the existence of undue pressures on prescribers in India is abundant. The
Gujarat-based Torrent Pharmaceuticals openly announced in their website incentives for
prescribing their medicines. The company then took hundreds of doctors on chartered
flight to various tourist destinations such as Bali and Fuket. Though a formal complaint
with evidences was made to IDMA on this, no punitive action has been taken so far
[Nagarajan, 2008]. Medical representatives were willing to talk to us in some detail
about the range of incentives they had available in return for substantial orders. They
are under great pressure to extend the incentives given on the launch of a new drug, or to
provide incentives to pharmacists if doctors are being given one. A medical representative
described the process in small-town north India, If I am promising a car to the doctor
then the doctor has to commit to me. Then I will tell the doctor that every month
suppose the cost of the car is Rs.2 lakh, then he has to give us the business of Rs. 5060,000 or 70,000 per month in one or two years. He will have to write a lot of medicines.
If the doctor is ready to commit then we dont have any problem (Interview transcript,
October, 27 2007, Bijnor)
Although there is a longstanding critique of these activities [Gulhati, 2004], then,
there is little embarrassment amongst medical representatives in talking about them [see
25
also Roy et al, 2007]. Some doctors refuse to be seduced into prescribing on this basis,
or check whether their patients have been given the drug they actually prescribed, rather
than a substitute. It is hard to find any information about the effectiveness of the voluntary
codes run by the larger pharmaceutical associations. In early 2009 Government officials
hinted at the creation of legal restraints on unethical promotion, but this seems to have
been pre-election posturing rather than a serious proposal [Alexander, 2009].
Local-language labelling and information sheets
We know that many prescribers and most patients in India are not literate in the English
that is used in drug information packs. Add to this that as in many other countries drug
information varies from brand to brand, leading to the possibility of misleading patients
and prescribers about appropriate use, co-occurring effects and drug interactions. A
WHO study called for further training and continued education aimed at drug regulatory
officials to provide the necessary knowledge and enable national authorities to meet
the need for drug information that is independent of commercial interests [Reggi et al.,
2003] but no substantive moves have been made in this direction in India.
A particular issue in India is the labelling of Ayurvedic medicines: after complaints
that some ingredients turn out to be heavy metals or even steroids, Ayurvedic medicines
for export now need to be labelled with their ingredients; no equivalent regulations
apply for drugs sold within India [Chandy and Mathew, 2006: 59]. Many pills are sold in
small numbers, cut off from the full strip and without any information on co-occurringeffects or advice about co-consumption with other medicines. In the absence of effective
information, the Indian Medical Associations call to be allowed rights to prescribe offlabel, activists noted the western example of off-label use being cited by the IMA
cannot be applied to India because Indian patients often have poor levels of literacy and
education [Sharma, 2004: 1372]. Obtaining informed consent is so hard, some argue,
that off-label uses would be equivalent to treating patients like guinea-pigs. Despite
these concerns, few efforts have been made to change the situation.
Eliminating harmful, ineffective and irrational combinations of drugs
Activists have been involved in trying to reduce the number of drugs for sale in the
Indian market, and particularly combinations of drugs, since the early 1980s. The
Government of India introduced a ban, using the generic name of the drugs involved,
but manufacturers have avoided the ban by saying that their drug name was not on the
list. In pharmacology the number of drugs that should be used for therapeutic reasons
is around 7000 but the Indian market contains almost 70,000 drugs, and 151 dubious
combinations of drugs that are not approved in developed countries [MIMS, March
2009]. Although irrational combinations was an issue taken up with some zeal by Dr
Venkateshwarlu, his successor has taken what some see as a softer stand, for example
allowing these dubious fixed dose combinations to stay on the market as long as they are
Architecture of Drug Regulation in India / Jeffery
26
the balance of risks, costs and benefits are very different. Once again, no serious
attention has been given to these issues within any of the documents we have been able
to access.
Significantly, in our view, two things are missing from these Commissions. The first
is a frank acknowledgement of how little effect the current regulations have: how far
they are flouted in practice, however well they have been crafted. There seems to be
a wilful blindness towards the everyday circumstances in which most drugs in India
are produced, distributed and consumed and the conditions within which substantial
numbers of people get such limited access that these concerns seem illusory. The second,
and linked to this, is the absence of a clear strategy to change that situation. The end state
a modern society where rational considerations hold sway, preferably through the
activities of small numbers of producers and marketing firms, with an honest and efficient,
technically qualified regulatory agency to keep an eye on them is imagined, with no
defined steps that might lead to that situation, except for more laws or regulations added
onto the existing ones. In other words, policy debate proceeds to ignore institutionalised
corrupt practices and vested interests and relies on a conceptualisation of policy that is
technical and depoliticised [Harriss-White, 1996: 85].
The image of society, industry and politics is dual: an existing modern sector that is
assumed to be distinct from a non-modern one, and it is assumed that the modern sector
will within a finite period swallow the non-modern sector up. The liberalisation of
the Indian economy since 1991 might be thought to hasten such a process. But it is clear
that deregulation of pharmaceuticals is not a defensible option in India, at least not in the
ways that are being tried out in other industries. No alternative strategy has been set out.
Furthermore, the modern sector is in fact interlinked with the non-modern one. Smallscale manufacturers, for example, make many of the drugs sold by the large companies
under loan licences, and the expansion of sales outlets is heavily linked to the unlicensed
practitioners and quasi-legal pharmacies, for example. In this sector of the economy, the
mirage of India Shining seems to have completely eclipsed that part of the Republic
of Hunger that, in part, makes the former possible.
III
Conclusion
The regulation of pharmaceuticals in India is a particular example of how the industry
is modernising: the government rationalises, tries to apply scientific knowledge to
controlling this area of social life, and in this way extends its reach, in order to reduce
the risks to which its citizens are subject. In the specific field of pharmaceuticals, such
interventions are justified both by the relative ignorance of patients about their medical
needs and by the potential for unfree competition posed by very large companies in
Architecture of Drug Regulation in India / Jeffery
28
29
Anon. (2009a): Cos may move contempt of court against SLAs for refusal to renew FDC DrugsControl.
Org. Mumbai.
Anon. (2009b): Pharma to get new regulatory regime, Economic Times, Mumbai.
Anon. (2009c): Tax-free bonds to fund drug research venture, Economic Times, Mumbai.
Barnes, K. (2007): New counterfeit report highlights worrying trends, Outsourcing-Pharma.com.
Chandy, S. J. and Mathew, B. S. (2006): Patient information and medication labelling: an area of concern,
Indian Journal of Medical Ethics, 3(2), 58-60.
Chatterjee, P. (2001): Indias trade in fake drugsbringing the counterfeiters to book, The Lancet, 357, June
2, p.1776.
Chibber, V. (2003): Locked in Place: State Building and Late Industrialization in India, University Press,
Princeton
Das, V. and Das, R. K. (2007): Pharmaceuticals in Urban Ecologies: The Register of the Local in A. Petryna,
A. Lakoff and A. Kleinman (Eds.), Global Pharmaceticals: Ethics, Markets, Practices pp. 171-205.:
Duke University Press, Durham, NC
Department of Chemicals and Petrochemicals. (2002): Pharmaceutical Policy 2002, Department of Chemicals
and Petrochemicals, New Delhi
___ (2005): Draft National Pharmaceuticals Policy, 2006.: Government of India, New Delhi
___ (2008): Annual Report 2007-08, Ministry of Chemicals and Fertilisers, New Delhi.
European Commission. (2008): Report on Community Customs Activities on Counterfeit And Piracy: Results
at the European Border 2007, Taxation and Customs Union, Brussels
Grace, C. (2004): The Effect of Changing Intellectual Property on Pharmaceutical Industry Prospects in India
and China: Considerations for Access to Medicines, Health Systems Resource Centre, London.
Gulhati, C. (2004): Marketing of medicines in India, Editorial, British Medical Journal, 328(3 April),
pp.778-779.
Harriss-White, B. (1996): Primary accumulation, corruption and development policy, Review of Development
and Change, 1(1), 85-101.
Hathi, J. L. (1975): Report of the Committee on the Drugs and Pharmaceutical Industry, Ministry of Petroleum
and Chemicals, Government of India, New Delhi.
Jansen, K., and Roquas, E. (2005): Absentee expertise: Science advice for bio-technology regulation in
developing countries in M. Leach, I. Scoones and B. Wynne (Eds.), Science and Citizens pp. 142-154).
Zed Books, London.
Keayla, B. K. (1996): New Patent Regime: Implications for Domestic Industry, Research and Development and
Consumers, National Working Group on Patent Laws (Center for Study on GATT Laws), New Delhi.
Lanjouw, J. O. (1997): The Introduction of Pharmaceutical Product Patents in India: Heartless Exploitation
of the Poor and Suffering? Discussion Paper., Economic Growth Center, Yale University, New Haven.
Mashelkar, R. A. (2000): New panchsheel of the new millennium, Pune.
____ (2003): Report of the Expert Committee on a Comprehensive Examination of Drug Regulatory Issues,
Including the Problem of Spurious Drugs. Ministry of Health and Family Welfare, Government of India,
New Delhi.
Matsebula, T., Goudge, J. and Gilson, L. (2005): Regulating the pharmaceutical sector: Coping with low
capacity while maintaining regulatory independence, Health Economics and Financing Programme
Working Papers, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, London:
Mehta, P. B. (2009): Creating a Credible State, Centre for the Advanced Study of India.
30
Myrdal, G. (1968): Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations, Twentieth Century Fund,
New York.
Nagarajan, R. (2008): Are your drugs boosting your doctors lifestyle? The Times of India.
NIPER. (2006): Impact of TRIPS on Pharmaceutical Prices, with Specific Focus on Generics in India,
National Institute for Pharmaceuticals Education and Research, Chandigarh.
OPPI (2007): OPPI Code of Pharmaceutical Marketing Practices, Organisation of Pharmaceutical Producers
of India, Mumbai.
Patvardhan, S. (2005): National Pharmacovigilance Programme: Monitoring Drug Safety Express Pharma
Pulse.
Pinto, S. (2004): Development without institutions: Ersatz medicine and the politics of everyday life in rural
north India, Cultural Anthropology, 19(3), 337-364.
Ramachandran, R. (2003): Dealing with Fake Drugs, DrugsControl.Organisation. Jaipur.
Reggi, V., Balocco-Mattavelli, R., Bonati, M., Breton, I., Figueras, A., Jambert, E., et al. (2003): Prescribing
information in 26 countries: a comparative study, European Journal of Clinical Pharmacology, 59(4),
pp.263-270.
Roy, N., N.Madhiwalla, and S.A. Pai,(2007): Drug promotional practices in Mumbai: a qualitative study
Indian Journal of Medical Ethics, 4(2), 57-61.
Sen, P. (2005): Report of the Task Force to Explore Options other than Price Control for Achieving the
Objective of Making Available Life-saving Drugs at Reasonable Prices, Department of Chemicals &
Petrochemicals, Government of India, New Delhi.
Shankar, R. (2008): Dr Mashelkar asks govt to provide autonomous status to CDA, Economic Times,
Mumbai.
Shankar, R. (2009): US FDA opens office in Delhi, around 100 approved plants to come under vigilance
Pharmabiz.
Sharma, D. C. (2004): Indian experts protest against off-label drug use, The Lancet, 363, April, 24,
pp.1372.
Sheth, P. D., M. Reddy, V. S. P., B. Regal, M. Kaushal, K. Sen and D. B.A.Narayana, (2007): Extent of
Spurious (Counterfeit) Medicines in India, SEARPharm Forum, New Delhi, in collaboration with Delhi
Pharmaceutical Trust and Apothecaries Foundation for WHO.
Standing Committee on Chemicals & Fertilizers (2005-06) (2005): Availability and Price Management of
Drugs and Pharmaceuticals, Fourteenth Lok Sabha, New Delhi.
Taylor, L. (2007): Drugmakers mocking Indian price controls, say reps. Pharmatimes.
Taylor, N. (2008a): India converts failing vaccine plants to testing labs, in-PharmaTechnologist.com.
___(2008b): PSI reports 24% jump in counterfeits, in-pharmatechnologist.com.
___ (2009): Lax and corrupt -- Indian Dr assesses clinical trials, Outsourcing-Pharma.com.
The Hindu Business Line (2002): Karnataka HC asks Govt to spell out policy on life-saving drugs Stays
implementation of pharma policy, The Hindu Business Line, Chennai.
US Food and Drug Administration (2008a): Warning Letter WL: 320-08-02, Center for Drug Evaluation and
Research, Department of Health and Human Services, Washington DC.
US Food and Drug Administration (2008b): Warning Letter WL: 320-08-03, Center for Drug Evaluation and
Research, Department of Health and Human Services.
World Health Organisation (2006): Counterfeit Medicines: An Update on Estimates, IMPACT, Geneva.
31
Notes:
1
In some cases, branded generic products are more expensive than those produced by innovator brands.
In India, a drug is defined as spurious a. if it is manufactured under a name which belongs to another drug;
or b. if it is an imitation of, or is a substitute for, another drug or resembles another drug in a manner likely
to deceive, or bears upon it or upon its label or container the name of another drug, unless it is plainly and
conspicuously marked so as to reveal its true character and its lack of identity with such other drug; or c. if the
label or container b ears the name of an individual or company purporting to be the manufacture of the drug,
which individual or company is fictitious or does not exist; or d. if it has been substituted wholly or in part
by another drug or substance; or e. if it purports to be the product of a manufacturer of whom it is not truly a
product. (Drugs and Cosmetics Act, Amendment Act of 1982. Section 17-B)
3
The Pharmaceuticals Security Institute [PSI] is closely linked to the International Federation of Pharmaceutical
Manufacturers & Associations (IFPMA). The IFPMA Director-General serves as the PSI President.
4
This study used flawed methods of collecting samples, and therefore cannot be relied on, but the contrast
with the industry estimates is too large to be ignored. A new study on similar lines was started in late 2008,
involving the collection of 24,000 samples.
5
The Government is also addressing the complications generated by the rise of technologies such as biogenetics
(See Anon., 2005 for discussion of the 2003 Mashelkar Task Force report).
6
32