The Kaantabay Case Study
The Kaantabay Case Study
The Kaantabay Case Study
DISSERTATION
Submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the
degree of Master of Philosophy in Land Economy
2003/2004
CONTENTS
Chapter Page
1 INTRODUCTION ....................................................................................... 1
1.1 Program Background ................................................................................... 1
1.2 The Global Campaign for Secure Tenure .................................................... 2
1.3 Research Questions ....................................................................................... 3
1.4 Structure of the Research ............................................................................. 5
4 ANALYSIS .................................................................................................. 37
4.1 Market Failure: The Case for Government Intervention .............................. 37
4.2 Beyond Welfare Economics: Empowerment of the Urban Poor ................. 40
4.3 Managing Urban Development: Bridging the Ideal and the Real ................ 41
4.4 Summary ...................................................................................................... 43
5 SYNTHESIS ................................................................................................ 45
5.1 Evaluation Research Questions and Methodology ....................................... 45
APPENDIX .............................................................................................................. 47
REFERENCES ......................................................................................................... 50
ii
CERTIFICATION
18 July 2004
I, Wilfredo B. Prilles, Jr., certify that the attached dissertation is my own original work,
iii
ACKNOWLEDGMENT
Foundation for the opportunity to experience Cambridge and be part of a great academic
I am also grateful for the help extended by the following individuals and group:
• Dr. John McCombie, my supervisor, for his wise counsel and kind
• Mr. Barry Moore, Dr. Peter Tyler, Dr. Nicola Morrison and Dr. Shailaja
development
• Mr. D.C. Nathan Sergio and Mr. Rolando Campillos, former and present head
of the Naga Urban Poor Affairs Office, respectively, for sharing key data and
Of course, everything would not have been possible without my wife Lynn; our
children Ezekiel, Jack Ryan, Sofia Loraine, Hilary Joan and Patricia Anne; my mother-in-
law, Corazon Reoveros; and my parents, Wilfredo, Sr. and Helen Prilles. Their abiding
faith, boundless understanding and untold sacrifices enabled me to live a dream. To them,
iv
ABSTRACT
The city of Naga in the Philippines has been implementing a social housing
homelots to urban poor residents of the city, the program exhibits key elements of the
Global Campaign for Secure Tenure launched by UN-HABITAT to attain the Millennium
Development Goal of bringing 100 million residents out of slum conditions worldwide by
2020. Arguing that the program is ripe for policy evaluation, the study takes a close look
by profiling the Kaantabay program and subjecting it to institutional analysis that takes
account of its economic, social and political dimensions. The profile shows a local
social exclusion by empowering the urban poor sector. The economic analysis explored
textbook justifications for the city government’s intervention in the local housing market
riddled with externalities and distributional failures. A multi-level social analysis informed
urban poor alongside state-centered power dynamics involving the political elite. The
political analysis affirmed the mediating role of elected political leaders in managing
urban development that requires them to balance competing interest among stakeholders.
Additionally, it demonstrates that commitment to the public good, guided by the Smithian
framework, it proposes a methodology and list of possible research questions for formal
v
ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS
vi
LIST OF TABLES AND FIGURES
TABLES
Table Page
FIGURES
Figure Page
vii
1 INTRODUCTION
On October 1, 2000, the eve of World Habitat Day, the United Nations Human
Settlements Programme (UN-HABITAT) held the African launch of the Global Campaign
for Secure Tenure in Durban, South Africa. This global advocacy, a key thrust of the
human settlements arm of the UN system, seeks to address poverty and homelessness and
One of the invited guests to keynote the launch is the former city mayor of Naga, a
small city in central Philippines, around 7,000 miles away from South Africa. On the
surface, the choice of Mayor Jesse M. Robredo seems to reinforce the internationality of
the event; but there is logic to it as well. Under Robredo’s leadership, Naga had been
partners in development) for more than a decade, apparently with a good measure of
success.
social housing. At its core is securing tenurial rights for urban poor beneficiaries. This is
accomplished by acquiring the landholding they are occupying through various innovative
schemes, with the city government playing a critical facilitative and mediating role. When
negotiations are completed, the beneficiaries are then able to amortize their homelots
under very affordable terms through community mortgage. When the landholding is fully
paid up, property rights to individual homelots are transferred to beneficiaries, thereby
1
But Kaantabay is more than just a simple social housing initiative by the local
state. As an urban poverty program, it addresses the difficult challenges being faced by
challenges:
organizations during a visit to Naga by then President Corazon Aquino late in 1987, the
Kaantabay program appears to have gone a long way in meeting the challenges described
by Tibaijuka.
In 1994, it won the Gantimpalang Panlingkod Pook (Galing Pook) award as one of
the country’s 20 most outstanding local government programs. In 1996, the UN Centre
for Housing Settlements (UNCHS, now UN-HABITAT) cited it as one of the world’s 40
best practices during the second City Summit in Istanbul, Turkey. It also received a similar
recognition from the UK-based Building and Social Housing Foundation (BSHF).
The Global Campaign for Secure Tenure (GCST) is one of two parallel advocacies
being pursued by UN-HABITAT, the other focusing on good urban governance (GUG).
The campaign seeks to implement the Habitat Agenda adopted during the Istanbul City
Summit in 1996, where “affordable shelter for all” became an overarching goal. In 2000,
it became part of the Millennium Development Goals (MDG) adopted by the UN General
2
Assembly. Item 11 of the 18 targets comprising the MDG aims to bring out 100 million
population worldwide that live in slums and shanty towns. And unless the campaign bears
fruit, the number is only expected to go higher as two-thirds of the global population shall
be living in cities by 2050, when the MDG is supposed to have been long attained.
The magnitude of the problem has clear economic implications. The current shelter
strategy, which has viewed slums in a kinder, more positive light, is an offshoot of failed
housing policies of the ‘60s and ‘70s, particularly resource-intensive publicly provided
housing. Securing tenurial right for the burgeoning urban poor population is a key
element of this strategy, owing to its catalytic effect. According to UN-HABITAT, secure
tenure “invariably leads to other processes and issues vital to sustainable shelter delivery
and upgrading. Countless examples reveal that when people are given security of tenure,
they tend to invest in the improvement of their homes and neighbourhoods (Cobbett
2001).”
Of course, this assisted self-help (ASH) approach that taps into community
resources is a pragmatic strategy as well, given the widening gap between growing
demand on one hand, and the budgetary constraints facing both governments as well as
particularly in Latin America, India and Africa, have spelled out key principles and
concepts that go beyond the ambit of basic shelter provision. They include housing rights
for all; security of tenure as essential for city stability, human dignity and urban
3
evictions; transparent and open land markets to fight corruption and reduce speculation;
and land availability to meet the needs of urban poor (Tebbal and Ray 2001).
of security of tenure, well into the realm of sustainable urban development and good
governance. Essentially, they represent a bridging of its two parallel global campaigns,
In view of the foregoing, a case can be made for subjecting the Kaantabay program
to formal policy evaluation. By predating the GCST by around 10 years, it can provide a
useful benchmark for the effectiveness and efficiency of the global advocacy. By
addressing as well the GUG norms as envisioned under UN-HABITAT’s parallel global
the World Bank, it can inform and enrich the growing body of literature on poverty.
But before embarking on such exercise, a close look at the “secure tenure”
program is needed to lay down the groundwork for a more robust, systematic evaluation.
This study therefore seeks to examine the program by seeking answers to the following
questions: a) How does the “Kaantabay sa Kauswagan” program work? What has it
accomplished? b) What conditions impelled the need to introduce the program in Naga
City? c) In what ways does it operationalize the “secure tenure” campaign of UN-
HABITAT?
The investigation will use the case study method in answering the research
setting or situation in as intense and as detailed a manner as possible (Salkind 1997, 211).
4
Chapter 2 begins by providing a theoretical perspective to the study. It looks at the
nature of poverty and “secure tenure” which form the interrelated foundational concepts
behind the Kaantabay program. Based on relevant theories underpinning these concepts,
it builds a theoretical and conceptual framework that will guide the analytical part of the
study.
Chapter 3 addresses the first research question. It looks at secondary data from the
city government, particularly documentation developed by the Urban Poor Affairs Office
information on Naga drawn from existing city profiles, indicators and datasets on Naga
available from websites of the Asian Development Bank (ADB) and the World Bank.
Using data from the program profile, Chapter 4 tackles the second and third
research questions by analyzing its economic, social and political dimensions in the
context of the framework laid out in Chapter 2. An economic analysis of the local housing
market examines the justification for government intervention through the program. A
socio-political analysis looks at how the program has managed to pursue a successful
Chapter 5 synthesizes highlights of the study, with the end view of specifying
possible research questions that can form part of a formal evaluation of the Kaantabay
program.
5
2 THEORETICAL AND CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK
This chapter develops a theoretical framework that will be used in analyzing the
2.1.1 Poverty
income. According to a World Bank economist, “poverty can be said to exist in a given
society when one or more persons do not attain a level of economic well-being deemed to
In the last two decades however, mainly as a result of Sen’s works on the subject,
education poverty; personal and tenure insecurity; and disempowerment. In urban areas,
these types of deprivation often tend to feed off each other, resulting in cumulative
deprivation where one dimension of poverty is often the cause or contributor to another
poverty.” It is closely linked with asset ownership, on the pretext that the more assets
people have, the less vulnerable they are, and the greater the erosion of people’s assets, the
greater their insecurity. Like deprivation, vulnerability is associated with five types of
6
assets: labour; human capital (health, education, skills and ability to work); productive
assets (of which housing is the most important); household relations; and social capital.
It is associated with depriving somebody from any right previously granted, or normally
Bank 2001, 22). Its relevance to poverty arises from shifting the concept away from
merely focusing on the issues of income inequality and material exclusion dominant in the
Anglo-Saxon view to incorporate the social and cultural dimension of the exclusionary
processes emphasized by the French corporatist model. It is even contended that “social
exclusion is broader than poverty in considering issues of social participation and rights
Secure tenure is still an evolving concept, owing to different situations that vary
7
rules, and that this right is justiciable. Tenure can be effected in a variety of
ways, depending on constitutional and legal frameworks, social norms,
cultural values and, to some extent, individual preference. (UN-HABITAT
n.d.)
for the goal of “affordable shelter for all” as a continuum of tenure types: from the
Surveyors (FIG) comprises of three elements, two of which have economic dimensions:
protection against eviction; the possibility of selling, and transferring rights through
inheritance; and the possibility of having a mortgage and access to credit under certain
are the key instrumental freedoms that tend to contribute to the general capability of a
conceding that shortage of income is a major cause, Sen contends that poverty actually
arises from the inability of certain functionings by an individual that collectively limits his
to education, health care, and political rights (forms of non-income poverty) inhibits an
8
Consequently, economic growth, in Sen’s conception, is seen only as a means to,
freedoms.
markets (Stiglitz 2000, 77). Theoretically, a perfectly competitive market freely decides
what, how and for whom to produce in the most efficient way, as if guided by what Adam
Smith called an “invisible hand” (Begg, Fischer and Dornbusch 2003, 8-9).
But in the real world, market failures exist, preventing market systems from
achieving allocative and productive efficiency. Whitehead (2003) said this applies to
housing, which suffers from significant market failures, particularly at the bottom end.
Among others, this is ascribed to direct, interactive and intergenerational externalities that
results to distributional issues that mostly affects the poor. Stiglitz (2000) points out that
income distributional issues provide an impetus for government intervention in the market.
(2000) controversial thesis that the absence of legally integrated property systems that can
convert their “dead capital” is the main reason why capitalism has triumphed in the West
9
Acocella (1998) ascribes this to the following realities: (1) The economic system is
not composed of anonymous agents but rather of classes or groups of individuals with
shared characteristics or needs. These individuals tend organize and act jointly to ensure
that their preferences prevail over those of other groups. (2) Policymakers are equally not
anonymous representatives of the public interest but can in fact be divided into politicians
The study of political economy employs the concepts of power, class and
approaching economic problems. While the approach lacks a clear and unifying
conceptual structure, it offers valuable insights for a more realistic treatment of economic
For instance, the interest group theory advanced by the public choice school holds
that government actions are a reflection of the pressure exerted by interest groups that
exist in society, both in terms of general policy attitudes or more specific interventions.
planning process, where mediation and facilitation between competing interests among
structures and the role of the local state. While there is no properly developed and
generally accepted theory of the behaviour and objectives of local government, or the
“local state,” the dominant managerialist view holds that focusing on the activities and
10
2.3 CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK
As pointed out in Chapter 1, the Kaantabay program is quite unique in the sense
that it is a social housing program with strong poverty and governance dimensions. As
Viewed at another level, the program represents the interplay between three local
institutions: the housing market, the local state and a segment of the local civil society (i.e.
the urban poor). The situation therefore lends to institutional analysis as the most
appropriate analytical approach, similar to the framework used by O’Sullivan and Gibb
(2003). It is envisioned that the combination and triangulation of these perspectives will
Figure 1 illustrates how the study is sequenced to bring these elements together.
Foundational
concepts
and theories
Economic
CHAPTER 3
Program Profile Policy
evaluation
research
Local & Social Political questions
National
Context
Program
Profile
11
3 THE KAANTABAY SA KAUSWAGAN PROGRAM:
A PROFILE
at the local context, as well as the local and national housing markets. Using secondary
data from the city government supplemented by other background information on Naga, it
details the program mechanics, including the governance framework upon which
Kaantabay was anchored, as well as its physical, social and financial aspects.
Naga in a nutshell
Population (2000) 140,325
Number of households 25,986
Per capita gross city product (1998) US$1,953
Average annual family income US$4,620
Poverty incidence 29%
12
2.1 THE SETTING
region comprising the southernmost portion of Luzon island in the Philippines. It is about
Nueva Caceres, it was one of the five original cities created by royal Spanish decree in the
late 16th century. It is seat of the 400-year old Archdiocese of Nueva Caceres that
oversees the predominantly catholic region famous for the beautifully shaped but fiery
Mayon volcano.
Over the years, Naga has grown to become the religious, educational and business
centre of Bicol, one of the country's 15 administrative regions. Today, it has developed a
reputation for being a centre for innovations in local governance. In 1998, Naga received
the Dubai International Award for having one of the Top 10 Best Practices worldwide in
newsmagazine cited it one of four most improved cities in Asia. And early this year, three
UN entities recognized its outstanding achievements in two areas: as one of the Women-
Friendly Cities of Asia-Pacific by UN-HABITAT and the United Nations Fund for
Women (UNIFEM); and Public Service Award for being a local e-government by the
1
More information on Naga City is available from the website of the city government at www.naga.gov.ph.
13
Government data shows that up to 40% of the total household population rely on
informal housing mechanisms to meet their shelter needs (HUDCC n.d.). Independent
estimates by the Global Urban Observatory place the number of slum dwellers a shade
higher at 44% (UN-HABITAT 2003b, 88). This indicates the presence of considerable
Of the 40%, the bottom 12% relies exclusively on informal housing, which is
financed either through self-help or through informal credit. The rest are able to access
some type of formal financing from existing government programs for low-income
In the formal housing market, which serves the relatively better-off segment of the
population, there are generally three types of housing products: socialized, middle-class
Coordinating Council (HUDDC), the country’s highest policymaking entity on shelter that
works under the Office of the President. HUDCC is a government-dominated body with
14
Over the last three years under the Arroyo administration, a pronounced shift in
housing policy was noted which explicitly gives priority attention to shelter needs of the
In the formal sector, housing is delivered by private sector developers, which have
organized themselves through the Chamber of the Real Estate and Builder’s Association
(CREBA). For the informal sector, the government is engaged in direct shelter production
through the National Housing Authority (NHA). Its activities focus on slum upgrading,
squatter relocation, development of sites and services and construction of core housing
units.
were delivered annually through formal housing. This contributed to further worsening of
the housing backlog, estimated to reach 1.1 million for the 2001-04 planning period. This
is apart from 2.2 million units required by new households, bringing total housing need to
Locally, official data show that in 1995, Naga's housing backlog stood at 6,400 and
was projected to increase to 7,400 by 2000 without strong government intervention. The
15
untapped, covering only 8% of total dwellings in the city, and underdeveloped, indicated
Compared to the rest of the country, income of city residents compare favourably.
In 1998, average household income stood at US$4,620 per annum, 42% higher than the
Philippine average and 126% higher than the average Bicol household.
spent on food (44%). Travel, utilities, health, education and other smaller expense items
ownership. While 72% of households own their housing unit, only 44% actually own their
respective homelots. The difference is not as pronounced among renters, as only 18%
rents their housing unit as against 23% who rent their homelots.
More than half of the total housing stock (52%) was built by the households
themselves, often with help from friends and relatives. Only around 27% were purchased
from the formal housing market, again indicating its limited extent in addressing shelter
needs. About 18% were built by hired contractors or skilled workers, usually in close
And of the homeowning segment, more than 90% have used own resources in
building their homes, again indicating very limited access to formal financing.
2.3.1 Beginnings
The Kaantabay sa Kauswagan program came to life on May 15, 1989 when the
city government organized its Urban Poor Affairs Office (UPAO), an agency dedicated to
16
The agency was created by the administration of Mayor Jesse M. Robredo after
nine urban poor organizations brought their plight to the national government’s attention
during a visit to Naga by then President Corazon Aquino late in 1987. By initiating the
program, Naga became the first Philippine city to recognize the urgency of addressing the
urban poor phenomenon at the local level. By organizing UPAO, it also became one of
the first local governments in the Philippines to establish a dedicated office for urban poor
concerns.
Organization of the Philippines Enterprise (COPE) Foundation helped the city government
to homelots for the urban poor of Naga, the program seeks to give their communities a
2. Poverty reduction. By helping the urban poor of Naga build capital, the
17
3. Urban upgrading. To complement the tenurial aspect, the program also
infrastructure and facilities, thereby restoring decency, ease and comfort to daily life.
Table 2.
in Naga has ensured that all major city programs are founded on partnerships and
participation.
Unlike other local authorities who were reluctant in working with NGOs and POs,
the city government seriously implemented provisions of the 1991 Local Government
promoting partnerships with these organizations. After the Code was passed, Naga was
among the first to pursue the mandate on NGO accreditation. During its first run in 1993,
close to 80 applied with the city council and were duly accredited.
further. A landmark
the establishment of a
system of partnership
18
the Naga City People’s Council (NCPC) was encouraged. This institutionalized a system
framework developed by the Robredo administration (Fig. 3). In this framework, three
• Progressive perspective. This component lies at the apex of the triangle, being a
function of leadership which the local administration must provide. Among others, a
progressive perspective seeks to build prosperity for the community at large, tempered by
• Functional partnerships. These are vehicles that enable the local authority to
tap community resources for priority undertakings, in the process multiplying its capacity
The Kaantabay program focuses on the urban poor sector’s two main problems:
(1) the absence of security of land tenure, and (2) the lack of basic infrastructure and
facilities in their communities. In response, the program focuses on two main physical
components: land acquisition and area upgrading. By addressing both, the program
becomes more comprehensive in its approach to the urban poor problem by responding to
Land acquisition
Land acquisition is the heart of the Kaantabay program. It facilitates the granting
of tenurial rights over a homelot to an urban poor household, culminating in the issuance
19
of a property title once payment is completed. In the process, it can directly contribute to
poverty reduction by actualizing capital building for the poorer segments of society.
Figure 4 shows how the program’s focus on the homelot is a strategic choice that
On-site vs. off-site. There are two categories of land acquisition projects under the
e) Community upgrading.
Off-site projects, on the other hand, focus on the establishment and development of
relocation sites to serve as "safety nets" for extreme cases of eviction and demolition. It
20
essentially involves: a) Site identification and negotiation with landowners; b) Purchase of
services
Coverage, project and homelot profile. Tables 3 to 5 at the end of the chapter
provide additional program details at the project, strategic and financial level. Table 3
describes the 41 projects being implemented under the program, showing the extent of its
coverage. As of October 31, 2001, the program has covered a total of 6,940 urban poor
households, representing 27 percent of the total. The figure is roughly 500 families shy of
the 7,400 low-income Naga households who live below poverty line.
In terms of direct benefit, 67 percent of the 6,940 households are on their way to
acquiring their property titles, having benefited from 27 completed projects under the
program. Negotiations are ongoing for 14 more projects that will cover the remaining 33
percent. Thus, for roughly 2 out of every 3 urban poor households in Naga, agreement has
been reached between the landowner, the urban poor association and the city government;
the tenurial status of the occupants is already secured; and they are in the process of
The table also shows that to date, the program has disposed a total of 62.6 hectares
under the 27 projects, with another 29.6 in the pipeline. In all, its portfolio covers a total
meters per household, excluding provision for roads, pathways and open areas for each
project. Across projects, homelot size ranges from a generous 150 sq meters in rural
settlements formerly owned by the national government which were subsumed under the
program, to around 70-80 sq meters in urban poor communities ringing the periphery of
21
Aside from detailing program funding, Table 4 profiles the average urban poor
project across the 27 completed projects under Kaantabay. Over the seven-year period, a
typical completed project would cost around P3.3 million (£33,0002) or P467,646.06
(£4,676.46) annually.
Homelot affordability can be measured by reducing project cost to the level of each
beneficiaries per project from the table (172, the ratio of 4,635 families across 27
completed projects), and spreading the total project cost among beneficiaries. Thus, each
homelot would cost the average urban household a total of P19,032.11 (£190.32) over
P227 (£2.27, roughly a local labourer’s minimum daily wage) or around P7.55 (roughly 8
Land acquisition modes. The program derives its strength from the innovative land
acquisition modes implemented both for on-site and off-site projects. These approaches
helped overcome resource limitations by reducing cost and mobilizing community and
external financing, thereby multiplying the city’s capability to do more with the same level
of resources.
Table 5 lists down and compares these approaches. Illustrative projects where
Area upgrading
improvement and basic service delivery. Implemented in conjunction with the land
acquisition component, this has also covered all 41 urban poor communities being assisted
by the city government under the program. From 1998-2000, around 10% of the city’s
2
An exchange rate of £1=P100 is used here to facilitate conversion. It is based on the actual rate for the first
half of 2004 that ranged between 98 and 107 pesos to a British pound. (Historical data on exchange rates
among global currencies can be secured from www.oanda.com/convert/fxhistory.)
22
Infrastructure Fund (placed at roughly P40 million [£400,000] annually) were spent on
urban renewal projects. From time to time, they are augmented by funding allotments
Urban renewal projects take various forms. They include construction or repair of
drainage lines; provision of public faucets and shallow wells; installation of street lights;
and concreting of pathways to improve access to and services within an urban poor
community.
Moreover, additional basic services are made available to the relocated urban
secondary levels is provided through day care centres, and public elementary and high
schools. Health is accessible from the community health centre. Transportation services
are made possible through provision of access road, the opening of new routes passing
through the relocation sites, and public utility vehicles loaned out to local cooperatives.
Electric power service is supplied to individual households through Casureco II, the local
power retailer. Water service is progressively being supplied by the Metro Naga Water
District (which has been expanding its coverage area) and through communal water
systems for far-flung areas outside the network. Livelihood development is facilitated by
the extension of capital assistance through Metro Peso, the city government's micro-
Community organizing
requirement under the Kaantabay program. A policy of dealing only with urban poor
23
organizations, not individuals, compels interested applicants to take the initiative in
organizing themselves.
In implementing the program, the non-government sector has played a key role in
social preparation and community organizing. The city government recognizes that these
The partnership between City Hall and the COPE Foundation therefore made
sense. As a result of COPE’s efforts, from the original nine urban poor organizations in
1989 when Kaantabay begun, there are now close to 80 urban poor associations in the
city.
Tripartism
problem resolution, involving the a) city government and other national government
agencies; b) urban poor associations, aided by NGOs and POs; and c) private landowners.
This mechanism enables the involved parties to sit down and cooperate in solving their
disputes.
By adopting a pro-poor bias, the city government gives the program strength and
credibility. This bias is particularly manifested in its treatment of urban poor associations
Urban poor associations, on the other hand, signify their support and commitment
to the program through their willingness to negotiate get organized and raise equity if
necessary, including money for land acquisition and labour for urban upgrading projects.
24
Finally, landowners show their cooperation through willingness to explore more
following:
their amortization and equity share in the Kaantabay Trust Fund, which helps the city in
• Strong community support for local tax collection. Notwithstanding the negative
impact of the Asian currency crisis in 1997, the ensuing economic downturn under the
national allotments from the central government, the city continues to cope well because
Over the last decade, receipts from property and business taxes have been
increasing steadily, enabling the city to achieve a collection efficiency ranging from 87-
115% and a very satisfactory rating from the Bureau of Local Government Finance
(BLGF) of the national government. The willingness of local residents to remit tax money
to the local treasury is an indication of strong support for the city’s directions, including
keyed Kaantabay’s sustainability over the past decade, especially the last seven years.
The turning point came in 1994, when the first of major land acquisition projects began to
get on-stream.
25
These include (1) the “no-doleout” policy that discourages freeloading and
mendicancy and seeks to collect of all recoverable expenses by the city government under
the program, and (2) the project equity policy that operationalizes participation at the
project financing level. Together, they have elicited meaningful beneficiary involvement
from the onset of a particular land acquisition project until government has collected its
recoverable expenses.
Program funding
Table 4 presents the program’s seven-year operating budget and fund sources since
land acquisition projects took off in 1994, totalling P104.5 million (£1.045 million).
government through its annual operating budget, augmented by short- and long-term
borrowings, grants from national shelter agencies and other program partners, equity
Of the total, around 20% is funded out of the annual city budget, mainly for
operation and maintenance of UPAO and part of land development costs. Around half
(51%) comes from short- and long-term borrowings guaranteed by the city government,
which finances land acquisition through community mortgage arrangements. Grants from
national shelter agencies and other program partners account for around 12%, covering the
bulk of land development. The remaining 17% is allocated for cost of money, which is to
From time to time, the program also receives donations and counterpart funding
from various program partners on project basis. In 1994, it received a US$1,000 donation
from the Asian Coalition of Housing Rights (ACHR). The following year, the Pacol Site
Development Project was given a P11.6 million (£116,000) grant by the NHA. In 1998,
26
the Liberty Commercial Center (LCC) Group of Companies spent an estimated P4.5
million (£45,000) for land acquisition of what is now the Metroville Housing Project.
Future sources. By virtue of City Ordinance No. 98-033, otherwise known as the
Kaantabay sa Kauswagan Ordinance of 1998, the city is mandated to allocate 10% of its
annual budget, net of personal services, for the program and its various activities. This
legislation is a concrete step taken by the Robredo administration to help ensure long-term
sustainability.
In addition, Naga has been identified as one of the four priority Philippine cities
Infrastructure Project (USCIP). The project, which seeks to test the feasibility of
Cost recovery
recovery over time, anchored on the principle of shared pain and gain among program
beneficiaries. This principle affirms the dignity of even the poorest sectors of society; by
giving beneficiaries the opportunity to pay for their homelots under affordable
amortization schemes, they not only build capital but also acquire it the proper way. Thus,
the program’s cost recovery mechanism enables them to become real “homeowners,” not
Cost items. Essentially, the program has four major cost items: land acquisition,
land development, operations and cost of money. Land acquisition covers payments for
the cost of land for on-site and off-site development. Land development represents
expenses incurred in land preparation and development, specifically for off-site relocation
areas, and area upgrading for on-site projects. Operating expenses represent the cost of
27
operating and maintaining the UPAO. Cost of money covers interest expenses incurred in
financing land acquisition, based on the project cost net of beneficiaries equity assumed at
the 10% minimum. Interest rate is set at 9% per annum compounded annually.
Of these, only land acquisition, land development and cost of money are
considered recoverable expenses under the program. Over the last seven years, they
amounted to P88.4 million (£884,000) or roughly 84.5% of the total program cost. On an
economic crisis in and the crisis-ridden Estrada administration, the program was doing
quite well. In 1998, a special audit team of the Commission on Audit (COA) Regional
Office conducted a two-month “Value for Money Audit” study. One of the salient
Over the last two years however, payments have started to fall behind. UPAO’s
collection status report as of December 2000 placed accrued collections at 30% of the
total, with accounts payable reaching 35%. This impelled a management review that
including an amnesty program implemented beginning July 2001 that condoned all
Project equity
especially for on-site development projects. While negotiation is taking place and there is
28
already assurance that the owner would sell his property, the city government starts
collecting money.
When the negotiation has been finalized and a contract executed, the city
government, in consultation with the community association, sets certain percentage of the
land acquisition cost as project equity. This equity ranges from 10 to 50 percent of the
Kaantabay Trust Fund for Socialized Housing and Resettlement was set up in November
The city administration has often used this trust fund to encourage beneficiaries to
amortize regularly so that the city can continue the program and assist other urban poor
families to also have homelots of their own. To illustrate: grants from outside source, like
the P11.6 million (£116,000) from the NHA, is being recovered by the city and placed in
the Trust Fund, which in turn can be used to establish another housing project. Thus, in a
worst-case scenario where internal cash generation of the program is unable to cover for
October 31, 2001, it had a retained balance of P4.08 million (£40,800). The amount
represents 43% of the P9.5 million (£95,000) project equity being eyed for eight ongoing
projects under negotiation with an estimated acquisition cost of P94.8 million (£948,000).
Enhancing affordability
act between fiscal discipline and the government’s social responsibility in uplifting the
29
poorest constituents of the city. This has yielded a mixture of cost-reduction and income-
Savings in land acquisition. Land acquisition stands out as priority area for cost
reduction, being the biggest cost item in program implementation. Apart from substantial
cost savings through proactive land banking and utilization of idle government lots, the
city also leveraged its reputation in negotiating lower acquisition cost for both on-site and
prices 30% lower than prevailing market values, as indicated by property values of
projects, taking advantage of the prevailing buyers’ market in the property sector of the
local economy.
The Bayadnihan program. This new work-for-pay program enables urban poor
beneficiaries to settle their lot amortizations, whether current or past due, through
Allowable work that beneficiaries or their family members can take on include
such as buildings, drainage systems, water supply systems, electrical installations, city
streets and sports facilities; cleaning and beautification of public facilities such as city
streets, parks, plazas, playgrounds and street islands; garbage collection and disposal, and
2.5 SUMMARY
resource constraints, a local authority can equalize opportunities for the poorest sector of
30
At the conceptual level, the program addresses shelter problems brought about by
with clients. This approach sees the urban poor both as a program partner and beneficiary,
To maximize scarce resources, it adopts the strategy of focus that delimits program
coverage only to the urban poor sector in Naga and the homelot as core of the assistance
package for each household. In the process, it fashioned innovative approaches to land
near universal coverage. It also overcame resource limitations that handicap national and
participation, the program has tapped the power of pooled community resources. The end
landowners and urban poor associations to work together in finding mutually acceptable
31
Table 3. COMPLETED AND ONGOING PROJECTS
Kaantabay sa Kauswagan Program
PROJECT NAME AREA NO. FAMILIES MODE OF ACQUISITION COST
(In Has.) ACQUISITION (In Philippine Pesos)
OFF-SITE PROJECTS
1. Abella Resettlement Project, Barangays Abella & Sta. Cruz 4.00 551 Negotiated Purchase 11,000,000.00
2. Calauag Resettlement Project 4.95 591 Negotiated Purchase 7,425,000.00
3. Cararayan P-1 Resettlement Project 5.84 219 Government Lots N/A
4. Cararayan P-2 Resettlement Project 2.00 65 Government Lots N/A
5. Del Rosario Resettlement Project 1.67 137 Negotiated Purchase 711,474.00
of foreclosed property
6. Isla Resettlement Project, Barangay Peñafrancia 1.13 81 Negotiated Purchase 1,325,324.00
7. Pacol Resettlement Project, Phase I 12.42 714 Negotiated Purchase 1,826,340.00
8. Panicuason Barangay Site 2.00 87 Negotiated Purchase 20,000.00
9. Sabang Puro (SPUKOI), Barangay Sabang 1.30 223 Land Sharing 3,900,000.00
10. Sabang Resettlement Project (Metroville) 1.70 184 Leveraged Land N/A
Sharing Plus
11. San Felipe Resettlement Project 1.00 98 Land Swapping 1,881,557.20
12. San Isidro Barangay Site 2.00 52 Government Lots 36,000.00
13. San Rafael Resettlement Project, Barangay Cararayan 10.01 433 Government Lots 150,000.00
14. BLISS-Cararayan Project, Barangay Cararayan 2.00 50 Government Lots 432,000.00
15. Happy Homes Resettlement Project, Barangay Balatas 0.60 62 Community-Initiated 3,000,000.00
Purchase
SUBTOTAL COMPLETED OFF-SITE PROJECTS 52.61 3,547 31,707,695.20
ON-SITE PROJECTS
1. Acacia Homeowners Association, Barangay Abella 0.30 52 CMP 753,000.00
2. Good Neighbors Homeowners Association, Barangay Igualdad 0.12 10 Negotiated Purchase 590,000.00
3. Igualdad Z-5 Homeowners Association 0.48 63 CMP N/A
4. Greenland Urban Poor Homeowners Association, Barangay Concepcion 0.87 52 City Property N/A
Pequeña
5. Lerma Urban Poor Association 0.30 78 CMP N/A
6. Lerma Z-2 Homeowners Association 0.14 23 Negotiated Purchase 471,750.00
7. Peñafrancia Service Coop. (Mitra) 5.50 428 Self-Help CMP 11,668,512.00
32
Table 3. COMPLETED AND ONGOING PROJECTS (Continued)
PROJECT NAME AREA NO. FAMILIES MODE OF ACQUISITION COST
(In Has.) ACQUISITION (In Philippine Pesos)
8. Pook Mangga Homeowners Association, Barangay Sta. Cruz 0.06 6 Negotiated Purchase 261,000.00
9. Tabuco Tenants Association 0.69 134 Negotiated Purchase 3,650,500.00
10. Calsada Neighborhood Association, Barangay Mabolo 0.39 56 Negotiated Purchase 1,936,000.00
11. Triangulo Urban Poor Homeowners Association, Inc. 0.96 139 Negotiated Purchase 2,016,000.00
12. Quinale Urban Poor Association, Inc., Barangay Tabuco 0.19 47 Negotiated Purchase 1,240,850.00
SUBTOTAL COMPLETED ON-SITE PROJECTS 9.99 1,088 22,587,612.00
TOTAL COMPLETED PROJECTS 62.60 4,635 54,295,307.20
ONGOING PROJECTS
1. Canda Neighborhood Association, Inc., Barangay Concepcion Pequeña 1.15 128 Under Negotiation 5,725,500.00
2. San Antonio Urban Poor Association, Inc., Barangay Concepcion 1.37 118 Under Negotiation 5,460,800.00
Pequeña
3. Azucena Homeowners Association, Inc., Barangay Calauag 0.34 35 Under Negotiation 3,713,000.00
4. Capilihan Homeowners Association, Inc., Barangay Calauag 1.79 110 On-going 5,313,600.00
5. Doña Clara Homeowners Association, Inc., Barangay Con. Pequeña 5.93 447 On-going 32,336,518.47
6. Queborac Relocation Site, Barangay Bagumbayan Sur 7.00 542 On-going 17,500,000.00
7. Villa Fulgentes Urban Kabisig Association, Inc., Barangay Sabang 0.85 103 Under Negotiation 8,510,000.00
8. San Andres Estate Neighborhood Association, Inc., Barangay 4.00 203 Under Negotiation 24,000,000.00
Peñafrancia
9. Concepcion Grande Z 5 Homeowners Association 0.75 76 Under Negotiation 14,924,000.00
10. Bagumbayan Sur/Norte Urban Poor Association, Barangays 0.74 23 Under Negotiation 7,379,000.00
Bagumbayan Sur & Norte
11. Central Business District II Residents Project, Barangays Triangulo & 0.70 169 Under Negotiation 7,000,000.00
Lerma
12. Tapas Urban Poor Association, Inc., Barangay Balatas 4.78 274 Eminent Domain TBD*
13. Tabuco-Ng Hua Urban Poor Association, Inc., Barangay Tabuco 0.06 47 Under Negotiation TBD
14. SPUKOI-Phase II, Barangay Sabang 0.10 30 Under Negotiation TBD
SUBTOTAL ONGOING PROJECTS 29.55 2,305 131,862,418.47
GRAND TOTAL COMPLETED AND ONGOING PROJECTS 92.15 6,940 186,157,725.67
Source: Urban Poor Affairs Office, Naga City
33
Table 4. OPERATING BUDGET AND FUNDING SOURCES, 1994-2000
In Philippine Pesos
PARTICULARS UNIT COST 7-YEAR PERIOD ANNUAL FUNDING
SOURCES
Land Acquisition 54,295,307.20 7,756,472.46 • Beneficiaries’ equity (Minimum
On-site 22,587,612.00 of 10%)
Off-site 31,707,695.20 • Short- and long-term borrowings
Land Development Cost 16,498,119.00 2,356,874.14 • Grant from National Housing
Authority (70%)
• City Infrastructure Fund
Operating Cost • Annual UPAO budget
Personal Services 10,889,256.00 1,555,608.00 • Grants from donor agencies
Salaries 671,964.00
Wages 316,800.00
Other Personnel Benefits 566,844.00
Maintenance & Other Operating Expenses 1,771,000.00 253,000.00
Travelling Expenses 30,000.00
Communication Services 35,000.00
Gasoline and Oil, Spare Parts and Repairs 98,000.00
Supplies and Materials 60,000.00
Other Expenses 30,000.00
Capital Outlay 3,500,000.00 500,000.00
Cost of Money 17,591,679.53 2,513,097.08 Program’s internal cash
generation
TOTALS 104,545,361.73 14,935,051.68
Average Cost per Project 3,273,522.43 467,646.06
Average Cost per Household 19,032.11 2,718.87
Average Monthly Cost per Household 226.57
Source: Urban Poor Affairs Office, Naga City
34
Table 5. COMPARATIVE LAND ACQUISITION APPROACHES
Kaantabay sa Kauswagan Program
MODE KEY FEATURES UPSIDE DOWNSIDE WHERE APPLICABLE
1. Conventional • A government financial institution (GFI) Does not need big amount Viability of national On-site development
community acquires title to an urban poor community of local resources, as this program can be affected projects near CBDs,
mortgage (CMP) • Property is subdivided among urban poor is provided through a by poor project where property values are
households national program implementation elsewhere higher
• Members of urban poor community amortizes
their respective homelots to GFI, usually
through an originator
2. Self-help • Local authority, instead of the GFI, provides Can be attractive to • Might require significant CMP projects abandoned
community bulk of financing requirement private financial amount of local by GFIs where the
mortgage • Urban poor community provides a significant institutions (PFIs) and government resources beneficiary community
amount of equity international development • Can affect quality of can raise significant equity
agencies, especially if other public services if
local authority has good not managed well
credit standing
3. Land sharing • Owner agrees to share landholding occupied Can spark urban renewal • May not accommodate Sizable occupied
by urban poor community by selling portion of in a blighted area due to all members of properties with high
the property combined public and community. Requires development potentials
• Owner gets choice portion (usually frontage) private investment alternative relocation
of the property sites for excess
• Shared portion is subdivided among urban households
poor households who amortize it under either • Might require local
straight CMP or the self-help variant government to provide
4. Leveraged land • Instead of sharing landholding under straight Can spark urban renewal infrastructure support as
sharing plus land sharing, property owner acquires an in a blighted area due to enticement
adjoining property and develops it into a combined public and
relocation area private investment
• Owner gets control over main landholding
• Adjoining property is subdivided among urban
poor households who amortize it under either
straight CMP or the self-help variant
35
Table 5. COMPARATIVE LAND ACQUISITION APPROACHES (Continued)
MODE KEY FEATURES UPSIDE DOWNSIDE WHERE APPLICABLE
5. Land swapping • Owner agrees to swap landholding occupied Does not need big amount • Dependent on On-site development
by urban poor community with another of of local resources, as availability of acceptable projects involving small to
roughly equal size or value, preferably without replacement landholding replacement property medium-sized properties
occupants is usually secured from • Becomes costly if local in peripheries of the CBD
• Swapped property is subdivided among urban land banking portfolio of authority did not engage
poor households who amortize it under either the local authority in proactive land
straight CMP or the self-help variant banking
6. Community- • In this variant of the self-help community Does not need big amount On-site development
initiated mortgage, the urban poor community puts up of local resources, as projects involving in
purchase at least half of the total project cost community puts up high relatively well-off urban
• Property is subdivided among households level of equity poor community
who amortize the balance
7. Proactive land • Essentially the acquisition of raw landholdings, Brings down significantly Might need a significant Local authorities with
banking especially outside the urban area, at the cost of land for amount of resources for surplus income
significantly lower cost housing projects the short term
• These landholdings are earmarked for
development into low-cost housing or
resettlement areas
8. Idle government Involves the use of unutilized/underutilized The least costly option for • Local authorities who
lots properties of the national government or the off-site development own idle landholdings
local authority for housing projects • Local authorities with
good track record and
working relations with
national agencies
9. Livelihood A new concept which involves the provision for A higher level of social Still untested Local authorities who own
housing communal farming and fishing, including housing that integrates idle lands, particularly in
support services, on top of the traditional livelihood into the basic rural areas
homelots for beneficiaries off-site development
project
10. Eminent • The last option to push on-site development Can provide final solution Usually a lengthy process • Local authorities with
domain • Involves the expropriation of privately-owned to long-standing housing since it has to go through eminent domain powers
landholdings by the local authority, invoking issues court proceedings. There • On-site development
the power of eminent domain is also the risk of losing projects where
the case, leaving negotiations have
government and the reached a dead end
community empty-handed
Source: Urban Poor Affairs Office, Naga City
36
4 ANALYSIS
This chapter looks at the economic, social and political dimension of the
Kaantabay sa Kauswagan program, guided by the two other research questions: What
conditions impelled the need to introduce the program in Naga City? In what ways does it
Two recently published research works that touched on the Kaantabay program
offer similar accounts to the one described in Chapter 3: problems associated with
urbanization in the late 1980s have cropped up, affecting the urban poor. The program
was fashioned when a new administration that took over proved to be more responsive to
their concerns.
Tumbaga and Sabado (2003) devoted an entire chapter to the program as part of its
case study on Naga. The case study is meant to exemplify a Philippine local authority that
is pursuing a program of “growth with equity” through its own initiatives and resources,
and mostly without support from the national government. Together with case studies on
two other local governments, their work sought to understand local governance amidst
Kawanaka (2002), on the other hand, examined local power dynamics to illustrate
the role of the state and institutions in local politics. By looking at these institutions, not
through conventional sociocultural perspectives but within the framework of the state and
maximizing the elite’s control—the predominant elite in this case being the elected
political leader. In a chapter describing the political machine, the program was
37
categorized as one of its components aimed at gaining the support and loyalty of the poor
These studies, together with other documents on the program, will be examined in
the succeeding sections. This section explores the economics of the Kaantabay program,
Figure 5 shows the local housing supply and demand in Naga City. With the
formal housing market accounting for 27% of the total housing stock of roughly 26,000,
the supply curve OS1 intersects the demand curve AD at the breakeven point X, which
roughly corresponds to a unit price of P300,000 (£3,000). The amount is well within the
price range for low-cost or economic housing package shown in Table 1. It will be noted
that while private developers theoretically lose money in producing units that cost below
38
the equilibrium point X, they nevertheless continue building them. These units
(corresponding to the supply curve XS1) fall within the socialized housing category whose
But it is the failure of the formal housing market to address the need of a greater
majority of the local society (represented by the area bounded by S1S2DC) that provides
Locally, this market failure stems from the information asymmetries, intergenerational
exacerbated by the private capital markets’ unwillingness to extend loans to the urban
the program. By expanding housing services towards universal coverage, the shift in
supply curve from OS1 to OS2 in effect causes a downward shift of the breakeven point
from X to Y. As a result, all housing units produced by private developers will break even
at the very least, enabling government to realign subsidies wholly towards the informal
sector.
programs such as Kaantabay can be seen when one considers its social aspect to enrich the
the city mayor’s political machine, using state-centered institutions as a key independent
variable in the analysis. The approach might be an improvement over the traditional
sociocultural framework used in analyzing power relations in the Philippine context, and
39
probably empirically valid in its own right. But when one uses other socially-oriented
Under Sen’s capabilities theory and Moser’s vulnerability framework, for example,
the Kaantabay program would easily qualify as a key urban poverty intervention as it
addresses the personal and tenure insecurity dimension of deprivation and the productive
facilitating the acquisition of land titles by the urban poor, their empowerment is another
benefit brought about by the program. Thus, even without the need to raise incomes as
social exclusion through community organizing of the urban poor (in the process creating
their own interest group) and compelling them to actively participate in problem
resolution.3
In presenting four case studies of gains made by urban poor groups in the
Philippines, Racelis (2003) placed the Naga City Urban Poor Federation at the top end of a
continuum of their relations with the state, characterised as ranging from “begging” and
This non-partisan body was composed of NGOs, POs, and private sector
groups, who could propose legislation and carry out additional duties. Soon
Council-designated NGOs were sitting on boards, councils, committees,
task forces and other special bodies of the city government. The Ordinance
also provided for representation in the city legislature of elected non-
agricultural labour, women and urban poor. (Racelis 2003, 15)
To be sure, the program suffers from its own weaknesses, including issues on long-
term financial sustainability, replicability and political dynamics as Tumbaga and Sabado
3
ADB’s draft poverty assessment for the Philippines made the same point. It said that “looking at poverty
in terms of capability deprivation can lead to programs that address the very poor…without having to
directly increase their incomes, such as improving social service provision.”
40
have noted. But viewed another way, they saw Kaantabay as “an exemplary way by which
a local government could manage the social costs inflicted on the urban poor by urban
4.3 MANAGING URBAN DEVELOPMENT: BRIDGING THE IDEAL AND THE REAL
The political dynamics associated with the program fits well the managerialist
stakeholders.
makers, in this case the city’s elected leaders led by the city mayor, contributes to a better
Healy’s framework, decision making takes place amidst competing demands and therefore
A classic case, which Tumbaga and Sabado documented well, is the conflict
between Robredo and a group of 221 urban poor households who refused relocation and
were thus displaced when the city government implemented the “leveraged land sharing
plus” project. (See the appendix.) In this instant case, the entry of the LCC mall
development forced the city to prioritize economic growth at the expense of equity insofar
as the affected households are concerned. “That the city government was perceived by
urban poor groups to have taken the side of the landowners/developers was an ironic twist
as the city government prided itself for being ‘pro-poor,’ or at least being impartial in its
The city government, however, believed their actions and decisions were justified
in the search for the most beneficial arrangement for the city. Succeeding events,
41
including favourable decisions by local courts and national agencies, as well as general
public support for the city government’s position, appeared to have confirmed this.
bridging the ideal and the real. For instance, the land acquisition approaches it prided
itself as having implemented under the Kaantabay program are conceptually nothing new.
In fact, Presidential Decree No. 1517 issued by President Marcos in the 1970s authorized
the state to use most of the very same techniques listed in Table 5. The only difference is
that while the national government has failed to pursue them, Naga actually did under the
program.
position in the Philippine context means having to survive regularly held elections,
compelling power holders to set up and maintain systems for distributing benefits, i.e. the
political machine, in order to win. But in the same vein, Racelis pointed out that “genuine
participatory governance is good politics and good politics gets good politicians re-
motivated by politics. As a politician, you can ensure your survival by buying votes, or
you can improve your performance as a public servant. By helping the urban poor, we are
also helping ourselves as politicians” (Tumbaga and Sabado 2003, 339).4 In other words,
The 2003 World Development Report echoes this, pointing out that
For cities and towns to realize the promises of a better life…they need
stronger institutions to provide wide access to assets and to balance interests
that ensure the provision of public goods. Such institutions are central to an
4
Over the five local elections held in Naga since 1992, Robredo’s slate had swept all contested seats—from
mayor, vice mayor and the 10 city councilors—including the most recent one last May 10, 2004. In 1998,
then Councilor Jacob himself earned a seat in the national legislature, representing the Metro Naga district.
42
urban governance that is inclusive of all residents, responsive to their needs,
and conducive to careful management of natural resources and wastes.
(World Bank 2003)
4.4 SUMMARY
The foregoing analysis of the economic, social and political dimensions enables a
richer, more textured characterization of the Kaantabay program. The economics of the
and attendant distributional issues that exclude a greater majority from accessing housing
services—is not only shown to be consistent with existing literature on the subject; it also
validated the necessary precondition for such intervention as voiced out by the affected
deprivation, vulnerability and social exclusion bolsters the contention that the program is
not merely a tool of the local political elite’s effort to stay in power. On the contrary, it
was demonstrated to have both empowered the urban poor, thereby addressing social
exclusion, and strengthened their security of tenure and access to productive assets as
Finally, analysis of the political dynamics attending the program has affirmed the
implicit mediation function of state agents on top of their traditional leadership roles,
towards the public good, anchored on the Smithian concept of enlightened self-interest, is
43
5 SYNTHESIS
The preceding four chapters have outlined the case for a formal evaluation of Naga
of UN-HABITAT’s global secure tenure advocacy, and it can enrich and inform the
research agenda on poverty and good urban governance. Chapter 2 developed a tri-
dimensional theoretical framework that was used in analyzing the program from
economic, social and political perspectives. Chapter 3 profiled the Kaantabay program,
including the local context, conceptual framework as well as the physical, social and
financial aspects of its operation. Using data from Chapters 2 and 3, the preceding chapter
then provided a richer, more textured characterization of the program by analyzing its
This concluding chapter brings all the previous elements together in proposing
this case study, the proposed evaluation research should make use of both quantitative and
a) Do benefits arising from the Kaantabay program outweigh its costs? Does it
44
These are the two key research questions for a conventional evaluation that looks
The number of urban poor households given tenurial rights under the program will
two levels: (1) in terms of the total market value of assets built up by urban poor
beneficiaries as recorded by the City Assessor, i.e. the value of landholdings whose
property rights will be transferred to said beneficiaries, and (2) independent valuation by
banks in the open market. The two nationally-funded CMP programs during the early part
of program implementation can serve as the counterfactual, i.e. what would have happened
in a “policy-off” scenario, which will help establish the Kaantabay’s gross and net
additionality.
Program cost will include a more detailed economic accounting of all direct and
indirect city government funds in support of Kaantabay, grants from national and foreign
warranted.
It will be noted that most information available thus far have come from leaders
and key players in the interaction between the housing market, the state, the urban poor
sector and other stakeholders. For a meaningful evaluation, it is important to reach out to
survey covering representative samples drawn from both on-site and off-site projects.
45
representation among geographical regions of the city (i.e. urban vs. suburban area), as
business sector, professionals as well as ordinary non-urban poor residents of the city. A
survey similar to the one described above will generate this information.
This will be the main question that will be asked during a focus group discussion
Information derived from the preceding activities will be presented to provide the
context for a special meeting of the City Housing and Urban Development Board, which
sets policy for Kaantabay. The use participative facilitation techniques—such as the
Technology of Participation (ToP) —will assist documentation and analysis of the FGD,
whose results will form part of the research findings, conclusions and recommendations.
These guidelines are by no means exhaustive, nor do they represent the final option
available to a policy evaluator. But they can inform and jumpstart the formal evaluation
46
APPENDIX
To save the situation, the city government purchased the property directly from the
Church, backed by loan from the Government Service Insurance System (GSIS)
supported by bridge financing from a local commercial bank. Banking on its
reputation and
goodwill, the
city got the
property at
roughly 25
percent of the
market value.
This enabled
the city to
resell it to the
428 families
at virtually the
same price as
acquisition
cost.
Amortization THE land sharing scheme for the Naga Centrum landholding. Previously,
of the SPUKOI members were occupying the rightmost portion of the property. A
property by bridge (heavy black lines) built by the city now connects it to the other side
of Naga River.
47
occupants is now almost complete, save for a handful of families left.
After a local court finally ruled in favor of the NCC, the SPUKOI community was
threatened with forcible ejection. With the city’s intervention, a “win-win” sharing
arrangement was hammered out. NCC allowed a 1.3-hectare portion for sale and
occupancy by the community, provided they transfer from the front end to the back
and the city build a bridge
into the property. The
bridge, now known as the
Tabuco-Sabang Bridge, is
already in place. This
increased property values
in the vicinity and
allowed the owners
optimum use of the
property.
• Leveraged Land
Sharing Plus. A
variant of straight land
sharing, this involves the
purchase of an adjoining
property by a landowner
where urban poor
occupants of his main
property can be relocated.
To solve the situation, the city convinced LCC to buy an adjoining lot and with
assistance from the city, develop a low-cost housing project for the affected families.
This ensured minimal displacement for most of the informal settlers.
Today, around 120 of the 200 have already transferred to what is now the Metroville
Housing Project; the rest to another city property in Barangay San Felipe. The LCC
48
Central Mall has risen out of
the ashes of the dilapidated
Superland and is now doing
good business, in the process
sparking urban renewal in
the South Riverfront area of
Naga.
The strategy paid off handsomely, as property values—in areas where the city used
direct purchase—have zoomed up by as much as ten times.
49
REFERENCES
Asian Development Bank. 2001. Cities Data Book: Urban Indicators for Managing Cities,
Matthew Westfall and Victoria de Villa, eds.
Begg, D., Stanley Fischer and Rudiger Dornbusch. 2003. Economics, 7th ed., London:
McGraw-Hill Education.
Cobbett, William. 2001. “Towards Secure Tenure for All,” Habitat Debate 5, no. 3.
Available from www.unhabitat.org/hd/
De Soto, Hernando. 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West
and Fails Everywhere Else. Black Swan Books.
Moser, Caroline. 1998. “The Asset Vulnerability Framework: Reassessing Urban Poverty
Reduction Strategies,” World Development 26, No. 1.
O’Sullivan, T. and Kenneth Gibb, eds., 2003. Housing Economics and Public Policy.
Blackwell Science Ltd.
Rydin, Yvonne. 1998. Urban and Environmental Planning in the UK, MacMillan:
London.
Salkind, Neil J. 1997. Exploring Research, 3rd ed., New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2000, Economics of the Public Sector, 3rd ed., New York/London:
W.W. Norton & Company.
50
Tebbal, F. and Kalyan Ray. 2001. “Housing the Urban Poor,” Habitat Debate 7, no. 3.
Available from www.unhabitat.org/hd/
UN-HABITAT. “The Global Campaign For Secure Tenure,” n.d. Available from
http://hq.unhabitat.org/campaigns/tenure/tenure.asp
UN-HABITAT. 2003b. Slums of the World: The Face of Urban Poverty in the New
Millennium? Available from www.unhabitat.org/publication/slumreport.pdf
World Bank. 2003. World Development Report, Chapter 6: “Getting the Best from Cities.”
Available from http://econ.worldbank.org/files/17956_WDR_2003_chp_6_web.pdf
World Bank. 2001. “TN12 - Beyond poverty: Extreme poverty and social exclusion”,
Well-Being Measurement and Analysis Technical Notes. Available from
www.worldbank.org/poverty/strategies/srcbook/tn0619.zip
51