Asian Miracle PDF
Asian Miracle PDF
Asian Miracle PDF
44
L,' 1.
*tT*I
O'i;
EAi
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~4!~11
#Mk A C l.,
("'t
,,~~~
iXS4
.8e,.l.e
SHS'WlIF
'' I!WSbi7S'XtWs6Ni
it,;t4
4
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
NE
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1
~ ~~~~~~~~~.''
( rOS
Cll
f)
s~~~~~~~~~~~~F
grX~~~I
,0
:.;] IX
fib~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-
Lul=lpph.
Jakarta
;
*
_' d
;.
.r.
*NWLI
X\
I)
6S
-.MF
:6
C)~~~C
The
East Asian
Miracle
EconomicGrowth
and PublicPolicy
OxfordUniveirmPressw
OXFORD NEV YORK TORONTO
DELI BOMBaY CALC;UJrA MADRAS KARACHi
kUAA LUMPUR SINGAPORE HONG KONG TOKYO
NAIROBI DARES SALAAMCAPE TOWN
MELBOURNEAUCKLAND
andasidad
companiain
BERLINIBADAN
0 2993 7lmriarmnd
Ba&nkfor
Reomtruawn
wdDevaop mewl OPJE U'2LD HAAh
1818 H Sreet N.W.
Mathinog D.C 20433. USA
Pub hed by Oxfrd UniAnityPrs, fINC.
Drwmm&mc4
in any farm
rewonmg&
ore.z
se,iw
or by any meas,
merhank4
etvepdorpermrnuonfxf0uirdUriviy
Mamftiazdn
she Unisd
s
Fon paning&Spemner 1993
Ciogun
ph
l .woredina rrtrudqsfem
deamn,
/Ameria
pumwpy4
Prm
Rephfir
ofKar=cowty
resy
ofMatricrAiser.
At
ofJindre
&pjDA
The map
tnappars o n the izsiderova,
bok wsprqmred soyfortke
onvenie
Caragtoing-Publadon
Dar
Incdaw r
3uietpieal
ner
,IrN 0-19-5209934I
L. AsEa;rnee-Ecwmicpli
23. Asi Sawi&s-Ecenamicpole
L. WorldBank f. Se,ie
HC4625.A275 1.993
338.95-c20
tE a-Econidc cendo-,
4. Ask
CitiomS
9S33046&
ismv1G20-0851
Torprepaper
P1pfr1Jiwd
anom
MreLw
ialr
wf
Foreword
EBATESON THE APPROPRIATE ROLE OF PUBLIC POUCY IN
ch. appears
This volumeis the summary
arc
as the firstin a seriesof PolicyRcsearchReports,which intendedto
on developmentpolicy
bringto a broadaudiencethe resultsof research
issuescarriedoutbystaffof theWorldBank.Asreportson policyissues,
we intend that theyshouldhelp us to take-stockof what we know and
cIealy identifirwhat wedo not know;theyshouldcontribureto the debat in both the academicand poli-y communitieson appropriatepublic policy objectivesand instrumentsfor developingeconomies;and
Becausetheysunmarize rethey shouldbe accessibletX nonspecialiscs.
search,wealsoanticipatethat PolicyResearchReportswill provokefarther debate,bothwithinthe Bankand outside,concemingthemethods
usedand the conclusionsdrawn.
The reWhat doesthisreport tell us about the EastAsianmiracle?
seawhshowsthat most of EastAsiasextraordinarygrowthisdue cosuperior accumulation of physical and human capita. But these
economiesWerealso better able than most to allocatephysicaland
cies, leadingto both higheraccumulationand berter allocationof resources.While this condusionis not strikinglynew,it reinforcesother
rcsearchthat hassressed the essentialneed fordcvelopingeconomicsto
ger the policy fundamentals igIL The researchalso firther supports the
successor failureas thepoliciesthemselvcs,and the reportdcvotessubstantial artention to the institutional basesfor East Asi-a rapid growth.
vi
Lewis T. Preston
President
The World Bank
Augur 1993
vii
Contents
7TeRear
Team
xi
Ack3wwkdgmnae
xiii
Defmiufons
xv
8
23
27
70
79
87
105
ix
157
158
5 Strategiesfor RapidAccumulation
HighHumanCapitalForrnation
EastAsia's
Explaining
191
192
203
ExplainingEast Asia'sHigh SavingsRates
221
ExplainingEast Asia'sHigh Investment Rates
Appendix5.1:GrangerCausaliyTestsforSavings
RatesandGrowthRates
242
beween
Noteon theRelationship
Appendix5.2:Technical
245
InterestRatesandGrowth
Notes
255
6 UsingResourcesEfficienty:Relyingon
259
Madretsand Exports
259
Use
EfficientResource
EastAsiais
Explaining
261
UsingtheMarkenLaborMarketsin EastAsia
theMarkctFinancialMarketsandAllocation 273
Assisting
292
Policy
andIndustrial
MarketTrmde
UsingtheInternarional
Productiviy 316
ExportsIncreased
HowManufactured
Appendix6.1:TestingdheImpactofIndusaial
326
Change
Policyon Productivicy
berween
TFP
Appendix6.2:TestsoftheRelationship
337
ChangeandTradePolicies
342
Notes
7 Polices and Pragmatismin a ChangingWorld
ofRapidGrowdh-Gettingdhe
Foundations
347
Right
Fundamentals
352
toPromoteGrowdi
CreatingInstitutions
353
Intervening
in Markets
Note
368
Note
Bibligraphic
369
347
XI
Acknowledgments
REPARATION
OF THIS REPORTDREWON SLVERALOTHER RE-
...
Definitions
EconomyGroups
OR OPERATIONAL AND ANALYTICAL PURPOSES. THE WORLD
'V
Groups
-Anabtical
OR ANALYIICAL
PJRPOSES,
THISSTUDY
GROUPS
ECONOMIES
into severalregions,defined as fIllows
*High-perfirmingAsian economies(HPAEs),led byjapan, arc identified by severalcommon characteristics, such as very rapid export growth. The HPAESare subclassified roughly according to
the duration of their succcssfiulrecord of economic growth:
igersusuallyidentifiedas Hong Kong, thc Republic
TheF
:
of Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan, China, have been growing
rapidly for decadesand havejoined or approached the ranksof
high-income economies.
* The newly industrialidZWgeconomies (NIEs) are Indonesia,
Malaysia,and Thailand. They havejoined the group of HPAEs
more recently,within the last two decades.
.
vur
DataNotes
* Bilion is 1,000 million.
* Trillionis 1,000 billion.
- Dolars arecurrent U.S. dollarsunless otherwisespecifiecd.
* Growthratesarebasedon constant price dart
Historical data in this study may differ from those in other Bank
pubLicationsbecause of continuous updating as better data become
available,becauseof a changeto a new baseyear for constant pricedata,
or becauseof changesin economycompositionof income and analytimlgroups.
Acronymsand Initials
CPI
Consumerpriceindex
DFI
-n.
Overview: The
Making of a Miracle
RECORD OF HIGH AND
AST ASIA HAS A REMARKABLE
-- :
~~~~~~~~
1jRRL
CLE
_____
HPAEs
EastAsiawithoutHPAES
South Asbi
Midae EastandMeditermean..
Sub-SaharanAfrica
OECD ec__
5
2
3
4
GNPpercapit growthrate (percent)
andCarlbbean
LatinAmedcm
0
Singapore, and Taiwan, China-and rapid growth. And in part it refleas the belief of those involved with this study that the eight
economies do share some economic characteristics that set them apart
from most other developing economies.
Since 1960, the HPAEs have grown more rhan twice as fist as the rest
ofEast Asia, roughly three times as fast as Latin America and South Asia,
and five times faster than Sub-Sahann Africa. They also significandy
outperformed the industrial economies and the oil-rich Middle
East-North Africa region. Between 1960 and 1985, real income per
capita increased more than four times in Japan and the Four Tigers and
more than doubled in the Southeast Asian NEs (see figure 2). If growth
were randomly distmbuted, there is roughly one chance in ten thousand
that successwould have been so regionally concentrated.
The HPAEs have also been unusually successfiulat sharing the fiuits of
growth. Figure 3 shows the relationship between the growth of gross domestic product (GPD)per capita between 1965 and 1990 and changes in
the Gini coefficient, a statistical measure ofthe inequality ofincome distribution. The HPAEsenjoyed much higher per capicaincome growth at
the same time that income distribution improved by as much or more
than in other developing economic% with the exceptions of Korea and
Taiwan, Chna, which began with highly equal income distributions.
The HPAEs are the only economics that have high growth anddedining
2.
Singapore
Rep.of Korea
Japan
Matta
Lescotho
Egypt
CYPMUS
Gabon
Greece
Brazil
Syria
Portga
:wA
Malaysia
Yugoislavia
China
Thailand
__
__
Norway
Itay
__
~-.-.-.---
Spain
Israel
Jordan
___
Germnany..
Mexico
Pakistan
Colombia
UnitedStatbes
20:
.Middle
United Kingdom
-----
Venezuiela
Keniya
________-
-----
Philippines
,.-----.-----------..
.-.
-.
Peau
Argentina
Uganda___
India
Benin__
__
__
_
_
_
_
_
_
Senegal
Haiti
Uberla
Sudan
Somalia
I___
Zaire_
__
NIgerfia
Afghardstan
~-*
'~~~~~~~~Bottom20
Midi
CentralAfricanRepublic
Ghana
Guyana
..
-
___
Madagascar
.-
Chad__
Zambia
Angola_
Mozamibique
Kuwalt
H A s--
----
-------
__
-2.
__
Soarae:.
Summers and Heston (1988).
3
2
1.
PercentagechangeIn GDP
45
-RACLLE
----
0.2--------
RankingbyGIni coefficient1980
0Q15
0.05
--
U Middle thibd
A Least equal thlrd
------------
A Chilet
--
Brazil A
0-
.Rep-
of Korea
Argentina
40.05
______________
!Mexico
______A_Colom
Colombla
bia
Thailand
* Venela
.
* Philippines
__
.Taiwan.
China
_ _
_
Malaysia
Srigapore
Hong
Indonesa
Kong
-J1-
APeru
-0.20
0.03.
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
NYet:Figurc3plots the relationshipbcetwenaveragcper capit incomcgroth and changesin the decadeavege ofthc Gini cocfficientfim
rde 1960sto the 190s; a negativenumber indicatesthar incomebecumelss concentraredL
The decadeavcge is used becausedata areavailable
for different years in diffacmr conornies the decade average
fbr the 1960s begins with dat from 1965.
SowrerWorld Bankdam.
r1A!N.
-M IRACLE
Malaysiaduring their heavy and chemical indusrries drives, governments pulled back In Japan the Ministryof Financeacted as a checkon
the ability ofthe Minisrryof IntcrnationalTrade and Indusry to carry
out subsidypolicies,and in Indonesia and Thailand balanced budget
lawsand legislativeproceduresconstrained the scope for subsidies.Indeed, when selectiveinterventionshavc threatenedmacroeconomicstabilty, HPAE governmentshave consistentlycome down on the side of
prudent macroeconomicmanagement.Pricedistortionsarisingfrom selective interventionswere also less extreme than in many developing
economies.
In the newly industrializingeconomies of Southeast Asia, govemment interventionsplayed a much less prominent and frequently less
constructiverole in economic success,whileadherenceto policy findamentals remained importamt These economies'capacity to administer
and implementspecificinterventionsmay have been lessthan in NortheastAsia.Their rapid growth, moreover,has occurred in a very different
internationaleconomic environment from the one that Japan, Korea,
and Taiwan,China, encountered during their most rapid growth.Thus
the problem is not only to try to understandwhich specificpoliciesmay
havecontributed to growth, but also to understand the institutionaland
economiccircumstancesthat made them viable. Indeed, the experience
of the Southeast Asian economies, whose initial conditions parallel
thoseof many developingeconomiestoday,may prove to have more relevanceoutside the region than thar of Northeast Asia.
The book isorganizedas follows:chapter 1 describesthe distinguishing characteristicsof the East Asian economic mirade, rapid growth
with equity and uscs economic models to attempt to account for this
growth. Chapter 2 reviewspolicyexplanationsfor East Asia'seconomic
successand introducesthe frameworkthat wewill use throughout to explore dte relatonship berween public policy and economic growth.
Chapter 3 discussespragmatism and flexibilityin the formuation of
policiesthat led to two impormnt characteristicsof the HPAEs'economic
performance:macroeconomicstability and rapid growth of manufactured exports. Chapter 4 disLcusses
the role of institutions. Chaprer 5
looks at the role of public poliqc in the HPAEs' unusually rapid accurnulationof physicaland human capital,whilechapter 6 analyzesthe means
usedto achieveefficientallocationof resourcesand productivitygrowth.
Chapter 7, in condusion, assessesthe successof EastAsian policesand
their applicabiliy in a changingworld economy.The remainder of this
7
-' .--
IICACLE
TheEssence
oftheMiracle:
Rapid
Growth
withEquity
PublicPoliciesandGrowth
What was the role of public policy in helping the HPAEs to rapidly
accumulate human and physical capital and to allocate those resources to
high-yielding investments?Did policies assist in promoting rapid produc8
tivity growth?There are severalexplanationsfor EastAsiassuccess.Geography and culturewere dearly important; however,dthy do not entirely
account for the high-performingeconomies'success,as the presenceof
unsuccessfuleconomiesin the same regionattests.Among the varietyof
policy explanations,two broadviewshave emerged(seedcapter2).
Adherentsof the neoclassical
viewstressthe HPAEs'successin gettingthe
basicsright. They argue that the successfulAsian economieshave been
better than othersat providinga stablemacroeconomicenvironmentand
a reliablelegalframeworkto promote domesticand internationalcompetition. They also stress that the orientation of the HPAEs toward international trade and the absenceof price controlsand other distortionary
policieshave led to low relativeprice distortions.Investnents in people,
education,and health arelegitimateroles for govenrnment
in the neoclassicalframework,and its adherentsstressrhe importanceof human capital
in the HPAEs'success.
-4iE$AS,kAN
MIRACLE
In other instances,such as Singapore'sefflortto squeezeout labor-intensive industries by boosting wages,policieshave dearly backfired.Thus
neither view fiullyaccounts for East Asia'sphenomenal growth.
The Market-Frendly
View. In describing the policies associated with
government-business
deliberationcouncilsofJapanand Korea.The key
featureof each contest, however,is that the governmentdistributes
rewards-oftenaccessto caedit or foreignexchange-on the basisof
performance,whichthe governmentand competingfirmsmonitor.To
succeed,selectiveinterventionsmust be disciplinedby competitionvia
eithermarketsor contests.
Economiccontests,like all others,requirecompetentand impartial
referees-that is, strong institutions.Thus, a high-qualitycivilservice
that hasthe capacityto monitorperformanceand is insulatedfrompoliticalinterferenceis essentialto contest-based
competition.Of course,a
high-qualitycivilservicealsoaugmentsa government's
abilityto design
and implementnon-contest-based
policies.
Our frameworkis an effortto order and interpretinlformation.We
are not suggestngthat HPAE governmentsset out to achievethe functionsof growth.Rather,theyusedmultiple,shiftingpolicyinstruments
II
RAC
MIRACLE
LAN
in pursuit of more straiglhtforwardeconomic objectivessuch as macroeconomic stability,rapid export growth, and high savings. Pragmatic
flexibilityin the pursuir ofsuch objectives-the capacityand willingness
to changepolicies-is as much a hallmarkof the HPAEsasany singlepolicy instrument. This is well illustrated by the great variety of ways in
which the HPAEs achieved tvJ important objectives:macroeconomic
stabilityand rapid export growth (secchapter 3).
Achieving
Macroeconomic
StabiltyandExportGrowth
More than most developingeconomies,the HPAESwere characterized
by responsiblemacroeconomicmanagement.In parricular,they generally limited fiscal defcits to levels that could be prudently financed
without increasinginflationarypressuresand responded quicklywhen
fiscal pressureswere perceivedto building up. During the past thirty
years, annual inflation averaged approximately 9 percent in dtese
economies,comparedwith 18 percentin other low-and middle-income
economies.Becauseinflation was both moderate and prediaable, real
interest rateswerefar more stable than in other low-and middle-income
economies. Macroeconomic stability encouraged long-term planning
Building
theInstutional
Basis
forGrowth
Some economistsand politicalscientistshave argued chat the East
Asian miracleis due to the hiighqualityand authoritariannature of the
regionsinstitutions.They describeEastAsianpoliticalregimesas "developmental statee'in which powerfultechnocraticbureaucracies,shielded
from politicalpressure,deviseand implementwell-honedinterventions.
We believe developmentalstare modelsoverlook the central role of
government-privatesectorcooperation.Whle leadersof the HPAEshave
tended to be either authoritarian or paternalisdtithey have also been
willingto grant a voiceand genuineauthorityto a technocraticeliteand
key leadersof the privatesector. Unlike authoriruian leadersin many
other economies,leadersin the HPAEs realizedthat econornicdevelopment wasimpossiblewithoutcooperation(seechapter4).
ThePrinciple
ofShardGrowth.
To establishtheir legitimacyand win the
supportof the sociey at large,East Asian leadersestablished
the principle of shared growth, promising that as the economy expanded all
groupswould benefit.But sharinggrowth raisedcomplexcoordination
problems.First, leadershad to convinceeconomicelitesto supportprogrowth policies.Then they had to persuadethe elitesto sharethe benefits of growth with the middle class and the poor. Finally,to win the
cooperation of the middle classand the poor, the leadershad to show
them that they would indeed benefit from future growth.
Explicit mechanismswere used to demonstrate the intent that all
would have a shareof future wealth. Koreaand Taiwan,China, carried
out comprehensiveland reform programs;Indonesia usedrice and ferfilizerpricepoliciesto raiseruralincomes;Malaysiaintroducedexplict
wealth-sharingprogramsto improvethe lot of edtic Malaysrelativeto
'3
- IRfLMIRACLE
ofrisk(seechapter5).
and socialization
mandatorysavingsmechanisms,
Bilding Human
Capiti. The East Asian economieshad a head start in
sourceswere avilable per child. Limited public fimding of postsecondaryeducation focused on technical skills, and some HPAEs
importededucationalserviceson a largescale,particularlyin vocationally and technologically
sophisticateddiscplines.The result of these
inclinedhumancapitalbvewell1policieshasbeena broad,technically
-stited to rapideconomicdevelopment.
.IHPAE
educationpoliciesalsocontributedto moreequitableincome
distributions.To be sure, initialconditionshelpedto set up a virtuous
circle:initiallowinequalityin incomeand educationledto educational
I5
.:~~~~~~~~~~~~~~;n
11
:t4iSjA-N
MIRACLE
(seefigure4)
4)
andaSelected Eiconomies,19704
(se fiur
HPAEs
nisms to increase savings. Singapore and Taiwan, China, maintained unusually high public savings rates. Malaysia and Singapore compeled high
private savings rates dtrough mandatory provident fund contributions.
- -
Othor _
0
2.0
20
30
'Percenta,ge ar GDP
40
Nenar.Finlind,uds AustriaBthee
um.
Dcrnmark,
Finland,Fmncc,theE:ederol
Republicof Gcmanybebore
reunificaion,
Greece, Iceland,Iredand.Imly, LuxemNorny, Portugal.
bour, dte Netherlands,
Spain,Sweden,Switxrland,
and the
UnitedKingdom.'Orie indudesthese
&-veoping
cconomies:
ArgenonaBrazil,T
developin eColombia.
Carenina
SEl,
Chile,Cdlombia,COredivoire, Egyp4,
Ghana,India,Mexico,Morocco,
NiScria,
Pakistan,Pem,SriLnka, Turkey,
Urugua.
the
upEra
Urgan
y Ycnzuels
Venezuela.
the fone YugosIiaI
and Zaire
SawreuSummer
andHeson (199l).
I6
'Japan, Korea and Taiwan, China, all imposed stringent contrls and high
interest rates on loans for consumer items, and levied stiff taxes on socalled luxury consumption. Whether these more interventionist measures
to increase savings improved welfare is open to debat On one hand,
making consumers save when they would not have otherwise imposes a
welfare c -r. On the other, the benefits are apparent in the rapid growth of
these ecovomies. Savings, forced or not, generaed high payoffs based on
ivoring investmentand of policiesthat kept the reative pricesof capimalgoodslow,largelyby avoidinghigh tariffson importedcapitalgoods.
These fiundamentalpolicieshad an important impact on pnvate investment. Third and more controversial,most HPAEgovernrents held deposit and lending rates belowmarketdearing levels-a practicetermed
financialrepression.
Japan, Korea,Malaysia,Thailand, and Taiwan,China, had extended
periodsof mild financialrepression.To be sure, increasinginterestrates
from negativeto zero or mildlypositivereal rates and avoidingfluctuations (by avoiding unstable inflation)encouragesfinancialsavings.But
becausesavingsare nor very responsiveto marginal changesin positive
real interestrates, HPAEgovernmentswere able to mildlyrepressinterest
rateson depositswith a minimalimpact on savingsand to passthe lower
rates to finalborrowers Becausesaversweremostlyhouseholdsand borrowers were mostly firms, this resulted in a transfer of income from
householdsto firns and in a changein the form in which savingswere
held, from debt to corporateequity.
Holding down interest rares on loans increasesexcessdemand for
credit, which in turn leadsto rationingof credit by the governmentitselfor by privatesector banksworkingwith goverrunentguidance.This
heightensthe risk that capitalwillbe misallocated.Thus there is a tradeoff betweenthe possibleincreasein investmentand the risk that the increasedcapitalwill be badly invested.There is some evidencethat in
Japan, Korea,and Taiwan,China, govemmentsallocatedcredit to activities with high social returns, especiallyto exporcs.If this was the case,
there may have been benefiEsfrom mild financial repression and
government-ided allocation; mirroeconomic evidence from Japan
supports the view thar accessto governmentcredit increasedinvestment
(seechapter 6).
Generally, financial repression is associated with low economic
growth, especiallywhen realinterestratesare stronglynegative.But test
of the relationshipbetweeninterest rates and growth in Japan, Korea,
and Taiwan,China, do not show the negativerelationshipbetweeninterest rate repressionand growEhfound in cross-economycomparativ
studies (seechapter 5). Whilewe cannotestablishcondusivelythat mild
repression of interest rates at positive real levelsenhanced growth in
northeastAsia, it appaently did not inhibit it.
in the northeastemAsian tier,
Finally,some governments,especially
risksto the
haveencouragedinvestmentby spreadingprivateinvestmcent
'7
A?
m
vLRC
y
~~~~~~~~V. ZiN [.IA
RC
LE
s;~
-o
public In some economiesthe govern-mentownedor controlledthe intitutions providinginvestmentfunds,in others it offeredexplict credit
guarantees,and in sdll others it implictly guaranteedthe financal viability of promoted projects. Relationshipbankingby a variety of public
and privatebanking institutionsin Hong Kong,Japan, Korea,Malaysia,
Singapore,Thailand, and Taiwan,China, involvedthe bankingsectorin
the managementof troubled enterprises, increasingthe likelihoodof
creditor workouts.DirectEd-creditprogramsin Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, China, signalcddirectionsof governmentpolicyand providedimnplicit insuranceto private banks.
EffcientAllocationand Pmductity Change
Somepoliciesthar favoredaccumulationin the HPA,s,induding financial repression and the socializationand bounding of risk, could
haVeadversely
afFectedthe allocationof resources.Similarly,industrial
targetingcould have resulted in extensiverent-seekingand great ineffidency.Apparentlyrheydid not The allocadionalrulesfolowed by H4PAE
govemments-particularly the devicesusedto shift marekeincentives-are thereforeamong the mostcontroversialaspectsof the Eat Asiansuccessstory (seechaprer 6).
Like policies related ro accumulation, policies affecting allocation
and productiviy change fall into findamental and interventionistcategories.Labor marker policies tended to rely on fundamentals, using
the market and reinforcing irs fiexibility.In capital markets, governmentsintervened systematically,both to control interest rates and to
direct credit, but acted within a frameworkof carefulmonitoring and
generallylow subsidiesto borrowers.Trade policieshave indcudedsubstandalprotection of local manufacurs, but less than in most other
developing
countries; in addition, HPAEgovernmentsoffiet some disadvantagesof protection by activelysupporting exports. Finally,while
interventionsto support specificindustrieshave generallynot been successfil, the export-push straregyE-themix of fundamental and interventionist policies used to encourage rapid manufacured cxport
growth-has resulted in numerous benefirs,including more efficient
allocation,increasedacquisitionof foreignrechnology, and more rapid
productivitygrowth.
Feible LaborMarkets.Govenment roles in labor narketsin the successul Asian economies contrast sharply with the situation in most
I8
isACLWMIRACLE
z0
rRAA
CVLIACLE
East Asia'ssectoral policies were usually geared toward export performance, in contrast to the inward-oriented policies of less successful developing economies. Japan, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan, China, all
relied on economic performrancecriteria, usuallyexports, to judge success.
For example, in Taiwan, China, the government suspended domesticcontent requirements that interfered with the exports of foreign investors. In addition, sectoral policies were closely monitored and
frequently adjusted. Thus, many of East Asia's "industrial upgrading'
programs of the lare 1970s and early 1980s were substantially modified
or abandoned when they failed to produce satisfactory results. Using the
export rule meant that even programs of selective industrial promotion
were indirectly export promoting.
Manufacmred export growth also provided a powerfil mechanism
for technological upgrading in imperfect world technology markets. Because firms that export have greater access to best-practce technology,
there are both benefits to the enterprise and spilloversto the rest of the
economy that are not reflectedin market transactions. These informationreated extemalities are an imporrant source of rapid productiviy
growth. Both cross-economy evidence and more detailed studies at the
industry level in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, China, confirm the significance of exports to rapid productivity growth.
These experiencessuggest that economies that are making the transition from highly protectionist import-substitution regimes to more balanced incentives would benefit from combining import liberalization
with a strong commitment to exports and active export promotion, especially in those cases in which the pace of liberalization is moderate.
Policiesfor RapidGrowthin a
Changing
WorldEconomy
5 IT>71AT
levels of domestic savings, broadly based human capital, good macroeconomic management, and limited price distortions, there would have
been no basis for growth and no means by which the gains of rapid productvty change could have been realized. Policies to assist the financial
2-3
-XIAIEMI
RAC LE
sector capture nonfinancial savings and to increase household and corporate savings were cental. Acquisition of technology through openness
to direct fbreign investment and licensing were crucial to rapid productivity growth. Public investment complemented private investment and
increased its orientation to exporcs. Education policies stressed universal
primary schooling and improvements in quality at primary and secondary levels.
Second, very rapid growth of the type experienced by Japan, the Four
Tigers, and more recently the East Asian NIEs has at times benefited
from careful policy interventions. All interventions carry costs, either in
the direct fiscal costs of subsidies or forgone revenues, or the implicit
taxation of households and firms, for example, through tariffs or interest rate controls. Unlike many other governments that attempted such
interventions, HPAE governments generally held costs within welldefined limits. Thus, price distortions were mild, interest rare controls
used international interest rates as a benchmark, and cxplicitsubsidies
were kept within fiscally manageable bounds. Given the overriding importance ascribed to macroeconomic stability, interventions that becamnetoo cosdy or otherwise threatened stability were quickly modified
or abandoned.
Whether theseinterventions contributed to the rapid growth made possible by good fundamnentalsor detracted from it is the mosc difficult question we have attempted to answer.It is much easier to show that tie HPAEs
limited the costs and durtion of inappropriately chosen interventionsitself an impressive achievement-than to demonstrate condusively
that those interventions maintained for a long time accelerated growth.
Our assessment of three major uses of intervention is that promotion of
specific industries generally did not work and therefore holds litde
promise for other developing economies. Mild financial repression combined with directed credit has worked in certain situations but carries
high risk. Export-push strategies have been by far the most successfil
combination of fundamentals and policy interventions and hold the
most promise for other developing economies (chapter 7).
But are these approaches feasible in the early 1990s? While limited
repression of interest rates may have contributed to ovemll higher rates
of investment in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, China, these three northeastern economies undertook their initial growth spurts-and their
most sustained and forceful repression of interest rates-during a period
when it was possible for a developing economy to dose its financial mar24
Icetsto the outside world. Furthermore,strong bureaucraciesand a genemlclimate of government-privatesectorcooperation meant that their
restrictionson capitaloutflowswere more effectivethan similarrestrictions in many other economies.In today'sincreasinglyglobal economic
environment,fewgovernmentshavethe abilityor desireto closetheir financial markets. Indeed, many East Asian governments are in the
-proes of liberalizing restrictions on capital flows. In such circumstances,the scope for repressinginterest rateswithout provoling capital
flight is sharply narrowed.However,in some exceptionalinstances,very
mild financial repressionof short duration to increasecorporate equity
remainsa viableoptiOII. This has been the case in Malaysia,which has
wide open financial markets but nonethelesssucceededwith very mild
financialrepressionfor more than a year.
The export-push strategy appears to hold great promise for other
developingeconomies.But the conditions of market accessunder the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GArr), and odlier trading
arrangements,will hamper developingeconomies'use of policiesviewed
as unFairin major industrial-economymarkets.Subsidiesto exports and
directed-creditprograms linked to exports are not generallyconsistent
with the GATrand may therefore invite retaliation from trading partners. Furthermore, like financialrepression,thesehighly directed interventions require a high level of insttutional capacity now lacking in
most developingeconomies.Fortunately,many powerfulinstrumentsof
export promotion are nor only within the institutionalcapacityof many
developingeconomiesbut remain viable in today's economic environment. Creatinga free trade environmentfor exporters,providingfinance
and support servicesfor small and medium-sizeexporters, improving
trade-relatedaspects of the civil service,aggressivelycourting exportoriented direct foreigninvestmnent,
and focusinginfrastructureon areas
that encourageexportsare allattainablegoalsthat are unlikelyto provoke
oppositionfrom tradingpartners. Indeed,some or all of thesehave been
part of the export push in Indonesia, Malaysia,and Thailand. These
three economies,the most recent participantsin the "economicmirade,'
may show the way for the next generationof developingeconomiesto
followexport-pushstrategies.
'
_Ni1ACCLE
policies to achievethreecritical functions of growth: accumulation,allocation, and productivity ,rowrh. The sheer divenrsiyof these policies
precludesdrawingany simplelcssonsor makingany simplerecommendations, exccptperhapsthat pragmaticadherenceto the fundamentalsis
central to success.These market-orientedaspects of East Asia'sexperience can be recommendedw;ithfew reservations.More institutionally
demandingstrategieshave often filed in other settingsand they clearly
are not compatiblewith economic environmentswlherethe fuindamentals are not securelyin place.The use of contestsin Japan and Korearequired competenrand insularedcivil servants.In parts of Sub-Saharan
Africa and Latin .Amnerica,
and elsewherein Asia where such institutional conditions are lacking, activistgovernment involvementin the
economyhas usuallygone awry.So the fact that interventionswere an
element of some East Asian economies'successdoes not mean that they
should be attempted everywhere,nor should it be taken as an excuseto
postpone neededmarket-orientedrefonn.
The successof the HPAEsbroadensour understandingof the range of
policies that are consistent with rapid development. It also teaches us
that willingnessto experiment and to adapt policies to changing circumstancesisa key element in economicsuccess.In the followingchapters we explore more fully the contribution of fundamental and
interventionistpoliciesto East Asiis remark-able
growth, and the crucial
role that institutionshave playedin their evolutionand application.As
we shall see,maakinga miracle is no simplematter
Note
1.Japan, which has been firmlyin the ranks of indus-
trialeconomics
arguablyforallofthiscentury,mayat first
seemto be an inappropriatesubjectfor study.However
manyof the policyinstrumentsusedby theJapanesegovemmnentduring the period of rapid growth, 1950-73,
26
Thus, notwithsranting
Japan'slongerhistoryof modem
economicgrowrh,it may providesome usefulinsights
into the relationshipbetweenpublicpolicyandgrowth.
diversein natural resources,culmre, and political institutions. Japan, unlikethe others,wasalreadya relatively mature industrial economy at chebeginning of
the postvar period. Moreover,the eight differ in the
degree of government intervention in the economy
and the manner in which their leaders have shaped and implemented
poticies.Korean policymakers,for example,have intervenedheavilyin
industrial,labor, and credit markets,whilepolicymalers in Hong Kong
have been consistentlyhands-off.
Despite many differences,however,the eight economieshave much
in common. In a number of ways, their postwar experience distinguishesthem as a group. Their most obvious common characteristicis
their high averagerate of economic growth. During the same period,
incomeinequality has declined, sometimes dramatically.These two
outcomes-rapid growth and reduced inequality-are the defining
characteristicsof what has come to be known as rhe Easr Asian economic miracle.
The eight economies share six other characteristicschat set them
apart. Compared with most other developingeconomies,all have had:
* Morerapidoutputandproductivity growthinagriculture
- Higher rates of growthof manufactured exports
* Earlier and steeperdedines in ferility
* Higher growth rates of physicalcapital,supported by higher rates
of domesticsavings
a* IHigher initial levels and growth rates of human capital
LkkYI&CE
RapidandSustained
Economic
Gmwth
GROWTH,
EQUITY.
AND
ECONOOM
Rate,196085, andGDPperCapitaLevel,1960
Fhgure
1.1 GDPGrowth
CDPgrwth rate (percent, average, 1.960.85)
Taiwan,China i
~*Rep.f
*Rep.-f
'aHongKong
Kor
Ko
--
ma~~~~~aa
lballand 111i
hOOh8SIB*
i
2-----O----
-*--_
0 **.
*S
-2
......
-----
-PEs
*A
--
. ...
..-
-.
U HIgh4I.come
econondes
-* HPAEs
S Other developingecononies
*~~~~
.
0
0.2
I
III
0.6
038
0.4
elativepercapitaGDP,1960 (percentag of U.& GDPpercapita,1960)
1.0
1.2
DecliningIncomeInequaliyand ReducedPoverty
HPAES HAVE ALSOACHIEED UNUSUALLYLOW AND DE-
ATSIYA!SLAN. M I RAC L E
Sin.s .oret
6%-
6$|-
_.!._
._ d_>_______
~~~Singapore**
of Korea
*Mai*a.siaRep.
Taiwan, China
*Thland
Japa
4% -w*,*f
0%~~~~~
*.
4%-
-6%--
.4%
U High-Income economies
*HPAEs
a Otherdeveloping economies
!
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
TEM
1960670
identifies economies with high growth (GDP per capit greater than 4.0
percent) and low relative inequality (ratio of the income share of the top
quintile to that of the bottom quintile less than 10). There are 7 highgrowth, low-inequality economies. All of them are in East Asia; only
Malaysia, which has an indexcof inequality above 15, is exduded.
When the East Asian economies are divided by speed of growth, the
distribution of income is substantially more equal in the fast growers
(Birdsall and Sabot l993b). For the eighr HPAEs, rapid growth and declining inequality have been shared virtues, as comparisons over time of
equality and growth using Gini coefficients illustrate (see figure 3 in the
Overview). The developing HPAEs dearly outperform other middleincome economies in that they have both lower levels of inequality and
higher levelsofgrow&h Moreover, as figures Al .7-A1.9 at the end of the
chapter show, improvements in income distribution gmerally coincided
with periods of rapid growth.
30
EQUITY.
GROWTH.
AND ECONOX-rO
Figure1.3 Income
inequalitandGrowth
of GCP,1965!89
GOP
* Botswana
Rep.of Korea
7
Taiwan.China
Singapore*. Hoagon
' Gabon
----------
apan----------
.M
e Indonesie
:- Malaysia
i Th.lland
_ _ _ _
--
_*I
;___ Brazil
.
IItaly
* Austria
.Spain
o France
* Belgium
AuS ilia
United Kingdom
e Sri Lanka
* iine
Switzerland'
Ia Pakistan
Mec,
'0Kenya
.A.t--
*NeChIIe
*PBolivia
*
Bangladesh
Colombia
i*
* Venezuela
. India
lMalaw_
1-._
;.
Argenttna'j
*eruge!tn
- Coted'lvoErr
* Maurita
nia
*. Ghana
I
*
a Sudan
-1
--
. __--...
- .-
Za~~mbia
$_
10
15
20
25
30
I
35
40
45
IncomeInequality
N-et Incomeinequalityis measured
bythe radoof thcincomesharesof the richesc20pexnr andthe poorest20 percenrofthe popularion.
Sm:n. WorldBankdacaL
31
ECLE
Dynamic
Agricultural
Sectors
iYPICALLY,
AS AN ECONOMY DEVELOPS,AGRICULTURE'SSHARE
tof
he economy dedines. The six HPAEswith substantialagricultural sectors-Indonesia, Japan, Korea, alaysia,Thailand,
and Taiwan, China-have been mak-ingthis transirion more rapidly
than other developingeconomies.4 But the decline in the relativeimis not becauseagriculturehas lacked
portance of agricUlture in the HPAEs
dynamism.Acrossdevelopingregions,agriculture'sshare of output and
employment has declined most and fistest where agicultral output
and productvity have grown the rnost (see table 1.3). From 1965 to
1988, growth in both agricultnualoutput and agriculmtalproductvity
washigher in East Asiathan in other regions.Many factors contributed
to the successof agriculturein theseeconomies.Land reform (notablyin
Korea and Taiwan, China), agriculural extensionservices,reasonably
good fastructure (especiallyin the former Japanese colonies), and
heavyinvestmentsin rural areas(notablyin Indonesia) all helped.
East Asiangovernmentshave activelysupported agriculatralresearch
and extensionservicesto speed diffilsionof Green Revolutiontechnologies. Their substantial investments in irrigation and other rural infiastruct hastened adoption of high-yieldingvarieties,new crops, and
the use of manufacturedinputs, such as fertilizerand equipment, to cultivate dthne In Taiwan, China, during the 1950s, 45 percent of rhe
32
GROWTH,
EQUITY.-
AND ECCOiL
A&vnenq
PTerntage ofpoprdauion
below thepoverty line
F.rst
Last
year
yar
aAnge
Year
HPAEs"
Indonesia
Malaysia
Singapore-Thailand: `
197242
1973487
1972-82
1962-86
58
37
31
59
17
14
10
26
-41
--23
-21
-30
67.9
4.1
0.7
16.7
50
41
45
30
54
21
25
24
31
43
-29
-16
-19
1
-9
34
-9
23
27
-31
-10
:36.1
8.9
0.8 .
-3.1
311.4
.
6.6
26.5
3.9
30.0
22
0.
13.6
-56
-46
-71
-18
Ot,ers
:Bra4YAb
:Wolombia
:. CostaRica
C6reds'Iire
I-ndia
0 1960-80
-1971-88
197146.
1985-86-1
1972-83
Morocco-R;
Pikismn0;
.-. >
1970-84.
.
Sri-Laik
1962-84 .
1963-82
-43
;
54
37
25A
7.5
0.6
3.3
315.0
7.4
21.3.
.
4.1
29.6.
-15.7
-25
.6.4
1
:12..
-19
5
:NoeThiis ableuseseconomy-specificpovertylines
Officialorcommonlyusedpovertyrlineshavebeenusedwhenav2iblec In other
hasbeensetas 30 percentofean incomeor expeaditrc.Theenge of povertylincs,epressed in tems ofewendi. perhouseholdmemberandin tersofpursingpowrpari
(P) dollars,isapproximnatdy$3004S700aycarin1985ececptforCosaRic (S960),-Malaysia
(SI 420), ind Singapore(S860).Unlessothenise indicatd, the cble is basedon expexliure perhousehold.s
ember.
- - ----::-..
- a. Measures for thse enties useinmcmccAherthanexpenditure.
b.Mcasurs fir dtse entriesare by hhold
aier than by householdmemnber.
Smwz World
Bk
(1990b,tabics3.2 and 3.3).
C3SC5die poveyie
growth of agriculure was due to rising productivity, much of which resulted fiom government programs (see Ranis 1993).
Information on the allocation of public investment betveen rural
and urban regions is limited, and it is difficult to make good comparisons among economies, but available data suggest that the HPAEs have
allocated a lager share of their public investment to rural areas than did
other low- and middle-income economies. Of critical importance in this
respect has been the build-up of infrastructure-roads, bridges, transportation, electicity, water, and sanitation. Table 1.4 shows that there
has been a more even balance between rural and urban public investment in sanitationand water &cilities in Indonesia, Korea, and Thailand
than in other developing economies. The data on rural electrification
also suggest that the HPAEswith rural sectors have, on average, more effectively provided electricity to rural areas. Since the early 1980s, elec-
33
I :1R.ACLE
Table1.2 LifeExpectancy
at Birth,1960and1990
Lif expeeane,
:-&onoalrfreon
-;HPAEs-
1.990
:,--
HongKong
Indonesia
-K(orea,
Rep.of.
Malaysia
Singapor .
Nailand: - -:
Th:
birthnh
6a)
-1960
;-.
OtherAsW:
-Chin.
-: -
64
78
46
53
58
65
59
772
71
74
- 52
.68
.0
.62
-69
43
In&dia
.47
-Sub-SaharnAlea
.
Lad Ame7ia and Cribbean
:Low-Inome econom
58.
52
43
54
.s
-Middle-lacnc
ieconomies
-Industnaleamenimie
36
. 49
70.
6266
70
N- TAherCgionalpavsarweghreda.;
-tExdudes Chinaandndi:L
SountWorld Bankdra.t
--
77:.
tricity has been universally available in the rural areas of Korea and Taiwan, China. Malaysia and Thailand have made great strides in rural
electrification. Endonesiahas not done as well, but even there die relatve
disparity between the urban and rural sectors is smaller than the disparity in econorries with approximately the same per capita income (Bolivia and Liberia) or the same population (Brazil [see table 1.4]).
Table 13 GrowthRatesofAgculturalIncome,LaborForce,andSharein Output,1965488
(percent)
:,,-;,:
t
:'
-irc,--:
SouhAsa
asrArn
:~xree..LLL2jt....
198
41
22
Decline,Average
A
2.
~~c:~;'nA2,
34,.,
34
.;-:-;:e
196
,3
1965-88l.
:10"
21~~3
~..
anased'growth rv&eof
Atcrds
A'd'-:.-.:'..'
kiborfirce
'
:-t
34
S
t,i d
37
LO)
17
"
<2., 6 1.l9U.::
rru8,,,A
2.2
GROWTH.
EQUITY.
AND
ECC
y -
. -
. Watrr
- S- ti don
1-
101
102
113
S PA Es
Korea,Rep. of
;54
-26
Thailand
Indoncsia -168
OtcrAia
Latin America
SubS
- bnibwAfrica
:-
64.6
58
43
38.6
4665
30
Ur
: -:0: g 5-
Rura
39
85
10
55
78
:40
-OrhlerAsik:
:India, 1981
-S -Lakna,j982
LeninAme-ic
<25
35
-..
15
8
*~ArcndinaJ
1982Bolivia, 1981:
.. Bra;Ail,
1981
->95
72
Senegk1982
Soercertoppanel:
UNDP
^
*
~-;
5
9
>95
..........
:0 0- - :
:-.i
N
-~
19.
93.
86
83
20
:
;
.
('r
fariousyis);Bottompan. Muasii
~0~
.12
(1987)
.; -
..
3S
_RACLE
manufacured imports reduces thc domestic currency proceeds of agricultual exports. Industrial protection acts as a hidden tax on agrculture,
raising the price of agricultural inputs to subsidize industry. Figure 1.4 illustrates the lower taxation ofagriculture by contrasting three HPAEswith
large rural economies with three South Asian economies. Direct interventions include export taxes and price controls, while indirect interventions also take account of industrial protection policies and real exchange
rate overvaluation. Both Korea and Malaysia have substantially lover taxation of the agricultural sector than the cornparators, and in Korea the
Figue 1A Intervembon
andGmwt intheAgricultural
Sector
.7=,,,_T; r--,.
Rep.of Kore,
Malaysia
-------w------
Pakis-tn'
__.
K.
PSilippines
_,
.........
_. _---_
-.
_ _ +_
_ _ _-1_
_j___________________________
Sri lanka '::H-~
-60
-50
---
-'i-~~R
19709~~
1
j
. .
-40
-30
*;
__I___._________
30
40
50
-20 -10
0
10
20
Levelof piotection (percent)
:~~~I
60
Rep.
of Korea
alys
...
i -............
I
Thaland .
--
PsidalsiU
=96
___
____
i
___
~~~~~N1970s
3---197ks
I
k
I
PhEippines
Sour= Schiff(1993).
36
.~
~ ~~ ~ ~~
~~~
l_
~~~~~~~~~~
I
2
4
6
Agrutural growthmte (percent)
__
10
GROWTH.
EQUITY.
AND
EC_OO
RapidGrowth
of Exports
table 1.5). Beginningaround 1980, the three SoutheastAsianHPAEs (Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand), which had been historically dependent on commodity exports, recorded a sirnilar but so far smaller surge
in manufactured exports.
Some analysts have, with hindsight, attributed these achievements to
unique cultural and geographical circumstances. But there was litde evidence at the outset that East Asian economies would achieve such spectacular results. In the 1950s even trade optimists were export pessimists
and did not anticipate that Korea's exports would grow four times as fist
as world trade during the next thirty years (see, for example, little 1982).
One obvious efFec of rapid export growth has been a marked increase in the openness of thcse economies, the share of exports plus imports in GDP (see table 1.6). Malaysia has been heavily tade oriented
throughout its post-colonial history while Korea, Thailand, and Taiwan,
China,
37
I1RAc IrE
i965-90
SelectedEastAsianEcononies,
Table1.5 ExportPenetration,
Share in wuorldeports
Eeonq
-
:1965
1980
1965
-1.980
1990
9.0
6.7
2.4
-7
6.0
6.2
13.3
33.9
7.8
12A
18.2
198
100.0
12.2
100.0
NA
21.1
100.0
NA
56.3
100.0
NA
13.2
1.1
44.9
3.8
61.5
12.0
73.5
-Totalmg,parn
Japian
Fourflgcr-
5.0
-7.
NEs
SoutheastAsian
HPAE subtoalAll developing economies
World
:
Japan> -.
--
Fourr
--i
-Nor
2.2
-13.1
28.7
100.0
7.9
.242
100.0
=.- ;-
7.8
rsa
AIIdevc1opingeconomies
*Wodd
1.5
a-u.-:;
SoutieasAsian NIEsbHPArEsubtotal
*
3.8
1.5
1.5
0.1-
9.4A
11.1
100.0
11.
5.3
O
17.3
7.9
1.5
21.3
11.8
12.9
11.8 -
1;00.0
-100.0
14.-
48.6
100.0
100.0
100.0
NA
NA
NA
available.
NA-.Norapplicable.
-ai Republicof Korea.Hong Kong,Singapore.and Taiwan. China.
b. Indonesia.Mala a. anlThallu:xL
: ort U.N.Trade Systemsdarn.
w-ith its vast economy and only relatively recent export drive, is only
sightly above the world average but growing.
RapidDemographic
Transitions
THE
.1.
GROWTH,
EQUITY,
A-ND E
EO1970
HPA&
'Hong Kong.
Indonesia- .
-lorea,Rep. of:
Japan
Malysia
Singapore
-Taiwan,China
1980
1.50
0.25
- 0.32
0.19
0.89
'0.25
.1.00
2.12
3.70
-.0.53
0.95
1.52
0.46 :
0.63
1985-
1.988
1.78
2.82
-0.38
-0.42
:0.66
0.66
0.23
0.11
0.85 -1.09
-2.77
3.47
...0.82
0.90
049
0.44.
0.35
SubR
-SSI,arnAfr-k
- 0.24
: 0.30
5out6Asia
-;
; :; 0.17
-: .-;
A-men-Amc'sa
ad Caribbema 0.20
025
0.27
- -0.11
0.16
0.22
0.45
Th1ailand
0.28
0.19
.0.23
N..-eTotlrade .-valueofxportsandvalueofiimpomr
dividedbygrassdomesdc
-
During the period 1965-80, all the developing regions of the world
experienced a marked decline in crude death rates (see table 1.7). The decline in most economies was 30-40 percent and did not vary much
among regions. There was, however, substantial regional variation in the
extent to which declines in birth rates held in check the potentially explosivegrowth in population from the rapid mortality decreases. In SubSaharan Afriicaduring this period, the declines in birth rates were around
2-10 percent; in South Asia, 10-30 percent; and in Latin America,
3040 percent. The sharpest declines were in East Asia: 40-50 percent.
As a result, the rare of population growth declined in all the East
Asian economies, in some cases quite sharply. For example, in Korea it
fell from 2.6 percent a year in 1960-70 to 1. I percent in 1980-90; in
Hong Kong, from 2.5 to 1.4 percent; and in Thailand, from 3.1 to 1.8
percent. In Latin America, fertility dcdines were also sufficient to reduce
population growth rates, though generally not to the levels observed in
East Asia.-In South Asia the picture is mixed, with fertility declines sufficient to reduce the rate of population growth in Bangladesh but insufficient in Nepal or Pakistan. In Sub-Saharan Africa, the combination of
sharp declines in death rates and modest declines in birth rates resulted
in an acceleration of population growth-for example, in Ghana from
2.3 percent a year in 1960-70 to 3.4 percent in. 1980-90, and in Kenya
from 3.2 to 3.8 percent.
39
Table1.7 TheDemographic
Transition
(percent)
Changein
cr-de
-ange in
crude
birth
eadl
rante,
Eonomy
-
Aventgeannul
grovtt of
popadation
rate,
19650
1965-80
160-70
1980-90
--52
-40
-54.
-25
45
-54
-46
-58
-16
-30
2.5
2.1
2.6
2.8
2.3
3.1
1.4
1.8
1.1
2.6
2.2
1-.8
-31
-40
-33
-31
-36
-55
-50
-38
-2.8:3.3
2.9
3.8
2.2
2.0
2.3
2.7-
EaswAsia
* HongKong
Indoncsia
. Korea,Rep.of
Malaysia
Singapore
Thailand
-55
-
LatinAmen'ca
Bazil Mexico
Peru
Venezueda
Sub-Saaran
Afri-.
Ghana
Kenya
SierraLeone
-6
Tanzarta
SouthAj~a
Banglad
India
Nepal
.-Pakisran.
I
:-2
-3A-
-50
--29-
-3.2
-1.7
3.8
2.4
-2
-22
2.7
5.1
--33
2.5
2.3
-45
2.3 1
2.8
2.1
2.6
31
-27
-33
-13
-:
-13
-Nor avaibbk.So5Wrrw
WorldBa dara
23
-13:
-2
42
-43
--
:-
HighInvestment
andSavings
Rates
GROWTH,
EQUITY.
AND ECOQi
rowing from abroad as well, that is, with foreigners' savings. Even so, inadequate domestic savings will eventually pull down investment rates,
either direcdy or through constraints on the continued build-up of foreign liabilities, which must eventually be repaid firomdomestic savings.
Between 1960 and 1990, both savings and investment increased
markedlyin the HPAEs, outstripping -',e performanceof other developing regions (see figure 1.5). Savings rates in the developing HPAEswere
lower than in Latin America in 1965, but by 1990 they exceeded Latin
America's savings rates by almost 20 percentage points. Investmenc levels were about equal in Latin America and East Asia in 1965; by 1990
East Asia's investment rates were nearly double the average for Latin
America and substantially exceeded the rates for Scuth Asia and SubSaharan Africa. The HPAEsare the only group of developing economies
in which savings exceedsinvestment, making them exporters of capital.
When we compare the HPAEs individually to all 118 economies for
which investment data exist, the picrure is more complex (see figure
1.6). During the period 196045, the HPAEs' investment levels were in
Figure5 Savings
andInvestnent
as a Percentage
of GDP
Gross
domesticinvestrnt
Developing
HPAEs
LatinAmericaandCauibbecn
SouthAsla
Sub-Sahaan
Africa
Gross
domesticsawings
Developing
HPAEs_-_
_|
i .1-...-&----I --_____________________________
LatinAmericandCaribbean
SouthAsia
Africa
Sub-Sahoran
: - .
g.
e10
20
-30
40
4'
RAC L E
Level,
1960
andGDPperCapita
ofGDP,1960-1985,
InvestmentRateasa Pementage
Fgut 1.6 Average
AverageInvestmentrate (percentageof GOP,190-8S)
40
30-----
bnga*Japan
0 *Malaysia
Rep. of Korea
Talwan.Chilna
207
-6-- -
'.-
'
SXhalland
111gb-Income
economnies
* HPAEs
* Otherdevelopingeconomies
U
1'
0--
0.2
0.8
0.4
0.6
Relativeper capitaGDP(percentageof U.S. GDPpercapita, 1960)
N
Note.Regressionequation: 16085= 10.125+ 59.12ORCDP60-51.88IRGDP602.
.0
2.2
119: R2 = 0.295.
(12.593)
*(1383) (10-344)
Swrre: Summersand Heston (1991); Bam (I989): World Bluk dat.
.427
GROWTH.
EQUITY,
AND
Creating
HumanCapital
I-N
jA C L
EitACLE
Fgure17 PublicandPrivateInvestnent
Private Investment/GOP(percent)
25
.5
-D- HPAEs(excludingJapan)
Other LMlEs
0
1969
1974
1984
1979
1989
Public Investmfent/GDP
(percent)
20
------
5~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
10
-U111FPAEs(excluding Japan)
0
1969
II
' }
1974
~~~~i
;
1979
-4i
OtherLMIEs
I
1984
19
Note: LMIEs
= low- and middle-income cconomics.
So=eueWorld Bankdami.
GROWTH.
EQUITY.
AND ECC
Firm 1.8 Crss-Ecnony Regressin for Prmaiy Enrolment Rates, 1965 and 1987
Pdmatyenrollmentrates
140' - -
:120
120Brazil(108)
.. ......... .
ioo
.n lindonesia (1118V
[37.0] HongKong(106)
--
Singapore(1053
Rep.of Korea-(101)u
[29.2,1
. Malaysia(90)
Thailand(78) [17-9_
Brazil(103)
~~~~~~~~~~~~~[-7.5]
[21.9] *
HongKong(103)
[15.61
_-
Tbai95)
[7.01
8 [10.8]
Indopes15
72)1
-;
I60 ~
pesI5ji2y
d
-- _ _ _
*Bangladeh(4.9)
4-Palkistan (40) 6$2...........
1-24.5]
_Banigtadesh
'[8
,Pakistan
1965
40-its
(59)
(52)
[O79]1
-.
Lw
20--
250
500
750
. ------- 197---
.
1,750
2,000 2,250
500
U.S.dollar)
1,000
1*500
3,500
Nater Figures in parentheses arc enrollment rates brackretd numbers show rcsiduaLs
Sourre: Bchrnan and Schneider (1992).
continued very rapid growth. In part as a function of their success in increasing enrollment, the East Asian economies have also been faster to
dose the gap between male and female enrollments (see box 1.1).
A common, though imperfect measure of educational quality is expenditures per pupil. Between 1970 and 1989, real expenditures per
pupil at the primary level rose by 355 percent in Korea- In Mexico and
Kenya, expenditures rose by 64 and 38 percent, respectively,during the
same period, and in Pakistn expendituresrose by only 13 percent between 1970 and 1985 (Birdsall and Sabot 1993b). These dramatic differences reflect mosdy differential changes during the period in income
growth and in the number of children entering schools, both of which
favored the East Asian economies. A somewhat better measure of school
quality is the performance of children on tests of cognitive skills, standardized across economies. In the relatively few international comparisons available from such tests, East Asian children tend to perform
better than children from other developing regions-and even, recendy,
be'tter than children from high-income economies.' 0
45
& 4TIRACLE
Fimre
1.9
Cross-Economy
Regresin for SecondaryEnrollment
Rates,1965and1987
Secondaryenrollment rates
100
-.
,U
.
so
60
,|
',
-;
Rep.of Korea(88)
_-
Indonesia1
Bangladesh(13)
0- 2 1
akstan
250
500
*!k [19.1]
*Malaysla (28)
77--{
~ir3jidnf
Malaysia(59)
.119.5]
40
40~~~~~~~~
-..
Singapore(45)
_-
--
--
,~-
~slhailand
.-
9)
750
BraA
9*-[18.
ril3s
(28)
I
.BalI (16)f
(12)
>I
Rp're\35 --lt-
Bangadesh
(18)Ft8
119
1,750 2,000 2,'
Percpl
500
1000
1500
3,500
NomtFigures
in parentheses
arcenrollmentraes;bracketed
numbesshowv
residuals.
SeurceBhrman andSchneider(1992).
How much a childleams isalsoinfluencedby the nature of the leaming environmentin the childcshome-Again, children in the East Asian
economics had advantges in the 1970s and 1980s. Using a simple
index taking into account the mother's education and the number of
children at home, we estimate that the learing environment in Korea
during twenty yearswas enhanced 114 percent more than in Braziland
147 percentmore than in Pakistan (Birdsalland Sabot 1993b).
RapidPrdu
Growth
HE FINTAL
OUTSITANDING
CHARACTERISTIC
OF THE
HPAFsIS
46
GROWTH.
EQUITY,
AND:,F-COX0
rT-77
MT VT!"12
Ze.
w,Was-,FAA
,i Mz
11AAHI'..MRICALLY-k6---,----!:
eci c.- ene tv o cu!,adng:V
.9d.
es Lrsuto - oyt i'an
biin subiiiiia 7
4.
lop.1
o y a=,;-.,us ygra uaUj;'..'ib;gdsj gender'
J--Th
d
il
iffii:ntii
f6cyiii-,.,
aryan sc6ndzrj'k:&
-rnenriv
n";'evc
1.o-ca-d6i.
in
-1--'-'6d---'
c,-th ower
ataun.-..,,.-,,,to-aiaineas-incomesmaeast
----bf thi Aia tir).Ji-I 965i at c pd-n-.---yztdj,.,1mpr6ve,
I
the' 'c[
rnaryp_
c
ccorioriuq,-,gnder
V V
WM Swl"cr-,,E=ticxpected.,,-Bye'--HPAB_
e.--homm`e:gcn-':-'.,-',;;,'
'j!aI[70Wid-,i" The,,;,.t-',"Jt)r,outst
e,--.tlii
'1987'thi,&ur
jan!eqonoa,Lies-f6i.W.W&6ca.
pmg
ot er eV 0
aM
r; ;cconomjqs,' splteZwr'u''iat,norms-,,ttl2t.
put, greater--, achieveduniversaip6mary
cation
C, :r
Wqq01Lucation-ofs6diaahi,
tisci;
-Ov-iiiiirii'n'aungthe''gendir p-at'th'a-'t-1e'%'rib7SLLbi6iL
C
dau
-d6cationl.,
ii
ai
dvt:
I
gender-gaps,M'Mm um mtescontinik46"
C CXCCPtI0r4.-in-liow-tncom"C'
M
e; ra er.
SUCCCSS
0r-t1MVCrsJid[7-,
Is
PUS
7-,C ...
P-M
'. -,; Z:. - , 'yucauon
Sphe'
thi! m c3q%=ono e,,
qarrip
oni
ive4rgu -64c4,,th
f G61
:F6v
=&T.1fij,'-1991
S31S
7
lecon6nues, GNPpq.qLpibi
'$500'-%
-in
aTsmoolv -o
0'ff
m Miienr, etwccwiboys
as,'no-r4n
fs-,--=,a,
ges-2 6fita- i pio,in,
.AD"Mak-Yea 6f'Edudfialfl
IF.AJRL''
,i'.
10
-'.
E.
-;-
"
-, -
-.
- , --
-. 4.-, -"s.
I.
..........
Sl
t Ca-1r0m-1
64i
'I.
In!;1965,
-.44
nAmi
C5
70,
4-. -jk
Z.1
fi
r1;CTACLE
changeand technologicalcatchingup.
Regressions
Evidence
fromCross-Economy
of perCapitaIncomeGrowth
In this section we use two statistical techniques to examine the rela-
48
GROWTH,
EQUITY,
ANDE'CO.'i
M77 i 7,
x ,Zrl%evjc,;i-.Ii_-.Ip"-."_2__
)NOMISTS,
ROAD,
1-4
mmmenr
onj'am Murpur
-w-V
VC.'.
h
e --o
Flj
V4,1.
3K
umanan
er:
accumuw-
.,Jf.
ton;t,&I
3Vlcwlls"_b"l
_T'.
yIC
um2n ppi
ajt
rexten
-
ait
r=en
ini
p
nonluesiysi
&pfil&72ACt
irk*,
-o'wth' an
1.06
-,,-,,.amo4ccon6n3jcs_cr
ccononiic,_-or
".w
rz-k iE66-Er;
esame,
-4
assem-
MR
6i&bffinva=
nonuc-.,gr
P tLon
_-llFAE:fa
"d
gan,=qon;,-jnnovau
o ogyarc
o arm y.14666i
-0
'lik"
zin
iAiii '446
ccum non-,
ii'ibilbimer
vict-, ruo
ll,z,
Om
,p
gm.
2ssum
rec
(SOIW49-5.7)
LW2'CX
0 f -T,
P,P'.
v
coiiiii.econoun
r
Oj_
,-,'2ni
----
i=cs 0
-nu e-mcoifi
.. ........
economc
oil ficior-
Z.-
have
ccum
con-._t-,,, -,-tc
Y
"W o
lporpcmicnVor
Om
_9M
31i
cKami)
CoDrifth
M,
07Ww"Ah
cromki&m
Cj;V;.
aupajmong
J:i
onspi
de
-J
crcmeat&jj06,
er,
6ibasji-,tVoutpu poon
f
ItaL
econo
;_2
gt
_7
c
19P
'gro
0
.4;_
V4
OD
'p
t
Sd'
49
i-MIRACLE
L
':
--.
':~~~~~~r~
~i.
l'--'rr'
r:*rt
',,
,..
:.;,..:,,
?%e 7 aWe to acqwre technologyhniore~ =ie4iy; daiinical efnaen4 chan ge- Bo6htho y -andempi ic
prgres&more rapidlj than induiial-- economics. evidence:leadusto, ncludechat tol&cr prucK>Thisiis
thdeindusirialecmomiioicilrer
.
mov dc
radbe- up..
i"
a vy growthl
;
<
U-pnid4crrybasedcatcbiiig:
j--
r'BuLiiiwrnadbsn4a1 be
targetTow
i---
t. technologicacg
-nonal
t
e practic4Whileinflow-and middle-icome
.-di
OM '-Co
>~~~~~~~~~
"ltec-noloejcl
r
pracice,
whitWChe
temi
bcwce
slp
ni#eicrsKn
~do
O&
banmcemanon
iia bhs'd
4'
9; >.~movemenrs)owardbestphiice,whicWweolraech'-
-sc toieto, oc
Z =
g5wrkXChenry 1986;B.n an
192
m
-liI;pm~~~~~~n
a &uncV~A9)--4
i,
pendix
in resents acformiantan4is"oEfi rea~onow-bs
;
the-. m
iic
j(Pacad
l .nocr;
mov4iidj
-moIn
-. must
11993XForpductrv-
ccInomits, cam-b
occr,
Ass*
.:
on, 6te
gaicing
'lo-Cand
zzG*
.- Ceposk,iv---:
GROWTH,
EQUITY,
AND ECO:4I-
Table1.8Basic
Cross-Economy
Regression
Results
(dependent variable: average rate of realper capita income growth, 1960-85)
113
* Variable
O&Osedns
Inte'rcept
RelativeGDi' to U.S.,1960
Priuary enrollment,1960
Secondaryenrolmenr, 1960'
4).0070
(0.0079)
-0.04O
(0.0118)
-0.0034.
0.0264M
(0.0065)
0.0233
(0.0062)
(0.0075)
-0.0293~*-0.0320
(.15)(0.0110)
~
0.0262
* (0.0139)
113
obsenmign
0.1015,
(0.2255)
0.0578
(0.0224)
0.0160
0.0069
(0.0131).
~~~(0.2095)
0.0998
(.03
0.450.0285
(0.0211)
(0.02.07)
0.0201
-(0.0056)
*LatiAmrca
0.0272
(006)
(0.0132)-
0.0230
I{HPAFS'.
~~~~~~~113
obsen'aions
0.0042
.(0.0081)
0.0171
(0.0056)
t
*-0.0131
(0.0039)
Sub-aharan
Africae
Adusted
R.
0.0o9.oo
0.48211
0300424
~Stadrisda1y.signfl=wacrtiC
0.0f lVeL.
-'6.
nnsdca1y.sniflc~nt2tt die0.051V&
Nr:coefficlent is:top number in cachceIllStandard
crror is in p
crnhses
t.Also indiudeTun".isiand
South.AMica.
S6an WoildBanksnffcsdnnrcs.
dicredcontributiontogrowthofinvestment,humancapital,population
It alsoshowsthe share of acg'rowrh,and relativeincome for eac-hH-PAE.
tald growthpredictedby thesevariablestExcept for Hong Kong (44 percernt),60 percent or mare of the actual growth rate in the HPAESis
predicted by the accumul-ationof physicaland human capital,initial income levels,and population growth, ranging as high as 87 perce-ntfor
FML~"xN
I R-A-CL E
Table1.9 Coutnbution
of Accumulation
to theGmwthof theHPAEs,
196045
,~~~~~~~~~~mm
11os
-aaf hiv
Pear
*VWzh&
mlal
~40676
.
Ian~~~x - car
US.2560
-f-mapa,Imau
15%6
S
5
md
-cmXular
. 19S0i
- -:
Gcpq&u.n2104
GM*
AwpiPdUwunt
160.85
:~
AaW Ewd.A
- U6
P- M&
gn
F-
.X7e
4.030
O-.Jf
e.o2 0.1025
~~~~~J
-L0N12
Mg.
4270
.e70
-ISe
20o
0.3
0X3
lex57
JaUsihIa-
Iha
aeihsh
6
MlUe
uik(si
(.26)
{.Nz
(7)
(a5)
(231
s1) -.
(4)
-1q
--
-..
&vh
5W.
(rf-)
476
(.1)
402
wu78
-141
4 32
(.242
1.77
-9)
0.16
(7)
2
(16) 2.10
It1._D.108 {1918
5.7
223
w .
ral
prial
gush
69
2A
pdiicS
* .vAwM
.6
(vi
-- fa-d
PedSI
4710
.1.1
-2.16
.72
1.4
0.20
If-d
pen&tu
fl,.~A,
P0f +:'
rmd
ugaqh
pia
guhw.
4.151
(1
(sw
1421
(2l
(.1)la
M
=.6P
r_
5
4.69
s
473
-W48
(-191
17-191
(10
+X4
243
e, a19)
0.79
.4
1.40
Lin
--
30
(44)(
cmibdn
yr.
wpz.n
-:dbc
vacsylwdwwAaeesI
.iwnyim
XI
.pi
nbdal
enIa dwbEnul(nr
dc bienps.
flqnJul
rend Grcceyqlsdwwm
.m.bl-dn.
Second,we are also able to look for regional patterns in growth rates
that are unexplained by physicaland human capitl investment. Controlling for their performancein education and investment, and initial
income,the HIPAEshave a significantlyhigher rate of growth than all
other economies.Latin Americaand Sub-SaharanAfrica, in contrast,
have significantlylower underlyinggrowth rates (about 1 percent),controllingfor the same variables.Thus, the expectedgrowrh rate differential between the high-performing East Asian economies and
Sub-SaharanAfrica or Latin America,even if they had the same accumulation and initial income, is nearly3 percent.
To assessthe contribution of the HPAEs'superior accumulation relative to other groups, we can predict growth rates in four groups of
52
EQUITY.
GROWTH.
... P
-"I'
-. *
a.77
-X
:.f
..
QOb
'-;)-
0,0284:
- 0 ,- . 1141
25 .S
W;t2
0624
uJ
lwt
1473
'.;4
-. 57
13z
1;
Ax-
-; S
3.70
'-R'
.-
C.gi7
.(6)
(69'
(tv
-
fi)ls.
(36)
6.03
3310
638c
'(3m
3.45;SC e
j19J
i)
.0.7
(-4q
-2-
-. 70.
''
.fw
,^c>*d*.s_
-;,.,,.- .r.,
; ,-
.I .,
.=: '- i. ::, . :.
4.~~~'~
7
.L4
231;
04
Om
-~i
.Jimut.-
G-
p-
a('
die
442.
(.)3
ANDND
*rr
4NB
t 21)
Om72
.%t
oil
(231
MIS2s{
IA9
(431
au
151
IG
is more
telling
in the comparisons benweenEast Asia and Latin America or SubSaharanAfrica.Betweenthe HPAEsand LatinAmerica,34 percent of the
predicted difFerencein growth rates is due to higher investment levels
and 38 percent to higher carollment rates. Far and away the major difand Sub-SaharanAfrica
ferencein predictedgrowthrates btween HPABs
derivesfrom variationsin primary school enrollment rates.Investment
accountsfor only about 20 percent of the diflerenceand is offset by the
oonditionalconvergenceadvantageof Sub-SaharanAfrica and its more
rapid population growth. Educaion is the main theme of the story of
53
ACLE
Table1.10 Accounting
for Differences
inGrowthDueto Differences
in Accumultion:
TheHPAEs,
Latn America,Africa,andthe OECDEconomies
:
. . .:;
-:
ff
..Pa r -e .
twst
Ab~~~-
G4CPIZdISIW
I CtLS..9l60
IrInay.enmIm-.-. 1960
- r,tuy a9uIbnnv.1910
-
-- AI
;UAaSt
K-
--
.-
.lar
-013-
-.
Afie.41.
.
-0-
O.
..
Q25
-
iHr:E.
am. I.3
0*3 2
.0*015
M.U095
*73
.
-(.
2427
4003
.I3:
;~~~~
:
-
X4774
774
66
l
.-
:4o
.
*fa
-DiPkmr ad posh
-:w
et
40
Irk
dLmImtMIbimriu
tjwdkm3cW.rhto
hkm6dundanJSwhA-.
c
: ;--T M,mtilhedSehthcrCn.lnfoawsehnwairlEa
:.
Irk
nrlm
EbnkrX
,:
.wsqewmbldlucnlueln
DNbuuhudaSdnb.wbmebn&
54
O
OEC :AAim-0D
0a7m7
y
4tE574
-:D612
Aq.whFdpla.
156045
*-- PAEn
Dl.
39.--AS
- b- mtME
: -.
GROWTH,
iup,2
*~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
.ad
UFAA.
wu,f
t-
li2
..
pwe pfnwi
Rel-"
,s''0'
CM!
(11i2
fm.
3,0'..
130
0.2
.-
L9
9C1H
.
- -"' '';'
~~~~A4i.ORD
(;0)
AND ECONONIIMC
.,.
A.Mm
0.17
136)
EQUITY.
H -1,
.<
~~~~4.IM
rs
,,;:.-.
()
(4).
;-
(
4b
., ,h
M-. P11
-013
15i200
;
(I 4
2.32
to 11.S.
GDP,1960
Pmodndivty
Growth,1960489, andGDPperCapitaRelative
Figure1.10 TotalFadeor
1FPgrowth(percentparyear)
Taiwan.China
~~*Hong
Kong
*Rep. of Korea
*Japan
Thai!rd
3
2 -U
Indonsia*Malaysia
*5
-2~~~
-2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Ratioof GDPto U.S.GDP,1960
0.8
1.0
1.2
Source.WorldBankdama.
one-sector, cross-economy estimate will also contain an element of allocative efficiency; economiecschar allocate physical and human capitcal
to low-yielding investments will have low or negative estimat-ed TFP
growth .rates. The dclarest -demonstrations of this ane the thirtee-n economies with negative output growth. and positive accutmulation. Thus
our estimates of TEP growth answer the following question: on the basis
of the average efficiency with which physical and human capital are used
in the world economy, does accumulation over- or underpredict income
growth? The answer is that for most low- andt mididle-income
HPAEs it underpredicts.'
56
GROWTH.
EQUITY.
AND
ECONOMICC
to best practice between 1960 and 1989. To do this we assume that the
elasticities of output, which should be used to calculateTIP change,are
those that apply to high-income economies only. These more allocativelyefficienteconomieshave elasticitiesofoutput with respectto both
physical and human capital that are higher than those for the whole
cross-economysample. We subtmct the averagerate of TFP change for
the high-incomneeconomies, which we have associated with movements
in international best practice, from TFP change estimated using those
higher elasticities to get an estimate of technical efficiency change. Using
this metlhod, Hong Kong (2.0 percent); Japan (1.0 percent); Taiwan,
China (0.8 percent); and Thailand (0.1 percent) are the only HPAEs
catching up to international best practice. Korea (-0.2 percent) was essentially just keeping pace with technological progress in the highincome economies, while the investment-driven economies of
Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand were falling behind international
best practice ac rates of 1.2 percent (Indonesia) to 3.5 percent (Singapore) a year (see table A1.3 in appendix 1.1).
When the HPAEs are contasted with other developing regions, however, their ability to keep pace with intemational best practice seznms
somewhat more remarkable. Using the same method, we have estmated
rhe average rate of technical efficiency change for Latin America (-1.4
percent) and Sub-Saharan Africa (-3.5 percent). Against these benchmarks, all the HPAESexcept Singapore stand up well in their ability to
keep pace with the world's shifting technological frontier. 7
Although the absolute magnitude of TFP in HPAEs is higher, so is
growth. Is the proportion of growth due to TFP high? On the basis of an
analysis ofsources of growth forasample of economies, Chenery (1986)
devc-cped a typology of the contribution of TFPgrowih to total output
growth by income. A typical low- and middle-income economy had a
relatively small contribution of TFPgrowth to total output growth, between 10 and 20 percent. High-income economies, conversely, derived
about 30-50 percent of dteir total output growdt from TFPgrowdt.
Figure 1.11 largely confirms this pattern for low-, midcle-, and
high-income economies. Only seven of the fifty-nine non-HPAElowand middle-income economies have contributions of TFP growth exceeding 33 percent, while for the high-income economies it was much
higher. The HPAEs fill into two distinct groups: investment-driven and
productivity-driven economies. The investment-driven economiesIndonesia, Malaysia, and Singapore-conform to the developing-econ57
&EAAS4
ksA N M I RAC L E
Dueto
Growthand Part of Growth
Figure1.11 TotalFactorProducti
Gmwthof FactorInputs,196049
TFP Growth1960-89 percentpar yer)
,\
4.
4.
4
4.
'. 2966
.4
2
64
.4
.4
Hong Ki
.4
.4
.4.
Highincomeecon
-2
.4
N .4
om.
''
1E
4.__
*.
'
Note:Dashcd
line:s tcprcscnc:
*Ta"n.Ch1na
4.an
4.
3[
4.npan
'4
HPAEs
Othiordevelopingecornomles
.*
'2%'
4.
':
0%
D4
-4~~~~~~4
r _
0
4
4.
".
.4
4.
10%
s~~~~~~
' 8%
4
per year)
omy pattemnwithalowTFPcontriburion. Conversely,theproductvitydriven economies-Japan, Korea, Hong Kong, Tliailand, and Taiwan,
China-are more unusual and look-more like industrial economies,
~~~~~~~~~with
our previous findings with cross-economyregressions,that be-
Asiansuccessstor. But it
''- s8
is nor
the dom-inantfactor.
GROWTH,
EQUITY,
AND
,~~~~~~7
-:
-..- -1
;:.tc~~~~~CtW
,111a'S;!
Ati:wud-btcmle
dout.'i cosdeaontf,:
-, - - o- a~v>s i--
I;anoa45!"26
r-. i-.o;.
...- 7
'
,jp,
Y:
=;^
B-soxn TnheChnese M ac
EN.FECNMI(.;OWFI.'EAST..o;
lnim.est:-an-astoundiiien3-...
1 men
;--tic t
'@-'
;!.
smc
-
G..P..
17.ase
ii.
rkia
S
.
C6ns1ump'non.ldf-I
em
da
improvement:
e.-
-.
in
---on..of.m
4.
:-
op.
NO--.
ASSESSMENT
tECns-Ofi
OFapn=enGNOMiC
OdmsIlas
T
nvest aatu
n 30erearonspnit
su''
i y
-?-ea;.e;
.. -aea.
y
.n-ca...r o"'
.& ow.. ub
-b&&mpledy,tcu.wir-thourconsideadolsm.he
71- 1
4-49
f4..r.;
.
metZ' sinledo
17hasoa
see a 1978:t.v
lnlfunaln
akdimrvmnt
1, Asia.ewofd:
:. v_of e19i8_8 oft
t-,
- ,/~t.o.
g~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1gtCnM-;..
_..;ie-.t
ze. ^ ,5m ;9 ,P;A,E_
A
in
!-
mwlgg
-wcm<tj~
ra
.tame~~nt
pronne:
fyn
,
=-r {to 't;--'v
'-..
- a ->- gpal
x- i ..
>;
T
WrtL
.9.s
-~~~~~
Ghina's
-,: ;
-j
fsh
_.
-te.-
-; ,:gr.d.m7
-rpDi
gntao
wlde .a>mos',-s -o tuc,:2E,
- ;...s
_ JWiflg'staiildsgo
f
r. thia.za,utOr19
comaierdmds.
e.orublihgnedpopuation oFalleigh-sbonomf
mC
- l sour;& W:nimal2'peror inp
the
>
CWfiyP
w;
.i-heiAEwdbledYfroi
198
.
!,
,
:^W3- . ,-s
%AAuciMAdannbaawaL.I
4
.4<. . .;;>t;!-<,.+<-=.<-2.
.&zt
,'4-
be-at
termeo d an'
Jdp
'"-f
;!n
eo
government-fbszeehxci&
evemen
;'ba
and
..recorde.av-nna
gewdoflocDeta;ose
. Bt'.*.urdiW4oremteonents
d. GNPud
iesebqdir alsOna
't?
4'
>-.-
;i'9
slXRoiinsgwing
'g
gnll;6roucy
ar>a.a-.
lled,c-;l
non ti
tliey
ton'
'health,
and ie Cinacrnoeuhhiiiicsr.'bili'ty,
.,China --- ~~~gecrber
wdt
2 jrcenr
ihcreincrTpjancs
w.:erenr'n~lso0,o
:onowicjmeifChina
nuiFxceibk4f%lorX
televi ia ksit
?r 9.leibusexiosnS.-'
iScr&Did1t0
-r.carmEa-relm.t
.;:
eoetsn:
1d16&arnvtlper.
alddyinnually
ill
aulEzdiD
S
t- fro<i;vasmessof,CltinE.lIiaks
B-,
edswmgatn,oterenmdyrai&y.avo&hlltaed
ftrnEm
l ta baarmcsinvsted
T in.ms.
Uk8 Jx:o5
in 1990.-uds,-,
inXrw
nsip-nd
1u.4;>pcrct}en.~R-<t,;saviing
1979
Asih'soCre
H'Fi
growdi-n;
-t zessment
ass, tonenili7
ph-:h^S
'&rf or.ii iah&isi
Af&0MF1982wjt
198~Fo
bier-retreii.chmin
aeti~se.Czi
il
-~
'
-'n
8iehi
tharS.comc.cauamlgyihsEhEr
Droblcmanc.
rcM'4&44eii&
p
mg
3)1125
onpmentn,,T-i.rW
s
4-breald&&ckfTt2r|n
rapid
anL
ndshi
h~iidM suFpn4dealbi.tiowih
c
v-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~frerLNqs
gnrou,
, ,-wzA;
cottE
tro
{tsIea'te
Ex
St*n
ovr the Ian.1,!
,e5Lrv
Ttpo*k-^nm~uvcs
as
-- ixbiJqjig
n iY-.U:-.-e.,;nomy;Tas
-~ X-.-&WZ-
-Ci
-si
our-p
eee
e&oiiozfies
r
s, A
dof
high
terms
reductionsind ininequali
un rates
captala
a.nd~ W
...
DeoDkallewedEom
Dvmosmce-EF
ofsms
Ch-inniaksj
4.-
.:y~~~~
~~
&n2
flSnr
'.
tt
-ikA'r.-.--oer
oftheecopnomies in-inour
stud_
t_.h.._
i aeynwichiuecnvinwg
cmpa- od wheno %ro r
4-
ip
noive
wererrm
ar-:S,
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~p~~~~~~6~~~~--Ie
,sfxpd
p"-'u
-:
jDiledyLbr.i of
t,s.
-C$Qeiiid
oAtes
r..
nu"C-S
--. .
";- iebhn
comesstIi
tbknaii&
chea
ha
ghptr,wth
--
'
mb
et44 efiuiiveN~rpsgy grwhanx-du&v
aIst..aa'~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~5
r in achieving
Asianeconomxies'
success
We havedescribedtheEast
hlighrates of growth and redluctions in inequality- These were accompamied by-.agricultural
transbrmnaions,
rapid
fertility
dedinci, andmau
factured. export: growth; and accounted for by rapid accumulation of
physical'and human capital and by productivity growth. What policies
lie behind this success? In the next chapter, we examine alternative cx-.
.w
59
CLE
Appendxc
1.1:Accounting
forGrowth
IN
THISAPPENDIXWE BRIEFLY
DESCIBETHE METHODSUSEDTO
estimate the relationship between accumulation and growth using
both cross-economy and producton function methods. We also
compare our results with other resulrs available.
Cross-Econonm
Regressions
The cross-economy regressions employ the basic specification of
other cross-economy growth smudies(Barro 1991; Dc Long and Summers 1991; Dollar 1992):
(1.1)
GDPG= f(L
ED, LFG,RGDP6O)
where GDPG is the average rate of real per capita income growth using
Heston-Summers' measures from 1960 to 1985; INV is theaverage
share of investmenr in GDP for the period 1960-85; ED is a measure of
educational ataiunment LEG is the rate of growth of the economically
active population, and RGDP60is the relative gap between per capita income in 1960 (at 1980 U.S. dollar prices) and U.S. per capita income in
1960.'; Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) have recently demonstrated
that this specification corresponds to the transitional dynamics of an enhanced neodassical growth model with human capital.
Table Al. below reports our basic results on the relationship between accumulation and growth. The estmated equations compare fiavorably with other studies using similar specifications. The overall fir of
the regressions is good, and the coefficients of the variables are ofthe expected sign and are significant at conventional levels (0.05 level).' 9 We
have also estimated the basic relationship fir two subperiods, 1960-70
and 1970-85. The fit of the regression is markedly better in the earlier
6o
GROWTH.
EQUITY, AND,
TableA.1 Deterinants
ofGrowth
(dependent variable.-per capita CDPgrowtl)
Smp-pe
rio
196
Nwnberofobsennrtianr
-965
1413
Intercept-,
GDPrelativeto U.S
1960
.19160-70 1.970-85
.11.3
11.3
1960-5
61
-1960-85
-0.0070.
0.0064.
-.
-.
04
004
0.0243*
*(0.0079):
(0.0092)
:(0.0109),
(0.0113)
0.8):
(0.0094)
--0.0430"
:-0.0444*
-0.0422*
0.0408**
(0.018)
* Drw.xynrolircnt, 1960
0(0.0103146
0.0264*"
0.0169'
(0.0065) (0.076)
~Secondary
enrollment,1960
0.062
(0.0139)
16
0.0192
(0.01G2)
0.034"
0090
.:
. - -
.00578*
,
0.1153"'
~~~~(0.0224)
.(0.0260)
0.25
016)
0.09
.07
(0.0.192) -. (0.0180)
0.1015, 013
0.2738.
K ~~~~~(0.223)
(0.2592) 7(0.3083)
AverageInvestmendGD,.1960-85'
.196-55
5
.0.0247"*
0.0082)
0.03
0000)
of population,1960-85
-
-0.0292'
(0.0133)
.Educational
attimemnt,
1960
Grot
"98
-0.0450
0281
-0-3135'
(.251
0.086"
0.0201
(0.0309)
-0.0002
0.0013)
.-0.4290
(O.64
1'.-
(0.0245)-
Avrge'qupmentinvestment
* GD?,.1960-85
0.3100"
-0.3050"
(0.0721)
2
Adjusted
R
~~~0.3480 0.3424
0.1921
0.36
~
0,1893
(0.0743)
0.2614
Safl1ilM
sgtfintt the0.01II~
Staisdeallyiignicattth
0.5 lve
* Ne
Coffiien istopnumbermn
eachceIL.Smiinkdanirrris
in parahee
SOUIrcZWorld
Bankstaffestiniares.
investment share in GDPis replaced with the share of equipment investment, the explanatory power of the regression is improved, and the co-.
efficient on the share of equipmrent investment is highly significant. Our
sample size is much reduced, however, and we condude that the reduction iniresidual variance is not sufficient to justifyra change in our basic
specification'. Because school enrollment may not be a good indicator of
Gi
,*
C LE
1IRA
-----
Hong Kong*
*Taiwan; China
Rep.of Korea*:
*
0.02 -
I*
O002-
-0.04
indon
..
~~
ia
e ,
*Japan
ngpo
__
s*!
.halwidi
--*
- - --
''*'
H*
HPAEs
* OUuerd.velopIugeconomies
.0.06.
-15
-10
-5
0
5
Orthaganalcomponentof I/GDP,1960-85
i0
i5
Note:TheXand Ycomponents rc orriagouai on RGDPBO,PRIM60, and GPOPGO85,wherc RGDP = eal GDPpcr c2pim relativeco US.
GDcper capita, 1960; PRIM6o =primy
school enl]ncart am, 1960; G0PP6085 = grwh mre ofpopulatian, 1960-85.
SourccWodd Bank dat.
6z
20
GROWTH,
EQUITY,
AND
EGo
HowWeEstimate
TFPChange
Suppose that every economy has access to an international crosseconomyproduction function of the form:
(1.2)
Q =AF(K,E,L)
(1.3)
q--a
+ s k-l) +s (e-l)
where lowercaselettersindicaterates of changeand sAand sEare the dlasticities of output with respect to physical and human capital.The shamweightedgrowth rates of plhysicaland human capiml per head give the
contributionofaccumulationto growthin output per worker.TEPchange
can be then found as the residualof gowth of output per workerafterdeducting the contributionsof human and physicalcapitl accumulaton:
(1.4)
elasticiy co-
growth, and log labor growth during the 1960 to 1990 period,
constraining their coefficients to sum to unity (that is, specilig
the
RLIRACLE
to CapitalISKI,Labor(SL),
TableA1.2 Elasticity
of OutputwithRespect
Economies
andHumanCapital(SH):FullSampleandHigh-Income
Fullsample
2,093
High-incomeeconomics
Ruling
460:
rtaO
SL
(t-)m
(f-stat
0.178
10.895
0.669
6.411
0.154
1.49
0.399
10.237
0.332
1.679
0269
1.476
&ximafi r t HPAEs
toasaifacuerprodsadvi4ygtou*h
; - - - -Eonomy/region.
TFPrwsA
; ; -0t;t(filsa5Jmpk,
.
parpameer
Japan
3.6470
1.2543
3.4776
Kore,.Rep.of
3.1021
M2;ysia
sing2pore1
Taiwa,China -
1.0755
1.1911
3.7604
-ThaiLnd
2.4960-
Hong Kong
Indoncsia
~+ - ~0
LatinAmerica
~
--SSub-Sahv fric'
-0.9978
TFPwtb1
(ldg-im
v:j
ates)
.te
2.4113
-0.7953
1.4274
0.2355
-1.3369
-3.0112
1.2829
0.5466
0 0.1274;
a. Alsoincludes
TunisiaandSouthAfNic:Sor- World Binkda:L---
64
. SH
SK
Obsations
-0.9819
--3.0140
GROWTH.
EQUITY.
AND
ECONOlT
FigureA112Per CapitaOutputGrowth
andCapitalStockGrowth,
196089
Percapita output growth (percent)
Taiwan,China
*Rep.
of Korea__---i;
*Singapore
*S.ong Kong
Thailand
i @
*Japan
*MalaWsia-----'
, --------
Indonesia
is
MS
'-__
0-
2 26--~
- 4i t' ;
9---
--
Se S
Fl
0D
sa.k
Capita-growth
-pL_
et
----
.06@(2*
510
rwh
_
- _ _
N4igh-Income
economies
*NPA~~~~~~~~~~~~~
tes eelpn economies
1520
capita growth(percent)
--
High-Income
economiesGDPgrOwth= 0.010 + (0.395*K growth)
Fullsanuple;
GOPgrowth=0.0076.+ (0.23*K growth)
Soure.rWodd Bankdata
65
MA.-IvIR
AC LE
Figure
41.3 Compadson
ofTotalFactor
ProductiNt
Cmowth
Estmates
TFPgrowthcamparator
(percent)(Ella)
4.
0*
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Singapore
2-
Ohina*
-Taiwan.
0--
a Hwighicomneeconomies.
A
* Otherdeveloping
econiomies
-2 -----
-3
-2
4.
TechnicalPrmgress
andTechnical
Efficiency
Change
As we pointed out in the conduding section of chapter 1, it is difficult
to disentangle the relative contributions of allocative mistakes, technical
progres, arnd technological catch-up to rm'growth, especiallyin a crosseconomy, one-sector setidng.One way of separating the concepts of tech-
66
GROWT1,
EQUITY.
AND
ECCN
GrowthEstimaites
of TotalFactorProductivity
FigureAlA Comparison
lVP growthcomparator
(percent)(Fischer)
----
3 -- __
-3-*
-2 ---O
Ch_
,:in
I~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~awn
O-
~~ ~
~~
econoiesn
~~~~~~~~~~~
Hlg-,h4ncldoesau
of Korea
t.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Rp
Whetdevlfopingeconomies
/~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
-3
-2
-1.
1
0
growth.1960-89 (percent)
TiFP
Sources:
Fischer(199,3);World Bankdata.
model formally the relationship between observed output and bestprIacticetechnology;We address the relationshipbetween accumnulation,
productivity change, and growth using a simple neoclassical model.
Following Nishimizu and Page (1982), we define an internationlally
accessiblebest-pralcticeproduction function of the form
(1.5)
Qf(W-=F7(t#]t
where Qf(t)
is porential OUtpUt
F(.) satisfies
puts in natural units at time t. We assume that the frmncrionx
the usulalneodlassicalproperties and that an appropriate aggregate index
of OUtpUt exists.
The best-practice function defines the "stare of the art" in the sense
inputs
can.not
be
-67
MTRA CL E
mulation of inputs. The introduction and dissemination of new techniques move the best-practice frontier and is tchnological progress as
defined by Solow (1956). Observed performance in a sample of
economies or firms reveals that few are at best practice.2 1 Rather, most
-lie below the production frontier due to use of dominated techniques or
to inefficient use of best-practice tcchniques. Observed output Qfit) For
a vector of inputs Z(:) can be expressed as
(1.6)
Q4) = Q%ft)eu
(t)
ON,t) e u
(1.7)
Q (tOIQ( =
where F and Eare the output elasticities of F(Z(t);t) with respect to inputs Z4-) and timnce and dotted variables indicate time derivatives.
Output changes in cquation 1.7 are decomposed into three main
elements. The first one gives output changes due to input changes,
weighted by the elasticity of output with respect to each input. This
is the component of growdt due to accumulation. The second element is the rate of technological progress of the best-practice frontier,
and the last element, u-et), is technical efficiency change during
period t. While i; is always non-negative, u *t) can be either positive
or negative.
We define the rate of total flacor productivity change as the variation
in output nor explained by input changes. Thus for any observation, i:
Figure
A1.5 TheGrowth
of InpuisandOutputs
(1.8)
Output-labor
A-
:: fflz
qo
f- -0
68
_
S ;-
TFPJ(t)=
F+ u -(t).
GROWTH,
EQUITY,
AND. EC
sources of rapid catch-up in technologicallybackward economies.Industrial economies,which employ international best practice, are limited to rates of TFP change determined by the rate of technological
progress, zvi(t)= 0. Economies that do not employ best practioe can have
TFP growth rates exceeding the rate of technologicalprogress if technical
-efficiencychange is positive, icit) > 0. It is also possible for TFP change
to be negative, if technical efficiency change is negative and greater in
absolute value than technological progress. A rapid shift from average
practice to best practice-positive technical efficiency change-can provide a powerful engine of growth that is recorded as high rates of (TFP)
change.
There are two possible approaches to the estmation of the model
outlinecdabove. One wvouldbe to estimate the best-practice production
function aiLdderive estimates of both the rare of technological change
and the rate oftechnical efficiencychangc3 4 This approach is notsuited
to the cross-economy data available, and we do not employ it. An alternative is to measure TFP change direcdy by growth accounting. Since
measured TFPchange consists of both technological progress and technical efficiency change, we impose the strong assumption that technoTableA1.3 TechnicalEfficienq
logical change, the movement of best praaice, is constant and does not
ChangeEstimatesforthe HPAEs
2
5
I enbikid
vary across economies. Under this assumption all of the variance in
effdciency
rates of TFPchange derives from variance in the rate of technical effiw
-60-89
ciency change.
'
lkEcoJomylrqov/g t-.1960L9
HongKong
:
9714
We have argued, however, that allocative mistakes were partly reIndoneia
-1.2352'
sponsible for the low output elasticities in the cross-economy producJapan -.
9876.
ton function estimates. Hence the high estimated TrrPgrowth rates of
-0.2044
Ko Rep. of
those economieswith rnid factor accumulation may represent allocaCM
a~Mlaysia
1L7767-3;4510
Eive efficiencvmore than either technical progress and technical effi0.8431K Tanvan, China
ciency change. To address this we use the parameter estimates of the
high-income economy production function on the grounds that these
Thaiaind
0-OI67-i-t
LatinAmeca- -- i
:17
economies are the most allocatively efficient. We then sub tract from the
estimated TPP growth rate the average TFP growth for the high-income
SubSdiaAfi
34539, -j
economies, our estmate of technical change.: The residual estimate of
1
a.AI inudesi,Ttnisiada
..
.
tedical efficiency changeis presented for the iihPP and other regional
grouping in table Al .3.
-
-:~ 0 ::~ ~ ~
~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~6
MTRA CL E
1.2:'WhatDoTests
Appendix
SkillsShow?
of Cognitive
Tests provide a convenient quantitative measure of diflFerencesin performnance.By providing a consistent instrument, it is possible to compare the performance of students in different learning environments.
The key is objective versus subjective assessmenr. It is important, however, to recognize the weaknesses of standardized tests. First, rests evaluate only a limited range of skills, and there is no reason to be confident
that the mastery of skills tested is highly correlated with the mastery of
other skills that may also have an importnt influence on subsequent
productivity in the labor market. Second, tcsting skills, not just cognitive skills, may influence performance; if there is significant "reaching to
the test," both the predictive ability of test scores and levels of skill in
areasnor tested may fail. Differences in the curriculum may also account
for some of the observed differences in performance (see Hanushek and
Sabor 1991).
Tlhesecriticisms suggest thart whenever possible, evidence firoma variety of rests should be reviewed before reaching a general conlusion.
While internationally comparable test data are not abundant, they are,
however, consistent with the results already noted. Table Al .4 shows the
performance of thirteen-year-old students on a stndardized test of
ea;-.RpNewf wkC
N-w Bf`Ilik.
|^s m&mac!;,t,
,,,,m/nvnc
-Biish
,Irelirdant,
100--.
100 .5-
lh
;100
(Frenc)
J Onrado
.99
tquebe(Fwnch)
69
55
-
6-
8t
. 95;
95
92
two-step'
ab/s
:-78
Ar
- .-nria'
Udrtns
-o.c-ptP
p0kn
24-
- :-
78 -
e14
.
58
5
1
:4
12
.16-
3222
2
-.
18
-65
55
:::-87
70.
~100.
;
!
,'problems
100 ;a 98-.
JE~igIish~
.tg
simple
::and
-.
1
-*U
GROWTH.
EQUITY,
AND'E-
mathematicsadministeredby the EducationalTestingServicein a number of different economies, including Korea.2 6 Students from Korea
ranked first in cach of the five categoriesof problems.The performance
gap between Korean students and the others, all of whom were from
high-income economies, was greater for higher-order skills.
The International Association for the Evaluarion of Educational
Achievement also administered mathematics tests to thirteen-year-olds
in 1980-82 and included children from Hong Kong, Japan, and Thailand among the children from twenty economics in the sample. Figure
A1.6 summarizes the results for algebra,which are very similar to those
for arithmetic, geometry, and measuremenL Japanese students rankled
first, students fiom Hong Kong were in the top half of the distribution,
and students fiom Thailand -werenear the bottom, at about the same
level of performance as students fiom Nigeria.
FigureA1.6 TestScores e:: AlgebraTests:Selected Economies
Swazland
Luxenboug
Nigei
____
.-_______
Sweden
______
-.
Thailand
--
NowZealand
England and Wales
Canada(Ontado)
_;
UnitedStates
Scotland
Hong
Kong
Finland
Israel
_.
Canada(Br Columbia)
Belgium(French)
Hungary
____
Netherlands
_ __
____
Belghirn
_*- _
__
__
France
Japan
20
40
60
Mom score
80
100
7'
- M 1RACLE
Asia witl respect to rates of enrollment in basic education,Thai children also lagwith respectto levelsof cognitiveachievement.
FigureAL7 #-Lii
Coefficient
andCW perCapitaGrowth
Rate,1965-70
G1nlcoefficint
0.7
;-
-16--- .
'
~~~~
i Peru
* Gabon
L-eio
'Brazil
*Colonmbia
j
0.5
Venezuei au
,-
Chile
Malaysia
Sudanm
Sudanu
*lnldia
0.4A--4---
Singapore
U~~~~~~~
-~~~s~Phiil;Dlr
~
U Philoianes
-~-
EZamba
E Argentina
*SrlLankau
EHong Kang
N~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
ThailandI
*
Olcoe-
I * Pakistan '
TaIan, CaJapanU
Chinau
*Rek'rwa
X3---X--i
0.2-1
* O .
-0.01
SaurceWorld
72
-----
----
Bank darm.
0.01
'-----
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
GDP per capita growth rate
'
'
0.06
0.07
0.08
:~~~~~~~~~*
0.09
0.1
GROWTH,
EQUITY.
_|O
AND
-enya
EZambla
NCOI
IPeru
iBrazil
Nepal CWIie
MeVdcof
enezuela
*Malaysia
* Singapore
E~~~~~~~~~~~Horg
Kong
EPhillippines
I
it-OA
-
0.4j
, *ArgenU;tinda
,_,,_hdiaE
.:
Indong
Idnea
* Rep.of Korea
Taiwan,China.
------
1111halland
* Banfjadesh
*~ L.~
02
--1 --
--
|1apa--
0.2-h
.
0
-- ,
.0.04
-0.03
-0.02
-0.
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
0.07
0.08
73
MPI RACLE
EChile
XMexiao
Venezuela
!
0.4
Argentina*
. -
l-~----------EPeru-O
alyi
Peru-
- ;>
* Philippines
_-ngapore
Ehilane
EThailand
M Hong Kong
Rep.of KoreaU
0.3
--In-,donesiaE
r - _ --**Talwan.-China
-
I~~
.I
~ ~~~~~~
~~~
.-
'-
~~~~~~~~~~
.
U.1~~~~~~~
-0.02
-. 01
74
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
CDP per capitagrowth rate
0.05
0.06
0.07
0.08
AND
EQUITY.
GROWTH.
EC
1987
I
I
987
1965
di
E Indonesia
[-5,
~~~~~~~~~~-~~~~~~I
>-
*Pahistan
~~~~~[19.21
.-
maliand 1nd
%ralaysna
[-10.t6]
N
[5.1]
jRlof Korea
t as21 Singaporeu;
'A-ndnei
[8
\
I
^ Hong kng * \
-~~~~
,I
0
o
500
2,0070 2,750
P^ercapita Incomer(1958 U5S doflars)
2,50
14-31:3
[-2.2]
1,000
1,S0
3,500
-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~[22
EnroilmentRates,1965and 1987
Figure M41.1Cross-Economy
Regression
for GenderGapin Seconldaiy
.
6,
a
Figre 0
di
,,
1 ~~~~~~
[7-7]-
* -Rep.of KoreaK,
~-
~~~~1965
I,
.a,
*__Indonesia
E37o.'j].
At1
250
Soo
750
CosEnoIy
.L[.1, -
*-61
RersinfD
edrGpin 2,M5
:1,750 2,000
noletRts
SOD
eodr
1,000
1,500
30500
95ad
J-
1987
*P'akistani ,,
5ware.
S
Bdhmnanand Schncidkr(1992).
IndonesaKo3g.
913
~~ ~
~ ~ 29 P.r cap6a
residual
Not- F4urcs in brucker show
E
~~~~'Thailand
1h
laysa)
Mcame
US. do
PoakKontan
[-.2
18.2]I
-J~~~~~~~~~~~~~
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~16
.98
* 7077
E
Sn
apore__
N
Av~~~~~~~~~~~~26
1,750 2,000
0 250
750 500
Maayi
2,250
500~
~~~~~~~
1,003,0
~~~~~~
1,00
Per1.998
(In
capitaU.S.
Inconie
dollars)Kore
NateFigures
in~brackets
~show
residuals.
~ ~
Scarce
andBehaan
Schnidern(1992)
1[2.91
~ ~ ~~3.4
rigN~~~~~~~~7
SI
A~~~~~XRC L E
Notes
1. As we pointed out in the Ovcrview,a strong argument couldbc made for indudingChina amongthc "mirade econorniesof East Asia. We lhavenor done so for
three reasons: (a) China's recent very rapid growth has
been highlyregionallyconcentrated;(b) the experienceof
very rapid growth is more reccnt than in Japan and the
Four Tigers and than thar of Malaysiaand Thailand
among the southeast Asian NIEs;and (c)-and most
important-the nature of the economicpolicyframevwork
in China is sufficiendydifferent from that of thc other
eight economies,and is in such rapidflux, that it makesartempts to understandthe links bctwen public policyand
growchon a cross-economybasiseven moreproblematic.
We lookatsome aspectsof China's rapidgrowthin the rmair.der of the book but have not tEratcdit as systenatally as the other economies.
2. High-income economiesare defined according to
rclative incomie to the United States in 1960. They in-
76
GROWTH,
EQUITY.
ANND-EC
77
R.TE
record of rapid income growth and declining inequality described in chapter 1? Some
observers attribute success to geography
and culture rather than economic or other
policies. But geography and culture cannot
explain it all; East Asia indudes Myanmar and the Philippines as well as
the Republic of Korea and Malaysia. Nor is there a simple policy story.
Of the successful East Asian economies, Hong Kong and Thailand have
had relatively little activist intervention in economuicsectors by their
governments, while Korea and Malaysia have had a lot.
in this chaprer, after examining the significance of geography and
culture, we suggest a simple framework for understanding growth in
the eight HPAEs. This framework explicidtlyallows for diffcrenc, bur potentially successful, mixes of policies across time and across economies.
To set the stage for latef chapters, we then show how very different
policies can be used, if circumstances are propitious, to address the
three critical functions of economic management mentioned in chapter 1-accumulation of resources, efficient allocation of those resources, and productivity growth, that is, increasingly grearer output
for given resources.
How much of East Asia's success is due to geography, common cultural characteristics, and historical accidenit Certainly some-but definitely not all. Ready access to common sea lanes and relative
geographical proximity are the most obvious shared characreristics of
the successful Asian economies. East Asian economies havc dearly benefited from the kind of informal economic linkages geographic proximity encourages, induding trade and investment flows. For example,
79
S_
MIRWACLE
throughout Southeast Asia, ethnic Chinese drawing on a common cultural heritage have been active in trade and investment. Intraregional
cvnomic relationships date back many centuries to China's relations
with the kingdoms that became Cambodia, Japan, Korea, Laos, Myanmar, and Viet Nam.
In South and Soutleast Asia, Muslim traders sailed from India to
Java, landing to trade at points in between, for several hundred years
befre the arrival of European ships. Thus tribute missions and traditional trade networks, reinforced in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries by surges of emigration, have fostered elements of a common
trading culturc, including two lingua francas, Malay and Hokein Chinese, thar remain important in the region today.
In our own cenrury, key Asian ports were integrated into the emerging worid economic system as the result of European military and trade
expansion. Cheap ocean transport and shared historical experiencesfirther knit together a far-flung, culturally disparate region. U.S. assistance
in rebuilding Japan after World War 1i, followed by massive U.S. economic assistance and military spending in the region rbroughout the
cold war, also helped to set the stage for rapid gowth. Positdveimpacts
included enhanced security, which enabled governments not directly involved in the combat to focus on economic development Perhaps as important, the U.S. military's exensive purchases in Asia provided a ready
market for emerging export industries. Japanese industry receiveda substantial boost from the provisioning of U.S. troops in Korea; just as
some of Koreis biggest conglomerates got their start selling goods and
services to the U.S. nilitarv during the war in Vietnam.
Regional linkages fadilitated the adoption of imitative strategies, in
both public and private sector activity. Policy imitation-specifically of
Japans industrial strategy-was an explicit objective in Korea and
Malaysia. Korea borrowed Japanese rechniques for building large trading companies and directing the structure of industry; Malaysia focused first on developing heavy industry and more recendy on building
business-govcrnment relationships. Furthermore, the general model of
Japanese success undoubtedly impressed policnfakers throughout East
Asia, engendering a sense of confidence as well as providing models of
potential instruments of gowth.
Fmally, geographical proximity has facilitated capital flows, particularly in the past decade, as Northeast Asian manufacturers of laborintensive exports moved their fiictories south to take advantage of lower
80
PUBLIC
POLI
wages. A surge of inves-tment (since the real appreciation of the Japanese yen following the Plaza Accord)-flowing first from Japan and later
from Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan, China-has contributed significantly to the dynamism of Indonesia, Malaysia, and
Thailand. From the policy viewpoint, these linkages have been encoutaged by the generally liberal treatment of foreign investment But even
where foreign investment policies have been restrictive, informal credit
and information networks have helped investors to move capital rela-
tivelyfreely.
In addition tO direct linkages and imitation, East Asian economies
may have benefited from positive regional externalities. Through their
earlier trade with Japan, Western importers had become farmiliarwith
Asian business, established networks for sourcing East Asian products,
and gained respect for East Asian quality. Later, U.S. trade policies imposed quantitative restrictions on Japanese products and created rare
opportunities for other East Asian producers to enter international
markets. Producers of garments, shoes, television sets, automobiles,
and other products in Korea and Taiwan, China, took advantage of
these episodes to establish lucrative market positions (Petri 1988).
Of course, regional cl'2racteristics alone cannot account for East
Asia'sremarkable success. If geography, history, and culture were an adequate explanation, other economies would have little to learn from
Asia's success stories. Fortuntately evidence suggests that this is not the
case. Indeed, cconomies that are part of the same matrix of geography,
culture, and history as the HPAEs but followed different economic
policies-the Democratic People's Republic of Korea and the Philippines are two widely divergent examples-have yet to share in the East
Asian miracle. We turn, then, to the heart of this book, an examination
of the policies that have shaped East Asia's success.
PolicyExplanations
TEMPTS TO IDENTIFY THE POLICIES THAT HAVE CREATED
the East Asian economic miracle fall inco several broad categories. Below we present a summary of these, focusing on ihe
differences in interpretation that have arisen among observers confronted with the same set of economic facs.
-8i
SvA
MIRACLE
LSYXN
TheNeodassical
View
In the neoclassicalinterprectaionof EastAsia'ssuccess,the markettakes
center stagein economic lifeand governmentsplay a minor role. For eaample,Wolf (1988, p. 27) found it 'a strikingfact that the few relatively
successfuldeveloping [economies]-Hong Kong, Malaysia,Singaporc,
the Republicof Koreaand Taiwan,China-have greatlybenefited from
decisionsand policiesthat limit government'srole in economic decision
making, and insceadallow markecs--notwithstanding their imperfections and shortcomings-to exercisea decisiverole in determining resource allocation."Similarly,Chen (1979, pp. 183-84) argucd that in
Japan and the Four Tigers(Hong Kong, Korea,Singapore,and Taiwan,
China) state intervention was largelyabsent. "Wha. the state has provided is simply a suitable environmentfiorthe entrrc -ne.iursto perform
tieir functions."
-St
PUBLtC
P OTC
medium-scaleexportng industries.
Moreover, capital markets were not free in these three economies.
Proponents of the neodassicalview have focusedon the reduced inter-vention,particularly in the 1960s,that allowedreal interestrates to shift
from negative to positive levels (McKinnon 1973). Buitwhile intervennion declined, it nonethelesscontnuedL In fact, Japan, Korea, and to a
lesser extent Taiwan, China, did not rely solely on markets to allocate
savings. Rather, they repressed interesr rates and directed credit in order
to-guide investments.
-The revisionist view, proposed by Amsden (1989), Wade (1989,
1990), and others, sees market failures as pervasive and a justification for governments to lead the narket in crtidcalways In this view, the experi-ences of Japan, Korea,. and Taiwan, China, provide evidence that governments can foster growth by "goveriing miarker and "getting prices
83
; *
-1-
- RA:
-advantage,
~~~~~L
E
TheMarket-Fdendly
View
WorldDevlopment Report 1991 (World Bank 1991 b), in a comprehensive attempt to describe the policies needed for rapid growth, fallsin
the middle ground between the neoclassical and revisionist views. It
condudes that rapid growth is associated with effectdvebut carcfully deitarticasMarrkea-tendly"suategy
limited government aciivism. In the
lates (see box 2.1), not only do governments "need to do less in those
areas where markets work," namely the production sector, they also
"need to do more in those areas where markets cannot be relied upon"
(p. 9). The appropriate role of government in a market-friendly strategy
is to ensure adequate investments in people, provision of a competive
cdimate for enterprise, openness to international trade, and stable
macroeconomic management.
But beyond these roles, govemments are likely to do more harm hn
good.On the basis of an exhaustive review of the experience of most de-eloping economies, WorldDevelopment Report1991 condudes that in
-gneral governments have been unsuccessful in improving economic
performance through attempts to guide resource allocations by other
than market mechanisms. Attempts to guide resource allocation in
international trade, financial markets and labor markets have reduced
competitive discipline, guided resources into low-productivity and internationally uncompettive sector, and resulted in widespread rentseeking. In short, though market failure is an importrant impediment to
rapid growth, so is government failure-and governent failure can
have high costs.
A cental contribution of WorI Development Refort 1991 is the ar-gument that sustined growth :esults fiom the positive
interaction of
four critcal aspects of econoomic policjr macroeconomic stability,
4.4
PUBLIC
POLICY
AND
GROWTH
Box-2.1MakingtheMostofMarkets;
c
nged 'produ y. TeRepor'aenergkmdaiongeconomists
on the best approac' to .stressd at omesticpolCy. ou d epeennepre- economic dedoprnetn -. This zonsensus'was
dp
-.-...
cissed'az. ngth:in WoMDev p'nt Rport 1991 -provide die infasuucure- and institutions'-at will
The-TSChalnge
oDv
ne (WdrIdBaiik.1?
' r 1199
Ib). ,-h''help he respond.i_
The Repor+thighlightedte iportance of a helty-'
' Oprness to
ona tr
invesren
nd'
privarc:sector, which.-rss
m
investments in -ides has been cra in encouraging omnsticpo
,people,tamuchreduced role or.,goveiment, opedu-r' toucutrcostsbyw
inrdi
holopos-;:r
-,nessroXd,'o eom
ndvs w ) t
rds Ce,oft anddeveopingnewand tcerpruct. By' esame:
K'world;,and; macroeononmc-stability TIh~s'idcas -token,3protonSr
erc indusa
ol
-'''av c#lled
into;whAtis now cae te-hemark'
d6elom
decades.He
-gon
np
'
rv.m
rriLokvole. Injapan an.dKorea,foruinstace,gov~Y
-;appro&;
0'T eReporrcnotedtrhtareeconomicufronim.
ement :agen and-indut asaton
co' bot investng mi peopplcan be high,bur manygovern-. rate to gahier and. disseminate i:normationon:.-J,.
'no..ton]
ar
rd-'anddeop quaity control'Ibrp& t.. '
-ntarget thcir
snbapkpmropacrod
ecoanro,-in':',-Ale'rocr
micc foundtionoi. on ofthe
5 did'
Brazil2nd Pakistan,'f
alone
m,sost i
'
oosihagormenrs
OOpublic
ca
- derto; .unprovt.
hie sot
.rovide,- as th neotpule.ot
o. Wt%an
~fl indicators;i Ce.and
jamnaica,howevr
to c
CarS inprov eVe. i
mnt ocr
th
o
times,ofKislogw.wth..Governmentsmust ais
overspens,
Mr
terdui
senoonowinaj
st
'monetayryl
n fnniscordfiute,'
opnin
.-prov- th 4ini
fhes
To,
hled
by inflation,choni
i
'''o% pvisios,
o
for -recurrent: pen
are
' inadeof
y alssof
,thel
o 'p
? i,
quam
te rEsuldjiawasrefilu undemrutli2ation>
Thdeconomies
with a:bs-orof macn&o'c
u"r>
Motsessfuuonlei
nudhJai;Si-"
iaiitprruesleionthaiidd
ArgeCntn.'olivia
<
=ic salihdter~o
o'
m on
s~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~n
~~~iposr-,adoc~hv
-sf-tabedili
.y>ir iel
d
hnOh&nu~rj
IN-THE;AST;-TWEN
YYEASA
CONSENSUS.HA -;trenologi
'
9'
tt
'w
?P
.biddk'.b
>
'betarizlyo
opeoi)
humancapital CtiaaCion,
romnmenr
that encouragesprivate invrestmentand comjpetition. Effective
hrmation)
imprves.
. 'csumThe
marke-ffiencdly.
approach
Asia's
...
,,.
.-.
aspects
of Eastcr
Asia-ssuc=ss These
-,
captures important
X
' - ' ' 0'
v85,
*,~~~~~~~~~~~vr
high leves of human capital, are thorughly integrated into the world
tmc
ocure
economy, and have very high levels
of
competition among firms. Moreoe,East Asian success sometmsocurdin
spite of rather than be-
-NMultip
Pathsto Gmwth
As these three viewsshow,while it is easyto see how elementsof East
Asianexperiencecontributed to rapidgrowth, it is nor easvto identifyra
single recipefollowed across the region. An alternativeapproach is to
recognizethis diversityofpoliciesand to assesswhether and how various
mixes of policiescontributed to successfilimplementationof three central functions of economic management accumulation,allocation,and
productivitygroth. 4 Thi4s approach recognizesthat policies,like tac--tics, can and should vary depending on the situation, while the central
86-
PUBLIC
POLI
Th Functional
Growth
Frameworlk
_ IGURE 2.1 PORTRAYS THE FUNCTIONAL APPROACH TO UNDERstanding growth in the HPAEs The figure shows, in four columnns,
the interaction among two sets of policy choices (fiudamentals
and selective interventions); two methods of competiive discpline
(market and contest based); the three central fimctions of econonmic
87>
Apprachto G
Figure21 A Functional
:owh
Comnpetitive
discipline
Policychoices
Hihsa.g
macroeconomy
* Highhumancapital
MdHgll
andsecure
: Effective
Metetransti
financialsystems
Export
isin
Um.t-igpricedistortions
capital competiin
* Hlghhuman
Openness to foreign
It
SOpennessto foreign
*technolrtY
InsUtUdons
W
. _
* H gh-ualfty
laborrnart
_
>
Monitoring
on
Ilmestmrent
<
>Equal
Ineeme
Contest4edtu
clstributbon
*Export credit
. Reduced poverty
.
* Lfwestmnent
civil service
of
use
capital in.
~~~~~~human
credit-Reduceyfective
coordination
* Information
exchange
Productty change
* PmduftJvpbased
catchingup
R
Insulation
o Technocratic
0-
industalizadon
ron
* High reurts
Export push
vz Financial repression
* Seiectivem prormotion
rI\
* Directed cedit
I
agricultural
RFoapid
Alboatin
I
I
growthof
Rapid
ho
ai
Rad
transformation
I
~~~~~~~~~~~~~capital
SelectiveIntprventionsI
Rapiddemographic
: Directedcredit
:
capital
sustained growth
human
*Hg,aigsexports
Contit
~~~pollicis
Increasing
Domesc
AFicultuial depelopment
Rapidand
Accnnmulatn
Fundanmentabe
. Stable
Outcomes
Growthfunctions
-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
+_______________________.______________
tec_
Improving sorlal
inditrs
&
____
managemenrt and tie outcomes of growth and equity discussedin chapter 1. Institutions are also shown as critical to the sucossful definiton
and implementation of policies and to supportng high levels of com:pettive discipline.
The solid lines in the figure show how policy choices contributed to
outcomes via attainment of the three functions. Many policies, such as
high human capital and openness, contributed simultaneouslyto two or
three functions. For example, stable macroeconomic management contributed to vigorous accumulation through higher rates of investment
and to improved allocation by reducing instability in relative prices.
High and growing investmenEs in human capital contributed both to
accumulation, since human capital is an essential input to economic
grwth, and to productivity-based catchiing up by permiting better
nmasteryof technology. Effective and secure financial systems helped to
increasethe level of financial savings (accumulation) and channel it to
high-productivity investments (allocation). Limited price distortions,
by keeping domestic relative prices relatively dose to intrnational
-pices, were good for alloaton andmay have provided incenives for
88-
LI C7-:
:~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
:
firms to adopt technologiesand innovate. Openness to foreign rechnology was a major vehide for productivity-basedcatching up, and agricultural sector policies that promoted rural development were cental to
both growth and improveddistribution ofincome.
The arrows indicate that the system has numerous self-reinforcing
feedbacks.For example,rapid growthand relativelyequal income distributions contributed to the HPAEs' superior accumulation by increasing
savings-rates and generating largr and more efective investmentsin
human capital; they also contributed to superior allocation of human
capita by fostering labor mobility and marker determinaton of wages.
varying degrees of intensity to alter market incentives. The broadest inrervenrions were generous incentives for manuhactured cxports. (These
are discussed in some detail in chapter 3.) As part of this export push, all
the HPAESpermitted exporters automatic access to imported intermediare inputs ar intemational prices. Most also offered subsidized credit,
often performance-based, for exporters. In Hong Kong and Singapore,
Whereinternational prices guided the domestic economy, massive public housing programs helped to keep down labor costs. In Japan, Korea,
and Thailand, implicit or explicit export targets were used as the basis
for awarding access to foreign exchange, investment licenses, or credit
In Taiwan, China, large-scale public investments, induding in public
enterprises, along with extensive support senices to small and mediumsize exporters, were used to support the export drive.
Most HPAEs also controlled interest rameson deposits and bank lend-ing. These financially repressive policies enabled governments to ration
credit; favoring some would-be bonowers over others. In addition to the
importance of these directed-credit schemes to export promotion, some
governmentsalso directed credit to other activities, induding agriculT
ture, small and medinm-size enterprises, and, in Japan and Korea, largescale imvestments.
By intervening
-
in credit makets,
- - -
governments
- -
- .
~~~~~~~~~~
-
selectively promoted industries, ownership groaps, and, in some instances, individual firms. (These issues are analyzed in detail in chapters
5 and 6.) Some HP'AEchose very narrow promotion iargets. selectively
assisting knowledge- and capital-intensive industries and firms in hopes
of upgrading the economjs overl level of industrial technology: In
Japan andt Korea the governments at timnesconcentrated on promoting
private domestic investment in)heavy and c-hemicalindustries (Hcas).In
Ta-iwan,China (and to some extent in Indonesia), the public sector invested directly in technologically sophisticated industries. Singapore and
Thaiand have attempted to attract foreign investment in capita- and
knowledge-intensive sectors. Malaysia initially undiertook public investmenus in HCI firms but has recendly shifted to a strategy of promoting
private investmnentmore akin to that of japan and Korea.
Some selective interventions went beyond helping markets perform
better. Rather, theyrguided and in some cases even bypassed markets. In
the following section of this chapter, we explain why, in light of market
failures, some interventions make sense even within the neoclassical
framework. We then describe how some of the interventions undertaken by HPAEgovernments addressed these marker fihilures,effectively
(if not necessarily intentrionally) reducing the gap between social and
privat-egains.
MarketFailures:
TheCoordinatiom
Prohiem
A primary function of markets is coordination. The price systemnis a
mechanism by w-hich the production decisions of the myriad firms that
make up the economy are coordinated; for instance, they signal to intermediate goods producers what outputs are required by final goods producer.
Whe marets arc incomplete or missing. they cannot efn
this signaling function. Since the prices of outputs and inputs (including
wages) depend critically on what- other firms are doing, there ar-egreat
potential benefits ofsharing information. Even in well-developed market
economnies,information is conveyedi in many ways other than prices.
Tradejournals,tradeassociationmeehings,
and informationnewsletters
areal inportant minsitutions
for the trsnsmissionof informiation.
AdamSmiteHs
invisiblehand paradigr arguesohat achindcividual,
in
pussuinghis or her self-inters also maidmizesthe commonwelare;
cooperationis thereforeunne
lssary-In rafiutymoderneconomiesare
characterized
by extensivecooperation.Amongfirmsimeconomis that
'90
':belong to the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Develop-ment (OECD),for example,formal and informalsharing of information
is common. Cooperation among firms is maintained whenever the gains
from cooperating outweigh the gains fromi cheating. Coope-rativerelations are ensured because of benefits from maintaining a good reputation. If a firm lidls to cooperate, its reputation will be damaged, and
future business chat depends on its reputation will be lost.'
Institutional. arrangements for cooper-ation and information exchange in developing economics are weak-er than in industrial econominis,yet the needs for these forms of coordination are undoubtedly
gre'ater. When economic change is.siow, making predictions about future prices is relatively easy: a simple projection of the recent past will
do. But when economic change is rapid, predicting the future is much
more diffi'cult. There is often need for coordination. beyond what markers can provide; hence there may be a greater role for govermecnt to
create institutions and facilitate coordiination.
MissingInfonnatio and CreditMarkets. Among the markets most affectedi by information problemnsare capita markets. Even in industrial
economies, equity markers generally do not finance much new investment, largely because of information asymmetries (Stiglitz 1993a). In
economies where'equity markers are weak- or absent, credit mechanisms become the primary vehicle for raising capital and. diversifyring
and spreading risk- But credit markects-even those flee of interest rate
controls-are often characterized by credit rationing. Credit is seldom
allocated to the highest bidden. This is for an obvious reason: bidders
* are bidding promnises;those who bid the most may not be able to fulfill
teir promiss Lenders are concerned nor with the promised return
but the actual return. As a result, capital is allocated by a screening and
evaluation process that is quite different from the anonymnitythat characterizes resource allocation in an idealized marker.
In some oftdie IHPAEs,
governiments intervened aggressivelyto address
this problemnin the credit marker, going beyond the normal regulatory
functions and prudential supervision that help ensure consumer confidence. For example, in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, China, government
helped establish andt aggresively supported development banks and
other financial institutions,-and only later encouraged equity and bond
markets. In Japan a-ndKorea, government set up and managed directedcredit programs,.and through explicit and implicit guarantees or other
forms of interventions, reduced the risks borne by investors.
A'
ScaleEconmnies,
Externalities,
andCiooperation.
Coordination may yield
substantial benefits when large indivisibiliries in investment lead to
economniesof scale. One such case arises when investments are interdependenc. For example, if a steel plant and a steel-uising industry are
needed concurrently, it does nor pay to develop the plant unless there
is a steel-using industry, and it does nor pay to develop the steel-using
industry unless there is a plant. If each awaits the other, nothing happens. Market failures due to incomplete markets, such as the absence
of capital and risk markets, exacerbate thi~ssituation. With such largescale investments,
no single entrepreneur
PUBLI
Some
HPAEs
L14
0;
Cooperation raises severalproblems, however.First, cooperativebehavior may become collusion,if firms act together to raise prices. Sccornd,cooperation may inhibit competition,leading to managerialslack
or a more generallossof efficiency.Third, business-governmentcooperation may encouragefirms to seek &vorsfrom government.
How did the East Asian economies that encouraged cooperation
avoid theseproblems?They combined cooperativebehavior-indcluding
sharing of information among firms and betweenthe private and public
sectors, coordination of investment plans, and promotion of interdependent.investments-with competition by firms to meet well-defined
-conomicperformancecriteriaThey developedinstitutionalstructures
in which firms competed for valued economic prizes, such as accessto
- credit, in some dimensions while actively cooperating in others; in
short, they created contests (see box 2.2). Market-basedcompeiition
*and contest-basedcompetition both included prohibition of monopo
lies, although the number of competing firms was sometmes small.'
EventhoughJapanand Koreahavetended to have high levelsof consector (seetable 2.1), domestic comf centration in their manufacturing
petition has usually been vigorous. The Japanesc government has
proceeded-on the assumption that competition among fewer, more
evenlymatched firms is preferableto having one large firm competing
with many smaller rivals,a principle that is well-recognizedin athletic
- -competitions
Table2.1 Concentration
RtoinManufacturing
Ratiosm
in-
7%em0cewhflia-.
i8
K&R9:oi962A
56Z'.
4;
nI9
KBraz41980
AtiZN
'--
s4
.
(NalebuffadSii193.v
&
~~~~~~
93
C
-RCLE
R RA
j:~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~'t.'
..
'X47
,.'.
'-
Y'Oi'3m2Running
a Contest,
Rewais;,Ruies,n
. JT-H-lE,ECONOTC
CONASTS.IT
GOVERNMENTS.
-.>..;--:
'''.;
.Y
....
?Rdees
.. !.;,.
..............
e5..,|
1_...-
7
'caconomicpertormance,primarilawull arrl&hi'
base,however,these :-centere
coh:
montns
ies-. land somchmes
rcontestis,anddiir-role-mthe
economy resmble chl7-"
understoodd:mpcrauve
to ,expor; Referees,he gov-ren,sprc gaes
officials-wh&hbave
design'ed~andsprie
ti.- .O:ganiihgconrc
s ists a more pccaned way
to .
,ihetonresrs
t5m
-have:been
gFnerally
comperciuandfir.,
run!;a e:,oomv Esez-fi*i;
than,el:'i.i
r
r:i W.
, -jt a
.'
."'
. been
- economy
.L
rC nng.on
ssz-talre, justas
nA
same time,;parcipation has nortbeen ,;
-b'f , p
s
r
r:,Complcate,
anatoq.
c at prce cd
rrtosit
out'a, contest
g.
!
Thul
IC
ffi.l1iezi
dobeeni
phdinr
igo.; In some inpunished
nave not
etunga-hcxiuo
pAovA
KaA~ieana-p ayingfid
tnAy-fied,
L
both'vk. . -.-srancessuchas
Hondasshifr
toHau-;
l easc., i-fa
ie
-fi;
s;-l--vm1
*i*o
-*e-toau
ut7laeyp"'
and-u&ec"oplay
game,:e-. 6ioniobile'
maniffctrang
.at a time whenzfJapines
.p
ugb
pgarta
a well-mrri
:^Bu--a-wdll-run.contesr,
.: .
-
.''ernmenc
,,
s'
luce
i~
.-..offiaiaIs
consideredthe
eautnomotiv
fieldsatruraced th i
ffhtolerance
haspald offandsomely
ofz5nconfdrmss
P.;or iLn
0
- l,
m
.
.Cnet.
won't w
cvcryw
er,.4
, c:
-as..
mnzatr
onttr.
steprpoi
m o:dvec6mga.
lioihjmstances
6I
therearc.threcprerequisitesfor.. derainceot:uuois
mutts`tic
be reoo
econiorreine'tat:
tck.a.e
la'
r,,,veJ-.;l-st .ep.of~uak-clear orov
ec
0~~~~S
. success:~
; rewards,'rules,p
f -g _6 andr&rees.Rewairds
-r:- o-u-h/t
i-.; .eliit .broa'
.partiipationan
'r.ues.and,retre m
. M
e in
instirutions,anwith-strong
government
ebe
dearcut so -; economies
:Rulesr
.oCnbeutidon
eA&rt&c
k .iW
,vih:fehvllb
e
, >;6 otestu
'e-ing contst -.
becd.es hardea, fs growand ther,:
X
aidnducingpartipantsto
forcwii.c
peduiioh~nL
; cooper-!..
qX~~cop
ta es
.pnt
--icac:llE
CYb
'
-J
-wardedL-ahcL.
whih
puiserh'FnulyL_ a
+;:z
iy&.wardyAandL.who
ch -om1 b~c-punssned*powurncreascin
icladon to.tat othe bureaucur"acy
y
gamnes-- .:As Japaneseofficialswho ate nowjmoving4ay.fom.,
* . ay .w hsrneclespary
...
cmcal.
,knosi;cet,aieraare
.-
a morefinuonal
'conrescard
-: ;pevs
rel- ghavdicoverd.runmng
niz thed_`hi
:..cd
&h :pa1ntnzr
Uiildren-Si -9 ,lgdi.byrfessil'-- -peten'to!-W/nLZhaeFidZ...-.&voin.dow d,ild.
;. -w
pakygaineTor".
,C'r
scr
rum-t
-:
. :
_.
ow,
aWhile
eaprt credt schemesvariedwidely,all madecreditavailableto
~~~~~irms
with confirmed export orders. For many small and medium-scale
p-
ts
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~P
U B Lil-C.
'2
. - - -;
exports became a performancecriterion for projects that were not directly aimed at serving the export market. In these cases monitoring
problems were greater, since both export perfomnanceatid the related
projects needed to be monitored.
A second type of contest used the power of government to grant licenses.Table 2.2 shows two of these contests,based on Japaneseexperience. In the first, the Bank of Japan created a contest in which
commercial banks competed to provide financial servicesin line with
governmentpolicy-for exampic,by opening rural branches-in hopes
of winning highly sought-afterurban branch licenses.The contest also
gave banks a strong incentive to comply with technicallynonbinding
Table2.2 Examples
of Contests
-It.w*
d.t
_,p
Voooehaaniernaef
ndn
Noon ep..r1
7.1..,;:-:-.
-Ctnin.
t- niaja lmeroroulbe.C).
1. Nomadidnbvn
lndrnnpons Cnrsqjdknm spnenndmqr
UCaMmnd
MaIqt3 bonge po.lpmeoe u
an.tita,-vo'.4
~~~,;1*
io
an.
zb
.ed-
* 6 F-v, ;
ee.r
,e
,-ef ,
,inInn
pre
edm
,n
,pntoe
-;
nt,htMepmpm-
. *,
Oneith
'~~~~~~~
,s'.
obetves.deFl
t.,. ,- ..
.
.
'J
pei, l
I, ,
cmin
iR
...::............ :
',
gonuesu
eem ankmpnda-I
'.
7'-7''
"'.'
DOz
.
'4
...
'
-rr
'i
~~~~
.....
:C
'.-'''
4Z~-
CL{~,
:,7:
'
.j--g.
esnndafdSepne&u
.
AYf
'
.7
.g
..
'
'M
yoteJvbgrnnueppn.
,e-,:
. -.
'
UPbnie
n
'JI,
dkmi
.;-t
~~~~~~~~~~TegIdaPund.,,'-:'..'
-.
ea ditM in.
a(Ja
onSk-
Tuyo;e.ayMemrnao
-0pcmr'ti156
.''
.c
.. .r
. .
*tep
.w
dexpnplocmfpeypm
-&hudue
An
hymn
Muhinewrder Pamnodom
kfim
tow (194141
. '
a,nno
...
..-
: cadSwt-e
pnepnder-idsbanwud.......................r-hsnnnccenahe
is etttitre'-'-\
'>biw
.....
danh"okma
:--- - : - .
. o
'mut
hav
;seadeomnu
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~i~f
: C,
-:
Cana bob
ofkrlnnL,
7'_,>:
.
i1
es
*a-;k.
u
n-iai
.-
b.;-.. :
kl
~~~~~(siwtubmncnwCa)ocscaonI
t
''
.C
.,boglCaeg
<
n,
to.m
n
_.
at
a0
eX.einIses
lftvo.epena&f
<' iI1 mOtmuanmatipn- deump
- r.h
*11.CUU~~Lordto
RM11112NEW411W
unto
LC. &smk
C. -
to;Fctdmi
... .
,$
7hr.r
. :- -
I'
.9
-"
,.-.-7.
'.:
Ct~.
, :,:
-;5
RA C LE
'Table2.2 (contfinued)
IN-
JtrP o u a u h d S i d h m :~
lnabSInInxhlnhm.um
udncmhhAnadit
~~~~~~~~~~~~
44-.
Tiw hnk
k ufj p uimppnwkteu
m hatd mh uu m u
-,two?"
t~~~~~iflncrwimm"AS1
ain
ls
kMhlngaahmla.
Am* rudpmiadl
*
h~iwIUcDlvsnn
andvbmmrad. Miseh.a-.
lie. *.
~kiW*rnnd
~~~~Th
~~~~~~~~~~
I
A.)..
-...
. ..
(dr
I~
zdlIc.M
-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ko
rd
~~
.1
Iwam
-'hZ-
(1d
~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~d
iime
initu
cm mm, dwhmmsd&dtuW
Damrmguhcflsp-dykdLn
p"c
apwtnruaiiitli
uilidwaI
*lugemlmerpand
ammafc SlpI.nsio.la
dto mul.
~~bmm.Kq~
.1
;'L,
bmulmyrnL
rJrmmck
yKrjymn&
wte
d,nknm
o"
rW61
uhidgl*p*lluuca
ddrrtmu
aaa
aS .
ade
Nlazm afirms SsAflCs.
.,.
lca
PCf'Wi Wdurn
.. tmunymhiepiRaIMacMftWOI.
1
tapumumnnsuuchatmaecdlmsrniiza~~~rnaum..
.'Z
uilobmalbr
*1~~~~~~~~~~i
(C-
it.
-',
mapnhdma.*
'VJ
Mm*mm:armshV,.a
lafaryolavcn
ItS nheppamatn4talmUd.
tedon Amaik
Nandi ladmim'strativ.
'.
'"Mr
guidoMancemf
Cumitla
cm dehpmimmmihqClr3lesc-usuanmkn.y
hev-n
thcauirau
S
ulending
hniclidstis
banksotbar
failneydIm oco
90
pl
19
-s
admsinistrpatsivegudacpithei
of
ledig:bakthatwas
feqired
to complye
wirsthaguidaceiabou the spreatsdubetweedepositiand lni-rngrtes werenrepermitteorexpandt
t
thesepoir
brnhnewrs
(Yohin o19)
Duringtherapidgrothperiodthe acMtinsr ofdIneratonlt
Trad
andonduisrysal(Mrr lieamnsedIt
capacit
Thpasioin sevral keytibindu-t
deries-usueall heavycandichemicaldinduestiesgI
makt'hea195s ands1960s,
Dmflpimted entrydoandimrkestrce compewtinga
irmpworts. ofimin-the protected
ndustrywerereuireds toscordnaeivsmnstopeeta
pcsite expansion.1offupacit
ibutby
tyheeas equiedtn to ompete
796~
~
~~~~Frs
htrcie
etaprft
let
euaio"(us-et)wr
PUBLIC
POLI
0:
LVRcE
rttC
'~
''-~~~~~~~*
W;'X
'~t
~~~~~M
5
~R
l'i
zmo.g
irk'~~~~~~~~~~~~k
C}:*ahezspmrheJsccPIAaEasJencdtixar&icellzngSowoFuha*cm
YE;uats~amcRA
'n.amamiarllot
~"
~
~
p_no
u -~~~~~~~~~~~~s
: ~~~~~~
R
FrsRER>^*z.zbV.F
tioo
__tij.;!str*
f
~~~~~~~Isoii
^gg;2ii5X;t>
a~~~goyrmmen<
Eiwa
, -. -
ortherslP.asyV
S p8
or
amodo
Zsa&UO%%OOi5UDnaV3flCPeSw
9
,*>w~~~~M.14o<tjf, -- rSi,'22...{
V
reihogn.
.r emuncess,U
e Sz >o c uc nt areusofdlereamorun
.'-~~~~~~~
.'~4r~
,g
:
..
gs,s
-0
BB,..N.X>.^*,>t
lR
a*t;
*.co
S~~~
3 ncollnpSaEpovtcotowDhsnRneurApmanceMDo6luonsqo
t>;I:6Sy
p8~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~M
9s-
oXBg,.sp
ttXs
+;X:j
a~~~~~~~~~~~~
PUB LIC
PO LI C.YAbrD4rO
.99
RAC
LBE
trialpolicyinJapan,and in KoreaduringtheHCIdriveboththepolitical
and theeconomicadministrationmonitoredperformance.
leadership
The.Liits and CoustaintsofCootests
usedto promore
Whatdetermineswhethercontestscanbe effiecively
betterallocationand fitstergrowth?Thereappearto be two important
elementsthe relativebenefitsof coordinatedbehaviorand the institutional costs of implementingnonmarket,contest-baredcompeiitive
discipline.
Wherethe benefitsof coordinatedbehaviorarenot great-for example,in small,highlyopen economicswith goodentrepreneurialskills
and smallnontradedgoodssectors-the benefitsof coordinationof investment decisionsor sharingof informationare likelyto be small.
Internationalprices conveysufficientinfiormationfor marketsto be
efficient,and socialand privatereturnswillcoincide-This mayexplain
suchasHongKongand Singaporehavenot foundit worthwhyHPAEs
while to run contestsand establishthe types of highly structured
councils)foundin Japan
mechanisms(deliberative
information-sharing
and Korea,despite the high quality of their bureaucracies.
contests cithcr bave had poorly defined rules or have bcen bijacked by
-their pardicipants.
These nwofactors may also explain why the reliance on contest-based
- :competition may change over time in the samneeconomy. Box 2.4 docurnents the changing nature of industrial potigr in Japan, from selective
tOfunctional incentives and fiom extensive reliance on contests during
the rapid growth period tOmarket-based competiuon in the 1990s. In
-large
measure this is due to perceptions among poliyrnakers that the
large benefits from coordination characteristic of the rapid grwth pe.-
etdf6i-r.iu
4waiJ.wISYt~OFuOsDEt
;-
luc>S
;v,==auSmat
.
as<ol^
nuL.
e eonos(ni
or-moseb
thnoi tsucr-asi--.:o;
-- et"N'Vith.
^c.
"mtsincl-u)
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~&~iggmii
'
w3
m usgaousmfluestrXn^SDriomeg-w
98,'
yjmr&|w[1Sim;-W*t;S>-rt-4r4---R,-F,3
m&m
R ;uncustue,Xandh8D~silldadrmcdl
t n>-
~~~~
'
;;~-
'e
C q
8,'.
4,^_s 4~
H:
I-
g'4
g:(~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
t- sovv
inreqmnemure,nnn;otdaterneationalreemisvaiSSnieEt
i;>snonaerDqns
tua~an-dc
FSl.gr.-otXZ
^se-i>t>tzr~<<;Qv
-%w,7
-t4i
litel\97osaaI-S-lsineznotXiiaN
iM
w-t
g -;
zC
- )sD~~~~~~~
t->.<,<-3
; V ; <gX*
jb,
-vS
-iissS
--
%~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-Wr
gi
nnNaarnlnen,-\nttniioegn
cmPulnscV
a
ura.N-Udj#et.uiibyi
71 P1
2-.
l$stp;.,
,v-.v;
3 <m .
-s
lRitFl-r|J-t
LtR
9stX-lr
g2J;i-*;
-9Oro!E,
5fS=tX
fZpno;MTp
ZEnSLEool>qcao^adeeomnhpnhat
.>+; e 5s- ,>:~"rn|y;E>.fi#.ana
iC
g>z.
sF^
,>:*
3;is iR 9+j=,-t%rinz+mmal DoMan;.was~~~~~
sQaxoamolaI4- ~~~~~~~
mos<Xsor;cell!loLeaElDr-u=Es{
8 -u^'.^&a>
t J-8 *iX45rW .+5=i
9s.+N
$t05Ar
~
=>. >
'>4XAS-rW3^DRbRX
2*^t
ttti
>,==
84tSitt
Drexnod7sw;:nEnUte,uedM
ms;n.
iotlkhEdasaloyEt
~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~Pq
.
-g>l~-leimR^ow
f~~~~~~~~~~~1~l
i1L
:-~
'gS
95,>uW,-^Q*
Z,oAaodnra:$rDvdcpcyTa-ytt
5W.^grLtg'@eS=< @X<'
: i
Q.
a =
...............................
ut9.
|R
,e
'
%M
Br
Ostbrecnsructo,lSycmDeesacm
n ea
Rr".wrl,>,,oE.isi,4e,a.2*,sw044>
i'-z-'tt.Z'^:
[^sl^ttt>'}Y'-'^F4Ea
ngn
'-ru
le.d>ndu l
>i
=.E$*-.w'xjl2>(g,.<t,'.X>an
blcne
ncg4cot.2-Xti.>C{vlsgt/4't.
W
t
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~io
l*jE;^;s
>
coinasoofiie
-
->4n4:,.,-
Yu*
or
d-
ots
MI~RACLE
.;e xe_^,r,>,U.le.x-U..
-t
i,_
riod had diminished as-the economy grew and became more complex,
and that the insttutional costs of administering contes had increased
as power shifted from government admininstmraors
to enterprises. Simnilar
concerns appear to be driving recent changes in Korean industrial polices (Km and Leipziger 1993).
quality and limit political influence and corruption are the subject
of chapter 4. The second is the pragmatism and flexibilityof governments in the high-perfonning East Asian economies where contests
102
PUBLIC. PO'LICyA
Notes
1. Forgoodexamples,seeBalam(1982)
Bhgwvati(1978),
Krueger(1978),and Litle, Scitovsky,and ScoEr(1970).
2. Moreover,some of the measurespresenord,such as
those of Itoh and Kiyono(1988) for Japan, are probably
minimumestmates insofaras theircalculationsof efieclve
ratesof protection(Em's)arebasedon triffdata, not on estimatesof nominallevelsof protectionderivedfrom comparisonsofdomestc and internationalprias. On Korea,see
PadcandWcstphal (1986)andtherefrencrscitedthercin.
On Taiwan, China,see Wadc (1990). On Japan, see Itoh
and Klyono(1988).Wade doesnot presentor dceestimates
of effeciveratesof protectionin Taiwan,China,for the period afer 1969, while the other two presentevidenceon
ERPS
forjapan and Korea Conversely,Wadedoesoffercarefrfly documentedqualittivc evidenceofthe extentofselective intervention.Despite the frequent use of Taiwan,
China,as a modd of limitedintervention,thercareno estimatesof whichwe are awareof effectrive
ratesof protection
or dome resourcecostfor the periodafter1970.
3. See Yamawaki(1988) on the steel industry, Mutoh
(1988) on cars, Yamnazawa
(1988) on textiles,Yonezawa
(1988) on shipbuilding, and Tanaka (1988) on aluminum refining.
4. A formal expositionof this concept is containedin
R%gand Peuri(1993).
5.Popular discussionsof the successofJapan and severl other economiesof East Asiahavestressedthe cooperanve relations between government and business,
betweenworkersand cmployers,and among businesses.
This phenomenon is sometimes rerred to as 'Japan,
Inc." or "Malaysia,Inc," conveyingan impressionof a
single-mindeddirecrionto economicactivity,promoting
the collectiveinuerescsof the economy.Clearly,dtis popular imge caggeractes.Like all governments, governments in EastAsialack the control t cnforcea common
set of goals.
6. The list is by no meansexhaustive,nIordoes it indude examples of failed contests, of which there are
many.
7. See, for example,Kim and Leipziger(1993) for a
dicussion of the instiutional features of the Ha drive
and an evaluationof the successof the program.
8. Amsden (1989) in a seminal workloudines the nature of perfiormancecritera used in Japan and Korea to
disciplineinterventionistpolicies.
9. Again,this is perhaps not quite accurate;there may
be spillovcrsfrom Iarning how to produce some commodity morecheaply.
103
M4acroeconomnic
StabIlt
an
ort
ACROECONOMIC STABILiTYAND RAPID Ex-
Export push isa more complex phenomenon than macoeconomic stbility and the variety of policies used is greater. Mechanisms range from
broad, export-friendly measuressuch as avoiding an appreciated exchange
rate, which are esmployedin all the HPAEs,to government-mn export contests, which have been used primarilyin Japan, the Republic of Korea, and
Taiwan, China. Universal export incentives, such as tax breaks and credir
guarantees for all exporters, have been the main instruments in Hong
Kong Indonesia, Malaysia. Singapore, and Thailand. Despite this diversity of approach, as a group the HPAES
are unique among developing countries in the attention they havc devoted to export promotion and the
success they have achieved. The second half of this chapter reviews the
evolution of export-push policies in each of the HPAEs.
Pragmatic
Orthodoxy
in Macroeconomic
Management
ry"IHE
MACROEC'ON
exceedsthe South Asian averageof around 8 percent. Singaporehas consistendy avoided fiscal deficits,while Malaysia'sfiscal deficit peaked at
18 percent of GDP in 1982. Hong Kong,Singapore,and Taiwan, China,
-do not borrow abroad, while Korea was the worlds fourth biggest
-debtorin 1980 and Indonesia'sforeign debt tripled during the 1980s.
Exchangerate regimeshave varied from rigidlyfixedto managed floats.
Arnid the diversiy, however,are some common themes. While some
governmentshave run substantialdeficits,none has financeda deficitin
a manner that destabilizedthe economy.The level of the deficit that is
affordable,and hence nor destabilizing,is specificto eacheconomy.It is
generallylarger the faster the rate of growth and the larger the pool of
privatesavings(both at home and abroad)relativeto privateinvestment.
have perforned better than many
In both these dimensions, the HPAEs
of their developing-economycounterparts during the past thirty years.
Becauseof this, while some economieshave had higher inflation than
others, none has had to endure the very highi,debilitating inflation that
has troubled other developingeconomies.
The HPABs chose a varieryof macoeconomic policy paths becauseof
different economic conditions and preferences. All lay within the
bounds of prudent stabiliy, and wheneverthe macroeconomyappeared
to be in danger of movingout of control, swift action was taken to restore stability.This was true even when the source of macroeconomic
instability was policies intended to promote growth in the real economy.
Adhering
to Macroonomic
Fundameuias
In contast with many other developing economies, where boom-
and-bustcycles have
indicators,
macroeconomic stabiliy. This has been a potent encouragement for private savings, investment, exports, and growth, since the private sector
could count on relatively constant prices and interest rates. Here we
consider the HPAE's successfiulmanagement of four macroeconomic findarnentals budger deficits. inflation, external debt, and exchange rates.
The HPAES' budget deficitsare not
Budget
Deficits
Manageable.
Keepi.g
dramatically better as a group than other developing economies'. But
there are two distinctive things about the HPAEs. First, dtey almost always kept the deficit within the limits that could be financed without
macroeconomic destabilization. Second, these limits were higher than
in other developing economics because of the beneficial feedback fiom
other good policies.
International experience suggests that the macoeconomic consequences of pubLicscaor deficits depend on how they are financed. 2 Excessive monetary financing of deficits leads to inflation; heavy
govermnent domestic borrowing drives up interest rates and crowds out
private borrwing; large external financing of the deficit leads to debt
kept each type of financing within bounds, avoiding
aises The -PAFEs
the corresponding macroeconomic disease.
The means for restraining deficit financing have varied widely. Some
governments established institutional watchdogs, such as the currency
board in Singapore. Others took rule-based appmaches. such as Indonesias balanced budget law and Thailand's exchange rate management framework, which undl the early 1980s resembled a gold
standard. Sill others reed on the discretion of economic policymakers,
as evidenced by the macroeconomic adjustment process in Korea and
Malaysia.
Table 3.1 shows consolidated public sector deficits for the 1980s fbr
three HPAEsfor which there are good data compared with a sample of
OECDand developing econornies. As a percentage of GDP,Korea's budget deficits were below even the OECD average. This helps explain why
Korea was able to keep inflation, extrnal borrowing and interest rates
within bounds. Malaysia and Thailand are more complicated. Thaieconomies in
lands budget deficits were about average for devdopi
the 1980s, while Malaysiaiswere substantally bigger than average. Both
ran bigger budget deficits than such troubled economies as Argentina,
Brazil, Mexico, and the Philippines. Unlike these and other economies
that encountered difficulties, however, Malaysia and Thailand successfully financed their deficits.This was possible for the foilowing reasons:
io08
MACROE.ON-O,
Table3.1 Consolidated
Public
SectorDeficits,
Selected
EastAsian
andOtherEconomies
pliRaikmo
-Averag
*Eir .,~ ~
1^89
Korea,Rep.of
;Mn.Iaysia
-nd e
;u0
10980'
5,8023
.*
.$Thai
ng
4O
def20tcii
pcet
0>;0vj6wP
dkevelpngncotrnries
'age:
-.
:
-gi
^.
ofDP~
D,a9r
'980-88; .(
(I
ehi
4stefx)
~~~~O .,
-.
.
'
034-
6.39,
Auemge~~~
-viag. OECDeronomnies- :
2.82
:.
-- Oderieconomi&
~~ Az~~cndna
~~9.62-
.BIUI
:4.02Yhilippines
Sewtcasticr1y
Rdgc
~~~~~z.4.30
-and S
Hcbbdl
-
(lirrhcomi-g).
~~~~~~~LE
C L E-
_~~~~~rIR
- -
Table32 InflationRates
-
Aveiag;'
*Econonre
tt96iAOi
75
,.- HPAt.
Hong
1'
.ong
tjQAKorei~iRe~of
&z^4J,l
.;
8.8
1^2.2 Athe
-I i ,
$3
-;
--..
6 > :;.
-
M-%
lie-.............
:.
-
.A
~
2005l|wzX,
^ .
* i s .>^7^
-1.1
- - -:
MiK&
i
__*>'1120Z:
no.
ld^y^ l
0.$g11i;ES
MACRQ ECON~
;:.~~~~~~~~~~~~~I
I: asa Percentage
Figure
3.1 Revenues
fromMoney
Creation
ofGDP.Examples
fromEastAsiaandOther
Selected
Economies
(Percent)
4
4
12 -
:: ..10
iMalayhia
IIa-
-a
~~~~~Thafland
Rep.of Komea
1970
1972
8
2
190
12-
22
NReene
ie
-
1974
1976
1978
1976
194
iw moe c:ato
ZaireM
Arge.tnna
10 -
198
1378f-
Ji a pecng
2982
988
1986
M2fy1984
-sde
afined
asroo
oaIl
-2_
1986
198.2-
1980
of G'
1984
--
GD--
6-uce World^
Ban data.
--
-I
j,
__
frode
ansfrgincrase goenmn
1970
1972
1974
1976
spending.#
1978
1980
1982
--
1986
is"4
iwcff Weridl
S
Bankc
damc
v dependence.In HongKong,
coloniial
rWfie
has
insffJated
the
government
; from demandsfor-increased
govemmrent
spending.- . 0 One result.of low tO moderatei&fltion'ratespardicula-rly
welco'me
tO
:businessis stable real
interest rates.Figure3.2 shows real interest rates in
V
.- .
-: -
~~~~~~~~~~
::-
; 4 S 'MIRACLE;
Korea,Malaysia,and Thailand,comparedwithArgentina,Ghana,and
is rcmarktble.In the East
Mexico.Aswith moneycreation,thecontrast
Asiancases,lowinflationand flexiblefinancialpolicieskeptrealinterest
rateswithina narrowrange.For the comparators,the combinationof
nominalinterestratecontrolswithhighand unstableinflationwasdeadly.
20~ -
JI
-70
SO-80._R.~~~
1970
1972
1974
20-
Rep.ofKorea
Malandu:
Malaysia. ,~~~1~
j
I
1978
197E
1980
296
2988
1984
40
o4-A-.
-30
-70
"-80
-- . '
-.
-1
!-
!_
i7[7
400
400
19-70
'
+_
'-
1972
1974
1976
197
2S80
Ghana
Argentina
_
1i982
_]
1984
_=
1986
11-2.,
--.
MACROECQ
Keeptmg
Extenal
Debtunder
ControL
Of the sevendevelopingHPAES,
-M
only
Indonesia,Korea,Malaysia,and Thailand havepublic or publiclyguaranteedforeigndebt. The governmentsof the others-Hong Kong,Singapore,and Taiwan,China-have not borrowedabroad. None of the
four with foreign debt has faced a aisis, in the sense of having to
rescheduledebt, but sharp incrases in debt have led to rapid adjustment. In some economiesduringsome periods-for example,Koreain
.1980-85, Malaysiain 198248, and Indonesiasince 1987--debt-GNP
ratios have been quite high comparedwith other indebted economies
(seetable 3.3). As with fiscaldeficits,however,fivorablefeedbackfrom
other policiesenabledthe HPAE debtors to sustain higherexternaldebt
to GDP han othereconomies.High levelsof exportsmeant that foreign
exchangewasreadilyavailableto servicethe foreigndebt. Similarly,high
growthimpliedthat retrs on borrowedcapitalweresufficientto pay
the interest.
4g-."
lndebtedness
-~S '
Pea pt
WStFrnom'rgo
199 d
HPE
x0
--
hdonesia
690
qv478r
,:
- *,
'A
;;f-
Dc';-.
r4+44;-;-t'
7:2
0hte;nme
*
~~-.-is~,t-
A..4.
-,'."-'
47"-
U' -:9
POW
-455
2
47
-`3408'
Pk
s66A
~~MaI~jysxa
~865
>Akioftvnal
deb
to
,xen
.- Ra,. ofor
1384
390T98joCr'.;
54
177
''
'''0
4:
r.
-'!r-sA
38
..
-.
026B0
tx
-1762II
"3
AaNt 1VRAC
burgeoning international reservesgenerated by exports to make payments aheadof schedule;by 1990the debrtCNPratiowas down-to14
percent (In contrast, when Mexicofaced scvereproblemswith its creditorsin 1982, it had a much /owerdebtto GNP ratio than Koreain 1984
but a much higherdebt to export ratio.)
KeepingtheExchangeRatein Une. The HPAEs avoided the severe appreci-
. f.
.Ecoonomy
..
: H
Indx
;t
:
f(highier
vau means. .
mareapp recr
Kong
*Indonesia.
Koreo,Rep. of
~~
0 ' ''
--
.8 D-
..-
.r.s
25
41
1
87;
I-
e-co
;;Slidiend
"nomiei-s
114' ,
'-
,,
~~~~~~0;
...
4a
ap.-p. at0a&O
~~~88
Singapore-
Bolivia
.e
98
1
Malaysia
Oce - .
( O: si.an10
most.-
,-
90
.2- J--";
MACRORC
:
.* -:
RespondingQuickly
to Macroeconomic
Shocks
--The HPAEs rapid responseto macroeconomicshockshas been greatly
300
Rep oKorea-
25D 0200
SD- -
__
0
1970
I__
I_
I'
1972
mo
__I.,
__
1976
1974
1978
I980
--
1988
-- Arg ntarM
e-i.o
Z.
100 -
~~~
10
1972
!1 i i
-5-
1970
1986
Tr.
MO-
1984
1982
300--
-------
300-
I___
!I
1974
1976
1978
1980
2982
1984
1986
i988
ROECNO:
MACRAC
-I
gik"I!xL~R
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~A
&q i"-,
J5tczur
g'%k
dafiii "
c7
'-#-
yx;rvn
*1 ~~~~~~~~
:tt
K>e,;efiile(nu
*-;--
tgl
g$>
>0
*t>
10
"'1"t.>-iJ
-F'
cnsxilngwod4sing
mn
is a
n boxa3&
ath-:
anca frgr ttSF
. variety of
-i to.ea
-,=- j*fd
l- E' Nh, ; + <succdi,
uya
athe HPAESinrsonde
in whidi*&e.mtvt'w>.ttiS.................-i>
rheismdy4bun&m ihakd&Rod&M->
-13eeoiOmlecs
,^fto
action in rs,'l;lponsewr; uhshcsanc-v
fMaulettaocltaket'imEely
that
<6_. f $X
,,3ii'-g\;-,..)-sVl,<w;-;='i--*,te>;t,r<,.,
=tr
2,;
j,
.;
t'F"'vhe
awer"'ou
sjeoomamr
term.asOft2dcbrnzoi.EhcEastArsiaccn
voabe
.,as
cfa-vscin
ohocsf
dvlo96u-t.aggl
'.-s
sods:Indonesia,
maCrOe:oneomic
hva rge
SomxenIobsrvr
-Bld-ow
*_
-..
-wlWtora--
wstas
mi*>>icshavebeoinaica
'a,d
t-;gTl,
or
r*T.
Uroole'Eithti
io*eeldvomgm
b&AkfrAhe
thinaUe.Weinri
hcdo
aia
bbiisl'btt`~i~
o-n'
uq`c1ie.aRAsianiconj
x1B
rm'n
m;
dXc~~~~~6aecord4icsi.&acrh.
.;
?YvsK:r~~
'
we
i-tand
s
uc shockl
unfaexa--
*su
Thand..
Siengapoenloand
rather
Asia has bee +lucky7
Ea'noooS>ast
ta ore,h,
%-"7J
2.eex14f-;RS,.-~*S.-4,~-tk;k.te-fSKe-t.w,WNit..hej
''-'~~~~~~~~-.'i'-:a~~~~~~n~;'
..
~_t-j
~~
~ ~~~~ ~
:1
~.
,,,',PO
_~
:fifl
~0'
*.
_V
..
O-MalwAfl&q8w
..........................................
d4x,O
--
no
fd
ipA
Aursou1s4
ntoJran
; -o errcostlsXnomy<naewdroDalln
':*mrC&jp.
XanonianadiLiebanksav-w1rkt1iaru&oPmnsm;amapcemad
trto
;DeB
.4l~~a
^n~~~~~t
5tf
~~~~~
XR2SOZSFU.uas=g
an cur exedtus
1986>=
in 198 awntd
.~~~~~~~~~~il
.~~~~~~~~~Ddnn
inilntacil90
adarLsIndonesa. OF
aalcs
oDmff
teachieveen
. remmentSemMewolskomeffmeasurem
>erStalfizaonx DastalpriXeoa.Srng
*-. . -~~~~~~~n
"8~~~~~~~~~E
.~ ~
~~
ca'lto
ollow
bthe
i
fosqrom
98tillPustated
n18,tegvranenTaa-nit
robinssnaett)eltSmitocapiml-intcnsivepoDjeC
--
faed
to 196,Iadronosi
rom.ut1982
SS
~~~~~1
by recedln
(fo
Li'
frormtab
overannon-oltexots f*i:3ls
OIhened
t eue
anc
otes
93
hegvrmn
account deficit
foromn)
192no
scdvices
F ove
si
~~~~~~~~~importsof
lslpiaiyb
td
rapidlyw~~~~~~~9orsligtrso
rosSarigi
urn
xeso
A96
exportsi facedfi
epoddw8
elnn
MACROECO
Koreahad plenty of specificproblemsbesides.Realappreciationduring the 1974-79 fixedexchangerate regine had made exportslesscompetitive,the rice crop had filed, and the assassinationof PresidentPark
* ~-Chung-Hee had exacerbatedpolitical uncertainty (Coffins and Park
1989).
Koreahad a few structuraladvantages,however Unlike economies
thatquidyfel into debt crises,Koreawas not running largeandgrowing budget deficits.And while privatesavingshad dropped due to decdining output and incomes, investment remained high. More
important, Korea responded quicldy to its troubles with an aggressive
~~~~~the
drop in output. Even so, and despite politicaloutraiesoverKords
risingforeigndebt,it continued foreignborrowingthroughout the cri-
publicspendingboom
then
Th
mcmeh
secondoilshockand the risein
worldinterestrates.By 1980-81,thetcornlidatedpublicsectordeficit
was 7 percent of GDP,nearlyhalf of which-wasthe deficitof nonfinan-
dal publicenterprises.
Thecurrentaccountdeficitwasalsoabout7 perctentBecauseforeignbo rro inghad been moderate-the debt-GDP
radtowasonly35 percentin 1982-Thailand wasnot &cinga dbt crnsis and continuedto borrow.Evenso, the new governmentthatrook
wover
in 1980 perceivedthat macroeconomic
adjustmentwas needed.
Monetry policyoptionswere
lifmitedbythe fixed xchangerateandthe
relativelyopencapitalmarke. The governmenttherfciretookthealternativepath,fiscl contraction,movig gradualybut consistentydudrg
the next severalyearsto cut expendituresand boost revenues
Policymakerssteeplycur deficits of the nonfinancialpublic enter-
;- . : -
120.
--
MACKtE~9
decining comperitiveness
StabiriyContnb-- to Gmowth
7---7Pen
MAL
MACROACCjj_~.
1980s.Asnotedabove,therehavebeenproblems,notablyin Koreaand
Malaysia,but theyweredealt with swiftly.The Indonesianand, even
more, Thai reactionswere more gradualbut also effective.Avoiding
crises and the need for reschedulingmeant that creditworthinesswas
maintained, and it was easierto borrow in the shorc term and to avoid
very deep cuts, especiallyin invesmenL Suddenreductionsin aggregate
Creating
anExport
Push
GOVERMENTS
by providing suitable microeconomic incentives. Macroeconomic stability helped exports by easing the liberaization of restraints on tade and by facilitating realistic and, in some cases,
undervaluedexchangerates.We discussthese issuesbelow.Few generalizations can be made about microeconomicincentives,however,since
these economies differed in the degree and selectivity of promotion, and
The successof the HPAESrests pardy on what they have done and
partly on what they have not done. One thing theyhave not done is to
n3
IRA~~~~CLUE
Land reformnanid
reconstruction,
~~~~~~~
Natural-resouirceae prs
~~~~~~1949-.521900
Impori-substinicing
industrialirzatiLon-,
1953-57
AF:K~~~~~~~~~~~Eport
promotion
1958-72
ZTilting.twr
~ incur
73 1967
tiC .;;J*-Export
promotion.
tSelectiv6inter:vendion>-2andirnPortssubst-~
Omlandcommoitydioi4hii:heavy2nd
-boomIn,974-81
cciakuwe
.
Fvoring import sb
Indi'srial. con-solida- sio
197180:
no
stontut7-o5
growth,1973-080
~~Functional
*
AdjstmntEto aex-
abdlbcraizaon,
1809
shodci`
~ ~ ~ ~85~ ~
..
.-
.':
~~~~~~~~~~~~icntvs
Hihtecnlgn
Adjw~~~mciz-andh- moeniztion,
19iiod-ors
cAIimno,
Derc~~~u1adon:and
oriU.nrarion,T
* outward
d
A_
~~~~~~~Refborm
ad epr
-1980-
present
,11986-9 CMLEMUOn,
present.
MACRO-EC;~~
and capitalgoods. But easingimport restrictionswithout accommiodating maacrconomic or exchangerate policycan womsencurrent account
problems,as consumersand firms buy imported goods not previously
available.The trade regimesof the eight H-PAEs
havedifferedwidely,but
each has gradually liberalizedwithout incurring a serious current account deficit. Often trade liberalizationhas been part of a policypackage chat included devaluation(usuallyto cushion the blow to import
-substitution industries), exchangerate unification, fiscal reform, and
foreign aid or concessionalloanisto offset a tempomarilydeteriorating
current account.
The dose link betweensuccessfuilmacroeconomicpoliciesand trade
liberalizationcan be seen in the experiencesof Indonesia, Korea,and
Taiwan,China. Taiwan,China, took its firstbigstep toward trade liberalizationin 1958 with a policy packagechatincluded a 25 percent devaluation,a unifiedexchangerate, exportincentives,and the widespread
remnoval
of quantitative import restrictions.In Korea,devaluationsand
tradeliberalizationhavegone hand in hand, beginningwith a dtrastkc
devaluationin 1961 (Collinsand Park 1989). Indonesiabegantrade liberalization in the late 1960s, together with the stabilizationefforts chat
marked the start of the Suharto era. The new government abolished
comprehensiveimport licensingand in 1970 united and devaluedthe
exchangerate. After an inward-lookingperiod in the mid.-1970s,trade
liberalizationresumed in the 1980s and has since proceedecdtogether
with an export boom.
Exchange
RatesandExports
As Wehaveseen,severalHiPAEgovernmentrsused exchangerate policies to off-setthe adverseimpact of trade liberalizationson producersof
import substitutes.A few went beyondthis objctive, however,and used
* deliberatelyundervalued exchangerates to assistexporters.In theseinstinces, exchangerate policy and the fiscaland monetary tools to carry
it out becamea part of an overal export-pushstrteg Taiwan, China,
avis
the most notable exampleof this, but Koreaand Indonesiaalsodelibecrately
undrvalued their currenciesto boost exports.We brieflydiscuss
aglthree belowo
The very large current
surplusesthat Taiwan,China, ran
in the 1980s, especally from 1984 to 1987 (when the surpluses
125
CL E
averaged16 percent of GDP,with an etraordinary peak of 20 percent in 1986), resultedfrom governmenteffortsto managethe exchange rates What would have happened if the New Taiwan,
China, dollar had been allowedto appreciatemorerapidly?Exports
would havebecomelesscompetitive,reducedexportgrowthwould
probablyhavehad a deflationaryeffect,and this in rum could have
reducedsavings.Alternatively-and more realistically-thc potential deflationaryeffectwould have been offset by increasedpublic
expenditure,leading to a budget deficir.
* Koreaused exchangerate protection from 1986 to 1989 when it
ran a current account surplus (which peaked at 8 percent of GDP
in 1988). A desire to protect the export industrieswas certainlya
fictor in Korean exdcangerate policy,but tie main concernwas to
reducethe debt ratio and build up reservesto avoid repeatingthe
closebrush with a foreigndebt crisisin 1984-85.
m The Indonesiandevaluationof 1978 can be classificdlaelyas anticipatoryexchangerate protection.No immediatebalanceof payments problem existed, as the adverseeffect of the previousreal
appreciationof the rupiah on non-oil exports had been offset by
the rise in the quantity and value of oil and natural gas exporcs.
Rather, the aim of devaluationwas to encouragenon-oil exports
and slow import growth. By 1982, when the balanceof payments
had sharplydeteriorated,the wisdomof the 1978 devaluationwas
clear.
One can see a fairlyclear relationshipbetweendevaluationsand export growth in the 1980s.Taiwan,China's,real exchangerate relativeto
the United Statesdepreciatedsharplyfrom 1980 to 1985 (the period of
generaldollar appreciation),and the result can be dearly scen in an export boomto the United States.The Koreanreal exchangerate waskept
fairlystble by numerous nominal devaluationsduring the period of the
first great Koreanexport boom, 1963-72. The effectson exportsof real
devaluation from 1982 to 1988 can also be seen very dearly. The
Malaysianreal exchangerate steadilydepreciatedfrom 1987 to 1990,
and this must have been one factor in rapid export growth-.
The effectsof Thailand's real devaluationin 1984-88 on export
growthwerequite dramatic,eventhough therewerealsoexternalfiators
explainingexportgrowth, notably the availabilityof capitl fiom Japan
From 1986 to
and Taiwan, China, for developingexport indlustries.
1989 the dollarvalueof exportsrose 12 percent.All three of Indonesims
126
in the sevendevelopingHPAEs.
'KoreaPushes
Exports
andIndustrial
*
X
::
L~~~~~~A4
41
,.
C,
E-
Even so, the first instruments of export promotion were highly discretionary.Exporters were supported with multiple exchangerates, direct cash payments(seetable 3.6), permissionto retain foreign exchange
earningsto import restrictedcommodities,and permissionto borrowin
foreign currcncies.This system not only avoided hampering exporters
with restrictionson capital and intermediate inputs for their own use,
exchange rates determined by
but it also gave access to he firavomble
scarcity rents in heavily protected domestic markets. Even as discreincentives were gradually replaced by more automatic instruments, exporters received significant exemptions from import controls.
tionary
for Imports
andExports,
Table3.6 Effective
Exchange
Rates
Republic
of Korea
'
'
'
''
'
-~~' '
Ecnge-
; 4 f-,--'-,"-,
Yen
:.ax ax a n.'
':D'treet
ji.
materb-- - '.' u a
equwa..
inSurceMt)
(percent)
p'remiums phs:
~d6r tcashX
of2&i<E&YZY.5.
suGbsud
. wE
-1958
1.79
1959
.19 0
-1961
1.962
97
10.7173
`19638
19
...196.,
,1970
:.~~~~~~~~~16
1964 114
'~~
.4
-225
118
.44
44
.-. :
113
-69
;
r'c onnrts;E
xz8
~~29: 21
33
'0
23
29
.5K
148
3:
,-
Efct. 'i=bunos
....J1.,--:-:5
MACROECON
-*
:.
~ -%.
-Cj
_
,-cmpnc
B EW4
P1...L
L E' .
fr:tU.C
rE
i4B
ySps
tioizhzr-nontss
,,mdopmentBaEcL:
)ctytpscueebeRayEng,:mlcK0wav,es0vens,3nfNthe:Earler
l ;!l:
ha&obtide3".*>mt'i
mt.'w"gWW $8!stft47
.PM.wodsbMwoucra'ovcnsaSo
t
* .5
i.-1OI6W4lKLQJon
loan-
2 5
,,-,-
033
apancsg-'co
ramadcaelz
ays-ng.cheap
s-Cot
2t m.~
oi
l.F.Sdcparunrnjstwe4*
&lSCca4O :ioo
cn
__~~~~~~-w
S-It?'
-EsSw-S^h
jwtiglrttm&ask*Glitbaej&fl
Moi~~~~~~~~~_S
an
___
a~-
of the>>z=>
economy ws
thait the comp_9;:lexity
.Stot F,ritiEgt,,fE,,.,^WK drafited in 97 recogiJ,zed
E rcouldnororZfoeveceedingwmatheurg;ovrnments anagement capEacitie.h plDan's emphsi
s entually
*themaret srss4-wtrg-|gs#Qz;btam
indictive planningand a greatr role
. |~~~~~~~~~o
SadiNosindustres,
R$kZsEasl@rteE;s
f echolgyand
scupport for h develokmopmcent
don
competitiont.ti
of in it apprs:oa
poSosoulcylis
ME-Z><dustM-iDsSoxrxSStesrtrialed
o fnaLncasetor
the promo-
rneform.The overn-si
oh bndcartiuepn
glarlyaact
eateinbaleofo
susete mand wlesacdcu in
dustries. ith remnantsoffnancsr liaeanr port-oitepizaie Ko grais
paymfedhaien
nt1has
been
thersdeat
of theonesomy
ws and
and
of the ex
th 1970m
was
incgnwized
th reideopei theompexcesse
mdn*e
197 opngithd
industries, sidpdetfnna h devsector.en of t-chnology and the promoparclarlyn andv in brailorsrole sunrt and oveaseveragedlly
-1309.y, ssovemmenn1.officms Wwortionhas bendciv
ofcompctiton.
progreamis.p
remants ofpsfinancies are ipart-libtepraiceio
; . ~~~~~~~~~~utrieslathedita
*Infoprointervention
iue tof
oest
ablishgandkme
edbishresse
olcies foruedo
ad forthe
ther failucure
for pror sicp9
ntrvention apolicies79and
-- ~~~ ~ ~~~~~m
adtepoo
fiupportfoste dvlpetofrc.lg
~~~~~~industrident
: -
MACRO: EcoNP.
of Export
PushinTaiwan,China
TheEvolition
Developmentpolicyin Taiwan,China,has consistedof fivestagesin
which the governmenthas implementedcomprehensivebut changing
poliqcpackages.Throughout,low inflationand macroeconomic
stabilityhavebeen a foundationfor growth-enhancingpolicyinitiatives,and
sincethe late 1950s-exportgrowthhasalso beena fundamentalgoal.
LandReformandReconstruction
(1949-52). When the Taiwanese authorities took over in 1949, one of their first initiatives was an ambitious
videdraw materialsfor exports and earned foreign exchangeto fund imports of machinery,equipment, and industrial raw marerials.These in
rapid development
turn helpedto make possiblesubsequent cxport-led
Impat-Substitg Industializaoun(1953-571.During the second stage,
the government attempted to developindustry as the basefor economic
self-sufficiencyThe government invested heavily in infrastructure, expanding transportation and power necworksbuilt by the Japanese;U.S.
aiidwas an important sourceoffiriance,funding 49 percent of public investment in infiastructure. Excensivequantitative restrictions and high
ta-riffratesshielded domestic consumergoods from foreign competition.
To take advantageof abundant labor, the government subsidizedsome
light industries,particularlytextiles.Consumer goods industries such as
textiles,apparel, wood andlearher products, and bicyclesdevelopedvery
rapidly. By the end of the 1950s, industrial production had doubled.
-'However,the costs ofimporc substitution increasedover time. By stimulating the import of capital and intermediate goods while penalizing
exports, imporc substitution contributed to a growing trade deficit, financedlargely by U.S. aid. As the small domestic marketbecamesaturated, overallgrowth declined, fiom 9 percent in the early 1950s to 6.5
percent in the mid-1950s.
Expot Prmotion 11958-72). Anticipating
the termination
of U.S. aid
131'
R~
~~TWL
ment alsohired the StanfordResearchInstitute to idendifjypromisingindustries for export promotion and development. On the basis of Taiwan, Chinas, comparative advantage in low-cost labor and existing
technical capabilities, the institure chose plastics, synthetic fibers, and
electronic components. Other indusrries subsequently promoted induded apparel, consumer eectronics, homc appliances, watches, and
docks. Direct foreign investment(Dn) playeda catalyticrole during this
period and replaced U.S. aid as the main source of foreign capitl. Although DFI was only 6 percent of gross capitalformation in the 1960s,
nearly 80 percent of it went into manufaacuring.More important, DFI
facilitatedtechnologyand skill transfers,leading to much improvement
in quality and the diversificationof industries.
The impact of these measures was dramatic. Exports, which had
grown less than 12 percent annuallyberween 1953-62, grew 28 percert
a year between 1963-72, rising from 123 million to almost 3 billion
dollars. The transition firm import substitution to export promotion
wasthe most important policy changein Taiwan, China's,economicdev-elopment.It shifted the economy from a relativelydosed to an open
economic system and exposedit to the forcesof international competition and technological change.
IndusirialConsoidationand NewExportGrowth(1973-80). As hic 1970s
MACRO'ECO
decade, Taiwan, China, confionted a challengingdomestic and internacional environmenc.The spectaculargrowth of the 1960s and early
1970s sputtered to just below 7 percent in the late 1970sXTaiwan,
ChinaTs,continued inrcgration into the world economy revealedstructural weaknesses,particularly the financial system'sinability to match
the increasingdemands of induscialization and external trade. Externally, Taiwan, Chinais, persistent trade surpluses with major trading
partmes led to growing protectionism. In the later half of the 1980s,
Taiwads exports faced an additonal loss of competitivenessdue to the
appreciadon of the Taiwan, China, dollar and rapidly rising wages.
Manufacuing wages rose, undercumrngTaiwan, China's; advantage,
and local firms moved production overseas.As in other first-generation
East Asian NiEs,Taiwan, China, manufacturerswere squeezedbetween
lower-wageNIEsin traditional, labor-intensivemanufacturing on the
one hand, and high-technologyproducts from industrial economies on
the other.
Once again, the governmentmoved to rescrure the economy.After
extensiveconsultationswith domestic and foreign advisers;,the government decided to focus on high-technology industries: information,
biotechnology,electro-optics, machineryand precisioninstruents, and
environmentaltechnolo&rindustries.Theshift to ahigh-technologyeconomy has necessiated the close coordinaton of industrial, financial, science and technology, and human resources policies. In 1984, the
government revised laws to provide tax incentivesfor manufacturers
who allocatea percentageof their revenuesto researchand developmenr
(R&D). Incentiveswere given to industry to diversifyr
and improve production techniques.The government encouragedthe establishmentof
venture-capital firms and revised university curricula to stengthen sci-
~1R'A CLE
In addition, in 1985 the government launchedfourteen major infrastructure projects, including expansionof the energy,telecommnunications, and transportation networksand developmentof water resources
and national parks. The government'sdevelopmentplan for 1991-96
callsfor 330 billion dollarsin public sectorprojects.To support theseeffbrcs,the governmenthas adopted an overallstrategy of economic liberalization and internationalization, including the lifting of foreigi
exchangecontrols.
While it is too earlyto assessthese policiesfillly,a few observations
are possible.A growing number of small, high-technologyfirms produce incrcasinglysophisticatedand higher-value-addedproducts. For
most firns, however,the transition to hi-tech industrieshas been difficult. On one hand, the rapid rate of technologicalchange and rising
protectionism in industrial economies make it increasinglydifficult to
obtain advancedtechnology. On the other, the small-scalestructurc of
industry is not conduciveto the costlyinvestmentsin R&D and skillstrainingneeded to shift toward high technology.As a result, most Taiwan, China, manufacturers are still assembling imported high-tech
components.
tD Manufacturd Exporus
Malaysia'sShift knm Resource-Based
strainedfiom heavily biasing incentives against agriculture by the economic and political importance of
theplantation
MAC ROE CO
-ALCL
I
Indonesia
TriesIt BothWaysandOptsforExport
Push
Indonesian trade policies have swung from protectionism to openness.The current open phase has gone fiurtherthan any earlier efforts
and obtained the most impressive results.
Nationalism
audGuidedDevelopment
(1948-66E
Followingindependence
annual rate of nearly26 percent from 1967 to 1973, comparedwith annual increasesof barely2 percentduring theprevioussevenyears.
OilandCommodtBoom(1974813. Indonesiabenefitedfrom the sudden
surgesin c-i prices in the 1970s, and the boom in primary commodity
x36
MACROECOO
Compared with many oil exporters, Indonesia used its enhanced resources well. Daring the 1970s, about 40 percent of the government
budget went to infrastructure for the economy. The government also
placed strong emphasis on improving the availability of education,
health services, and family planning. As a result of these physical and social investments, Indonesia was able to make extremly rapid progress
during the 1970s in reducing poverty and improving social conditions.
Economic growth averaged dose to 8 percent through the 1970s and
early 1980s, as a result ofstrong expansion of public and private investment- Non-oil activities reinained buoyant, especialy agriculture and
manufacturing. The government maintained good macrocoonomic
managerment and, following a debt crisis with the state oil firm Pertamma in the miid-1970s, a conservative foreign borrowing straregy, By
1980, the current account of the balance of payments was in surplus,
and debt service payments were less than 13 percent of exports
Despite these achievements, the trade and investment regime became
increasingly state dominated and inward oriented. Fluzh with cash from
oil and commodities the goveme nt invested heavily in such capitaland resource-intensive sectrs as oil refining, liquid natural gas, chemicaL, pulp and paper, fertilizer, cemenc, and steeL As the states role in the
cconomy grew, the govemment tightened regulations on foreign and
domestic private investment Meanwhile, gradual appreciation of the
exchange rate eroded the competitiveness of non-oil exports, and pressure from domestc interests caused the trade regime to become more
protectionist and variable.
AdMjusuenttExtenalShocks(1982-85. The high-cost nature of the industrial scaor and die end of the oil boom sparked a debate and reassessmentof industrial strategy in the early 1980s. The govermnment
initiated a broadly based adjustment program designed to maintain balance of payments and fiscal stability while reducing the economy's dependence on oil revenue. As with previous macroeconomic imbalances,
the government responded with a combination of fiscal, monetary, and
'37
.rs>I&A1
M I RAC L E
exchange rare policy adjustments. It also initiated comprehensive financial and tax reforms, and made major improvements in customs, ports,
and shipping.
As we discuss elsewhere in this chapter, the macroeconomic measures
successfiuly restored financial stability. The current account deficit dedined, and inflation was brought to below 5 percent, from 7.6 percent
in 1982. But trade and industrial policies gradually became even,more
inward oriented and subject to government intervention. In addition,
the adjustment resulted in slower growth of output and incomes, reduced public and private investment, low rates of capacity utilization,
and the emergence of financial problems among industrial enterprises.
Moreover, although textiles and plywood both emerged as important
exports during this period, overall manufacturing growth slowed in the
face of weak non-oil exports and weak domestic demand.
By 1985, a plethora of decrees had brought a wide range of products
under different forms of import control. Overall, the production regime
favored import substitution rlatidve to exports. As a result, domestic resources were drawn into relatively inefficient capital-intensive activities
supplying the domestic marker- This disadvantaged the more labor-.
intensive, efficient downstream producers and reduced export growth.
In 1986, the economy sufOrietaton(1986P--.
DerigflationandOutward
fered further shocks, as declining oil and commodity prices led to a steep
dererioration in the terns of trade and a jump in the debt-service matio.
This time, however, in addition to successful efforrsto restore macmeconomic stability, the goverrnent launched a program of broad trade
and regulatory reforms that opened the way for a decisive shlfif o export
promotion. Exporc-oriented deregulation has gathered momentum
Figum3.4 EffectiveRatOs
...
Import-:X
Impoflb 2sminvestment
Tramnston
_ l
:Exportpush-dI
1--+,i
o-- 20 40
- 6o so 100
Effatve rtedf potectJon
(percent)
31Indonesia Thabnd
and Mcyanadmn
-cSalieb,
Xcah.
* Mlaysia
-mcr
507zSo&k,
138
(1993); BbarracharyaandPangx
Brinmbc (1993).
(1992w);
'MACRO E
'CON
export-oriented
reflrm. If this is the case,future swingstowardprotectionism,should they occur,are likelyto be lesspronouncedand less
damagingthan thoseof the past.
Thailand's
Shiftfom Resource-Based
Exports
to Manufacturing
LikcIndonesiaand Malaysia,Thailandhistoricallyexportedprimary
and agriculturalproductsderivedfrom its rich naturalresources.Early
rent associated
tradepoliciesemphasizedtaxationof the resource-based
with theproductionof theseexportablecommodities.Tradewasheavily
controlled.Rice exports, Thailand'smajor commodity export, werecon-
ffl ,, ]\,,
.RWCLE
ACROECO?rw1
. .~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
-,J
-_
ii~~~~LE'
~~ ~
.g ~.
~ .,L~ . ~ ~~ie
.
~
-~
E-or
-. ~~~~~~~~~~~~~f
wS_
.'',M
''.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
~~~i
'
ar
-"
.n
'.ape'roa9AesS>'~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
'
-
=CU
roa
es
:~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
-:
f
NT
:~
:~~~~~~~~~
~~~~~~~~~~nstet
sm W-96
ne
:--:: ::~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~i3
!:g
:-
;~~~~
- l~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~a
- u - ~~~~~
- ~~~
- The-outcome
of thesepol~~~~~~~~~~~~~~iy
alaacB
96*
- - : -
manufacoJres
reprcsented
30.6pelt
pora;.Ladingsecorsinclu ed
d
: - -.-
elrr, ad integrarcd is
.~~~~~~~~~P
.- 0 .
X
:xS.;
50
;
-;
.:
..
Woin,
~IO
foei
Oirect
ilVtmetpl
n
*
0--
ex-
ojla
ofa gowingvolumeofThat
ao
MACR0O
of Man.factnriug,
Thailand
: 0 -0Table'3.7
v3: Distribution
;n.uMtA
C R1O36
J~~
(Percentageof grossdomesticproduct)
Senor'
,97.
'1986
Hev inutis3.9
* . Total.mTab
3 e Banko
ofTi2n
3.
.13.3
.23.'3
42.6:
High-skilllabor-intensive
idusre
Traditionallight inutis19.2
9.7
11.1
201
100
100
100
aflTiland
0 ovrnen:shn
wof
adminisrative
cormiptenc
'-43
_5
-tCL~CE
...
..
."
~ ~~ ~ ~
. . ~
~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
M
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~pt,
- :
, ar, L
.*
G
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
g.
..
<._
...
MC
pogamtoenux
we oberve i
- shorr-tan),
f
dizedraresX,
theselecizviyallQqporT
ve9u
T~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ ~
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~A-
..
~~~~~~~~~~~~~
.V.
. .-:.: . ~, .:: -~ ;:
~
ipesvartyofhye
.r,
-a
Lgo-.
T_
.5
ex
5age
, ortatirres
~~I
MACRO.ECRO:E
IE~~~~~~~~~~~
MA CR- O
The successfulEast Asian economieshave had much greater macroeconomicstabilityand much more rapid exportgrowththan most other
developingeconomies.They achievedmacroeconomicstability by adhering to macroeconomicfundamentals-particularly by keeping fiscal
deficitswithin the linmitsof prudent financing-and by rapidlyand effectively correcting major macroeconomic imbalancesthat emerged.
They achieved rapid export growth by fostering a favorableenvironment through macroeconomicstabilityand by applyingon a trial-anderror basis a vast array of market interventions and microeconomic
incentives.In contrast to the many lesssuccessfiuleconomiesthat have
clung to filled policies,the HPAEs have pragmaticallychosen and assessed policies accordingto their impact on macroeconomicstability
and export growth. They have adapted policiesas necessary,kept those
that worked, and dropped those that failed or outlivedtheir usefilness
'Why did the EastAsian economieschoosemacroeconomicstability
and exporrsas their policy yardsticks?And why have they been more
succsfil than other economiesin selecting,implementng, and altering policiesas necessaryto attain thesegoals?We mrnto thesequestions
of politicaleconomyin the next chapter.
3-47
R'A CLE
Appendix
3.1 Economic
andPloflitcal
rimermes
Indonesia
M.~
OpemdanatsubhJJisa':-
~~nnhcfup
ho
mita
b m n m
&
mawiled
~~~
Ci
Wed
dkea,mtecuainl
atpinduainnmmd
rank gugjsajfraden
ccanoiny.. a.
Rdninrpaaaim
Th~Nw
ndp
Wailvs!m
~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~Ol
McPtsUniicatone.
dm
-fr'nlto.'--totim
in.
-f
.
cak-
r.hghmafi
firms ewzuedwt
Sq 01
HjyCIfDAhtuIKI
ins-LM
c=7-
7.
148
Gicderiy
1New
bcip
ntu
aio
asI&uiamoat
-minm
iila
Su&,wont
z.kdqaSns,~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
"~"_...
MACRO
i-
Rqmn.
.h.c 1
J;.Dfdb
it
4
'S~~~~~~~~~~~~~~F
,;-b
Fa t h-
appmv.4mpa;
'
'.-
;elto
~~~~~~n ,
;
,,.E,--.-.ica
.,p9&
;9?,
:cauua
t~~~~~
~~~~~~~~~~~~~-__
* ~~~~
aduap ~~~~~~~
Duicamny&mns~
m-pr
,had;,
. .rtat&
4(**
*.
.--.
__
__
EWuaJn
.:PN
.
Smwod
SB
lBS.
1982
'
ai
185
298
cpu!
rus,* ;t
Sore
Applbw
mun-of
kauga
.DcpIaa
-Oc
sar
bb-l
-iiil0
6hd
0-
'149
::::~~~~~~'W
--
Malaysia
RmMaj'
t,.
-; ,,hiu..mREr;Fads''\
'
.,
-t* --.
.~~~~
-!
: .,,ar
-,'1
F95
-'
1;:'
'., .as
- 'eT
:. V
Wea
'--
''H
.>::-*
a'
TaiFhvki
...;.i:AeMof
T
~ ElbIrn f
.;Me:.i
.-
CoaiI
1.:;
2.95
286
26.
;36
.56
150
-;
1
_o
-d -d
aidnfrminMlyCnrn
-.
'
-.
:Invutcu
-'''t Inra
C.nnhzmoc
nduth
Ai.
.. s--
P-o
-d
Dcv
F uIn
.-.edpam
Atikd
2.;6
.~~~~
:~ ~ ~ ~
'a 'za
. .-
2.6
;, -
n:
--
tr*m
=t.
PmThdc
'Z,Aa
_39
27
Flu'
-|-.:
Guarimeu
-.
_.
puawersii.linccihispendcin
P-a
;'
lnancc
-it.hl,duc.rf
-,
155
'
-_
8h
-:
F. . .UIfllf
--
19:7'2
.uc-y:-- ,"
*e
;--T
MACROE!cONOI'd
f'aasuanu
Jlae
flundd
rA
Caaveuaan
7mteaa&
fmAapaL
-.--
w?Lntae
d
w?apAL
ik.;
-~tw
Ccep0
mdon.has
flatten
hakswete,
CoalIuonAa
mm
~~~~~~~~~~~~Hwedpma
A
H~
DFMdapt
6dm;
ate
Pummlga9onc
.9
-95
ZntaAa~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
SzittqfSis~~arhz4wteutitym
alirsics~~
Fmna
,
Dndh
Avl&mmmac=:-cdtdldnrc
kbca~hsrt'
Ddpsasll
imInanics .lard
~ ~
mn
toa rsc
indusif
dvilnnm
- lctor
Praadnfpn)-
aun
RelasionsAct
apusrake
Vzmz
Epl'e
A
asnr
ad~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
tarn
rwmpato
mqtpmoD
emda.A
indusrs
a cnpi
in
152~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
cir
q
Cud
byp(uu
adlcldorrr
'I
p
.1
ijr Ii
I:
S.
4
5.
N
U
E.
..
.2
U
Fgfl
Liii
iI
jS
H*
*j.
I:
* lB
*
* up
U
N
i
i.irr
I i-Ii
JJ'L[
**
a
.
I
I"
'
I,
ill
-
Lr
'(U
Id
CLE
Tainan,China
~~~~~~~~Tbhir
liur-Yac;Ema,nonc
i
141gbmaaflntmt
aauvlapdcpnrIndprn
D
Pi'lt
*
LiRnClp
LaNd
to
Ddnr
1845
1550
-
'54
-.
.93'164
1952
1953
law-
~~~~~~isarml
Smax far
nd
Tnug.IJiar
~~~~~~~~~~cadlazao
lan
lWborm
'InniCal
1965
290
1571568
1359
[WI
SWiPCle
RateL
86
Stwn fa
-cnt
of~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
'CLWO'
*'
mv"nt
Kmr
oa
panacfmcfmeat
herpm
.7.
54
Nto
.-
185-19
16
C.
MACROE
. ,;s s ;-,?anma,nr,aklbrc
-.
, -RL.----
; pn.ductviycatcr
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~f
;[7'<
Rauanachimn
vith
- -
f fd;
Urnlimdon
Dewlcpmmr a
FAmU6k,cn&
-ofIndustr[al
0
:-,f - S T.-;
Estahlubman
'
-.d zial
Ins
-
,.,,'N
T.
,'
010
. aiwan.
-.
.,Ne
e
-'','.or
l.:-:,
Wdncbu
,, -
D -l
.'
Foreign
SAkbmcnt
O~Iiutr
=,
- &ah
.d;1972:
197n
,:
t; - ' -;*< u
i-,0 ' &uU'nihmc,
-d' c
"
:infmu,-c
'J;D';;
laboriaws
.
'x
'5en;-
Initkials&.a.
_______
WoddEatak
.
pu4n
*-.'
.d
d''',''
.;
oppm-IIn
Liwnadotpl
..
.. I
m7i~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~5
0
f ....
,,,me%'to
Nat
''
is, i1ce
-.
m--a-r".
..
Notes
1. Bradfordis among the first to categorizea combination of functionaland sclectiveinterventionsthat resultin
the effectiveexchangerare for exports exceedingthat for
imports as an export push. By this definition the SoutheastAsian NiEswould not qtalifl (Bradford1986, 1990).
We we dse term somewhatmore broadlyro indude sustained movementtoward parity of incentivesbetweenexport and import substitutes,combinedwith institutional
supporr for exporters.
2. The analysisin this section draws on Easterly and
Vchmidt-Hebbel (Ibrthcoming. The data on consolidated public deficits,as wellas the resr of the data in this
section except where otherwise indicated, are from the
same source. Consolidated public deficits, though less
widely availablethan central government deficits, are a
much more reliable indicator of fiscal management becausetheyindude operating deficitsof public enterprises
that have played a critical role in some macroeconomic
cases.
3. Although the mean level of effectiveprotecrion was
low, varianceamong sectorswashigh.
.56
R 4
An Institution
Basis
forShared Grot
N EACHH-PAEEXCEPTJAPAN,NEW LEADERSPACEDAN URGENT
4~~~~~~
~C
KlA
CLE
Legitimacy
throughSharedGrowth
Achieving
T
tHE
for all Malaysians, irrespective of race and (ii) accelerating the process
of restrucruringMalaysiansocietyto correcteconomic imbalance,so
as to reduceand eventuallyeliminate the identificationof race with
economic function.... The effortsto attain theseobjectiveswere, in
-turn, to be undertaken in the contextof rapid structural change and
expansionof the economyso as to ensure that no particular group experiencesany loss or feelsany sense of deprivation. [Salleh,Yeah,and
Meyanathan 1993]
The principle of shared growth is also explicit in Indo- .esia,where
President Suharto advocates "economic democracr. For example,in
1990 President Suharto himself strongly endorsed research results of
the Indonesian Economists Association stressing the importance of
sharing the benefits of growth. 'I hope that IsEfsfindings on the system of EconomiicDemocracyreceivesas m.uchpublic exposure as possible and that all levelsof society become involvedin the discussionof
this vital issue. This will enable us to reach national consensus as we
strive forward toward the full implementation of Economic Democ:
58
::-
-:
AN..:INsTn'
Universal
Education
Education is arguably the most important of these wealth-sharing, opportunity-creating mechanisms. The provision ofuniversal primary education and wide access to secondary and higher education contributed
substantially to opportunities for upward mobility. This mobiity in turn
mirigated the feeling of non-elites that society is unjust and made them
more accepting of the market-orientedpolicies needed to foster growth.
In Korea, for example, the government invested heavily in the expansion of education at the primary and secondary levels soon afier the wan
In rhe mid-I 960s, Park Chung Hee's export-promotion drive boosted
demand for educated labor, providJingjobs for the first crop of graduates
to benefit from the postwar education push.
Equitable
LandHolding
andLandRefonn
Theory and empirical evidencesuggest that widespread ownership of
land not only improves equity but also improves land prodlccrMry
(Berry and Cline 1979). All the lPA.Es
with subsEantial agrarian sectors
have widespread land holding, resulting from either taditional ownership patterns (Indonesia and Thailand) or land reform (Japan, Korea,
and Taiwan, China). In Malaysia, corporate-owned plantations have
dominated agriculture since the colonial era. But with a relatively small
dpopulaton
and ample land, it has avoided equity problems common-to
other developing economies with highly unequal land distributions.
Hong Kong and Singapore have almost no agricultural seroc.
x6o
AN
Euuterpises
Smalland Medium-Size
AreBeautiful
Just as numeroussmall land holdings improvedequityand efficiency,
the HP'AEsbenefited fiom a profusion of small and medium-size enterprises (SMEs). The large number of SMEsgenerally reflected market
forces rather than government intervention. But several of these
economiessupported SMEswith preferentialcreditsand specificsupport
services.Rapid growth of labor-intensivemanufacturing in these firms
absorbed large numbers of workers, reducing unemployment and attracting rural labor As firms shifted to more sophistcated production,
efficiengrrose and workers'real incomes increased.
Support for SMEshas been most explicit and successfulin Taiwan,
China. As shown in table 4.1, SMEscomprise at least 90 percent of en-r-erpnsesin each secor. Not surprisingly,the SMEs also dominate the
export sector, producing about 60 percent of the total value of exports
r16i
- g,sji~~srA
I IACCL E
inTaiwan,China
Businesses
andMedium-Size
Table4.1 SmaUl
--.
- ,.-; ;e
-.
-;
..--
,,
.d
;-u.,.nt
-i
Smell
-s
-;f
---
-- - 0E u~0--:--::-Tou
talnipX resX
Cue.ory
^Agri
culur, fishing,livstock,forestry
..Mning and:quarlying
.
MItanu-;ting
gm a
r. . .: 1t..
;Ee c,gis,nd
,
-.
Constructon
Commerces:
Tmansporr,-srorngc,and
ommunimcations
services
Funancc,.isurancerel estatebusiness
social,andpersonalservic .69,550
--.:.Comxruunit$,
Total
-';
-1,390-157,965,
8628,419
489,864
36,897
30,534
a -ni
vi - rts
3,171
97.39
.1,360
155,263
97.84;
98.29:.
90.32
168.
818,061=- :':
StmrnnTai
Percentageof
Number0
3,256
-medim--e
-.
26,456
475,106.96.99
35,818 28263
69,229..
93.09.
-794,834
0 . . --
,97.16
-- : - ,: :
97.08-;
92.56: ;
99.54
China(1992b).
(see tabIe 4.2). Other HPAEshave also encouraged small and mediumsize industries. Japan has direaed enormous financial resources toward
dcveloping small and medium-size enterprises. Public financial instirutions have allocated an average of 10 percent of lending toward
SMES.During the rapid growth period of the 1950s, as much as 30 percent of their total lending for fixed investments went to SMEs.The various government-supported direcred-credit programs have proven
particularly helpful during times of transition and rapid change (Itoh
and Urama1993). Although there are mixed evaluations of the success
of these programs, one thing is dear. The SMEsector has become an
important cornerstone of Japan's economy. In 1989, SMEsaccounted
for about 52 percent of both manuficturing value added and sales,
and their share of employment in various manufacturing subsectors
Businesses
in Taiwaan,
China
Table4.2 TheExportValueof SmaliandMedium-Size
.,.
-V
.::
-e~tkr.f
g .
'M2d
Auqon.
Po
.436.89
64
;,23525
-2.'...L.',
674'-'4
,:
OSrTIIJ
hn
3---
42
-'
i6z~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~6
9b.
.~.
-'
.ni&
Housing:
Successfully
TargtingLow-lncome
Households
Two HPAEs,Hong Kong and Singapore, intervened heavily in housimg markers to win the support and cooperation of non-elites. By proriding low-cost housing for the majority of residents, both programs
have helped to decrease inequality and minimize social unrest, thus providing<the long-term stability attractive to investors. Moreover, the massive construction effort created lobs when both economies faced higb
unmemploymenrtsubsequendy, the wide availability of low-cost housing
for workers helped to hold down wage demands, subsidizing laborintensive manufacturing.
In Hong Kong, which has generally followed a laissez-faire approach
to the economy, mass housing programs were a iesponse to a massive influx of refiigees and migrants from China. The rapid increase in Hong
Kong's population from 600,000 in 1945 to 2.4 million in 1950
spawned slum areas, high unemploymenr, and poverry. These led to social disturbances, which culminated in riots in 1967. To difflasethe tension and improve living conditions of the general public, in 1972 the
govemment launched a Thst- track public housing program that has
since expanded to include the construction of entre new towns outsidc
the city propet By 1987, more than 40 percent of the population lived
in public housing.
Like Hong Kong, Singapore experienced a dramatic influx of mi-grants in the late 1950s and early 1960s and faced similarproblems. Its
expulsion fiom the Malayan Federation made matters worse. The govermuent responded by creating the Housing Development Board (HDB)
in 1960 to provide public housing to low-income f2milies. As these
-63
-FIAA
CL E
TheLabor
Trade-Off:
Cooperative
UnionsGeta BiggerSlice
In Japan, Korea,Singapore,and Taiwan,China (and to a lesserextent
Malaysia),governmentsrestrucured the laborsectorto suppressradicalac-
MM. J"F
.3>titY$~
'-V.-AiiGwn~~Skj&tiEboy,
\,\4NC
PIN# GECONONESf-EU-'E
Urox
-.
ojcalits
l RPe%mcn9do
y,W
d
*~.~FLt ~L ,gos
ia.tj.
aalHrnlaaf.ok
1 new.urbanj
1 t
!A?
i.>rohow
.,,peratlvece;
N,:i_OPULt-;
JU,SF
unablcosafford,...
-,
conca4 ctconianrsbdI'nolidal
nri
schaSuetck&^le
r
lu;
uron,
isarbcle
d.:-oLo6.
NI-4 &tr;$
'i=rt%v(i
0E e shCazi
cisr;+f_,';i
s,the lndoneslan
,dii,i potntil
.$QyiTOi'eSpottiid2*it&
-
14PT
'jA'A
ThdlW1I&wnroSfi
mmp~~~~g
V,
.
0~~~~~~~~~~~~~'
praflvhezoeinxa e4!zng.aa-WpdcaaunOp;pflennca
.2
O' q
.rp4rEonrir.
-
..
.rcen
2 ~,
atM
4zh4overnnenthshepd,h
b__ rl
01 1onapmcwohWidin-ahd.s
l
1c64
ooen3 4'
ao0O&n1nttl&n4
tt
own4paymentt,
5L~;
a., .~~i
oaraW-X;
4 ::
mmnnns
ropenu~1auz
,- ;ORS..
AN IN4S-TQ -*
manufacuring by suppressing independent unions and assuring investors industrial peace. To meet workers' rising expectations, the governmnent in 1969 instructed the National Trade Union Congress
(NrUC), the officially recognized labor umbrella organizaton, to suggest
new directions for the union movement.
The NTUC,which is in effect a branch of the ruling People's Action
Parry (PAP),made two recorimmendations:govemment, management,
and labor should work together to avoid antagonistic wage negotations;
and workers should organize into cooperatives with a stake in the economy. To firrher cooperation, the NTUCestablished the trpartite National
Wages Council (Nwc). Each year, the NWCreviews wage and economic
trends before advising the government on wage adjustment guidelines.
Although recommendations are officially nonbinding, the govemment
usualy endorses them wholesale, and business and labor use them as
wage settlement benchmarks. The NWCseffectivenesswas evident during
I65
C LE
, 1, ,t77;tS>ri
ATVESORAGANIZD*.BYSINGAPORE'S
K
i-ONQO5tTHEE1R.
FIRCOOPE
LW. ,>NtwOACoA't
bf.lrodany,
a
byOf&r(
ari
.....
eforp1crncuorVrne
-r
aarryrJo
f,ruung_.
fridhbYii
80.ebrrelxelw:pa
te .Tdfoms;. iAti4niz
6N-ii!'Ode4if&1I
oflisr int
m,drNeriiBccause
n q,qfgoods41n1.p
there west limirbon
ZihcnumberErg4$-;$
;$S-E wre&nn
owners .were-ab1le to
O
&sute
htAusvresorred-ro
dnyangiotr
*
tt-.
lcenseds
hA
Ar'hAgsLen.fl
-ac,a.l
|cd
h
,-s;-'kasb'Vid'e6B'6&f
.tovbay4larg&numbers.ofwasxn
;~~~cas.D
;.si iservitlones,
tmhmr
eranve
dnL1c
Uii dehWdiilcdt
!h
rt
%L&AY.=u'.&O
'j
,s
sout__ro
z6b-d_
admzn,
*~~~~
2 .,i.. Mos
tamnve5
3'r-7.aWef
D;9iS!si
,5i2&~o
,.Kt,> Zrix
~~~1miUtw Xonda;toso&.faealtrncensei
unDedarUG.
id.@ 2
r,=LTz.eiC
;~~~~~~~~~~~~~g
-~
30 X123
.:.
~~~~~~~~~~~nf.wn
-~ ~ ~ ~~
~ ~ ~ ~ ~: ~ -:"~ ~
,T.4
,5r S
nd.sotonuceSE
oarEs;;2ancasc.
,C
25R"-iTr7:aCPVSi:*'
f-
I;"
.~
..
Ei
.ii
_'
..-
:s~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
Technocracy
the Economic
Insulating
IMPLEMENTING
SHARED GROWTH TO SOLVE THE PROBLEM OF
,p-
No .
*-3,--es
4:i30-49
.-.
.85.
29S.
.;
-2
.t
19.45
So28
,a
.
.51
:X05
6.26i_'
r'-SourerTaiwan,
clnnChial
Bure of rheTii _Proviial
tSt
&'980-84
Norrenponre
06.M
.44
51:05
,
9:
-f67-
-i-:;.
-ojo.itX6
008
015
0
37T'..
Government,
Annual
:
167
ii.
o;#{~~~~~~~
Percent(IndEx:1952;100)
:.:
l~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
.::
0~~~~~~~~~~
'
~~~~~~~~~~Murnsfacturln
300
of
Fue41Inv
RelWgsI927
400 -
glAtr
200-
p1952
1955
1955
1M1964
1967
1970
1973
1976
1979
Direct
Mechanisms
insulaton
Hong Kong offers the cearest case of insulation, since the colonial
government, which has been stronglycommitted to free marker forces,
recommendations.
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~A
N- -INS
~ ~~~~~~
.u'
-:
t.di
.____.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~I
::~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~I:
::: 4W"u
G
1;ivestex
n6nLY:Ji CVt'i: 9
EP,Pr
L
,psuN'_O
utyt~~~~;g
,i
dgm
:~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~O
Ce
Ico,
u~~~~~~~~~t)r,,
V ormmg
-wsC
0:00000~~~~~~~~~ICR
a
-~~~~~~~~~~~~'
an
:P3p
3986
rcotan aswep
0.''0 .~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~r
.f
'
.wLtS~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~I
- 3 f : ' -:~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~7
}:g_D
,-.
. f ,
, X; 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~S
.
.t:
:= --
f -
f . D6d .tD r r
;0~~~c-un0000.;:0-0--0I6.:
.
:
D~~
'R'AtCL
Inflation
Control
and DebtManagement
in Thailand
andlIndonesia
For historical reasons, Thailand and Indonesia have been proroundly concerned with low inflation and debt management. Thailand
is unique in Southeast Asia for being the only economy in that region
not to have been colonized, in fact one of the few in the.developing
world. One reason for this remarkable alchievement was the openness of
the Thai Kingdom to trade with foreigners. Another was the monarchy's concern with avoiding indebtedness to foreigners. And a third,
-170-
IN.r:a.n.s-ANNm.
and perhaps the most important, was the establishment of a bureaucracy in 1892 that enabled the monarchy to centralizepolitical control
over the kingdom'smany regions.Historically,then, the bureaucracyin
Thailand has alwayshad a powerful influence over public administration and policymaking.But it was-not until 1957, when Gcncral Sarit
took over the reins of government, chat bureaucratic reforms were introduced to address macroeconomic imbalances.Since then, keeping
inflation low and efficientdymanaging debt have been among the government's key concerns.
These same issueshave been extremelyimportant to the Indonesian
governmentsince President Suharto took power in 1967. The previous
Guided Dem'ocracyregime of President Sukano had let goverrnent
spending run out of control, leadingto annual inflation rates of 1,000
percenicand other seriouseconomic problems induding a rapidly deteriorating infratructure. Suharto'sNew Order govemment ascendedto
power with an explicit conmitment to fight inflation and develop infratructure, particularlyin the rural areas.This led to passageof a balanced budget law and to financial controlsthat addressedinfrastructure
ddevelopment.
To achieve the rwinobjectivesof low inflation and prudent debt
management, both governments created mechanisms tO insulate their
-: .economic redcnocracies.In Thailand, the government'sBudget Bureau
has tight control of the budget drafting process and has maintained a
stable exchangerate and low inflation. To draft the budget, the Budget
Bureau consultswith the National Economic and Social Development
Board about proposed public investmentsand with the Finance Ministryabout expectedrevenues.It then deternines together with the Centtral Bank how much deficit financingthe economy can toleratewithout
increasing inflation. Having detcrniined aggregateallowable expenditure, it calculateshow much each government agency may spend and
:forwardsa broad outline of proposed expendituresto the cabinet.
The cabinet may propose changesto the outline before forwardingit
to a parliamentary budget committee for evaluation. But since neither
the cabinet nor the committee receivesbudget details, the bureau'sproposals usually survivewith few alterations.After approval by the commnittee,the budget outline is submitted to the endiic parliament fior
routine passage.
Throughout, the bureau draws support from budgetary laws that
-'-'lUriiit
the governmentdeficit to a small percentageof the year'stotal ex-
'7'
VMRCLE
,
penditures and that cap the percentage of the budget that can be spent
servcing the foreign public debt (the current cap is 13 percent). Parliamentary rules offer a fiirther unusual guarantee against runaway deficit
spending nonrninisrerial membe of parliament on the budget commuitte may propose-only minimial changes and in any event may nor revise the budget upward. The results have been impressive (see figure
4.2). Except for the diruptions caused by the 1972 and 1979 oil shocks,
the annual inflation rate has been dlose to 5 percent. Few. developing
eoinoies can lay dlaim to such an achievemet and even more adwinced HPA.Rs
such as Hong, Kon-gand Korea have had higher rates. This
demonstrates how a small technocratc core, insulated from politics, can
set a positive tone for an entire economy.
In Indonesia, too, technocrats keep a tight rein on the budget. Under
Suharto, a balanced budget has been the cornerstone of government 6inancial policy: In 1967, the legislature approve-da law limiting expendiares to domestic. revenues plus foreign assistnce. Since then, he
finance ministry has institutionalized a review that requires each ministry to justify prposed expenditures on a line-by-line bAsis. In addispend ~ing
nminisr
of priaet
onIh
ugtc
Iemer
20--
k.ii----
10 -i'
4j
If
r72
1973 1976
S~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
ST
dion, parliamentary rules restrict the legislature'sdiscussionof thebudget to broad policy issues.Armed with thesc instruments, the finance
ministry has establisheda macroeconomic environment favorable to
growth. Inflation has dropped since the 1960s and has generally remained low and stable (seefigure4.3).
Indirect
lusulation
Mechanisns
SomeHPAEshaveenhancedbureaucraticinsulationindiiecdyand generally inadvertently.For example,wealth-sharingmechanismsreducethe
potential gain to interestgroups of intervening in policymakingand implementation,sincesomeshareof the firuitsof growthhas alreadybeen assuled. In addition, when wealth-sharingmechanisms reducethe size of
oroductionunits, aswithland reformand support for smalland mediumsize industries, the marginalcost of organizing and lobbying increases.
'Withthe benefitsof lobbyingdown,and the costsup, interestgroups tend
to be more willingto leavethe policyprocessto the technocrats.
Reozganizationof labor from industrywide unions into company
unions, along with labor federationprovisionof goods and services,has
*.
rv--
--
30
-'-N-
20 -~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
0-
; I
0~~~~~~~
~
-~01970
-5400
~~~~~~~~~~~I
1
j
~~~~~~
f
1972
l- :n eItional
197, 197
0
;our.neranaa
1974
1976
197t1
h
Monc4y Fund daa
"SO
1982
lS84
1986
.
2.97 197
29:
=8
Mocx Fun darn00. ,
196
;8
1.98S
_
819
1990
_'.
.98
-17_
similarly reduced the marginal benefit and increased the marginal cost of
collectiveaction. Thus, in contrasr with wokers in many other developing
economies, workers in the HPAEsarc more lihklyto refrain from work stOppages and other disruptions and fiom lobbying the government for mandated wage increases. Because employers faced fewer demands fiom labor
they, too, have had less incentive to press demands on the reclnocracy.
Of course a powerfil bureaucracy insulated fiom external pressure
can also be dangerous. Indeed, the description ofjapan's bureaucracyan independent force that controls generous incentives and issues vague
guidelines-is nor unlike that of bureaucracies in ocher economies that
engage in corruption and malfeasance on a vast scale. In Japan, itselE
some ministries are perceived to be captured by the interests they regulate. These ministries enjoy less power and prestige than those that resist
politicization. 5 Even well-intentioned bureaucrats may become counterproductive or lose sight of the goals they are supposed to pursue if bureaucratic insulation means that they are not held accountable for their
decisions. How have the HPAEskept insulated bureaucracies honest and
responsive to legitimate private concerns? The next two scctions address
these perennial problems of bureaucracr. honesty and responsiveness.
-'74
ANN I NSTUT
competuve.
* Total compensation, induding pay, perks, and prestige, must be
competitivewith the private sector.
* Those who makc it to the top should be amply rewardecd
Merit-Based
Recnuibnent
andPmmotion.
Recruitment in Japan revolves
around highly competitivecmil serviceexaminationsadministered each
year by the National PersonneIAuthority. For the higher-levelexams,
the rate'of successhas been less than 8 percent. Indeed, in 1980 the averagerate of successwas 2.7 percent (Kim 1988). Promotion within the
bureaucracyis basedon a combination of seniorityand a host of performnanceindicators that dif&r across the ministries. Becausethe number
of personnel in the bureaucracyis fixed by law, compention for promotion can be intense (seePempel 1984)!'
Korea also relies on exams and performancebut has supplemented
thcsefilkersby,,recruitingheavilyamongacademics
with advanceddegrees.
(Box 4A describesthe turnaronundin the Korean civil service in the
1960s.)This has resultedin a prolifcrationof researchinstiutes associated
with ministries. Since die Economic PlamningBoard established the
Korea Development lnstiute in 1971, most other ministries have followed SUiL Most institute researchershave a PhD., many from a respectedforeignuniversity(im and Leipziger1993). LikeKorea,Taiwan,
primarilyto offsetweaknessesin
China, recruits heavilyfrom academnia,
the civilserviceexamsystem.Academicsare recruitedfrom major universities,usuallyfor fixedperiods rangingfrom three to sixyears.
acion
In Malaysia,civilserviceexam resultsaresubjectto affirnmative
guidelinesmeant to increasethe number of Malaysin gaovement. Becausethis reducesthe pool of eligibleapplicants,it probably hinders development of the bureaucracy
Incentie-BasedCompensation.
In bureaucracies,as in nearly everything
else,you get whar you pay for. Table 4.4 suggs that relativepay is significandy berter in the Four Tigers than in other economies. Relative
pay in Mvialaysia
and Thailand is about the same as the averagefor other
low- and middle-in&me econo-miesbut is brillsignEficantlyhigher than
-in the Philippines,which is widely perceivedto have one of the weakest
bureaucraciesin SoutheastAsia.In general, the more fa-vorablythe total
public sector compensation package comparesto compensation in the
private sector,the better the quality of the bureaucramcy
'175
....
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
'e.:.
2
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~,
~ ~~ ~~ ~.~ ~.4 ~
.~~
tyJQ.y~i*S
L~~~
r'A)l4A'
trta
~d.
Wotsurp'sne4ingapre,uowhidii'widely'
JapanF.t anfiS Korca
I
alsomke^6
Japn,oteNationaul
a, dcieatem;
Pcrsnne
Koreabascsldsaelwrthan
W-pine
aflownrs
hlp
effor*;t
>Jto<>
icAuthmForityHo
thepulic sectorwforsentry-level,m_id-l
bu
he
;1 tNrnsnorecdRBErmwt
oinon
1 an
ontlybaejmlayofacputHministercvdiningapordranws d:o
bCS
'fie
sector
peroivd' tohv>
match
the
annuay
posi_-io
private
sur
dif-
salnre.otarein
lare pivaslrbed
copnisto narrowr th;e
; *iffcen-
Tain
acon
of salary
plus* bonuss
in thlet
pvteo seaorzan sahlary
plus hatltowne
in
S$22,100to S$7,2
;3iF (aou US$i3,812'l_e9
to US$1,390)
s
whl .. a n
Japan
ndKreaalo
ak
dliert
effort tomathte
privaste
s
seconn Jeapan th@eNationalt Per,.sonnel
kAu*thoit
annuallyS*,-,{F.4
surves
thu
dso
o
mpanis toderin :job
pay rates$(Kimo1988 p.) In
Koea
bs
p;saries
arcloer
than
saares
in largepmays
pr,;iFitvate
cmpaies.x
gin's mtost compentsan uaprihtabreacracyb
itasn
iburacr
ofisalar plusthly onuss
te riae sector amnd
alrypls a llowncsin
b7estT
basensalayoaflmister
iSngorerang
-~~ ~ ~
176-go'
~~~~~ne
pgtbracaqspy
tOhane
t
in most
ueurt
1NSTwt:ANWpNS
Table4.4 ICPEstimates
of PerCapitaGDPandRaftioof Publicto PrivateSectorSalaries,1992
(penent)
';f - i ; *;
apo*r;
n4:b
:Korea,Re.. of
;
-.
Ta aM China
98.
40
47.G.6-;
0 f;
.
Thailand.
- .Philipie
60.3
33
*.;
0:--2i7.50
.:
i277
GDPpacai
'Mddee
B~A
114.
,':o-
;65.2
0LMa1-aysia
Seir leve
HPA&; &ononq/regran
,.f.4i.
-a),
L2r;4:;.3
_B-A
;Ennyluas
1150
-
107-'.
7.
.
8 .3
63.5343
-;33.6
. -
.-43.0
25.0
325
822
83.6
60.0
65.8
920
-710
7,954
-5001
5oo
4418.0
62.
232
A-
;Tind-anToa,
.
63.5b -
,3
SnbSsjz70Afia
~~2 tmgu;
;~aLua
2416
;.
lAor
76'9
-
24
35
2.
;wCili
63.5
-
Somi- a
-LEsciae
a.
_.
779
3 1P
25.0-
11.2=, -'
2
-
'
average compdranontn
122r-
'.
i~
iconomige
u
te
public sector.
In other HPEs public sector base salaries are consistendy lower than
:-their privare sector counterparts (table 4.4).7 W7hile figures were not
availablefor Indonesia, anecdotal evidence suggests tat te private-: :tpublic
wage gap tre is the largestamong HIAEs. A stdent graduating
-from an Idonesian universitycan expectto earn t o to four times as
much in the private sector as in a government job. Nor surprisingly,
c Som
frsle the technocratic core, Indonesias bureaucracy is perhaps the
least sell
regarded among HPAES.
In economies where public sector wages are at least decent, prestige,
job:seciny,
c cll -=AE-s.
and other
advantages
of public employment will persuade
cas
reare
amn
H
se
6-g, :---06
60.0
007
3 7.1
toth UN4.
Ineraoa ComparZionPr e. ,. reth to i- ernational
indude alloaneos and boiisetDtarnibrpriarteseor comnpmsdoui ae ased
smalrilab,
on
8,51 ;0
oDfpu -
plymn
wil: peruad
;.
in
asurveyof
(o
-::
r~~~~~~~~
V ItALE
HPAE bureau-
E*AEs,
retrement comes
to indude
a golden parchute.
The
0~
~ ~~
~A
~~~~
IN.ST-W
A NijN
,~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
~~~~~
B The Iu1e.f
NXA
&A,
nL~
iR:ACkAUnENrTO` A BUW-
: IIIGHLYCOMPErITJV& MESBASED
-auaa
,
3'-
fieai
E6~~~at
ftheel
-cr
Dbutmntiad-pr
MouShaMW no
faos
witha'L,
|
cotxmpedarive
l mana
is n
thcaw
re
levimnmcnt
e iteia e
-.
to
:2O
idii vatue
beisreweeninstrvies,i
firns
welcome
tha firs
elom
denying
whohatv
Be--'-4
6n,isui,
i`
Whl
noiv;Enr
~
1,4u2
~
faos
-~~~~~~~~~~~ruCG-2~eP
iWZIi&
rbiidMdZl2&
int.scl
except
the
,1
unnv,zes;2ix cra~tcsanzespnt de4Ff*
ra;cmtomsfo:grslcne
roc=on
r-
Ilentrusns%lenlowingimem-w.?-
creaeswuciors
vy
etredseniceor
bu-
rtiedseiob
reuras partyo
b strs~eopsilngthe
the reatiree ar
'i,sg ofteni2/
oaucrac pusfultiesih
mens thatgzovenmersternno
crrcntueo
h bureZaXi
aaftiexceptonal
naueo mnagers
h v ueacaymasta
the rtirees
LiPare
ofe "
\alubl
in theivrown t9ightF,.4^S-t>><is*
CiCompetemncBmet~ids
ompetitivniscourgesenvironmesny
witein ciamonalso
anbtworyof
e ministries,
Ienace
hownesty
M %ehanimsthtidc
nbrityicospoDBSimpeteny
gofclmgi
guard
againrs
firsq
o
iffern
apst-rticrement
jobs
cin
etis
hae
for
or dis-^
Competiimrlon
dscoraesdhoetsice.sgdistar<acsuovryo a corrupt specia
hoet
bya
havlue
c wull4ould
diquaif nyiapplicant,. in.rsocietiEes
acommite
wthatincthei
cminitrycThese faturs,
publicr
combined wihoanesy
179
i;RA ACLE
Developing
BetterBusiness-Govemment
Relations
Whereas most other low- and middle-income economieshave only
recently turnedto the private sector to stimulate growth, the HPAEshave
done so for many years1 often decades.They have done this by providing a legal and regulatory enviro=nent for private invesment, by creat-
- t;-
~~~~~
4N.l
~~~~~~AN
regulatoryenvironmentconduciveto privatesectordevelopment.Based
on selectedcriceriaor fourteennewlyindustrializingeconomiesin the
1992 WorlzCompetitiws Report,
in whichlowerscoresindicatea better
environment,the HPAES
had an averageoverallscore of 32.3 (with a
standarddeviationof 18.4) comparedwith an averageof 56.9 (with
a standarddeviationof 13.3)for the odtereconomies.8
EncouragingSrall
andMedinm-Size
Enterpriss Smalland medium-sizeen-
texprises
generally
havedifficultygeridngcreditto financecapitalimprove-ments, obtain better technology,and break into markets, particularly
export markets.Hence, a nontrivial SMEsector cannot be established without external assistance. Studies indicate that the northern-tier HPAEsJapan, Korea, and Taiwan, China-lhcv been able to develop relaively
effecdve financial supporc programs (Itoh and Urata 1993; Kim and Nugmt 1993; Wade 1990). largdy because of weak institutional capabiities,
Indonesia has not had much successwith itS support progams(Berry
and
Levy 1993); however, the private banking system appears to have been
hdpf3i irndeveloping some sNEs. Both Malaysia and Th
h
atiV
V
support prograams but not much is known about their effectiveness.
WooingBigBusiness
communication and cooperadon between die private and public sectors, whereby rentsharing rules can be made transparent and whereby each participant can
be assured of a share of rents. These art, in effect, an institutionalized
form of wealth sharing aimed primarily at winning the support and cooperation of business elites.
fciitate
EastAsia'sDeliberationCouncils
Japans efforts to establish such institutions are the most widely recognized and have been the most thorough. Since the beginning of the
postwar period, the Japanese government and private industry have en-gaged in serious policy deliberations though deliberation councilsoftwo
ype The first is organized along functional or thematic lines, such as
pollution or finance; the second is organized according to industry, fr
: 8ii
council, the group revises the report and releases it to the public to acplain the objectives of the new policy. Final approval by the diet is usually routinc. Without consensus from the relevant deliberative council,
however,a MITmpolicy stands little chance of success.9
compile
data
r|
MMjuniorstaff
Hearing
studygroup
- Learned
individuals
- Interested parties
- Overseas erployees
- Local rpresentadves
Prepare draft
>
{eedbacM
- oUers
Research group
(Subcommittee)
(Outside lcturers)
Otdelcue;
(Briefings.subcomnittees' reports)
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
-|Deliberativecouncil
Publec r
(Report) ----
-*
Public Aions
Explanatorymngs
Lectures
-Others
S&urn-.Ono (1992).
:
'
-~~~~~
Ationr
Koreahimselfpresidedoverdiscussions
berweenthe economicministers
andictop
businessleaders.Businessmenexpressed
theirviewsabout marets,regulations,and potentialplans.The president:
theninstructedspecific ministers to attend to each important issue;at the nt
meetng,
mnUnisters
dlivered a progressreporton theirassignedtasks.
Thesemeetingsweresupplerm
ented bygoverment-initiateddis-of
siongroupsinvolvingcompanymanagersimiddbe-level
governmentof-ficials, and expertsor scholars.As in Japan, there were basicaluytwo
types: fumnctional
(for example, taxation) and sectoral (usuallyfocused
cvenalac
beCe
rwhaddsrbnn
o xml, underthe
conulttivstuctre,
of the
bycth pruie minister and includes more than sixty members from industry, labor, and govermennt.
Thailand has been slower to develop consultative mechanisms. In
1983; the govenmmentestablished the National Joint Pubfic and Private
Consulkative Committe (NJPPCC)with the prime munister as chairman
and the head of the plnning agency as searetary general. Othmermembers are top government officials, particularly from the economic agenaies,
and nine private sector represenmives dmawn from the Thai
Chamber of Commerce, the Association of Thai Industries, and the
Thai BankersAssociation. Provincial consultative comrnitees have been
established to supplement the NJPPCC (Samudavanija 1992, p. 26).
Views about the effectveness of the committee differ widely.
Public-private consultation is most cxplicit in Singapore. The private
sector paricipates in policymaking in many ways. For example, private
citizens serve as directors on government statutory boards and as members ofad hoc government advisoy commirtees. In both capacities, they
review policies and programs and make recommendations for official
considemraion.In addirion, the government regularly invites chambers
of commerce, trade associations, and professional societies to subniit
their views on specific issues (Chia 1992, p- 11).
The Singapore
ents
efforts to manage dhe economy are most.
fully apparent in the National Wages Council, which indudes rp-resentatives fiom govenmen; business, and labor Becauseof this tripartite structumr, the Nwc fulfills several coordination funcuons, simultaneously
fiurthering the govenment's guidance of business and of labor, as wel as
business-laborcooperation. Having rejected more typicaldenocratic ifrms
as too adversaial, the PAPhas also etablished a wide variety of citizenassociatiorLsto provide channels of communicanon with the government
Formal mechanisms for business-government interface are almost entirely lackingin Taiwan, China. Instead, coordination is handled tirough
large public entrrise
that provide basic inputs to manu
cturers
and
through enterprise owned by the Khomintang the dominant political
184
AN
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-
NST
-----
- ---
weaknessof its bureaucracy.Coordination appearsto be handled by infbrmal networkslinking senior officialswith major enterprises.'2 Little
is known about thesenetworks,but theyappear to have produced a high
degree of cooperation in the economy. In contrast to the deliberation
councils,where rulesare more transparent, thesenetworksare more susceptible to captLre by participants and to corruption.
Deliberation councils natually reflectthe history and culture of the
societyin which they operate Evenso, the experiencein the HPA:Es
suggeststhat their applicabilityis not limited, as some analystsmay suggest,
to the Conf&ciancultures of Northeast Asia. Becausethe operation of
deliberation councils has been so importanr in winning the support of
business elites, we now look in greater derail at the operation of these
councils in two very differenteconomies,Japan and Malaysia.
Japan's
Councils: e Foreunnes The concept of deliberation councils
in Japan is most closelyassociatedwith Mm. Because of m1Im's
role in
developing and implementing the economys industrial policy, the
public-private consultativeprocess was most dearly manifested in the
councils attached to it.
Government-businesscollaboration has long been a hallmark of the
Japanese economy. The zaibauu-Japan's large corporate holding
groups-were dosely linked with the military-bureaucraticcomplex of
the 1920s and 1930sand were a key element in building the economy's
industrial and military base. At that time, the influence of big business
matched and sometimesexceededthat of the bureaucracy.
The U.S. occupation forces,ideniliing the zabatiu as a keyelement
in the build-up ofJapan7swartime machiney tried to limit their power,
185
= - .
QSI.YMiI
R-AC L
reaucracy.Ironically,this not only strengthenedthe bureaucracyparticularly MITT,which became the center of developmcnt policy
processhasbeenadministrative
guidance,the useof threatsand rewards
to induceprivatcpartiesto followor implementmeasures
suggestedby
the bureaucracy.
Administrativeguidancedoesnot depend on any law
or regulation.Rather,it employseidter threatsof adverseconsequences
should a private party refuseto conform to a 'suggestion
or recominen-
-I86
:.;
AN
INS'
Before 1983, Malaysia had some consultative panels within ministries that dealtwithspecialized
issuesand wereconcernedmainlywith
cutting red tape. Many had litde privatesector participation; those that
did, however,produced concreceresults. Since then, more deliberation
councils have been formed,dealing with broader and more complicated
issues (the budget and trade,for instance). One of the most ambitious,
the MalaysianBusinessCouncil, which was formed in 1991, resembles
Koreashighly successfulExport Promotion Council.
Although it is too earlyto know how effectivethesenew councilswill
be, thev would be hamstrung without an efficient and rcpurable civil
servicebureaucracy.The government recognizesthis and is trying to increase the bureaucracy'sefficiency,eliminate corruption, and educate
civilservants on the value of cooperatingwith the privatesector.
*.
WhyDeberaton
Councils
Assist
Growth
From an economicstandpoint, deliberatve councilsfacilitate information transmission-They enable the bureaucracy to gadter infbrrnation about world markets, technology trends, and the impact of
regulationsdomesticallyand abroad, synthesizethe information into an
action plan, and communicate the plan back to the private sector. Selfinterested behavioris more or less constrained by the repeatednature of
the collaboration.This in part helps establishcredibility-private sector
participants believe cheating and reneging are less likely. Politically,
these councils serve as proto-democratic institutions, providing direct
channels for big business,labor, and academniato the seat of power.Finally,becausethe rules that governan industry are effectively
esablished
- rwithin
the council, everymember is assuredthat the rules canolt be altered arbitrarily.With dear rules established,memberscan concentare
on market competiton and not worry about others tring to curry special &ivorsfrom the government.In effecr,their share of industryprofits
is determined more through competition than through rent-seeking.In
this sense, a deliberation council can be viewed as a wealth-sharing
mechanism.
:
. -
-. ,
Studies of the successfulAsian economies have fiequently emphasizedthe authoritarian nature of their leadership.Leadersof these soCd-
are
etiesdescribed
as benevolent
dict;ators
who,incontrast
0
0 X H -:-:
- - :.
to
mostother-
1-
I~~~~~~~~
- - -
~~~~CL
E
The taskof initiating and susmininggrowth thus presents a very difficult coordination problem. Lcadersmust persuadeeliregroups roshare
the growth dividend.They must demonstrate to non-elites thar part of
the dividend will indeed accrue to them. Governments must create
examine
the
HrAE
govern-
;I88
Notes
1. For example,the National WagesCouncil in Singapore has helped coordinatewageriseswith increasingproductivity. In Japan, the establishment of the Japan
Produtctivity Center helpedi institutionalize labormanagement consutrations.
2. In fact, the smE.sectordeclinedonly when the HCI
push wasinitiated in the mid-1970s.
3. In those cases where the prime minister appoints
both vice ministers, he is constrained by custom to appoint a career bureaucratfrom the ministryto the post of
admninistrative
vic minister.
4. The debt-equityratio has beeninordinatelyhigh in
Korea. Official statisticsindicate that this is in the range
310-80, although the 'true' figuresare said to be lower,
at about 160-80 (Wade 1990). Nevertheless,this is still
high comparedwith the ratio in the United Statesand the
United Kcingdom,where the rangeis50-90.
5. Okimoto (1989) ranks the power and prestigeof
ministries as the inverse.of their degree of policicization.
* The heavilypoliticizedconstructionministryrankslowest
and the relativelynonpolicicizedMmu
the highest.
6. Senioritybearsheavilyon promotion decisions.It is
189
-w~R
OF PRODUCrIVE
ASSETS IS THE
Explaining
EastAsia'sHi'gh
Human
CapitalFonnation
XCEPTrFOR IN THAE AND, THE QUANTITYOF BASICEDUCATION
iEtiigierin
192.-
STRATEGIES
FOR RAIMDACPIDA
level.
RapidEconomic
Growth
Rapid economic growth is the first factor that accounts fbr East Asia's
extraorlinary quanrity of education. For example, during the decade
1965-75, CDP growth averaged6.7 percent in Malaysiaand 4.1 percent
in Argentina. This implies that over the decade a conscantshare of GDP
allocated to education would have doubledthe resourcesavailablefor
education in Malaysia,while in Argentina they would have increasedby
less than half Rapid growth also crearesjobs, increasesreal wages,and
raises the rate of return on labor forceskills, thereby increasingthe deo
mand for education (Ing, Anderson, and Wang 1993). Thus, rapid
growth operates on both the supply side of the market for educational
services,by increasing the potendal resourcesavailablefor education,
and on the demand side.
The risingreal wagesthar area product of rapidgwdicould have a
dampening effect on educational opportunities, if the relativewages of
teachers rise. Fortunately,rapid accumulationof hurnan capitalfacilitates
subsequent educationalexpansionby increasingthe potential supply of
eachers,thereby reducing the premium teacherscommand.' The wages
of educated workers,includingteachers,tend to rise at a slowerrate than
averagewages.Therefore, the impact of risingwages on the cost of education and hence on enrollmentsis weakened.2 For example,per pupil
operatng costs at the primary level average roughly 13 percent of per
capita GNP in Indonesia and Malaysiabut more than double that, 29 percent, in Sub-SaharanAfrica. In Indonesiaand Malaysiathe annual earnings of primary teachers are roughly 2.4 times per capita GNP. In
Sub-SaharanAfrica, however,where human capital is relativelyscarce,
that ratio is much higherA-The
pattern is similar at the secondary leveL.
'I93
--- RAC_LE
DecliningPopubtion
Growth
EastAsiaprecededotherdeveloping
regionsin movingthroughthe demographicuansition,and the educationsectorwasa majorbeneficiary.
One important outcomeofa decelerationof the rate of populationgrowth
of tota pp
.,
(rnl
*.FIPA&E2.1:
-- f-.-
-rcaRPf -
-i'o n
143r4o-
'4
'
p"t.of."
d'
1 Banglaesh.X'
...
1~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~6
:,..:a'
'
'
' ' ..
'C:
T-
1:
402
ong-Ko
iio:' 26--r:'0.7.
- _- 37
'194.
Brazl ; t,
-0,.,3'
0.2
'
'.4-4
'-.'43
'.47
''.,
0
2 9'
47s51_3
igrn.~~~~~~
46 ~~.
~~~~~~
35
. ...-...
9~11
* I94
120
-
4
r! 7 t
' "1-
STRATEGIES
FOR. R-A:P-D`
Accordingly,declining,stagnant, or slowlygrowing school-agepopulations have allowedsubstantial increasesin per pupil expenditure in all
of the HPAEs.
Table 5.2 shows the magnitudc of the savingson expenditure on basiceducation in East Asiadue to the decline in the proportion
of the population of schoolage.5 Consider the most striking example:if
the share of the school-agepopulation in 1988 were as large in Koreaas
in Kenya,the Korean govemment would have had to spcnd 5.6 percent
Table5.2 Percentage
of CNPAllocated
to Education
Saved
Dueto Lower
Fertility
Rates
_f
;\;
X~-
Expendtre
dne torowthm;s#e
rhuol-aepopnltdon
tower an.
'.on
:Economyp- :.-;
Ho,gKon'
1975
- 7 t180-1
Mcio
#t
X.n
;1975 .
1. 98849
.
.*-
12
1.0
1.7
1.5
4.
38
8
3
3.9
~~~
04
~~.
04-
4.2
2.8
- --
w;~~~~~~~~
-..
2.0
:4.8
w
l9-;
1975
13
28
1988-89:
3.
16
* ''J1975
; .21
''i
-9 8
4t,'-,'^ .iNnc'
Fr.
, .
ofcul
:ijS"
<
t'' ''05i'!
1.
..
0~~
6
.
1980-81
~~~4:4
11
;1988-8 4.40
"_J
1.0
20 %8
:14
0 4'0
04
08
20
'.'
','
268
lan o. [Cur
on basic ed
0.3
'
an an asapccara2e
08
aof )
'
ErAsiznan4orhcrccononucs
inscihoolWsg
popadi)'n2u',_ -+,L{';
zpercencddference
s S * q ;~~r between
;2,-,;j:u;f
t
*, , 1;-th.iii
(cxpcn
mme
on
on .a;p ied ;oFGN)an cCai
=a
f
addal
itht
would havte
been rqe
h
p
gw
e
m
rp
s. A 0C-d
.
.
- t - r.
LTvuuut1accoarcstuiooup.
4 %Th%isanndImrrofd1Saviui
Thris
ra ndxue
n
asic dlihearo,usso(iouy",brn"~
':95
.~~~~~~~~C
rates.Thissuggeststhatlowerfcrtilityratessaved
Korea'shighenrollment
school-agepopulahad Pakistan's
Korea2.8 percentof GNP.Conversely,
tiongrownat the relativelylowKoreanrate, thegovcrnmentof Pakistan
couldhaveincreasedenrollmentratesby as muchas 50 percent.
Equality
inDistributon
ofIncome
The moreequalan economy'sdistributionof income,thehigherpriof more
maryand secondaryenrollments tend to be. In a crosa-section
significantnegthereis a strongand statistically
than eightyeconomies,
ativecorrelationbetweenbasiceducationenrollmentratesand the level
of incomeinequality,asmeasuredby the Ginicoefficient(Clarke1992).
As we discussbelow,educationalexpansioncan havean equalizingimpact, so the causality in this relationship could run from enrollment
ratcsto the distributionof income.However,thereare a varietyof reasons why low income inequaliry,which we docurmentin chapter 1,
might havebeen a third factorco:ntributingto highenrollmentratesin
East Asia.
STRATEGIES
FORR-R
Coordination
Probemsthat Hinder
HumanCapitalFomation
Numerous studiesshow thata person'scarningsare higher the higher
their human capital,as measuredby their education and 'iealthstatus.As
shown in chapter 1, the same is true for nadons; we know that investments in education contribute significandtyto economicgrowth. But
neither of thesepoints necessarilyjustifiespublic provicionof education.
Indeed,
if the privatereturns art as high zs socialreturns on theseinvestments, individualsand householdsare likelyto make adequate (from an
economywidepoint of view) investmentsin human capitalon their own.
However,two kinds of problems generatea gap betweenprivate and sowhich-if not countered by governmentaction-will result
cialretumrns,
in
interesLFirst, theremay be filures in the capitalmarket and in information, discussedabove, that reduceparents ability or interest in investing.
Second, educationalinvestmentshave positiveexternalities,which imply
6
that familiesthar invest in education are not the sole beneficiaries.
The difficulty of borrowing to send children to school affectsthe
poor especiallyCreditors cannot easilystake a fuitureclaim on embodied human capital (as they can for other types of collateral).Evenpoor
&milieswho might be willingto borrow,becauseschoolinghas high priratcreturns, usually cannot The poor are also likelyto be less awareof
fixturereturnson education-and thereforeinvest less in their children's
schooling than would make sense even from a strictly private point of
view.7 These market faulres in principle suggescmaking loans available
and improving information about future retuns. A simpler, and more
common, alternative is for government to reduce the direct costs of
schooling by making public schooling availableand free.
The second classof marker failure-externalities-has more immediate implicationsfor what type and levelof schooling the government
should subsidizeand for whit groups.There are severalsourcesof externalities.An educated person may increasenot only her household'sincome but also the income of other households, because her ideas and
. -- MIRAC
LE
onInveshnent
Figure5.1 Returns
in Education
byLevel(Latest
Year)
Ratreofrtuwm(percent)
Pri_
:Primary
c- ndia1
---
--
I-i
Kr
SondarJ
-Hi4her
05 ID2may L
0~~~'
5 10 15- 20 25 30 3!i
SocIalreturn U Pilvato
Social retrns
N Nvaf mt
*;
Soww Pswchaopoulos(1993).
cation. All of this argues for universalprimary arid broadly based secondary education as a means to improve economic efficiency and
income distribution.
Table5.3 PublicExpend4tnre
on
Education
as a Percentage
of GNP
;E con>msrnyI +.
if
5 .-
-1960 196.i9
oegg
:~5
Policiesthat PromotedHumanCapitalFormation
Kong2.8
2.0 p.oE
Korc
]46
-2.8
34
'.97~
pV W -
;:,--Smngipoin
?g1ayi
T
23.",
2z3
'.3]9.2.
J.'x',tfg>R;
z lndocs
0.9
ovr
*~~~~~~~'
*;*ZAvctnX
;.sc
2i.5{
,.1
Si
---
PakfisraaV$1'I
-- ttdc4cs:oPcdr
;
;
-6'
d0Zn~
0- - ~
SaharanAfrica, 4.1 percent, was higher than the East Asian share, 3.7
-l
economies,3.6 percent8
3.1S'St;
.7.'.
-. Q:-
9'n
5|;
>Nor
econom
oFcDnms'
j^['.''Lli{,.rM<developing
-ourc
esdaral
fl
41/
wa1
.-
...
thn
most
,ies
subsequent increases in primary and seconday
;'
Ni
t>
secondary enrollment
rates were
.98
--Ef g
in Sub
;t
Et
governments
'
'_t_AX'l
in*'ii;iother developing regions. In 1989 the
.-- J 26{bSs
1
nts- ogVIg
f! Eas.............t2T-J
share
ntheof national output they invested in formal educaion, but so
;.
;;rg
sa
1;9
fiuly
-..
-.
STRATEGIES
FOR
RID7ArCCU-M4
f~~~~Pbi'K>. r;j6Z.et.t
Pub&-,
Peretge
of Percenag
~~~~~~~~~*
s -- g.
; r ' ; - on
~-
-*
* t--
... i
--.
--
; L;;te>ni8s.
on'! .- .t
- '
cn.
eoncain
as
..
*W-
2-~.
;E~ A:LdcaoonzyGW
Singapore
5.0
-.Taln
, eniag
eu4oi
.t3.ofthe
.
. t-.-
~tini985-8
..-
.,Lltf
.0
10.3,
0f
14.6~
749
Siid,cinollnt
bsc ducanon
i:980. .
30.7:
.
4
-
;E-310
.2' a9d4.3itwfl95.46,iiuhatrthe
e-3
buidgealarcmbic?Iuconwns_81
2..10
dc: ng
St.adalu`p*
e
P-d
'
o 32,N-
't
-1 '-
",
..
-'~~~~~~~I"
7
t
L' a6E
-
..
72..
Mn
. ,9;
iKoeaRepo
0
1vIalay~~~~~ia
79
.4.
cio*
;- educanonsit
-Indones23:
'F.
-atv.Sosc
it
--
-c-
per
m 9S48; and80,
Mg(*
.8.
'I
--
W5Ofli
Qu-.
'99.
STRATEGIES
-Wl
UsN
Ed
n :p quesm--lSZ
Mud
gg
FO.R. k-Ai
31
ou
to
.,H,
PC-=
Pff
citi0ii"bf-
propoipomp
Y,
$61
-5-i
-r. n.
ZOM
ulca'don- ud et,'
00
pq*"
90
r
w=ntpmbamrucauonz,-,F-,,"j,,.
C uc2uoq
diiii2b
M-ffiki6
0,-percmrp
-,-PFF
2=enta o
Bft a c;-,MC:rcmamclcri,,-,,
CUOn.
arsozaLs=
R -'zcu -m
y,'one
in
C
j'an
jopPrO
7
o non,
liEfic,ar-kniv
iham
P C
ZhQ?
:ax
gr
.11;2pcm
"ea
):PM
C=O
1987'
;",O
m 's,
caiiNwduj
Li
&-Co
zm
owcvcr
Lti
SCIOLOO
201
Few studies have been made of training in the HPAESor ocher developing economies, in part because of the difficulty of defining tamining.
One lage survey of 48,00 0 manufliLccring firms in Taiwan, China, conduded chat firm-level trining rised productvity by encouraging the
efficient use of technolog (Aw and Tan 1993). The study also found
chat returns from training were higher in industries with well-educaced
workers in an environment of rapid technological change. Another Taiwan, China, study with a smaller survey sample and stricter definition
Other studies in the HPAaEshave reached similar conclusions.Enterprise and preemployment training have produced social rates of reTur
of 20 percent in Maaysia. In-plant taining for welders in Korean shipbuilding had a socal rate of return of 28 percent, higber than in nonfirm. training institutions
STRATEGIES
FOR
RAP
Explaining
EastAsia'sHighSavingsRates
A5
: -
HUMAN CAPITAL
0j
IRACLE
of the income-savings
relationshipin a broadcrosssectionofeconomies
indicatethat whileincomeand savingsgrowthare highlycorrelated,incomesoften haverisenbefbresavingsratesratherthan after,suggesting
that growth drivessavingsrather than the other way around. Recent
econometricstudiessupportthe idea that rapid incomegrowthboosts
savingsrates as householdsacquireresourcesfister than they increase
consumption(Carroll,Weil, and Summers 1993). Accordingto this
view, East Asia'shigh savingsrates since the 1960s are partily an out-
STRATEGIES
FOR
At
lation agesand the old age dependencyratio rises,an effectseen in studies of European economies and Japan (see Blumenthal 1970; Horioka
1990).
For the HPAES other than Japan, there is litle evidence of the relationship between demographic changes and household savings. The
Singapore study mentioned above showed that most of the increased
savingsrate fiom 19 to 46 percent betwi.:n 1970 to 1989 was attributable to dedining dependency ratios (MonetaryAuthority of Singapore
1991). In Taiwan, China, where household savingsrates are generally
very high, households headed by prime-ageworkers tend to save more,
possibly reflectingin part preparation for old age. (Bursavingsin older
households are also remarkablyhigh and stable, contrary to the view of
the life cyde savingshypothesis [Deaton and Paxon 1992].) Demo,raphic factors may also interact with corpwt"c behaviorto increasesavings. In Japan the tradition of employeesworking beyond retirement age
at reduced wages appears to contribute significantlyto higher savings
rates (Horioka 1990).
PolicyFundamentals
andHighSaings Rates
In addition to benefitingfrom higher growth and demographicshifts
conducive to savings, East Asian governments selected, ofien through
tial and error, a broad spectum of policies rhat encouraged savings.
Two fundamentalsthat facilitated high levelsof savingswere the management of macroeconomic policy and the making of budgetary
choices.
TheRoleofRealInterest
Rates.Foremost amongmacroeconomicfmndamentals was the effort to control inflation discussedin chapter 3. Because high inflation rates also tend to be volatile, real interest rates are
often negativeand unpredictable, discouragng domestic financial savings. Moreover,since unanticipared high inflation erxdes the ral value
offinancial assets,volatilityof inflation ,increases
the riskassociatedwitth
holding,them. Conversely,low to moderate inflation, partculady astable rates, encouragesfinancial savings.Thus the HPAEs' generally superior record at avoiding long-term fiscaldeficitsand restaiing inflation
gavepeople the-confidenceto save (Neal 1990).
Table 5.5 documents average real interest rats in the uAEscompared with other low- and middle-incomeeconomies.Real interest rares
on depositsin the HPAEswere either positiveor nildly negative.In con2.05
MC LE
Table5.5 Average
RealIntkeresRatesonDeposits,
Selected
Economies
-
*.
MJPA&
AIcegtsx
r~~~~~~~~~~~~~~nwiu&wrd
~~~~~~1973-2.
'
* Tan.Iiq,~~~~~d
1
-
Taiwan C.
ThIml
~~~~~~~2.43
.8
4.4197
1177-got
~~~~1976-92
Naqj.dab
NcpI
04
i
'-
.'3
55
~~~~~J314
1935-91
Un4m7
EWF
-.
~~~~~~1976-9
-.
Am.-
'.
'*aIa~~~~~~~~17
-63m-
83
-~~~~~~~~~~~521
144
-243
. -:
:I!-:
;w
334~~19
-. 21033j
9
12793-q
Zsra ore
G2aeret
mAi
average
~~~~~~~~~~LA9
Ism,
~~~1976-1-5
At.tqc
94.9
~~~~
3976-9'
Taft,1
2o6~~~~~~~~~~-l
.2.47
1791443$3'.4
M-ils
uas
7*
~-3.6
117449
177
19,7-91
94-3
',
AS3
1973-90
* MmhI&
-.
-tJ
1Sgonsshw
-5an ecnmc*it1agIeadertso
ae
er
1.
13.1
nZaba.Ra
intercst
109
ra4e
prciinTASseS
weeas'
3
an
evlOS
3
as
STRATEGIES
FOR
'AlI'
TheRoleofPubicSavings One direct way that any government can addressthe concen that aggregatesavingsare too low is to generate public
sector savings through a combination of tax and expenditure policies.
Although in theory forward-lookingprivate saversshould increaseconsumption (and reduce savings)to match any increase in public savings
(becausetheir future obligationsare reduced),in practice householdsare
facedwith liquidity constraints and are not able to act on expectaions.
Thus total savingsmay risewith an increasein public savings(Summers
1985). Empirical evidenceshows that governmentsavingsdoes not fuly
crowd out private savings. Furdtermore, the method of raising public
savings matter.s:on average,increasing public savings via reduced expenditures is more effectivethan raising taxation. For a sample of thirteen
developing
economies,
a transitory
increase
of a dollar
in public
UI4MXLCLE
STRATEGIES
FOR RAI3D
-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-
Taiwan,
ChIna
Singapore
Rep.of Korea
EHPAEs
Oetheeownomies
o,10
20
30
40
Averagepubliccontsumptlon
(percentage
of GDP)
.Soe
_,
orldB2nk6 --
209
!&4iIRfACLE
Table5.6 PublicandPrivate
Savings
of HPAEs
andOther Selected DevelopingEconomies
(pereL'ntage of CGP)
u-blesaings
;
i4o6
J-apa,,*
')0955-70
z |
'
i . R:|?8
~~191480
6
0 17.2t^6.2
4.6
-19714=0
0
312
.2;X
f.;::
-198190.
'2011
0f:
103
187';
15
191i
Singapore.
*.
-4;---o
1981-90'b
1980-B5
1-ft
.--
14.3
-j198
.3-. -- ->;-i24.0
;:'
14
8.6.
.-
Oird deSpigeconemi
-.
-Argendna~S.Kw'lii
-- ;--.1980-85* .....
.
s_
-'
_
,t''-'.''
. 5
I4.2
-19804871,
1980-8.
:: 985647
:
j-
235
1980-84
3.9
*'~~~~ 1980-84~~
*19858
1985~~~~-187
Csti Rica198-8
-~~~
P'ia9i5-8704
.2IO:
~~
.s
'1503
'.--'-,0.;;'--.
2~~~~~~1.6
1364
7.9
06
7.
7.
161
61",
'Philippines~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~J
i.o,9.O
I9
.4-.
,.
,.,
06
1690
1.
97-
'.=-'
I83
STPTRATEGIESFORJLAiPPD&
Coorditon Problems
thatHinder
Savings
Savringsare afficted by severaltypes.of coordinationproblemsinducedbyfeaturesof financialmarkets.Below,webrieflydescribeeachof
thesecoordinationproblemsand the policyresponsesof HPAEgovern* ---ments+The rangeofthe HPAES'
policrresponsesto theses-rual or incipmarker fhiluresrange fiom standard remediesthat the HPAEsmay
...haveimplemented better, such as the prudential regulationof banks, to
-ient
. .~
~~111
I`-
LE
Policies
that PromotedSavings
Governmentresponsesto these coordinationproblems arevaried.All
governmentstake stepsto alleviatethe lackof deposit insurance markets
and to promore stble financial institutions. These generally indude
prudential regulation of savingsinstitutions and protection of depositors from bank defaults. In general, the developing HPAEs have performed these fundamentals better than many other developing
economies.East Asian governmentshave artached great inmportanceto
maintaining saver' confidence in financial institutions. Often their
policieshave gone beyond prudential rgulations to include protectng
banks fiom competition to increasethe financialstrength of banking institutions.1 2 Sometimes this has been done at the expenseof long-nm
efficiency.
When necessary,all EPAR govenments have bailed out troubled financial institutions through financial and managenent assistanceor
mergerswith stronger banks (seetableA5.5, at the end of the chapter).
This isnot to saythat the iEnshave not experiencedbanking crises.Indeed, some financial instability is probably unavoidable in economies
that are expanding as rapidly as those in East Asia Nonetheless, the
crisesthat have occurred,for exanpie,in the wake of the 1980s' real estate speculation boom in Hong Kongi Japan, Korea, Malaysia, and
Thailand, havegenerallybeen brief and modest, particularlyin comparison with the protracted and disruptivebanking crisesin Bolivia,Chile,
Ghana, the Philippines,and Turkey during the same period.
toProaneBank
Solvency.Central banks and departmentsof
Regu;llions
appearto have been generallymoresuccessfulin su'financein the HPAEs
pervising commercal banks, which have reported a rdatively low proportion of nonperforming loans in thcir portfolios. There are some
2.17
STRATEGIES
FOR RAPI
LE
eral and sought to reduce loan concentration by limiting lending to related parties.Enforcemnenr
has been difficult,however,becausecompanies
are doselyheldland dlisdosurerulesare geCnerally
weak.Moreoverinm
severl economies,notablyIndonesia,Japan, and Thaiad, banks and firms
rend to have inrerlikng ownership.
Many East Asian financial systems appear to be moving to ara
mixed system of enfbrce-menr,in which the highly structured exposure
rules that characterizeinternational supervision are backed by traditional moral suasion in which bank regulators use their control of
branch licensing,rediscounts,and other regulationsas leverageto ensure
cooperation.The Bank of Japan, for example, has used constant interaction between city bankcsand the supervisoryauthorities, coupledwith
its tight control of branch licensingi to encourage prudent behavior.
Malaysia'sbank supervisorsoperate in a similar flhshion.
Coping
witfDistessedFinancial
Iustitutioas.
In spite of generaly good
pmudentialregulation, there have been financial crises in Eas Asia
brought about by a mix of macroeconomicshocks,insufficientprudential regulation,and seculative lending (seetable A5.5, at the endtof thechapter). However,goverrnmentsrapid and effTctivcresponsehas been
able to maintain confidenceby acting as implicit insurerwithout excessivefiscalcosts. Rapid growth and spiraling real estate priceshave often
tempted financial instittions into property and sometimesstock speculation. This has happened repeatedly in Hong Kong (in 1965, 1982,
and 1986), but it has also been a problem in Malaysia,Thailandt,and,
most recently,Japan. By the late 1980s, financial institutions in each of
these economies were facing diffliclties, as nonperformningloans rose
due -to the economaicdownturn.
Korea encounteredsimilardifficultiesbut for somewhatdifkirenrreasons, among them the heavyindebtednessof firmnsthat had been beneficiariesof government-directedcredit. 'When exenldemand fell in
the 1980s, many firms had large excesscapacityand poor -debtservice
capability.Among them were gvrmecnt priority projects in shipping;
overseasconstruction, texties, and machinery.Becausethe firms were
highly leverged, they werefinanciallyvulnerableto changesin demandt
and interest rates.
'When fnnildistres
has occurred, HPAEgovernmentshave come
to the rescue_Table A5.5 describesthe originsof and responsesto some
of the significantbanking crisesin the HPAEs.Whil only KoreaandtTabWn, China, have estOablished
explit deposit isurance (both in the
2-4
STRATEGIES
FOR RiAPVT
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1
utations by prudent lendling. Moreover, restricting competition mncreasesprofits, and higher profits increasethe financialstrengthiof the
banking system (provided banks do not distribute profits to shareholders).These effcts would raisesaverconfidenceand hence increase
savings.Yet,in most economnies
regulatorshave arguedthat the financial
sectoes tendency toward concentration is so great that govermnments
must interveneto maintain competitionwithin the banldngsector,preventing monopolistic practices that squeezedlients, reduce efficiency
and innovation,and hence, lowersavings.'
Therefore,whethe-rcontrolling competition results in &avorablcor
unfaivorable
outcomesfor savingsdepe-ndson whetherthe increasedsolvency comes at the expenseof efficiency.The evidenceamong developed economiessupports the view that financial systems with fewer,
larger banks outperform systems with many smaler banks (Vitrs
econoes financialmarketsare domi1991). But in many developening
natal by a few large,veq inefficientbanks whose size is bad less on
economiesof scalethn on restrictionsof bank licensesand othecrlimits
on comp'etinon.
The impact of limited competiton on banking efficiengcvres
acrosseconomiesin East Asia.Japanes commercalbanks, for example,
of the presare regardedas efficient,despite enty restictions,
sure of competition among existing banks (Sakaklbaraand others
1982). Thee is no dominant commercialbank in JapanyThe top five
ban are roughly equal mnsize,and they accunt for about 40 percent
of total commercialbank assets(seetable A5.6). In comparisonto large
German banks, Japanese banks tend to have lower lending margins
(spreads),although smal German banks have lower spreadsthan small
Japanese banks. The Japanese banks also have lower lending margins
tha equivalentbankcsin the United States but approximatelyequal
rates of return oncquity (Ueda 1992). Gross nterest miarginsas wellas
net operating costs (as a percentageOf total aSSetS)ofbanks in KoreaI,
Malaysia,and Thailand werein line with oECDeconomiesand substantialy lower than othecrdevelopig economics notably Liberiof Sri
Lanka, and Turkeysand selectedeconomies in Latin America (Hanson
Be
p
rtn
cot(asofprcetg
tt t)of
- = ner ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~spo
and Rocha 1986). Conversely,studiesof the bankingsystemin Indonesia and Koreafind that protecion has led to lessianovautvepracbtces(nternal World Bank reports).
Thus the evidencedoes not condusivelysuprt the efficacyopl
acesto imitentry.CWhereted,encies toward large nancial institutions
z16.
STRATEGIES
FOR
and lowerinnovation.This is
in some
pentspread
14~~~~~~~~~~~~~
' ---
. \.
- 0-
;
,
'
fl---l
~~
---
-/-
~~~~~~~~~~i
,-m'-.
.-
1-
;(t,~ . K
0~~
2-
-,
1 1-'
1979
1930
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
2988
1989
2;7
..- A GL EL
stricdions
madebanksin East
Asiarlaivelyefficientcomparedwidtthose
in otherlow-and middle-income
economies.
Regulatedspreadsare not alwaysbinding,however,becausebanks
can circumventthem by chargingfeesor requiringcompensatingbalances.Banksin Japan and Korea,for example,chargedcompensating
balances.Thereis someevidencethat thesepracticesweresufficientto
circumventthe regulationsin Japan (Ueda 1992).Intermediationincomeofcommercial
banksin Koreahasbeenhigherthanthesimpledifferencebetweenlendingand depositrates.In contrast,regulationson
dcpositand lendingraceshavebeen bindingin the state-ownedcom-mercialbanksof Indonesiaand Taiwan,China. In Thailand,commercial bank lendingratestended to bunch aroundthe ceilingrate, and
interestratespreadsincreasedslighdyafterthe mid-1980sdueto a drop
in depositratesand the relatively
unchangedlendingrateceilings(aninternalWorldBankreport).
prudentialsuCreatng
PostalSaiugslnsoboansIn additionto effective
pervisionand regulationof entryand spreads,all of whichencouraged
savingsby ensuringstablebanks,Japan, Korea,Malaysia,Singapore,
and Taiwan,China,established
government-run
postalsavingssystems
to attract small savers.Postalsavingssystemsoffrecdsmallsaversgreater
security and lower action costs than the private sector and were
:....
.:
STRATEGIES
FOR. RAPD
jILA~~~CLE
Savings?
HavePordesIncreased
savings?
werepoliciesin theHPAEsaimedar increasing
Howeffective
accountfor
growthconditionsand goodpolicyfundamentals
Favorable
Maoeconomicstamostof East Asiassuperiorsavingsperformance.
bilitycombinedwithsolidprudenrialregulationof financialinstitutions
createdan environmentin which savingsweresecureand retainedtheir
value.Limitsto competitionamong banks and the willinpess of govenments to rescuefinancialinstitutionsin troublehad costs-reduced
STRATEGIES
cxtnalities associatedwith investment.The social return also must acceedthe private returnto jusfyr interveningin households'savingsdecisions. In Japan (during its rapid growth period), Korea, and Taiwan,
China, there is cvidencethat economywideproductivitygrowthhas been
positiveand rates of return to capitalhave been good. In Singapore,however,evidencesuggeststhat aggregae total fctor productivitygrowth is
negativeand rates of return to capitalare low (Young1992). Singapore
may havecompelledits consumersto savetoo much.
Rates
Explaining
EastAsia'sHighInvestment
JNE
OF THE MOST REMARKABLEASPECTS OF THE HPAEs IS
conditions for the private sector tO provide it. Limited econometric evi-
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~22
FOR RAPD
X
i.*
CLE
-- ta
;-Wr
FB!N
cenw
f.
Paetge of
roads
e,
w.c4
odaivr
telhone'
padca
Ec; rsonomy^
0-i- 1971- *1986
_.1975 -1985: g
RPAFs
-
.
100Hong-Kongs
^^.
coe.Rep.
-14 of
. $a1
'
.yuia
. 85
S ;-in
80
,'-. i
'= *r,=,
160.6-18.3
100
62.2
. .....
77
... . .
.2 542
332 . 5621--
Thailand 67
'
49:C-'
- : ; ....
-:11.6
Gn
3182.313t3;
396
--18.2,
,...;
12.4.
34W
muridu
174.2
12
5
6
13
7.9
~~48.0-
24
i95.-- -;309.0,
:..........
11'
98.6:
..528:
79.7
209
89.5
'352,
1 .7
21
-
167
'-20
935
3
,60.0
-hilippine. - - - :--
12 5
..
1P7o-mlj
66
FL
=2.2
16
India
Si
tnlt
242
2818
95 8
.0.0
-. C'Ivoi-e
'205
,~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~--8
-:351'7
<
~~~->-:
M'-'co
4025
7~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~!
KU
W--
STRATEGIES
FORRKR.A%W
ment of decvelopment
banks,and mechanismsto increasetheattraativeness of privateinvestment-and attempts to evaluatewhethereachwas
effectivein increasinginvestment.Wedevoteparticularattention to the
third category,whiichincludesseveralpoliciesthat involvea high degree
of interventionin markets.At the simplestlevel,many HPALEboosted
corporations'retainedearningsby adopting low corporatetaxes.So'me
alsoreducedthe cost of investmentby adjustingtax,tariff,and exchanige
rate policiesto hold downthe relativepriceof capitalgoods.Severalgovermecnts, particularlyjapan, Korea,and Taiwan,China, triedto reduce
risk for investorsby shoulderingsome of it themselvesor spreading it
acrossother firms.The northern-tierFIPAE-s
also stanldout for their effortsto increasedomesticinvestmentby restrictingcapitalflows,Finally,
severalHPAEs,
againparticularlythe northierntier but alsoMalaysia,subsidizedinvestmentfinancingbyslightlysuppressingthe interestrateson
savingsdepo'sitsand corporateborrowing.This last mechanism,which
we term mild financialrepression,playsa k-eyrolein capitalallocaidon,
the subjectof the next chapter.
Bendamd
EqLitMarkets,
Developed
aftertheTakeoff.
Despitethe phenomenalgrowthofAsianco:poatons, bond and equitymarketshaveplayed
a relativelysmall role in Asian finance. As table 5.8 shows,bonds on
averagebetween1970and 1990accountedfor lessthan 10 percentof the
net financingof corporationsfor the fiveHPAEs
forwhichdataexist This is
higherthan the shareof bond finanding-inthe oECDeconomies,however
Ironically,pofides that contributed tcosome of the HPAEssuccessin
developingother financialmarket institutionsmay have been inimical
to the earlydevelopmentof a corporatebond market.In Japan, for example,the long-ternm
creditbanks govermnment-protected
monopolyon
the issueof long-ternm
debenturesdiscouragedthe developmentof bondi
8
markets.' TeTa
governmentcreatedthe samemonopolyfor its private long-termcredit banks.In addition,tb"~lack of governmentsecurities in most HPAEs,
a direct outgrowth of their successat minimizing
fiscaldeficits,has deprivedembryonicbond marketsof the most widely
utilize-drisk-freebenchmarkrate. This has impededcorporatebondtismsues,sincemarketsfind it difficultto determinesimultaneouslythe riskfree,rate and the risk premiumassociatedwiiAa specificcorporatebond.
In response,Hong Konghas issuedbonds,re.-n though the government
did not need the financing,to establisha risk-fleebenchmarkfor the
corpomte bond market. Malaysiaand Sina
ar now considering
followingsuint.
.22.4
STRATEGIES
FOWIRAP-r"DA&
-table5.8.NetFinancing
Soumes
ofNonfinancial
Corporations
in EastAsiaandSelected
OtherDeveloping
Economies
I~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
~~'S57D.75
Malajiula.
I
126-Si
Z'~~~.6
$245
$61
36.125
423
137
'I 0,W~3N
~~ 132-W
293
LI14
14
~~~~~311
.-
IjaV
~~3a~1(tnpI2p.frmr&uu)..'
-3.
971-1113
t1
26.0
1564-US'
-~~~~
4 1m971-$
.0
Ca.uu 3 .I97-Z5~~~~~
.7
'23j.-
47
80.
I L-)
7.7
I&U
LO
L32
--
'0i
10d
jan23.2.&)
!P
LuSti.
v~74;-
1.
23
'
T..wi
b.CaWuW.K
m.a1dua~~~~~~~~~u~~~y.,~~~
_:; immu'
Wu
w0.A,i~
Iua
-VNIIA
hl.1z9h2.~
a
hitoicAym
RamilkWm
been
B.ubumiawamuiEsu
small.Makfhzds
appeamrs
'corporatebonds
have -notibeen?
imnportant-in Asia'stakeoff,:theyrare
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~I
The story for equity markets is broadlysimilar to that for bonds: development has tended to follow rather than lead the HPABs economic
takeoff.In this, the HPAESare similar to other economies. Indeed, recent
evidenceshows thar equity markets do not play a dominant role in capital formation in either developing or industrial economies (Stiglitz
1993a). Even so, as the East Asian economies have matred, govemments have moved with varying degrees of success to promote their
growth by streamlining listing procedures and strengthening safguards
against fraud. In Hong Kong, for example, the govemment pushed the
1986 merger of four competing exchangesinto the unified Hong Kong
Stock Exchange, and it has since gradually strengthened discosure requirements and antriaud safeguards. Korea has prodded firms toward
the equity market by limiting bank lending. Since 1987, Indonesia has
liberalized restrictions on share issues and allowed foreign-owned joint
ventures to operate secur;'ies firms.
Even so, before the remarkable bull market of the late 1980s, Asian
stock markets played a relativelyminor role in the mobilization of capitalexcept in Korea and Taiwan, China, where issues of shares accounted for
more than 10 percent of net financing. Since 1985, new share issues
have increased, and the proportion of external financing from equity has
nisen steeply.
Recent policies to support the development of equity and bond markets have been largely successfUl. The growth of stock marker capitalization in the HrAEs was very rapid in the 1980s, altiough the volatility
of stock prices in response to speculative pressures and capital inflows
may have reduced their value in signaling efficient investments.20
However, the Asian stockmarket boom is a relatively recent phlenomenon, and its timing-beginning long after most HPAEs'economic takeof3swere well under way-suggests that it is a result rather than a cause
of East Asia's rapid growth.
Devopmnt Banks. East Asian governments created a wide range of fi-:
nancial institutions to fill perceived gaps in the types of credit provided
by private entities (see table A5.8, at the end of the chapter). Thcy3addressed the need for long-term credit for industry by creating development banks. Most have also aeated specialized institutions that provide
credit to agriculture and small firms.
-Industrial development banks have been substantial. long-term
leders in Indonesia, Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, China, but not in the
other HPAEs.In Japan, the development banks-the public Japan De-
:226
STRATEGIES
FORP RAPDCG
'
velopment Bank ODB) and the private Industrial Bank of Japanaccounted for about two-thirds of loans outsmnding for equipment investment in the 1950sand about half in the early 1960s. Their share in
total lending to industry was small, however,and has dedinedLAt its
peak in 1953, theJDBaccounted for 18 percent ofnewfimndslent. Sarting in the mid-1950s, job lending fell to 1-6 percent of new lending;
the rest was accounted for by private banks (Kawaura 1991).21 The
Korean Development Bank made an averageof a third of all loans and
guarantees in the 1970s, and the development bank of Taiwan, China,
the Bank ofCoimunications, holds about half of the assetsof the banking-system. Conversely, Malaysias development financial institutions
repayment rates; a representativesample of eighteen industrial development banks in developingeconomies had on averagenearly 50 percent
of the value of their loans in arrears (World Bank 1989c). The most
commonlycited causesof developmentbank flilureshave been political
pressiureto finance bad projectsand the poor incentivesfor and capability oFfinancialinstimutionsto screen and monitor projects.
Development banks have performed much better in the HPAEs, especially those banks in the northern tier economies concentrating on industrial finance.2 Fmancial performance has been adequate to good,
and the capacity to evaluateand monitor projects has at least in Japan
created spillovers for the resr of the formal financial.systen (JDB/JERI
1993).23Successfildevelopment banks in East Asia have applied commercial criteria in selecting and monitoring projects and firms, even
- bwihin
the constraints set by government prioriiy activities. Development banks in Japan and Singapore,for example, must select projects
that-will repay, since the banks are expected to repay with interest the
--funds thy obtain from the government Taiwan, China, introduced another mechanism when in the early 1960s it required borrowersreceiving fumdsfrom the U.S. Agency for International Development to put
-upmathing funds and made lending to a nonperformer a criminal offensei imposed on:the loan Officer.
227
Policies
tolacrease
theAttractiveness
ofInvetmnt
Besidiesfostering a dimate conducive to investment, encouraging
bond andiequity markets and, in some instances,establishingdevelopment banks, each of the HL'AEsresponded to coordination problems
that hinder investment with a variety of mechanisms to make private
investment more attractive. Like most other governments that have
tried to increaseprivate investment,the HPAEsembodied many of these
pro-investment policies in their tax codes. These codes varied across
economies and over time, both in their specificintentand in the degree
of succe-ss,but have nearly alwaysaimed broadly to encourage invest-'
ment. Becausetax codes are often central to the quait-y of the investment climate, this section begins with a brief survey of tax policy in
each of t-hewpAEs. We conclude the section, and the chapter,with a discussion of foiurhighly specificmechanisms usedtin some of the HrWAEs.
to encourageinvestment. low relativeprices for capitalgoods, risk slaring, controls on capital outflows,and mild financial re-pression.
TaxPolicies,
to Encorage
Investment
The HPAEShave employed a widle
variety of tax policies to increase investmnentby raising the retained
earnings of companies. On one extremne,Korecaand Taiwani,China,
used complex tax codes not only to favor investment but also to direct
the pattern of their industrial development. On th: other extreme,
Hong Kong has maintained a simple and largely neutral tax structure
with lo croaetax
rates. Other tax policy regimes fll inxbetween..
Singapore uses taes to promote industrialization and to attain social
objectives.Indonesia and Malaysiahave relied heavily on oil revenues
andt so until recently have paid little a-ttention to other aspects of tax
policy. Like Korea and Taiwan, China, Thailand has tried to use tax
policy to provide investment incentives; however,weak administrative
cap.abilites mean such efforts have been distortionsxy rather thin
2oi.
STRATEGIES
FOR
RA
helpful. Box 5.2 further explores these issuesfor Korea, Malaysia, ant
Thailand.
Below we review briefly the investment-relatedaspects of the tax
structr in each of the developing HPAEs.
* In Taiwan, China, income taxes generate only a small share of revenue because of extensive exemptions. Income from dividends and interest were tax-exempt until 1981, as were capital gains until 1989.
Corporate tax incentives have also been extensive. Research and development expendituresare exduded from the tax base. New industries receive a five-year tax holiday, and industry generally is offered accelerated
depreciation of investments. Industries that the government deems
strategic receive additional special tax credits (Tanzi and Shome 1992).
* Korea was the first HPAE to estblish a value-added tax (VAr).The vAT
in Korea provided revenue to support incentives for investors in indusry,
particularlyexporters Tax incentives induded credits, accelerated deprecKorea has
ation, and special exemptions. In contrast with the other HPAEs,
continuously fine-tuned itStax policy to promote industrial development.
From 1953 to 1986, there have been nine major tax reforms.
* The most distinctive feature of Hong Kong's tax policy is its low
rate strucmre and the low level of revenue it generates. The maximum
personal income tax rate is about 15 percent, while oorporate income
taxes are 17.5 percent. Hong Kong uses low taxes to attract investments
in contrast to the mix of high tax rates and high tax incentives offered in
Korea and Taiwan, China.
* Singapore's tax regime is as interventionist as those in Korea and
Taiwan, China, but focuses special incentives on foreign investors and
on promoting savings. (Contributions to the Central Provident Fund
are tax-exempt for both employers and employees.) Malaysia has the
highest level of taxation. Its tax-GD? ratio averaged 21.45 percent in
1979-88 but fcil steadily during the period because oil revenues
declined without compensating increases in non-oil revenucs, and the
government continued to expand tax incentives to sustain its industriilization drive. The resulting high deficit and emergng constraints on
spending have focused attention on the need for systematic tax reforms.
* Since the 1970s Indonesia has relied heavily on revenue from petroleum andgas, and did not until the early 1980s use tax policyforspecific
incentive objectives. In 1985 in response to dwindling oil revenues, it
embarked on a comprehensive reform that unified personal and corporate-income taxes, introduced value-added and urban real estate taxes,
229
2~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~i
; =L
;Wni XV
x.2'.fCTL
r
e.
Ei
~~~~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~~~-
q'
adeimntd
obse
. -
fill
Thiln
hii~~~~
-~~pa
-~~~~4
'
-..
clisroriions
fzsoeo
H2AEs.
Business
and incorne
and
pe.n.men.I
-ae1nealwrkda
cetie
apert
conrs
wihtora
aedoemr
a eeroesysc
mx rerenuesP~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
_,
increasing
otcmpe
xEsn
amtl
ode h
-,. .,. .
: S;
5.o:
oermn
f,
.
,-
:aea.s
iuiesnaX
*~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~er~-n
t.,
frts
-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~k
y
.. compl .n
-:f
.~
~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~11ta-t
_ ,
.
.
i:~~~~~-2i
:xI
raS:
ac.. ;.'-V
~ f.eos~av-~~t~
~
oX-, o1anes--
mn
~~~~tahnueabwidrgary
Crmpevi aindii~,lackFTof
b
~.
-~~~~~~A
n0tvsNewon
in rKlucing
: .
f - -
.n
o,
-
0;
:-f
p-:
FOIR-
STRATEGIES
4e~~
17:&tu~t
r,
,*.
4.
Z>-
- .
!14r
fr^Mstoa
{g'
.omorumavntaaeealorne
hstrowCr,,>.mdlnon;
ow
ts)boni.tacnnve~idrssi. rte
xbat'flpC
rte-
'lmiberoniboanM
baafpmeERm-@edlafsicrtoqsnutoC*Ddae
~ 0,fl
GDP~Its
'tl
f1
49.W4.,.
5
!5j7crceXu
alyEboult
&rntlolsescllubTncd
sFMi
PgrOwd ~- S16
ite:
n~
at
,J
=lMQl:}enn,>zem
- 'zi*:<firtl*8if
rmi4mlulceSeancQgi
4$i.<v:eiopmencfI
e ^D
3
4
t.ct
jO?9S
onoImc,3n&213
f,!ri<
-.-.{S
.~~~.rDooe>Doeiln
*^
5brd
gu
c-..s%
mictaves:ant
4nordi#Pnd
w*kw4ti4<_4$SF->
aji&ht
eau:tvrgone:revcnuc.
N~S
de2Tmcnc
-N
ooteono
*u;lro:et
~~~~~~~~~~
tZib1c$varro~~~~~~adn
ra-I
*in mostroftherHrAEswitha2ctvisttax polldies~itrislikelythatrthey raised aggregate welfare But the administrative burden associated withi a compliCared tax incntitructure
costs itself The success of ocher economies in East Asia, such as Hong
Kon
with very low but unifrm. tame on corporate incomes, suggests that:
LowRelative
Pties forCapital
Goods.Unlikemostrocher
low-and middleincome economies,the H-iPAEs
wereable to hold down the relativeprices
of invertment goods, especiallyequipment, during the 1980s (Bhiartacharya and Page 1993). Figure 5.4 shows the relativeprice of investment of goods (ratio of the investmentdeflator to the GDPdeflator)for
forty economies for whi'ch consistent real private investment data are
ava-ilable.F-orthe group as a whole, the price of investment goods increasedabout 15 percent fasterthan all otlicr goodsduring the 1980s,in
part because devaluationsincreasedthe domestic price ofinmportedand
import-intensiveinvestment goods.
The HPA.Esarc different in severalways. First, the relativeprice-of'mnvestment goods remained lower than in other developingI economiues
:i~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
throughout the global economicexpansionof the 1970s and the adjustment period in the 1980s. Second, the relative price- of investme'nt
goods declined during the early stages of adjustment frm 1980 to
1984-a period when they were rising in most other developing
economies-and
only began
to rise in'1985, when
the HiPAEeconomies
letog
od rtoo
h necetdfao
oteGrttso)fo
werewell on the way to recovery.By 1989, relativeprices betweenHPAES
fr hih onisenrrel riat iarsten
dt0ar
-foerecnoie
and ocher economies were again aligned. Thus in these economies de-.
h middle-ncmconcs
rieo tenetmn
od-n
104lbe
awoe
NowLMeafe oregopa
ices fo=aia
od low-niems
and
Figure5.4 InvestmentDeflator/GDP
Defator
-
ta~~~~~~~~Suceay
PeTrandPand
Index1970
_
Mad93).a (1992)
hwv
daieprc
f net
120 -
middler-ievlopin
than .
vestme.t godsreaie lower
ir~~~~~~~~~~~~ource
Pout-an
th lbleooi
Madaassa(I 92xaso
- ;:
122
e.peidi2h328sScnd
232~~~~~~~~~1
economnies
fe17sand
eaiv
rc
f neimn
STRATEGIES
FOR
RAPI
Iiwestwm Some
HPAE govemrnments,
primarily
in
: :: gC -:
0
A CLX
_EEFLE
V-~~LE
Performancecriteriaplay an important role, even in declining industries. Interacton among firms and between firms and MITIare a means
to prevent free riding and to monitor performance.Thus the organization of an industial adjustnent assistanceprogram in Japan conforms
to the model of contests presented in chapter 2 and suggests that
economies without similarlywell-developedinstitutional capacitymay
wish to avoid the commitments to orderly exit policies.
In some HPAEs,most frequentlyin Japanand Korea,troubled priority
projects have been bailed out by the govemrnment.
Often, the financial
cost of the bailout was large. In Japan the govenment took over some
lossesassociatedwith financingdecdiningindustries,such as in coal mining. When govenmuent-supportedheavyand chemnical
industry projects
in Korea experiencedsevereexcesscapacity and financial diffidultiesin
the 1980s, the governmenzprovided seventy-eightdistressedfirms with
new, subsidizedloans (totaling abour 16 percent of commercial bank
loans)and rescheduledoutstanding ones. The govrncmentalsoprovided
banks, whose nonperformingloans rose substantiallyand whose profits
dedined (partly becauselending rates werecut), with subsidizedcredit
from the Central Bank and allowedthem entry into attractiveareasof financial services.In Indonesia, the govemment bought 35 percent of the
STRATEGIES
FOR RAPI
Dcvcdopmenrbank lendingmay also confrr implicit insurance.It fiequendy signals areas of government commitment, providing an additional measure of comfort to private investors and banks JDB/JERI
1993). These commitments may extnd to efforts to ease adjustment
problems in promoted sectors. With government inducement, the Industrial Bank of Japan has led syndications for firms in distress and
forced their restructuring&substituting for liquidation or external
cakeovers.In the 1980s Koreaextended cheap development bank loans
to firms that were nor meeting their debt obligations.
Has bounding risk contributed to growth?Bounding risk by the private sector was apparently successfulor at least not a fitilurein Japan,
Korea,and Taiwan, China, but this is almost unique comparedwith the
experience of other economies, developing or industrial. Risk sharing
generates moral hazard problems, which Japan, Korea, and Taiwan,
China, attempted to contain dtroughfostering insitutions to monitor
priority projects. One consequenceof shared risks was shared monitoring by the private and public sectors. Severalinstiutions, induding development banks, private financial institutions, firms, and various
ministries in the governmenr,often had stakesin the implementation of
the project. The government's role as monitor of firms was important.
For example, Korea'sfinancial policies promoted high leverage,which
made firms vulnerable to loan rol over decisions of financial insttutions. Since the government was able to influence which loans were
rolled over, it was able to use them as a lever for elicitingcompliance
from firms (Sakong 1993). Similar monitoring was rarelyoresent in the
Southeast Asian HPAEs, with the consequence that attempts to bound
risk there were not successful.
Coeralson CapitalOufflows.Restrictng capital outflows is one of the
f-a.;;..
5Y
WVhatimpact, then, do capital export restrictions have on accumuldadion?The obvious fuilure of such restrictions in economicesprone to capit-alflight suggests that capital is too fluiidto be retained wvhendomestic
conditions are inimical to savings and investmenc. Therefore the simplest explanation for the seemningsuccess of these restrictions in Northeast Aiistathecnmsoffered
returns adequate to retain capita
even without restrictions. Converely, for reasons we discussed in chapter 4, these particular governments have been unusually successful in
eliciting the cooperation of economic elites, t-he very groups and individuals who might otherwise shiip capital offihore.
Thus, for certain periods in these dthre economies, government restricdions on outward capital flows may have contributed marginally to domesnc accumulation, if only by raising the risk and therefore the cost of
sending capital abroad. If so, such restrictons; which have the potential
disadvantage of driving otherwise legitimatc ecoonomnicactivity underground or even provoking capital flight, would rank among the comparatively risky interventions that are likely to prove successfujlonly in
economies that have able bureaucracies and have already established the
fundamentals of growth. Moreover, as the trend toward capital account
liberalzation in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, China, suggests, retrctions
are probably useful orl4 for a lImited dimc: as economniesgrow, becoming
more sophisticated andi more dloselylinked to international markets, restrictions on capital exports inhibit efficiencyand must be dismantled.
In aniy event, the success of the more open BPAEsundermines any
suggestion
that
capital flow restrictions are somehow necessary for savings and growti. Hong Kong, Malaysia, andlSingapore have all achieved
1Z36
STRATEGIES
FOR R
AR
CL
e
dn
d&rgdl
~
guhuS
k4
U2
T heHofNavust
assessme
suggests'rle'op
5 fnanr
meore,s
L4i
rs
$
nhgh9
sfrgsures to
flV.w%
1"
.a
~4W
~oi'nrArf
iJ*&V
beresoom s codnsitn
se fzinanchial
Hoevr,83acile
elctdco&nomic naecitlrsea.
time or notherheldrntcrestirtes4below
nnthelsHacShaeveinog used ancmia
hl
makt-dZaringlcv
citen
repressionasgrea
and
de-nia
23-8
STRArEGIE
=t~~~~~~~~~~~~~NT
.
37
RAIDXO
R0
=~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~t
S T~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
RAE
;7;;
SF
X.
2
-; . .
nr+ridd
rd4
-uMffiedylwn
.iis
a4the'interestr
s
- rpn
9SiytoiBhves
overrnment
hogusaneo ser,Un
Cld
ie
oRnted,thes
y.$0
ulbCC&
-:cooiesinmthreeaimpom.nvhent
rElativdy
moderate arldw
in
pen;istndy
...
subidy
-:
sh
mchiaseher
aatet
r poirsii bostp
cij
2
dshedrefeeshiond
-lir`dexcepions
di
notcrtoet
as.
Iit
of euryn
ubkflt&7Q
wasmo
tablea5.5
In
i3rprsso
*r
s-
d &MCM-.-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
iid
real.ninterestrat
.-
mrgina
e
ipnvacerafinnci
12
has
r:Fa
t
ODW.nm_xc0xnVcbUarQto.%cn
n
the
cc, .' t ;:l
t3.es.
* - -ment.by reducUingborrowig
pmasewoduc-s
andservces'inuluhdprvate
b
iid it
ae
in a enon h&gbvn
merntnenrghn
non
ieod
A.....
- fiom
.to firsns
househol
inreases the oolorate!profitabljusvof invest
;
::: ofth
flfiC0
duringn
--.g
,J
to2E'eooctaefprosbpo
'qiymru
- -FandiadorpressincinthuHAEghs
s
iffered froimlatStin ro.swd
o
nthernasrxcs
from
ousehlds o frms inceaesth crprates proitbiit1o
iinvest-.trq
i4owe
=--
the euityoffins,
nablig thm toinvet inriskier-projetsnd bo
Uo
ings is,'more
sufficiently
low
and
t
corporate
sector has a highe
financethese
to
projec.' Thi
ma hvepadyofe
te marginal
eanes
.~~.+*~a.-,..-~ off'
-..
mareooi
an
was
conseque
*1-ai
urintede
no
--
..-
havteshowninychapktedri3g
rheprsion wasonderctakenoifapenvironmentpro
oFmnancninic
rpestainintye
ecoomis
HandEws
nohes unintened
rmta conmseqecofhe
W27S.rlrt,
i
thee
mpotanhe
legee
rpresio3Wa
N.
-of
L E .
0~~~n-t
,~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
~
1p
-,w
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
:
.-
':~~~~~~~~9O,9
.2
,-'''
;':~~~~~~~~~~~a
~unosyxyi}neetrtSadvabnod
~ xb~
--lasqueezetL+Si
: -
..
FQ15g"fim%1,,.,-1B
I.;-i
e:on
"Minterajelnal=knsa
_>9-=
neFEen^o,rmn
B
. Xtn<sn
or4-mom
oisbly
eottzSnprXdarmem;
s;-
.~~~~~~~~R~p
Siz.EbrincrS
pl,o
in,rainrasne.-dig
0_,ovn
2r-
.:~~~~~~~a
.%>l-
-tuv--tr>>
rv;s.>
r.4 }
~ ~~~ ~~~ ~
~oovr>navnolX
~ ~
.f~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
oryaetd::-..
-v>l-t-)
cuuenw,te
mxtl!oruenv
sann=
: f^we*,a
ts^
itrFt..4->><stxts,t<i/gt;
,,>,'gsSw4'St;t
_.I
9WillhOtilL9tlt'iOiEiittCrClltOnnpis-:SIi
~,-;
er..
N...................
rv-S ,
\*.M1 sRonn
z:pRrC=sOn,,wo
aculii4tz1-
wt1E
-;Si
-;;f4
cosraire-mti=ur.a:
1uuNvdeLAtsts@
_N
-tU
~~,r-J;.>a)>iJ--.i
b
pem6d
a '<l-'4' '^
P
j>S;<,
2* s- e r., Xs >
I_
c.en
ponsdw7e.cmpabl
aiS^-
0',''~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
'V
:
~ - ~ ~~~~~~~~~r
-icmiemltGsaco
I B;be>vE;uldshor-rem;tfinancrqprn=svsitrmalsmm4ia;UkI,
: . ; I g ;,=
E >*-5s-^st2
Srsge
~ ~ ~~ ~ ~
.4
,fF
,4
l- =J oSaN
t:' _fi< .
i
Id_
dA
g4i
ul
~~~~~~contos.ce
X$Sssrtmus y>dforeacchan^
;-bod
-. ec:
oemihan a6ouvzRcDrcenq-,.t.s
dw mtnznllts-isl-mmedoucti;.
irg;ont
A*
{--
-Wofnloin
itres-onldt
on+
'
'+!F
S..
os
et r >Et
s:
s--a
{ 4swrs emosd(firsJ.
.lE:reaLtdepoitr atesas iw
> ,",snewep.zSerm
68.;e.
&1t'aifer-
T,1
~S- t',S:-
6ti-;5f
=tr2aonnPnrllgno-vnvscLitg.de6tea
v sr-eecv4ec,.ak-o
; ;
t
,,
r,
<S:t' n
- *t i :
-vat.FSeracser.
} "~~~~~~s
vereLstri
--
Ji
Of.ii.rAdilICDO:4Wai&
&1
-O
Sg.^=^,
wer s>.w--\*1.tPGK>
fNtf<!
mof-
uS.7;1vt
bzmatH.fRftAS;sf-he;Ho
S-,R,;wiftW:2.S'sruXs
.{2;;7t>iv1X;742-r
it^.=x
4.-*l -. -r-9. Pj
. f.mE~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-m
;
"Proodx
tssXadMeneeRnf>Bcue.i
zn-<S'6Stae>-en
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~a.-::'
A.,~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
':
.
| - r
:
-
0 -
1, ' '
';--
'
. - 0 f' -7-'
;.~.
stuleding
:
''
;:
.- '
e~~~rapifinfancial
.0
- '
'-.
.
ers,
*,~
-' ~~~
,,
~ ~~~~~~~~~~~hs
0,'
'
thsaye,
indtwirdl
sp=,d,
hav
cosqu-e
.
:--
to
tleatlo
repression
arue
rhatidie
on
WSuring
finiandial
bankt
ehansth
wercpaed
Nonethesltni
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~tde
o.- ~ ~ ~ ~. ~
..~
-f0~
~ ~
-~ ~~
~ ~0 ~ ~ ~ ~~eav
,
rate
households)
.-
Av
in
racsae
pId
into
at
(Wrl
depositorsla
posauedo
dmanct
'
8).e'
frae
efetos'ofmow:ayic
reslt
Bank
is infiin
SevAeralc
1989:
Fr
and
198.
pes
:0:,-':
Svrate
th
e.msancs.-stngin2da.r
dcepoit.
rorld ations).
mess
~ ~ ~~~m
grwt
foth
resuts
raest
thrd
fo
that
borrw
with geneitie.
tha
eguatossquee
:.:
has
:on !'paricuarl
e,'-t'o
mod--,-
d-':
STRATEGIES
Evn widhoutfinancialrepression,banks do not allocateloansto the highest bidders. Since biddersfor credit offrerpromisesrater than payment,
banks must evaluate the bidders and decide which promises are most
likelyto be kept. Since rationing alreadytakesplace in financialsystems,
the additional impact of moderate financial repressioncan be relatively
small. Indeed, credit rationing may actually be good for growth, if the
mechanismused to selectborrowersgeneratesincentivesto perform. For
-emmple,Japan, Korea,and Taiwan,China, allocatedsubsidizedcredit on
the basisof past performance,usuallywith exportsas the criterionof success.Since the valueof subsidizedcapitalwas high, firms perceivedhigh
marginal returns from greater effort and competed accordingly.We explore this finction of credit allocationin detail in chapter 6.
Did moderate financial repression hinder growth? We address this
question by examining the relationships between income growth, real
interest rates, and inflation using two statisticalmethods and two data
sets:a sampleof nineteen economiesthat includesa subserwith positive
real interest rates, and time-seriesdata for Korea and Taiwan, China.
(Details are in appendix 5.2). In the nineteen-economiessample, inflaton rates are far more important in explaininggrowti than real interest
rates. i the subset of economieswith positivereal interest rates, the inwrtestrate is statisticallyinsignificantand actually has a negativeeffect
on gowth when inflation is included.
Similar tescscan be made using time-seriesdata for Korea and Taiwan, China We use the differenceberweenthe curb rate and the institutional interest rate as a measure of financial repression.Its coefficient
is statisticallyinsignificant.In Korea, inflation and the curb market rate
(our proxy for the equilibrium interest rare)significantlyexplainincome
growth. In Taiwan, China, none of the variablesis significandy related
totrhe growth rate. While these testsare not condcusive,they support the
view that moderate fnancial repression did not necessarily hinder
growth in Korea and Taiwan, China.
Which were the factors that contributed most to the HPAEs7 extraordinary record of accumulation over the past thirty years?Judgments
are difficult,given our incomplete understanding of the costs and benefits of all the policies used. But on balancethe common elementsacross
the eight emnomies tend to favor the importance of doing the finda-mentalswell-encouraging stable and predictablemacroeconomicenvi.,
. =
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~4
FOR
P.A P,r.
.~~~~~~~~~~dr
'.
Appendix
5.1: Granger
Causality
Testsfor
Savings
RatesandGrowthRates
EXISTENCE
OF A REIATIONSHIP
BETWEEN VARlABLES
fluence.Granger-typetestsareofienusedto test forcausalitybetweentwo variables,in this casethe growthrate of realcD per capita
i) and the grosssaving rate (s).Testsweredone for regressionresult
fir the eight East Asian economiesand the United States. Vectorauto-
g=X
k-I
(5.2)
s=
k-
S*-k +
k-I
242
s,+,i
g',- +
grk-I
STRATEGIES
FORItAI
'.
,cmy
-.
-i
Hog'Y
'cora,Rep.of-'
1 'aaysi=5.
147
90
Primacy - ;C
180.5
512
32
8.15581
3898
'
810.2*
352.5
t0xnanana
-67i
i49
-8340O
1881
.176
,;j 09699
572.5
314.7
~~~~~~~193'3.
PT
t~ e
-' Seconday
1923.-3
28
1975:18
-.
~~2.
I 778.0.' 1r2
~~ 'Brazil
I
_-'3
India53
~23&
Mexicot.
0j
76.9
1~~~~~~~~~79.1-'
15.4-22.
175
4
-
713
566
2 9
~~~~
9
30.9
~~~~~~~~27
62.3
3.
~~~~~~~~5038
1210
312
`6
'
10.
875'
)3
,..,
fl wwevtAunat.wl
c
tea,
'UNFUd--.
ta.
' '.
243
~~~~~~~
~
*~~~~~~~
~~~~Sig
Si
0
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
jas
1S
.m
S -8
MSN NS~~~~S
3;.KS. .
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-
S,
-,*-tX
Kqq,-S--
'
N'S
MS'
Mdapua1-
;-i
Z g,;t-fI..
. ..
g
~~~~~~~
..
SBal
.Si
, -~.
Ng~~~~~~~a
Si
-Si
S .i-41rs
NS
MS
.~~~~~~~S
.~~~~~~~
KS
16
,~
~~~~Si
MS
11
-,
Mg~~~~~~S
'
115_ ; ;.
.2
PM-
S
la
In.i
-S
Si
K~~~~~~~~~~Si,
Ti wuyo-u
"S
~~~ ~
- '
~:
~
.-
~~~~
~2
'
,,-
MS
:7
md &"
244~~~~~~~~~~
~ -~ -;~ ~ ~ ~
luhLgO8
''
KS
gX
STRATEGIES
FO
EGERAYIF
NoteontheRelationship
5.2:Technical
Appendix
between interestRatesandGrowth
P;
(5.3)
changes in growth
monetary
also indude
system
in 1973.
Both
Fry- and
positve
and statistcally
rate).
High
negative
ordinary
least
data Both
dine-sries
significant
relation-
Fr,
it fahils to disinguish
system repression
(the dif-
repression
financial
by the equation.
economies
with negatve
5.3,
or positive ef-
These difirences
or in-
Woods
between
Gedb apply
to pooled cross-economy
rates following
plored
equation:
G= consrant +-IRu+
Gelb's equations
whereas
can be ex-
to degree of financial
real rates of interest
problems
rates as well.
245
constant fPi,R+
J32 1NF:.+
STRATEGIES
FOR,
Rea hien
'; aJrnsr&-vru.'
~~.L. rw&ratr''Whole
sample(2S):-
P1=2
92
; ;7s
Ekiuado .Rn
1.
-.
rate
. .;.
- ..
-.
f
,F-
Rea *cur
*b.,,
=
interest rnf
,.-
;
0.148
-000;;
1
<tLLUL
LAJIA
5
tuft*nn.. .
'T,
~~~rat
- -'.'-'
A,
0.277
Subsamplcof&os
o-i;
AX
C5
tri-ot
Equaiontl
-.
>tT-.>g
. .
,
'
-0-:
'
i Equaon&
2
Equarioni)..
0.391~~~0.
;'w-.
0.059
Eqarin3 -- . A389
M6
WattTrto-sSt
aeEa
i
on
Icr............,;><,.
regesons
were
.
.;:-;frA.
on
estimated
>:
<
..-
of w-
hmp b
the nm
suhsampl.ofcaniameoLswason
otlie
swarcw&iBank
dima
2;
-~-::~;0363u-
0 438a
C~1;peratlewd.,'
Ieastst
-~
x0
-: -
:l'
r..
;:. f!:.y*:...............
,.. ...... , .. -
:-
the subsample of economies with positive real interest rates, the coefficdent of the
realinterest
inflation is induded. Then the coefficient of the real interest rate is sig.nficat and ngative, suggestingthat lower real interest rates may have
had a positive impact on growth. The coefficient on inflation remains
negtive and significanL
'Table A5.3 also reports estimares of a time-series analysis of the relationship of interest rates, inflaton, and growth in Korea. A third equa-
dudced, the real interest rate is no longer significant, but the real curb
rate is. When the infladoti variableis added, the eal curb rate rerains
highly significant,but the real interest rate and the inflation rare do not.
'When the same tests are perfonned on time-series infboration for Taiwan, China (not reported in tale A5.3), the esdmatedcoefficientshave
the samesignand similarmanitudes as those for Korea,but the standard
errorsaremuch largerand none of ti coeffiacntsisstatisticallysignificant.
747
fI.
F--ACLE=
- Table
AIA
IcomeDo Rzobution
shareof.
GNPper
:: - -..
cap
iib
omm 2
Ec--fonomy,;- .f(perytr) -t
; :pon~f;= =2 1:
I96590
: .HogIong-'Indonesia)
9AEV-Japa
Ysrr
.-
71
4Maaysia"'
=
tq.
-gapo 6.5:
Taiwan,China.
1976
Thailandh
-
1975-76 5.6
4.4
*.
f.OzhtAid
5.2
4317.95
6.1;
.51.2
'
--16.03
E11.1
991982683
6-.-.
-3.68:
8.89
35.0
:49.8-
.I - 00---
.;53.9
f51985
--l985b;.- --0
5
-;;
.48.0'
*-0
8.7
74
;375
453
5.1.
995.
hovsseholds
-47.049.4-'
41.0
19e
g70-71
- 03.7
PhilPEippines000:
1.i3
14.6
8.7
Brad!....
-. taiRica
..
1983' 2.47
626
26.0.
1.4
.:.
'1;:-971.
3;3'..........
54.8
} :t. ~~~~~~~~~-.;
54
8c8--S
......;:--1 -16.61.51-41986" ~..3 33 -.
-Mco
p~.
-I{
.
5.4A
--6.6
.0'-.
1973:3.5
. .0;198T'0.:4G6
R -
pertof
pferentof
7.9
*0-XX1979..
'
8.7
1976.- '5.7
f-
tope
botm20
eholkoouse hold
6.;62 1980'
4.50 0>i1976'
4.r
i1~ ; 1969`
Korea,Rep.of
of
arof:
:top20.
...
;.
3..
3
1972
3i3
-5.6.5
2.8
0.2
- - ^: --:- - -- .
1977 2.9
1I72
;L1-98546w 44< -
V&elzuea
2.0
- '_!.
-10
00
0
1970
-.-
57.7--0.
i-9
:5139
3.0
.-
7197'
-:.
19.9
2.11
179
;.:-54.0
.
.- ....................
{;
;76
0~~~~~~~~~~~0
iBoiswana.
--^
=' -- :i -4- 19856 --`2'.:
Cbce'Ivi-re
05
198- ;8-T50
Gh-.na
',-.
dia
-14-.
1-9
19s8j9'
a.-~~
1 ''i ''
--- 248---:-
~~
'
, 0 -..
. -
~
i"'
'.
~~~t'.nerprcznmoc
q
'
'-a~
'
-..
r.
'-,:
10 5
rt
7 .:
- n s04..
00-
527
'19645
-9 6.7'
1975-76
50
48
7.2
49:4
314....
-.
-s.-u
r'|
bou'e.i"k.c'p.ndz'ut.
'~.D
.o
.-
STRATEGIES
FOR RA:PtDiW
.:'Enfisrj
::s
..-- Ninedeposi:-aingc-
T-TnnHon
na
-1982-83
....
b.
- ,
Japan.
: -
--;- :-.
Thegovement rem
and mismanagement.
* andw
wak prudential
...-
regation.
1rg*itrst
..
.' ;..---
t- res
large-exposureto real
The gormentookoverthe
estatelendingand spillover lagebankcandintrduced ne
effers fiom 1983crii
in
cludingtopexecusince che banks o-;ccL- -sewn&de
t-v
from tceJargeieo rnDTCs
'
aSsubsidiaries.
(a) Excive
and a
4,
- ;.
'
'~~~I
-'
'
-d,
.i44~~~.;'C~~ijrr.
SI"' ':ononur
X . . 4- ,- ' .
dthecosto,
de&eoftbsie
among commercia bank.;
:i'
..
M
i"
'.
Bank
iiit of
OXi
P-
r exposuredititugh
Ins to
nonbanic
,ic
,.gee'
nieterealsoiinacial dis-
...butOO~~
~ .1C
~
t
dalinstidon,and
---
one deposit-
and4 (of
= 47) i'Iedfe
naiicecompa
1'
lon to be
-.
~~~cooperatie
ini8cuec
88.rins:
tO
ban-sNo-~
transu
-a-lureof
'1985-88
4.
rnergerioFweaker
epdeclinein
'
were:.s;rale to
..
Encourage
--- realestatelending,corn-1
prisi about 90 pcentofthe bid loansofd
systrem:ase,.S. .n
nrial
me.
by thgovernrmenrreaivedcrdt
from toher
com rcialnk
reg-
ulatoryandaudiuing
system and
tr
ACenini
; -l991
11;
m or:.
--
Hihinternational
g;or&.,
inhteiiga
[7stwi
or re
(a) rg exposurc
toreal
eestateiled
lending f-raud
t*
1{o4 Kong,
:1;8-86 ::
Nature ofbiot
Causes
.n7.'
i..,u..
,.-
n.r-'$20
4..h,4.to
s,.
J8'4r y0'"C-:
..
~~~
OUr1Uust:-&rnpan
_S
n
~~..
.-...
Z L'ooeratLVeS
ae
,L'
-J,
.luo
trbek~
.
'S44.
(&4kivirnnre
-. '-
opt
-
,,..
,-4
Z9
249
LE
TableASS (coawiaWed)
Economy
NantresJiitttn.iI
ThailandL-1983-87
Thegovernment'st
ofbout of 50 financecompanies
w..as
estiinatedtUS$190 milion or 0.48percent ofGNP.
- 0f:-; ---ii -
0 .X
-*--
t 3 u;9 ; - - ; -
45
.an
() EHigh
concenaon
unscuredinsider
loans.
financial-difficulties
in
(c Hit
*a
000t9B6-;87
1 - '' .< < ' ->>
g 50t,0 -0"~
~-
- 0- - 0- -; -:0~;
-.-Mat-uri-y
-t soldthmto ncwmvsots
-
ands
tinvestors
i
n o
banks)
It bouiht someshares ofrou-
bledbank
-
.6
'
-'
--
ksocaeda-Ioarid
to_provid emnergec loans to
rubd
-TheRind
would be finlancedby contribui-:
tions frdmn
commercial-banks.Trobe
-m-00-orriom
t
of
Matitymismatchesof
.Troubled
assetsand liabilitiesas
liqudat
~~~~~~~~~~~~~interestrates
woscandi
- -
The governmentliqtuidaed 24
financecompanis and-meriged
another 9, andthe Centra-:
Bank cookoverthe other 17
:
of
te
" - - inestrae
mowwcre'
~~~~~~~~~~~~inadequate
Capital
~~~~~~~~~~~~~requirements-,.
*
-*:
Five
0 ,commercialbanks
accounting for 24 percent ofcommercia bank assct were in
-.
fbaib ut
Aauee
-5banlholdingsofbadconcrpe
cost
est
&iiloutrct
dat
-was
US$6bil-
7 .
~~~~~~~~~C
ofthe banking
'Ghana
Thlicnetwot
-1988
system,-lose
waxnegativsiat
1hr
ec
e rate.-,
schemetomee-rcgnkabik
p
'
ltoadsupervisowo
and r2Mpaniisider
and speculativelendling
tesd
raie
nc
--
,.-,,
andahppor-,
_'50
...... I.
'''t
-. ,';30>-.Maa
'
'~tew.
~oi.
ipuin ~A enig
Encourage drpe:and
L....
0,
'rionirononiperfrrnng2ans
o
ng
heavylosses.~
~
Bankalsoreqs--
-.Hug foreinecag
*c&rof restructuriii as 7
US-$300 millionornealy 6
tradedueto:ihecol-.
n1981. thegoverrncmntbqu
dat ed:8insticunon&sIn:1983:it
rook ovceS(liquida*ng-3nd
rccapitzng5).n The:Ceir
coppero
(
. .0 !, _,'
-.
.-
STRATEGIES
Naftre ofLalikt
~~Nature
offlwwal
Economy
-1-;
Eco ov
dt-ress
.~*-PhiUippinas,---- :. Amongsmaller finanacalinsti--
cause:
(a).Inrcrascsin oil prices
i- 5;- :1981-87
wituuons,comprising7.6 percent
.Ilb)
-- ;;:-.By-1986,
centl b:.lcassis--e.- :;: -- -- :-.tance to financialnstirudons
am9-:outto 19.1 bmiionpesos
; . E .!.
y:.Sor 3 percent-ofGDP.i
j .--i4,
r-
i;Turkey.-
:-
- .'.198245-8
5
-'
Thegovernmentrecapitalized-
the
the--a
banuks an'd isistedonthe-ir
op-opucrurt,
erriaires
ofsal brokers,=
collapsc
5. .-.- 8-
-adfeba
weres
re+ xc=ured.
'Of
superision.----
:- ~
dara
appodirel 4,500
X i57s9-89;
;
'
.-
(a)Predominat &wewa
Q
- '
'D?.
i
.
''
..
4..~.,
themers'nd.rnew'ana2ei-
banks(a d od
pru
x!srctn&-
mcesineetrob
'to
poo7r-q,ueprtc~
alr ecerpaid t depostors,.
S&Ls)
f, . .
'.
rea esat
1989
_-~0-- (o
ne1~fift oif~
~w over60
were solvent
-'.Toed
-!;4
-.
of
~~~~~
(~~~~~~iarioi1987.sB
KiCwewn198
(19)lindz
,~ i:
_lrg ,b=., 6
.VV~'p
er
...e0
liaosoS
-- A.
L a
,,
.4-0
'
~US-$13 bilion
ibi-i,sl9
'
4A
'
'f*_
r22
'
acquiredw
(96;Seg(18A9)Sii&ae
CO'.rbn
costs'OLcLa.ofA.Lupec,rtsoFGN
t 1~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
!ei2 ge ioanC.Q'I otspJ
additionlg'
up
~~~~
inic
vi
aennas
supervision;
let
__
(b Dergultion ofS
'
S&._ .- to le_h
'
-
.-
r. noe
~il~jii15o
~S'
'-
on its prudentialregulaons.
Sincel9i
epe ~ ( ~ ~ ~ ~~"rceve
Berien 1
D988, about
1,5O6
..f :-'.:(ofES,147)
S&Jwre
2 l
98Ireiducedrhev
~~
aluc -;ur;;IeC&porons.ised
al crisis
uptea wid-nT
:i
sp
~~ ~~
.-
~~~~~-:.M'
fiwxra.ouc'acdequateat
-'1.
175 liqudated.
n
-:ofanks'aserand
.21982-87.
bank,
spcltv
A
meried1,575
'andfi eriarporen~
b1~!
upcr
;N ; E >- -'-troubl
in 1987.tec en 1982 - loans:;;
- and1988,
e
ou 424banks
i.
liquidatedand depositorspaid
Afinancialcrsis
Aeruptedwith: ~Inadequate prudential
'-:',.
.>,Uwe Strs .
or rescue
Insolventisttutions weas
'
-.
4>
FOR RAPI
,_
.A.,
-:'
,s, -t rb -7 >'thertJ5Ss
of
~~~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
&rp
_.e
.'
,.
Tnw
.;g
TableA5.6Comparison
ofBankingSystem
ConcetainRto
* g f
~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
-tuSI
~~~193
Hmlshnet
Indaish
lapi
'
KcrsRep.J
75
28-54
_d qil n
15 94
: >;
0,0.1959
.00
77.7
59
2
41
40
50
2:
60
~~~~~~~~~~~~~hil.,nd
.
359f8
9
56
Pidais
~~~~19116-U
hipln
tips-Y;an
.2
690.10
37
1.-
56
6
'51
61
7.
DI OP
0i-.,
66
72
t,
3986-U
t<N-x-~~~~~~~~~~Dhlds)
CA"ac
'.19156-111-
O.26
40
CLOW)
74w
20..
(UGh
90
0.50
52
X=atbr i
.Camdz,
Pane
*.
.
993
.. ,
~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~&cw
~~~
~
;
~~~~~~
W..~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
cs~~~~~~~~~~~~~~I
-.-
~~~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~.91r ~ ~ ~ ~
.20.
Iy
0040
41
6
69,
.43
LU
431a
as
71
:2
,.M.Ifbbrh
mAh6hIfl6&lkj
67X,
4:02
**
.7
d k=ni htl
klptn
3
76
.-
3.8
.r
cineanmtflrKd
ktmdinfrask~.~ah.k
indah SmwcnSm
d
Iph.Pn
ISbehbrasO
tnzh,S),,
baptvv
I
[naMti cm(x9kzphw,JnJ wi
3,nishll
u~~~~~~~~~~~Ti,;
*~~~~
..
5~~~4
. tlkHcdnMiI main&Inedbna~iuIl.,w
Sahi
DdU n(Ihhkaa&
higuhie Saif
wn(5
~~~1383
..
~~4enua1abJc
S'ahgznbnd
~~~ ~~.C. ~
' ~50
1359U
5.
2989
1989
6CM.
! .9!i
l O s-u
ses
-.
ka
mi
U.f:t
- -
-.
FOR0 RA,_s
STRAT~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~EGIES
F ST1_s;RAT
~~~~~~~~~~*
Banks,SelectedHPAErs
-.TableA5.7 InterestRateSpreadsof Commercial
@
S
;.^r
>
s;=
r.z<-i
=
-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~..
........
P > la.; s;] s r _ps
tS
i ;J1980
*',i-i#t..
-3, 21. ..
;-;
';,'1;';
'.........
l'-'
'....................
r19909' I--1
Silg9O8|e
0 1' r
to
-7.0
-- 0S@03e2
. r ."5
,s;
_L _Na
;~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
X .. @V
ac:
tclHai-ners
or:ptnsn<SiXpn:-il-cl
:/_~~~~~~~~~2
-1aitltwo
- . X .e.
>nfre.
<,>3.g,c<anddwoslE.!
kV'N
-tasta;6OrM-.7;Ft..f
we;ostffnsfrIhln,&-
tiluo,,.ii.rn=ii
.- ,-~~~~~~~~~~
-::~~geed
lGo e s.v
x,,ua,o.lpoxasedr
fl,c.,.
.l
.te
-r7- 4 . .- -.
:-
s4
L&enm&at ~ 'calS'
tMposrnt'ctsaresweaswond;El}i
i
.
;;
.;r4,4
:!i
. -IR_AL
E5
EE
TableA5.8 Outimes
of MajorPolicy
Implem on inancing
Institutions
-Aals a
(Af it
-~~~~~~~
-PtN009 '
Bath(
0rWSM7mIlm,
(
M3 manC4
- (GO~~~~~mt)
%nr .
;f0Q00Q.--
-.
-. .
< . ;.
U..e
--
bafowa
nd.Acwith bath.
De
f-
terstssX
n1ef
'1135~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ii
Ewe uneur
Das.
'-
hAS?bik
r6'w-S>
'f,
05,
C
lat
l
,x
'MWkm~
;
**
(US$3LEADe38)
H
- 351 ,Wtau
,
,.
ra
DcbuaP.aceD,adepeet. BakefMaLquh
nrlmam4ea
n . n- ,---s
iicrs)
821sata
.huu
~~ ~ ~
-m'.
''
hp
0;..
Iaaswmi-aawha-uda
h-
-to
mmdmmBan
Mas.s-~
beta-1usdm
b*r
e
-
inpesmu,
haEraw$
Fw*
'tn
i-:)k
W"
'
.-
rtu7
(US$54
r"T"'ad
5, p=^
UmmlUll 23
MO
-u
*t
we-'
b;;-l -l,e
A,
t ;r-{lwace
.-
*t2
tss9,~lnsgTe
.*, raEd
.0,--;0Dl
~tirl;.u;
-
17a= l,
Pksci.fwpa&M.y-
.4n
LnU1S
wi4
nnii7.5pantna..d
..
pre:,:
..................
;
M
~~~~mylwdncg
15*41=
s'.-
iu
(383fpm
f6ai,na
Saa,Dwqscfa
Ouse
aena,iacpehfehtd
cMa&aashqm
na
.' "~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~w
(U
-.
-'ps,
1
1-
F.
:w
aucef,u
..
DZI~hhy
.!
~~~~
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~i.anuctl&nl
_~
...
254
-. -
.. -
.e
. .~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
ST RATE GI ES
notAum
bnal.pnwant nkdkdw
Phllpphim(inw) .
FORRWD
56Na'.".mnouvkt
aayTciamr
-17MpcLIpa:Dad.xemowwt
UISI
Caa,g--st
WUDNW
salmawn4 younfixwmldtus
Hai,
Ealcmwmaaima
25dluftolankga.safaw,
fhlsi5p).Amam1ka(vn$
Ml~~~~~~~~~~~~~naCr)
-*.
-.
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~agmriaa
ftfiwm.Fwre io
.
taandeatnamI
&Wtuat.,.
'ra'.
Cia...
lwx.~
L U.Jm..
...
flakdC.ma,wdcttaaa.
..
I
Indian]
Psunatatd
-. -
~~~~~21.1 raiKonbAixtaIwna
~(USSLIS
ils.)
Rime.
Capstans: Jlbadand
~~~~~Damu-lag
rumtht ptwmsnt.
..
M.&Sns-toharm
Ova.sbmmPt-gbaii.ouwbg
fa
pnaar'AaSlak
hAlfpnaee
- -isllh-
spn
s.leantam line.
fiwrdxsA aee nmt&
nxd.dbamd mAman
~45JW
KWon
Back fhcAgcdswc
(MAO
54 pm--
Drpsu
(W1i5tPSmaxlonwund-
PiLbSzaa
aghhinAxn
0(W)
G Na'orSbn
Haaxid2781
.easmatn
snaenntw
ix ai
t 13tmx
aotnaan
=it
dndaif.d,136
(n
bnvarFan&nsn
lelmnaina Rantm (199011. nc.Ceainullash ripen Exap nImpaMllk a Japa bmtlwa
kandblnkLTuixwaLnz
h
Eaptut-ap Bank f,V bases
mixs
dhcDdJchi KangacDank.lad. Malayt, teat] banksa.iaa.Dn
fllnAadRps
33Twhfpa.Ca
ai
u.uo
Iqi
Bthtapnbahndoknet
Japa Cntlnmmod
Kot.spaeqtaa(nip
am
TDank 52ldr.
w
mi lee
N.re
hl~C"lbakum
T
a
Novtes
1. See chapter 6 below for a mor'ederaileddiscussion
of the relationship between educational expansion, the
* growth of labor demand, and the educationalstructure of
wages.
* 2. From aross-economny
school expenditureequations
esinared by Schultz (1988), the elasticityof enrollments
with respect to the relativeprice of teachers is -0.80 and
--0.70 at -theprimary and secondarylevels.
CRACL
E
-256
STRATEGIES
-.
FOR
R_
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~5
0;
R 6
ASIAN
ExplainingEastAsia'sEfficientResourceUse
0 t|HE
_EE
[+
~C
LE
USING
REESOURCiS
of the industrial labor force, helped to ensure that these new processes
and equipment were used and adapted effectively.Thus export orientation and high human capitl formed a virtuous circle;exports raisedthe
returns from education,and educationiraisedthe retuns from exporting.
UsUsng
the Market LaborMarketsin EastAsia
5
xT
rILE
0 ~~~~~~~~~~~
-
,'','
e!'kCLE
LaborSupply
andDemand
in the HPAEs
Shiftsin theaggregatesupplyand demandfor laborin EastAsiacomparedwith otherdevelopingregionshaveledto morerapidlyrisingreal
wages(seefigure6.1).East Asia'smorerapid rate of increaseof wages,
followingan initialperiodduring whichwagesdid nor increase,.is the
reslt ofslowergrowthof supplyand morerapidgrowthof demandfor
labor.2 Fora givenrate of growthoflabordemand,the slowerthe rateof
increaseof labor supply,the bigger the increasein wageslikelyto result
USING
RESO5 RC
Figure6.1 Increase
hi RealEarnings
Japan
Rep.of Komea
;-
__
Tawan,nChina
7=
HongKong|
Singapore
Indonesia
- -
Thailand
LatinAmneuca
andCertheanF-
mi
SubSahIranAbica
d980-90
-'AI
1SrO.:It
-t
l
I0
-Z
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
IncreaseInrealeamings
(p'e.nt)
10
11
Labor
Force Growth.
During their period of industrializarion in the nineteenth century, the populations of the currendy high-income economies
grew, on average, ar an annual race of only 0.8 percent.3 Today, the population of Sub-Saharan Africa is growing at roughly four times ca rate;
the populations of Latin America and South Asia are growing at romughly
three times that race. Only in East Asia have populaton growth rares, and
the share of the population less than fourteen ycars old, declined to levels
approaciing those that prevailed in the high-income cconomies.4
We have already seen how the early denographic transition in East
Asia markedly reduced the rate of growth of the school-age population
to levels well below those in other developing regions, thereby easing the
financial burden of maintaining education enrollment rates. The early
demographic transition also reduced, with a lag, the rate of growth of
new entrants into the East Asian labor force. The annual rate of labor
force growth during the 1980s was 2.6 percent in Sub-Saharan Africa
and Latin America and 2.2 percent in Soudt Asia. In East Asia the rate
was 1.8 percent (see table 6.1). The labor force growth rare in Singapore
is only 0.8 percent, about the same as that experienced by the highincome economies in the nineteenth century. In Sub-Saharan Africa the
rate of labor force growth continues to increase. In Est Asia, despite increases in the particpation rates of women, labor force growt rates have
been declining much faster than in Latin America or South Asia.
263
RACL
E
Table6.1 LaborForceGrowth
Rates
Ecenomy,vfonegjn.
H; , s;Indonesia: . -~-;
Rep.of.
2.5
-2.4
2.7
2.9
1.9
t'rKc,
Malaysia
..Sinore
Thailand
-;
2.5-
thAsria
L4 in Am6icai
1985-2000
J--.90-85
bhea-n
ST--S
m2ranAfr.
.
.-
1.8
2.2
1.-9
2:6
0.8
1.7
0-
2.2
2.2
2.8
2.6
2.3
2.6:.
S areWorldBank(1987b).
Growth
ofLabor
Demand.
Not only has the growth of labor supply been
slowerin East Asia than in other developingregions, but the growth of
labor demand has been faster. For the period 1960-90, the rates of
growth of wage employment in manu&cruring construction, and services have tended to be substantiallyhigher in East Asia than in SubSaharan Africa, Laiin America, or South Asia. This is not because
gowth of employment has been unusuallyslow esewher Widt the exception of the 1980s, during which output and employmentstgnared
because of the macroeconomicadjustments made necessaryby debtserviceproblems, the pace of industrial sector employment growth in
Sub-SaharanAfrica, Latin Arnerica,and South Asiawas more than double the pace in the currentlyhigh-income economies during the perod
1880-1900 (see table A6.4, at the end of the chapter). Rather, the interregional differcnce reflects the unusually rapid growth of employment in East Asia.
Even as it has been growing rapidly, labor demand in East Asia has
become increasingly skill-intensive.As a share of wage employment,
white collar and technical employment increased steadily during the.
1970s and the 1980s;in Korea,for example,it rosefrom 29 percent in
1980 co36 percent in 1990, and in Taiwan, China, from 32 to 40 percent during the same period (seetable 6.2). The pace of change in the
occupational structure of employment is lower in other developing regions. The change in the occupational composition of labor demand in
the HPAEs reflected increases in the abundance of educated labor, and
consequent declines in its relative price, as well as changes in compara-
264
USING
RESO-UE
Table6.2 Professional
andTechnical,
Administrative
andManagerial,
Clerical,andSalesOccupations
as a Percentage
of TotalEmployment
e
Kora,JRp of
1980
29.0:
.1981; 292
0 S-; 198200:
f - . 30.6: 0 :
30.8
.-- 0
1983
-1984
1 l985*. :-1986.
- 1987 2
-1 98 8:. . . :
,1l989~0 0
34.6
42
31.8
32.7
33.1
33.1
33.7
34.2
34.3;
35.1
45.6
-
379
-
- 35A4~> V- -? 36.2
;1990_
*/
34.3.3
34.1
Tariano Chbina
-42.8
.
*;:
-;-44.2
32.1
32
34.3ta;;
Shngapore
46.5
- |--.46.5
46.247.0
.-X
46.1
-t-46.8
60.0
37.2
X
38.5
39.8
-
r'-_Notvanilablc;
aToml
employmentforHoneKongindudesLinmployed
whohavepreviously
bald
KIidudes serviceworke
:Somiwfe::ields
(1993).
-X
Letting Markets
WoricPublicPolicyin the LaborMardt
The term "labor market?' generally refers to the complex of interactions between employees and employers. The labor market thus bears
the responsibility for melding the changing needs of the economys pro265
iR_ACLCE
high levelof efficiencyin the allocationof laborwasachievedby allowing wagesand employmentto be determinedlargelyby the interaction
of thosesupplyingand those demandinglaborservices,ratherthan by
governmentlegislation,publicsectorleadership,or unionpressure
Perform?
HowWePl
DidEastAsianLaborMarkets
In EastAsia,wageswerepulled up by increasesin the demand for
labor,whereaselsewherethere was a greatertendencyfor wagesto be
pushed up artificially.Earningsgrowthwas determinedmore by the
growthof the economyas a whole hn bygrowthin anyparticularsector (Fields1992).In economieswith highlysegmentedlabormarkets,
the oppositeis the case.
Labor
Markets.Bynot allowingthe price of laborin
EastAsia's
Flexible
somesectorsto risewellabovewhat workerscouldearnelsewherein the
avoidedthe creationof a high-wagelaborelite.
economy,most HiPAEs
For example,thereis evidencefor Taiwan,China,of a remarkablyintegrated labor market; there is no significantcorrelationbetweenthe
growthrateof earningsand the growthofoutputwithinsectors.Manu&acuringwagesfor unskilledlaborare only20 percenthigherthan agriLulturalwages.By contrast, in Colombiaand Jamaica,where labor
markersare highlysegmented,workerswith the sameievel-ofskillearn
wagesby 150 percent
nonagriculturalwagesthat exceedagricultmral
266
USING
-R
1Figum
6.2 Industrial
WageGaps
-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~t
'
.
..
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
'
Wage a Taiwan,Ch._a
of 1955 NTS)
Meanmonthlyearings (thouK;mds
T-
....
:~2~
'
to-I
O.
-l
rea walp
F4
IF=
~~~~~~0.5-
--
I|
X t
'
]I
I .
UnakflledlIndustulal
realwags4
11~~~~~~~~~~-MeradusLnduilrsalwags
0.0
1953
1955
l9S7
1959
1961
1963
1965
2967
1969
2.971
40
10
1963
_________
1965
1967
1969
1971
*I
-.-
1973
Unskilld
odustrialreal wa
1975
1977
1979
Sounrs: Kuo (1983); Taiwan. China (various years,1988); Korea (1978); Kim (1990).
26-:
USING-RESOUIRCE
&onorny/~on
Peno
LnAmericaazndC"bantbe:
CostaRica
Panama *':,
Peru
Trinidad`
Venezuela
'
:1970-84
;1967-82
1.4
:6
.
~7.3
Gh~~~~ina
~~~196246.
-1966-080
K
India
6.1'
7.2
Taiwan,China
.:
'
-196.5-85
~~~~ 1963-83
I'
Unwciglired.mC"ean"
p b tsector In
inrase p/otl
wageemplyment
00.
0.3
92
2.
45
37
27
103
28353
061.4
12
34
,195
'.
ahr,pbicaresons
employmentEwswns
.
1.619
67
7
09393
23-
665501
6.
..
33,
.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1
bl'emlyetwsntarsostolbyninud
publennat0.
__
Toal
--3.8'
-r0943
~~~197183"
~~Thailand
__
rkwre
23-.
.~~~~~~1960-80 42213.2
8.0
SnI nka
__
-5.93-4.
64.2.
196381
LZambia
-c
~~196048-734
Tanzania
__
,.,18
6.61-
tA
,Keny
~~~~~51
1~~966-76f
n*nj.I
__
Public
~~~19733
1~~973-43.
:1963-82
~~~~1970-44
__
__
by2.la0or
tolbyn
nue
mar2-
bynlaborcma-
USING
RESO
*CL
14
USING
:
:
RESOURO
sulitinggap between the wage and the marginal product of labor are
likelyto divert scarcesavingsfiom productiveinvestments,loweringthe
rate of capitalaccumulationand stcadilyerodingthe grwth potential of
the economy.15 For a time, Malaysiawas an East Asian illustration of
this point, but there are manrymore examplesoutside the regionwhere
governmentshave been slowerto rake correctiveaction.
If the government provides make-workjobs, squandering the producdivepotential of human capitalmay be another consequence.In the
worst case,which unfortunately is quite common, workers in whom a
substantialeducationalinvestment has been made are paid the prevailing (relatively)high public secrorwage to do jobs in which their marginal productivity is zero or even negauve.1 6 In this way creation of
makei-workjobs impedesthe processof hunan capitaldeepening that is
cen-tralto education'scontibution to economicgrowth. Had the labor
market been allowed to functon without intervention, these same
workcrswould have entered lower-payingoccupations,and the conscquent mcreasein the educationallevelin those occupationswould have
contributed to an increasein labor producdviry.
Becausewageswere responsiveto changesin the demand for labor,adJustent to externalmaaoeconornicshocks,suchas those inducedby the
oil crisesof the 1970s, was ofien quickerand lesspainful in the HPAEs
(Mazwrndar,forthcoming). Ifthepriceoflabordoesnotadjustquick-lyand
smoodily to macroeconomic shocks or to secular changes in the macroeconomic environment, then either the quantity of labor must adjust or
the ratesof output growth or inflation are liely to. In relaton to fluctuauionsin aggregatedemand, employment stabilitytends to be much greater
in East Asia than in other rgions, so that East Asian econonies genelly
adjust to downturns without laying offworkers (Shah and Marhur 1992).
Assisting
theMarket FnancialMarkets
andAllocaioDn
-T-L MARKETSSPERFORM
THEIR ALLOCATIVEFUNCTION IN
'.,
..
J:RACLE
EastAsia'ls
RecordofGrowing
FinancialDepth
The growth of financial assets in East Asia has been ve-ryrapidfaisrerthan the growth in aggregate savings-leading t usata
grwth in the financial depth of East Asian economies. Figure 6.3
comparesEast Asia'sratio of M2 (rime plus demand deposits) to GDP,
which is often used to measure the depthi of the financial sector, with
the M2IGDPratio for a group of low- and miiddle-incomeeconomies
and the OECDeconom-ies.The relativelygreater financial depthiin East
Asia far surpassesmost developingeconomies and comparesweli even
with the OECDeconomnies..
A broader meaure of financial depth, the
ratio of financial liabilities(M3) to GDP?,
shows a similar trend.
Korea is unusual in that its ratio of M2 to GDP?is low compared
with many developing economies at similar levels of per capita mcome,
USING
RESOI5
Figure
6.3 Financial
Dept in IPAEs,OtherDeveloping
Economies,
andSelected
OECD
Economies
~~~~~~~~~
.~~~
East
Etropeand
LaiMaidde
HAmaEs
190:7
Sub-Saharan
Afrks
OECD
economiesI_________________
0
20
40
60
M2/GDP (percent)
100
so
latin America includes Argendina Barbados. Bolivia, Brazil. Ch_c. Columbia, Costa
Not
Portugal. Syria.
and Switzerland.
Finland,lGermany,Ireland,Netherlands,Norway,Spain,Swecden
NoweM2IGDP= [currency + demand deposits,+time deposits,+ savingsdeposits(except
largecertificatesof dcposit)jas a percentageofgross domesdtcproduct.
SawrrrIntemnatonalMonetaryFund data.
.Mg-~~~~~~
CP
in emerging
of rpid
growthof financial assets in the banking system and rising savings dut-
igthe past two decades has meant' that bankcshave played an maceasinly i
an
AL
C
EACt
control over entrepreneurs, who must maintain their good credit standmgin order to renew loans.
Financal institutions evolvein responseto these market limitations.
For example,bank-dient arrangementsrespond to incomplete in$onmadon through relationship banking. Loan contacts are characterizedby
more than lust interest rates. The namre and amount of collateral become key. Yet despite efficiency-enhancingmarker responses, capital
markerSremain imperfct. Market power by banks may raise inrermediation margins, resulting in monopoly rents for the banking sector
Banks also faceincentives to misallocateresources;underfunded banks
rend to finance excessivelyrisky projes. Social returns on investment
may differ markedly from the private remrns to investors, and social
perceptionsof the riskinessof investmentsmay differsubstantiallyfrom
pnvate assessments.
For the abovereasons,most governmentsare reluctant to rely entirely
on private markets to allocarecapital. Twotypes of government involvement are thereforecommon: first, efforts to reducemisallocation of resourcesby financial institutions; and second, eflorrsto control banking
spreadsro limit monopoly rents. While these measuresare by no means
unique to East Asia, the HPAEs have been unusually active in exercising
them. In addition, most HPAs have gone a step further and attempted..
to direct credit to specific sectors, industries, and even firms. We discuss
this more complex and controversial topic in a separate section below.
-76
U S I N G R E SOUlCM
ReducingBadImuestmentChoices.
Portfolio requirements,
eitherto avoid
Table6.4 PropotinofTotalDeposits
withGovernment
Financial
Instutionsin EastAsia
(percentage oftotaldeposits)
c3
Wi.h
IM
or
Wi.h
iteI
pus ed singspwvidearinsturance
Economy/year
insa*adem
fiends
~~-
.:mmcw
XjiOQ~~~~~~et-r
.,1971-76
>ing-sy
,91960
81-8 5
-
-10-.
-.
N'
N-.
;-
1981-85
1971-75'
NA
8.79.9a
NA.
5F-A
~~~~~~
_1971-75-
197
1976'-80
-.
44308
14t3}
36
'.0
.19 0
---
.2
Thud
7 1.
7 1. 7
7M
61.3
'
4.
NA.
Noa
NA61
~
~~2.280.7
N'
461.3
151
855
4
22-.3;-':r.
_
NA.
24.7
02.
.~~~~~~~~~~8
..
~~ ~ ~ 22,N.37
.
198145:~ ~
~ ~ efiieg
1906-89
~
~
~ 15 itede
.~~~~~~~~~2
.
.3-
: .
108,
rid aem
n
s~Pecielixzdi
banks'
:0;
-,
NA
NA
-6
0-~~~~I
dcigtevlrl9o
57rsueealoainb
30cora4 prdn
beavo
netel
an3nhne
1ovnq9
: -0 - coprateos.
; ;. - - - =.: -ndesprad
- --~~~~~~~~~~I
stradbtutoryboardsinand goernment
Kreauete
n~ ~~
2t78
-:
~~~~sra
duvencthoeef
bewe
aes
inceas
ihsrasrdc
thecen
averageins.h
USING. RESOI1
With pvernsment or
Vit? pensoi
~~~~~~postalsavings
~provident awntrance
**
4 J pbi
commercdialad
*SingPapre
1971-75
1976409.
19814~5
1986-90
2.1-1.0-
~~~~~12.7
1971-751976-80
~~~~~-13.81
t18-5
-.
-:1986-90
10.8
92N.53.5
19.4
21.6
30.0
34.6
34.9-
-23.7
39.4
456'
47.6
A67978.7
NA.
63.6
NA
52.4
77.4
727
71.8-
.Thailand
-1971-75
1976-80
* -1981-85
*1986:190
.12.7
10.
N.1.1
NA.
8.2
NA1.
7.6
NA-
-13.8
13.7
.
-
2.2
is fbr 1978-80.
a.Th fguxre P6rpotd
c Te figure-for-Taiwan,
China, are bed on the depositsof all COMmercial
banksand'accneunl
vrsiae
eas
ny1
f he16 commnrdalbans&aregov&nmncnr
owned.Nvtlds,xgocnnrwndbanks
acon forthe mjrshare of!commer-,
cilbankdeposits.
SomorrlndoesizIndonesian
Financial-Sratiirk(Vadlouis
issues).Japan:jDDIFJI (1993); ooi
Staijsnal(aiu
er)
Kore= fronmndcWSraisdtYew-book
(ari,ous years).MaasaQuartrl(yBaliab (199O)-.
Singaporc~
Yearbook
ofSaiac (1991);Eoomic
~a.uSoraiSwszi
1:160-2,195).Taiwan, China: Sraisrca Yebrnoak
(variou vears). Thind& QnarurlyBulletin(vrosise)
-
~~~~~~~A
LE-
Like many governments,those in East Asiahave gone beyond the indirecr guidancedescribedabove to target credit direcdy at priority acrivities.The categories to which they directed crduit have differed litde
from other developingeconomies.However, HBPAEs,
particularlyJapan
and Korea, have uscd unusual mechanismsthat have helped to increase
loan repayment rates and overallsuccessof directed credit. They have
limited the size of credirsubsidies,and theyhave applied stringent standards to the selectionand imlplementationof projecrs.
Criteria
forSeecting
Dreeed-Cree.
Tagts. There are three broad types of
directed-credit interventions. First, governments can direa credit to
specificfirms or ind ries.Second, they can direct credit on the basis of
broad functional criteria, such as promotion of exports or small and.
medium-sizeenterprises.T ird.they can direct credit to accomplishsocial objectives,such as mass housing or redistributon of assets among
ethnic groups.HimAE
governmentshave engagedin all three.
Ta?etingfirms or indutdes. Japan cuinng its postwar reconstruction
and Koreaduring the 1970sdirectedsubstantialcredit to specificsectors
and firms, mostly in heavy and chemical industries (Has) (see table
6.5). Japan'sFILPaccountedfor about a third of newequipment lending
in the 1950s. Between 1973 and 1981, Korea'spolicy loans were about
60 percent of the total loans of its deposit money banks. Most ofJapan's
priority lending targets through the early 1960swere industries associated with large optimum scalesand increasingreurns to scale; so were
Korea'sduring the HCi period. Indonesia and Malaysia,conversely,had
disappointing experienceswith credit interventions targeted to specific
industries in the 1970sand early 1980s and abandoned the schemesin
favor of more functionally directed credit Hong Kong and Thailand
have not been active in using credit instruments to push selected
industnes.
USING
RtESOURGWE,j
Table6.5 Pmoportion
of Loans
Accounted
forbyGovernment's
PolicyLoans,
Japan
andRepublic
of Korea
Japan
-22.
.SE5.9uS:
sare f ne'.7--
I96'':.iV
Republic~~~~~~~~6
fKa:reat
k'onsas a'
o
sa
or
,
'Pa/C
. 1 lons
Pol.
4965.
09
~~~~~~~~~*
;,..e i
..
1955
J3~~~.2.
32.
~~,1970 ~~~~~~9.8
.,W
~
1975
............
'
t; .. ',
''
..
-13.8
47.41
................
I'
W
106'
:1.75.390
*~~~
PoS loan indude loans0
udrJ
t
some kind oftexii ;rrna
;&I prg;m
1980 1
141
,~~~w'.u 176,
.D,>,,0inuerestzat
eandaada8llt
or suppor;tend
b'' ch Cenra Bn's auomr
8:12'.~~~~
Srnc:JpaCiDqE
;Wr;-;rfX(
19).0 i-r
uS-.rn;n-oth:
7,
.,1'
tht,
(192.
8- :,
byiavemmentad
'
lon eted&emnali
h au
59.78"
term
19.4
ofal lan
Imn'Policgram(FIlP) Outstanding
Rloancre
cd
',
and d-
f2 finanKial
,_,_
iwo
_
rh6~~~~~~~~~dveometinttuin
~2U'Foreig
'rmd.nn
va7&bni
banI d
oF
:;rl)w
* fi:'ir
-',ey b- ',
j'Ban
privasector madeby &- '::'; of ICor&de-'o'
.-
"11.~~~~~~~~~~~J771:
w:
'nicws&tdnglar
,;;
-:
a d loa
;te
of Trkeyand
exio. Lans y te bakng systemto public enterprises
in Turkey'in 1975were 28 percent of bank assets,and to the public administration, 19 percent; those proportions rose to 24.9 and 35.9 per-cent,repectively, in 1980. In Mxico,- the largest developmentbank
provided about 75 percent of its industrialloans to fbur state-owneden-.
terprises.UJhfortunatelyv,
t-hesepublic enterprisesoften did not perform
--a
n
econmic
c193)ep
oInS-goes
1
9t* Malaysia,and
well economicallyor fina-ncially.
East Asia, Indonesia,
Singaporehavedirectedcredit to state enterprises,but the proporions of
total acrdit were not p
tversistently
Ehigh
the parastatalstended to perfbrm
better financially,and thaeintLerest
ratesubsidieswerenor
large (exceptin
7
Indonesia).1 1Koreawas an exception; its lending to the public steel
*plant, Posco, was substantia but is widelyconsidereda succes story.
Ta.rgeting
eorerne and smalland medium-sizeenteTiprises.
The broadest functional-targetingof credit in the HPAEshas been to exporte-rs.All
Easturkeanecnmisexcept
Hong
and Sigpem
subsidized
-f creit
-- Sngaore
o steKong
avedircte
nterriss,
ut hehave
popotios
o
export credits, often through the centralbank redis onSt te
(see
table 6.6). Exportersfrom all industries'have had access.Smalland
medium-size-firms,
whichoftenhad to relyon curbmarkets
ibund axportfinancingone of theirfewreadysourcesof fnral finaneow.
Box6.1
rAa, Maltznus
onpagd284)
.AC
SKAN MIRACLE
in EastAsia
Table6.6 Characteristics
of the ExportCreditSchemes
Hong Kong
Japan
Between 1946 and 1972, the Bank ofjapan (BO,Irediscountcd axport bills at low.ratesof interest (I to 2 percentage
points lower than that applicable to general trade bills).
During this period, the HOydirected 10 percent of its loans to
export finance (which financed 50 percent of toal exporrrelated bankIcnding).
Kara, Rep. of
Malaysia
Singapore
andre-exports.
Thaand
28z
USING
-Cref'itWork.sBox61 Directed
as aSupplemen,
,Bed
MANY ECONOMIES
CREDIT TOE-:
HAVEmID TO USEDIRECD
fewhavesucceeded.The
smalland mediuni-sizeen erriss;,
prounsusinuiable
-contrast
betwcen an unsuccessfiullandulumately
-a .., =;.tE,.,;-n';
in K
,..
i..
gram in J-Idonesiaand a successhflprogram in Koreatshowswhy.
f--'
.- In Indoncsiawhich itdl 'th_early.198 s hada heavilyreprcssed
financialsystemsimilartothatof' niany,developingeconomies,heav-,
'..ysubsidizedcredit dixectcdto enterpriseir. pnvdmnent-d&ignared
wre divcn-bypoliticalf
- categonesoften went awry.Cr&dizallocautions
=aswellas conomicconsiderations.Repaymentrateswereas iow as 53:
percent imone program supporredby'the World BanL Meanwhile,.
the politcal
medum-ze ; firmsi that lacked
porentialy aedrcwdrth
-,P.
q.R. d-,--,!j,:V
d R - ' ;,m a um'
..
-:influenceofireenterprises and the speci.alcret access cnjoyedby
- counge
Perhaps
..
-. '.
most important-todmesuccess&4I{eKoreanPprogram,Jn,:.
subsidieshaveben
-. teresr.iates
thoseTin
wtcompason
wih
modest-
rt
r,0I.
.-
,.!],
_',pi,'
its;'-
-4h
_..
Prlss-
0--
2:rCm
SU-
c.
'
RESOURCS
*II.MIRACLE
enterprisesin
contrastsdirected-credir
effortsforsmalland medium-size
Indonesia,wherethey fiiled and werediscontinued,and Korea,where
they have been moresuccessful.
As we arguedin chapter2, the sizeof
the subsidywasprobablylessrelevantto firms,especiallyto smalland
medium-sizeexporting firms, than was the automatic access.Allocation
wasstricdybasedon exportperformance,and commercialbanksmonitoredperformance,sincetheyonly collecredrepaymentson realizedexport sales; governments, through customs, had the means to verilfr
USING
RESOURCES*'EflI
Table6.7 RealInterestRatesonDirectedCredit,
SelectedHPAEsandOiler Developing
Economies
(percent)
Economy
Direcedit
FIPAESI
Indonesia, 1981-83, liquidity credits
Japan, 1951-60
Korea,Rep. of, 197040, industry
cxporrs
Taiwan,China, 1980-89, industry
1984-85, exportsQOterdevelopingeconomies
Brazil, 1987
3.1-4.6
2.9
2.9
4.6
4.6
-23.5
-1.7-4.0
0.5-3.0
-2.7
-6.7
1.9-3.9
1.5
Nonireted credt
1.5
13.5
-2.5-4.0
-24.0
7.0
6.0
13.9
13.0
-4.0-15.0
-14.0
'
S!WNMIRACLE
romost
other economies that have rried but fiiled to use directed credit, Japan
and Korea appear to have strong institutional capacity for project design, appraisal,and monitoring. Becauseof this, direccedcredit has generally gone to projects that are creditworthy and viable. More
importan-and in sharp contrast to many developing economiesfunds have usually been utilized for the purpose for which they were allocated. The result has been a high level of loan repayments and a
correspondinglylow levelof loan losses.
In Japan, officials working within government sectoral guidelines
operated much like loan officers in private commercial banks, scrutinizing projecr proposalsand the firms involved to ascertain their abiliry to repay. Once a loan was approved, close cooperation between
development and commercial banks ensured continuous monitoring of
the performance of the borrower and enabled development banks to
take early action if loan repayment was in arrears.Coupled with Japan's
overall economic success, effltive pre-appraisal and monitoring resuited in very low loan losses.The Japan Development Bank, the main
government lender,experiencedwrite-offsof a mere 0.09 percent of average loans outstanding in 1951-55 and just 0.01 percent in 1956-65,
lower than comnmercialand trust banks that focused on short-termn
lending and had a more diversified portfolio. The JDB's superior performance may be partly explainedby its greater reliance on collateral
security, particularly equipment purchased with the loans. Fear of losing collateralized equipment gave borrowers a strong incentive to repay
their loans.
In Korea, the government, banks, and industrial firms worked together and shared responsibility for the success of directed-credit pro-
286
USING
RESOURCESO
3iR
LqR"A`ThMIRACLE
USING
REsot1RCE`S,r
drive during the early 1980s, rapid growth resumed easily in the mid1980s, in part because of increasing utilizationof the HCI investments,
which were in physicalcapital, as demand increased.
However,the cost of extensiveand highly subsidizeddirected credits
was substantial-and likelyto increaseas development proceeded. Directed credits burdened banks widt nonperforming loans, interfered
with the financialsystem'sefficient operation, hindered the growth of financial savings, and sometimes threatened macroeconomic stability.
Koreawas able to weather thesedifficultiespartly becauseits closed capital market at the time enabled the governmentto suppressinterest rates
on deposits, thereby funding the subsidiesfor loans to corporations. In
addition, relatively easy credit in international capital markets and
Korea'sstrong relationship with two key lenders,Japan and the United
States, helped to ensure the availabilityof foreign capital, which was either fimneled into directed credit or went to bail out troubled enterprises unable to repaysubsidizedloans. Today,boch the greater openness
of capital markets in most developing economies and the heightened
competition in international capital markets suggest tiat financial repression and directed credits are now less viable options for developing
economies.
22
To argue tlat directed-credit programs in general reached their target groups and that loans were effectively monitored does not establish
that they contributed positively to growth. To do this, microeconomic
evidence is needed to establish two facts: government lending promoted investment and did not simply displace investment from other
sources, and the social returns on the incremental investment exceeded private returns, justifying the targeting of specific sectors. Such
evidence is rare-even for the northern-tier HPAEs-but
two recent
studies attempt to address these questions for a sample of firms in
Japan.Z3
A careful microeconometric study of Japan's industrial credit programs in general machinery, electrical madcinery, and precision instruments during the 1980s-sectors
selected because of their high
potential for externalities due to innovation and learning-reaches the
following conclusions:
* Government lending had a large, positive, and statistically significant impact on both gross and net investment; the three-year cumulative effect of a one-dollar increase in debt financing from
289
MRACSN
MIRACE
* JDB
*
keiretsu bank).
290
USING
RESOURCESj
Thus, directed credit appears to have acted as a signalingand insurance mechanism. By selecting among borrowers, the JDB encouraged
complementarylendingfrom private financialinstitutions with a consequent net increase in investment. Moreover,policy-based lending was
most successfiulwlhenit was directed at nontraditional borrowers.The
JDB's loans stimulatedgreater lending by private banks to firms not affiliated with main banks but did not have the same impact on firms
affiliatedwith main banks.
Another study of credit programs in Japan and Korea based on an
analysisof the objectivesand outcomes of the programs adds an additional element, noting the positive role of coordination achieved
through govrmment lending programs. During the 1950s the bulk of
directed credit in Japan was given to "basicindustries"-electricity, iron
and steel, and coal mining-that were characterizedby increasing returns to scaleand that produced basicinputs for other parts of the economy. Once these basic industries were developed,Japan subsequendy
promoted industries whose expected spilover effectson the economy
were large, for example, machine toolS (JDBIJERI 1993). During the
1970s, Koreachanneled most ofics directedcredit for fixedinvestments
in manufacruring to the HCI industries, among them such producer
goods industries as steel and machinery.Using a frameworknot dissimilar to the contest frameworkoudined in chapter 2, the study reachesa
similar conclusion: the coordinating role of government in Japan and
Koreahas diminished overtime, and hence the effectivenessand desirability of using credit programs to improve coordination among private
firms are diminishing as well (Cho and Hellmann 1993).
But many other directed-credit
programs, even in the HPAEs,did not
mect their objectives.In fact, the track record of most directed-credit
programs in Indonesia, Malaysia,and Thailand was so poor that their
governments, demonstrating the pragmatic flexibilitytihat we have argued characterizeseconomic policymakingthroughout the HPAEs, abandoned many of them. Limited differentialsbetween directed credit and
market interest rates and smaller volumes of directed credit relativeto
the size of the financial system meant that financial market disrortions
in the HPAEs, even from unsuccessfulattempts to direct credit,were not
generallylarge. In addition, the focus of HPAE governmentson providing credit for the private sector meant that, in gcneral, loss-making public enterprises were not priority lending targets, unlike in other
developing econonies.
Z91
ANL~MIRACLE
Using
the International
Market:
TradeandIndustrialPolicy
USING
RESOURCESF
MarketFailures,Trade,and Industrial
Policies
Why should governments inreriere with the level playing field created by the international market? Our ditcussionof coordination failures in chapter 2 touched on many of the reasons,but it may be useful
to reviewsome of the arguments specificallyas they apply to trade and
5 Among the many reasonsfor discrepanciesbetween
industrial policy26
socal and privatereturns cited earlier,four stand out:
X Interdendent investments and economiesoficale. Increasingreturns
fom scaleand capitalmarket imperfectionsmay mean that investments
that could be internationallycompetitive at optimal scaleswill not be
undertaken. This is especiallytrue with large, interdependent projects
for which optimum scale depends on simultaneous investnent in upstream and downstreamindustries.The larger the indivisibilitiesand returns from scale,dhemorelikely that private initiativeswill be absent.
a Straegic negotiations.In negotiatons with other economiesand foreign companies, governmentscan alter the nature of the marker environment by intervention. The outcome of any bargaining problem
293
RACR"MM!IRA
CL r
USING RESOURCE
RCE
tors. But as tlc many inf.int industries that have never grown up amply
demonstrate, prorection does not enisurethat the promised learning and
economies ofscale actually materialize.
TradePoliciesin the HPAEs
Most IHPAESbegan industrialization with a protectionist oricntation
and ihave%radually
moved toward increasinglyfreetrade. Along the way
(as we showecdin chapter 3), they often tappcd some of the efficiencygeneratingbenefits of international competition through mixed trade
regimes:they granted exporters duty-free imports oFcapital and intcrmediate goods while continuing to protect consumer goods. Export
prices were set in the international market and were often substantially
less than current marginal or averagecosts.31 Losseson axpart production offset profits in the protected market, while competition in the international market ensured that the firm would not suffer from loss of
have reduced their proteccost discipline. More recently,all the HPIAEs
dionof import-substituting industries.
Belowwe describe the evolvingpatterns of protection in the HPAEs,
with the exceptions of Hong Kong and Singapore, which adopted essentially free trade stances early in their development.
Japan. Japan pursued an early import-substituting industrialization
strategy,similar in many dimensions to those of Argentina, India, and
ocher less successfideconomies. As late as 1968, effectiverates of protection (ERPs) in Japan were still quite high and exhibited the cascaded
pattern from raw materials (low) to consumer products (high) that is
rypical of most developing economies (see table 6.8). Unlike many
import-substituting economies, however, there was surprisingly high
protection of machinery (final producer goods), confirming other research indicating that the Japanese atuthorities engaged in an intensive
effort to develop this sector. Eiu levels in the machinery sector were reduced during the 1970s, only after it was evident from export performance that the sector had become internationally competitive (Itoh and
Kiyono 1988). Quite high levels of protection were afforded sectors
such as iron and steel and nonferrous metals as late as 1970. Protection
in capital-intensive sectors such as pulp and paper and chemicals also remained high, to say nothing of the remarkably high levels in textiles.32
Korea. There is considerable evidence, summarized in Pack and
Westphal (1986), that Korea selectively protected sectors that the gov295
RACLE
-A
19 8
_-NRP
NARP
ERP
3.1
-P.
0.8
29.6
3.9
15.2
0.9
22.3
-2.3
15.9
-3.0
7.1
Intermediate producergrods
12.3
28.0
14.1
21.7
15.7
7.6
Finalproducergoods
15.9
21.6
32.3
44.6-
16.9
23.6
23.2
.35.8 .
15.4
23.0
6.3
12.2
Type
Rawmatcrials
Producergoods
-13.7
Consumer
goods
1968
B yindry'.r
Iad*m 1
:*1963
Manufacturin
Tattiles
32.3
54.3
Spinning
27.1
Weaving
-44.6
Products
1968
1972
24.2
282
.18.6
14.4
12.5
I.0
30.5
15.5
72.8
32.8
22.4
Woodproducts
14.0
25.6
16.1
Pperandpulp
9.7-16.7
18.0
11.0
Publishing
Learherand rubberproducts
Chernicals
Perroleumand coil products
30.9
33.4
19.5
1.0
21.8
17.7
14.5
-0.9
12.3
8.8
7.1
Nonmeallic minerals
22.2
15.7
8.1
Iron andsterl
Nonrfrous metals
Metalproducts
Machinery
Genemal
machinery
Electricalmachinery
TransportequipmentPrecisioninstruments
30.1
30.4
13.8
36.7
23.0
30.9
61-5
34.9
30.0.
34.1
-19.9
20.0
14.5
16.5
17.1
22.1
9.9
7.7.
8.7
-5.4-
31.0
9.2-
22.9
IG.4
a. NRP=Nonial RateofProtcdon.
b.-ERP=Efficdvc
RarcofProtecion.
c. ERPbasedon simpleaverages
of riffraes-Sovw Fortop panel,Itoh mndKiyono(1988);fiorbottompancl,'Shouda
(1982).
USING
RESOURC
SE E
Table6.9 OverallDegrees
of ImportLiberalization
byMajorIndustry
forthe
Republicof Korea,Selected
Years(ConsoEdating
BothQRsandTariffs)
(percent)
Mgjor indunrLy
Printary
Industry
Food,beverags,
and tobacco
- III. -Textiles,clothing,and lcathcrproducts
IV. Woodand its produas
V. Paper,paperproducts,andprinting
and publishing
VI. Chernicals,
perroleurm,
coal,rubber,
and plasticproducts
VII. Nonmetallicmineralproducts
VIII.Basicmetalproducts
IDC Meralprotucts, machinery,
and
eqwupment
X. Othermanufiacturing
Allmanufacturing(II-X)
Lighrindustry(II-VX)
Heavyand chemicalindustry(VI-DC)
All-industry
avcrage(I-X)
966
1970
1975
1980
1983
1985
30.0
34.7
24.2
5.5
56420
32A
.36.6
64.0
55.1
38.4
43.8
69.1
58.8
49.6
74.0
76.5
65.3
49.6
74.3
82.7
71.2
64.1
87.8
92.4
39.5
54.7
54.5
78.4
88.8
90.8
47.9
41i.
44.7
57.1
77.0
73.3
58.4
65.9
74.8
89.1
86.2
75.2
89.2
90.1
80.0
76.8
91.7
92.0
41.0
31.8
37.5
33.7
44.5
39.6
59.3
39.5
47.7
38.2
62.5
50.8
55.4
38.7
52.6
43.7
61.2
52.3
63.6
58.2
66.8
62.3
70.5
65.6
69.7
65.4
71.3
63.8
76.5
70.4
77.8
76.1
79.8
76.8
81.7
78.5
I.
* II.
Near:This tablegivcs
thedegreesof importliberalizationbymajor indusuy theseare obcainedby averngig scrmal damweightedby
productonforrespcriveyer
thecurrent
pricevalucofdom:sric
Sowcan:Sakong
(1993).
MURN!iL IRACLE
agriculture and exports. Malaysia was notable for low, if variable, protection of import substitutes, while protection levels in Indonesia and
Thailand were higher. All three economies began export-push trade
strategies during their periods of protection of the domestic market.
Tables 6.10, 6.11, and 6.12 provide recent data on the structure of effective protection for these three economies. Effective prorection rates
are declining but in Indonesia and Thailand they remain sufficiently
high to result in some anti-export bias. The free trade regime for exporters in these economies partially offsets the structure of protection.
The Closeness
of EastAsian DomesticPricesto IntemationalPrices
Notwidtstanding the protection thar exists in all the HPhEs except
Hong Kong and Singapore, domestic prices in these economies are
closer to international prices than in other developing regions. Two bodies of evidence lead us to this conclusion. First, nominal tariff rates adEffeciveRatesof Protecticn,
Table6.10 Selected
Malaysia,
Selected Years
(percent)
Sector
Foodprnducts
Bev:rages
Tobaco
Textiles
Apparel
Wood products
Furniure
Paper and paper products
Printing and publishing
Industrial chemicals
1Peroleumrefineries
Rubber products
Plasticproducts
Iron and sted
Fabricatedmetal products
Nonelectricalmachinery
Electricalmachinery
Transport equipmenr
-Not
1969
1979
1987
83
88
38
58
45
38
84
66
26
32
22
129
312
63
26.
89
4
59
-22
-26
15
6
82
43
29
-9
12
5
14
163
289
30
19
12
65
20
125
-
400
33
40
140
230
60
265
84
40
1,600
130
185
available.
Note Theeff&cive
mceof prorectionis thepercentgebywhichvalueaddedat
domestic
pnicesexcereds
valucaddcdatworldprics.
SoweSalleh,Yeah.andMeymnathan
(1993).-
298
USING
RESOURCE-SC
Seaor
1975
1987
1990
Food, beverages,andtobacco
336.2
122
124
Textiles,cloth,and foonvear
35
33
20
231.8
102
Wood products
-12
25
Paperandpaperproducts
Printingand publishing
Industrialchemicals
Petroleumrefineries
Rubberand plasticproducts
Ironaandstcel
873
31
13
14
-1
-I
426
18.2
57
13
48
10
Fabricatedmeaulproducts
*Nonelectrical
machinery
Electricalmachinery
28.4
-1
63.6
60.2
53.6
74.1
68
59
Transport equipment
Non-oil
:
-Cement
Manu&crmnrng
Total
(eclduding
oilsector)
-Nor
ailablo
Pngestu (1993).
Sowr.cBhmacharyaaand
jusred for the presence of nontariff barriersare lower in the HPAES than
in most other developingeconomies.Second, comparisonsof real GNP
across a broad range of economies indicate that domestic relative prices
fortradablegoods in theH-iAEsare doser to internationalprices than in
other regions.
Table 6.13 presents one of the few systematicattempts to compare
nominal taiff rates for a broad range of developingeconomies (Erzan
and others 1989).34The authors have also atrempted to adjust for the
eflc of quantitativerestrictionson levelsofprotecion. (We have added
comparable data for Taiwan, China, and have computed the average
nominal tariffi for Korea, Malaysia,Thailand, and Taiwan, China.35 )
Nominal tariffs in the HPAEs are lower than for any other grouping of
developingeconomies except the island economies of the Caribbean
and the oil states of West Asia. The differencebetween Latin America
(albeit before its recent trade liberalizations)
and the HPAEs is striking.
Thus while these economiesfavored production of import substitutes,
they did so less than most other developingeconomies.
299
WN MIRACLE
Thailand,SelectedYears
Table6.12 SelectedEffectiveRates of Protection,
(percent)
Sept
Secor
Averages
Allseccors
Exdudingfood,beverages,
andtobacco
87.2
18.6
45.9
70.2
90.3
44.2
-
April
1985
1978
Textiklprmducts
Woodproducts
Paperand pulp
Chemicalproducts
Rubberproducts
Othernonmetalproducts
Metl products
Machinery
Consumergoodsandmotorvehicles
Nov.
1984
Oct
13984
1974
Manfacmuring
Leacherppmducs
Marc/i
1983
1971
7.4
248.5
151.3
60.7
39.5
54.3
48.7
99.8
1981
633
14.1
34.9
67.4
144A
199.7
53.7
43.0
52.9
46.0
102.7
62.0
23.6
33A
65.3
127.8
199.0
55.0
43.0
51.9
46.0
102.3
61.9
23.6
33.5
57.0
108.0
167.0
49.7
39.0
46.6
39.3
89.8
53.9
21.0
30.6
66.3
118.4
152.7
62.0
53.5
44.5
42.0
108.5
70.9
29.3
45.6
Nor available.
Table6.13 AverageTariffsandPara-tariffs,
byRegion1985
Tranip
para-ta
Ceatral
Caribban America
Soudt
America Africa
Otler
DeveAlpg
All
Africa
Asia
Asa
PEAt'
aglow
Tarffi
Economies
unweighlted
16
23
34
29
32
36
19
26
-import-weightedb 17
24
38
30
35
22
17
24
18.
65
46
36
34
42
24
34
import-weightedb 17
66
51
39
36
25
20
30
Economies
Tariffplus
pars-tar:ffi
.
Economics
unweighted"
Economics
a Simpleaverages
acrossproductsand economies.*b.Simpleaveages cwssproductsacrosscountries,avcegs weightedby otal impor.
c IndudesKdrca,Malaysia,
andTaivan,China.
d. For Taiwmn.China, 1981 dat:.
now=
Erzanandothers(1989).
300
USING
RESOURCEStURECF
SouthAsia
LatinAmeadca
andCadbbman
MldcileEast
SabSaharan
Africa
0
Svnnre:Dollar(1990).
301
.SIAN'-MIRACLE
to MablysiaTechnology
BuigsExport
I stEn
Box
6.2.ri-Forign
a
:
,
.
:;W.6.:--,
chemical2
toward eecrcal- and electronic;priductsC
Gonenbbe
investment
Was weloMe in Malaysia.
htanaur
anddecliniginvesmt broun
.,pC
.
. . for. -xpos
. :
. PO..
-. e
;-Dlocal
partcpaton incorporateowner. Then,
-receson of 1985-86 largefiscalantrdedefi
spuh
for
,
. o
melproucs, and
rduc
:
pelm. Moreoftheinvtents were-dedicated:before.
t- exorsiv
policy
-encourd foregn investorye the eec
ing
a of i
i
was.inhibitedby-
Z .-
eloc
.
no-my
V
.
... .
..
I.
atogas i neighig&
t--- cenives
ax andrladdomesticquity strast,not
cpits
of
DETwoimportntreasonsfirtatare,
potentialinvesto,
bparigpaiong
requzrcnmcis-or
:#ny g of the investments LIn
tecleogy and-e-portan& employment thec young
MC
Wr-.-an
~~-.,,CO~31
MU
opporrumnes.
confo
averagd
U US$300millionayearin198385,jmpe
foreig inveset
pj
cts
thmselves
-h
to US$2
bbi981
-''. Som-L.@
tii&&ibJanii
nare frriiJapzi>fllo~1..arwah,Chi&anc
y
302
-.
hd'bcen_:W
when thegreatest soureof-D.El
gaporet
afraed
nanfrlly tiicafti&and
than$0 ilo
&crrinMlysase9io~
u
i;L
bfisb&ffrtedrd
tsi
hertcnooyr
-k
kceepu
USING RESOUPRCEts;EPfl
absence of exports reinforced the suspicion. EvenwhiereDPI was permitted in inward-oriented economnies,it was not viewed as providing access
to international best practL e but rathieras a source of additcional domestic production. Thus some economies in Latin America that were hiostile to licensing nevertheless allowed DFIin production for the domestic
market. The basic difference between these economies and Singapore,
which was much more heavily dependent on DFI, is that the multinational corporations locating in the latter could only do so to export,
b~
--
~
-
er
~~
., --
actmis
M2)Sa.
.o
eprs
i-h&
t'u
Tmrld'
I
li-
Ma
Unfiterie-s).
Birocincmais
a&okp
to _seinc5ndu&rois--vestmentsin dectroAicshave
r~~eincohduccbrPa4s.A
~uppljilocal
Motbrolaind
~llo(r&
Hiachilii~e
tSei~a&has
os
plntffaiya,jn
th&tat&-1980 Matus
i%5Pi~&nr4'
~conchcioner
`ia's
rei:ywor1d=
m rke Sr-roomtair,-'n
op.(-1991)
303
MiR
LN.MIACE
given the small internal market. Korea and Taiwan, China, with larger
domesticmarkets, created a similarsituation by encourging DFI in production for acport and in those sectors where substantial technology
transfer could be anticipated. In contrast, the large import substitution
economies, such as Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico lured investment of
foreign firms by offering access to protected domestic markets.
Poicies
Industrial
We define industrial policies, as distinct from trade policies, as govermnent efforts to alter industrial structure to promote productivitybased growth. Productivity-based growth may derive from learning,
technological innovation, or catching up to international best practices.
All the HPAEs, exceptX llug Kong, have employed industrial policies as
defined above. Japan and Korea had che most systematic set of policies
to alter industrial structure. Efforts in Taiwan, China, were less systematic but were nonetheless widespreacL Industrial policy in Singapore was
more functionally directed at the rapid upgrading of technology by direct foreign investors, regardless of type of output. Indonesia, Malaysia,
and Thailand have all used industrial policies but much less systemaucaly than the northeastern HPAEs.
Industrial
GrowthandProducivit Change. HPAE industrial growth pattems
diffier from the patterns in most other low- and middle-income
economies in the relative size and growth rates of two important industrial subsectors: metal products, dectronics, and machinery; and texies
and garments. Table 6.14 shows the share of value added in nine Internatonal Standard Industrial Classification ('sic) subsectors as a percentage of the tota value added of manufacturing. Among the HPAEs, metal
products, electronics, and machinery (isic subsector 38, or MPM) have
grown unusually fast The sector's share of manufacturing value added
doubled in Japan and Singapore, nearly tripled in Indonesia and Korea,
and quadrupled in Malaysia. More surprising than the importance of
growth
facturing subsectors, is the contnued importance of tctxiles and garments even as the rapidly developing Asian economies shifted fiom
labor- to capital-intensive production.
Appendix 6.1 describes our method for determining the projected
relative importance of specific industrial subsectors in cross-economy
comparisons. As can be seen in table 6.15, both capital-intensive seccors
304
USING
RESOURS
ValueAdded
Table6.14 CurrentPriceValueAddedasa Shareof Manufacturing
Eismjf
-m
hwo~~~~~~'"
w-d
TM"&
ad...d
ad
X.-
~a
"ad
;dr
pA'
HPA&
'
.I
3973
0.05
0-.
3573
3511
0.-16
L15
.4
0.35
0333
all
3053
IL"9
0.36
am
oi3
MP
a"
.2
-Y196
0.13
ISO538
0.39
0.35Om0
Ut
0.01
0.
"I
0.01
0.36
0.35
00)
0.05
DA3
an0
0.0
0.34
0.36i
035
0.12
ON2
os 1
0.46
013
Alli
013
0am
Wu0
.0
3.00
La
e5
-0.6
I.3l1
gmJZ
0.12
0.10
WI
33
gm
0.05
0.21
.3
0.4
00Ms
as6
DA.
.03
IW
0.59
0.02
IL"
a
1960
0.36
0.7
all
0.27
0L
a0
0.23
J1A
3583
0.18
0.07
07
00
p.27
0.06
0.1
0.27
013
tAO0
3,319
0.05
0.0
WI3
0.05
0.20
003
0.01
0.6
"I
a."
1313
e.s
0.33
1.04
0.16
-D0
0.32
.Ot
3936
0.42
0.03
0.103
0.9
DA0B
0.0
0.1I
0.01
1.03
0IL"
L137
02
0-
-O0
1A
3970
0.32
0.23
3101
0.A5
0.12-
0.2
O.01
0.12
0.5
001
004
WO3
0L4
04
1916
05
0.10
0.9
01
.03
1970
0.24
034
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.04
Om.02
014
14"
Iwo
0-17
0.33
0.5
3965
0.24
-04Z
0.19
OA
0.12
am
0.0
0.24
0.0m
0.011
.3 01 -L30
W0
0.36
0.03
0,4
.06
I0D
020
.27
0.0
30IJ
4.36
0.23
0.7
0
am0
Lot
00e4
a3
0to
GAe
.314
ILl5
0.l
01
30
.00
0.35
0AS
0.24
01e
0.0
1.03
0.37
0.33I
41.1
0.5
amo
3.0
g 3970
1916
0.37
Gm2
0.12
0.33
0.3
1970
19[g
o0e5
0.30
0-5
013
103
0.06.C0
0617
01.15
I=7
0.31
0.8
D101
0.0
*1,34
0.~~
01
~~28
AM3
OA05
~ ~~~~~
0.06
'-56
AiRAC
MIRACLE
term rFP growth rates. Given the length of time of the observations,it
seems unlikely that the measured growth rates of TFP could be attributable to cyclical phenomena or growing capacity utilization of initial
large investments.3 6
Sbtres of SelectivePrmnonion.
Here we describe the strategies of selective promotion that have evolved in the HPAEsas they developed their
industrial policies.
Japan. Early Japanese industrial policy aimed to encourage sectors
that faced income-elastic demands in the international marker and exhibited economics of scale, large fixed costs, and the potential to learn
from experience. This purely economic rationale was supplemented by
a sense that some sectors were critical to national morale and the
ITC
&nwqd#
hnnwj.
rqi"
a&d
&tS..
gadbe
a"
P4-
_d
ukA
ad
p-AKw
jminaAw
ruUvr
e12
.89
0.53
0,7
e.14
0.43
IMF95
036
065
Dh67
0.14
1973
1.63
0.75'
[.7
03'
0h30
1.42
O3
IAO
0.6
0.54
0.20
095
15SC
19
on
9s
_,~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~7 :-5
1329
O.98
2.412
36
Uhr
13a52
ns
a,66
0.73
0.67
0.63
0rt
TsIt
m
sad
0nay
ter
nuMb
uhmn6wf
1973
9ISBt
lo
10-3
;,.daV
N..Mlfk
0.37
0.17
0.00
Z.62
I.Woil
2.6
0o35
1 2s
11.6
0.3
1.2
0.44
a.ll
0."
0.01
Oda
0.57
L69
0,14
423W7
e0
'
Kar. Rxord
1563
19
0.99
D35
0.
17
2:4
2.0
o.n1
1.04
0.64
0.94
0.56
0:73
02
0.52
1.13
2.0
276
0.20
0.32
1.04
1.26
155
19B1 -
0.J5
0.94
025
0e5
1.55
33
O."
0.7
G."
C."9
0o.e5
0.70
Jo57
@0A
1.03
'.44
1.43
0.07
0D4
OS7
1973
t9S9
0.31
0@36
2.14
11.32
2.40
0.31
0.49
0.47
L09
0.75
0o27
1.53
oa
1236
50
0.13
t.7
0.34
IAI
to3J
1968
19: 6
0.!0
.34
121
3.33
4.35
1.85
al
071
0.3
0.65
1.9
135
02
033
3.16
1.32
0.09
022
0.95
3.s
6.00
2.39
0.54
(L
233
1.02
033
0.39
0.37
0.35
1so
3,74
0.63
L51
0.32
D.09
1.10
052
SeM
1I56
19S6
0.50
0.56
Lai . AM
'listS_;a
-
'-
1
3963
0.91
I10
1.34
1.03
Q69
0.51
1.31
218
G.AD
1.02
1785:
03 4
170
1.21
0.73
LIZ
0.48
0.11
1.92
GaG
1.09
193
19t0
1.11
1.1
3.04
3.M6
1.21
I1'[94
1.07
oi9
-. 67
0.73
0.43
L63
436
2.65
D.8S
0.24
4.03
121
1.1
0.45
4
0.41
-76
0.84
37
am64
Chile
1915
1954
-306
?dkcJ
:
_
uhiew
37
1.57
90711C
'
aku*t-l.t..p..
0.15
15
t
a.70
1.04
ftrn
am
0.0
e
_32
l
US ING RESOURSCOU
Table6.16 Long-Tenn
TFPGrowthRatesbySector
TFPgrowtldrare
Taiwan,
Sector
FoodBcverages
Tobacco
Apparel
Tcxctiles
Lcather
Shoes
Wood
Japan,
1960-79
-1.76
0.0
Kirea
7.30
7.90
C-/ina,
1966-6
2.0'
13.40
10.70
12.60
-
1.98
0.47
1.03
1.03
10.5
7.6
_
o3b
9.40
2.81
Furniture
Paper
Printing
Chemicals
12.10
8.20
10.70
13.10
1.74
1.44
-0.18
3.36
Pecroleum
-0.30
_3 55d
O.Ob
Rubber
Nonmetallicminerals
Basicmetals
Ironand-steel
Metalproducts
Nonelecricalmachinery
Elecncalmachinezy
Electrical
equipment
Transportequiptnent
11.40
2.80
3.70
7.60
.00
10.70
11.20
1.02
134
3.41
230
537
432
63b
2.4
7.2
2.3c
3.3
4A
67'
7.1
2.7
11.0
Prccision instrumencts
Plastic products
Oilhermanufacturing
Average
o.92f:
0.0
-1.76
1.2
4.6
7.50
8.8
-Not availablc.
a. Foodmndbevrages.
b. Rubber,petroleum,andwoodproducts.
c Paperandpaperproducts.
d. peuroluemref and coaLc. All machincry.
f Plasdc..
SowrePack(1993b).
achievement
of international
respect3
had a narrower technological focus, for example, promoting establishment of the technological base for very large-scale integrated circuits
(Borrus, Tyson, and Zysman 1986). Among the sectors carefyl 7 nurtured were steel, automobiles, textiles, shipbuilding, and aluminum refining in the earlier years and then electronics and semiconductors in
307
A :LA?WUIRACLE
USING
RESOURCES.E
Box63.31TeHCIDrive:Costsof
lidtervention
THE-KOREAN C;OVERMENT'S INTERVENTION
r CaCed
wit intervenCiin. Govcrnment intervention in-:X-.- ',.cureddiecthefosts thform ofsubsidies to strateic
sectors through-policy loans andl tax-exemptions, esecialfr during the..1973-79 periodof.HCI .promoMcQf
nflosPA
tidon. Intervention
rred idirici c
t
in:iec
eInost
amounwird roperceatord2tc
-romotrionpmo.n
aton,
Upfipjwo
100pr.fr:hi
percht-irfor the` ew
yas
;'-rate aboutatwo-tl
beilijoeawon q-;~
rationaiefis
ations
ea
ad 50
to Cen
.. balaces
-provi
'
1977-a
piceit
_;-
4 tGNP'(6kIiby
issW_-_.
bankIoSii4- Ths
L-:-,
75io
aitg
an
eshdmshoulbe
V-
It...
hash:urtbthe
rf
nt of.
l ugb'p
.idede
toawith
.sdircefi-
form of accuulated.nonpdomn'on
'squed
ba
pr
tKore
governt
oubida
to
an
C45
93t
aonce
med
pl
n6perceinnt
domesais,eilo
stlact
Afrgen&al
<collecned)>a.~~~~~~~~~1ost
of fi
;-XstedT
ha..spredomnant
-.
?-.-,.&asupoirH
U-wa:pr&etl
pOliclon
1
dirtedtokey-industes.
snp
n977r
percent
wfahe:oiidome
tioflthe
T&
kaMng
rhplicinin&i&~~~~P
ib
.nanci I
r iii dHCIi uppsorCofInsfpoic
theiic
,.sectr: I.l
Bakdiscoun-rswhich
; .0
overnmeab r
eK
owerfor
strategic IndustrIs-,
drive in.197 alone,abou& 82
e vbenuo
percenmeofrtot
won
adt
of tot
&
separate.; Da&k-
ad
nerest<
troughicbuaet
atyetto bedeermicos:ts.-:.
(1993 NM-stB.
ank
con-
orin:.gounentannoLnce~a-memura-;
;.-...;
to.z adle.t tc
(1987) LKep
Pew
.pan---- -
309
?SdRA
C
EMIRACLE
US ING RESOURCESCE
pivarized
firms becae
more pr
ly snall util the late 1970s,wheni the gopertlnment - ductiveand innovative.Nor can the macroeconomic
.rapidly,expandedthe umberof stat efirms, pary to
bencfits be overlooked.in the end, tihecderal gDi'-,;;givehMlay'sopportuniuesand.partlyoutofa convic- -emuent anticipatesthata-tleast15 percentofitsouri,noniat the govea entcould s
de&elopmentr. snd -in debeen trred
to privafizedi
MLSifuch
of th& vgrowt
i the early 1980swas due to
firms.
'HICOM,. the Heavy and, Industrial Corporation of
Malaysia'sslow but steady divestiture and' the
Malaysia,which esiablishednine subsidiaries'in such, b enits it realized by 'adaping flexibly to thcir=areasassteel,automobils, cement, ant paper.
cumsrances of-each--cas provide anI examplefor
.- , :fkis, especiallEy
State
in HCOM, performed less. . niany
m
oter deveopig cnos,
wh privatiza,'wl
thanexpeced
nd in 1984
:thedefici of the-
cEdfictraa&la
mngs of trade threat-
,,
Dipg
fiA:il
-ened -macroeconomic
stability
sthe govemenc
begat
pdvaize in 1983.iOfm
orerhan 800 state
fiMrs existing Mi th mid9Os, about a hundred had,
been
by'WO.Maire
s
conmecial
.manuring
oper
s,butsome
were quite big,.
incl=du,ding
an--airline; a shipping' company,, and a
telecc}tnmuincatiotis
fim,
*
there
have
beeinglitches.-For
offeingshave
been
heavily
; the:government
in
that
Imps
sing
as much
instance,
wa no
gc in
an
Eve so, managment
gnd
public
esscbed,:suggt
upde.*ied.i'
as US$150
investrment
sha'res
s
million
i,
per-
sl
decisions
of
while ir contintue to
Sect or r-femain
;
X sL.,ibni,
more.than
,, d .
--e.;
;;
H-tover
theaiSaxontrall PRO-
company
ON,taornil
t.
y__Fxpcrcnxe
Ke,'SczE,,edr
,h&,,,6nrinf
eII&'
'ubl-PiIcsc~
r
phec
*as-
no,
ra
b
becamec
profitablta-paying
ALA a~
l'i2bu
',Rb-,cn
:.
even,
;piblic
-o -tickets
ile
har.
dlS.
.
. to.,t the
;,
pia
sales. Ith.
~~rodxicri
tvi&de
6&
tiea
cotrings
:2 ~flrn ihake
permission'
the farie
hysia.
s -meant
thoughte
ublic secor retained control, the
indmcude'l ashosr"of
'
;.rm
that took over, many repres'nnt''
Bumi
-p
d h c.thh'
ontro
srests,
-'
ireincentvet
to ear Pr6fit.nK
ounigh
:schems
tovrpro
--.
and eventulywon
less, rationing
Ii.-mg
t or de 'jur autl{orit'"
de t
contrl
over
fares. Whie
changes m incen-
ui
s a luc
-- 1,ing container.
inWCOM. E
ienad
Even
ref.ier
.nb-e'rir
the-fi-ms&vi
s.s
sub
m mnagrsinat-nyaestanisinad
taonintd
kspoldecrk&4he~~
mor' toit~z
r''
wa tha
traicinand
ofdie
nopbzcaf
reion
nil
. ah
tanrlyimprove
iworkeri,productv--
shamtrome.' w,
Sw,,t;
~ Slkii(199);
es,
out
'-;
(iu)
od Bn
(1992);
(.1988)"'-
3"I
-C
_AIRACLE
Japan, Korea,Malaysia,and Taiwan, China. Thailand's Boardof Investment (BO})has attempred to promote variousactivitiesviewedas having
the potential for technologicallearning, but, as we pointed out in chapter 3, it is difficult to discern any sysrematiceffort to change industrial
structure from the pattem of promotion of the BOI. Indonesia has used
public investment in an effort to move roward high technologyindustries. Indonesia'stechnologydevelopment efforts representan cxtreme
case of state-supported technologicalupgrading, but the public sector
researchfacilitiesand strategicindustries have fev linkswith the private
industrial sector. One experimentwith leapfrogginginto high technology industries-Indonesia's attempt to create an aircraft industry-is
describedin box 6.5.
DidIndushialPolicyIncreaseProductiv?
Have atrempts [o alter industrialstructure helped accelerateproductivity change?We attempt to answerrhis question by addressingrwo related issuesin appendix 6.1:
* Firsr, did industrial policy alter the sectoral configuration of industries in ways that we would not predict based on facror intensities and changing relativefactor prices?If changesin dhe seaCoral
composition of output are largely rnarket-conforming,
industrial
policiesmust have failedirhat least one of their objectives:to guide
industrial development along paths thar it would not take if it
wereguided by market forces.
* Second, what were the rates of productivity changein industry in
the HPAEs, and what were their sectoral patterns? If rates of proctucivity change in industry are low overall or in promoted
sectors,prima facie, industrialpolicydid not meet its productivityenhancing objective.
In both cases,our answersleadus to conclude that industrialpolicies
were largelyineffecnive.
Indusbial
PolcyOnlyMarginaly
Altered
Induri Structure.The cross-econ-
omy comparisonsof industrial structure raise quesrionsabout the efficacyof government effortsto promote or discouragespecificsectors. In
Korea, for example, despite the government'sextensiveefforts to speed
the privatesector'sshift from labor-intensiveto capitml-and technologyintensive industries, the relativelylabor-intensivetetiles and garments
312
USING
RESOUCES
sectorwasnearlythreetimesbiggerthanintemationalnormsprediaed
in 1988, a substantialincreaserelativeto internationalnorms from
1968.Duringthe sameperiod,Koreamerelymaintainedthe internationalnormin chemicals,a heaviLy
promotedsecror,whileocherheavily promoted sectors, basic metals and metal products and machinery,
achievedonly modestimprovements.
Similarsurprisesare evidentin
Singapore,
which,likeKorea,hasa governmentthat aggressively
inter-
Box6.5 Indonesia'sTurbulent
Leapinto HighTechnology
* SECr1oRAL-.TARGETING TO ACHIEVE RAPID PRODUCTIN
changeis a rislybusiness-paTilarlywhenpubliclyfundedfirs
arepemiedmtoily onprotecred
domestcmardratherdian bing
subJece to international
compeunon.
Thedangesoofsucha coursc
*areevidentin
thedifficulties
encountered
byIdonesianai.ramfpro- ducerPM. Industri Pes;wat Terbag Nusantaa(iv),
whichhas
absorbed
$1 billionin goverment.
fiud
-timefromdesign
compleonoplucon, i is-
iesil
313
:AN
MIRACLE
USING
RESOURCES
315
STN
MI R A CL E
Increased
Productivy
Exports
HowManufactured
OES THIS MEAN THAT PUBUICPOLICYHAD NO ROLEIN THE
USING
RESOURCESC
How did the unusually high rates of growth of exports and human
capital contribute to the productivity performanceof the East Asian
econonies? Most explanationsof the link betweenTFP growth and exports emphasizesuch static factors as economiesof scale and capacity
utilization.While thesemay account for an initial surge of productivity
soon after the start of an export push, they are insufficient to explain
continuing high TFr growth rates. Rather, the relationshipbetween exports and productivity growth may arise from exports' role in helping
economies adopt and master international best-practice technologies.
High levelsof labor forcecognitiveskills permit better firm-leveladoption, adaptation, and masteryof technology.Thus, exports and human
capital interact to provide a particularly rapid phase of productivitybased catching up.
Of course, it is possiblethat the move to a higher production finction occurred beforethe growth in exports-that TFrgrowth causedexport growth rather than the reverse.41 But even if expors began on the
basis of productivirychangedue to such domesticeffortsas plant reorganization, the cumulative magnitude of productivity growth over
nany yearsis most unlikelyto have been a resultof purely domesticefforts.42 It stretchescredibilityto suggestthat the largecumulativeeffcts
of TFPgrowth in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, China, could have been
achieved by the plant floor innovationsproposed as important sources
of productivity growth at lower TFP growth rates (Packand Page 1993).
Were that the case,it would be difficult to explainwhy these gains far
outstrip productivityincreasesin the industrialeconomies during their
own rapid-growthperiods, when TFP growthwas attributable largelyto
domestic factors.Clearly,then, an increasedability to tap world technology has been an important benefit of exports.4 3
Exports'Rolein ImpedectKnowledgeMarkets
Why do exportsfacilitatethe move towardinternationaIb&,:-practice
technologies?The knowledgethat pernits this shift is availableonly in
quire imperfectmarkets. Often the marketsdo not exist-some knowledge is simply not sold, because its owners fear that licensingor direcc
foreign investment will eventually Ieakthe knowledgeto future competitors. Evenwheremarkets exist, they are likelyto be characterizedby
bilateral monopoly,so thata varietyof difficultiesconfirontfinns trying
to purhase such knowledge(Arrow 1969).
317
4MIfA
CL E
* Technology
licensing.licensing exsting technologies,both rights to
proprietaryequipment and derailsabout production pocesses,offersdevelopingeconomiessubstantialopportunitiesfor improvingdteirlevelsof
best practice.During the 1950s and 1960s,Japan benefiredconsiderably
fiom licensing (see, for example, Nagaoka 1989). The net gains were
3I8
USING
RESO URCC
-ALRACLE
USING
RESOURCES :EFI:d3r
The HPAEs'
rapidexportgrowthhasoftengeneratedpositiveinteractionbetweenhumancapital,physicalcapital,and knowledge.
The externalitiesgeneratedby manufacturedexportsin the high-performing
Asianeconomiesin the formof cheaperand moreeffectiveknowledge
transferswouldhaveundoubtedlybeenlessproductivehad therebeen
fewerskilledworkersto facilitatetheir absorption,while the HPAEs'
rapidincreasein educationlevelsreflectedin part risingprivaterowards
for greater education made possibleby exports and export income.5 0
Thus laborforceskills,flexiblemarketsfor labor,lowdomesticdisrortions, and exportincentivesall interactedto promote high ratesof technologicalupgradingand productivitychange.
We can use the cross-economyregressionframeworkdevelopedin
chapter 1 to look at the impact of trade and indtLstrialpolicies on
growth (seetable6.17). We introducetwo variablesinto the basiccrosseconomyregression:the index of openness(as describedabove,the degree to which domestic prices conform to international prices) and
measuresof export performance.51 Openness to the world economy
capturesnot only effidencr gains induced by the need to remainglobally competitivebut alsothe likelyallocativebenefitsof having relative
pricesdose to internationalprices.
Introducing these two trade-relatedvariablessubstantiallyincreases
the explanatorypower of the cross-economyregression.The effect of
opennessis positive.Economieswith limited relativeprice distortions
5 2 We chooseas our measureof export performance
grewmore rapidly.
two indicators-the averageshare of manufacturedexportsin total exports and the share of manufacruredexportsin GDP.5 3 Manufactured
export performanceis stronglycorrelated(at the 1 percent level)with
high rates of per capita income growth. When the share of manufactured exportsin totl exportsis introduced togetherwith the openness
index, only the latter is significant.Conversely,when the share of manufactured exports in GDP is used, the opennessindex remains positive
and significant.One possibleinterpretationof theseresultsis that a high
concentrationof manufacturedexporcsrelativeto total exports, rather
thanopenness,contributesrelativelymore to productity change in a
cross-economyframework,which would be consistentwith our reasoning concerningexport externalities.54
Estimates of the sources of total factor productvity growd (described in appendix 6.2) confirm the results of the cross-economy re-
-MIRAC LE
Table6.17 Output,Growth,
andInvestment
(dependent variable: rate of growth of real GDPper capita, 1960-85)
NrinnJerefobneations:
92
86
69
97
79
Intercept
-0.4237
(0.1650)
-0.0124
(0.0083)
-0.2324
(0.1550)
-0.0055
(0.0085)
-0.3943 (0.1748)
-0.1033
(0.0268)
-0.0459
(0.0108)
-0.0837*
(0.0256)
-0.0381 "
(0.0123)
-0.0892
(0.0280)
0.0259
0.0216'
0.0221
0.023!W
(0.0081)
(0.0064)
(0.0079)
(0.0069)
(0.0085)
Secondaryenrollmcnt, 1960
0.0317
(0.0203)
0.0211
(0.0134)
0.0218
(0.0210)
0.0206
(0.0148)
0.0156
(0.0210)
0.1322
(0.2699)
02693
(0.2346)
0.2054
(02806)
0.1856
(02376)
0.1222
(0.2870)
AverageinvesrmenrlGDr.1960-85
0.0568
(0.0259)
0.0659
(0.0232)
0.0625 *
(0.0291)
0.0444
(0.0242)
0.0436
(0.0276)
0.0042 *
(0.0017)
Averagemanufacturedexpotslrotal
exports, 1960-85
0.0210**
0.0023
(0.0016)
0.0002
(0.0001)
0.0003
(0.0001)
0.0011
(0-0003)
0.001a
oi
(0.0004)
0.5217.
0.3530
03938
0.0132
0.0147
0.0155
Averac manufacturedexportslGDP.
1965-85
AdjustedR2
0.3947
0.4912
RMSE
0.0159
0.0124
0.0040
(0.0018)
Statisicailysignifieanrax
the 0.01leveL
-
USING
RESOUIRtCE
PT
of TotalFactorProductivity
Growth,1960489
Table6.18 Determinants
(dependent variable: rate ofgrowtlh of real GDPper capita, 1960-89)
67
Numdrmrofobservatons:
Intercept
-64.9123
(14.0585)
Educationalattainmcnt, 1960
-72.0692*u
-70.8604
(14.8657)
(15.6104)
(15.4608)
-5.5757 **
-2.3509
(2.3225)
-2.1562
(2.0637)
0.1471
(0.0874)
0.0680
(0.1082)
0.1574
(0.1064)
0.0738
(0.1207)
0.7154 IA
(0.1508)
0.7225
0.7134
(0.1558)
0.0314
(0.0066)
Interaction ten: Educarionalattainment 1960 times
manufacturedexports/totalexports, 1960-85 .
-71.1186
(1.9771)
(0.1417).
0.0159
0.0032
(0.0026)
J.0686
(0.0966)
- .. . . m:
;-
(0.1574)
(2.3008)
(0.0142)
0.02
51
-4.8047
O.6493
51
67
0.6333
0.6376
0.0284....................,
0.0625
(0.0269)
. 0.0284
0.4507
0.4628
(0.0201)
** Smzisically
significant
at the 0.01level.
SmziricaHllyiignificantat
the0.05 leveL.
XNoeCC
dicmt
istop number Standard error is bottom numbernpathes.-
SoureWorldBakstaffesdma.---
323
r&IAN"MIRACLE
USING
RESOURCES
ducersin the SoutheastAsiannewlyindustrializingeconomies.Governments were credibly committed to export competition. Exports were
important becausethey ensured that, giventhe HPAEs'high human capital base, productivitygrowthwould be facilitatedby the improvedability to tap international knowledge.
*..
What are the m2in faors that contributed to the HPAEs' superior allocationof physicaland human capital to high-yieldinginvestmentsand
their ability to catch up technologically?Mainly,the answerslie in fimdamentally sound, market-oriented policies. Labor markets were allowed to work Financial markets, although subject to more selective
interventions to allocatecredit, generallyhad low distortions and limited subsidiescomparedwith other developingeconomies.Import substitudiorn,although an earlyobjective of public policy in all the HPAS
exceptHong Kong, was quicklyaccompanied by the promotion of exports and duty-freeadmissionof imports for exporters.The result was
limited differencesbetween international relativeprices and domestic
relative prices in the HPAEs. Market forces and competitive pressures
guided resourcesinto activitiesthat were consistentwith comparative
advantageand, in the case of labor-intensiveexports, laid the foundadon for learning international best practice and subsequent industrial
upgrading.
Does this mean that selectiveinterventions played no role in East
Asia'ssuperior growth? Our conclusion is that selectiveinterventions
were neither as imporant as their advocatessuggestnor as irrelevantas
their critics contend. All eight economiessucceededin establishingautomaticaccessto creditfiorexporters;this simplecontest wasan important component of their export-push strategies. Other directed-credit
programswere lesssuccessfulWhere rheyappear to have resultedin allocationof credit to high-yieldingactiviries,mainlyin Japan, Korea,and
Taiwan, China, it was becauseof carefulszieening and monitoring of
projectsand an orientationtoward the privatesector.Where they failed,
governments limited the damage by offering more limited subsidies
than the credit programs in other developingeconomies. Finally,we
have conduded thac industrial policy,with the possibleexception of
Japan, did not alter industrial structure or patterns of productivity
change. The most successful selectiveintervention in the HPAEs-the
commitment to manufactured exports-was also the most general.
3Z5
x&EXkMIRACLE
Appendix
6.1: Testing
theImpactof Industrial
PolicyonProductivity
Change
should give rise to growing total facror productivity in the entire industrial sector,though the resulting pattern ofrFrpgrowth
across subsectors is not easily predictable. Knowledge-basedimperfections are likely to yield TFP gains, primarily in the subsecaors in which
the intervention occurs. Subsidization of knowledge acquisition in textile production will mainly benefit other textile firmnsas knowledge seeps
out to them or trainecdengineers go to other textile firms. Some knowledge in textiles may benefit dosely related sectors such as dothing
through production of ftbrics that are better suited to local conditions,
that is, are not obtainable on the world marker.
T-he secroral locus of gains is important for several reasons. First, empirical efforts to relate government interventon to productivity growth
are desirable as aweak restofthe efficts of intervention. Productivitygains
in rhe entire industrial sector or the entire economy attributable to other
factors might mistakenly be ascribedto the intervention, even if it had ac-
economic
history (Rosenberg
USING RESOURRCES
43
-yASrAN
MIRACLE
Economy
actua vae-ad
:TFPSrow*,,
weighn
-adIjal wegkh
Korea,Rep. oE 1966-85
6.7
6.1
Japan, 1960-79
2.3
1.9
esimaresforJapan.
328
USING
RESOURCESOEUF$
;M-IRIARACLE
Predicting
the Pattern of Sectoral
Growth
The newerliteraturesettingout the meritsofinterventionhas not rested
whetherthe sectoralevolutionof successfilAsian economieshas differed
fiom what would have occurredhad therebeen neutralpolicies.Nevertheless,showingthat many instrumenms
wereselectivelyemployedis not the
sameas provingdat they had a significantquantitativeimpact on the sectoral structureof production. Even'whereeffectiverates of protectiondifferamongsectors,the impact on sectoralstructureisnot easilypredictablc.
In generalequilibrium,the movementof resourceshas no monotonicrelation with ERPs (Blackand Taylor1974;Bhagwatiand Srinivasan1979).
For each economy,four simple regressionsare run of the form:
(6.2)
ei= f(x,)
where ei is the change in the current price share of value added in secror i, relativeto value added in all manuficturing. The independenr
variables,xP,are the wage per workerat the beginning, zv5,or end of dte
period, we,or value added per workerat the beginning or end of the period, vZabor va. La competitive labor markers, the wage per worker
shouldmeasurethe skill intensityof workersin each sector.Valueadded
per worker should reflectboth skill and capiralintensity and is a proxy
for technologicalcomplexity.Although valueadded per worker and the
wagerate are likelyto be correlared,both are used, as there is a possibility of divergence. Governments also may have employed one or the
other as indicators in targeting sectors.Wageper worker may be translated as "goodjobs,' while value added per worker is a natural measure
of "high productivity."
330
USING
RESOURCES
'E!jl
Consider the movement from inward orientation to more neutral incentives.The static Hecksher-Ohlin model predictsthat for low-income
economies sectorsthat exhibit low physicaland human capital-laborratios by international standards are the natural candidates for growth.
Hence, the prediction is that dvu/zdwband dvl.Idvab c 0. While many
newer theories of trade, including neotechnologyand those emphasizing increasing returns subordinate differenccsin factor endowments.
they are more likelyto describe intra-industry patterns of tradc among
industrial economiesthan the evolutionof the sectoralstructure of production of developingeconomies whoseproduction structure islikelyto
reflect differencesin factor proportions.
If interventionhas been of great importance in promoting the expansion of capital- or knowledge-intensivesectorsand, eventually,affecting
tradepatterns, the data should show dvjldwb>0 and/or that do1.Jdva
6>
0. An alternatetest of the impact ofselectivepromotion is to testwhether
the sectors that expandedexhibited high capitalintensityor wagesat the
end of the period. A result fvoring the interventionistview would be
ehi-iIdw or dzIlIdva > 0; the sectors that grew most exhibited a high.
capitalor high-wageintensity at the end of the period.
We have performed these tests on each of the Four Tigers plusJapan,
wsing two-digit lSIC classificationsof industrial sectors. Table A6.2
shows the sign of the regressioncoefficientand its significancefor each
period for each economy. The years chosen reflecta distillation of rhe
existing literature for each economy on significant intervals during
which intervention was practiced. It is not possiblein all casesto utilize
the ideal interval. In Japan, for example, data from before 1953 vary
considerablyin definition from those after 1953.
These are clearlyvery simple tests of the determinants of structural
changes in production but capturc the spirit of the opposingviews. The
statistical results must be employedcarefully.Even if it is slhownthat
there was a significanrnegativecorrelation between 9i and w1 , supporting the HOS view,some of the individualsectorsthat grewmost may still
have been high-wagesectors. Thus, we will examine some individual
sectors as well as report the statistical results.
Korea.For most periods, the signs of the wage and value-addedvariables in Koreaare negative.For the period 1973-80, the one characterized by promotion of the heavy and chemical industries, the negative
coefficientsof w and va for the beginning of the period are significant.
The same pattern occurs in 1980-88 as well as the entire 1973-88
33'
*;EA?rM1RACLE
Explaining
TableA6.2 Signsof Regressions
Shareof Sectors
Changein Value-Added
Economy
Period
IHengKong
Japan
WE
1973-80
1980-88
1973-88
+
+
+
+
+
-
+
+
Singiporre
Taiwan, China
VB
1953-63
+
4-
+
+
1973-80
1980-S8
1973-88
---
1969-73
1980-89
-;
1973-89
-+-
1966-86
(end) of
heperiod. VB
1963-73
1973-80
1980-89
Korea,
Rep.of
VE
Wu
1968-73
'
Signficncatthe0.10IeveL
= Value
period. This implies that at the two-digit level the relative size of more
labor-intensive seccorsincreased during each period On the face of it this
result is surprising. Quite apart from policies of selective promotion, this
was a period in which both labor skills and the capital stock were growing. One would have expected, according to the Rybcyznski theorem,
that the labor-intensive sectors would have declined in importance.
Part of the explanation for the relative growth of labor-intensive sectors despite the promotion of ostensibly capital-intensive suzbsectorsis
that the major branches that grew most rapidly in these years, and indeed over the entire period 1968-88, were machinery, electrical machinery, and metals-all sectors exhibiting somewhat less-than-average
labor productivity at both the beginning and end of the period- Conversely,some of the declining sectors induding iron and steel, industrial
332
USING
RESOURCES:E'FPtC
chemicals,and paper and paper producrs, were sectors with greaterthan-averageu and va1, A more completeexplanationof the contnuing growthof labor-intensivesectorsisthat they experiencedmore rapid
growthin TFr, and the cost-reducingeffectof productivitychangestimulated expansionof output by more than the output growth induced in
capital-intensivesectors by the decreasing relative cost of capital and
skills due to accumulationand subsidies.
In sum, the regressionsfor Korea indicate that: (a) the more laborintensivesectorsmaintained their relativeposition or grew, (b) many of
the promoted sectors themselveswere not capital intensiveat the tWodigit level;and (c) subsidiesto the cost of capital may nor have been sufficient to overcome the ongoing differentialsin TFP growth among
sectors.Moving away from the anecdotesabout individualchaebol,the
quantitative importance of governmentintervention to alter the structure of production is not confinned at the sectorallevel.
Japan. The regressionresultsshown forJapan in table A6.2 have no
significant coefficients.At leasta simple versionof HOS does not work,
probably nor surprisinglyasJapan by the earliest year considereain the
table, 1953,was sufficiendyadvaxced
so that intra-industryrather than
interindustry trade would have become an important determinant of
the sectoral producton structure.Scale economiesor a neotechnology
explanationof production and trade patterns are more useful at this
stage of development. Going back to 1945, which the data do not permit, would not change this picture much insofir as this earlier period
was one of reconstuction, in some casesof firly advancedsectorsthat
had brkenquite important before and during World War IL A simple
HOS story would be interesting to test for the period from the Meiji
restorationonwards.Once an economyis in a world of technology-and
scale-economy-baseddevelopment, the requisite conditions exist to
allowalmostany assertionto be made about the determinantsof the sectoral evolution of production.
HongKongandSingapore.The cwo island economies revealdiffcrent
patterns of development. In Hong Kong there is no relationship between our explanatory variables and patterns of production. In this
sense it is similar to Japan but derived fiom different causes.The slow
growth of capitalstock per workerin Hong Kon& partly reflectinglarge
immigration, miliated in favor of a slowerchange in industrial structure. There is simply very litde variance to be explned in the valueadded shares in Hong Kong.
333
RAC L E
period, certainly after 1953 when our data begin, Japanese trade parterns are more likelyto have been dominated by technologicaldevelopment and scale economies. The failure of Hong Kong to conform to
334
USING
RESOURCfSts$r.
neoclassical
comparative
advantageis at firstglancesurprising,given hie
enormousimportanceof its trade. Therewas, however,relativelylitde
variationin the dependentvariable,the changein the sectoralsharesof
valueadded.
Growth
Patternsof SectoralProducfivit
This sectionconsiderstwo issues,namely,the patternofsectoralproductivity growth and the impact of the changing composition of productionon the manufacmuring-wide
rateof growthof productivity.
The
issuehere is whethergiventhe observedvaluesof sectoralTFr growth,
A*i,the unusualevolutionof the sectoralpatternof productionin some
of the economieshad a significantquantitativeimpacton overallTFP
growth.
SIRANL MIRACLE
Appendix
6.2: Testsof the Relationship
between
TFPChange
andTradePolicies
HE
TFPG=
TableA6S3Regrssionof TFPGrowth,1960-89
(&tpenkt variable:totalfactorproductivitygrowth, 19610-89)
Na&refdsa
67
- inrn
.L7120(0.)1483
lnnlem
I,%0
2.
SalmlSycndlmr9G.
-9)
51
67
*.634 *419
(034n7
.2.40r
OM095)
.5.0403
(2.3467)
.4.4383
(. 2599
2-2-1
0.6722)
2.0941(44757)
2-6731
(0.6646)
2A.1(0.65939
I.6WS
(5.5121)
1.6382
(L25)
(O.59
390430
11.1417)
2.604 *
(1.1406)
3.069*
(1.5790)
3.443'
(I.6325)
015543
(LI441)
L52Z
(0.150
a4u6
(MG02M5)
.356
(e.ecs
1.1991
(1.045
(0o1073
-.
HiAtt
-
r,-
M)uud IV
LOW60
(2.55)55
047!50
(0.13Z)
(0-23712
025D0
p(0593
0.0255
(a.00W
E0L=75
(0.0073)
at7G
(04261)
55
(0Q4531)
CO50
-0
Q4457
0UA
.604
OD354
(0D33)
%0641
(.U0246)
M0
54),
CAW67 -
aAIeSs7
4817.
(0.50
e70
03673
KNG,'tr.
N -- >-- ff-
0R5579J
(24.A871.
-53.0356
(t4.5
.33W
(ld0219)
2399
(2.0633)
004
-
*-5L119I
.*t3538
(2067)
t4943
mliauraape&.n
apomn.
I9GWS
5i
4.584
(0A3041
*5F311J*
(189294)
3S53
(0.56501 (
AmW
53
-I .376(0.437)
49925 (0.9791
Dallwqrnamkrla
*'
69
St
(035712
:(0.573C
*-
4&5615(135162
50A684
23.W095)
o.dtr
::m
- -
. n-mrn
. - - .
: -
--
337
Fr~~X
MI.RACLE
USING
RESOURC
Atcunm
1880-1990
Indury
Serikes
Thoe
0.4
2.1
2.1
1.2
1.1
3.8
3.9
2.0
DDcvropingeconomicsb
1960-70
a. Developing
economics
includethecountiesofAricawiththe exception
of Soudh
Africr LatinAmeica;Asiawith die exceptionof China,the DenocmaicRepublicof
KoDrea,
Japn; Mongoli:.andViet Nan; and Oceaniawiththe exceptionof Australia
and NewZealand.
b. Industrialeconomiesindude Australia,Cnada. Japan.NewvZeland. SouthAfuic,
the UnitedScrcs, and countriesinXYVesrrmn
Europe.
- iwrc Squire(1981).
a~~~~J
bawwnjtunkt ?tlautwrr
'
nrmaBen Us tanRg Uqunc d
by do m. neei,i-g
bush sad
inyharlw.
ISMNWIh'NZd
kshn*qjuio.n
rwniy
timenateAmhek tug Kn
-Mndab,odbsnaid(M.AI-fIAB
dmmcniewairAn
nsw&ayrndeumciwa
swjydryc-nnpa
ben
atn
Theen,ttiian
ints
-- :
: f:
---
'--
, Lnalnbemi::
nmppoadi
-hn --
i-flOAbbidIwbbnS
amaiS
ledsnso
ksduapnd
hSI-UniWatSde
umuck
adanhis
d
sibicckExbnGDe,nnilmicce
u-
iltrHn
tngLn
dewlukInde=
FunnUmbw
pe of
num.
t
It ini
rels125elmns
panytq.o
- 6..m DTLCsd iumda
ar W mn k
ionm
eymm.totx is ,kni,a d
195* Etsd fdsetl9dwSuikmadl Fume
CRn
Onindelesun. iehuuansiiYwEmk
aa
Cod eFda Edung cmetd puidestpeindn
:CntwmmI
baokcahmn
ntto
,i
1tu-
4apter
in
6ih-k-m
hi
awstdasd
&g.
anchahe
s
bends iuqm.
enag
'
bcnriitss&s.-.
ut
pin
.3hiselnkid
innS dthw
se
epdm
tsaty
S
aujxMEn;MCmmi
'w u
capiaIcstwmrlnsfiS.
'
MJ*b
lksdiJ*l 6anchintnnas.
rkaalidlifirdismacmor
stm puivute
huskid widfir4ig
tcru
-nqtsin'nionvi_en-
SW:Smtuib aetbl"i a] 0
line in na. inplnst nalFuiwtnats-a
eneaominmhemsy
ainmn
tpedenn
dhbsufl4hiWntoteoIbesL
la
ualrB&)inua&cnL
ruw
1Y-21ailnz_
r c
AMS,EstdghAdNWwr-ducmimmi-T
INnamDU
finnkfj,rlnsnntkst5ankmn
(HI) mki&
tn
O
pplic
)etanassp
,dbmk&mxli
,l,ssi
dzctc
-
f&
-fitovr
sakvi
b6iIss Fd6ER.PwdioInwili.
ctadseopintrtCD4)
annl.
otnoMpUifMttI Ad
hEn.r.
i(DtC4md
Qinkiua
dumt. .syaniydsngd*
Usn
RadA Reuian LiCe
Lnb.aid Dlr
At danethire
uw
'wedaspheolaiu. Cmavitccilnp
ahh&C
,, -baksiiar.-i.
u
dw p- l-dia wm &LSwpAOt
qykriogiDI
mi" ,
'
lmorntd1rmllysw
nadce1Jhun
trdnefidlkiusndtelkisteel
- m'- idadwiegnn
dinm.
,;Mstnie pidhoe
enom (B
1a lmd
25d5f-imdtrnim.
IMtlnsnemutermsicdsmanitnl
depCSfbUIadruttnlub
luta~w
Lrmnamo(iutehab.
ITden
dwpntncdadmifillsiA
iumadiaitsdwaWnim
ILkand Uno" ikerdflq'ek.it
/ort..rDatEd mknatu
39Q,
he irans.
fer
liauibsnbe fRn HlU5et to Hls 1in litA
murafltk
t
andscowinnisldu&
y,'% eiW-Balimcomuimnu cirye mebawithdie
sin rdIasEqking,ts
G et
qBiz.Wl.tobmU
mnndma%imaams nid
hT,
dti-nirnma AiedmdnpduWed
o inte
fini ecano.
St
imoatnspipsad
vith
w-binnlnge1yforbamla
;nrk"du
'
bkh
IVA4ime-wgnla
9IS-Tbeerrcrk
cadmftgeablkxd
19P3I:1iedfeecI
odue
aesnu -r pin
Hanl og
tqir
Ddgt-TudSC
sii
bynttnn
kn-
gstdi
!tmoba..It I.L
rihadjrnnnat
TuingC.o
~~~~nsaa
h- (3W0
snunreyA
.fflaw-dd
-In
Tudiduifr
r&d
hum 6W awi
eoniumNMmforfrwva.x. Yeq ib
n&kr inarusul bsdznmgpam.
Aldwien-cking
kn.utim we
19*
6kTn
sop innrvmewidn
5
-i nenuis
dtpma .iln - undo th
dimisonJibe achuop wlln6
A-dairt$EI
byvkita&-s
Jfrg fly
)Isrssien
N.o
dRtel
puMladan
hd
pwrdfBtk.w-i eye
nedmw
Laureleng
~~ ~~~~~dcwys
tna..sTsdahgaingaina
(^~~~~~~~
p:Xd
im. _
aqu
muse
quoky. Pa-
- inaI
- :Eri*ntd
.
: Ninmss
- -- - : :-.-
SwitinamdlEueGCmrm
--
lil
nde
h sh &eupa
plscigsghe,
nw.rWa'
nmh339
339>
MIRACLE
iASJ*
(confinued)
Table A6.5
Fi_nes 1
tflnwu&gku
-fnanq
.f?e.emw
hmaClg7talwdmailunlmeuhaa
(I 91
hig CWaet maeberamtnls
(bean.
'ngleanEcesnlldCa
Ml
eF
e-
ra(nS).1
a'el
amarke
JImeqIad
ruin
Jq_
~n
Ifl&selandpwLeaand(pualk
I"h ly bn6 pwnal.nLapuend
ceargnadrMh,lmwL
by Ereiga.
wesneJ
TniT
uu hu
IJ
hakbd
boan..
lWtSinI9 NWiedlum
btw6n(Seg)wem endvn aul
BAten
Inf:
te
ro
l esgi
Batik Iti
incs
sudiarlsnlf iea
elek
bfldJUb-& EarnWerd
Tdkyq DrLlr
trannd
lmae.
hebd
petin
I97Puealing
eqeriancC ietCFi) muSs
mpl6.
flfaRnictiuon.sinurinral
eiclLd n.UhULi
/misarkar(pulickmmdAutiuL
I9eat*Gw nubeaeeet a
u
.n
nrlca andt
ISW&T mmuyiuco
ng
nwaed
fi.rm
SrngpnErd
Feuip atitia
maianheniphntheTLy.Snk
wme
m
ExdaKJ.wafuned
-tan.
p4mt
Iwkueai
Sesehreem
(CC)mkask mmneiL
.trdin
thteUs
mya
andns
IVRf=
M."
_y
,fiecu
tse
is
bue
witi iwn
The MinyfFlhlna
mpmnimry
eauu
eA
U werwik pwns fr. the akae Lwa%
e
SecuidmitedadEhnd LnTreeleandlki
.J.lr
. _J.mlrghti6d
J
ELASp
mpAmdeycaie
eunainenda ituahuks..
son
m
pnd udea
iItStnMU.ddl
iaJ
ndwepirle
dia
Mea
inada
In
Dq*
191: EatbiMlu dthellWd
prcedes
Coonamtidenaeda.ceqnr
I...caaaar.L
cw lon&
tN
Itnh beanit anenimpat herniae law
iftiUenUIStrd.
r
ed
u lanird
ag
I
Sequlds
.Kern
4p.f
~~
-~
-r msigid.sunfreinrdepode
=
tnt Mm bekake .ukflntin
b he.deeetw (NR loaig
eiq
Dil insmialen (NOR) imnm niem
dcpdtmc a
MON li
mlnrt
ihmsm.L
gd
1W
6r
maini.
IA9 rlhid
.a
CD,
:.
:r.'o-Sf.th,
Ilsotlrfeaciual eapelisn t
ie td l.
i
pq-e takre
Jilt csneni
cualdieetI.Setupcstmeaed
lieiwg
ifnhtet-Sr
i;1..
s up OTCtae
Ieefarkinu
anM*bUn ieUd ahea my
I bgewen
. PIa
po4u
nm.nkn-aae
banldlagnrld
)mPAwdl kgwidaehID cace?
JW
lamemat lnaancnmpudics ate
scaaelckshanSipuaeauadmaqqwd
licthcc
JNIPouaiaac
fmlap
a
hey.mkannrioait
atcljeeitk
inpdoeiii
ipe
roNaliq_iIFi
ii
r-oel
vnXd
iFa_balloerd M eAs
_:,_
340
340
&i*.h4n
NllFIswrb-UL
dkpoir
A-m
csneed
t% t4iodd Inla
eptoh
lJuCaeGnrt
cheat
eua-mnani cn?i.eri
IWI-AS:P
nwn,61 Udissad ailowdaeyof
rewdmmicaeidfrnephink.
eagn
lt
fwaegunla (enenere r`fieigs
te
Bn IS is I
btd.ia iama
incndtudi64 in 199li. Deei. p
if cngrefAmuiei6c%ukhleaditccank%
erpsdamenprctr.nbuineband
Noa atw bankas ma any &W
tna.2
qchncAhelFlsmeded
FIksaJ9c.
s
ewiInen
.-
la shiauia
iinpne
mhlhiscynrf inae(MOljwapeniassal
rma pe.tionnsftWBk
pn&i6l g;dd
fahnv
in rej
rnd
a p.*hmfia
arW
r=;o&m
f6rtLirg'
USING
~iapig
1971:hmnaei aianhrfind&pdewicf
nmmzho flmyw,g. hiajlty 6cua
ffkb loUtes aam.csa11icMFumnl
Inkik&p.sitmuinr am pr uawiru
aM.opta
Mi.hudantf194hmoaku
haiLbmab Howemi.dndc
bmil kw Inured aainsO
theyhawha. napmdto insni
w6iiu ne&lernn
fl%-KmJus"s
Li
cIS&E
w nab&hd
NW
50, &Ldqwia p-cer.
wmardubinmnbedq
rmaota
nmnduat
if LRid
hJAiog&t-eonpickalyddsdn
p &hf.
Idga
Jtaincfbhulu prcaci, of
dqiWmnc anvocrUe
i maumpnamu
andaural of
9
buil
jMs--aoVmei.fUanaic
6i.& mnd0TC
1374-KNew Anaidelimuamsn
ngmitoinhclupot..49 prenm
139W8
h A kaC.1'dohia Wiath
gasiddnmenogle
mu' KManddhcfamdanX
AnbudgesZudiddspli
dfitpakiLm
rordineindng Ktndialaw
1398 mALina%ar
Finadi lasituhm.Ar-~cwjw
~~~~~~~bn~nchh
(End.
nhh.rCmbsponlosasd&4
57&MA wnianuadu
Laekbaing
Ewa
.aac ouhAseleiA
CD%
mnd
hr&r
sit
alibe,tindaweL
drpca
aaqumcninamn
Flame.ma
h1 Bwm.l melube.
aua0cmdrm
n
oa sriau
19~~~~~IN-%O,SshSab,rdan
cff-,bca
tifan
manroe
plfthklAngSram
biWngto
1 UL
-)flCrmmrulbmk-alminhunced Bar
phmuLSac
cadlgeuzie
h Sfiogper.l
~~~~~~~~~~~17r0
asa
hraiaglirnbna
aiiua
aWeCD*
ro
frran
t^ii0ilbding
Sk~~ar
CLCruStbaku6,
iuqMaCCaKrhia.
1:&ibdla
c ue,pWcctc
'n..-taupary.
2dIcrjta
/>sindl
3 aflhlsc
LadIng1atehrodcednmanlhe.
199-.(snt ISZ211lutternilaprnn
at liamfln
car-
RESOURCESSO
sliad6
poad rtheakingAadZ5l'ManlFonmanceGimpma
Act
p
wdn f
SoL:i..tm,.lacu
.1M.
lc&g guidolina
andactig awtdiinmsu.darda&afiaaCd,hainnd it
- dhr~~~~~.M aJeimonqefi
and -gi
)ni cceaDTlcsdbi
vm&g-;ia:-r-
tnO
-w
ii7kCamplcc~fi-Nrad libaclin-
IWI
9Aanmoderelmcnminoal
IAf
uam.Bankouitn
aa J&odeurmia.
J"ifSupwpurS&Exhap
kg fitcennuccd*mow dqaodtand
IcadhguotaJimam Rial
aintuudrlpmz
1
aftoe Ads=ODi. AdLs
I6IxMA a
I=
9laUhlmI
dwSIngar pveI.
a!,1niidloocuiy
E
aFeat
MqencdcwlS1VpmrCG&1dEn
dbze.pupcdatnimnmsd
--_iona
tSlgt
had..rbankiang
lnnard
lacun
flflSWtFocf dooic
15M.kEorkWhh MqntuAki&
or
iyaVSaypm
AlonigwmAt
canal bau'ngAocticm. mope-bnou-
and
Mlaa1fi
Stock
buk par-
lanti
c..mnnpecl
in apitban orfbeeW
c L
hniari
mir"uiomefluainidey*riwai
pIMatler4l
inlocalboaokomps.Poretbasik
oatior
Jfmgn t
madlbomgarvhow, nuk(hd
tacnve tehdi,19 poite sula,
re...
1950(Lirbclsd C
aim.
Ckit
at.
*drpltionsadlarcog.it
iSa
meien
kb;-itpebid.
*lirinn
I.Ab
rofihltDam
reTolwet
awidr uatrumap
.aatnr
*
-aciallraktimcrpoitas
g~~~~maetmaa.ryraL
* Imhbclitttallepa&
nemlbnga
-n aaadalbaukaledimcdepm-o
.bat anepm.Abormiued
.h&dbAlh,v&o.5oa.dii
hl.z
T.iwao19t
IQiEahlsbehrx
Suit.tud.a
t mccoy
nTh.alc
RappmhscMakanr
mlet11CP. CDaamnW.4Atwit
awknntctnwinal. inauacsmm.
1956 Craed .W.&bovebadaig
long-mmlendin hwodam.
N Cepnui
c.rtahn
naaapmnicaanal
InacknEacsof
ioadligrolumbrod.
anl
nof oiunp
Jwifletnnrymecti6pkbocWitnca
,nau.rin. bmI ficoInuSpnnz hid
iatyiuedbyuatybw
73&11J
AttaInhit
1 ban mw
fmnddradcpitbd
d
a
e
ow
I*oaow
r.vlmrrial
aJbn
padpermttdartoiWtid.scutlq6a1aw
.ppmnL Madaadnsmcuicaiomfiurfoaig bade.malm)ined
CdllhOGtoMldkrhgaenIf1
ew .dn
lNtPcekd
1562habonglwaIn
bat11strada
;
uclikehagnharm.aidndunl.
r-
D.SsxhiS ad Exitnu b
Crwnuiona
ucpbcnm.pnvreaepital ni.arktpeaaks.
IWi tfmbl&d aedqmiIa rpnce
copses .
lflnlSboib rh
tlni
ucccmopatuy
Zn6
IN*-JflA.."dclSriabTrmanatdn
I.A. t
acpdwMaaenrmandb.tnauborahmIthan
ainp.
Raiwd banbinglausnD
puohlbktcrdiemn Iiewma
kdaiuAwld
maas
mW
ITTmanrortoa
ltpleamatedo
ate.
f/m"an
gto
purcm fiadand a
ansby~
EnltaqccftluiIp
trdnStds
J^*LdC>
FanceCsNp,
ticrmuAdpmdu
/Is*hrbeglarff@6f:-_IT
-n
/fftSBpS:r3
caabl Lsa
II"urewse
E uubcd d.c trer;Anbc
Rtrctcioa;fr
titmmucaL
Ca. maktow
heiJMA&iur.jpnba.ndioemc
iH mintd-i
machemmanh.wiOgdiwtcndhac
Oay.r Pa
cdt cmibriuinafocf mersan
nd iea
acsaaahimunsdrdlpih
wmaunaal
mi5i
dnfitlcpipntadtc
.na.Xcmain
q-yydm.rllaoap
sIrkn
:flhauzJMvs
baJutk
Ret.
ti.dindopMMimdaanigf
~~~~~~~~~~~InhatWdcCS.aI
~ff
WDmillion bOIL
am padh
clicducaon InF
ISthSaundsandSabaa
-
:~
,9,d.i4
aada
~~~~~mn&,uno
ltmcl napdcnacuaad miumntimarrff
113qsskd.p
startd buioandoin 197tkdua.
pw"-Ph.
-
,,em ledwiard
0am.d
cmasal wnit
--
-*,-*-
5jE
eMRSCINMRALE
Notes
1. See Greenwaldand Stiglimz(1988) on the effecrof
coordinationfiailuresin labor markets.
7. The costs do not derivesolelyfrom the misallocadionof labor impliedby gaps in marginalproductamong
workcrswith thc same human capitalendowments.The
rarelyexceed 1-2 per2. Altematively,
conscantrealwagescouldbe due to a re- costs of such static misallocations
duaion in surpluslabor(Lewis1954; Ranisand Fei 1961). cent of GNP. Dynamiccosts can run much higherwhen,
for example.employmentin enterprisesis excessive(im3. A populationwilldoublein 87 yearswhen it isgrowv- plyinga wedgebetweenthe wageand the marginalproding at an annual rateof 0.8 percennwhen it is growingat
uct of labor) and the subsidiesrequired to keep firms
3.2 percent a populationdoubles in only 22.5 years.See afloat divert scarcesavingsfrom productiveinvestments.
Squire (1981) for a historicalcomparisonof population Sec Gelb, Knight, and Sabor(1991).
and laborforcegrowthin developingcountriesin the cur8. A labor market is segmentedwhen some workers
renly high-incomecountriesin the nineteenthcentury.
reccivehigher wages than others with the sarmelevel of
4. For the period 1989-2000 population isesrimated human capital simply by virtue of their sector of
to growat an annual rate of 0.8 percent in Hong Kong, employment.
03 in Japan, 0.9 in Korea, 1.2 in Singapore,and 1.4 in
9. Clearly,a high share of the public sector in wage
Thailand.Indonesiaand Malaysiaare forecastto growat
higherratesof 1.6and 2.3 percent,respectively.The share employmentgrowth is not definitiveevidenceof a relativelyhigh share of surpluslabor in the "modemsector.'
of the populationlessthan fourteenyeawold was31 percent, circa 1900, in the currentlyhigh-incomecountries. The publicsectorcould be findingproductivejobs for all
its employees.
In 1989 it was30 percentin EastAsiaand 36 percent in
LatinAmerica;in 1986it was46 percent in Sub-Saharan
Africa.
10. In more than one-third of the economies,private
sctor employrnentactuallydecreased,implying that the
public sector accounted for all the observedincreasein
5. Increasesin the rechnologicalcomplexityof nonagriculturalproductionand in the sizeof establishments total wageemployment.
bring greater divisionof labor and, hence, increasesin
skilldifferentiationat thesame time that greateravailabil11. While there is no doubt about the roleof governmeat in suppressingunions in Koreaand Singapore,in
ity of educationalopportunitiesincreasesthe supply of
Taiwan, China, there is some questionwhethergoverncducatedworkers.
ment action, for example,
prohibitingthe ChineseFeder6. Labor market efficiencyis assessedby comparing ation of Labor from engagingin collectiveaction, was
marginalproduczivitiesin losingand receivingactivities. decisive.Market forces,and in particularthe sizedistribuworkersin Taition of firms,alsohelp explainwhyso fe%w
Evidenceof changesin laborallocationsuggeststhat individualschooseamongalremativeoccupations,industries, wan, China, are union members.See Fields (1992) and
chapter 4.
and geogaphic areasas though they had a fine regardfor
marginalcosts and benefits.Ihough behaviorconsistenrt
12. SeeFields(1992),who noresthat until 1972unions
with rationaldecisionmakingon the part of individualsis
a necessarycondition,ir isnot sufficientto ensureoptimal were freeto bargainoverwages,whichwerelargelydetermined by marketforces,and Freeman(1992),who, refrallocationof labor. It is also necessaryfor workersto be
price-takersand to be freeto enter any industryor occu- ring to the post-1972 labor market poliqc regime, has
pation for which theyare qualified.Restrictionson free- asserted,"Singaporcis possiblythe most interventionist
dom of cntry arise from such sources as nonopsony
governmentin thecapitalistworld."It is irterestingto note
power, discimination, government interventions,and
that the sameinstrument-the NationalWagesCouncil,a
deliberationcouncildiscussedin chapter4-was useddurworkers'associations.
342
USING
RESOURCBS$T:
stndard of good performance. Its industrial rationalizadion programs used as criteria cost reductions that were
based on the costsof inTernaionalcompetitors.This was
enforcedthrough the tireat of internationalcompetition
as imports were graduallyliberalized(for example,machine tools and steel).
22. The meritsof well-managedand fbcuseddirectedcredit programs have long been advocatedbv Japanese
govemment officials.For example,a study by the Overseas EconomicCooperation Fund has argued that government involvement in directing crcdit is warranted
when there is a significantdiscrepancybetween private
and socialbenefits,when the investmenrrisk of particular
projectsis too high, and when informationproblemsdiscourage lending to small and medium-sizefirms (OECF
1991). Use of policy-basedlending rather than other
forms of industrial assistance(for example,lower taxes,
grants, and so on) is premised on the argument that the
main constraincfacing new or expandingenterprisesis
their accessto extemal finance at reasonableterms and
conditions. Directed-credit programs involving small
subsidiesovercomethis consuaint, but Japaneseofficials
havestressedthat to avoid the misuseof funds and abuse
343
LERAGLE
31. Exportpricescan be set in the international(unprotected)markersat long-run marginalcost. Is is possible to show, under certainsimplifyingasswnpdons(see
Spence(1981), dhatoptimal production of the firm entails setting the marginalvalue of output cqual to the
long-runmarginalcost.
USING
RESOURCES
lR
A
CIRACLE
346
iVj
A.,
q!TER
Foundatons
of RapidGrowthGetting
theFundamentals
Right
HESTRESS
ONPOUCYFUNDAMENTALS
ISA HALLMARK
OFALL
347
#PACI
RACLE
Ensuring
LowInflaionandCompetitive
Exchange
Rates
Macroeconomicstabilityand low inflationwere necessarypreconditionsfor rapid growth in all eight HPAEs.The keyelement was the management of the fiscal deficit. Fiscal policies havc been generally
conservativein avoiding inflationaryfinancing of budget deficits, and
some HPAEs,
such as Singaporeand Taiwan, China, have run sustained
budgetsurpluses.While Indonesia,the Republicof Korea,and Malaysia
acquired considerableforeign debt, their debt to export ratios were
lowerthan other developingeconomies,so creditorsnever lost faith and
they never faceda fuil-blowndebt crisisrequiringrescheduling.Moreover,budget rules and legislationrequiringcharsovereigndebt be used
for developmentexpenditureshelped to ensure that borrowingfunded
investnent rather than consumption.The successfulrecord of low inflationand sustainedgrowthof the HPAEsreinforcesthe viewthat there
is no substitutefor fiscaldiscipline.
The HPAEs' successin export-drivengrowthwas predicaredon competitiverealexchangerates.Prudent fiscaland monetarypoliciescoupled
with flexibleexchangerate managementwereusedto keep exchangerate
movementsalignedwithdchangingstructuresof trade protectionand inflationdifferentialswith tradingparmers.The HPAEsavoidedstrategiesof
macrocconomicstabilizationthat stressedthe roleof the exchange rtc in
breakinginflationaryexpectations.Rather, exchangerate adjustments
weresupportedby expenditure-reducingfiscalmeasures.While Indonesia,Korea,and Thailand have had periodsof realappreciation,they did
not try to maintain a fixedexchangerate regimein the faceof inflation
ratesmuch greaterthan thoseof their tradingpartners.
The HPAESrespondedto externalshocksmore quicklyand effectively
than other developingeconomies.East Asian policymakershave been
more adept at managingfiscalcontractions-cutting expendituresand
increasingrevenuesin a growth-orientedframework-to attain viable
deficittargets.In contrast,governmentselsewherecommittedto funding
largeentidementprograrins-incometransfers,untrgeted subsidies, cessivepublic sectoremployment,and loss-makingpublic enterprisesoften lackedthe flexibilityto deal efficientlywith budget contractions.
Rather than cutting spendingon entidements,theYhave often resorted
to cuttingpublic investment.
In eachHPAE,a technocraticelite insulatedto a degreefiom excessive
political pressure supervised macroeconomic management. The insula-
348
POLICIES
CI
tion mechanisms
rangedfromlegislation,suchasbalancedbudgetlaws
in Indonesia,Singapore,
and Thailand,to customand practicein Japan
and Korea.All protectedessentially
conservative
macroeconomic
policiesby limitingthe scopefor politiciansand interestgroupsto derail
thosepolicies.
Building
HumanCapital
benefitswereparticularly
evidentin thecountryside.
Basiceducatonin theHPAESis highlyorientedtowardtheacquisition
of generalacademicskills,while post-secondaryeducation tends to be
oriented towardvocatonal skills.SomeHPAEs have alsobeen unusually
large-scale
importersof educationalservices,particularly
in vocationally
and technologically
sophisticateddiscplines.In addition,enterpriseleveltraining,muchof whichwassubsidized,accelerated
technological
acquisition.
The benefitsof dosingthegap betweengirlsand boysin primaryand
secondaryschoolenrollments
havebeensubsmntial,
evenin economies
in whichfemalelaborparticipationratesarelow.Bettereducatedmodtersraisebetrereducatedchildren,complementing
publicinvestments
in
basiceducation.The rapid increasein the educationalattainmentof
womencontributedto Ehe earlydeclinein fertiiy, whichin turn resultedin a lessrapidlygrowingschool-agepopulation.As a result, mDre
resourceswere availableper child, in homes and in the dassroom.
CreaingEffective
andSecureFinancial
Systems
Financial sector policies in tie
HPAEs
crucialfunctions.First,theyencouragedfinancialsavings.Second,they
channeled savingsinto activitieswith high social returns. There was
great varietyin the policiesand institutions used to accomplishthese
349
_RALLE
P O L I C IES AN Dn:rIcv
A:
-X1RACLE
industries.In thesecases,however,domesticmachinerygenerallyfalls
short of internationalstandards.Such machinerybecomesyet another
high-costimportsubstitutethat inhibitsexports.
Limiting
the BiasagainstAgriculure
Agriculturehas playeda morecentralrolein the H1IAEsthan in many
other low- and middle-incomeeconomies.Wide adoption of Green
Revolutiontechnology,
highinvestmentin ruralinfrastructure,and limiteddirectand indirecttaxationof agriculturemeantthat ruralincomes
and productivityrosemorerapidlyin EastAsiathan in other regions.
As in othereconomies,agriculturalsectorsin the HPAES
werea source
of capitaland laborfor the manuficturingsector.But in EastAsiathese
resouroesweregenerallypulled into manufacturing by risingwagesand re-
Creating
Institutionsto PromoteGrowth
rT-%HE
Sam the policies they have adopted and partly from the insti.1trutionalmechanisms they created to implement thenL AUlof
the HPAEscreated secure institutional environmentsfor private investment that led to very high levels of private sector-led growth. HPAE
civil servicesrange oromthe highly meritocratic and insulated bureaucracies of Japan, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan, China, to the less
effective and less insulated public administrations of Indonesia and
Thailand. Nevertheless,each of these economies has a core of technocratic managers. In Indonesia and Thailand, their scope is limited to
management of the macroeconomy. In the other HPAEs,competent
POLICIES`
Second, in the HPAEswith high-quality bureaucracies, rules and procedures governing public sector employment were institutionalized and
insulated fromn political interventions. In particular, recruitment and
promotion were merit based. Third, public employment was accorded
high status. These factors improved the quality of the bureaucracy, discouraged corruption, and created an esprit de corps among civil servants
that helped insulate the bureaucracy from political pressures.
Each of the HPAE governments created institutions to improve communication with the private sector. Formal deliberation councils esrablished in five of the economies-Hong Kong, Japan, Korea, Malaysia,
and Singapore-included government officials, journalists, labor representatives, and academics. The economic and political benefits of these
councils, and of the more informal mechanisms in the other HPAEs,are
impossible to measure systematically. It is likely, however, that economically they improved coordination among firms and improved the flow
of information between businesses and government Politically they
helped establish a commitment to shared growth and reduced rentseeking. Information sharing made it more difficult for firms t curry special favors fiom the government and for government officials to grant
special concessions. Thus the deliberation councils helped check opportunistic behavior. The deliberation councils in Japan, Korea, and Singapore also performed an important monitoring function, assessing
performance at the industry or economy leveland administering contests.
Consultative mechanisms in Indonesia and Thailand were less formatl, and their role in facilitating business-government communication
was much more limited. Malaysia's experiment with deliberation councils is quite recent but appears to hold some promise in the area of
macroeconomic management.
Inteirvening
in Markets
MIRACLE
354
POLICIES
AE
1.A
poretheirindustrialstructuresevolvedlargelyin a mannerconsistentwith
comparative
advantage.
marketfoirces
and factor-intensiy-based
It is nortaltogethersurprisingthar industrialpolicyin Japan, Korea,
andTaiwan,China,tendedto be marketconforming.Theseeconomies,
indusalthoughselectivelypromotingcapital-and knowledge-intensive
tries,still aimedto createprofitable,internationallycompetitivefirms.
Taiwan,China,placedgreatemphasison pricecomperitiveness
in evaluatingthe performanceof its largepublic investmentsin intermediate
and capitalgoods.Moreover,in Japan especially,
but alsoin Korea,institutionalmechanismsthat stressedcooperativerelationsand exchange
of information betveen firms and governmentintroduced a largc
amountof marketinformationinto the processof industrialpolicyfbrmulacion.And the yardstick used to evaluateindustrial policies'
success-mainlyexportperformance-provideda markettestof the success or failure of the policy instrumentschosen. Thus the seeming
successof industrialpolicyin thesethreeeconomiesprobablyrestsnor
on pickingwinners-that is, on the adroitselectionof whichindustrial
subsectorto promote-but on the setting of export targetsfor promoted industries and the use of export performanceto assesspolicies.
Our testsmayhavefailedto captIe one importantaspectof industrial policyin Japanand Korea:informationexchangein a competitive
framework-in short, contests-may havelessenedinvestmentcoordinationproblemsand resultedin earlierand betterinvestmentsin what
ultimatelybecamemarket-conforming
sectors.But among the HPAEs,
onlyJapanand Koreahad the instiutionalcapacityto organizeand refereethe kind of contestsusedin formulatingand implementingindustrial policies.
Despitetheir potential benefits,collaborativearrangements,especiallywhencombinedwith accessto scarceresourcessuchas foreignexchange and cradit, have a high risk of capture by the participants.
Capture was avoided-and resource allocation may have been
improved-in Japan and Koreaby the combinationof repeatedrelationshipsbetweenbusinessand governmentand the useof exports,not
domesticGDPgrowth,as the yardstickby which the successof the industrialstrategywasmeasured.In other HPAES,such elaboratecontests
were not used-for example,in Hong Kong, Singapore,or Taiwan,
China-or wereunsuccessfil,as in the casesof the heavyindustriafization drive in Malaysiaor recent attempts at technologicalleapfrogging
in Indonesia.
355
.X4
N-MIRACLE
Repressing
Interest
RatesandDirecting
CreditWorked
Somefimes
All HPAEscontrolled interesr races on deposits and loans during much
oF their rapid growth. Low real interest rates on deposits and loans increased corporare equity by transferring resources from savers (mostly
households) to borrowers (mosdy firms). At the same rime, by limiting
the spread between deposit rates and loan rates, govemments prevented
banks from earning excessiverents. On the downside, such controls undoubtedly discouraged banks fiom taking on riskier, nontraditional
dients.
Interest rate repression was key to the HPAEs'directed-credit programs. Low interest rates on loans resulted in excess demand for credit,
which permitted governments to take an active role in credit rationing.
This in turn gave governments strong leverage with which to influence
the beihavior of firms. In this section we discuss why directed credit was
relatively successfid in hie HPAES but often had large negative consequences elsewhere. WVethen consider whether such polidtes could be effectively adopted in the increasingly open capital markets of most
developing economies.
Interest rate subsidies were smaller in the HPAEs than in other developing economies. In several HPAES, government-directed credit served
primarily to signal commercial banks and private investors which sectors
enjoyed govemment support Banks and private investors then selected
projects within those sectors and offered them additional funding at
commercial rates. Moreover, credit was frequently allocated according
to export performance. Our evidence leads us to condude that credit
programs directed at exports yielded high social returns and, in the cases
of Japan and Korea, other directed-credit programs also may have increased investment and generated imporcant spiliovers. Even within
East Asia, however, when interest rate subsidies were large, or export
performance criteria were not imposed, directed credit often went to inefficient ventures and those with low social returns.
The financial sector policies used by the HPAEs in the 1960s through
the early 1980s took place in a world economy in which it was possible
to close domestic capital narkets. Since the early 1970s, developing
economies have become ever more integrated with the global capital
markeL While this has reduced government? already limited abiity to
restrict capital flight and speculative capital inflows, it has also given
them accessto less expensive capital and offered them better possibilities
356
POLICIES
AND:P
Under these conditions, the choice for developing-economy policymakers is not between financial integration with the global market and
isolation. Rather, it is between two-way integration that permits outflows and thus facilitates inflows, on the one hand; and de facto one-way
integration that consists primarily of unauthorized capital flight, on the
other. The HPAEs have recognized this dcanging global environment; all
357
'&1N
IR A CLE
are moving-albeit at different speeds-to liberalizetheir financial sectors and integrate them more closelyinto internationalfinancialmarkets.
Financialsector interventions-specifically repressionof interest rates
and contest-based direcEionof credit-may have contributed to rapid
growth in such economiesasJapan, Korea,and Taiwan.,China. Bur eadi
of these economies had competent and insulated bureaucracies and
banks to select and monitor projects, and each applied export performance as the main yardstickfor credit allocation.In addition, thesegovernmentswere able during the earlystagesof rapid growth to closetheir
financialmarkets to the outside world. Few developingeconomiestoday
have the institutional resources to consistendy impose performancebased criteria for credit allocation. Moreover,the capital markers of all
economiesare becoming moreand more integraced&
Thus, successfulrepressionof interest rates and contest-basedcredit allocationmay only be
possiblefor the very few developingeconomieswith strong institutions
and then only to a very limited degree.
Export
Push:A Successful
Mixof Fundameitals
andInterventions
The export-push strareg;y-the use of findamentals and interventions to encouragerapid export growth-was the HPAEs' most broad
based and successfulapplication of selectiveinterventions.Furthermore,
of the many interventions tried in East Asia, those associatedwith their
export:push hold the most promise for other developing economies.
While the changing trading environmentwill limit the use of highly targeted policies-similar to those of Japan and Korea during their early
export growth-the broad pro-xport stance characceristicof all eight
HPAEs remainsviable.
Trade policiesin all the HPAES (exceptHong Kong)passedthrough an
import-substitutionphase with high and variableprotection of domestic
import substitutes.In allcases,however,policiesthat stronglyfavoredthe
production of import substitutesto the detriment of exports were abandoned, and HPAE
governmentsadopted strategicpro-export policiesthat
establisheda free trade regime for exportersand offereda range of other
incentivesfor exporrs.This export-pushapproachprovided a mechanism
by which industry moved rapidlytoward international best practice, despirehighly imperfct world marketsfor technology.
Export-pushstrategieswere implenented in three verydifferentways
in the HPAES. Hong Kong and Singaporeestablishedfree trade regimes,
358
POLICIES
AN
359
S'IWN'M[RACLE
lhe Export-Push
Strateg in a Changing
TradingErwiroment
The early HPAE export drives-those of Hong Kong, Japan, Korea,
Singapore, aiLdTaiwan, China-took place amid the cxpanding world
economy of the 1950s to the mid-1970s. Economic growth in the industrial economies was rapid, barriers to trade were declining, and
global effortsto spur free trade under the General Agreement on Tariffs
and Trade (GArr) were the order of the day. Times have changed. Economic growth has slackened in the mature economies thar traditionally
provided the main markers for developing-economy exports. Regional
trade groupings are becoming more and more prominent. Industrial
economies have begun to retaliate agnst allegedly unflair export practices by imposing quotas or countervailing duties. In such a trading environment, can today's developing economies successfi&llyemulate the
export-push strategies of the early HPAEs?
In the following section we break this question into two parts. First,
will there be adequate, open markets for developing-economy manufactured exports? Second, will the need for market access constrain the developing cconomies' use of export-push strategies? We conclude that
markets will be adequate and open and thar an export push, therefore,
remains possible. However, global realities will limit developing
economies'abiliry to adopt rhe more interventionist instrumcnts of export promotion. The experience of both the northern HPAEs,with their
mixed export-push regimes in which protection of the domestic marker
coexisted widt incentives or requirements to export, and the Southeast
Asian NIEs, with their gradual trade liberalizationscoupled with improvemencs in export insitutions and availability of export credit, suggests that economies thar are in rhe process of trade liberalization would
benefit from providirg specific incentives to manufactured exports.
Modest subsidies to exports could be linked, for example, to the bias
against exports in the domestic economy and bound by strict time limits linked to the pace of trade policy reform.
36o
POLICIES
ANDP
RASW&NMIRACLE
world merchandise trade (Riedel 1988). Emerging exporters are unlikelyto approachthis level for many years to come. In 1989, for example, Sub-SaharanAfrica'sexporcsof manufactured goods amounted to
just 0.43 percent of world exports (United Nations 1992).
Evenif industrial economy marketsgraduallybecome lessaccessiblc,
changesin the global trading environment are creating new opportunities for South-South trade. As recently as the mid-1980s, importsubstitution strategies in most developing economies forced
developing-economyexporters to rely heavily on industrial-economy
mark-ets.Since then, formerly closed economies in Asia, Sub-Saharan
Africa, the Middle East, and Latin America have responded to debt
problems, slow growth, and the need to raise fresh capital by becoming more and more outward oriented-and therefore more open to
imports. They have assumed greater obligations under the GA1T and
through numerous regional trading arrangements.' Under these circumstances, the potential for Soudt-South trade has increased
considerably.
But while global markets are growing, they are also becoming more
and more competitve. Each economy seeking to emulate the East
Asian axport-push model will encounter difficulties because many
other economies are trying to do the same. For example, Collins and
Rodrik (1991) estimate that Eastern Europe and the republics of the
former SovietUnion will increase their share of world trade from 10 to
23 percent, relying initially on agricultural conmnoditiesand laborintensivegoods that compete direcdywith the products of other developing economies.
Despite this heightened competition, severaltrendssuggest that expanding global mnarketswill remain open to developing-economymanufactured exports. Onc of these is the continuing effort to open
markets under the auspicesof the GAIT (see box 7.1). The other is the
growing role of regional trading blocs,which present a major opportunity for increasedglobal trade (see box 7.2). Who providesthe mnarket
if all economies push exports? The dramatic growth of trade within
Asia makes clear that export-oriented economiescreatemarkets for import. To compete internationally, exporcersmust meet global standards of quality and price, for which they need accessto technology,
capital,and intermediate inputs at world prices.As a resulr, production
in Asia has become more and more international, with capital goods
coming from Japan, labor-intensiveassemblybeing perfbrmed in low362.
POLICIES
s7fFiTr
Pb~~ ~~~~-
AN:
D.
er' he;|G
trade.Since the end of World War II, tariff rates around the world
havcplummeted.Among the major induistrialeconomics,weighred-averagetanff lcevlshave been lowered to blow 5 percent. The current UruguayRound of trade negotiationsis addressing .~~~~~~~o
.
.V.i s is ad ci.r.
..
ad
; -rnents
CAT rules, especiallythose coveringantidump.: -Strengthening
ing subsidization,
productstandards, import licensing,"safeguards" (temporary import protection)
ard dispute
selemenr
--Conversy,developing CononMies-wouldlose imporntopporni-nies if the round fails.Thcsc would be pardq. lary seriousminagn.. :culturebecause the global natuie of gn&ilrure markets,makes
_*regiosounsineffectve
Devopi
economis
udao beffecd byie increased use of unilateral and bilateralre- . adversely
.- stictions in te' event oh GArile.
'. U
I
363
ASAM-
IRACLE
Box:7.2 Regional.TradingBlocs
'
''ROGRESSTOWARD
GLOBALWINTEGRATONCOULDcapital flows. Stronger regional integraton need not
.be reversediffdworldconory
splits into regional be' assdciaredwith higher exteral barriers. Indeed,
trading blocs, each centeredon a major currencyand regionalblocs could havepositive globaleffects,prodlosed ro' outsiders (Thuirow.1992).Some.observeis -vided the blocs remain open to trade from outside.
worry that the emerging regional trading blocs will 'Deeper integrnwionwithin Europe, for example,will
imposc-subtle and nor-so-subtle protectionist' mea&cilitate trade with the rest of thc world. A common
esurs'.
Inboth teEurpean
Comrnunity; (EC) and -set ofsrandards nakes it easier forallwho wish to se[l
the :iNorth Ainerican'.Free Trade. Ara (NAFMA),for
in Europenor
just insiders. Tough rules to prevent
ex'ample, fins' are already lobbying Forules
olisnit -governments
from subsidizing 'domestic firms .aid all
the marker 'access of extra-regionial competiors.
'competitors, not only those located in the European
Community.
Typically
these rules require that products entering
one memrber economy contain ai inimuma regional
-Eierging regional arrangements may provide an
' content to quaJr for entry to the markets of oiher . incentive -for some economies to. open, more rapidly.
, members. (In--the,United Stares-Canada Free Trade
than they would havcr otherwise. For example, the
formation of the Ecwas an imortant
inipulsc for the
,Area, a 50 percent regional value-added content re. quirement was required for eligibility for regional
Kennedy Round (L.wrence
1993); As Mexico
access. .In the NAFTA,tihere a`re special rules. for automoved into the' NAFTA negotiations, it simukmnemobiles and tetiles.`The textile provision is particu- . ously made overture toward the Pacific and towaid
.lady protectionist-it
requires triple uansformation,
Cential and South America. Mexico is 'now seeking
such that'finished:foihing.products
have'to becuiit :to join the OECD, is negotiating to form a free trade
signed agree..- "..'.and
sewn flom &ibric spun rom Noth American.
area wthVenezuelaandCie,andhas.
1
- fibers. This could resiilt in considerable trade diver-. :mcnts for freer trade with seven Central American
sion.) Regiona:l blocs'may also,-tighten fbrcemen
economes. .
-.
'.ofrules
against
-Ddeiiumping.
as: another means of,'
oDevelopingeconuisib' differently
,-prorecion.
.by
th -Eco
e
n
of rgn
b
,- .; con.erns
But
-.
about regional .protectionist
-endencurrendy enjoy prefrrentiaJacc
to'the,U.S.
des are easily overstaie. Unlikc-their predessors,m..arkets
under schem such as thc gene
tha
and EC
ed S
m- -.
ten-of prefer
th Cabbe
Ina
th:
en 5 wblcs go beyondliberaizationoftradeto
;dudetlibealizdion
of investment Lwrince
1993).- and the Lom-nConvention are likly to 'see te vale
Thi- in-rai necessitates the libealinidonf
naional
-of, thee
prege
erod& 1f- hoever,
w
regional
.production standardsthat
would otherwise raise-the;
arrangements further multilaibalitidn,.thy'
.'.-cc'.c of=.r'*onlly
nmtegt
prodcton
Moreover,
. wl ot
new opportunities
r.traedaif
bl-s"
-in each'insrance where-regional conomic gups-are
em.
''erging,
hie' movation -has b'e'a at.re
LrOato*
further.access
and internationl
:opportuities.
wage economies
such as Indonesia
and Thailand,
cated operations
from Hong
utation
rrade.
364
Kong, Singapore,
for protection,
and Taiwan,
of teiembcrs,
increased expor
-
rapid increases in
POLICIES
AN
RG
liT
intenweuions
Howthe Needfor MarketAccessWillConsbtain
Developingeconomicsseekingto increasetrade and attract investment will experiencegreater pressuresto open their economiesand
bring their practicesmore closelyin l ne with those in industrial
economies.Those that attempt to usemoreinterventionistversionsof
che export-pushmodel will risk retaliationfrom industrial-economy
markets or punishment under the GATT.For some policy options, such
as financial repression, increasing integration with global markets will
limit the scope for intervention.
Over the years, developing economics have daimed and received exemptions from GATT rules (Whalley 1990). By invoking Article XII, to
safeguard their balance of payments, or Artide XVIII, which allowvspromotion of infant industries, developing economies have been able to escape GAIT disciplines more or less indefinitely. Thus developing
economies have been free to implement trade policies of their choice at
bome while benefiting from the openness of industrial economies. But
as GATT shifts from a narrow focus on tariffs to a broad approach that
seeks agreements on rules, developing economies will find it more and
more difficult to hang onto exemptions. Under Uruguay Round proposals, rules governing intellectual property, subsidies, countervailing
duties, and trade-related investment would eventually be the same for
industrial and developing economies. Although developing economies
would have up to eight years to bring their practices into line, the trade
obligations of developing economies clearly are increasing. Changing
rules about dumping illustrate the case. Industrial economies are increasingly applying antidumping and countervailing duty measures to
developing economy exports (Lawrence 1991). These measures will
make it more difficult to follow the example of Japan and Korea, which
protected domestic industry in order to subsidize exports.
Developing economies that seek access to the emerging regional
trading blocs may find that it comes tied to increased obligations that
could inhibit adoption of the interventionist policies. For example, interventionist versions of the export-push model could not be implemented within the EC with its stringent rules on stare aid and its
provisions allowing for the fiee movement of capital and for the community to implement competition policies. Moreover, no economy exposed to European competition could operate an effective infant
industry strategy.
365
MASVAN
IRACLE
POLICIES
AND
PRAGMAS
367
1rtCA'*T3
M 1 R A CL E
icics,history, and culture. Taking such large realitiesinto account complicates rather than simplifies the caskof development. The challenge
for policynakers becomes twofold: to uisepolicies compatible with axistillg institutions and to avoid policies tha. exceed the economy7sinsti-
Note
1. In the past, regionalarmngementswere motivated
by the desireto pursueimport-subsrirution
policieson a
largerscale and were thereforedoomed to failure;the
morc recentinitiativesare motivatedby a desireto consoildate more outward-orientedstrategies.Subregional
arrangementsareflourishing.In Latn America,for example, theseincludethe North AmericanFreeTradeArea;
Mercosur(Argentina,Brazil,Paraguay,and Uruguay),
whichaimsat a common marketforgoodsand services
by
1994; the Andean Pact (Bolivia, Colombia, and
368
Bibliographic Note
THIS
terials,includingspeificallycommissionedbackgrund
studies, outputs of related World Bank-sponsored research, economic and sectorwork carried out by Bank
operationalstaff;and the errensiveacademicliterature
_L
on the EastAsian economies.Citations in the text and
footnotesrefer to specificsourcesused. The principalsourcesand specific
contributions to individualchapters arc discussedbelow.Lists of background and other commissionedpapersand refrences for workscited are
at the end of this note.
Many members of the World Bank Staffassistedin the design of the
researchand made helpfidcomments on one or more drafts of the report.
They indude: YoshiakeAbe, Ramgopal Agarwala,Harold Alderman,
Paul Armington, Ahmad Ahsan, Mark Baird, Gerard Caprio, Ajay
Chhihber, Yoon-JeCho, Jaime de Melo, Shanta Devarajan, Ron Duncan, Wllliam Easterly,Gunnar Eskeland, Delfin Go, Jeffery Hammer,
JamesHansen, GregoryIngram, Paul Isenman,EstelleJames,Emmanuel
Jimenez,Christne Jones, Koji Kashiwaya,Homi Kharas,Miguel Kiguel,
Elizabeth King, Michael Kline, Brian Levy, Samuel Lieberman, Will
Martin, Deepak Mazumdar, Saha Meyanathan, Vikram Nehru, Arvind
Panagariya,Martin RIavallion,D. C. Rao, Anandarup Ray,SetsuyaSato,
Andrew Sheng, Lyn Squire, Vinaya Svaroop, Shekhar Shah, Jee-Peng
Tan, Jacques Van der Gaag, Dominique van de Walle, Dimirri Vrtms,
Andrew Warner,David Wheeler, Shahid Yusuf,and Heng-Fu Zou.
Those outside the World Bank who contributedwith comments and
materialindude: AliceAmsden,New Schoolfor SocialResearch;Masahiko
Aoki, Sranfrd University;Jere Behrman, University of Pennsylvania;
Robert assen,Oxford University;Gay Fields,CoomellUniversity,Richard
369
,JG
A1':ipKNOTE
BIBLiO'
Singh (1992). The Asian Miracle ResearchProject has also funded research by professor Shigeru Ishikawa and his associateson the rapid
growth of China'scoastalprovinces.Preliminaryoutputs of that research
will be availablein the fall of 1993.
Chapter
2
This chapter draws primarilyon Pack (1993), Pageand Petri (1993),
and Stiglitz (1993). The description of contests also draws on Leipziger
and Kim (1993), Uy (1993), Okuno-Fujiwara (1993), and Ito (1993).
WorldDevelopmentReport1991 provides the basis for the discussionof
the market-friendly approach. Box 2.1 draws on WorldDevelopmentReport 1991. Box 2.2 draws on a paper prepared by Nancy Birdsalland
John Page for the Colloquium on Lessonsof East Asia, February 1993.
Box 2.3 draws on material provided by Jaime de Meld. Helpful discussions with VimodThomas, Robert Wade, and partcipants in the Development Economics Study Group, Tokyo, and the Trade and
Development Seminar at StanfordUniversitycontributed to the chapter.
Chapter
3
R&fl(c
OTE
Chapter
5
Material on human capital accumulation is drawn primarily from
Birdsall and Sabot (1993). Robert Gassen provided the material on
vocational training. Data and analysis on savings and investment are
drawn primarily fiom Uy (1993), Stiglitz (1993a, 1993b), and Sriglitz
and Murdock (1993). YoonJe Cho, Dimirri Vitras, and Andrew Sheng
made important contributions to the analysis of financial repression,
based on the results of a research project, Effectiveness of Credit Policies in East Asia. The section on tax policy draws on Shah (forchcoming) and on preliminary results ofa research projecr, Tax Policy and Tax
Administration in East Asia. Discussion of the relative price of investment goods is based on data drawn from Pfeffermann and Madarassay
(1992). Lant Pritchett made important contributions to the chapter.
Box 5.1 was writen by Myriarn Quispe. Box 5.2 was prepared by
Leora Friedberg. Andrew Sheng provided the material on which box 5.3
is based. Box 5A was writren by Jennifer Keller.
Chazer6
The discussion of labor market performance is based primarily on
BirdsalUand Sabot (1993) and draws on contributions by Felds (1993),
Freeman (1993), and Ranis (1993). The discussion of the capitl marker draws primariJy on Uy (1993), SEiglitz(1993a, 1993b), and on contributions by Andrew Sheng, Yoon-Je Cho, and Dimitri Vittas. The
sections on industrial policy and exports arc based on Pack (1993) and
Pack and Page (1993). Data on axport performance are drawn from the
BESDand World Development Report 1991 data bases. Discussion at the
1993 Canegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy were helpful in
improving the sections on export extemralities and growth.
Box 6.1 was written by Brian Levy. Box 6.2 was prepared by Leora
Friedbeg. Box 6.3 draws on a recently cornpleted internal World Bank
report on Indonesias industrial seaor. Box 6.4 was prepared by Leora
Friedberg. Box 6.5 was prepared by Danny Leipziger.
Chapter
7
Discussions of the international trading environment and boxes 7.1
and 7.2 are drawn from Lawrence (1993). Discussion of the international capital market is largely based on Global Economic Prospectsand
the Developing Countries (World Bank 1993a). Vinod Thomas made a
number of helpful comments.
372.
BIBLI9CAi
Background
Papers
Behrman,JereR., and RyanSchneider."AnInternational
Perspective
on SchoolingInvesrmentin the LastQuarter Century in Some Fast-Growing Eastern and
SoutheasternCountries."
Birdsall,Nancy,and RichardH. Sabot."VirtuousCirdes:
Human CapitalGrowthand Equityin EastAsia."
Campos,Ed. "The InstimtionalFoundationsof HighAsianEconSpeedGrowchin the High-Performing
omies: Part I, Insulation Mechanismsand Public
Sectr-PrivateSectorRelations."
. "The Institutional Foundations of High-Speed
Growthin dteHigh-PerforningAsian
EconomiesPart
II, The Bureauacy asan Instruent of Development."
Chia,SiowYuC.'The Roleof Institutionsin Singaporc's
Samuudavanija,
Chaianan."HighSpeedGrowthand High
Pertfrmancein a TechnocraticPolity:The Thai Case."
Shah, Shekhar,and SubodhC. Marhur. 1992."Sources
of LaborMarkecr
Flexibilityin EastAsia:A Reviewof
SelectedIssues."
fromtheAsianMiracle."
Stiglitz,JosephE. "SorneLessonis
Uy, Marilou."The Roleof CapitalMarketsand the Role
of Government"
AsianEconomies
Studiesofthe High-Peforming
shortlya WartldBankCoaznThesepapers
willbepublished
seriesdteThe Lessonsof EasrAsia.
tryStudfiesu rsh;lje
Bhatracharya,
Amar,andMan Pangesrn.'Indonesia:DevelopmentTransformationsince1965and theRoleof
PublicPolicy."
EconomicSuccess."
Chau, Leung Chuen. "Hong KongjA Unique Case of
Development."
Corden, W. Max. "SevenAsian Miracle Economics:
Overviewof Macroeconomic
Policies.Christensen,Scott,DavidDollar,AmmarSiamwvlla,
and
PakornVichyanond."Thailand.The Insirtuionaland
Dekle, Robert."RaisingSavingRates:Lessonsfrom the
PoliticalUnderpinningsof Growth."
JapaneseExperiencc."
'Taiwan, China:
Carl,and OusaSananik-one.
Fields,GaryS. "ChangingLaborMarketConditionsand Dahlmnan,
Policiesand InstitutionsforRapidGrowth."
EconomicDevelopmenrin Hong Kong,Korea,SingaKim, Kiwan,and Danny Leipziger."Korea:A Case of
poreandTaiwan.'
Development."
Government-Led
Freeman,Richard. "Does Suppressionof Labor Contribute to EconomicSuccess?Labor Relationsand Leipziger,Danny,and VinodThomas."CountryLessons
Markersin EastAsia.'
Relationship
Kim, Chang-Shik "Government-Business
in Korea:SelectiveCaseStudies."
"Trade Policyand Industrial Transformationin
Korea."
from EastAsia."
Petri,Peter."GovernmentPolicyandEastAsia'sSuccess."
Salleh, Ismnael,Kim Leng Yeah, and Saha Dhevan
Growth,Equity,and StrucMeyanathan."Malaysia:
rural Transformation."
Rates."
Studiesof PublicPolicyinJapan
at a SeminaronPublicPoliy
Thesepaperswerepresented
Tolyo,Jzanry 1,993.
duringJapanf?RapidGrowth.
Horiuchi,Akiyoshi."GovernmentControluJ Financial
Mechanismin PostwarJapan:A TentativeReport."
Itoh, Motoshige. "Industrial Policy and Corporate
Japan'sPostwar
Growthin the AutomobileIndusaryr
Experience."
373
IflCNTE
Koike, Kazuo. "Human ResourceDevelopment Systems
in Japan.'
Kuroda, Masahiro,Takanobu Nakajima,and Kanji Yoshioka. "Industrial Policy and Economic Growth in
Japan 1960-1985: PreliminaryReport."
Kuroda, Masahiro, and Shoko Negishi. "Comparison of
the SrructunmlChangesin AsianCountries Outline."
Maki, Atsushi. "The RelationbenveenHousehold Saving
Rate and Economic Growth: Consumer Stimulus to
PurchaseDurable Goods."
Ohno, Kenichi. 'Dynamism ofJapanese Manufacturing.
Evidencefrom the PostwarPeriod."
Okuno-Fujiwara,Masahiro.'Government BusinessRelauionship
in Japan:A ComparativeInstitutionalAnalysis.'
Shimomura, Yasutami. "Industrial Policy in the Rapid
Growth PeriodcEvidencefrom Early Writings."
Teranishi, Jurn. "Emergenceand Establishmentof the Financial Svsremin Postwarjapan: Government Interven;ion, Indirect Financing and the Corporate
Monitorinp System."
Ueda, Kazuo. "The Industrial Bank of Japan and Public
FinancialInstirutions."
Urata, Shujiro. "Technological Progress by Small and
Medium Enterprisesin Japan.'
Yoshikawa,Hiroshi. 'Demand-Led Growth and Income
Distribution: The PosnvariapaneseExperience."
Yoshino, Naoyuki. 'The Low Interest Policy and Economic Growth ofjapan.
References
DcherOJud. 1985. dssa .
Aheuwal,
New Delhi: Oxford UniversityPress.
Aigner, D., and P. Schmidr,eds. 1980. "Specificationand
Estimation of Frontier Production, Profir, and Cost
Functions," a specialissue of Journal of Eoometrics
13:1-138.
Amsden, Alice H. 1989. Asia'sNext Giant- South Korea
and Late tdusriaLzaeon. New Yorlc Oxford University Press.
Ando, Albert, and Franco Modigliani. 1963. 'The Life
Cycle Hypothesis of Savings:AggregateImplications
Economic
Review53(1).
andTesrts."American
Arrow, KennethJ. 1969."ClassificatoryNotes on the Production and Transmission of TechnologicalKnowledge."AmericanEconomicRetiew 59(2):29-35.
374
407-43.
Barro,Robercj., and Jong-Wha Leer1993. 'Incecmaonal
Comparisons of EducationalArtainment." Paper presented at a conference on How Do National Policies
Affec Long-Run Growth?World Bank, Washingron,
D.C. February.
Behrman,Jere P. 1987. 'Scholing in DevelopingCounrries: Which Countries Are the Under- and OverAchievers and What Is the Schooling Impact?"
Economia ofEducaSn Review6(2): 111-28.
Behrman,Jere RP,and Ryan Schneider. 1991. 'How Do
PakistaniSchoolingInvesunentsComparewirh Thosc
of Other Developing Countries?" Williams College,
Williamstown,Mass.
. I992. "An International Perspectiveon Schooling
Investment in the Last Quarter Century in Some
Fast-Growing Eastem and Southeastern Countries."
Backgroundpaper for TheELatAsianMiracle.World
BIBLIO-GR
OG4R~KflflC-NOTE
1-jniversity l ress.
hong k'on~g
JpaP,
376
BIBLAjt
-.
LOGR ATPMIC--N O T E
BI BLOO,G.X
379
Jto,
Takatoshi1992Thejapanese
RncAnoerdamNorthrHolland.Katseli,
Io Takatoshi. 1992. TheJapaneseEconomy.Cambridge,
1993. "Industial Policyfor Development Japanese
Experience and Replicabiliry." John F. Kennedy
School of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge,Mass.
Itoh, Motoshige, and KazuharuKiyono. 1988. "Foreign
Trade and Direct Investment.' In Ryuraro Komiya,
Masahiro Okuno, Kotaro Suzumura, eds., Inditfil
Policyoffapan New York:AcademicPress.
Itoh, Moroshige, Kazuharu Kiyono, Masahiro OkunoFugiwar, and KataroSuzumura 1988.'Industrial Policy as a Corrective to Marker Failures." In Ryutaro
Komiya,Mashiro Okuno, and KoraroSuzumura,eds.,
IndustiaPoficy offapan.New York:AcademicPress.
1991. EconomicAnalysisof ndustrialPoiy. New
York:AcademicPress.
Itoh, Motoshige, and S. Urata. 1993. "Small and
Medirun-Size Enterprise Support Policy of Tapan.
World Bank Policy ResearchDepartment, Washington, D.C.
Jaff, Ad-amB. 1986. 'Technological Opportunity and
Spilloversof R&D: Evidence from Firms' Patens,
Profits and Market Value."AmericanEconomicReview
76(5): 984-1001.
_.
380
adlteniodEooisI()
DevelopmentCenter.
1988. Japan Civil Service Sys
Structre,
sonne andPolitict New York: Greenwood.
ICm, Y. C., and J. K Kwon. 1977. "The Utilization of
Capital and the Growth of Output in a Developing
Economy: The Case of South Korean Manufacturgc Trad Polcy and the New Intenational Economics.
ing.?Journd ofDevelopment Economics 9: 265-78.
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
King, Elizabeth, Katherine Anderson, and Yan Wang.
Kumar, Nagesh 1985. Cost of Technology Imports:
1993. "Feedback Effects on the Labor Market on
The Indian Experience.? Economic and Political
SchoolingChoice in Malaysia? Paperpresented at the
Weekly 20: Ml 03-114.
April 1992 Meetingsof the Population Associationof
Kunio, Y. 1988. The Riseof Ersaz Capitalism in South
America,Cincinnati, Ohio.
EsAsia. New York.Oxford UniversityPress.
King, Robert,and RossLevine.1993. "Financz,EntrpreKuo, S. 1983. The Taiwan Economy in Transition. Boulneurship and GrowdLhPaper presentedat a conference
der, Colo.: Westvzew.
on How Do National Policies Affect Long-Run
Kuo, Wan-Yong. 1976. 'Income Distribution by Size in
Growh? World Bank, Washington,D.C., February.
Taiwan Area. Changes and Causes." Indmut of Free
Knight, John, and Richard H. Sabor. 1991. Education;,
Cbina 45.
Produciviy, and Inequality. New York.cOxford UniKuznets, Simon. 1955. "Economic Growth and Income
versityPress.
Inequality. American EconomicReview 45(1): 1-28.
Komiya, Ryutaro. 1990. The Japanese Econoyn: Trade,
_.
1959 Six Lectures on Economic Growth. Glencoe,
Induatry, and Government. Tokyo: University of
Ill.: Free Press.
Tokyo Press
. 1966. Modern Economic Growth. New Haven,
Komiya, Ryuraro. Masahiro Okuno, Kotaro Suzumura,
Conn.: YaleUniversityPress.
eds. 1988. IndusialPolicy ofjapan. New York AcadLal, Sanjaya,and G. Wignaraja. 1992. 'Foreign Involveemic Press.
ment by European Firms and Garment Exports by
381
>NTE
-and
Bandh
Insttution.
Mellor,John, ed. 1993. "Agriculntreon the Road to Industrialization." International Food Policy Research
Institute, Washington, D.C.
MiddkUton,J., A Ziderman, and K van Adams. Forthcoming. Skillsfor ProdictivicV.Baltimore,Md.: Johns
Hopkins UniversityPress.
Modigliani, Franco. 1970. "The Life CycleHypothesisof
Savingsand Intercountry Difirences in the Savings
Ratio." In W. A. Elis, Maurice FG. ScoEt,and J. N.
Wolfe, eds., fnduccion Growth and Trait Essaysin
HonorofSir RoyHarrod Oxford. Clarendon Press.
Mody, Ashoka,R. Suri, and J. Sanders. 1992. "Keeping
Pace with Change: Organizationaland Technological
Inperatives." WorldDeveopment2o(l2): 1797-816.
Monetry Authority of Singapore.1991. "Savings-Invescment Balances in Singapore: Determinanrs and
Medium-Term Outlook" Singapore: Economics
Department.
Morris, Felipe, Mark Dorfmnan,Jose Pedro Ortiz, and
Maria Claudia Franco. 1990. laan America5 Banking
Systems in the 1980s: A Cross-CountryComparort
World Bank DiscussionPaper 81. Washington,D.C.
Mukai,Yurio.1963."DevelopmentofPOStalSavingsand Its
Factora In Japanesr.IGnywI(eiza no. 83. December.
Munasinghe, Mohan. 1987. Rural Electnficationfor De-
AcademicPress.
Myrelka,Lynn. 1978. "Licensingand TechnologyDevelopment in the Andean Group." World Development
6(4): 447-60.
Nagaoka,Sadao. 1989. 'Overview ofJapanese Industrial
Technology Developmenrt" Industry Series Paper 6.
World Bank, Industry and Energy Department,
Washington, D.C.
p_E"
-.
_. 1992. 'Leamningand Producdvily Change in D:evelOping Countries." In Gerald K Helliner, ed., Trade
384
BIBLO'4
ton, D.C.
Solow, Robe M 1956. "A Conterbution to he Theory
QuareeryJornalofconomics
ofEconomic6Growth."
701)65-9.T
-1957. "Tehnca Chang and die Agreae Producton
Function.' Reizew of Economicsand Sttstics
~~~~~~~~39(3):
3 12-20.
Soon, Tek-Wongand Suan Tan. 1992. Public Policy
andtEcnomic Development in Singapore.' Manuscript prepared for a Wodd Bank Conference on the
Role of Goverment and East Asian Success,Wash-
143-51.
Washington,D.C.
ingon, a.C.
Spence, M. 1981. 'Te Learning Curve and CompetiShapiro, Helen, and LanceTaylor. 1990. "The State and
on BeffJourd ofEconomics 12(l): 49-70.
Industrial Strategy." World Development 18(6):
861-78.
Lvn. 1981. Employment Policy in Developing
Shea, J.D.Fothoin.DeeopenadstuSquire,
Shea, J. D. Forrhcoming. 'Developmcnt and Strruaural
CCounS: A Surveyof lssuesand Evidence.New YorkOxfordUniversityPres
Changeof the FinancialSystem."In Patrick Hugh and
Srinivasan, T. N. 1992. "Datbas for Development
Yung Chul Park, cds., Financia DevelopmentJapan
Analysis:An Overview.' Paper presentedat a ConferKorea, and Taiwan. New York: Oxford University
ence on Data Base of Dcvelopment Analysis,Yale
Press.
University,New Haven, Conn., May.
Sheng, Andrew. 1989. "Bank Restructuringin Malaysia,
Stem, Joseph,Ji-Hong Kim, Dwighr Perkins, and Jung1985-88." PRnE
Worlkng Paper 54. World Bank, FiHo Yoo. 1992. "Industrialization and dhe Stare The
nancial Sector Development Department, WashingKorean Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive."
ton, D.C.
Research reporr Harvard Institute for International
_. 1990. "The Art of Bank Resuucturing2Isues and
Techniques."World Bank, FinancialSector DevelopDevelopmenr,Cambridge,Mass.,and KoreaDevelopment Department, Washington, D.C.
mentInsitute, Seoul.
Stevenson H., and J. Stigler. 1992. The Learning Gap.
Shouda,Yasutoyo.1982. 'EffectiveRatesofProteciion in
Japan." Nikd7onieza Kmkyu 11 (March).
New York.Summir.
Shoven,John. 1988. GovernmentPoicy TowardsIndustr
Stewart, Francis, and Ejaz Ghani 1991- 'How Significant AreExternaities for Development? WorldDevelm the United Stares and Japan. Cambridge, U.K:
opmentl9(6): 569-94.
Cambridge UniversityPress.
386
Stigicz Joseph E. 1993a. "The Role of the State in FinancialMarkets."Paper preparedfor theAnnual Bank
Conference on Development Economics, Worldc
Bank, Washington, D.C.
. 1993b. "Some Lessons from the Asian Mirade."
Backgroundpaper fbr The EastAsian Miracle.World
Bank, PolicyRescarchDepartment,Washington,D.C.
Summers,LawrenceH. 1985. "Issuesin NationalSavings
Policy." NBERWorking Paper 1710, Cambridge,
Mass.
Summers, Lawrence H., and V. P. Summers. 1989.
"When Financial Markets Work Too Well: A CauriousCase for a^
uious Cse for
a Secuwriics
SecuritiesTmnsaceian
T ransactionTax."
Ta." In
In RegvRet&no'yReforrnof Stockand FuturesMarkeet,a special
issue of the Joumal of Financial ServicesResearch.
Boston:KiuwerAcademicPublishers.
Sumnmers,Robert,andAan Heston. 1988. "ANew Set of
International Comparisons of Real Product and
Prices:Estimatesfor 130 Countries." Reviewoflncome
and Wealth34(1): 1-25.
. 1991. 'The Penn World Tables (Mark 5): An Expanded SeEof Inenational Comparisons,1950-88.'
Quane4yJournalofEconomics105(2).
Sun, C., and M. Liang. 1982. "Savings in Taiwan,
1953-1980." In Kwoh-Ting Li and Tzong-ShianYu,
eds., Experencesand Lessonsof EconomicDevelopment
in Taiwan.Taipei: Institute of Economics,Academia
Sinica.
Sundavarej,Tipsuda,and Tniiranvorakul,Prasarn.'Experiencesof FmancialDistrss in Thailand." PRE Working
Paper283. World Bank,Officeofthe VicePresidentfor
DevelopmentEconomics,Washington,D.C
Sussangkarn, Chalongphob. 1988. "Production Structures, LaborMarketsand Human CapitalInvestments:
Issues of Balancefor Thailand." Thailand Developincur ResearchInstitute,Ofijprinr#7, Bangkok
Suzuki,Yoshio.1987. ThejapaneseFinancialSystem.Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Syrquin,Moshe,and Hollis B. Chenery. 1989.Paterns of
Developmenr,1,950to 1983. World Bank Discussion
Paper 41. Washington, D.C.
Taiwan, China. Various issues. Financial Statistics
Monrh4. Taipei: Cenial Bank of China.
Variousyears. Statistcal Yearbookof the Republicof
=Chinz
Taipei: Directorate General of Budger, Accounting, and Statistics.
388
_.
1989a. 'Indonesia: Strategyfor Growth and StrucTrade Policyand the New International Econonmia.
Cambridge, Mass.:MIT Press.
tural Change." Counny Department V, Washington,
_
1985. The Politial Economy of fapan. Stanford,
D.C
Calif.: Stanford UniversityPress.
1989b. Malaysia:MatchingRisk and Rewardsina
Yamawaki,Hideki. 1988. 'The Steel Industry." In RyuMixedEconomy.Washington, D.C.
taro Komiya, Masahiro Okuno, and KomaroSuzu_. 1989c. WorldDevelopmentReport1989. New York:
mura, eds., Indusrial Poliy of Japan. New York:
Oxford UniversityPress.
l990a. Indonesic SterategyJfra SustainedReduction
1.
AcademicPress.
Yarnazawa,Ippie. 1988. "The Textile Industry."In Ryuin Povety. Washington, D.C.
taro Komiya, Masahiro Okuno, and Kotaro SuZU. 1990b. WorldDevelopment
Report1990. NewvYork:
Oxford Universiy Press.
murm, eds., Industrial Polic of Japan. New York:
1.l99a. Colombia:IndustrialCompettionand PJeforAcademicPress.
Yan, Lin See. 1991. 'Savings Investment Gap, Financing
-mance.
Washington, D.C.
-.
199lb. WorldDevelopmentReportThe Chalengeof
Needs and Capital Market DevelopmenL"Bank NeDevelopment.
New York:Oxford UniversityPress.
gara,Malaysia.September.
-.
1992a. "China: Reform and the Role of the Plan in
Yaron,Jacob. 1992. SuccessfidRural Finaee Insitutions.
the 1990s.' East Asiaand the PacificRegionalOffice,
World Bank DiscussionPaper 150. Washington,D.C.
Yonezawa,Yoshie. 1988. YThe Shipbuilding Industry."
Washington, D.C
-.
1992b. GlobalEconomicProspects
and theDeveloping
In Ryuraro Komiya, Masahiro Okuno, and Kotaro
Counties.
Washington, D.C.
Suzumur eds., InduserialPoliy ofJapa;LNew York:
. 1992c. World
BankStpportfor
Industridizaton
in
AcademicPress.
Korea,Indi, and Indonesia.Washington, D.C.
Yoshino,Naoyuki. 1993. "The Low Interest Rate Policy
-.
1992d. WorldDevelopmentReport1992. New York:
and EconomicGrowth ofJapan." Department ofEcoOxford UniversityPress.
nomics,Kelo University,Tokyo, Japan.
1993a. GlobalEconomicProspectsandtheDeveloping Young,Alwyn. 1992. "A Tale of Two Cities: Factor Accumulationand Technical Change in Hong Kong and
Counties.Washington, D.C
. 1993b. WorldDevelopmnt Report1993:Investing
Singapore."Paper presentedat a World Bankseminar.
pmenthRrport1993:
PFrbebruary.
rdzwfnginii
Health.Ncw YorkmOxfordUniversityPress.
Yusof,Z A., A. A. Hussin, I. Alowi, S. Singh, and L C.
Wporld
EconomicForum. 199eneWorldvCompetitiveness
Sing. Forthcoming&The Impact of FinancialReform
ReporGeneva.
in Malaysia" In Gerard Caprio Jr., Izak Ariyas,and
TheoryandExJames Hlanson,eds., FinancialRefrnrn
Yaamamura,
Kozo. 1986. "CaveatEnmptorThe Industrial
PoliCy of Japan." In Paul Krugman, ed., Strategic
perience.Cambridge:Cambridge UniversityPress.
~ ~~~
~~~~
<
C,,,
~~~~~C
J~~~~~
I]
,..
C't
~~
~ ~~~~~~~~~~ClHINA6
r
6r-
j,
>~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~L
%L:0
befI/
_-.
j2kmmx~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
SfDN
I
Ais,~
-;, ;; D
D-
..
1)
~
~~~~~~~~~~-
1
*.