Gov 16
Gov 16
Gov 16
Economic
Policy
For decades the Republicans complained that the Democrats
were big spenders. But when a conservative Republican, Ronald
Reagan, entered the White House in 1981, he cut taxes and allowed
spending to increase. The government spent more money than it took
in. Yet in 1986 the Democrats, who had long complained that
corporations and rich people didn't pay enough in taxes, voted for a tax
reform bill that cut tax rates. In addition, politicians who had always
looked for new tax loopholes to let people escape some taxes voted to
close many existing loopholes.
For a decade or so, the politics of economic policy making was
turned upside down. People who were supposed to hate deficits voted
to create them; people who were supposed to want high taxes voted to
lower them; and people who loved tax loopholes voted to close them.
It made it hard to write a chapter like this one.
By the 1990s, however, order had been restored. A Republican
president (George Bush) unhappily went along with tax increases, and
a Democratic president (Bill Clinton) happily signed a bill to increase
them even more. The national deficit began to decline-but not because
spending had been cut,
only because taxes had been raised.
By the mid-1990s cutting the deficit had become a joint
endeavor of both President Clinton and a Republican-led Congress.
They had a lot of arguments, but mostly over who was cutting the
budget faster. Things got so testy that at one point Congress would not
pass spending bills the president would sign, and so the federal
government was partially shut down for a few days because there was
no money to pay many government workers. In 1997, Clinton and the
Republican congressional leaders agreed on a deficit reduction plan.
How do we explain all of these gyrations? The answer lies in
ourselves, the American people. In the early I980s voters thought taxes
were too high, and so the government cut them. As the deficit shot up
voters objected, and so politicians looked for ways (higher taxes,
mostly) to cut it. From a political point of view there are three kinds of
economic realities: the general health of the nation (as measured by
employment, inflation, and growth in incomes), the level and
distribution of taxes, and the amount and kind of government
spending. Voters and interest groups judge the government on the
basis of how well the economy is doing, how much they are paying in
taxes, and how much they are getting from government spending
programs. Economists may tell us that these three realities are closely
intertwined, so that a change in taxes or spending will affect inflation
or unemployment, and vice versa. But voters are not very interested in
these relationships and theories; they are interested in results. They
want economic growth, low taxes, high levels of government spending
on most programs, and no budget deficit. This confronts the
government with a problem: it may be impossible to achieve all of
these results simultaneously. To see why, we shall look at these three
economic realities.
Economic Health
Disputes about the economic well-being of the nation tend to produce
majoritarian politics. This may seem strange, since each individual
presumably cares most about his or her own material comfort. If that
were the case, we would expect each voter to support politicians who
offer programs to make that voter better off, regardless of what those
programs would or would not do for other voters. In fact, though,
people see connections between their own conditions and the
economic health of the nation and tend to hold politicians responsible
for those national conditions,
Everybody knows that just before an election politicians worry
about the pocketbook issue. We have seen in Chapter 8 that economic
conditions are strongly associated with how much success the
incumbent party has in holding on to the White House and to the seats
held by the White House's
party in Congress, But whose pocketbook are voters worried about?
In part, of course, it is their own. We know that low-income
people are more likely to worry about unemployment and to vote
Democratic, and higher-income people are more likely to worry about
inflation and to vote Republican.' We also know that people who tell
pollsters that their families finances have gotten worse are more likely
than other people to vote against the incumbent president.2 In 1980
about two-thirds of those who said that they had become worse off
economically voted for Ronald Reagan, the challenger, while over half
of those who felt that they had become better off voted for Jimmy
Carter, the incumbent.3 In 1992 people who felt economically pinched
were more likely to vote for Clinton than for Bush, Clinton campaign
aides often reminded each other, "It's the economy, stupid!"
But people do not simply vote their own pocketbooks. In any
recession the vast majority of people will still have jobs; nevertheless,
these people will say that unemployment is the nation's biggest
problem, and many of them will vote accordingly-against the
incumbent during whose watch unemployment went up.4 Why should
employed people worry
about other peoples unemployment?
By the same token, younger voters, whose incomes tend to go
up each year, often worry more about inflation than do retired people
living on fixed incomes, the purchasing power of which goes down
with inflation.5 In presidential elections those
people who think that national economic trends are bad are much more
likely to vote against the incumbent, even when their own personal
finances have not worsened.6
In technical language, voting behavior and economic
conditions are strongly correlated at the national level but not at the
individual level, and this is true both in the United States and in
Europe.7 Such voters are behaving in an "other-regarding" or
"sociotropic" way. In ordinary language, voters seem to respond more
to the condition of the national economy than to their own personal
finances.
It is not hard to understand why this might be true. Part of the
explanation is that people understand what government can and cannot
be held accountable for. If you lose your job at the aircraft plant
because the government has not renewed the
plant's contract, you will be more likely to hold the government
responsible than if you lose your job because you were always
showing up drunk or because the plant moved out of town.
And part of the explanation is that people see general economic
conditions as having indirect effects on them even when they are still
doing pretty well. They may not be unemployed, but they may have
friends who are, and they may worry that if unemployment grows
worse, they will be the next to lose their jobs.
Nations that have tried to run this machine by central commands have
not done very well. Presidents thus become very dependent on the
advice of experts who claim to have an idea about how best to nudge
the machine in the right direction. For better or worse, presidents (and
governments) choose among competing economic theories.
There are at least four major theories about how best to manage
the economy. Each theory, if fully stated, would be quite complicated;
moreover, many experts combine parts of one theory with parts of
another. What follows is a highly simplified account of these theories
that highlights their differences.
Monetarism
A monetarist, such as economist Milton Friedman, believes that
inflation occurs when there is too much money chasing too few goods.
The federal government has the power to create money (in ways to be
described on page 508); according to monetarists, inflation occurs
when it prints too much money. When inflation becomes rampant and
government tries to do something about it, it often cuts back sharply
on the amount of money in circulation. Then a recession will occur,
with slowed economic growth and an increase in unemployment. Since
the government does not understand that economic problems result
from its own start-and-stop habit of issuing new money, it will try to
cure some of these problems by policies that make matters worse-such
as having an unbalanced budget or creating new welfare programs.
Monetarism suggests that the proper thing for government to do is to
have a steady, predictable increase in the money supply at a rate about
equal to the growth in the economy's productivity; beyond that it
should leave matters alone and let the free market operate.
Keynesianism
John Maynard Keynes, an English economist who died in 1946,
believed that the market will not automatically operate at a fullemployment, low inflation level. Its health will depend on what
fraction of their incomes people save or spend. If they save too much,
there will be too little demand, production will decline, and
unemployment will rise. If they spend too much, demand will rise too
Planning
Some economists have too little faith in the workings of the free
market to be pure Keynesians, much less monetarists. They believe
that the government should plan, in varying ways, some part of the
countrys economic activity. One form of economic planning is price
and wage controls, as advocated
by John Kenneth Galbraith and others. In this view big corporations
can raise prices because the forces of competition are too weak to
restrain them, and labor unions can force up wages because
management finds it easy to pass the increases along to consumers in
the form of higher prices. Thus during inflationary times the
government should regulate the maximum prices that can be charged
and wages that can be paid, at least in the larger industries.
In the mid-1980s inflation was not the problem that it once had
been, however; instead the automakers were cutting car prices and
labor unions were accepting wage reductions. This shift drew attention
to a different form of economic planning. Called an industrial policy,
it reflected the publics concern for the declining health of certain
basic industries such as steel and automobile manufacturing. People
thought that these .smokestack" industries would not recover through
market forces; what was needed instead was for the government
somehow to direct or plan investments so that either these industries
would recover or new and better industries would take their places.
Advocates of this form of
--Are Economists Ever Right? -The jokes about them are endless, George Meany, a labor
leader, once said that economics IS the only profession m
which you can rise to eminence without ever being right.
Rudolph Penner, onetime head of the Congressional Budget
Office (and himself an economist), quipped that economists
can't even predict what happened in the past. What Paul
Samuelson, a Nobel-prize-winning economist, once said about
the stock market could also be said about economists: they
have predicted nine of the last five recessions.
It is true that economists have not done a very good job
of predicting which way the economy would move in the years
ahead. In 1986, for example, the forecasts, made one year in
advance by fifteen leading economic forecasters (two in the
government. thirteen in the private sector), were in error by 25
percent in forecasting growth in the gross national product, by
nearly 99 percent in forecasting price levels (that is. inflation),
and by 19 percent in forecasting key interest rates.'
The government forecasters are the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB), part of the executive branch,
and the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), part of Congress.
Both tend to make overly optimistic predictions. For example,
both thought that economic growth in 1986 would be higher
than it was by an average of 44 percent.2
Does all this make economics useless? Not at all, any
more than meteorology is useless despite the inability of
meteorologists to predict the weather one year (or even one
week) in advance. Today economists measure, with growing
accuracy, what the economy is doing at any given moment. By
contrast, when Herbert Hoover was president, we had no
reliable information on how many people were unemployed or
how much money workers were making.
Moreover, economics remind us of some sensible
propositions that we forget at our peril: for example, that
"Reaganomics"
The Machinery of
Economic Policy Making
Even if the president knew exactly the right thing to do, he would still
have to find some way of doing it. In our government that is no easy
task. The machinery for making decisions about economic matters is
complex and not under the president's full control. Within the
executive branch three people other than the president are of special
importance. Sometimes called the "troika,"* these are the chairman of
the
Council of Economic Advisers (CEA), the director of the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB),
and the secretary of the treasury.
*From the Russian word for a carriage pulled by three horses.
Spending Money
If only the economic health of the nation mattered, then majoritarian
politics would dominate, and so the president and Congress would
both work to improve economic conditions. Although they still might
work at cross-purposes because they held to different economic
theories, the goal would be the same.
But the government must also respond to the demands of voters
and interest groups. The trade bill was an example of that. While these
demands are no less legitimate than the voters' general interest in
economic health, they produce not majoritarian but client and interest
group politics.
The sources of this conflict can be seen in public opinion polls.
Voters consistently say that they want a balanced budget and lower
government spending. They believe that the government spends too
much and that if it wanted to, it could cut spending. When the
government runs a deficit, the reason in the voters eyes is that it is
spending too much, not that it is
taxing too little. But these same polls show that the voters believe that
the government should spend more on education, homelessness: child
care, crime control, and almost anything else that one can think of
(except welfare and food stamps).
The voters are not irrational, thinking that they can have more
spending and less spending simultaneously. Nor are they hypocrites,
pretending to want less spending overall but more spending for
particular programs. They are simply expressing a variety of concerns
and a theory about spending. They want a limited government with no
deficit; they also want good schools, cleaner air, better health care, and
less crime. They believe that a frugal government could deliver what
they want by cutting out waste. They may by wrong about that belief,
but it is not obviously silly.
What this means for the government is easy to imagine.
Politicians have an incentive to make two kinds of appeals: The first
is, "Vote for me and I will keep government spending down and cut
the deficit." The second is, "Vote for me and I will make certain that
your favorite program gets more money." Some people will vote for
the candidate be-cause of the first appeal, some will vote for him or
her because of the second. But acting on these two appeals is clearly
going to lead to inconsistent policies. Where those inconsistencies
become evident is in the budget.
The Budget
A budget is a document that announces how much the government
will collect in taxes and spend in revenues and how those expenditures
will be allocated among various programs. In theory the federal budget
should be based on first deciding how much money the government is
going to spend and then allocating that money among different
programs and agencies. That is the way a household makes up its
budget: "We have this much in the paycheck, And so we will spend X
dollars on rent, Y dollars on food, and Z dollars on clothing, and what's
this formal budget process has made a difference, despite the loophole:
Congress is now conscious of how its spending decisions match up
with an overall total that, for reasons of economic theory and practical
politics, it wants to maintain.
When President Reagan took office, he and his allies in
Congress took advantage of the Congressional Budget Act to start the
controversial process of cutting federal spending. The House and
Senate budget committees, with the president's support, used the first
budget resolution in May 1981 not simply to set a budget ceiling that,
as in the past, looked pretty much like the previous year's budget but to
direct each committee of Congress to make cuts--sometimes deep cuts-in the programs for which it was responsible. These cuts were to be
made in the authorization legislation (see Chapter 13) as well as in the
appropriations.
The object was to get members of Congress to vote for a total
package of cuts before they could vote on any particular cut.
Republican control of the Senate and an alliance between Republicans
and conservative southern Democrats in the House allowed this
strategy to succeed. The first budget resolution ordered Senate and
House committees to reduce federal spending during fiscal 1982 by
about $36 billion-less than the president had first asked, but a large
sum nonetheless. Then the individual committees set to work trying to
find ways of making these cuts.
Note how the procedures used by Congress can affect the
policies adopted by Congress. If the Reagan plan had been submitted
in the old piecemeal way, it is unlikely that cuts of this size would
have occurred in so short a time, or at all. The reason is not that
Congress would have wanted to ignore the president but that, then as
now, Congress reflects public opinion on economic policy. As stated at
the beginning of the chapter, the public wants less total federal
spending but more money spent on specific federal programs. Thus, if
you allow the public or Congress to vote first on specific programs,
spending is bound to rise. But if you require Congress to vote first on a
budget ceiling, then (unless it changes its mind as it goes along) total
spending will go down and tough choices will have to be made about
the component parts of the budget.
That, at least, is the theory. It worked once, in 1981, but it did
not work very well thereafter. During the rest of the Reagan years the
budget process broke down in the warfare between the president and
Budget reforms
Hardly anyone is satisfied with how the federal government
makes spending decisions. It is a complex, cumbersome, and
time-consuming process, and in the end it does not produce a
true budget but merely a list of appropriations only loosely
related to how much money the government has to spend.
Two kinds of reforms have been proposed-procedural
and constitutional. In general liberals have preferred the
procedural changes and conservatives the constitutional ones,
but there are many exceptions.
Procedural Changes
1. Have Congress vote on a budget and pass appropriations
bills only once every two years. This would unclog the process
and lighten the workload.
2. Combine appropriations and authorization bills. At present
separate committees must approve the authorization for a
program and the appropriation for that program.
Constitutional Changes
1. Amend the Constitution to require a balanced budget. As of
1988 thirty-two states had passed resolutions asking Congress
to call a constitutional convention to consider a balancedbudget amendment This is only two states short of the number
needed to force Congress to call such a convention, which
would be the first since 1787. The amendment would allow an
unbalanced budget in wartime or whenever an extraordinary
majority in Congress voted for it One version of the
amendment would also limit increases in federal spending to
some percentage of the increase in national income.
2. Amend the Constitution to give the president a line item
veto, now possessed by the governors of forty-three states. This
would make it possible for the president to veto a specific item
in a bill without vetoing the whole bill. A mild version of a
line-item veto has been authorized by legislation, but the courts
may declare it unconstitutional.
Corporations
-Moving expenses.
-Travel expenses.
Eliminated deductions for lobbying expenses.
Minimum Tax
Levying Taxes
Tax policy reflects a various mixture of majoritarian politics ("What is
a 'fair' tax law?") and client politics ("How much is in it for me?"). In
the United States a fair tax law has generally been viewed as one that
keeps the overall tax burden rather low, requires everyone to pay
something, and requires the better off to pay at a higher rate than the
less-well-off. The law, in short, was viewed as good if it imposed
modest burdens, prevented cheating, and was mildly progressive.
Americans have had their first goal satisfied. The tax burden in
the United States is lower than it is in most other democratic nations
(see Figure 16.5). There is some evidence that they have also had their
second goal met-there is reason to believe that Americans evade their
income taxes less than do citizens of, say, France or Italy. (That is one
reason why many nations rely more on sales taxes than we do they are
harder to evade.) Just how progressive our tax rates are is a matter of
dispute; to determine whether the rich really pay at higher rates than
the poor, one has to know not only the official rates but also the effect
of deductions, exemptions, and exclusions (that is, of loopholes).
Keeping the burden low and the cheating at a minimum are
examples of majoritarian politics: most people benefit, most people
pay. The loopholes, however, are another matter-all manner of special
interests can get some special benefit from the tax law that the rest of
us must pay for but, given the complexity of the law, rarely notice.
Loopholes are client politics, par excellence.
Individuals
Corporations
Minimum Tax
What may have sealed the victory was the behavior of the client
groups who fought to keep their favorite loopholes. At congressional
hearings on the bill they would sometimes applaud when, in the early
negotiations, some pet loophole survived intact. Members of the
Senate Finance Committee finally rebelled at this, tore up the bill that
they had been considering, and voted overwhelmingly for a new bill
that eliminated many loopholes and cut rates. Within a few months the
bill was passed and signed (for its provisions, see the box on page
519).
Tax politics had come full circle. The original 1913 tax law had
been the product of majoritarian politics. Then, as the fight over rates
intensified, subsequent versions of the law became more the product of
client politics. In 1986 majoritarian politics reemerged to dominate the
proceedings. As with airline deregulation, civil rights, and (as we shall
see) foreign policy, ideas sometimes are more important than interests.
But in time, the old system began to reassert itself. Tax rates were
slowly increased from where the 1986 law had left them, and more and
more tax deductions were added to the law. By the mid-1990s, many
people were complaining that the
tax law had become so complex that the average person could no
longer figure out his or her own taxes.
SUMMARY
There are three economic factors that make a difference to voters; the
policies for each are fom1ulated by a distinctive type of policymaking. The first is the economic health of the nation, the second the
amount and kinds of government spending, and the third the level and
distribution of taxes.
National economic health has powerful effects on the outcome
of elections, as much through peoples perception of national
conditions as from their worries about their own finances. The politics
of inflation, unemployment, and economic growth tend to be
majoritarian. The president is held responsible for national conditions.
But he must meet that responsibility by using imperfect economic
theories to manage clumsy government tools controlled by divided
political authorities.
SUGGESTED READINGS
Birnbaum, Jeffrey H., and Alan S. Murray. Showdown at Gucci Gulch.
New York: Random House, 1987. Lively journalistic account of
the passage of the Tax Reform Act of 1986.
Kiewiet, D. Roderick. Macroeconomics and Micropolitics. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1983. Argues that citizens vote on the
basis of their estimate of national economic conditions as well as
their own financial circumstances.
Samuelson, Robert J. The Good Life and Its Discontents, New York:
Times Books/Random House, L995. A readable, intelligent
account of American economic life since the Second World War.
Schick, Allen. The Capacity to Budget, Washington, D.C.: Urban
Institute, 1990. Analysis of federal budget and spending policies.
Stein, Herbert. Presidential Economics: The Making of Economic
Policy from Hoover to Reagan and Beyond. New York: Simon &
Schuster, 1984. History, by a knowledgeable insider, of how