Illiquidity and Stock Returns - Cross-Section and Time-Series Effects - Yakov Amihud
Illiquidity and Stock Returns - Cross-Section and Time-Series Effects - Yakov Amihud
Illiquidity and Stock Returns - Cross-Section and Time-Series Effects - Yakov Amihud
This version: August 2000 Please do not quote without the authors permission Comments are welcome *Stern School of Business, New York University, New York 10012, NY. E-mail: [email protected] I thank Haim Mendelson for valuable comments and suggestions and Viral Acharya for competent research assistance and comments. Helpful comments were also received from Michael Brennan, Martin Gruber and Richard Roll. Copyright 2000 By Yakov Amihud
Abstract New tests are presented on the effects of stock illiquidity on stock return. Over time, expected market illiquidity positively affects ex ante stock excess return (usually called risk premium). This complements the positive cross-sectional return-illiquidity relationship. The illiquidity measure here is the average daily ratio of absolute stock return to dollar volume, which is easily obtained from daily stock data for long time series in most stock markets. Illiquidity affects more strongly small firms stocks, suggesting an explanation for the changes small firm effect over time. The impact of market illiquidity on stock excess return suggests the existence of illiquidity premium and helps explain the equity premium puzzle.
1. Introduction The hypothesis on the return-liquidity relationship is that stock expected return is an increasing function of stock illiquidity, as proposed by Amihud and Mendelson (1986). This study contributes to the study of this hypothesis in two ways. First, it tests the return-liquidity relationship not only across stocks, as was done by a number of studies in the past, but also over time. In particular, this paper proposes that over time, expected market illiquidity of stocks has a positive effect on the ex ante stock excess return. Second, this paper employs a new measure of illiquidity from daily stock data, which makes it feasible to obtain it for most stock markets where microstructure data are unavailable, and also enables to construct long time series necessary to study the time series illiquidity-return relationship. The measure of stock illiquidity employed here, called ILLIQ, is the daily ratio of absolute stock return to its dollar volume, averaged over some period (here: a year). It can be interpreted as the daily price response associated with one dollar of trading volume, thus serving as a rough measure of price impact. This measure can be obtained from data on daily stock returns and volume that is readily available. Finer measures of illiquidity, such as the bid ask spread (quoted or effective), transaction-by-transaction market impact or the probability of information-based trading require data on transactions and quotes which is practically unavailable in stock markets outside the U.S. Importantly, this measure enables to construct long time series of illiquidity that are necessary to test the effects over time of illiquidity both expected and unexpected on ex ante and contemporaneous stock excess return. This would be quite impossible to do with microstructure measures of illiquidity. The results show that both across stocks and over time, expected stock returns are an increasing function of expected illiquidity. Across NYSE stocks during 1964-1997, the proposed
1
illiquidity measure has a positive and highly significant effect on the expected return. In addition, stock turnover, a measure of liquidity, has a negative and significant effect. These results reaffirm the importance of liquidity in asset pricing. The new test here is on the effects over time of expected market illiquidity on ex ante market excess return (stock return in excess of the Treasury bill rate). Stock excess return, traditionally called risk premium, has been considered a compensation for risk. This paper proposes that expected stock excess return also reflects compensation for expected market illiquidity, and is thus an increasing function of expected illiquidity. The results support this hypothesis. In addition, unexpected market illiquidity lowers contemporaneous stock prices. This is because higher realized illiquidity raises expected illiquidity that in turn raises stock expected returns and lowers stock prices (assuming no relation between corporate cash flows and market liquidity). This hypothesis too is strongly supported by the results. These illiquidity effects are shown to be stronger for small firms stocks. This suggests that variations over time in the size effect the excess return on small firms stocks are related to changes in the market liquidity over time. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 introduces the illiquidity measure used in this study and employs it in cross-section estimates of expected stock returns as a function of stock illiquidity and other variables. Section 3 presents the time-series tests of the effect of the same measure of illiquidity on ex ante stock excess returns. The section includes tests of the effect of expected and unexpected illiquidity, the effects of these variables for different firm-size portfolios and the effects of expected illiquidity together with the effects of other variables bonds term and default yield premiums that predict stock returns. Section 4 offers concluding remarks.
2
2. 2.1
Cross-section relationship between illiquidity and stock return Measures of illiquidity Liquidity is an elusive concept. It is not observed directly but rather has a number of
aspects that cannot be captured in a single measure.1 Illiquidity reflects the impact of order flow on price the discount that a seller concedes or the premium that a buyer pays when executing a market order that results from adverse selection costs and inventory costs (Amihud and Mendelosn (1980), Glosten and Milgrom (1985)). For standard-size transactions, the price impact is the bid-ask spread, whereas larger excess demand induces a greater impact on prices (see Kraus and Stoll (1972), Keim and Madhavan (1996)), reflecting a likely action of informed traders (Easley and OHara (1987)). Kyle (1985) proposes that because market makers cannot distinguish between order flow that is generated by informed traders and by liquidity (noise) traders, they set prices that are an increasing function of the order flow because greater order flow is more likely to result from informed traders. This creates a positive relationship between the order flow or transaction volume and price change, commonly called the price impact. These measures of illiquidity are employed in studies that examine the cross-section effect of illiquidity on expected stock returns. Amihud and Mendelson (1986) and Eleswarapu (1997) find a significant positive effect of quoted bid-ask spreads on stock returns (riskadjusted).2 Chalmers and Kadlec (1998) use the amortized effective spread as a measure of liquidity, obtained from quotes and subsequent transactions, and find that it positively affects stock returns.3 Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1996) measure stock illiquidity by price impact,
1 2
See discussion in Amihud and Mendelson (1991b). Amihud and Mendelson (1986) study is on NYSE/ AMEX stocks, 1961-1980. Eleswarapus 9197) study is on Nasdaq stocks, 1974-1990. Bond yields are also found to be increasing in the bid-ask spread, after controlling for maturity and risk. See Amihud and Mendelson (1991a) and Kamara (1994). 3 The effective spread is the absolute difference between the mid-point of the quoted bid-ask spread and the transaction price that follows, classified as being a buy or sell transaction. The spread is divided by the stocks 3
measured as the price response to signed order flow (order size), and by the fixed cost of trading, using intra-day continuous data on transactions and quotes.4 They find that these measures of illiquidity positively affect stock returns. Easley, Hvidjkjaer and OHara (1999) introduce a new measure of microstructure risk, the probability of information-based trading, that reflects the adverse selection cost resulting from asymmetric information between traders, as well as the risk that the stock price can deviate from its full-information value. This measure is estimated from intra-daily transaction data. They find that across stocks, the probability of information-based trading has a large positive and significant effect on stock returns. These fine measures of illiquidity require for their calculation microstructure data on transactions and quotes that is largely unavailable in most markets around the world. Even in the U.S. these data are not available for long time periods. The illiquidity measure proposed here uses daily data on return and volume which is readily available for most markets and over long periods of time. This enables to study the time series effects of illiquidity. The measure employed is based on the idea that illiquidity is the relationship between the price change and the associated order flow or trading volume. This follows Kyles concept of illiquidity the response of price to order flow, and Silbers (1975) measure of thinness the ratio of absolute price change to absolute excess demand for trading. Stock illiquidity is defined here as the average ratio of the daily absolute return to the (dollar) trading volume on that day, |Riyt|/VOLDiyt. Riyt is the return on stock i on day t of year y and VOLDiyt is the respective daily volume in dollars. This ratio gives the absolute (percentage) price change per dollar of daily
holding period, obtained from the turnover rate on the stock, to obtain the amortized spread. 4 This measure, based on Kyles (1985) model, is estimated by the methods proposed by Glosten and Harris (1988) and Hasbrouck (1991). Basically, it is the slope coefficient in a regression of transaction-by-transaction price changes on the signed order size, where orders are classified into buy or sell by the proximity of the transaction price to the preceding bid-ask quote. Adjustments are made for prior information (on price changes and order size) and fixed order placement costs. 4
trading volume, or the daily price impact of the order flow. For each year y, the illiquidity measure of stock i is calculated as the average (1) ILLIQiy =1/Diy
Diy t =1
|Riyt|/VOLDiyt ,
where Diy is the number of days for which data are available for stock i in year y. This illiquidity measure is strongly related to the liquidity ratio known as the Amivest measure (the ratio of the sum of the daily volume to the sum of the absolute return, see Cooper et al. (1985), Khan and Baker (1993)). Amihud, Mendelson and Lauterbach (1997) and Berkman and Elsewarapu (1998) use the liquidity ratio to study the effect of changes in liquidity on the values of stocks that were subject to changes in their reading methods. The liquidity ratio, however, does not have the intuitive interpretation of measuring the average daily association between a unit of volume and the price change, as does ILLIQ. Stock liquidity can also be measured by the turnover ratio: (2) TRNOVRiy = 1/Diy
Diy t =1
VOLSHSiyt/NSHRSiyt .
VOLSHSiyt is the trading volume in shares of stock i on day t in year y, and NSHRSiyt is the number of shares outstanding of stock i on that day. Amihud and Mendelson (1986) propose that turnover is negatively related to illiquidity costs. Assets each have a different liquidation cost and each investor j has a different expected trading frequency per unit time, denoted by j. In equilibrium, the more illiquid stocks are allocated to investors with lower trading frequency who amortize the illiquidity cost over a longer period, thus mitigating the loss due to the assets illiquidity costs. Thus in equilibrium, there is a negative relationship between asset illiquidity costs and trading frequency. This proposition is tested by Atkins and Dyl (1997) who find a strong positive relationship across stocks between the bid-ask spread and the holding period,
5
measured as the reciprocal of the turnover ratio (controlling for stock capitalization). The effect on stock return of stock liquidity, thus measured, is tested by Haugen and Baker (1996), Datar et al. (1998), Hu (1997a,b) Rouwenhorst (1998) and Chordia, Subrahmanyam and Anshuman (2000). They all find that the cross section of stock return is decreasing in stock turnover. Another measure of stock liquidity is size or the market capitalization of the stock, since a larger stock issue has smaller price impact for a given order flow and a smaller bid-ask spread.5 Size is known to negatively affect stock return (Banz (1981), Reinganum (1981), Fama and French (1992)), which is consistent with it being a proxy for liquidity (Amihud and Mendelson (1986)). The negative return-size relationship may also result from the size variable being functionally related to the reciprocal of expected return (Berk (1995)). Trading volume is a natural measure of stock liquidity. Brennan, Chordia and Subrahmanyam (1998) find that the cross-section of stock return is negatively related to the stock (dollar) volume, and that volume subsumes the negative effect of size. These measures of illiquidity can all be regarded as empirical proxies that measure different aspects of illiquidity. It is hard and unnecessary to capture liquidity in a single variable, and it may well be described as a function of a number of variables, each being a proxy for that elusive concept of liquidity.
2.2
Empirical methodology The effect of illiquidity on stock return is examined for stocks traded in the New York
Stock Exchange (NYSE) for the years 1963-1997, using data from daily and monthly databases
5
Barry and Brown (1984) propose that the higher return on small firms stock is compensation for less information available on small firms that have been listed for a shorter period of time. This is consistent with the illiquidity explanation of the small firm effect since illiquidity costs are increasing in the asymmetry of information between 6
of CRSP (Center for Research of Securities Prices of the University of Chicago). Tests are confined to NYSE-traded stocks to avoid the effects of differences in market microstructures.6 The test procedure follows the usual Fama-MacBeth (1973) method. A cross-section model is estimated of monthly stock returns as a function of stock characteristics, for each month m=1, 2, 12 in year y, y=1964, 1965, . 1997 (a total of 408 months): (3) Rimy = k0my +
J j =1
Rimy is the return on stock i in month m of year y. Returns are adjusted for stock delisting to avoid survivorship bias, following Shumway (1997).7 Xji,y-1 is characteristic j of stock i, estimated from data in year y-1 and known to investors at the beginning of year y, when they make their investment decisions for the coming year. The coefficients kjmy measure the effects of stock characteristics on stock expected return, and Uimy are the residuals. The monthly regressions of model (3) over the period 1964-1997, produce 408 estimates of each coefficient kjmy, j=0, 1, 2, ..., J. These monthly estimates are averaged and tests of statistical significance are performed. Stocks are admitted to the cross-sectional estimation procedure in month m of year y if they have a return for that month and they satisfy the following criteria: (i) The stock has return and volume data for more than 150 days during year y-1. This makes the estimated parameters more reliable. Also, the stock must be listed at the end of year y-1. (ii) The stock price is greater than $5 at the end of year y-1. Returns on low-price stocks are
traders (see Glosten and Milgrom (1985), Kyle (1985)). 6 See Reinganum (1990) on the effects of the differences in microstructure between the NASDAQ and the NYSE on stock returns, after adjusting for size and risk. In addition, volume figures on the NASDAQ have a different meaning than those on the NYSE, because on the NASDAQ trading is done almost entirely through market makers, whereas on the NYSE most trading is done directly between buying and selling investors. 7 Specifically, the last return used is either the last return available on CRSP, or the delisting return, if available. Naturally, a last return for the stock of 100% is included in the study. A return of 30% is assigned if the deletion reason is coded by 500 (reason unavailable), 520 (went to OTC), 551-573 and 580 (various reasons), 574 (bankruptcy) and 584 (does not meet exchange financial guidelines). Shumway (1997) obtains that 30% is the 7
greatly affected by the minimum tick of $1/8, which adds noise to the estimations.8 (iii) The stock has data on market capitalization at the end of year y-1 in the CRSP database. This excludes derivative securities like ADRs (of foreign stocks) and scores and primes. (iv) Excluded are stocks whose estimated ILLIQiy (defined in (1)) or TRNOVRiy (defined in (2)) is at the highest or lowest 1% tails of the distribution in year y-1. (The distribution is calculated for stocks that satisfy criteria (i)-(iii).) This eliminates outliers. There are between 1113 and 2267 stocks that satisfy these four conditions and are included in the cross-section estimations.
2.3
Stock characteristics
2.3.1. Liquidity variables The following variables are employed as measures of liquidity. 1. ILLIQiy is calculated for stock i in year y from daily data as in (1) above (multiplied by 106.) 2. TRNOVRiy, the turnover ratio, is calculated for each stock i in year y as in (2). The calculation from daily data accounts for mid-year changes in the number of shares outstanding due to stock splits, stock dividends, stock issues and stock repurchase. (This variable is multiplied by 104.) 3. VOLDiy, the dollar volume of stock i during year y, is the sum over the year of the daily product of share volume by the price. (This variable is divided by 103.) 4. SIZEiy, the market capitalization of stock i at the end of year y, is given by CRSP. (This variable is divided by 103.)
average delisting return, examining the OTC returns of delisted stocks. 8 See discussion on the minimum tick and its effects in Harris (1994). The benchmark of $5 was used in 1992 by the NYSE when it reduced the minimum tick. Also, the conventional term of penny stocks applies to stocks whose 8
5. Piy, the stock price at the end of the year, may be related to liquidity because the minimum tick affects the minimum bid-ask spread as percentage of price (Harris (1994), Anshuman and Kalay (1998)), and used by Brennan et al. (1998) in their cross-section estimations. In the cross-section estimation models, lnVOLDiy, lnSIZEiy and lnPiy are the logarithmic transformation of the respective variables (see Brennan et al. (1998)). INSERT TABLE 1 HERE Table 1 presents estimated statistics of these liquidity variables. For each variable, the annual mean, standard deviation across stocks and median are calculated in each year for stocks admitted to the sample, and then these annual statistics are averaged over the 34 years. The correlations between the variables are calculated in each year across stocks and then the yearly correlation coefficients are averaged over the years. As expected, ILLIQiy is negatively correlated with variables that are known proxy measures of liquidity. Corr(ILLIQiy,lnVOLDiy)= 0.668, Corr(ILLIQiy,lnSIZEiy)= 0.611, Corr(ILLIQiy,lnPiy)= 0.459 and Corr(ILLIQiy,TRNOVRiy)= 0.144. The correlations suggest that each liquidity variable contains information that is not included in the other. For example, the correlation between ILLIQiy and lnVOLDiy means that lnVOLD explains less than half (0.446) of the variability in ILLIQ. ILLIQ, which is calculated from daily data, should be positively related to variables that measure illiquidity from microstructure data. Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1996) use two measures of illiquidity, obtained from data on inraday transactions and quotes: Kyles (1985) , the price impact measure, and , the fixed-cost component related to the bid-ask spread. The estimates are done using the Glosten-Harris (1988) method. Using estimates9 of these variables
price is below $5. 9 I thank Michael Bennan and Avanidhar Subrahmnaym for kindly providing these estimates. The estimated variables are multiplied here by 103. Outliers at the upper and lower 1% tails of these variables and of ILLIQ are 9
for 1984, the following cross-sectional regression was estimated: ILLIQi = (t =) 292 + 247.9 i + 49.2 i (12.25) (13.78) (17.33) R2 = 0.30
These results show that ILLIQ is positively and strongly related to microstructure estimates of illiquidity. In each year, the average market illiquidity across stocks is calculated as (4) AILLIQy = 1/Ny
Ny t =1
ILLIQiy ,
where Ny is the number of stocks in year y. The average illiquidity varies considerably over the years. In estimating the cross-section model (3), ILLIQiy is replaced by its mean-adjusted values, (5) ILLIQMAiy = ILLIQiy / AILLIQy .
The stocks that are used to calculate the average illiquidity are those that enter the cross-sectional regression (3) for each month and satisfy conditions (i)-(iv) above. Turnover is mean-adjusted in the same way, (6) TRNOVRMAiy = TRNOVRiy / ATRNOVRy,
where ATRNOVRy is the average turnover across stocks that enter the cross-sectional regression. Clearly, the means of ILLIQMAiy and TRNOVRMAiy are constant and equal 1.0.
2.3.2. Risk variables Model (3) includes BETAiy as a measure of risk. It is calculated as follows. At the end of each year y, stocks are ranked by their size (capitalization) and divided into ten equal portfolios. Size serves here as an instrumental variable. Next, the portfolio return Rpty is calculated as the
equally-weighted average for portfolio p on day t in year y. Then, the following market model is estimated for each portfolio p, p = 1, 2, , 10, (7) Rpty = apy + BETApy RMty + epty.
RMty is the equally-weighted market return. BETApy is the slope coefficient, estimated by the Scholes and Williams (1977) method. The beta of stock i, BETAiy, is the portfolio BETApy assigned to each stock i in portfolio p. Fama and French (1992), who use similar methodology, suggest that the precision of the estimated portfolio beta more than makes up for the fact that not all stocks in the size portfolio have the same beta.10 The stock total risk is SDRETiy, the standard deviation of the daily return on stock i during year y. (This variable is multiplied by 102.) This risk variable is considered since empirically, ILLIQiy may be construed as a measure of the stocks risk, given that its numerator is the absolute return which is directly related to SDRETiy. Theoretically, the stock total risk is related to illiquidity by Stolls (1978) model, where the bid-ask spread set by a risk-averse market maker is increasing in the stocks risk. Constantinides (1986) proposes that when the stock variance is higher, traders incur higher trading costs because they need to engage more frequently in portfolio rebalancing, and this positively affects the return that they require on the stock. The evidence, however, is that the correlation between ILLIQ and SDRET is low, 0.289 (see Table 1, Panel B), suggesting that ILLIQ is not a measure of risk. The inclusion of SDRET in the model is also because some asset pricing models show that it is priced, since investors portfolios are constrained and therefore not well diversified (Levy (1978), Merton (1987)).
10
The models were re-estimated using betas of individual stocks in lieu of betas of size portfolios. These betas has an insignificant effect in the cross-section regressions. The results on ILLIQ remained the same. Also, omitting BETA altogether from the cross-section regression has very little effect on the results. 11
2.3.3. Additional variables The estimation model includes the dividend yield for stock i in year y, DIVYLDiy, calculated as the sum of the dividends during year y divided by the end-of-year price (following Brennan et al. (1998)). DIVYLD should have a positive effect on stock return if investors require to be compensated for the higher tax rate on dividends compared to the tax on capital gains. However, dividend yield may have a negative effect on return across stocks if it is negatively correlated with an unobserved risk factor, that is, high dividend paying stocks are less risky. The coefficient of dividend yield may also be negative following Reddings (1997) suggestion that large investors prefer companies with high liquidity and also prefer receiving dividends.11 Finally, past stock returns may affect their expected returns due to momentum in the market, as found by Brennan et al. (1998). Therefore, the cross-sectional model (3) includes two variables: R100iy, the return on stock i during the last 100 days of year y, and RYRiy, the return on stock i over the entire year y. The model does not includes the variable BE/ME, the ratio of book-to-market equity, which is used by Fama and French (1992) in cross-section asset pricing estimation. This is because this study employs only NYSE stocks, for which BE/ME is found to have no significant effect (Easley, Hvidkjaer and OHara (1999), Loughran (1997)12). Also, Berk (1995) suggests that an estimated relation between expected return and BE/ME is obtained by construction, given the functional relation between expected return and equity.
11
Higher dividend yield may be perceived by investors to provide greater liquidity (ignoring tax consequences). This is analogous to the findings of Amihud and Mendelson (1991a) that Treasury notes with higher coupon provide lower yield to maturity. 12
2.4.
Cross section estimation results In the cross-sectional model (3), monthly returns in each month of the year are regressed
on stock characteristics that are estimated from data in the previous year (following the FamaMacBeth (1973) method). The model is estimated for all 408 months (34 years), generating 408 sets of coefficients kjmy, m=1, 2, . 12, and y=1964, 1965, . 1997. For each stock characteristic j, the mean and standard error of the 408 estimated coefficients kjmy are calculated, followed by a t-test of the null hypothesis of zero mean. Tests are also performed for 374 monthly estimates excluding the month of January. This is because some studies find that when excluding the January, the effects of beta, size and the bid-ask spread become insignificant (Keim (1983), Tinic and West (1986), Eleswarapu and Reinganum (1993)). Finally, to examine the stability over time of the effects of the stock characteristics, tests are done separately for two equal subperiods of 204 (17 years) each. INSERT TABLE 2 HERE Table 2, Panel A, presents the results of a parsimonious cross-sectional model that includes BETAiy, ILLIQMAiy and past returns R100iy and RYRiy. The results strongly support the hypothesis that illiquidity is priced. The coefficient of ILLIQMAiy, denoted kILLIQmy, has a mean of 0.163 that is statistically significant (t = 6.90). The median of kILLIQmy is 0.141, close to the mean, indicating that the result on the mean is not driven by a few extreme values. Of the 408 monthly estimated coefficients kILLIQmy, 275 are positive which constitutes 2/3 of the sample a proportion that is significantly different from 1/2 (the chance proportion). The serial correlation of the series kILLIQmy is 0.05, insignificantly different from zero. The illiquidity effect remains positive and highly significant when January is excluded:
12
Loughran (1997) finds that when the month of January is exluded, the effect of BE/ME becomes insignificant. 13
the mean of kILLIQmy is 0.131 with t = 5.73. The stability of the illiquidity effect is evident from the estimation results of the model over two subperiods of 17 years each. The mean coefficients kILLIQmy are 0.204 and 0.123 for the first and second subperiod, respectively, and the corresponding t values are 4.78 and 6.04. The effect of BETA is positive, as expected, and significant (the statistical significance is lower when January is excluded and in the first subperiod). Its effect, however, becomes insignificant13 when the size variable is included in the model, since beta is calculated for sizebased portfolios (see Panel B). Past returns R100 and RYR both have positive and significant coefficients (R100 is insignificant in the first subperiod). Table 2, Panel B presents estimation results of models that include additional variables. The results show that liquidity is priced in the market. First, ILLIQMA has a positive and significant coefficient for the entire period, for the non-January months and for each of the two subperiods. The effect of ILLIQMA remains positive and significant in all three models in this table that include different sets of variables, with its coefficient and significance changing very little. Second, the other liquidity measure, TRNOVRMA (turnover, mean-adjusted), has a negative and generally significant coefficient for the entire period, for the non-January months and for each of the two subperiods. The coefficients of TRNOVRMA show stability and do not vary much in all these estimations. In addition, the coefficient of lnSIZE is negative and significant, although its magnitude and significance is low in some specifications of the model. Size may measure liquidity, but its negative coefficient may also be due to it being a proxy for the reciprocal of expected return (Berk (1995)). The effect of lnVOLD (dollar volume), which measures liquidity, is expected to be
13
As pointed out earlier, when using individual stock beta, its effect is insignificant. 14
negative, which is the case (as in Brennan et al. (1998)) when ILLIQMA and TRNOVRMA are excluded from the model. Yet, its sign turns positive when these liquidity variables are included. The effect of volume on expected return is, however, captured trough both ILLIQMA and TRNOVRMA which include volume in their calculation. The effect of the price variable lnP is insignificant. Risk, measured by SDRET (the return standard deviation), also has an insignificant effect. The sign of its coefficient is negative as in Amihud and Mendelson (1989), contrary to predictions of a positive effect. Importantly, the coefficient of ILLIQ remains positive and significant when SDRET is included. This suggests that the illiquidity measure ILLIQ, whose numerator includes absolute return, is distinct in its effect from that of risk. The negative coefficient of DIVYLD may reflect the effect of an unobserved risk factor that is negatively correlated with dividend yield across stocks (less risky companies may choose to have higher dividend). The negative coefficient is also consistent with the hypothesis of Redding (1997) about the preference for dividends by some types of investors. These effects could offset the positive effect of DIVYLD that results from the higher personal tax on dividends. In conclusion, the evidence strongly shows that liquidity affects expected stock returns. Stock liquidity can be represented by the variables ILLIQ and TRNOVR, which have significant effects on the cross-section of stock returns, in addition to the effect of lnSIZE. The cross-sectional models are also estimated by the weighted least squares method to account for hetersokedasticity in the residuals of model (3). The results, presented in detail in the Appendix, are qualitatively similar to those using the OLS method. In all models, the coefficient of ILLIQMA is positive and highly significant. Its effect remains positive and significant when estimated for all months excluding January and for each of the two subperiods.
15
3.
The effect over time of market illiquidity on expected stock excess return The proposition here is that over time, expected market illiquidity positively affects
expected stock excess return (the stock return in excess of Treasury bill rate). This is consistent with the positive cross-sectional relationship between stock return and illiquidity. If investors anticipate higher market illiquidity, they will price stocks so that they generate higher expected return. This suggests that stock excess return, traditionally interpreted as risk premium, includes a premium for illiquidity. Indeed, stocks are not only riskier, but are also less liquid than short-term Treasury securities. It thus stands to reason that the expected stock return in excess of the yield on Treasury securities should be considered as compensation for illiquidity, in addition to its standard interpretation as compensation for risk. The difference in liquidity between stocks and Treasury securities is quite large. The bidask spread on Treasury securities was about $ 1/128 per $100 of face value of bills (0.008%), $ 1/32 on short-term notes (0.031%) and $ 2/32 on long-term Treasury bonds (0.0625%) (see Amihud and Mendelson (1991a)). For stocks, the bid-ask spread was much higher. The most liquid stocks had a bid-ask spreads of $ 1/8 dollar or 0.25% for a stock whose price is $50. The average bid-ask spread on NYSE stocks during 1960-1979 was 0.71% (value weighted) or 1.43% (equally weighted; see Stoll and Whaley (1983)). In addition, brokerage fees are much lower for Treasury securities than they are for stocks. The fee was $12.5-$25 per million dollar transaction value for institutions trading T-bills and $78.125 per million for notes, that is, 0.00125% and 0.00781%, respectively (Stigum (1983), p. 437). For stocks, brokerage fees for institutions were no less than 6-10 cents per share, or 0.12%-0.20% for a $50 stock. For individuals, brokerage fees were of the order of magnitude of the bid-ask spreads (Stoll and Whaley (1983)). And, while investors can trade very large amounts (tens of millions of dollars)
16
of bills and notes without price impact, block transactions in stocks result in price impact that implies high illiquidity costs (Kraus and Stoll (1972), Keim and Madhavan (1996)). The effect of market illiquidity on stock return is studied by Amihud, Mendelson and Wood (1990) for the October 19, 1987 stock market crash. They show that the crash occurred (in part) because of a rise in market illiquidity before and during October 19, and that the price recovery by October 30 was associated with improvement in stock liquidity. The proposition tested here is that expected stock excess return is an increasing function of expected market illiquidity. This is done in two steps, following the methodology of French, Schwert and Stambaugh (1987) who examine the risk premium interpretation of stock excess return. First, an expected illiquidity is estimated by an autoregressive model. The second step employs the estimate from the first step and tests the hypothesis that ex ante stock excess return is an increasing function of expected illiquidity, as well as the hypothesis that unexpected illiquidity has a negative effect on contemporaneous unexpected stock return.
3.1.
Expected market illiquidity and its effect on ex ante stock excess return The ex ante effect of market illiquidity on stock excess return is described by the model
(8)
RMy is the annual market return for year y, Rfy is the risk-free annual yield, and lnAILLIQyE is the expected market illiquidity for year y based on information in y-1. The hypothesis is that f1 > 0. Market illiquidity is measured here by average illiquidity AILLIQy (see (4)), the average across all stocks in each year y of stock illiquiidty, ILLIQiy (defined in (1)). The calculation of AILLIQy here excludes values of ILLIQiy in the upper 1% tail of the distribution for the year. There are 34 annual values of AILLIQy for the years 1963-1996. AILLIQy peaked in the mid17
1970s and rose again in 1990. It had low values in 1968, the mid-1980s and in 1996. The results presented here are for the logarithmic transformation lnAILLIQy; they are qualitatively similar when using AILLIQy instead. Investors are assumed to predict illiquidity for year y based on information available in year y-1, and then use this prediction to set prices that will generate the desired expected return in year y. Market illiquidity is assumed to follow the autoregressive model (9) lnAILLIQy = c0 + c1lnAILLIQy-1 + vy ,
where c0 and c1 are coefficients and vy is the residual. It is reasonable to expect that c1 > 0. At the beginning of year y, investors determine the expected illiquidity for the coming year, lnAILLIQyE, based on information in the year that has just ended: lnAILLIQyE = c0 + c1lnAILLIQy-1. Then, they set prices in the market at the beginning of year y that will generate the expected return for the year. The assumed model is (10) (RM-Rf)y = f0 + f1 lnAILLIQyE + uy = g0 + g1 lnAILLIQy-1 + uy,
where g0 = f0 + f1c0 and g1 = f1c1. Unexpected excess return is denoted by the residual uy. The hypothesis here is that g1 > 0: higher expected market illiquidity leads to higher ex ante stock excess return. The effect of unexpected market illiquidity on contemporaneous unexpected stock return should be negative. This is because c1 > 0 (in model (9)) means that higher illiquidity in one year raises expected illiquidity for the following year. If higher expected illiquidity leads to higher ex ante stock return, stock prices should fall when illiquidity unexpectedly rises, so that ex ante stock returns rise (assuming that corporate cash flows are unaffected by market illiquidity). Thus, higher realized illiquidity should lower stock price, generating a negative relationship between unexpected illiquidity and contemporaneous stock return.
18
The two hypotheses discussed above are tested by the model (11) (RM-Rf)y = g0 + g1 lnAILLIQy-1 + g2 lnAILLIQyU + wy ,
where lnAILLIQyU is the unexpected illiquidity in year y, defined as lnAILLIQyU = vy, the residual from (9). The hypotheses imply two predictions: (H-1) g1 > 0, and (H-2) g2 < 0. In estimating model (9) from finite samples, especially from a small sample as here, the
1 is downward biased. Following Kendalls (1954) proposed bias estimated coefficient c 1 is augmented by the term correction approximation procedure, the estimated coefficient c 1 )/T, where T is the sample size.14 This procedure is applied here to adjust the estimated (1+3 c coefficient c1. The estimation of model (9) provides the following results: lnAILLIQy = 0.200 + (t = ) (1.70) 0.764 lnAILLIQy-1 + residualy (5.89) R2=0.53, D-W = 1.57
The model seems to fit the data well. Applying Kendalls (1954) method, the bias-corrected estimated slope coefficient c1 is 0.869 (the intercept is adjusted accordingly). The estimated parameters are found to be stable over time, as indicated by a Chow test.15 It is therefore reasonable to assume that investors know them and the analysis proceeds using the coefficients that are estimated using the entire data.16 The structure of models (9) and (10) resembles the structure analyzed by Stambaugh
Sawa (1978) suggests that Kendalls approximation is virtually accurate in spite of its simplity (p. 164). Also, the following model is estimated: (9) lnAILLIQy = c0 + c1 lnAILLIQy-1 + c0DUMT + c1lnAILLIQy-1DUMT + vy , where DUMT = 1 for the last 16 years of the sample, 1981-1996, and zero otherwise. The estimated coefficients c0 and c1 are not significantly different from zero (their t-statistics are below 1.0), suggesting that the parameters of model (9) are stable over the two subperiods.
15 14
19
(1999). Since by hypothesis (H-2) it is expected that Cov(uy, vy) < 0, it follows from Stambaughs (1999) analysis that in estimating (10), the estimated coefficient g1 is upward biased. However, when the an additional variable the residual vy from (9) is added to the right hand side of (10), as it is in model (11), the estimated coefficient g1 is unbiased. Therefore results will be presented for model (11) only. The residual vy is calculated from the estimated model (9) after its coefficients are adjusted by Kendalls (1954) bias-corrected method, and then it is used in model (11) to estimate g1 and g2.17 In estimating model (11), RMy is the annual return on the equally weighted market portfolio (source: CRSP), and Rf is the one-year Treasury bill yield as of the beginning of year y (source: Federal Reserve Bank). INSERT TABLE 3 HERE The estimation results of model (11) are presented in Table 3. These results strongly support both hypotheses: (H-1): The coefficient g1 is positive and significant, meaning that expected stock excess return is an increasing function of expected market illiquidity. (H-2): The coefficient g2 is negative and significant, suggesting that unexpected market illiquidity has a negative effect on stock prices. This result is consistent with the findings of Amihud, Mendelson and Wood (1990). The model is tested for stability and the results show that it is stable over time.18
16 17
This approach is similar to that in French et al. (1987). Simulations conducted using parameters of the estimated models show that the bias in g1 can amount to about 2% of its estimated value. 18 The model estimated is (11) (RM-Rf)y = g0 + g0DUMT + g1 ILLIQMy-1+g1ILLIQMy-1DUMT + g2 ILLIQMyU + f2 ILLIQMyUDUMT + wy , where DUMT = 1 for the last 16 years of the sample, 1981-1996, and zero otherwise. The estimated coefficients g1 and g2 are not significantly different from zero (their t-statistics are below 1.0), and the coefficients g1 and g2 hardly change. 20
3.2
The effect of market illiquidity on stock return over time varies between stocks by their level of liquidity. Amihud, Mendelson and Wood (1990) find that during the October 1987 crash, the rise in illiquidity instigated a flight to liquidity: more liquid stocks declined less in value, after controlling for the market effect and the stocks . This suggests the existence of two effects on stock return when expected market illiquidity rises: (a) A decline in stock price and a rise in expected return, common to all stocks. (b) Substitution from less liquid to more liquid stocks (flight to liquidity). For stocks with low liquidity, the two effects are complementary, both resulting in the same effect on stock return (both expected and unexpected). However, for liquid stocks the two effects work in opposite directions. As a result, small, illiquid stocks should experience stronger effects of market illiquidity a greater positive effect of expected illiquidity on ex ante return and a more negative effect of unexpected illiquidity on contemporaneous return. However, for large, liquid stocks both effects should be weaker, because these stocks become relatively more attractive in times of dire liquidity. Thus, unexpected rise in market illiquidity, which has negative effect on contemporaneous stock prices, also increases the demand for liquid stocks and mitigates their price declines. And, while higher expected market illiquidity makes investors demand higher ex ante return, it also increases the attractiveness of liquid stocks and reduces the expected return that investors demand on them, thus weakening the effect of expected illiquidity on their expected return. This hypothesis is tested by estimating model (11) using returns on size-based portfolios, where RSZi is the return on the portfolio of size-decile i: (11sz) (RSZi-Rf)y = g0i + g1i lnAILLIQy-1 + g2i lnAILLIQyU + wiy .
21
The estimation is carried out on size portfolios i = 2, 4, 6, 8 and 10 (size increases in i). The proposition that the illiquidity effect is stronger for small illiquid stocks implies two testable hypotheses: (SZ1) The coefficients g1i in model (11sz), which are positive, decline in size: g12 > g14 > g16 > g18 > g110 > 0. (SZ2) The coefficients g2i in model (11sz), which are negative, rises in size: g22 < g24 < g26 < g28 < g210 < 0. INSERT TABLE 4 HERE As seen in Table 4, both hypotheses (SZ1) and (SZ2) are strongly supported by the estimation results of model (11sz). (SZ1) The coefficients g1i decline monotonically in size: 15.230 > 11.609 > 9.631 > 7.014 >
0.447. The statistical significance of the coefficients is declining in firm size; the last
coefficient is statistically insignificant (t = 0.13). (SZ2) The coefficients g2i rise monotonically in size (i.e., the effect becomes weaker): 28.021 < 24.397 < 20.780 < 18.549 < 14.416. All coefficients are statistically significant. The results mean that the effects of market illiquidity both expected and unexpected are stronger for small firm stocks and become weaker for large firms. These findings explain the variation over time in the "small firm effect," i.e., the excess return of small firm return over the return on large firms. Brown, Kleidon and Marsh (1983) who document that reject the hypothesis that the ex ante excess return attributable to size is stable over time (p. 33). The findings here explain why: small and large firms react differently to changes in market illiquidity, both expected and unexpected. A convenient way to present small firms excess return is through the return differential
22
(12)
where RMEW and RMVW denote, respectively, equally-weighted and value-weighted market return. The estimation results are presented in Table 3. They show that the small firm excess return varies over time as a function of liquidity: it is an increasing function of expected illiquidity and a decreasing function of unexpected illiquidity.
3.3 3.3.1
Illiquidity and other variables that predict stock excess return The effects of volatility
The stock excess return (RM-Rf)y is traditionally considered as risk premium. Therefore, the model is extended to test the effects of both illiquidity and volatility on ex ante stock excess return. Since the illiquidity measure contains in its numerator the stock absolute return, it could be argued that its effect results from the effect of volatility on ex ante stock return. Define lnSDy as the (logarithm of) standard deviation of daily return on the market portfolio (equally weighted) in year y. The standard deviation of daily return is used by French et al. (1987) to examine the effect of monthly market volatility on ex ante stock excess return. Indeed, volatility and illiquidity are related, but the correlation is low: Corr(lnAILLIQy, lnSDy) = 0.307. The analysis here follows the procedure applied above to illiquidity. It is assumed that investors estimate expected volatility for year y, based on information in year y-1, from the model (13) lnSDy = a0 + a1 lnSDy-1 + ey .
The estimated slope coefficient is adjusted applying Kendalls (1954) bias-correction method. Using the adjusted parameters, the residual ey is used as unexpected market volatility, denoted lnSDUy, in the model
23
(14)
(RM-Rf)y = g0 + g1 lnAILLIQy-1 + g2 lnAILLIQyU + h1 lnSDy-1 + h2 lnSDyU + wy . Given investors risk aversion, the following results are expected (see French et al.
(1987)): expected volatility has a positive effect on ex ante stock excess return, i.e., h1 > 0, and the effect of unexpected volatility on contemporaneous stock return is negative, i.e., h2 < 0. The hypotheses on the effect of illiquidity imply, as before, that g1 > 0 and g2 < 0. An estimate of expected lnSDy is obtained from model (13): SDMy (t = ) = -0.164 + 0.448 lnSDy-1 + residualy (2.23) (2.86) R2 = 0.21, DW = 1.84
The slope coefficient, adjusted by Kendalls (1954) method, is 0.520. Unexpected volatility, denoted lnSDyU, is calculated by using the adjusted coefficients. Then lnSDy and lnSDyU are used to estimate model (14). The estimation results of model (14) are presented in Table 3. For the model where the dependent variable is the stock excess return (RM Rf)y, the effect of expected volatility is positive and the effect of unexpected volatility is negative, both as hypothesized., but only the effect of expected volatility is significant. Importantly, the effect of illiquidity remains significant when the volatility variables are included in the model.
3.3.2 The effects of bond yields: default premium and term premium
Two bond yield premiums are known to have a positive effect on expected stock returns over time: the default yield premium (the excess yield on risky corporate bonds) and the term yield premium (long-term minus short-term bond yield) (see Keim and Stambaugh (1986), Fama and French (1989) and Fama (1990)).19 The question is whether expected illiquidity remains a
19
Fama and French (1989) and Fama (1990) study separately the effect of the default premium and the term premium on ex ante excess stock return. Keim and Stambaugh (1986) combine the two in a single measure, the 24
significant predictor of ex ante stock excess return after controlling for the predictive effects of these two yield premiums. The default yield premium is defined as (15) DEFy = YBAAy YAAAy
where YBAAy and YAAAy are, respectively, the yield to maturity on long-term BAA-rated and AAA-rated bonds. DEFy is naturally positive, reflecting the premium on risky corporate bonds. The term yield premium is (16) TERMy = YLONGy YTB3y,
where YLONGy and YTB3y are, respectively, the yields on long-term Treasury bonds and threemonth Treasury bills. All yields are as of the end of year y (December). The data source on bond yields is Basic Economics. The model that estimates the determinants of ex ante stock excess return is (17) (RM-Rf)y = g0 + g1 lnAILLIQy-1 + g2 lnAILLIQyU + a1 DEFy-1 + a2 TERMy-1 + uy.
DEFy = DEFyDEFy-1, TERMy = TERMyTERMy-1. Model (18) is predictive since all data on
yields and illiquidity are known to investors at the beginning of year y during which (RM-Rf)y is observed. Bond yields are observed at the end of year y-1, and expected illiquidity is a function of past illiquidity, lnAILLIQy-1. The hypothesis on the positive effect of expected illiquidity on ex-ante stock excess return implies that g1 > 0 as well as g2 < 0, controlling for the effects of the default and term yield premiums, i.e., a1 > 0 and a2 > 0. The correlations between the variables are low: Corr(lnAILLIQy, DEFy) = 0.227, Corr(lnAILLIQy, TERMy) = 0.214, and Corr(TERMy,
DEFy) = 0.113.
difference between the yield on corporate bonds with rating below BAA and on short-term treasury bills. Boudoukh, 25
INSERT TABLE 5 HERE The results in Table 5 show that lnAILLIQy-1 retains its positive and significant effect on ex ante stock excess return after controlling for the default and the term yield premiums. As in Fama and French (1989), the two yield premiums affect positively the ex ante stock excess return. Illiquidity thus emerges as a strong determinant of ex ante excess return on stocks. The differences in the effects of illiquidity on different size-based stock portfolios is tested again here in the model (17sz) (RSZi -Rf)y = g0i + g1i lnAILLIQy-1 + g1i lnAILLIQyU + a1i DEFy-1 + a2i TERMy-1 + uiy RSZi is the annual return on CRSP size-decile portfolio i, i=2, 4, 6, 8 and 10 (size increases in i). Table 5 presents estimation results of model (17sz). As before, the estimated coefficients of lnAILLIQy-1 decline monotonically in the firm size and the estimated coefficients of lnAILLIQyU rise monotonically in the firm size, indicating that the effect of illiquidity is smaller for larger firms. The model is also tested with the dependent variable SRy = RMEWy RMVWy, which reflects the excess return on small firms stocks. The results strongly show that liquidity both expected and unexpected affects ex ante stock return, after controlling for the yield premiums.
3.4
Stock turnover, which measures liquidity, is shown in Section 2 to be a significant determinant of the cross-section of stock expected return. Here, its effect is examined as a factor affecting ex-ante stock excess return. The variable used, lnATRNOVRy, is the average turnover (defined in (2)) across stocks in year y (in logarithm), calculated in the same way as the
Richardson and Smith (1993) study the effect of the term yield on subsequent stock excess return. 26
average illiquidity.20 Then, an autoregressive model is estimated, similar to model (9): (18) lnATRNOVRy = (t = ) 0.384 + 0.879 lnATRNOVRy-1 + vy , (1.56) (10.50) R2 = 0.781, DW = 2.01
The estimation results are used to obtain the unexpected turnover, lnATRNOVRyU, the residual from model (18), after adjusting the coefficients by Kendalls (1954) method. The effect of turnover on stock excess return is estimated by a model similar to (11), where stock excess return is regressed on lnATRNOVRy-1 and on lnATRNOVRyU. Turnover being a proxy for stock liquidity, its effect on stock return is hypothesized to be as follows. Higher expected liquidity should lead to lowers ex ante stock excess return, implying a negative coefficient on lnATRNOVRy-1. And, the coefficient of lnATRNOVRyU should be positive: higher unexpected liquidity in one year raises expected liquidity in the following year, which would make investors require lower stock excess return. Assuming no effect of liquidity on corporate cash flows, this should raise stock price, i.e., contemporaneous stock return is positively related to lnATRNOVRyU. In a regression of the stock excess return (RM-Rf)y on the turnover variables, the coefficient of lnATRNOVRy-1 is negative but insignificant, and the coefficient of lnATRNOVRyU is positive and significant, as expected. Since small, illiquid stocks should be more sensitive to market liquidity, the model is estimated using SRy = RMEWy RMVWy that represents the excess return on small firms stocks. The results are as follows: SRy = 32.406 (t = ) (2.65) [tR =] [2.93] 10.028 lnATRNOVRy-1 (2.41) [2.66] + 0.848 lnATRNOVRyU + wy. (2.62) [2.47] R2 = 0.354, DW = 1.90.
The negative coefficient of lagged turnover, which is statistically significant, further supports
20
The calcuation uses the same sample as that used to calculate lnAILLIQy, that is, eliminating the highest 1% cases. 27
the proposition that expected market liquidity affects ex-ante stock excess returns, especially for small firm stocks. The coefficient of unexpected turnover is positive, as expected, further supporting the hypothesis on the effect of liquidity on stock return. When both lnAILLIQy-1 and lnATRNOVRy-1 are included in the equation (the correlation between them is 0.680), only illiquidity is statistically significant whereas turnover is not. However, the test presented here using an alternative measure of liquidity lends further support to the hypothesis that liquidity is priced in the market.
28
4.
This paper presents new tests of the proposition that asset returns are increasing in illiquidity. In addition to finding that illiquidity explains differences in expected returns across stocks, which is known from earlier studies, this paper presents a new test showing that market illiquidity affects over time the ex ante stock excess return. The stock excess return RM-Rf, usually referred to as risk premium, also provides compensation for the lower liquidity of stocks relative to that of Treasury securities. And, expected stock excess return vary over time as a function of changes in market illiquidity. The study employs a new measure of illiquidity, ILLIQ, the ratio of a stock absolute daily return to its daily dollar volume, averaged over some period (here, a year). This measure is interpreted as the daily stock price reaction to a dollar of trading volume. Its virtue is that it can be easily obtained from databases that contain daily data on stock return and volume. This makes ILLIQ available for most stock markets that do not have detailed microstructure data on transactions and quotes that are necessary to construct finer measures of illiquidity, used by others.21 Importantly, since the use of ILLIQ enables to construct a time series of illiquidity over a long period of time, it enables to study the time series effect of illiquidity this would be impossible to do with microstructure data which are available for only short periods of time. Using data on NYSE stocks for the period 1964-1997, illiquidity is shown to have a positive effect on expected stock return both cross sectionally and over time. In the cross-section estimations, two liquidity variables are strongly priced: ILLIQ has a positive effect and turnover (trading volume divided by shares outstanding) has a negative effect, both statistically
21
Other measures of illiquidity are the bid-ask spread (Amihud and Mendelson (1986), the effective bid-ask spread (Chalmers and Kadlec (1998)), transaction price impact (Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1996)) or the probability of information-based trading (Easley, Hvidhjaer and OHara (1999)) all shown to have a positive effect on the cross29
significant. Also, size (stock capitalization) has the usual negative effect on stock return. The new tests presented here are of the hypotheses that over time, expected market illiquidity has a positive effect on ex ante stock excess return and unexpected illiquidity has a negative effect on contemporaneous stock return. Market illiquidity is the average across stocks in each year of their individual ILLIQ, and expected illiquidity is obtained from an autoregressive model. The effect of unexpected illiquidity is because higher realized illiquidity raises expected illiquidity for the following year. Then, if higher expected illiquidity raises stock expected return, stock prices should decline (assuming that corporate cash flows are unaffected by market liquidity). The estimation results strongly support these hypotheses. The effect of expected illiquidity on ex ante stock excess return remains positive and significant after including in the model stock volatility or two variables that are known to affect expected stock returns: the default yield premium on risky corporate bonds and the term yield premium on longterm Treasury bonds. The variations over time in the small firm effect the excess return on small firms stock is shown to be a function of changes in market illiquidity. This is because in times of dire liquidity, there is a flight to liquidity that makes large stocks relatively more attractive. The positive effect of expected illiquidity on ex ante stock excess return suggests that the stock excess return, usually referred to as risk premium, is in part a premium for illiquidity. This contributes to the explanation of the equity premium puzzle which suggests that the excess stock return over Treasury securities is too high. The results mean that stock excess return reflects not only the higher risk but also the lower liquidity of stock compared to Treasury securities.
References Amihud, Yakov and Haim Mendelson, 1986, "Asset Pricing and the Bid-Ask Spread." Journal of Financial Economics 17, 223-249. Amihud, Yakov and Haim Mendelson, 1989, The Effects of Beta, Bid-Ask Spread, Residual Risk and Size on Stock Returns. Journal of Finance 44, 479-486. Amihud, Yakov and Haim Mendelson, 1991a, Liquidity, Maturity and the Yields on U.S. Government Securities. Journal of Finance 46, 1411-1426. Amihud, Yakov and Haim Mendelson, 1991b, Liquidity, Asset Prices and Financial Policy. Financial Analysts Journal, Nov./Dec., 56-66. Amihud, Yakov, Haim Mendelson and Beni Lauterbach, 1997, Market Microstructure and Securities Values: Evidence from the Tel Aviv Exchange. Journal of Financial Economics Amihud, Yakov, Haim Mendelson and Robert Wood, 1990, Liquidity and the 1987 Stock Market Crash. Journal of Portfolio Management, Spring, 65-69. Atkins, Allen B. and Edward A. Dyl, 1997, Transactions Costs and Holding Periods for Common Stocks. Journal of Finance 52, 309-325. Banz, Rolf W., 1981, The relationship Between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks. Journal of Financial Economics 9, 3-18. Barry, Charles B. and Stephen J. Brown, 1984, Differential Information and the Small Firm Effect. Journal of Financial Information 13, 283-294. Berk, Jonathan, 1995, "A Critique of Size-Related Anomalies." Review of Financial Studies 8, 275-286. Berkman, Henk and Venkat R. Eleswarapu, 1998, Short-Term Traders and Liquidity: A Test Using Bombay Stock Exchange Data. Journal of Financial Economics 47, 339-355. Boudoukh, Jacob, Matthew Richardson and Tom Smith, 1993, Is the Ex Ante Risk Premium Always Positive? Journal of Financial Economics 34, 387-408. Brennan, Michael J. and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 1996, Market Microstructure and Asset Pricing: On the Compensation for Illiquidity in Stock Returns. Journal of Financial Economics 41, 441-464 Brennan, Michael J., Tarum Cordia and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 1998, Alternative Factor Specifications, Security Characteristics, and the Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Financial Economics 49, 345-373.
31
Brown, Philip, Allan W. Kleidon and Terry A. Marsh, 1983, New Evidence on the Nature of Size-Related Anomalies in Stock Prices. Journal of Financial Econmics 12, 33-56. Brown, Stephen and Mark Weinstein, 1983, A new Approach to Testing Asset Pricing Models: The Bilinear Paradigm. Journal of Finance 38, 711-743. Chalmers, John M.R. and Gregory B. Kadlec, 1998, An Empirical Examination of the Amortized Spread. Journal of Financial Economics 48, 159-188. Chordia, Tarun, Avanidhar Subrahmanyam and V. Ravi Anshuman, 2000, Trading Activity and Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming. Constantinides, George M., 1986, Capital Market Equilibrium with Transaction Costs. Journal of Political Economy 94, 842-862. Datar, Vinay T., Narayan Y. Naik and Robert Radcliffe, 1998, Liquidity and Stock Returns: An Alternative Test. Journal of Financial Markets 1, 205-219. Easley, David and Mureen OHara, 1987, Price, Trade Size and Information in Securities Markets, Journal of Financial Economics 19, 69-90. Easley, David, Soeren Hvidkjaer and Maureen OHara, 1999, Is Information Risk a Determinant of Asset Returns? Working Paper, Cornell University Eleswarapu, Venkat R., 1997, Cost of Transacting and Expected Returns in the NASDAQ Market. Journal of Finance 52, 2113-2127. Eleswarapu, Venkat R. and Mark Reinganum, 1993, The Seasonal Behavior of Liquidity Premium in Asset Pricing. Journal of Financial Economics 34, 373-386. Fama, Eugene F., 1990, Stock Returns, Expected Returns, and Real Activity. Journal of Finance 45, 1089-1108. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1989, Business Conditions and Expected Returns on Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 25, 23-49. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1992, The Cross Section of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Finance 47, 427-465. Fama, Eugene F. and James D. MacBeth, 1973, Risk, Return and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests. Journal of Political Economy 81, 607-636. French, Kenneth R., G. William Schwert and Robert F. Stambaugh, 1987, Expected Stock Returns and Volatility. Journal of Financial Economics 19, 3-29.
32
Glosten, Lawrence and Lawrence Harris, 1988, Estimating the Components of the Bid-Ask Spread. Journal of Financial Economics 21, 123-142. Glosten, Lawrence R. and Paul R. Milgrom, 1985, Bid, Ask and Transaction Prices in a Specialist Market with Heterogeneously Informed Traders. Journal of Financial Economics 14, 71-100. Harris, Lawrence E., 1994, Minimum Price Variation, Discrete Bid-Ask Spreads, and Quotation Sizes. Review of Financial Studies 7, 149-178. Hasbrouck, Joel, 1991, Measuring the Information Content of Stock Trades. Journal of Finance 46, 179-207. Haugen, Robert A. and Nardin L. Baker, 1996, Commonality in the Determinants of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Financial Economics 41, 401-439. Hu, Shing-Yang, 1997a, Trading Turnover and Expected Stock Returns: The Trading Frequency Hypothesis and Evidence from the Tokyo Stock Exchange. Working Paper, National Taiwan University. Hu, Shing-Yang, 1997b, Trading Turnover and Expected Stock Returns: Does it Matter and Why? Working Paper, National Taiwan University. Huang, Roger D. and Hans R. Stoll, 1997, The Components of the Bid-Ask Spread: A General Approach. Review of Financial Studies 10, 995-1034. Jagannathan, Ravi and Zhenyu Wang, 1996, The Conditional CAPM and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns. Journal of Finance 51, 3-53. Judge, George G., R. Carter Hill, William E. Griffiths, Helmut Lutkepohl and Tsoung-Chao Lee, 1988, Introduction to the Theory and Practice of Econometrics. John Wiley & Sons. Kamara, Avraham, 1994, Liquidity, Taxes, and Short-Term Treasury Yields. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 29, 403-416. Keim, Donald B. 1983, Size Related Anomalies and Stock Return Seasonality. Journal of Financial Economic 12, 13-32. Keim, Donald B. and Ananth Madhavan, 1996, The Upstairs Market for Large-Block Transactions: Analysis and Measurement of Price Effects. Review of Financial Studies 9, 1-36. Keim, Donald B. and Robert F. Stambaugh, 1986, Predicting Returns in the Stock and Bond Market. Journal of Financial Economics 17, 357-396. Kendall, M.G., 1954, Note on Bias in the Estimation of Autocorrelation. Biometrica 41, 403404.
33
Kraus, Alan and Hans R. Stoll, 1972, Price Impacts of Block Trading on the New York Stock Exchange. Journal of Finance 27, 569-588. Kyle, Albert, 1985, Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading. Econometrica 53, 1315-1335. Levy, Haim, 1978, Equilibrium in an Imperfect Market: Constraint on the Number of Securities in the Portfolio. American Economic Review 68, 643-658. Loughran, Tim, 1997, Book-to-Market across Firm Size, Exchange and Seasonality: Is there an effect? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32, 249-268. Merton, Robert C., 1987, A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium with Incomplete Information. Journal of Finance 42, 483-511. Newey, Whitney K. and Kenneth D. West, 1987, A Simple, Positive Semi Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix. Econometrica 55, 703706. Redding, Lee S., 1997, Firm Size and Dividend Payouts. Journal of Financial Intermediation 6, 224-248. Reinganum, Marc R., 1981, Misspecification of Capital Asset Pricing: Empirical Anomalies Based on Earnings Yields and Market Values. Journal of Financial Economics 9, 19-46. Reinganum, Marc R., 1990, Market Microstructure and Asset Pricing. Journal of Financial Economics 28, 127-147. Rouwenhorst, K. Geert, 1998, Local Return Factors and Turnover in Emerging Stock Markets. Working paper, Yale University. Sawa, Takamitsu, 1978, The Exact Moments of the Least Squares Estimator for the Autocorregressive model. Journal of Econometrics 8, 159-172. Scholes, Myron and Joseph Williams, 1977, Estimating Betas from Non-Synchronous Data. Journal of Financial Economics 5, 309-327. Shumway, Tyler, 1997, The Delisting Bias in CRSP Data. Journal of Finance 52, 327-340. Silber, William L, 1975, Thinness in Capital Markets: The Case of the Tel Aviv Stock Exchange. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 10, 129-142. Stambaugh, Robert F., 1999, Predictive Regressions. Journal of Financial Economics 54, 375-421. Stigum, Marcia, 1983, The Money Market (Dow Jones-Irwin, Homewood, IL).
34
Stoll, Hans R., 1978, The Pricing of Security Dealers Services: An Empirical Study of NASDAQ Stocks. Journal of Finance 33, 1153-1172. Stoll, Hans R. and Robert H. Whaley, 1983, Transaction Costs and the Small Firm Effect. Journal of Financial Economics 12, 57-79. Tinic, Seha M. and Richard R. West, 1986, Risk, Return and Equilibrium: A Revisit. Journal of Political Economy 94, 126-147.
35
Table 1: Liquidity variables Statistics of liquidity variables for the years 1963-1996 for NYSE stocks. The illiquidity measure, ILLIQiy, is the average for year y of the daily ratio of absolute return to the dollar volume of stock i in year y. The turnover ratio, TRNOVRiy, is the average for the year of the stock daily ratio of its trading volume (in shares) to the number of shares outstanding. VOLDiy is the dollar trading volume for the year, the sum of the daily product of share volume and price; lnVOLDiy is its logarithm. SIZEiy is the market capitalization of the stock at the end of the year given by CRSP; lnSIZEiy is its logarithm. Piy is the stock price at the end of the year; lnPiy is its logarithm. DIVYLDiy, the dividend yield, is the sum of the annual cash dividend divided by the end-of-year price; SDRETiy is the standard deviation of the stock daily return. Stocks admitted in each year y have more than 150 days of data for the calculation of the characteristics and their end-of-year price exceeds $5. Excluded are stocks whose ILLIQiy and TRNOVRiy are at the extreme 1% upper and lower tails of the respective distribution.
Each variable is calculated for each stock in each year across stocks admitted to the sample in that year, and then the mean and standard deviation are calculated across stocks in each year. The table presents the means over the 34 years of the annual means and standard deviations and the medians of the annual means, as well as the maximum and minimum annual means.
Variable
ILLIQ TRNOVR SIZE ($million) VOLD ($million) PRICE ($) DIVYLD (%) SDRET
Mean of Mean of Median of Min. annual Max. annual annual annual annual mean mean Means Std. Dev. means 0.372 0.588 0.319 0.060 1.089 19.28 14.36 18.90 7.73 32.60 776.9 1,589.4 525.17 245.6 2,163.1 409.9 776.1 186.6 29.3 1,445.2 27.8 29.7 27.04 16.9 42.5 4.15 5.23 4.16 2.43 6.76 2.07 0.75 1.94 1.56 2.82
Panel B: Means of the annual cross-stock correlations of the liquidity variables. ILLIQ TRNOVR lnSIZE lnVOLD LnP TRNOVR -0.144 LnSIZE -0.611 -0.092 LnVOLD -0.668 0.336 0.869 LnP -0.459 -0.058 0.688 0.570 SDRET 0.289 0.577 -0.393 -0.084
-0.461
36
Table 2: Cross-section regressions of stock return on illiquidity and other stock characteristics The table presents the means of the coefficients from the monthly cross-sectional regression of stock return on the respective variables. In each month of year y, y = 1964, 1965, 1997, stock returns are regressed cross-sectionally on stock characteristics that are calculated from data in year y-1. BETA is the slope coefficient from an annual timeseries regression of daily return on one of 10 size portfolios on the market return (equally-weighted), using the Scholes and Williams (1977) method. The stocks BETA is the beta of the size portfolio to which it belongs. The illiquidity measure ILLIQ is the average over the year of the daily ratio of the stocks absolute return to its dollar trading volume. The stock turnover ratio, TRNOVR, is the annual average of the daily ratio of stock volume (in shares) to the number of shares outstanding. ILLIQ and TRNOVR are each averaged every year across stocks, and ILLIQMA and TRNOVRMA are the respective mean-adjusted variables, calculated as the ratios of the variable to its annual mean across stocks (thus the means of both variables are 1). lnVOLD is the logarithm of the dollar trading volume for the year, the sum of the daily product of share volume and price. lnSIZE is the logarithm of the market capitalization of the stock at the end of the year, lnP is the logarithm of the stock price at the end of the year, SDRET is the standard deviation of the stock daily return during the year, and DIVYLD is the dividend yield, the sum of the annual cash dividend divided by the end-of-year price. R100 and RYR are the cumulative stock return over the last 100 days and the entire year, respectively.
The data include 408 months over 34 years, 1964-1997, (the stock characteristics are calculated for the years 1963-1996). Stocks admitted have more than 150 days of data for the calculation of the characteristics in year y-1and their end-of-year price exceeds $5. Excluded are stocks whose ILLIQ and TRNOVR are at the extreme 1% upper and lower tails of the respective distribution for the year.
Panel A: Variable
All months
Constant
-0.449 (0.94) BETA 1.263 (2.66) ILLIQMA 0.163 (6.90) R100 0.530 (1.97) RYR 0.417 (3.09) (t-statistics in parentheses)
Excluding 1964- 1980 1981-1997 January -0.242 -0.910 0.013 (0.52) (1.41) (0.02) 0.826 1.458 1.068 (1.80) (1.87) (1.96) 0.131 0.203 0.123 (5.73) (4.78) (6.04) 0.937 0.299 0.762 (3.56) (0.79) (1.99) 0.526 0.568 0.265 (3.98) (1.47) (1.54)
37
Table 2 (cont.)
Panel B: Variable
All months Constant 0.982 (1.60) BETA 0.422 (1.25) ILLIQMA 0.090 (5.26) TRNOVRMA -0.294 (4.83) LnSIZE -0.325 (4.21) LnVOLD 0.208 (3.01) LnP -0.088 (1.17) SDRET -0.141 (1.67) DIVYLD -0.054 (4.26) R100 0.574 (2.60) RYR 0.484 (4.47) (t-statistics in parentheses)
Model (1) Model (2) Model (3) Exclude 19641981All Exclude 19641981All Exclude 19641981January 1980 1997 Months January 1980 1997 Months January 1980 1997 0.632 1.521 0.444 1.730 1.154 2.337 1.123 -0.449 -0.189 -1.143 0.244 (1.04) (1.60) (0.57) (3.52) (2.37) (2.82) (2.14) (0.98) (0.42) (1.80) (0.37) 0.385 0.423 0.421 0.298 0.286 0.316 0.280 1.683 1.279 2.343 1.023 (1.18) (0.84) (0.93) (0.86) (0.87) (0.60) (0.62) (4.18) (3.32) (3.86) (1.94) 0.088 0.074 0.105 0.071 0.063 0.056 0.086 0.119 0.083 0.129 0.108 (4.94) (2.42) (6.94) (4.32) (3.80) (1.91) (5.85) (5.75) (4.28) (3.58) (5.41) -0.233 -0.366 -0.222 -0.197 -0.225 -0.242 -0.152 -0.167 -0.212 -0.198 -0.136 (3.83) (4.29) (2.56) (2.94) (3.27) (2.58) (1.59) (2.44) (3.01) (2.02) (1.42) -0.220 -0.402 -0.247 -0.146 -0.069 -0.269 -0.022 (2.85) (3.49) (2.41) (3.56) (1.82) (4.02) (0.49) 0.129 0.215 0.202 (1.86) (2.03) (2.25) 0.076 -0.167 -0.009 (1.11) (1.33) (0.12) -0.178 -0.069 -0.214 (2.06) (0.60) (1.73) -0.061 -0.083 -0.025 -0.046 -0.054 -0.077 -0.015 -0.044 -0.053 -0.073 -0.015 (4.56) (3.56) (2.58) (2.91) (3.25) (2.60) (1.38) (2.78) (3.24) (2.47) (1.34) 0.881 0.503 0.645 0.493 0.861 0.343 0.643 0.463 0.862 0.286 0.640 (4.05) (1.62) (2.06) (2.07) (3.72) (1.05) (1.86) (1.90) (3.68) (0.85) (1.81) 0.505 0.550 0.417 0.404 0.519 0.466 0.343 0.391 0.512 0.447 0.336 (4.72) (3.23) (3.12) (3.28) (4.44) (2.40) (2.24) (3.17) (4.38) (2.31) (2.19)
38
Estimates of the models: (11) (RM-Rf)y = g0 + g1 lnAILLIQy-1 + g2 lnAILLIQyU + wy , RMy is the annual equally-weighted market return and Rf is the one-year Treasury bill yield as of the beginning of year y. lnAILLIQy is market illiquidity, the logarithm of the average across stocks of the daily absolute stock return divided by the daily dollar volume of the stock (averaged over the year). lnAILLIQyU is the unexpected market illiquidity, the residual from an autoregressive model of lnAILLIQy. Estimation results are also presented for the model using a volatility variable: (13) (RM-Rf)y = g0 + g1 lnAILLIQy-1 + g2 lnAILLIQyU + h1 lnSDy-1 + h2 lnSDyU + ey . lnSDy is the (logarithm) of standard deviation of daily market return (equally weighted) for year y. lnSDyU is the unexpected market volatility, the residual from an autoregressive model of lnSDy. The models are also estimated with the dependent variable being SRy = RMEWy RMVWy, the difference between the equally-weighted and value-weighted market return. This depicts the excess return on small firms stocks. Dependent variable Constant (RM-Rf)y 14.740 (4.29) [4.37] 10.226 (2.68) [2.74] -23.567 (4.52) (4.11) SRy 7.785 (4.51) [5.76] 8.256 (4.30) [6.90] -7.242 (2.76) [3.08] (RM-Rf)y 17.504 (4.52) [4.93] 7.681 (1.95) [2.19] -22.251 (3.66) [4.21] 13.342 (1.68) [2.28] -8.665 (0.82) [1.35 0.572 2.62 SRy 8.349 (4.04) [5.35] 8.044 (3.84) [6.34] -7.820 (2.41) [3.02] 2.171 (0.51) [0.71] 1.206 (0.21) [0.25] 0.504 1.84
LnAILLIQy-1 LnAILLIQyU
LnSDy-1 LnSDyU
R-squared DW
0.512 2.55
0.499 1.85
(t-statistics are in parentheses) [Numbers in brackets are t-statistic calculated from standard errors that are robust to heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation, using the method of Newey and West (1987).]
39
This table presents regression results of the excess returns on five size-based portfolios as a function of expected and unexpected illiquidity. The estimated model is (11sz) (RSZi -Rf)y = g0 + g1i lnAILLIQy-1 + g2i lnAILLIQyU + wiy , RSZi, i=2, 4, 6, 8 and 10, are the annual returns on CRSP size-portfolio i (the smaller number indicates smaller size) and Rf is the one-year Treasury bill yield as of the beginning of year y. lnAILLIQy is market illiquidity in year y, calculated as the average across stocks of the annual average of daily absolute stock return divided by the daily dollar volume of the stock. lnAILLIQyU is the unexpected market illiquidity, the residual from an autoregressive model of lnAILLIQy. The period of estimation is 1964-1996.
RSZ2 -Rf RSZ10 Rf 19.532 4.686 (4.53) (1.55) [5.12] [1.58] lnAILLIQy-1 15.230 -0.447 (3.18) (0.13) [3.92] [0.14] lnAILLIQyU -28.021 -14.416 (4.29) (3.14) [3.91] [3.39] R-squared 0.523 0.249 D-W 2.42 2.28 (t-statistics are in parentheses) [t-statistics in brackets use standard errors that are heteroskedastic-consistent and robust to autocorrelation, following White (1980) and Newey and West (1987).] Constant
Excess return on size portfolio RSZ4 Rf RSZ6 -Rf RSZ8 -Rf 17.268 14.521 12.028 (4.16) (4.02) (3.78) [5.04] [4.32] [3.55] 11.609 9.631 7.014 (2.52) (2.40) (1.98) [3.31] [2.74] [1.84] -24.397 -20.780 -18.549 (3.88) (3.80) (3.84) [3.63] [3.41] [3.50] 0.450 0.435 0.413 2.64 2.47 2.39
40
Table 5: The effects of expected market illiquidity, default yield premium and term yield premium on expected stock excess return
Estimation results of the model Ry = g0 + g1 lnAILLIQy-1 + g2 lnAILLIQyU + a1 DEFy-1 + a2 TERMy-1 + uy, where Ry takes various values: (RM-Rf)y is the annual equally-weighted market return in excess of the one year treasury-bill rate at the beginning of year y; SRy = RMEWy RMVWy, the excess return of the market equally-weighted portfolio return over the value-weighted return (a proxy for the excess return on small firms stocks); (RSZi -Rf)y, i=2, 4, 6, 8 and 10, are the annual returns on CRSP size-portfolio i (the smaller number indicates smaller size) in excess of the oneyear T-bill rate. lnAILLIQy is market illiquidity in year y, calculated as the logarithm of the average across stocks of the annual average of daily absolute stock return divided by the daily dollar volume of the stock. lnAILLIQyU is the unexpected market illiquidity, the residual from an autoregressive model of lnAILLIQy. DEFy = DEFyDEFy-1, DEFy = YBAAyYAAAy, where YBAAy and YAAAy are, respectively, the yield to maturity on long term, BAA-rated and AAArated corporate bonds. TERMy = TERMy TERMy-1, TERMy = YLONGy YTB3y, where YLONGy and YTB3y are, respectively, the yields on long-term treasury bonds and three-month Treasury bills. Yields are as of the end of the year y-1, known to investors at the beginning of year y. The estimation period is 1964-1996.
RM-Rf SR RSZ8 -Rf RSZ10 -Rf Constant 13.151 7.177 10.719 3.911 (4.11) (4.24) (3.55) (1.27) [5.63] [5.30] [4.38] [1.55] LnAILLIQy-1 7.370 7.163 4.663 -1.840 (2.02) (3.71) (1.35) (0.53) [2.71] [6.38] [1.60] [0.62] LnAILLIQyU -22.016 -6.634 -17.302 -13.675 (4.58) (2.61) (3.81) (2.96) [4.85] [3.05] [3.96] [3.73] 13.733 3.799 14.193 8.208 DEF (2.06) (1.08) (2.26) (1.28) [2.10] [1.44] [2.33] [1.30] 2.983 1.539 1.660 1.042 TERM (1.75) (1.70) (1.03) (0.64) [2.41] [1.86] [1.48] [1.04] R-squared 0.618 0.566 0.523 0.303 D-W 2.39 1.90 2.20 2.09 (t-statistics in parentheses.) [t-statistics in brackets use standard errors that are heteroskedastic-consistent and robust to autocorrelation, following White (1980) and Newey and West (1987).]
Dependent variable RSZ2 -Rf RSZ4 -Rf RSZ6 -Rf 17.716 15.557 12.718 (4.32) (3.92) (3.88) [6.00] [6.05] [5.43] 11.966 8.533 6.389 (2.56) (1.89) (1.71) [4.23] [3.21] [2.59] -26.244 -22.736 -19.021 (4.26) (3.82) (3.86) [4.46] [4.15] [4.04] 15.235 15.739 15.642 (1.78) (1.91) (2.29) [1.93] [2.05] [2.56] 3.533 2.952 3.370 (1.61) (1.40) (1.93) [1.94] [1.75] [2.61] 0.609 0.546 0.578 2.31 2.49 2.27
41
In model (3), Uimy may be heteroskedastic, i.e., VAR(Uimy) may vary across stocks. To address this problem, weighted least squares (WLS) estimations are performed, following the procedure in Judge et al. (1988, Sec. 9.3.4). First, model (3) is estimated for each month m in year y by the OLS method. The variance of its residuals Uimy is assumed to follow the model (A-1) E(U2imy) = exp[d0 + d1 SDRETi,y-1 + d2 lnSIZEi,y-1 + d3 TRNOVRMAi,y-1]. The first variable, SDRET, is a natural measure of the residual variance and it is expected that d1>0. Indeed, this variable has by far the greatest explanatory power in the estimation. The second variable, lnSIZE, is included because the cross-sectional residual variance is assumed to be larger for small firms, i.e., d2 < 0. The third variable, TRNOVRMA, controls for liquidityrelated heteroskedasticity. Model (A-1) is estimated for each month m in year y and the estimated values of the variance, E(U2imy), are used as weights to estimate model (3) by the WLS method. Notably, however, while the estimations show that heteroskedasticity exists, the WLS estimation results of the model are not materially different from the OLS results reported earlier. In addition, the WLS estimation results of model (3) are robust to the specification of model (A1), and they are about the same when only SDRET is included in model (A-1). INSERT TABLE APP-1 HERE Panels A1 and A2 in Table APP-1 present the results of the WLS regression for the parsimonious model that includes only BETA, ILLIQMA and lagged returns, and Panels B1 and B2 present the results for the WLS regression models that include all variables. Panels A1 and B1 present the WLS coefficients of model (3), and Panels A2 and B2 present the coefficients of model (A-1), which are the averages of the coefficients obtained from an estimation of the model
42
for each of the 408 months. The results from Panels A2 and B2, showing that the coefficients of model (A-1) are highly significant, suggest that the residuals Uimy are heteroskedastic. The residual variance is not constant across stocks. Instead, it is greater for stocks with higher volatility, smaller size and higher liquidity. The most important variable is SDRET, and when only this variable is included in the model, the cross-sectional results remain about the same. As in the OLS results, the estimated mean coefficient of ILLIQMA in Table APP-1, Panel A1, is positive and highly significant in the entire estimation period, in all months excluding the month of January, and in each of the two subperiods, demonstrating stability over time. The median of the coefficient of ILLIQMA, 0.109, is close to the mean of 0.141, and 2/3 of the 408 estimated coefficients are positive, a proportion which is significantly different from the null proportion of 1/2. The results in Table APP-1, Panel B1, show again that liquidity strongly affects stock returns when additional variables are included in the model. The coefficient of ILLIQMA is positive and highly significant in the entire period, in all months excluding January, and in each of the two subperiods. The coefficient of TRNOVRMA is negative and significant as expected, but its effect is weaker in the second subperiod, and when lnSIZE is excluded from the model. The size effect is negative and significant, as expected, but its significance declines when January is excluded and it is insignificant in the second subperiod. The effect of lnVOLD is positive, but it may reflect the correlation of this variable with the other liquidity variables that are included in the model and which are functions of volume. The effect of stock price is insignificant. The effect of SDRET is insignificant, and the effect of DIVYLD is negative and significant, as before, except being insignificant in the second subperiod. Notably, BETA gains
43
greater significance in the WLS regression, especially when size is excluded.22 Importantly, including the risk variable SDRET in the cross-section model does not change the results on the effect of illiquidity. The results show again that the effect of ILLIQ is distinct from that of risk. Altogether, the results from both the OLS and the WLS are consistent. Liquidity, measured by both ILLIQ and TRNOVR, is an important determinant of expected return on assets.
22
Recall that size was an instrument for the formation of portfolios to estimate beta. 44
Table APP-1: Cross-section weighted-least-squares regressions of stock return on illiquidity and other stock characteristics The table presents the results of weighted-least-squares regressions, done in three steps. (1) In each month of year y, y = 1964, 1965, 1997, a cross-section OLS regression is estimated of stock returns as a function of stock characteristics that are calculated from data in the previous year. (2) The logarithms of the squared residuals from step (1) are regressed on stock characteristics that include SDRET, lnSIZE and TRNOVRMA (and a constant). This follows from model (A-1). The exponential values of the fitted values from this regression, estimates of the stocks variances, are used as weighting factors in the third step. (3) In each month, the same model as in (1) is estimated by the weighted least squares regression method. Panel A1 and B1 present the means of the coefficients of the weighted least squares regressions in stage (3). Panels A2 and B2 present the means of the coefficients from the model in step (2) for the respective models.
The variables: BETA is the slope coefficient from a time-series annual regression of daily return on one of 10 size portfolios on the market (equally-weighted) return, using the Scholes and Williams (1977) method. The stocks BETA is the beta of the size portfolio to which it belongs. The illiquidity measure ILLIQ is the average over the year of the daily ratio of the stocks absolute return to its dollar trading volume. The stock turnover ratio, TRNOVR, is the annual average of the daily ratio of stock volume (in shares) to the number of shares outstanding. ILLIQ and TRNOVR are each averaged every year across stocks, and ILLIQMA and TRNOVRMA are the respective mean-adjusted variables, calculated as the ratios of the variable to its annual mean across stocks (thus the means of both variables are 1). lnVOLD is the logarithm of the dollar trading volume for the year, the sum of the daily product of share volume and price. lnSIZE is the logarithm of the market capitalization of the stock at the end of the year, lnP is the logarithm of the stock price at the end of the year, SDRET is the standard deviation of the daily stock return during the year, and DIVYLD is the dividend yield, the sum of the annual cash dividend divided by the end-of-year price. R100 and RYR are the cumulative stock return over the last 100 days and the entire year, respectively. The data include 408 months over 34 years, 1964-1997, (the stock characteristics are calculated for the years 1963-1996). Stocks admitted have more than 150 days of data for the calculation of the characteristics in year y-1and their end-of-year price exceeds $5. Excluded are stocks whose ILLIQ and TRNOVR are at the extreme 1% upper and lower tails of the respective distribution for the year.
45
All months
Constant
-0.764 (1.63) BETA 1.562 (3.41) ILLIQMA 0.141 (6.24) R100 0.368 (1.25) RYR 0.489 (3.24) (t-statistics in parentheses)
Panel A2: Variable Constant
Excluding 1964- 1980 1981-1997 January -0.579 -1.310 -0.218 (1.30) (2.05) (0.32) 1.156 1.842 1.281 (2.70) (2.50) (2.35) 0.115 0.163 0.119 (5.39) (4.12) (5.45) 0.862 0.249 0.487 (3.12) (0.65) (1.09) 0.623 0.607 0.371 (4.51) (2.77) (1.79)
All months 1.621 (29.83) 0.573 (44.44) -0.049 (8.86) 0.099 (15.63)
46
Model (1) Model (2) Model (3) All Exclude 19641981All Exclude 19641981All Exclude 19641981months January 1980 1997 Months January 1980 1997 Months January 1980 1997 Constant -0.044 -0.144 -0.052 -0.035 1.023 0.612 1.020 1.027 -0.671 -0.425 -1.473 0.132 (0.07) (0.25) (0.06) (0.05) (2.27) (1.42) (1.30) (2.28) (1.48) (1.99) (2.34) (0.20) BETA 0.801 0.708 1.138 0.464 0.702 0.660 1.097 0.307 1.805 1.464 2.503 1.106 (2.44) (2.31) (2.25) (1.11) (2.13) (2.19) (2.13) (0.75) (4.62) (4.07) (4.32) (2.12) ILLIQMA 0.085 0.082 0.068 0.101 0.073 0.065 0.056 0.089 0.110 0.079 0.113 0.107 (4.86) (4.73) (2.20) (6.36) (4.56) (4.10) (2.02) (5.67) (5.60) (4.34) (3.42) (5.00) TRNOVRMA -0.338 -0.291 -0.392 -0.284 -0.146 -0.185 -0.184 -0.107 -0.123 -0.175 -0.148 -0.098 (5.53) (5.00) (4.45) (3.36) (2.06) (2.66) (1.76) (1.13) (1.71) (2.46) (1.35) (1.04) LnSIZE -0.305 -0.217 -0.340 -0.270 -0.099 -0.039 -0.187 -0.011 (4.28) (3.21) (3.19) (2.83) (2.76) (1.19) (3.24) (0.27) LnVOLD 0.215 0.151 0.211 0.220 (3.39) (2.50) (2.17) (2.67) LnP -0.024 0.098 -0.100 0.052 (0.35) (1.53) (0.87) (0.63) SDRET -0.043 -0.087 0.038 -0.123 (0.46) (0.94) (0.31) (0.86) DIVYLD -0.044 -0.057 -0.065 -0.024 -0.041 -0.055 -0.064 -0.018 -0.038 -0.054 -0.058 -0.017 (3.16) (4.04) (2.52) (2.17) (2.30) (3.13) (1.94) (1.31) (2.12) (3.11) (1.77) (1.26) R100 0.424 0.827 0.492 0.357 0.323 0.771 0.284 0.360 0.302 0.776 0.244 0.359 (1.86) (3.84) (1.65) (1.03) (1.26) (3.22) (0.89) (0.90) (1.16) (3.19) (0.75) (0.88) RYR 0.530 0.578 0.564 0.495 0.438 0.569 0.464 0.412 0.441 0.574 0.460 0.423 (4.54) (5.34) (3.36) (3.05) (3.21) (4.74) (2.45) (2.19) (3.24) (4.79) (2.33) (2.24) (t-statistics in parentheses)
47
Model (1) All months 2.196 (53.69) 0.110 (47.74) -0.064 (11.72) 0.161 (23.90)
Model (2) All months 1.377 (27.57) 0.646 (55.61) -0.039 (7.12) 0.085 (13.08)
Model (3) All months 1.333 (26.76) 0.653 (55.91) -0.0363 (6.00) 0.082 (12.52)
48