Hedge Funds en
Hedge Funds en
Hedge Funds en
Presented by Ieke van den Burg, Socialist Group ECON coordinator Poul Nyrup Rasmussen, PES President
Foreword Acknowledgments Executive summary Our Europe Part 1 Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work Part 2 Six concerns about our European social market economy Part 3 Lessons to be drawn for future regulation Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work The real economy is still there 1. Hedge funds 2. Private Equity Funds 3. The European response current EU regulation 4. Conclusion: New Social Europe and the financial markets increasing contradictions! Part II Six concerns about our Europan social market economy Social Europe versus capital markets 1. Economic viability of private companies 2. Decent work and workers participation 3. Public sector and universal provision of services of general interest 4. Employees, pension fund investments and long-term real value 5. Stability of financial markets 6. Coherence, co-responsibility and ethics 7. The need for change to ensure a sustainable New Social Europe Part III Lessons to be drawn for future regulation 1. The market cannot do it alone 2. Market transparency a common interest 3. Hedge funds 4. Private Equity Funds focusing on LBOs 5. Our immediate proposals Annex Case studies Glossary
3 7 9 11 14 19 23 29 31 34 62 84 97 99 101 103 109 118 125 132 146 148 151 153 156 159 170 178 185 241
FOREWORD
Since the 1980s the financial markets have undergone fundamental change. The impact of globalisation has not been so dramatic and far-reaching in any other part of our societies. Hedge funds and private equity funds have existed for a long time but their enormous growth is one of the most striking new developments with strong implications for the structures, the behaviours, and the transparencies of the financial markets, as well as business practice within them. The question is: does this new development bring down the cost of capital? Does it lead to higher efficiency on the capital markets? Or are we faced with new risks of financial stability, imperfections or abuse on the capital markets? An even more fundamental issue is: Do we have today, with the increasing dominance of hedge funds and private equity funds, financial markets in Europe functioning with full transparency, financing the real economy on optimal conditions? This precise question has given rise to much concern among progressive political parties including PES and the PES Group in the European Parliament, trade unions, corporate businesses, and employees. Hedge funds and private equity funds cannot be analysed and discussed in a clear, fair and logical way without placing these capital funds in a broader context. And this context is our social Europe, in other words the Lisbon agenda. In 2000 the European Council defined in Lisbon the objectives of the strategy as making Europe: The most competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world, capable of sustainable economic growth, more and better jobs and better social cohesion. In preparation for the Spring European Council 2005, the PES group presented on 1 February 2005 its report: A Europe of excellence- the Lisbon strategy: Getting from declarations to results. Europes choice is to base its competitive strategy on excellence, on the high quality of its infrastructure, its public services, its environment, its welfare systems, its workforce, its labour markets, and its companies. Europe has no future trying to compete as a low-cost producer in a global economy. We want to renew our welfare societies our social Europe so that it can survive in the global economy. The Lisbon idea is to recognise that by favouring investments and creating an environment in which globally competitive companies can flourish. Europes social and environmental model is not an obstacle but an ally.
We clearly confirm our readiness for reforms in our welfare societies from the labour market to the market in goods, to education policies, social policies etc. but the right reforms! And reforms must go hand in hand with investment, growth and more and better jobs: investment in research and development, new technologies, education and improved qualifications, in public sectors as well as in private business. Investment public and private is the crucial agent of transformation. We need investment to make our welfare societies more competitive in the global economy. The very basis for New Social Europe in the global economy is a pro-active European industrial policy, focusing on knowledge and information, and smart green growth. But, to achieve these objectives, long-term, patient investment is crucial. We still believe in the market but it must be a social market economy, not a market society. This fundamental distinction was reiterated in the spring 2005 communication from the European Council, which quotes the draft vision for a European constitution of a highly competitive social market economy. The decisive question is to what extent the growing sector of alternative investment funds the hedge funds and private equity funds conform and contribute to a positive, efficient and long-termist role for the capital markets in financing the enormous amount of investment needed to make a Europe of Excellence in the real economy? Alternatively to what extent the activities of hedge funds and private equity funds are inimical to the wider social interest, extracting rather than creating value, and leaving others in the society to pick up the cost? Answers could not be found in existing, actual information or analyses. Neither, unfortunately, can we expect answers from the European Commission. In July 2005 the European Commission launched a public debate on possible ways to enhance the European framework for investment funds. The Commission established a couple of Alternative Investment Expert Groups to describe how they see the future development of the hedge funds and private equity funds in Europe, and whether there are any European-level regulatory or other obstacles which hold back the efficient organisation of the business in Europe. But the purpose of the reports as described seems to presuppose that the major problem is too much existing regulation. In July 2006, the result of this work was published in two reports titled Developing European Private Equity and Managing Servicing and Marketing Hedge Funds in Europe. The PES-Group in the European Parliament welcomes that the European Commission has drawn attention to the alternative investment market in general and private equity funds and hedge funds in particular. However, the PES-Group is critical of the fact that the two reports have been drafted by expert groups, mostly consisting of representatives of organisations with a strong interest in the light touch regulation of alternative investment markets, which both reports duly proposed. Moreover, the PES-Group is deeply concerned by the strong bias in many of the analyses of the reports. A bias towards deregulation is even more striking in the policy proposals derived from these analyses and the reports fail to address a number of pivotal issues. This work at the behest of Commissioner McCreevy is in stark contrast to the very well documented worries expressed in reports from among others the ECB, and the World Bank. The PES-Group first voiced its criticism in preliminary comments to the European Commissions two reports by the so-called Alternative Investment Expert Groups.
***
At the same time the PES Group took full account of the present lack of coherent analysis and reflections on how to tackle the new trends on the financial markets in the interest of our societies. Therefore, we decided to establish our own group of experts (henceforth referred to as PESExperts Reiner Hoffmann, Christen Amby, Giovanni Di Corato, Jeppe Jrgensen, Michel Aglietta, Norbert Kluge, Pierre Bollon, Will Hutton, Paul Windolf, Andrew Watt, Lothar Kamp, Mick McAteer, Roland Kstler, Sam Ironside, William Melody, Norbert Wieczorek) and with them to analyse the situation and consider the need for regulation. The group has now finished Capital funds in Europe a critical analysis, reflecting discussions during the period July February 2006/2007. From the outset we insisted that this report should not be based on feelings or our perspective but on facts and a very clear commitment to the future of Europe the Europe of Excellence, the New Social Europe, the Lisbon Process. Therefore, the report is based on a number of case studies from the real economy to document the strategies and the pattern of reactions followed by most private equity funds. Accessible studies, analyses, information and updates have been integrated into our work supplemented by our own experts analysis. Our analyses have shown that some hedge funds and private equity funds contribute to making capital markets function more efficiently, to making some passive, corporate business managers more pro-active and ensuring returns to investors, pension funds etc. However, overwhelming evidence and practical experience show that most of their activities raise serious concerns and problems in the real economy, e.g. the impact on long-term investment in R&D, new technology etc. in co-operative businesses, jobs and working conditions, investor protection and systemic risks to the stability of the financial markets. Finally, this report considers a number of tentative proposals that should provoke discussions on the objectives and form of future regulatory issues incentives, codes of conduct, monitoring, regulations by member states as well as the European Union and other international bodies. We deeply believe in a transparent, well-regulated market economy as the basis for the social economy in our welfare states and in the future global economy. But we also strongly believe that such regulatory measures have to be stronger than the light touch regulation proposed by the Alternative Investment Expert Group of the European Commission. Otherwise, we will simply weaken the future of our companies, industries and services, and the capability to be at the front of the added value chain, which requires constant high investment in knowledge, research and advanced employment more and better jobs. And our Lisbon goal to become the most competitive and dynamic knowledge-driven economy in the world, capable of sustainable economic growth with more and better jobs and greater social cohesion will surely be under threat. There is a better way.
Foreword
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This report has become a reality thanks to the determination of Poul Nyrup Rasmussen, President of the Party of European Socialists and Ieke van den Burg, MEP, PES coordinator in ECON. We also thank Pervenche Bers, MEP, Chair of ECON and the MEPs actively involved in the Contact Group created for this project: Harald Ettl, Peter Skinner and others. The support of the PES Group Bureau was also very warmly welcome. Our work has benefited greatly from the input given by the following experts and observers: Michel Aglietta, Paris X University and Scientific advisor to CEPII, France; Christen Amby, Denmark; Pierre Bollon, France; Giovanni Federico di Corato, Member of the Board of FOPEN, Italy; Simon Cox, EFFAT, Brussels; Reiner Hoffmann, ETUI-REHS, Brussels; Sam Ironside, UNI-Europa, Brussels; Jeppe F. Jrgensen, University of Potsdam and Berlin School of Economics, Germany; Lothar Kamp, Hans Bckler Stiftung, Germany; Dr. Norbert Kluge, ETUI-REHS, Germany; Dr. Roland Kstler, Hans Bckler Stiftung, Germany; Mick McAteer, Independent Consumer Advocate, UK; William Melody, Center for ICT, Technical University of Denmark, Denmark; Dr. Norbert Wieczorek, ex-MP, Germany; Andrew Watt, ETUI-REHS, Brussels; Paul Windolf, University Trier, Germany.
In addition, we want to add to this list the names of those who have also provided highly valuable written input to our draft report, in the way of drafting case studies, providing sources of information and data or making specific research/comments: Stphane Janin; Peter Rossman, IUF, Switzerland; Johannes Heuschmid, legal expert, Berlin; Sebastian Sick, Alexandra Krieger, Hans Bckler Stiftung, Dsseldorf; Sigurt Vitols, Science Center, Berlin; Dr. Volker Telljohann, Institute for Labour Foundation, Bologna. A special thank to Annabel Garnier, Political advisor, PES Group and Jonas J. Mller, assistant, whose commitment have made this project a reality. It goes without saying that Morten Damm Krogh and Tina Hjlund Pedersen from the Office of Poul Nyrup Rasmussen have been more than helpful to keep the project on the right tracks.
This report does not necessarily express the views of the PES, its member parties or its Parliamentary Group.
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
7845.35781499
Our Europe
In this new era of globalisation, conditions have changed for our welfare states. We know that globalisation offers new opportunities and enormous potential wealth if we bring the European social market economy and the global economy together in the right way. And this must be our concern whether we are formulating concrete, new initiatives in the real economy or the financial markets. This is not a discussion as to whether we should reform or not. We need reforms of the real economy, the labour market, business, education, service etc. We must combine social justice and social security with full employment, growth and competitiveness. And we can do it a number of European countries have proved it. We all stakeholders in the real economy as well as in the financial markets will base our strategies on our common values. ***
The question
The question is, do we have today, with the increasing dominance of hedge funds and private equity funds, a financial market in Europe, which lives up to optimal conditions? This has given rise to concern among progressive, political parties, PES and the PES Group in the European Parliament, trade unions, corporate businesses, and employees. Hedge funds and private equity funds have been operating for many years but their enormous growth is the most striking new challenge for our societies, and the structures, transparency and business practice on the financial markets. We regard it as a common responsibility to assure that this new development leads to higher efficiency on the capital markets, effective financing of long-term investment, and full transparency. And we are certainly aware of the related risks i.e. financial instability, imperfections or abuse of the capital market. HFs and PE funds cannot be analysed in a fair and consistent way without placing these capital funds in a broader context. This is our social Europe. In 2000 in Lisbon the European Council defined the strategy for making Europe The most competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world capable of sustainable economic growth, more and better jobs and better social cohesion. This was confirmed at the Spring European Council 2005. The PES Group was precise in its preparation for this council decision by presenting its report: A Europe of Excellence the Lisbon process: Getting from declarations to results. Europes choice must be based on its competitive strategy on excellence, on a high quality of infrastructure, its public services, its workforce and labour markets, its environment and welfare, and its companies.
Executive summary
11
12
These reports are in striking contrast to the very well-documented worries about lack of transparency expressed in reports from the ECB, the World Bank, the FSA, and American monetary institutions like the SEC. The PES Group has already voiced its criticism of the work of the European Commission through a number of comments on reports by the so-called alternative investment expert groups. Recently, the responsible commissioner, McCreevy, has expressed his views: Private equity houses and activist fund managers of all kinds including hedge funds play a much more valuable role than any government or any regulator in reducing the cost of capital. We are not aware of any other voices expressing similar views neither in Europe or the USA nor at the London and New York stock exchanges. With the exception of Commissioner McCreevy, all others have reached recognition that some change is needed to ensure a betterfunctioning capital market.
***
13
Executive summary
14
outs of European companies, it is still striking to see the dominance of the US funds. They are simply the most powerful funds in the world. US funds like Texas Pacific Group, Blackstone and KKR, together have a capacity equalling more than 30% of worldwide equity. *** Hedge funds, PEs and the banks, including investment banks, enjoy ever closer cooperation and interdependence. HFs are very important partners for prime brokers and investment banks providing revenues and services. This increasing interplay and interdependence also increases systemic risks and there seems to be an extra argument for claims of disclosure, transparency and regulations such as already exist for commercial banks and investment banks. This argument is underlined by the high complexities in asset evaluation of derivatives, managed by the hedge funds. When HFs compete in delivering high returns, there is the possibility of careless evaluations and even miscalculation.
***
Investment strategies
Hedge funds and private equity funds are based on investment strategies with a much shorter time horizon than is needed for long-term investment in the real economy of Europe. Looking at the LBOs major strategies, there is an even stronger shortening of the time horizon for retrieving the money invested with extremely high benefits. Several methods of ensuring these returns and fees are at his disposal: extraordinary shareholder dividends, stepped increases in leverage, fees, job cuts, sale or flotation. The LBO managers take their time and choose the exit method that would maximise the cash-flow. All this is done quite independently of the long-term interest of the company.
Highly leveraged investments are also a common strategy for HF and PE funds. The high growth of leverage is, of course, influenced by the extreme pressure on average performance.
15
In a very low interest-rate landscape it is highly possible that the appetite of investors for risk and performance is bigger than risk-free instruments (typically bonds) can offer. This militates towards placing assets in HF and PEs. It looks like a vicious circle and it would be completely reversed in a high-interest rate scenario. This forms part of the discussion of systemic risks. Margin loans, securities lending and use of derivatives could lead to a total estimate on the enormous amount of leverage. In the HF industry the total debt including derivatives is something between 150% and 250% of HF single values, i.e. 2.0 3.3 trillion USD. Within this broad framework we see extreme cases. LTCM is well-known and CITADELs leverage amounted to 11.5 times. This is an example of groundbreaking ability to access capital markets for unsecured debt. The majority of HFs only have a few ways of boosting returns and extensive leverage is one of the few think LTCM. *** The PE industry and its use of LBO in many ways has serious, direct consequences for the target companies: The PE funds usually co-finance an acquisition through leverage and its own assets. Thus the PE is acquiring a high return on the investment and at the same time pushing down debt on the target company.
16
3. The target company is merged with the newly formed company owned by the PE-fund. In this way the creditors security rights give access to the assets of the target company. In a number of cases where the merger is based on real economic concerns for the future of the company, we see constructive results. But, as shown in Part II, we often see a clear asset stripping of the company acquired with major detriment not only to its debt level, but often also to its employees and investment capability for the future. The LBO itself only uses its own money to a very small degree, often of the acquiring sum. The majority of the funding is borrowed through leverage. This is creating the so-called leverage effect: the difference between the return on equity and return on capital employed. Through leverage it is possible for a target company to deliver a return on equity exceeding the rate on return on all the capital invested in the business, i.e. its return on capital employed. And at the top of that the company has to use its liquidity and earnings capability to pay interest and debts. The company will be forced to use most of its earnings for this purpose and is in worst cases no longer capable of investing in further development of the company. In a socalled secondary sale the last part of the companys added-value is extracted with damaging effects on the workplace, investment capabilities, competition and the companys employment and education of employees etc.
Tendency of crowding
Where HFs are pursuing similar strategies, there is a similar risk that they will buy or sell their positions at the same time thereby disturbing liquidity, i.e. the normal drive of supply and demand. Such behaviour could in turn leave HFs and their co-operators like banks and institutional investors highly vulnerable to adverse market dynamics. Even in cases of strategy differences, our calculations and analyses show that there is still a strong correlation among HF actions on the financial markets.
17
Executive summary
The ECB has highlighted this crowding problem recently in its 2006 financial stability report: The fact that correlations are trending higher not only within some strategies, but also among strategies, raise concerns that a triggering event could lead to highly correlated exits across large parts of the hedge fund industry.
18
19
Executive summary
in the sustainable development of the enterprise and innovation or human resource management and training. Should interest rates rise there would be a risk that the debt could no longer be serviced, bringing the target enterprise to the edge of bankruptcy.
20
The effects of LBOs on infrastructure operators are magnified because of their unique characteristics. The most significant impact is on their capability to efficiently finance long-term investment programmes. This is where we see the short-term priorities of the PEs in conflict with the long-term priorities of infrastructure operators. After the acquisition, the new owners have a powerful incentive to pay themselves the major portion of the large, internally generated cashflow that would have been used for re-investment. The company is forced to acquire the large debt borrowed by the LBO fund. The net result is that the company is no longer well positioned for making efficient long-term investment. The entry of PE funds into the infrastructure industry raises serious questions over investment in these incumbent operators, holding strategic positions with significant monopoly power and public service responsibilities. The telecom industry is the key example.
21
Executive summary
***
22
23
Transparency in practise
Some are thinking of indirect regulations as a further development of already existing frameworks. But this seems more and more insufficient because investment banks including prime brokers are strongly dependent on PEs and HFs for their business volumes and profits. They are increasingly active themselves in proprietary HF and LBO business. In realising transparency and supervision, it is natural to focus on the interests of our societies in Europe, our view is, in principle, to fully harmonise the framework for European HFs in order to create a unitary category of onshore funds with a common minimum investment threshold. It would obviously not prevent some investors from keeping their activities secret in offshore funds, but it would offer an alternative choice for the rest of investors, through a higher level of safety, a guaranteed level of professionalism of fund managers, and oversight by regulators. Such EUregulated projects will be offered as complementary to off-shore funds. The transparency and disclosure regulation relating to alternative investments needs to be improved to enhance accountability and ensure a high degree of consumer protection. To this end the EU should draw up minimum reporting standards. To detect liquidity risk, the aggregate deposits for all HFs in key markets should be made known to bank supervisors. Those data, indicatively not to be publicly disclosed, should be shared by prime brokers and bank supervisors. We are fully aware of the difficulty of introducing common supervision of such projects undertaken by a unique supervisory body, for instance the ECB. But we still consider this possibility as the only effective way to achieve such an aim. As far as investor protection is concerned, especially pension funds interest, the focus should be on the information side. Pension fund managers should be able to assess and compare financial returns and risks of the different types of management. Transparency requires more frequent disclosure of returns and risk characteristics, and a resulting public database should be available to all investors. Besides the information disclosed to the supervisors, disclosure to the general public is of common interest. New standards relating to the sale and promotion of alternative investment projects needs to be developed to protect consumers from mis-selling and mis-representation of risks. Funds that are eligible for marketing to retail investors should conform to a number of safeguards. A number of concerns have been raised about the valuation of assets within alternative investment funds including HFs. The European Commission should establish robust minimum standards. As far as private equity is concerned, the following initiatives should be considered: The regulatory step to be considered is to increase the transparency of the key funds by requiring reporting at regular intervals to an appropriate regulatory authority on (i) the investment strategy of the company, (ii) details of the assets held by the company, (iii) disclosure of the risk management model used, and (iv) the managements incentive structure. Direct supervision of LBO through the appropriate agencies should take place via guidelines and direct controls. It appears worth considering whether new tasks within the framework of supervision and regulation could be transferred to the ECB. At EU level one could at least argue for a directive defining minimum standards for disclosure.
24
Corporate governance
As far as HFs are concerned the following should be considered to ensure best functioning of corporate governance: Rules relating to the fair and the equitable treatment of different classes of share holders are needed to ensure that funds cannot use pricing policies to attract potential investors or dissuade potential sellers. The EU should establish rules to ensure this. The EU should create a framework to allow the HF industry and PEs to be rated according to investment strategy and risk. The EU Commission should also reflect on the conduct of business rules enacted by the financial community. These rules should include strong sanctions modelled after the City Code on Takeovers and Mergers of the LSE. Reporting requirements should include not only assessment of risks and returns but also a corporate responsibility report to allow investors to understand the impact on other stake holders in the investment chain (employees). As far as LBOs are concerned, we should try to create incentives for longer-term investments. It needs an overall effort to ensure the further development of the Rhenanian model of public companies. This model guarantees the engagement of all stake holders including employees and other investors. The following proposals should be considered: Besides creating incentives for long-term investments, long-term investors should be rewarded by permitting weighting of voting rights according to duration of share holding and by means of differentiated taxation of income from shareholders. In order to prevent value extraction, limitations on the withdrawal of liquid assets from the target company should be introduced. One could also imagine restricting owners freedom to set managers remuneration packages (stock-options) autonomously. The desired character of investments could also be channelled in the right direction by capital-maintenance provisions which proscribe a limitation of the transfer of debts to companies that are the object of LBOs, through the restriction of credit financing.
In order to ensure a better protection of pension funds investing in LBOs, we can consider relevant regulation at European level.
Executive summary
25
Tax policy
We must distinguish between taxation of funds and taxation of fund managers. The funds themselves are as the broad majority located outside the European Union, first and foremost for the reason of tax minimisation and light regulatory regimes. The consequences of tax losses for the region of Europe cannot be calculated exactly, due to a lack of information, but we are talking about a huge amount of money. This loss of income cannot be saved by ensuring the managers pay the correct amount of tax for their onshore activities. We know that most end-investors are located offshore. Ideally, a uniform, progressive capital gains tax rate should be applied in all member states. The progressive rate should be high for short-term arbitrage deals, to discourage the short-term buying and selling of firms on the market for corporate control. Taxes should be paid in the country where the object of the transaction is located. The fact that investors in private equity funds are most often untaxed is exploited by the funds, partly by utilising the low rate of corporation tax and partly by allocating large dividends from target companies, since the latter are not in reality subject to taxation. Leverage buy-outs mean that both the acquired company and the associated holding companies have contracted a considerable amount of interest-bearing debt. Since it is possible in most countries to establish joint taxation or tax consolidation, the acquired company is allowed to deduct the interest expenditure inquired. Result: The tax base is eroded. Therefore, common rules should be considered in EU countries to counter-act such tax erosions: Rules should be introduced limiting deductions for expenditure on interest in the target company, its holding companies and its subsidiary companies once the target company has been taking over through a leverage buy-out.
26
The limitation could take the form of no deductions being allowed for interest expenditure by the local holding companies that have been established to carry out the takeover. The limitation could also take the form of removal of the deduction for interest expenditure by the target company, in respect of interest on the debt incurred in order to pay an extraordinary dividend after the company has been taken over by a LBO. There should be various protection rules to prevent the crass over-exploitation of tax saving opportunities. In the area of taxation of hedge funds, there are mainly two proposals: To introduce a fiscal discrimination, including FOHFs and all tax-exempt organisations, against offshore projects. To address the risks associated with offshore jurisdiction, consideration should be given to changing the tax rules, so that the location of the manager determines the tax position of hedge funds.
The demand for change and better regulation seems only to grow.
27
PART I HEDGE FUNDS AND PRIVATE EQUITY FUNDS HOW THEY WORK
7845.35781499
31
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
The first era of capitalism took the form of family-owned capitalism where large family not only owned companies but also had the funds to make the necessary investments into their business. This traditional form was characterised by very close relationships between the management and the employees despite a cruel lack of social rights. Although in retrospect it appeared to some analysts as the good times, this period also revealed a lack of dynamism, where the economy was closed and very local, with few perspectives for expansion. Since the financial markets were not well developed, the access to finance was limited. Growth was too weak and the decision-making in companies was too top/down. This situation, described here in very broad terms, was the reality in Europe more or less until the 1950s.Then, an important decision taken after World War II, i.e. the convertibility of currencies into gold and the opening of trade at an international level, completely changed the face of capitalism. We saw the rise of international markets, leading to the development of shareholder ownership. Managers controlled large public corporations, but they did not own them. Shareholders owned corporations but were unable to control them or coordinate their own actions due to their large numbers. They provided long-term capital on the condition that managers paid them a decent dividend. The separation of ownership and control kept the shareholders at arms length from managerial decision-making. The public corporation was not insulated from stock markets, but entrepreneurial decision-making was not directly influenced by the volatility of financial markets. The immediate benefits from this change of international dimension were a boost for growth, an increase of productivity and the development of new technologies. A new type of company appeared: the so-called multinationals. While industry at the same time suffered from a poor capacity for renewal, there was a growing distance between owners of companies and their employees, and a slow-down in upgrading infrastructure. We witnessed the internationalisation of stock exchanges but not yet true international financial markets. The 1970s were characterised by an acceleration of internationalisation. There was strong potential for economic growth until 1979, with increasing productivity. A phenomenon, called globalisation, became the new paradigm, going beyond the level of nation states and deep into the real economy. There was also a re-concentration of ownership in the large public corporation. The last development of this evolution of capitalism had its roots in the USA. The shareholder value-concept has been increasingly influencing our societies, not only financial markets, but also managerial decision-making in companies in the real economy. Capital markets have changed fundamentally during the last decade. Today, financing capital is organised in relatively larger funds, compared to the traditional channel of bank financing. Today, pension funds and insurance companies re investing in up to 50% of all shares and 40% of other stocks and bonds. Another new phenomenon is hedge funds and private equity funds both focusing on shortterm profit and huge management fees. This new type of ownership means in reality the predominance of institutional investors: banks, insurance companies, financial conglomerates, pension funds and other funds like private equity funds and, sometimes, hedge funds. Financial market capitalism may therefore be defined as a specific capitalist regime within which the real economy is more and more dominated by the operational principles of the financial markets. This is a quite recent phenomenon where, in addition to imposing their operational principles, funds are also the owners of the real economy, in one way or another. They may act in concert or not, they may exercise their voting rights or not, but in all cases, they are characterised by a damaging lack of transparency which affects both the
32
market itself (in terms of price transparency, herd effect and volatility) and the end-investors (in terms of risk management and sound investment decision). In Germany, a political decision was taken in the late nineties, the magnitude of which was unforeseen. A law allowed the banks ownership of companies to be passed to financial market ownership. This completely changed the philosophy of the German company model, which was based on the two-tier decision process the supervisory board ensuring the influence of shareholders, and the management ensuring coherence of all stakeholders in the company. Hedge funds and private equity took full advantage of their new opportunity with substantial effect on German industry. It is essential to view the private equity phenomenon as well as the hedge funds growth within the context of the changed, financialised environment as a whole, because their impact is not limited to their target companies, but exerts a profound influence on the economy as a whole, including those companies which remain under traditional ownership, whether publicly listed or privately held. The decisive question is to what extent the growing sector of alternative investment funds the HF and PE funds conform and contribute to a positive, efficient and long-term oriented role for the capital market in financing the enormous amount of investment needed to promote a Europe of excellence in the real economy? Unfortunately, our worries are that they do not. Our analysis in this report indicates, that many activities of HF and PE funds are inimical to the wider social interest, and are simply about extracting rather than creating value in the companies. The aim of Part I is to give a comprehensive description of the hedge fund and private equity fund industries in Europe as these are the fundamental part of the alternative investment industry. Both are to a large extent deregulated and both operate with short-term horizons to realise planned high returns. Although their effect on the real economy is similar they use financial markets in different ways, which is why we shall consider them separately. Of course, there are huge differences to be found among the investment funds. Venture capital is invested in new and upcoming companies, often within high-tech industries. It generates real growth, supports good ideas and is a very important aspect of the investment market to promote the knowledge-economy of Europe. But our main topic in this report is HF and PE funds, especially the so-called leverage buy-out funds.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
It is highly important to underline again that the alternative investment industry is heavily deregulated and opacity is its general rule. Consequently it is not possible to gather public information concerning products and managers, as it is in the case of the UCITS industry. A full understanding of the current size and shape of the market, of its most relevant features and of its trend is necessarily influenced by these limitations. However, the report is based on industry sources, a whole range of important, new publicly accessible research and a set of concrete case studies (see annex).
33
1. Hedge funds
In the following pages we will try to offer an analytical and comprehensive picture of the hedge funds industry, focusing on its European segment. Hedge funds are a recent development in Europe. The purpose of hedge funds has been twofold: 1. To create an opportunity to secure the overall development of an investors active portfolio. 2. To create a profit by betting on different market developments between different actives/ passives of the same type. The achievement of the above was attained through varying long/short strategies in different areas. This could happen through buying and selling of assets, through futures, or through acquisition or issuance of options. It could also be through a combination of such contracts, including the conclusions of SWAP-deals1. In recent years the general fall in interest rates has led to a change of the business model of many hedge funds. Decreasing rates have on the one hand led to a large inflow of capital because the investors in hedge funds expected a higher return on investment than through traditional interest-rate-bearing products. On the other hand, the hedge funds have increasingly placed their investments in stocks instead of market-neutral, interest-rate-bearing assets. Many hedge funds have thereby become overexposed to investments in stocks, which can be seen from the fact that indices of share prices of investments in hedge funds have followed the developments of the international stock indices. This in turn has made hedge funds look more like the stock-based investment funds where the investment in stocks is complemented by some financial contracts. Lately the hedge funds have begun investing in more risk-prone interest-bearing products such as junk bonds, corporate bonds, and bonds from emerging markets. Although there is a difference between hedge funds and private equity funds in the sense that traditionally hedge funds are investing short-term without exercising ownership authority, whereas private equity funds are more likely to exercise ownership authority, we have in recent years seen a development where the two types of alternative investment funds have become more closely related. In a number of cases, hedge funds have been buying up stocks in publicly listed companies that have subsequently been bought by private equity funds. This is because hedge funds have been able to trace the specific companies most likely to be bought by private equity funds at a later stage. The placement of stocks in a hedge fund facilitates the acquisition by private equity funds, since the hedge funds is focusing on the short-term yield on stocks, and hence is more likely to sell to gain a quick return. The relation between the two types of funds also occurs after private equity funds have acquired a target company. The leveraged buyout funds increase the debt of the company in order to finance the acquisition, and hedge funds have been buying the corporate bonds, junks bonds etc. issued by the acquired company. The hedge funds invest in these bonds because they have a relatively higher interest rate due to the higher risk.
34
Among the above possible solutions we are drawn to definitions more related to the production side: the hedge funds are more a set of investment strategies and a specific business model than a set of products or a separate asset class. According to a recent occasional paper published by ECB the term hedge fund denotes a fund whose managers receive performance-related fees and can freely use various active investment strategies to achieve positive absolute returns, involving any combination of leverage, long and short positions in securities or any other assets in a wide range of markets2. Given the above production-related definition of the phenomenon we feel it right to stress the distinction between single strategy products and fund of (hedge) funds (FOHFs). Our desire to separate the single strategy landscape from the FOHFs is due to the differences between the two categories as far as production techniques, investment skills, localisation of business operations and leverage are concerned. The latter is focused on the selection of single strategy funds and so, generally speaking, is much less risky. It absorbs an incomparably lower level of leveraged capital (ideally zero), does not imply any kind of direct involvement in dealing financial instruments on the markets and mainly requires excellent relationship/networking inside the hedge fund community in order to have access to the best-performing and in-demand funds.
Typical hedge fund characteristics Investment strategies Position-taking in a wide range of markets. Free to choose various investment techniques and instruments, including short-selling, leverage and derivatives. Positive absolute returns under all market conditions. Usually managers also commit their own money, because preservation of capital is important. Typically a 2% management fee. And a 20% performance fee, often conditioned of a certain hurdle rate which must be exceeded before managers receive any performance fees. Predefined schedule with quarterly or monthly subscription and redemption. Lock-up periods for up to several years until first redemption. Offshore financial centres with low tax and a light touch regulatory regime, as well as some onshore financial centres. Private investment partnership that provides pass-through tax treatment or offshore investment corporation. May or may not be registered or regulated by financial supervisors. Managers serve as general partners in private partnership agreements. High net worth individuals and institutional investors (pension funds, insurance-institutions and others). Not widely available to the public. Securities issued take form of private placements. Generally minimal or no regulatory oversight due to their offshore residence or light touch approach by onshore regulators; exempted from many investor protection requirements. Voluntary or very limited (in many cases no) disclosure.
Return objective
Incentive structure
Subscription/Redemption
Domicile
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
Legal structure
Managers
Investor base
Regulation
Disclosure
ECB (8/2005), Hedge funds and their implications for financial stability, Tomas Garbarivicius and Franck Dierick.
35
Hedge funds have a structure similar to mutual funds in that they are both pooled investment vehicles that invest in publicly traded securities. There are, however, some important distinctions, when compared to the table Typical hedge funds characteristics: Mutual funds are highly regulated and restricted in the variety of investment options. Mutual funds are measured on relative performance such as a market index or other mutual funds. Hedge funds are expected to deliver absolute return. Mutual funds typically remunerate manager based on percent of assets under management. Hedge funds remunerate managers with very high fees that are geared to performance. Hedge funds make requirements on much larger minimum investments (average $1m) than mutual funds. Usually very little of the investment managers own money is invested in mutual funds. While mutual funds are available to the general public, hedge funds usually face many restrictions in selling their product3. *** One of the questions related to investor-protection is, whether a retailisation of hedge funds is under way? We can share the evidence recently highlighted by ECB researchers as follows: There is a trend towards the retailisation of hedge funds, and several European countries have recently permitted the distribution of hedge funds to retail investors, even though, compared to the traditional funds industry, retail investment in FOFH is still very small. Allowing hedge fund products to be distributed to retail investors raises specific investor protection concerns, such as inadequate disclosure, the risk of mis-buying and mis-selling, the lack of sufficient diversification, disproportionate management costs, etc. Some of these concerns can be addressed by only allowing certain variants of hedge funds to be commercialised, such as FOHFs or funds with capital protection. the United Kingdoms FSA concluded that there was no great desire on the part of the industry to produce and sell retail hedge fund products. However, more recently the FSA has indicated that it might re-examine the prohibition to sell hedge funds to retail investors. Germany, by contrast, adopted at the end of 2003 a new investment act that implemented a new legal framework for domestic hedge funds and the marketing of foreign funds in Germany. The new act explicitly distinguishes between single hedge funds and FOHFs. The former are hardly subject to any investment restrictions at all, whereas the latter are subject to more stringent restrictions, since they are the only hedge funds that can be distributed by public offer. For example, the latter are not allowed using leverage or short-selling, can only invest in single hedge funds, and are subject to certain diversification requirements. The development of regulations in France and Italy will be further considered in part III of this paper. *** Typically a single strategy HF operates though a very lean organisation. Apart from major players, managing a set of products or huge amount of money; it is rare to see an investment management organisation composed of more than 10 professionals. While the decision making, dealing in financial instruments and risk management are retained in the hedge fund itself, operational tasks are done mainly by external providers (prime brokers and others).
3
36
Onshore Offshore
Investors
Fund Administrator
Hedge Fund
Custodian
Prime Broker
Fund administrators (hedge fund managers). Some conduct all administration internally while others choose to outsource certain functions such as their accounting, investor services, risk analysis or performance measurement functions to third party administrators. Managers of offshore hedge funds typically rely on offshore administrators for various types of services and operational support. Prime brokers are firms offering brokerage and other professional services to hedge funds and other large institutional customers. This is a major growth area for investment banks, which are typical providers of such services. Rather than providing particular niche services prime brokers try to offer a diverse range of services including: financing, clearing and settlement of trades, custodial services, risk management and operational support facilities. The bulk of prime brokers income, however, comes from cash lending to support leverage and stock lending to facilitate short selling. London is Europes leading centre for prime brokerage services and accounts for more than 90% of its activity, as the largest investment banks are either headquartered or have a major office there. In Europe in January 2005, Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs were by far the largest prime brokers with 26% and 16% of the market. They were followed by CSFB, Deutsche Bank and Lehman Brothers. According to Tremont Tass the largest global providers of prime brokerage services include Morgan Stanley, Bear Stearns and Goldman Sachs. As can be seen, the European prime brokerage market is highly concentrated: The top six players control a 66% market share. Custodians. Hedge fund assets are generally held with a custodian, including cash in the fund as well as the actual securities. Custodians may also control flow of capital to meet margin calls. Auditors. Traditional investment funds are subject to auditing. By contrast most hedge funds are set up in a way that does not require them to have their financial statements audited. Some hedge funds however, may undergo annual audits if this is a part of the contract between the hedge fund and its investors. In addition, some offshore locations such as Bahamas and the Cayman Islands require hedge funds to have their accounts audited4. ***
The description of agents draws on International Financial Services (2006): HFs, City Business Series, March.
37
Hedge funds have flourished in a deregulated environment. In recent years, there has been increasing effort by regulators to try to, at least softly, regulate the industry nationally and to a limited extend internationally. So far national or domestic regulation of hedge funds has taken place at three levels: the level of the fund manager; the fund itself; and the distribution of funds. Based on domicile, hedge funds can be registered in offshore and onshore locations. Offshore hedge funds are registered in jurisdictions allowing investors to minimise their tax liabilities. Thus, hedge funds often do not pay any fiscal charge on the financial returns at the fund level. In addition, the jurisdictions are characterised by a deregulated environment where there are short authorisation periods in connection with the establishment of funds and constraints regarding investment policies are very limited. Offshore hedge funds are usually structured as corporations although they may sometimes be limited partnerships. Generally the number of investors is not restricted. Onshore hedge funds often set up a complementary offshore fund to attract additional capital without exceeding limits on the number of investors. According to HFR, as of 2005, 68% of single strategy products worldwide were domiciled offshore and only 32% onshore. According to data elaborated by the ECB (European Central Bank), the preferred off shore domicile was: Cayman Island 58%, BVI 20%, Bermuda 12% and Bahamas 4%. Onshore or domestic hedge funds are investment companies registered in an onshore location. Here the most popular locations are the US and within the EU the UK. Within the US and UK investment managers are usually domiciled in the most important financial districts, mainly New York and London. Historically, hedge fund managers in the US have not been subject to regular SEC (Securities and Exchange Commission) oversight. In October 2004, the SEC approved a rule change implemented in February 2006, which requires hedge fund advisers with more than 14 clients and $30 million in assets to register with the SEC as investment advisers under the Investment Advisers Act. Nearly 1,000 hedge fund managers had registered before February 2006. The measure, which requires hedge fund managers to disclose certain information about their operations, aims to protect investors and stabilise securities markets. *** In most European countries, fund managers are generally allowed to manage hedge fund products and both hedge fund and conventional fund managers operate under the same regulatory regime. Nonetheless, there are variations in the regulatory approach of EU member states. The UK is the most popular location in Europe for hedge funds, with an estimated European market share of around 73% based on AUM (assets under management) and 62% based on number of managers. One of the key drivers behind the growth of the hedge fund sector in the UK is the Investment Manager Exemption (IME). The IME essentially provides tax freedoms of funds based on a simple set of rules: A fund manager, based in the UK, will not bring a fund onshore for tax purposes, provided that overall policy and control of the fund rests outside the UK. UK/London based fund managers provide services to hedge funds, including consulting services such as advice on investment strategy and are therefore regulated by the Financial Services Authority (FSA). The FSA specifies the restrictions on sales and marketing of hedge fund products. Hedge fund products cannot be, for example, marketed to the general public but UK investors can deal directly with offshore funds. Towards the end of 2005 the FSA created an internal team to supervise the management of 25 so-called high impact hedge funds doing business within the UK.
38
This view is confirmed if we relate hedge funds to traditional mutual funds (UCITS). As of 2005 traditional mutual funds (UCITS) globally managed $ 17.771 bn9 with very modest or no growth. This compares to then $ $800-1.000 bn AUM of hedge funds growing rapidly (see above). In other words, hedge funds already manage assets amounting to at least 8-11% of the amount of capital managed by traditional mutual funds.
5 One prominent HF database is the Trading Advisors Selection System (TASS) which is managed by Tremont Capital Management Ltd. The database business has recently been sold to Lipper a worldwide well known provider of data and metrics concerning traditional (long only) asset management. TASS database is used in order to calculate the CSFB/Tremont HF indices. TASS database covers almost 80% of the global single strategy HF industry. For a detailed analysis of the database issue in the HFs field it could be useful to refer at the already mentioned occasional paper published by the ECB (8/2005), HFs and their implications for financial stability, Tomas Garbarivicius and Franck Dierick. 6 7
HF Research (HFR) is a prominent database managed by HF Research INC. The database stores the data concerning more than 6,400 HFs worldwide. HFR on a periodic base provides a wide range of HFs performance indexes according with an internal classification along the different investment styles. For more information see www.hedgefundresearch.com. Our calculations based on Eurostat. The figures include expenditures on R&D financed by the industry, by governments and from abroad. Source FEFSI.
8 9
39
The European hedge fund industry is growing fast. To provide a rough picture it could be useful to refer to some 2004 UBS research: As of December 2003, 298 hedge fund managers domiciled in Europe were managing around $ 125 bn, i.e., around 15% of the global assets under management of $ 817 bn. The growth rate of the European hedge fund industry between 1995 and 2002 was around 50%, albeit from a very low base. The United Kingdom is the dominant location with market share of around 73% based on AUM and 62% based on number of managers. Strategies related to equity are dominant. European long/short equity had a market share of 36% based on managers and 30% based on AUM. The largest 10 managers have a 33% market shares. It should also be signalled that: since 2003 the growth of European single manager hedge funds has continued to reach $ 256 bn AUM, according to EuroHedge data as of 2005 BoY; the weight, on an AUM basis, of offshore domiciles in the case of European single strategy hedge funds managers is only slightly lower than that prevailing worldwide: 61% versus 65%; the preferred offshore domiciles for European single strategy hedge funds are: Cayman Island, BVI and Bermuda; the prime manager location is London, the next Paris: managers domiciled here drive more than 80% by AUM of the European hedge fund industry
*** It is important to note the increasing relevance of FOHFs, which hold a portfolio of other HFs rather than investing directly themselves. Historically investors, private and institutional, invested directly in HFs. But since 2000 FOHFs compound annual growth rate has been around 36%, compared to 11% growth in the direct access funds. Today FOHFs own almost one third of hedge funds AUM, more than doubling its weight in the last 5 years. An important reason for this dynamic is a growth in demand for FOHF products by smaller and medium sized investors, not least investors based in countries where the offering of such products to the public has only recently been permitted. Given the low amount of public information available, few retail investors have the capabilities to research the market, let alone the expertise to determine the blend of managers and strategies that will provide the risk-return profile they are looking for. Consequently, such investors are prone to channel investments through the intermediary FOHFs.
1.200
Direct access
1.000
36%
800
600
400
200
40
Europes share of FOHFs total market is around 40% based on the location of FOHFs managers, and 49% based on the location of the parent of FOHFs managers.
1996
10% 5%
7%
2005
7%
12%
16%
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
In combination, the figures on institutional investments and FOFHs are likely to reflect a growing readiness among institutional investors to consider non-traditional strategies of investments, using derivatives and leverage in order to achieve their investment targets. A study by State Street HF Research Study confirms this view. Thus, it finds that one-third of institutional investors surveyed in 2004 had at least 10% of their portfolios in hedge funds, while half intend to have 10% or more invested by 2007.
41
Institutional investors Current and forecast mean strategic allocations to hedge funds
12% 11,4%
10%
8%
7,1%
6%
5,3% 4,5%
4% 2,5% 2% 1,7%
3,6%
0%
North America
2001
Source: Russel Research
Europe
2003 2005 2007 Forecast
Japan
Taking the 2005 Russell Survey on Alternative Investing as a proxy for institutional investors behaviour we estimate the allocated capital to hedge funds ranges from 5% to 8%, with differences from country to country. This may be underestimating the real size, due to higher investments from pension funds in FOHF. European investors are currently the least exposed to hedge funds and Japanese the most. In all areas since 2001 the allocation has grown impressively at percentage increases ranging from +80% in Japan to +212% in Europe. The medium term trend is oriented toward a further exposure to hedge funds at growth rates ranging from +18% (Japan) to +40% (Europe) in three years time.
4%
61%
60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0%
74%
35%
26%
North America
Single Funds
Source: Russel Research
Europe
Funds of Funds Internally managed
42
The Russell Survey also hints at the attitude of institutional investors towards FOHFs. In North America approximately 60% of institutional hedge investments are carried out through FOHFs, 74% in Europe. These figures confirm the assumption that nowadays FOHFs represent the preferred way of institutional investors, perhaps a specific cluster of them, to gain an access to the hedge industry. On this point the prevailing view is that institutional investors lacking investment and analysis skills and bounded by significant P&L constraints (particularly the smaller ones) prefer to outsource the hedge funds selection to the specialised professional managers of FOHFs. It goes without saying, that in practice, there will be an upper limit for FOFHs share of allocated capital by definition they cannot all be FOHF!
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
43
Funds of hedge funds (FOHFs) invest in a number of other hedge funds and are expected to have lower volatility and attractive risk-adjusted returns due to diversification benefits. On the grounds of the data provided by the TASS database, we can conclude that: The role of hedge funds in the corporate field is relevant and has increased throughout the last fifteen years. Long short equity, Event driven, Equity market neutral and Convertible Arbitrage are strategies exclusively focused on corporate financial instruments like ordinary shares, convertible bonds, corporate bonds and derivatives having the same instruments as underlying asset. In aggregate terms these strategies represent approximately 60% of the sector. By now pure futures trading, generally based on technical trading system and the top-down approach implemented by Global Macro, dealing with derivatives (option and futures on equity indices or government bond baskets) are only a minor, almost marginal, sub sector of the hedge funds industry. The most recent trend prevailing in the industry is the aggressive growth of Multi Strategy funds which try to diversify and swing dynamically, according to a direct disciplined risk management approach, among different strategies. Despite the differences of the strategies presented above, some common concerns must be taken into account. There can be bandwagon effects due to the crowding of hedgee fund trades using similar strategies entailing higher correlations of hedge fund returns with the extensive use of leverage. Also, some of the massive interventions of hedge funds on the market have clearly had a negative effect on its functioning, as they dont increase liquidity or contribute to price equilibrium, thereby denying their so-called market-efficiency promoter role. A tendency becoming clearer during recent years is that the differences between the traditional fund management industry (incl. investment banks) and hedge funds seem to narrow. There is a tendency to start using investment techniques similar to hedge funds.
44
Based on Greenwich Associates findings, we can assume that hedge funds pay approximately 30 per cent of all equity trading commissions in the US. This, and similar information on the European side, confirm our beliefs that hedge funds are important client groups for investment banks. But the lack of disclosure by the banks makes it difficult to quantify. Based on accessible reports and data estimates we can approximate the importance of hedge fund activities for the investment banks they derive about 15-20 percent of their revenues from hedge fund activities. Similar, recent information confirms that investment banks are purchasing more hedge funds. Information from 2006 confirms, for example, that Morgan Stanley increased its minority positions and total acquisitions in hedge funds in 2006. There are several examples of this activity confirming that banks through their investments in direct hedge fund industry are snapping up managers of hedge funds to meet increasing demand for these types of investment. Investment bank business with hedge funds is often first and foremost associated with prime brokerage. But the interrelations are much more complex linked to other sources of revenue such as bid ask spreads from trading commissions etc. All in all, the tendency for the behaviour of hedge funds and investment banks to become increasingly similar, raises the question of regulation. When it comes to banks, the actual regulation and need for updating on a regular basis is not questioned. The central argument is the externalities. Ordinary banks are regulated to protect their depositors. The argument for regulating investment banks is to protect investors in securities markets. And the central argument for regulation is, after all, that any serious malfunction of the banking and securities market could create serious systematic consequences for the real economy, for jobs, for investments, for growth. If there is a case for systemic risks connected to the hedge fund industry and there seems to be, as we shall see later it creates a further argument for claims of disclosure, transparency and regulations as in the case of commercial banks and investment banks.
The level of management fee on average is currently around 1.5% of AUM in the case of single strategy products and reduced to 1% for FOHFs. As far as performance fees are concerned, those paid on single strategy products are higher than for FOHFs: 25% on average in the former and 10% in the latter. According to a UBS top-down analysis: The global aggregated amount of fees generated by the hedge fund industry in 2004 has been in the region of $ 45 Bn. 90% ($ 41 bn) of the above amount rewarded single hedge fund managers and the last 10% ($ 4 bn) those of FOHFs. As we can see, the fees are huge relative to other forms of asset management.
45
If we assume US mutual fund industry to be around $ 7.000 bn and the average management fee to be 0.60%, the aggregate gross fee income would be (simplifying to the extreme) around $ 42 bn. In other words, it is not entirely unthinkable that the global hedge funds industry is generating more fees than the much larger US mutual fund industry. But this is not the total picture. Some studies estimate that hedge funds pay: 4-5 % of AUM to their managers (management fees plus performance) Around 4 % of AuM to the investment banking industry To maintain this pay-out and keep investors confident and satisfied, hedge funds need growth returns of around 20 %! This fee structure and the level is not a law of nature. Neither is it market based. It simply seems to be a characteristic of the hedge fund industry and not questioned or challenged by anyone. We think it highly questionable because the pressure of hedge funds to create such huge gross returns is in itself having strong effects on the character and concrete content of hedge fund strategies. The impact of fees and transaction costs to hedge funds, investment banks, prime brokers and trading counter parties is illustrated in a recent study (Dresdner/Kleinwort. Equity research. February 2007). As seen from the two charts, the net return to investors on the right hand side represents the HFR composite index return net of all fees. By adding the 2 % plus 20 % fee structure, the gross performance after execution costs is reached. If we then add the execution costs, we are having the gross performance before execution costs. A recent paper from Dresdner Kleinwort illustrates this point11 :
Hedge fund industry from gross return to net return
(%) 25 20 15 10 5 0
Gross performance Execution cost Gross performance before execution received by investment after execution cost cost banks Fees paid to hedge fund managers Net performance to investors
22.5
2006
(%) 25 20 15
17.0
3.8
13.1
4.3 18.8
2005
10 5 0
Gross performance Execution cost Gross performance before execution received by investment after execution cost cost banks Fees paid to hedge fund managers Net performance to investors
46
Dresdner Kleinwort, Credit Suisse, Deutsche Bank, UBS - How important are hedge funds for the investment banking industry?, Equity Research 6. February 2007, p.16.
Whether or not these fees and transaction costs are sustainable in the middle or the longer run will depend critically on at least two factors: How can the industry sustain the necessary gross performance of around 20 %? Are investors confident and satisfied with the net return to them from the hedge fund industry? The size and high growth of hedge funds are in themselves creating new problems for ensuring growth returns by ingenious stock picking or niche investment strategies. That is why we in our understanding of the hedge fund industry will make a link with the well-known, high leverage phenomenon. For many funds employ long/short strategies removing market risks which are essentially spread or arbitrage bets with a relative low return. So the only remaining way to boost returns to the necessary growth returns of around 20 % is to employ extensive leverage.
Older hedge funds, perhaps managed by more experienced mangers, tend to be more leveraged than new ones and also the largest single hedge funds (greater than $ 1 bn) tend to exhibit higher levels of leverage. It would be possible to argue that hedge funds could be on one side the object (as far as the growth of its AUM is concerned) and on the other side the drivers (as far as its performance and leverage size are concerned) of a possible virtuous / vicious circle related to the interest rate dynamic. As we have seen, the low interest rate in recent years has in itself been a driver to the expansion of the hedge fund industry. In a very low interest rate landscape it is highly possible that: the appetite of investors for risk and performance is greater than those granted by the risk free instruments (cash and short term bonds). This would push towards an increase of the assets gathered by the hedge funds;
12 13
IFSL 83/2006), Hedge Funds City Business Series. ECB (8/2005), Hedge funds and their implications for financial stability, Tomas Garbarivicius and Franck Dierick.
47
the hedge funds themselves would benefit from comparatively better financing conditions, increasing leverage and the possibility to attain better financial returns. Such a virtuous circle would be completely reversed in a justifiably higher interest rate scenario. Assuming the above hypothesis one could see a boom and bust cycle among hedge funds following major movements of the interest rate structure. The recent increase of investors appetite for hedge funds can be at least in part explained by the present extremely positive positioning of the interest rate structure. So, despite the boom and bust hypothesis to be verified, one has to consider the possible threat to the financial stability provided by the hedge funds in the case of a major, global increase of interest rates. As we will see from the evaluation of the trend in hedge fund industry returns, there is evidence that it is downward. This is in itself creating further pressure on the leverage of the industry. Together with the continued growth of hedge funds, leverage will be increasingly important to continue squeezing high double-digit growth ROE (= Return On AUM) out of low-ROA investment strategies. An increasing dependency on leverage could pose serious challenges for absolute return investment and the risk of the vicious circle. It is not easy to get an idea on the state of leveraged hedge funds owing to lack of disclosure. But estimates from different studies shed some light on the issue. Looking at the most used types of leverage relevant for hedge funds: margin loans, securities lending, reverse repos and derivatives, there seems to be basis for an estimate of the following magnitude: Margin loans: In 2005 with all the necessary, reasonable assumptions given lack of disclosure it is estimated that global margin debt of hedge funds could be roughly $300 b. Securities lending: Assuming that hedge funds are probably the only customer group that has a structural demand for securities borrowing and taking a 40 % ratio as the representative for the industry, securities lending to hedge funds could amount to roughly $500 b. Reverse repos: This leverage activity is not only used by hedge funds, but by many other customer groups as well. A reasonable guess would be that 20 % of all reverse repos are with hedge funds; this creates a volume of hedge funds at 120 b US dollars. Derivatives: This is, based on all accessible studies, the most important source of leverage. Leverage in a derivative comes from entering into a contract with a relatively large notional value in that context there is only a need to have sufficient cash available to meet the initial collateral margin. The notional value of the derivatives book is likely to overstate its economic risk. All in all, it could be estimated that total hedge fund industry debt including the derivatives is between 150 and 250 % of AUM, i.e. 2.0 3.3 trn US dollars. Within this estimate extreme cases like LTCM are well known. According to the Financial Times (1.12.06) the balance sheet of Citadels two main funds show that the leverage (=liabilities/shareholders funds) amounted to 11.5 times. This is an example of ground breaking ability to access capital markets for unsecured debt and thereby putting rising pressure on the collateralised lending of investment banks. A majority of hedge funds have limited choices for boosting returns and extensive leverage is one of those. Think LTCM!
48
49
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
management fees? It is a fact that some financial authorities recently have handed out fines to investment banks and hedge funds over market abuse. In particular with credit default swaps (CDSS) there are problems with the relevant information available to the administrators. From national financial authorities we can deduce that some managers have exerted pressure on administrators to manipulate evaluations, creating inflated returns and artificial fees. From the investor side it seems unclear as to who is responsible for providing market evaluation. The impact of these problems and conflicts of interest has led to pricing errors. There are examples showing that investors are paying inflated prices on subscriptions and later on finding out that funds have been making substantial losses, masked by inflated valuations. For some investors this has created substantial losses also connected to situations where office controls are weak and administrative mistakes are detected too late. In recent years, where equity markets have been stable, combined with low interest rates, it has been relatively easy for the banks to manage these situations without exposing too high levels of risks. But now, stock markets are becoming more volatile again, pushing the banks to comply, to readjust their positions in accordance to the internal risk management rules. This process is further under pressure because the speed at which the banks need to adjust increases as the market becomes more volatile. As we can see this is another example of the self-reinforcing nature of these trends, running the risk of market problems. National and international financial authorities have become conscious of the necessity of closer monitoring financial stability forum FSA, MAF etc. Growing concerns focus on the risk of inadequate evaluation of illiquid and complex assets that are held in various proportions by hedge funds, as we have seen. As is stated by the French national authorities, in cases of bad performance or where bonuses are based on the managers absolute performance, careless evaluation of the positions held may prove very, very tempting. The difficulties in evaluating these assets and previous experience underlines the need for developing appropriate standard procedures in this area of hedge fund evaluation among all concerned parties: Prime brokers, depositaries, the auditor and the manager. The use of derivatives and the enormous growth in these credit-oriented assets have also given rise to concerns in the European Central Bank. A recent paper by researchers says that these derivatives are used for speculation as well as hedging: We have introduced a new product, Insurance, which appears to be used by people not looking for insurance. It is not the instrument, which is causing liquidity concerns, but the way market participants may be using them. Our analysis is that these concerns are well-founded.
50
The international financial authorities are not offering clear answers. Anyhow, for the sake of clarity we must distinguish between taxation of the fund and taxation of the fund manager. The broad majority of funds are located outside the EU chiefly for the reason of tax minimisation with the consequence of tax losses for the EU region. This loss of income cannot be avoided by ensuring that managers pay the correct amount of tax for their on-shore activities. It is a complex challenge to try to enhance efforts to protect tax revenues for Europes welfare societies given the international character of hedge funds and private equity funds. It is not impossible there can be a case for coordinated actions among member states. But a condition of a more efficient approach will be higher transparency and disclosure.
Investment objective Convertible Arbitrage Dedicated Short Bias Emerging Markets Equity Market Neutral Event Driven Fixed Income Arbitrage Global Macro Managed Futures Long Short Equity Multi-Strategy Hedge Fund S&P 500 NASDAQ
Excess of Return 2,8% -7,3% 2,5% 3,8% 5,2% 0,3% 7,0% -0,1% 5,4% 3,1% 4,4% 4,3% 2,6%
Tracking Error 6,5% 17,1% 17,3% 5,3% 7,7% 5,8% 10,9% 11,3% 11,1% 6,9% 8,6% 15,6% 27,4%
Information Ratio
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
0,42% -0,43% 0,15% 0,71% 0,67% 0,06% 0,64% 0,00% 0,49% 0,44% 0,51% 0,28% 0,09%
51
These data notwithstanding, several commentators have criticised the claims made for hedge funds. Historically hedge funds have been a niche sector focused on specialised investment strategies that worked reasonably for a given limited amount of invested capital. The current growth of their AUM sparked by low interest rates could put at risk in the future ability to provide investors with the high financial returns promised in their marketing. Other commentators argue that the performance of hedge funds is overestimated already. For example, the investment bank Barclays Capital put the typical level of overstatement of returns at 1 6 per cent a year, depending on the index14. A recent study by the renowned Princeton professor Berton Malkiel and Atanu Saha reached a similar conclusion15. The study identifies a number of biases that exist in the published indices of hedge fund returns, biases that lead claims about investment performance to be overstated. Analysis produced by Vanguard Investments, which adjusted the annual returns of the Tremont HF index for the biases identified in Malkiel and Sahas study, suggests that hedge funds produced returns well below those achieved by a simple portfolio of 50% bonds and 50% equities over the entire period, as well as when segmented into bull (1995-1999) and bear (2000-2002) equity markets16.
Average annual returns 1994-2003 Tremont HF index: returns without Malkiel-Saha adjustment Tremont HF index: returns with Malkiel-Saha adjustment 50% Dow Jones Wilshire 5000/ 50% Lehman Aggregate 11.11 2.32 9.30 1995-1999 18.16 9.37 17.41 2000-2002 4.09 -4.66 -2.10 2003 15.47 6.72 17.93
What reasons may there be for such an overstatement of hedge fund performance? According to Malkiel and Saha the key reasons relate to biases that they call backfill, selection and survivorship bias. Furthermore, there are additional reasons related to the lack of persistence of returns and the relatively high attrition rates amongst hedge funds. Below we describe these reasons in greater detail. Backfill and selection bias: hedge funds are often established with seed-capital and will begin reporting on their results at a later date. Yet, backfill and selection bias can occur because hedge fund managers are able to fill back only the most favourable investment returns into an index. This can result in returns being overstated. According to the study by Malkiel and Saha backfilled returns significantly bias the returns upwards. The arithmetic mean of the backfilled returns over the period 1994-2003 was 11.69%, while the mean for the contemporaneously reported returns was 5.95% a difference of 5.74%. Survivorship bias can occur because the published indices may not include the returns from hedge funds no longer in existence (known as dead funds), or funds that exist but no longer report their results (defunct funds). Malkiel and Saha examined the effect of this survivorship
14 15
Malkiel, B. G./Saha, A. (2005): HFs: Risk and Return, Financial Analysts Journal, Volume 61, Number 6, CFA Institute. The study draws on the TASS database.
16
52
bias by comparing the annual returns achieved by live funds with a universe of live and defunct funds over the period 1996-2003. They found that the arithmetic mean of the annual returns of the live funds was 13.74% for the period whereas the arithmetic mean for all the funds (live and defunct) was 9.32% a difference of 4.42%. Naturally, all indices face problems with survivorship bias. However, Malkiel and Saha report that survivorship bias produced an overstatement of returns of 1.23% in mutual funds, compared to the 4.42% for hedge funds17. Risk, volatility and attrition rates: In the past, hedge funds tended to exhibit low standard deviations (volatility) and correlation with general equity indices offering significant potential for risk diversification. However, there appears to be a greater volatility in cross-sectional distribution of returns risk, i.e. a great risk of choosing a poor performing fund. Thus, Malkiel and Saha examined the cross-sectional standard deviation of different hedge fund categories over the period 1996-2003. They found that the standard deviation of their returns is considerably higher than it for mutual funds. In addition, Malkiel and Saha noted that the so called attrition rates the proportion of funds that fail to survive were three or four times higher than for mutual funds over the period 1994-2003. In other words, the range of returns is much wider so while investors may face high rewards for selecting top-performing funds, they also face a high risk of picking a bad performer or a failing one. Assuming that hedge fund performance is overstated, what are factors in the current growth? We cannot ignore the fact that some hedge funds have delivered impressive investment returns. In addition, they do offer significant potential for risk diversification. However, we also believe that there are other important reasons for the current growth of AUM. Two relate to matters that we will deal with in greater detail in other parts of the report, so we will just briefly touch upon them here: the high performance fees paid to hedge fund managers and the likelihood of lower regulation and taxes. In traditional investment funds, managers typically charge a management fee for their services but do not take any profits. Hedge fund managers, by contrast, generally charge two fees: management fees, averaging 1.5%, and performance fees, averaging 25% of the net profits (see section 2.10). The high performance fees make it attractive to set them up. In other words, explanations for the rapid growth in AUM by hedge funds should also be sought on the supply side. In addition, the performance fee issue underlines the importance of calculating returns by HFs net of the (often very high) performance fees something that many publicly available statistics do not do.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
Hitherto, low regulation and/or tax exemptions appear to have provided another important impetus to the growth of AUM by hedge funds, particularly the assets managed by offshore funds. Offshore funds are unregistered pooled investment funds domiciled in offshore centres like the Cayman Islands or the Virgin Islands. They are usually structured in a way that allows them to avoid various portfolio management restrictions that apply to registered funds. This might, for instance, be the case in terms of the use of leverage. In addition, offshore funds are likely to pay no tax, or much lower tax than both registered and unregistered domestic funds. Above, we showed how traditional institutional investors allocate ever more funds to hedge funds. As a result hedge fund managers may be facing new choices: would they align themselves with the large asset managers, who act as a distribution channel to institutional money and therefore seek to comply with the institutions demands for transparency, strong governance and a robust operating environment? Or, would they choose to remain focused on the rich individuals and endowments, which allow more flexibility in the standards and often also the locality of operations? Given the size of traditional institutional investors, some managers are likely to choose the former option, thereby increasing the reach of existing regulations regarding traditional investment funds.
17
53
54
It goes without saying that effective monitoring of market abuse, asset assessment, accountability, early warning etc. is simply not possible without transparency. In his prize lecture (Information and the change in the paradigm economics, December 8, 2001) when receiving the Nobel prize in economics, Professor Joseph E. Stiglitz shows that information economics represents a fundamental change in the prevailing paradigm within economics. As we know from our economic history, the micro and macro economic theories have for years focused much more on the functioning of perfect market mechanisms than the imperfect markets, although we all know that in the real world, imperfect markets are more widespread. As Stiglitz underlines, the world is, of course, more complicated than our simple or even more complicated models would suggest. In the past couple of decades many major economic political debates have centred on the question: The efficiency of the market economy and the appropriate relationship between the market and the government. This debate has new importance considering the enormous influence on the financial markets of the hedge fund industry and private equity funds. In his Nobel prize lecture Stiglitz makes observations highly relevant to our study of the development of the modern financial markets: In a section on The theory of corporate finance, he says, Under the older, perfect information theory, it made no difference whether firms raised capital by debt or equity, in the absence of tax distortions. This was the central insight of the Modigliani-Miller theorem. We have noted how the willingness to hold (or to sell) shares conveys information, so that how firms raise capital does make a difference. Firms rely heavily on debt finance, and bankruptcy, resulting from the failure to meet debt obligations, matters. Both because of the cost of bankruptcies and limitations in the design of managerial incentive schemes, firms act in a risk averse manner with the risk being more than just correlation with the business cycle. Moreover, with credit rationing (or the potential of credit rationing) not only does the firms net worth (the market value of its assets) matter, but so does its asset structure, including its liquidity. While there are many implications of the theory of the risk averse firm facing credit rationing, some of which are elaborated upon in the next section, one example should suffice to highlight the importance of these ideas. Corporate governance: In the traditional theory, firms simply maximised the expected present discounted value of profits (which equalled market value) and with perfect information, how that was to be done was simply an engineering problem. Disagreements about what the firm should do were of little moment. In that context, corporate governance how firm decisions were made mattered little as well. But again, in reality, corporate governance matters a great deal. There are disagreements about what the firm should do partly motivated by differences in judgements, partly motivated by differences in objectives. Managers can take actions which advance their interests at the expense of that of shareholders, and majority shareholders can advance their interests at the expense of minority shareholders. The owners not only could not monitor their workers and managers, because of asymmetries of information, they typically did not even know what these people who were supposed to be acting on their behalf should do. That there were important consequences for the theory of the firm of the separation of ownership and control had earlier been noted by Berle and Means (1932)
55
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
Theory of money: In modern economies, however, credit, not money is required (and used) for most transactions, and most transactions are simply exchanges of assets, and therefore not directly related to GDP. Moreover, today, most money is interest bearing, with the difference between the interest rate paid, say on a money market account and T bill rates having little to do with monetary policy, and related solely to transactions costs. What is important is the availability of credit (and the terms at which it is available); this in turn is related to the certification of creditworthiness by banks and other institutions. In short, information is at the heart of monetary economics. But banks are like other risk-averse firms: their ability and willingness to bear the risks associated with making loans depends on their net worth. Because of equity rationing, shocks to their net worth cannot be instantaneously undone, and the theory thus explains why such shocks can have large adverse macro-economic consequences. The theory shows how not only traditional monetary instruments (like reserve requirements) but regulatory instruments (like risk adjusted capital adequacy requirements) can be used to affect the supply of credit, interest rates charge, and the banks risk portfolio. The analysis also showed how excessive reliance on capital adequacy requirements could be counterproductive. We also analysed the importance of credit interlinkages. Many firms receive credit from other firms, at the same time that they provide credit to still others. The dispersed nature of information in the economy provides an explanation of this phenomenon, which has important consequences. As a result of these general interlinkages (in some ways, every bit as important as the commodity interlinkages stressed in standard general equilibrium analysis) a shock to one firm gets transmitted to others, and when there is a large enough shock, there can be a cascade of bankruptcies. What does all this imply for growth and thereby wealth creation in our societies? What are then the implications of imperfections of credit markets arising out of information problems asymmetric information on growth? Joseph Stiglitz gives the answer himself: The importance of capital markets for growth has long been recognised; without capital markets firms have to rely on retained earnings. But how firms raise capital is important for their growth. As we see it, this is in essence the set of theories showing how fundamental the interplay is between the real economy and the financial markets and how important it is to enhance transparency to limit the negative effects of asymmetric information on the capital markets. This is, as we see it, a fundamental but not necessarily sufficient part of a coherent new strategy to ensure the real economy and our European ambition as stated in the European Council, 2000 in Lisbon. It is about more and better jobs, it is about investment in research and development, it is about education and competence, it is about long-term strategies to guarantee the real economy as the precondition for our welfare societies in the age of globalisation.
56
Country
Manager authorization
Product regulation
United Kingdom
FSA (Listing Authority) Not requested There is no FSA authorization specific category to manage or of authorized advice a UK-listed onshore FOHFs, company but such product investing in have typically hedge funds been structured as UK listed companies BaFin Diversification limits (not more than 20% BaFin invested in a Minimum single product) capital equal to Investment 730,000 + a % manager and of AUM custodian bank are required to be located and regulated in Germany
Nil
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
Germany
Yes
Nil
Equal to UCITS fund, but in Germany both UCITS and Hedge funds to be tax transparent have to meet some transparency requirements
Continued on page 58
57
Country
Manager authorization
Product regulation
France
AMF Minimum capital requirement equal to the greater between 25% of annualized expenditure 125,000 + 0.02% of AUM > 250 Mln Bank of Italy Specialized asset management company is required Minimum capital requirement ( 1 Mln) CNMV 300,000 + a % of AUM and income generated by investment activity
AMF Max leverage (200%) Diversification Yes limits (Min 16 underlying funds) Required the appointment of a depositary bank Bank of Italy / CONSOB No specific diversification limits Required the appointment of a depositary bank CNMV Diversification limits to be qualified Required the appointment of a depositary bank
Transparency
Italy
500,000
Transparency
Spain
Subject to the full introduction of the new regulatory framework
Yes
Nil
Transparency
Country
Manager authorization
Product regulation
United Kingdom
FSA FSA Qualified Own funds of Investors 50,000 plus Funds with 3 months annual- no specific ized expenditure investment constraint
Only private Ranging Equal to UCITS placement from 250 funds (transto qualified to 250,000 parency) investors
Favorable versus non resident offshore funds, but pension funds investors are tax exempt on both
Continued on page 59
58
Country
Manager authorization
Product regulation
Germany
BaFin No specific investment BaFin constraint Minimum Investment capital equal to manager and 730,000 + a % custodian bank of AUM are required to be located and regulated in Germany AMF Three different categories of products with different investment constraints, among them only contractual funds do not forecast any kind of investment constraint. Required the appointment of a depositary bank Bank of Italy / CONSOB No specific investment constraints Required the appointment of a depositary bank
Only private placement to qualified investors. Possibility to distribute Nil single strategy funds via wrapper products
Equal to UCITS funds, but in Germany both UCITS and Hedge funds to be tax transparent have to meet some transparency requirements
France
AMF Minimum capital requirement equal to the greater between 25% of annualized expenditure 125,000 + 0.02% of AUM > 250 Mln
Ranging from Equal to 10,000 UCITS funds to 30,000 (transparency) for qualified investors
Italy
Bank of Italy Specialized asset management company is required Minimum capital requirement ( 1 Mln)
500,000
Transparency
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
Spain
Subject to the full introduction of the new regulatory framework
59
Considering single strategy products regulators in the main European countries seem oriented to substantially limit the distribution of such funds on the retail segment. As far as fiscal treatment is concerned, on one side, the common aim of fiscal Laws has been to inspire the taxation of domestic onshore vehicles to a principle of fiscal transparency and, on another one, to discriminate offshore vehicles domiciled in the main fiscal heavens. It has anyway to be signalled that the effectiveness of such policy is in part undermined by the tax exemption granted to some kind of institutional investors (for instance UK pension funds).
60
Insufficient supervision of operational risks and insufficient internal control. This is the question of inadequate validation of illiquid and complex assets held by hedge funds. Mis-selling of the sale of inappropriate alternative projects to insufficiently informed clients. Hedge funds have shown very impressive growth over recent years and have developed into a very important alternative investment instrument for good and sadly also for the less good. The international character of the hedge fund industry and its unregulated nature, challenges our societies and authorities. The possible implications of hedge funds for the stability of the financial systems are not only a problem for the hedge funds the far-reaching consequences in case of a risk being realised will hit corporate industries, employment, and investments as well as pensioners savings. All in all, there is a central argument for reducing risks associated with the increasing role of hedge funds in the financial system. Given the case for regulating banks and investment banks and other financial actors we must ask why should hedge funds and private equity be any exception? Given the readiness to reforms labour markets in all European macro economies as well as our goods markets why should the new developments of the financial markets around hedge funds and private equity be exempted? We can summarise this part of our analysis by saying there is a strong case for demanding transparency and disclosure and a strong case for some sort of incentives/regulations to ensure against systemic risks, market abuse, risk to the governance of listed companies, risk of poor asset evaluation, and protecting insufficiently informed investors.
61
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
19
62
Lets look at different types of Private Equity: Venture capital is focused on young, entrepreneurial companies and is an essential part of value creation in the whole private equity financing cycle. It provides finance for start-ups- at their inception or shortly after their first technical or commercial developments. Much of this segment is technology-related e.g. new information and communication technologies, life sciences and healthcare, electronics and new materials industries. Investments are often in individual minority shareholdings with a number of venture capital funds investing alongside each other in successive rounds of financing. The investors are closely involved in determining the investee companys strategy, hiring key employees, organising the search for further financial resources and negotiating partnerships with larger corporations. Venture capital includes: Seed: financing provided to fund research, assess and develop an initial concept before a business has reached the start-up phase. Start-up companies: financing provided to companies for product development and initial marketing. Companies may be in the process of being set up or been in business for a short time, but have not sold their product commercially. Early stage companies: financing to companies that have completed the product development stage and require further funds to initiate commercial manufacturing and sales. They will not yet be generating a profit. In later stage expansion capital finance is provided to purchase holdings in existing, generally profitable companies by subscribing new capital (as equity or quasi-equity). Investee companies here have growth profiles that necessitate the consolidation of their financial structures e.g. to develop new products or services, set up a foreign subsidiary, make an acquisition or increase their capacity. Expansion capital includes: Expansion (as such): financing provided for the growth and expansion of an operating company, which may or may not be breaking even or trading profitably. Capital may be used to finance increased production capacity, marketing or product development. Bridge financing: financing made available to a company in the period of transition from being privately owned to being publicly quoted. Rescue/Turnaround: financing made available to existing businesses, which have experienced trading difficulties, with a view to re-establishing prosperity.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
63
Buy-outs are typically majority investments made in companies together with the existing management (a management buy-out or MBO) or with a new management team (management buy-in or MBI). These normally use sophisticated financial techniques that involve bank financing and debt financing. Opportunities for buy-outs are created from the sale of familyowned businesses; the sale of a non-core subsidiary by a large corporation; taking a listed company private, typically a company underpriced by the stock market; and sale by financial shareholders. Buy-out funds do not focus on any one industry, though many managers have sector specialities. Buy-out capital includes: Management buy-out: financing provided to enable current operating management and investors to acquire existing product line or business. Management buy-in: financing provided to enable a manager or a group of managers from outside the company to buy-in to the company with the support of private equity investors. Leverage buy-out: financing provided to acquire a company, by using a significant amount of borrowed money to meet the cost of acquisition. None of these activities are transparent. *** An LBO typically involves the following three steps: The investors form a company (often a limited company) which borrows the capital to acquire the shares in the target company; i.e. the acquiring company is typically heavily financed by borrowed capital. The investors acquire the target company. The target company is merged with the newly formed company. The purpose of this multi-stage acquisition process is to give creditors security rights to the assets of the target company. Given the short-term nature of the commitment, the creditors are often willing to do without securities and/or to provide loans which rank below those of other creditors. Since there is greater risk attached to these secondary loans, they are often provided with debtor warrants. In a number of cases, where the merger is based on real economic concerns for the future of the company, there may be constructive results. However, as Part II of this report will detail, we often see a clear asset stripping of the company acquired, with major detriment not only to its debt level, but often also to its employees and investment capability including in R&D and long-term survival of the company. Buyout funds purchase business divisions or a whole, big eventually listed company. Then they change the liquidity / capital structure immediately, with the aim of realising the added value created by selling the business on to an industrial buyer or to other financial investors20. Unfortunately this strategy of creating added value goes too often hand in hand with short-termism, and its negative consequences in terms of business management and competition. The buyer generally finances the purchase of the company with the companys own equity. The LBO only ever uses its own money to a small degree, if at all. In other words, the majority of the funding is borrowed. This enables it to make use of the so-called leverage effect: it is the difference between return on equity and return on capital employed21. Leverage effect explains how it is possible for a company to deliver a return on equity exceeding the rate of return on all the capital invested in the business, i.e. its return on capital employed. However, there is also a risk of a loss if the cost of borrowing the capital outweighs the profit but due to the LBOs short-term investment profile, this is rare.
20 21
64
Since private equity firms also extract equity from the business they acquire in exchange for credit in order to satisfy their own investors and fund managers, there is a great risk that they may use up their equity on the business that they acquire. By the time refinancing has been completed, private equity companies will frequently have refinanced their equity, i.e. they will have got it back before reselling. Furthermore, liquidity and earnings capability are used to service debts; the company is no longer available to invest in its further development. This risk rises further following reselling of the company, which is frequently also funded by borrowed capital; in this case, more of the cash flow is used to service debt. In addition to the burden caused by servicing borrowed capital, the acquired business frequently has to mortgage its assets in order to secure loans. Banks providing money for credit-financed buyouts are increasingly allocating what are known as second-lien loans. These are secondary loans which, in the event of the business becoming bankrupt, are not repaid until the debts owing to other creditors have been. However, the creditors are offered higher rates of interest because of this. This means that the LBO company can achieve greater returns than first-rank creditors22.
Evolution of recycled LBO (secondary + recap.) in total activity of LBO financing in Europe
(%) 70
60
50
40
30
20
10
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
Private equity assumes unrestricted liability for losses. It is not repaid until the businesss sources of borrowed capital (creditors) have been satisfied. Given the higher risk involved, private equity companies demand higher rates of return than creditors. Capital providers generally have big influence on both strategic and the operational decisions taken by management. They request wide-ranging rights to inspect internal company data and to receive ongoing reports. In reality the LBO takes full control of not only the shareholder board of the company, but also the management of the company. This means in practice making all relevant decisions including job cuts, investments, dividends to shareholders, financial engineering etc.
22
65
66
What is a fund of funds? The fund of funds is a structure for sharing investment across several private equity funds. The fund of funds is managed by a team of professionals offering investors the strategic construction of a diversified portfolio and the selection of management companies. These professionals manage the relationships with the various underlying funds, organize the review of valuations, transfer information and provide back office services for the funds.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
67
What could you do with 72 billion euros? Well, with the right conditions it could significantly fund the enormous need for investment in R&D if we are to realise our Lisbon goals. Compared with funds raised in Europe in 2005 (72bn), business enterprise R&D expenditure in Germany in 2005 was approximately 39 billion euros23.
bn
40 30 20 10 0
19
20
20
19
Number
50 50 50 50
19
19
20 03
20 04
20
20
20 03
20 04
20 05
S2
S1
S1
Years
23
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page?_pageid=0,1136250,0_45572561&_dad=portal&_schema=PORTAL
68
S2
S1
S2
20 05
As mentioned earlier, PE-funds, in most cases LBOs, operate with heavy leverage of funds, according to David Bernard from Thomson Financial. To get the real picture of money/funds available for acquisitions from a LBO point of view, we must use a factor of 6, i.e. multiply the amount of funds raised by six. So in 2005the new funds available really amounted to 432 b Euros. All indicators tell us that this trend will continue in Europe. For funds raised, UK is top with 46bn or 64% of the total. France accounts for the next largest percentage at 16% (12bn raised) and Germany is third with 4% (3bn raised). Among the 7 biggest Member States in terms of funds raised by management location, the ranking is the following:
bn
40 30 20 15 10 5 0
5,2%
Th eN et he rla nd s
Ge rm an y
4,8%
21,8%
68,2%
De nm ar k
Fr an ce
Sp ain
Ita ly
UK
69
And it highlights the comparatively difficult position of venture capital managers in recent years, caused by the bubble of 2000, and the wider downturn in the EU economy at that time. Although the top European venture capital funds have performed at a similar level to their US counterparts (where the market is more mature), a wider recovery may take some time because of the longer holding periods necessary for venture investments. Since the 2000 bubble, venture capital managers in Europe, in particular in Europes smaller markets, have found it more difficult to raise funds as a result of historic underperformance. This situation is likely to persist until consistent performance is delivered. Taking into consideration the enormous growth in leverage buy-outs of European companies, it is striking at the same time to see the dominance of the US funds, especially their size. They are simply the most powerful funds in the world. Looking at US funds like Texas Pacific Group, Blackstone and KKR, they have together a capacity equalling more than 30 per cent of worldwide equity. Recently, a new study made public the total LBO take-overs worldwide as shown in the table. As the pie chart above shows, buyouts account for by far the largest part of the private equity investments. The buyout markets in Europe have developed substantially and aggressively over the past 25 years. The European market seems to be experiencing its third phase of significant growth, following the waves of buyouts during the latter halves of the 1980s and 1990s. Records have been set in terms of both individual deal size and the total market value of transactions in recent years. From 1996 to 2005 the value of buyouts/buy-ins has experienced a tremendous rise of 445.4 percent points, as shown in the table.
Development of LBOs value of buyouts/buy-ins in EUR mil in Europe Year Index figure 1996 100 1997 156,9 1998 193,1 1999 391,9 2000 326,3 2001 285,8 2002 294,8 2003 287,5 2004 353,0 2005 545,4
140000
900
Number of transactions
millions
80000
60000
750
650
70
19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 20 05
The illustration underlines the LBOs as the dominant financial actor. Together with the vast number of LBO take-overs of EU companies, this is the basis for our engagement in this report. The Private equity rankings below give us a sense of the major players:
Private equity rankings By M&A deals (Year to Dec 20 2006) US Value $bn Number Europe Kohlberg Kravis Roberts 3i Value $bn Number AsiaPacific Texas Pacific Macquarie Bank Allco Equity Partners Onex Value $bn Number
Blackstone
85.3
12
27.5
12.0
81.9
11
25.9
25
11.3
74.7
20.8
11.1
53.4
19.7
11
11.0
Goldman Sachs
51.2
17.3
Carlyle
8.0
Carlyle
50.0
14
14.9
CVC. Capital Partners Kohlberg Kravis Roberts Goldman Sachs Capital Partners Allianz Capital Partners MBK Partners
7.5
Apollo Management Kohlberg Kravis Roberts Merrill Lynch Cerberus Capital Management Industry total
44.9
Cinven
12.4
5.2
44.5
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
12.2
4.0
35.9
11.3
3.9
28.6
11.3
1.7
402.6
1,157
Industry total
272.6
1,564
Industry total
48.0
271
71
The figures provide a substantial justification for the debate about the phenomenon of ever larger deals, a trend which is supported by banks willingness to leverage transactions, as well as increasing institutional investors appetite for the sector. As illustrated in an annexe to this report our case studies document the need for change in societys strategies vis a vis the LBOs. Like its private equity counterpart, the leveraged finance market experienced a pause in activity in the 2001-2002 economic recessions, as institutional appetite for debt declined. According to Rating agency Standard & Poors the leveraged loan market has increased significantly in 2006, posting record volumes and Europes largest-ever buyout. In the first-quarter of 2006 leveraged loan volume was $44.4 billion. The comparable figure for first-quarter 2005 was $25.5 billion, and first-quarter 2004 volume totalled $20.0 billion. The prior record for first-quarter volume was $24.2 billion in 200124. The increase in aggressive take-overs from LBOs is mirrored in the fact that leverage ratios also continue to rise. Pro forma average total debt to EBITDA for European leveraged loan borrowers was 5.9x in first-quarter 2006. The median was also 5.9x, but the third quartile threshold (25% of the population was greater than this level) was 6.7x. In 2005s first quarter, these figures were generally a full turn lower, at 4.8x for the average, 4.7x for the median, and 5.9x for the third quartile. Even the fourth-quarter 2005 numbers are a half turn lower, at 5.3x for the average, 5.1x for the median, and 6.1x for the third quartile25. As we can see, the debt factor increased from average 4.7 to 6.7. In 2006 this development continued. Recent data of leverage buy-outs in Europe have shown that relaxed attitudes in the markets, or the banks need to get liquidity to work, are tempting borrowers to take on a lot of debt. The rising debt levels in companies owned by private equity funds have been fuelled by unprecedented demands for risky loans and bonds from hedge funds and other investors. Now, the average ratio of leverage rating is almost six times higher, according to Standard & Poor Leveraged Commentary and Data. S&P is not denying that LBO activity is pushing up the average transaction size for loans. Fifteen percent of first-quarter transactions included $1 billion or more of senior debt, and nearly half of those deals were huge transactions, at $2 billion or more26. This huge amount of debt is in itself creating risks for financial systems, of which we should be aware. According to The Economist the global private equity activity in the first half of 2006 took on cheap credit to buy companies for 300 billion dollars. This means that for the whole of 2006 they could in theory borrow enough money to buy a fifth of all listed on Americas NASDAQ, or nearly a quarter of Britains FTSE 10027.
24 25 26 27
72
Private individuals 6%
Banks 18%
One of the best surveys to demonstrate the involvement of the pension funds and insurance funds in the alternative field is the last Russell survey on Alternative Investing, dated 200528. This survey analyses the investment habits of 327 organisations worldwide responsible for managing taxexempt assets. The greater part of the sample is pension schemes (the minority are endowments and foundations). The evolution of such investment in Private Equity is shown in the table below.
Current and Forecast Mean Strategic allocation to Private equity made by pension funds 2001 US Europe Japan 7.5% 3.6% N/A 2003 7.5% 4.0% 1.8% 2005 7% 4.5% 1.8% 2007 7.6% 6.1%
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
4.5%
Analysing the above figures we can state: US players are leading the growth of the alternative investing among the institutional investors and mainly among pension funds. This investment practice seems more suitable to US investors, and anyway in this geographical area such investments are not in an expansion phase (from 2001 to 2005 they ranged from 7.5% to 7.0%). The catch up dynamic of European and Japanese investors to the US standards seems weak. At a first glance, the reported figures do not seem worrying in terms of the financial safety of the subscribers (stakeholders) but as indicated, the high debt activities are creating financial market concerns.
28
73
74
Venture capital is investing in a technology start-up this requires different skills from managers who deal with LBOs of companies. Performances between teams will vary based on their experience and the quality of their management. They will also vary according to the year and industry. The lack of a real benchmark index measuring the performances of various management teams makes the selection of a team particularly tricky. It is therefore necessary to use other means of analysis in accordance with the investment strategy. As a result, it will be easier, for instance, for a European investor to choose a team that invests in its own country than to choose a North American team. It is time to engage in defending the public limited company, which separates management and ownership. Increasingly capital in the hunt for higher returns to make vast personal fortunes is going private to escape the demands of public accountability on stock markets. At the same time the LBOs acquiring a public limited company take full control of not only the financial management and the board. If this new trend is not corrected by better regulation in our societies, there will be serious long-term adverse consequences of privatisation of capital for our economy, society and democracy.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
75
Domicile of the fund The choice of location (domicile) of the fund can be between different national regulated schemes (e.g. UK-based funds or French-based funds) named onshore funds or between an on-shore fund and an offshore fund (e.g. Channel Islands, such as Guernsey or Jersey). The choice of location between different national onshore funds will be made on the basis of tax usually onshore funds are mainly designed to reduce taxation for national investors. The official reason for this practice is that by this method double taxation can be avoided. However, at the same time there is no control as to whether investors are getting taxed on the profit from the private equity funds. The lack of control relates both to the amount of the profit and the time of the taxation. This is due to the fact that there is no possibility of controlling how private equity funds distribute profit. It should be clearly recalled that in many off-shore centres, tax authorities are not as effective as in the major capitals of Europe. When choosing between an onshore fund and an offshore fund, other reasons may appear. For instance, the advantage of the Channel Islands is that they have no significant domestic investors so there is no need for heavy domestic regulation and enforcement by the local securities regulator unlike continental regulators. Therefore, a light regulatory regime for private equity funds in terms of product design and contract conditions allows their faster registration in those offshore centres than in onshore ones (so called regulatory arbitrage). We should recall that all LBOs without exception place their fund off-shore, precisely for these well-known tax reasons. The fund structuring arrangements for EU private equity funds is typically like this29:
Manager Off-shore
Portfolio Investments
Investment X
Investment Y
Investment Z
29
European Commission: Developing European Private Equity, Report of the Alternative Investment Expert Group, July 2006, p.26
76
Domicile of the manager For funds raised: Many LBO managers are based in London, as the City marketplace is probably the most cosmopolitan location in Europe for finding a wide range of institutional investors, and specific taxation schemes are especially attractive for managers splitting location and placing funds off-shore. But other locations such as Paris are also booming. For investments: A large number of LBO management companies wish to remain close to the companies they invest in, in order to keep a close eye on them, which means that many of private equity management companies investing largely in French companies remain in France, as long as they stay in the company (2-3 years) and the same applies to the other continental EU countries. Among the biggest 8 Member States in terms of private equity investments, the situation is the following:
bn
10 5 0
Th eN et he rla nd s
Ita ly
Ge rm an y
De nm ar k
Sw ed en
UK
Fr an ce
Sp ain
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
77
Specific economic function of Venture capital: Venture capital investment involves risks, as capital is invested in new technologies and/or, unproven business strategies. Venture capital investment fosters innovation by financing young companies with innovative concepts and generates high-skilled jobs. Venture capital investment creates new employment and new wealth. The venture capital industry represents a transmission channel of privately available capital into sectors of the economy that have no access to the public capital markets. Specific economic function of Expansion capital: Expansion stage investment involves in some ways less risk than venture capital, because investments are made in existing, generally profitable, companies. Expansion capital can provide capital for new premises, plant and equipment and product or service development needed for growth and in addition support the internationalisation process and the adoption of advanced governance and management skills. Specific economic function of Buy-out capital: Buy-out investment involves less risks for the management companies and investors as investment is made in mature established companies where there is the possibility to create value, mainly through reorganising of businesses or restructuring operations. In the best cases, this is effectively what is taking place, where for example buy-outs help solving corporate succession situations or finance ownership transfers. But buyout capital looks mainly for significant stable cash flows, for example in the infrastructure based as their investors are looking for a stable long term return with regular dividends and reduced market risk. In general, management companies do not invest in all segments. Most specialise in an industry or type of investment. They are also differentiated by the value of assets managed, which affects the size of their transactions and defines the profile of the targeted companies. Certain private equity investors have specialized in major shareholder transactions while others have focused on smaller investments to build a big portfolio of minority investments. LBOs are investing in a wide range of industries. The analysis is based on full consideration of the cash flow opportunities on an industry-by-industry basis in the manufacturing sector and in consumer goods and services. The LBOs buy companies and delist them from the stock exchange. This has the advantage that they do not have to inform the public about strategies, vital change etc. which are conducted in the boardroom or in the CEO office. It is only the investors who stand behind the LBO fund, who have access to this information while an eventual minority shareholder or the public are left outside. The lack of transparency is a huge problem in a democratic society. European labour unions from all over Europe report examples of how LBO funds change the internal organisation and working conditions of the companies. This group of stakeholders therefore wants to unlock the mystery of the funds. To build their portfolios, manager works at generating the cash flow corresponding to their investment strategies. After completing the analysis process, complemented by prospective studies, audits and negotiations, they choose the companies that offer the short-term outlooks that match the objectives set out in the LBO fund.
78
The manager insists on being close to the central, operational life of the companies. Management companies in the LBO fund will often be represented on boards to take part in crafting strategy to varying degrees. But there again, LBO funds generally insist on total control. The managers ultimate objective is to maximise a return/cash flow and develop revenue for its investors. There are several ways to assure these returns and fees: Extraordinary shareholder dividends, stepped increases in leverage, fees, cuts in jobs, sale or flotation. The LBO management picks the time and the exit method that will maximize the cash flow. Every three to five years, managers must raise capital on the market or at the time of cementing an acquisition project. Faced with arbitrages between asset classes and competing projects, they meet investors to propose new fund investment opportunities and try to convince them on the basis of their past performance and their professional ability. A distinguishing feature of LBO is that the financial reward of the investors, the investment management team and the investee companys management will largely come in stages. Firstly, fees, shareholder dividends. Secondly, fees and value creation realised when exiting (by sale or flotation). An important part of the investment management teams/private equity managers strategy is therefore the early identification of alternative routes for exiting their investments.
79
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
Mortgaging the future to capture gains for personal enrichment in the present is quite an easy activity. The task for a good manager in a public company is to resist it! Managers have to balance the interests of todays shareholders with tomorrows shareholders and all other stakeholders including the employees. As seen in so many of our case studies, the one party unrewarded is the employees. In many cases they suffer an erosion of job security and a loss of benefits.
80
European Private Equity and Venture Capital association and KPMG: Benchmarking Tax and legal environments, Dec 2006. See Glossary 32 Idem 33 Idem
there are specific fiscal scheme for supporting the creation and growth of young and innovative companies there are fiscal incentives on R&D the income tax for private individuals is below the EU average (43.03%) the taxation of stock options is made upon sale and not when they are granted, vested or exercised. The country where all these conditions are met gets the best evaluation (1) and the worst get (3). The table on the next page gives an overview of the ranking of European countries according to the EVCA findings for 2006, in comparison with previous years.
Overview of results Results tor 2006 Country Ireland France United Kingdom Belgium Spain Greece Netherlands Luxembourg Portugal Italy Austria Denmark Hungary Switzerland Total Average Finland Estonia Norway Sweden Latvia Germany Poland Slovak Republic Czech Republic Slovenia Romania
Source EVCA
Results for 2004 Country United Kingdom Luxembourg Ireland Greece Netherlands Portugal Belgium Hungary Italy France Switzerland Spain Total Average Norway Sweden Czech Republic Poland Finland Germany Austria Denmark Slovak Republic Total Score 1,25 1,49 1,53 1.75 1.75 1.81 1.82 1.88 1.86 1.89 1.95 1.96 1.97 2.04 2.05 2,12 2.13 2.30 2.37 2.42 2.46 2.49
Results for 2003 Country United Kingdom Ireland Luxembourg Netherlands Italy Greece Total Average Belgium France Sweden Spain Finland Portugal Denmark Germany Austria Total Score 1.20 1.58 1.67 1.79 1,96 1,96 2,03 2,0S 2.09 2,09 2.17 2.25 2.32 2.S6 2.41 2,53
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
Total Score 1.27 1.36 1,4S 1.51 1.52 1.55 1.62 1.62 1.71 1.72 1.74 1.75 1,83 1.83 1.84 1.91 2.08 2.08 2.12 2.12 2.15 2.16 2.17 2.21 2.26 2.35
81
Main conclusions: The total European average, at 1.84, indicates that the tax and legal environment create more and more incentives for private equity and venture capital in Europe. The gap between the best country average at 1.27 and the European average at 1.84 is smaller than the 2004 gap (1.26/1.97), However, the composite score of the lowest country in ranking (2.35) is not closer to the European average (1 .84) than the measured gap in 2004 (2.49/1.97). This means that, overall, a certain convergence is taking place in the upper part of the table but that less mature countries still have a long way to go. This is how it looks unless we consider instead our common interest in protecting our welfare states including our tax revenues. Here, we are way off. But we have clear goals as defined by our Lisbon strategies. On the European situation as a whole, the EVCA makes the following points as far as circumstances for LBO operations look: The European average for domestic fund structures is good, at 1.47. Most of the countries assessed have taken steps towards having an appropriate fund structure available in the country to attract capital from domestic and international limited partners. Also favourable are the environments for pension funds and insurance companies to invest in private equity and venture capital, with European averages of 1.55 and 1.42 respectively. Most countries allow those institutional investors to invest in the asset class and many of the previously existing obstacles have been abolished over the past four years. Very few countries are providing incentives to encourage investment in LBOs, leading to a European average of 2.04. As the LBO see it , Europe provides a very unfavourable environment for both company incentivisation and Fiscal R&D incentives, with European averages of 2.36 and 2.13 respectively. From our point of view, societies interest and our common interest in assuring a sustainable financing of the real economy, we lack: Adequate protection of pension funds as investors in LBOs Adequate incentives and rules which can ensure companies comparative capability in the global economy through long-term investments. Sufficient regulations to ensure improved qualifications for employees The role of the social partners The financing of our welfare societies through taxation The lack of coherence between different national regulations is a major problem considering the international nature of the phenomenon, but the lack of a common direction is even worse. The Socialist Group in the European Parliament and the PES have recently, in our reports, Europe of excellence and New Social Europe, underlined that Europe is not about competition among states, but among other things about assuring fair and transparent competition among companies within the single market. And Europe is about making progress for our common goals, the Lisbon goals. The main conclusions to be drawn form the trends described above is that there is on-going liberalisation and deregulation in order to attract funds and investments. And worse: without a corollary in terms of risks involved, social costs, innovation promotion and investor protection.
82
83
UCITS (Undertakings for Collective Investment in Transferable Securities) are specially constituted collective investment portfolios exclusively dedicated to the investment of assets raised from investors. Under the UCITS Directive, UCITS investment policy and its manager are authorised in accordance with specific requirements. UCITS legislation aims to establish a defined level of investor protection. This is achieved through strict investment limits, capital and disclosure requirements, as well as asset safe-keeping and fund oversight provided by an independent depositary. UCITS benefit from a passport allowing them, subject to notification, to be offered to retail investors in any EU jurisdiction once authorised in one Member State.
From the positive experience of the UCITS Directive, the UCITS funds developed very well after the adoption of the Directive in 1985 as it proved to be a very efficient way to develop a real Single Market for such a financial product while not harming investors protection. Thanks to this Directive, UCITS benefit from a European label/brand, which is now a tool to export pan-European expertise at worldwide level (e.g. two thirds of funds currently registered in Hong-Kong are European UCITS). However, there are several limits to the current framework of alternative investments in the EU. Currently onshore hedge funds/funds of hedge funds/private equity funds are fragmented through divergent national regulations. So, there is still a long way to go, in developing a Single Market for such onshore alternative investment vehicles. No actual EU regulatory framework is provided for onshore alternative investments. A good next question is: what about offshore or non-EU regulated products? The European Commission (Commissioner McCreevy) wishes clearly to develop the so-called Private Placement: i.e. the ability for a firm registered in the EU to sell any type of product (including offshore funds or non-EU regulated product) in the EU, to so-called qualified investors (i.e. professional investors: insurance companies, pension funds, etc). Our concern is that the final risk will be borne anyway by the end investor (e. g. retirees, retail investors) as unit-linked life insurance and defined contribution retirement saving products develop. Therefore we think that it is necessary to provide a minimum safety net for alternative products to be sold in the EU. In addition to giving increased investor protection, a EU regulatory frame for alternative investments (direct hedge funds/funds of hedge funds; private equity funds) could provide a success similar to the UCITS case. Within the EU, a regulated framework would help develop a Single Market for alternative investments, with the right level of investor protection and possible overseeing by regulators. Out of the EU, a non-UCITS fund Directive would help develop a
84
non-UCITS fund brand which would be a serious competitor to offshore and non-EU hedge funds/private equity funds. This proposal would take into account the fact that these funds are to be found largely outside EU sovereign territory and so are not accessible to direct EU-regulation. However, although the funds themselves are located offshore, the managers generally run their businesses in the large financial centres (especially London and New York). It would be then possible to make managers and their business partners for example, prime brokers or hedge fund managers the addressee of such regulation. In fact, they are already partly covered by some directives. Nevertheless, this does not deal with all the relevant potential consequences of alternative investment strategies. More has to be done. Before giving an overview of what exists in terms of regulation at EU level, one should keep in mind the aims a regulation of alternative investment should pursue: It can and should protect investors. This is the principal consideration of the EU Commission and conventional regulatory methods. Rules serving this end are also directed towards the auditability of the investment products on offer. The object of the investment itself, in other words: how can we promote initiatives which can improve the basis upon which the employer together with his employees and creditors can sustain their legal environment, and thereby avoid negative eventualities (above all, leveraged buy-outs, asset stripping). It should be possible to register the investor or his business partner as a formal undertaking, which is subject to the usual corporate standards. The employees of the enterprise in question should be able to assert their social rights and have them respected by alternative investment actors. Typical risks pertaining to alternative investment should be framed in order to guarantee a sound functioning of financial markets in the common interest.
3.1 The single financial market basic principles and common rules
Right of establishment, (Articles 43-48 of the EU Treaty); Freedom to provide services (Article 49) The right of establishment, set out in Article 43 of the Treaty and the freedom to provide cross border services, set out in Article 49, are two of the fundamental freedoms which are central to the effective functioning of the EU Internal Market.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
Article 43 Within the framework of the provisions set out below, restrictions on the freedom of establishment of nationals of a Member State in the territory of another Member State shall be prohibited. Such prohibition shall also apply to restrictions on the setting-up of agencies, branches or subsidiaries by nationals of any Member State established in the territory of any Member State. Freedom of establishment shall include the right to take up and pursue activities as selfemployed persons and to set up and manage undertakings, in particular companies or firms within the meaning of the second paragraph of Article 48, under the conditions laid down for its own nationals by the law of the country where such establishment is effected, subject to the provisions of the Chapter relating to capital.
85
Article 49 Within the framework of the provisions set out below, restrictions on freedom to provide services within the Community shall be prohibited in respect of nationals of Member States who are established in a State of the Community other than that of the person for whom the services are intended. The Council may, acting by a qualified majority on a proposal from the Commission, extend the provisions of the Chapter to nationals of a third country who provide services and who are established within the Community.
The principle of freedom of establishment enables an economic operator (whether a person or a company) to carry on an economic activity in a stable and continuous way in one or more Member States. The principle of the freedom to provide services enables an economic operator providing services in one Member State to offer services on a temporary basis in another Member State, without having to be established. The principles of freedom of establishment and free movement of services have been clarified and developed over the years through the case law of the European Court of Justice. In addition, important developments and progress in the field of services have been brought about through specific legislation in fields such as financial services, telecommunications, broadcasting, the recognition of professional qualifications and the services directive. These provisions have direct effect. This means, in practice, that Member States must modify national laws that restrict freedom of establishment, or the freedom to provide services, and are therefore incompatible with these principles. This includes not only discriminatory national rules, but also any national rules which are universally applicable to domestic and foreign operators but which hinder or render less attractive the exercise of these fundamental freedoms, in particular if they result in delays or additional costs. In these cases, Member States may only maintain such restrictions in specific circumstances where these are justified by overriding reasons of general interest, for instance on grounds of public policy, public security or public health; and where they are proportionate. The Financial Services Action Plan 1999-2005 (FSAP) has laid the foundations of a financial market in the EU.
Article 56 1. Within the framework of the provisions set out in this Chapter, all restrictions on the movement of capital between Member States and between Member States and third countries shall be prohibited. 2. Within the framework of the provisions set out in this Chapter, all restrictions on payments between Member States and between Member States and third countries shall be prohibited.
86
Article 57 1. The provisions of Article 56 shall be without prejudice to the application to third countries of any restrictions which exist on 31 December 1993 under national or Community law adopted in respect of the movement of capital to or from third countries involving direct investment including in real estate establishment, the provision of financial services or the admission of securities to capital markets. In respect of restrictions existing under national law in Estonia and Hungary, the relevant date shall be 31 December 1999. 2. Whilst endeavouring to achieve the objective of free movement of capital between Member States and third countries to the greatest extent possible and without prejudice to the other Chapters of this Treaty, the Council may, acting by a qualified majority on a proposal from the Commission, adopt measures on the movement of capital to or from third countries involving direct investment including investment in real estate establishment, the provision of financial services or the admission of securities to capital markets. Unanimity shall be required for measures under this paragraph as they constitute a step back in Community law as regards the liberalisation of the movement of capital to or from third countries.
For citizens it means the ability to do many things abroad, as diverse as opening bank accounts, buying shares in non-domestic companies and investing. For companies it principally means being able to invest in and own other European companies and take an active part in their management. The liberalisation of capital movements in the EU was agreed in 1988 (Directive 88/361/EEC) and came into effect in 1990 for most Member States, while for the rest specific transitional periods were agreed. There are exceptions to the free movement of capital both within the EU and with third countries. These are actually primarily linked to taxation, prudential supervision, public policy considerations, money laundering, and financial sanctions agreed under the Common Foreign and Security Policy.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
87
The purpose of this Directive is to harmonise requirements for the drawing up, approval and distribution of the prospectus to be published when securities are offered to the public or admitted to trading on a regulated market situated or operating within a Member State. Directive 2004/109/EC on the harmonisation of transparency requirements in relation to information bout issuers whose securities are admitted to trading on regulated market and amending Directive 2001/34/EC (Transparency Directive). The purpose of this directive is to establish requirements in relation to the disclosure of periodic and ongoing information about issuers whose securities are already admitted to trading on a regulated market situated or operating within a Member State. This directive sets out the rules governing the issue of annual and semi-annual financial reports for securities issuers. Directive 2003/6/EC on on insider dealing and market manipulation (market abuse). The directive prohibits any person who possesses inside information from using that information by acquiring or disposing of, or by trying to acquire or dispose of, for his own account or for the account of a third party, either directly or indirectly, financial instruments to which that information relates. This directive also sets out measures to combat market manipulation. Directive 2004/39/EC on markets in financial instruments amending Directives 85/611/EEC, 93/6/EEC and 2000/12/EC and repealing Directive 93/22/EEC (MiFID). The directive addresses investment firms and regulated markets whereby the home Member State shall ensure that the authorisation specifies the investment services or activities the investment firm is authorised to provide. The authorisation shall be valid for the entire Community and shall allow an investment firm to provide the services or perform the activities, for which it has been authorised, throughout the Community, either through the establishment of a branch or the free provision of services. Directive 2001/65/EC amending Directives 78/660/EEC, 83/349/EEC and 86/635/EEC as regards the valuation rules for the annual and consolidated accounts of certain types of companies as well as of banks and other financial institutions (4th & 7th Company Law Directives). In order to maintain consistency between internationally recognised accounting standards and Directives 78/660/EEC, 83/349/EEC and 86/635/EEC, it was necessary to amend these Directives in order to allow for certain financial assets and liabilities to be valued at fair value. This will enable European companies to report in conformity with current international developments. Regulation (EC) 1606/2002 on the application of international accounting standards (IAS Regulation). The Commission proposed that all EU companies listed on a regulated market (estimated at around 6,700) should be required to prepare consolidated accounts in accordance with IAS. Finally, this led to adoption of the IAS Regulation introducing the International Financial Reporting Standards (IAS/IFRS) for listed companies in the EU. *** As we can see from this partial list, EU competence covers a wide range of issues. The implementation question is now key. There is the need for safeguards and EU-initiatives to promote a forward looking, subordinate relationship between the financial market and the real economy.
88
The Take-over Directive applies to takeover bids for the securities of a company governed by the law of a Member State if those securities are admitted to trading on a regulated market in one or more Member States. The scope of the companies and merger transactions covered by Directive is narrow. However, Member States can choose to regulate a wider range of companies and merger transactions if they want to. The general principles in the Directive are: All holders of the securities of an offeree company of the same class must be given equal treatment in particular, if a person acquires control of a company, the other holders of securities must be protected. Holder of securities in an offeree company must have sufficient time and information to enable them to react a properly informed decision on the bid the board of the offeree company must give its views on the effects of the bid on employment, conditions of employment and the companys business locations. The board of the offeree company must act in the interest of the company as a whole, and must not deny the holders of securities the opportunity to decide on the merits of the bid. False markets must not be created in the securities of the offeree company, the offeror company or any other company concerned by the bid in such a way that rise or fall in the prices of the securities becomes artificial and the normal functioning of the market is distorted. An offeror may only announce after ensuring that it can fulfil in full any cash consideration it offers and after having taken all responsible measures to secure the implementation of any other type of consideration. Offeree companies must be hindered in the conduct of their affairs for longer than responsible by a bid for their securities.
89
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
As far as the hedge fund and Private Equity industry is concerned, however, Art. 47 para 2 EC is a more obvious regulatory norm but its application must be considered on a case by case basis. Regulations in this area have the aim of coordinating legal and administrative provisions on the commencement of independent activities. A regulation could therefore apply in the case of investment companies themselves. Fundamental money market legal provisions are already founded on Art. 47 of the European Treaty: for example, the Markets in financial instruments directive (MiFiD). Particularly the Directive on the coordination of laws, regulations and administrative provisions relating to undertakings for collective investment in transferable securities (UCITS) is based on this regulation.
MIFID introduces more detailed requirements covering: the organisation and conduct of business of investment firms, and how regulated markets and MTFs (Market trading facilities) operate; new pre-and post-trade transparency requirements for equity markets; the creation of a new regime for systematic internalisers of retail order flow in liquid equities; and more extensive transaction reporting requirements. Types of firms to be regulated by the MiFID requirements are: investment banks; portfolio managers; stockbrokers and broker dealers; corporate finance firms; many futures and options firms; some commodities firms. Most firms that fall within the scope of MiFID will also have to comply with the new Capital Requirements Directive (CRD), which is similar to Basel II, which will set requirements for the regulatory capital which a firm must hold. MiFID will require transaction reports for any instrument admitted to trading on a regulated market including commodity instruments e.g electricity, oil and metals admitted to trading on exchange.
*** Looking to the challenges of offshore activities, there is much work to do. In accordance with Article 56 of the European Treaty free movement of capital and payments, there is in principle a comprehensive prohibition on restrictions also in relation to third countries, which may be limited only under the conditions laid down in the exceptional provisions of Art. 57-59.
Article 59 Where, in exceptional circumstances, movements of capital to or from third countries cause, or threaten to cause, serious difficulties for the operation of economic and monetary union, the Council, acting by a qualified majority on a proposal from the Commission and after consulting the ECB, may take safeguard measures with regard to third countries for a period not exceeding six months if such measures are strictly necessary.
For the regulation of offshore investors or their on-shore resident business partners the basis of authorisation of Art. 57 para 2 EC can be taken into consideration. According to that, only the EU, more precisely the Council at the proposal of the Commission, can enact new restrictions (which hasnt happened since 1993) on capital movements with third countries, in connection with direct investments, including real property, with the registered office, the furnishing of finan-
90
cial services, or the listing of securities on the capital markets. The aim is to ensure the EUs capacity to act in negotiations and dealings with third states. Direct investments in accordance with Art. 57 EC include the foundation, takeover or participation in an undertaking, long-term loans or re-investment of proceeds with the aim of creating or maintaining lasting business relations.
Article 308 If action by the Community should prove necessary to attain, in the course of the operation of the common market, one of the objectives of the Community, and this Treaty has not provided the necessary powers, the Council shall, acting unanimously on a proposal from the Commission and after consulting the European Parliament, take the appropriate measures.
In its Communication on worker information and consultation [COM(95) 547 final not published in Official Journal], the Commission took stock of Community action in the field of information, consultation and participation of employees. Some directives have already been adopted in this area (collective redundancies, transfers of undertakings and European Works Councils), while other proposals have not yet been finalised (European company, European association, European cooperative, European mutual society). Despite the existence of specific provisions on employee information and consultation, the Commission emphasised the need to redefine the Community legal framework in order to establish more binding rules and presented a proposal for a Directive, the objective of which was to establish a general framework for employee information and consultation in undertakings located in the European Community. The Directive 2002/14/EC of the Council and the European Parliament of 11 March 2002 establishing a general framework for informing and consulting employees mentions that employee information and consultation cover three areas in relation to undertakings: economic, financial and strategic developments; structure and foreseeable development of employment and related measures; decisions likely to lead to substantial changes in work organisation or contractual relations. Member States must establish the procedures for applying the principles set out in the Directive, with a view to ensuring the effective application of employee information and consultation. They also have the option of limiting the information and consultation obligations of undertakings with fewer than 50 or 20 employees according to the Member States discretion.
91
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
The following are regarded as serious breaches of the obligations laid down in the Directive: total absence of information and/or consultation of the employees representatives prior to a decision being taken or the public announcement of such decision; withholding of important information or provision of inaccurate information rendering ineffective the exercise of the right to information and consultation. In the event of a serious breach with direct and immediate consequences in terms of substantial change or termination of employment contracts or relationships, the decisions taken have no legal effect. This situation continues until such time as the employer has fulfilled his information and consultation obligations. If this is no longer possible, the employer must establish adequate redress in accordance with the arrangements and procedures in place in the Member States. Since economic trends are bringing in their wake, at both national and Community level, changes in the structure of undertakings, there is a need to provide for the protection of employees in the event of a change of employer, and in particular to ensure that their rights are safeguarded. To that end, the Council Directive 77/187/EEC on the approximation of the laws of the Member States relating to the safeguarding of employees rights in the event of transfers of undertakings, businesses or parts of businesses foresees that the rights and obligations arising from a contract of employment or from an employment relationship existing at the time of the transfer are transferred to the new employer. Member States are required to adopt the necessary measures to protect the rights of employees and of persons no longer employed in the transferors business. The transfer does not constitute grounds for dismissal, which may only take place for economic, technical or organisational reasons or when Member States make exceptions in respect of certain specific categories of employees. The status and function of employees representatives are preserved unless, under the provisions or practice of a Member State, the conditions necessary for re-appointment of employees representatives are fulfilled. The former employer and the new employer are required to inform the representatives of their respective employees in good time of the reasons for the transfer, the legal, economic and social implications, and the measures envisaged in relation to the employees. This information must be given for the employees transferred before their transfer is carried out and in any event for all employees before they are directly affected as regards their conditions of work and employment. When the former employer or the new employer envisages measures in relation to their employees, they must consult the employees representatives in good time with a view to seeking agreement. It should be also underlined that referring to Art. 137 i lit. f of the EU treaty, the European Commission is provided with a power of initiative to create a European provision on obligatory employee involvement on boardrooms as a European wide standard.
92
Article 137 1. With a view to achieving the objectives of Article 136, the Community shall support and complement the activities of the Member States in the following fields: a) improvement in particular of the working environment to protect workers health and safety; b) working conditions; c) social security and social protection of workers; d) protection of workers where their employment contract is terminated; e) the information and consultation of workers; f) representation and collective defence of the interests of workers and employers, including co-determination, subject to paragraph 5; g) conditions of employment for third-country nationals legally residing in Community territory; h) the integration of persons excluded from the labour market, without prejudice to Article 150; i) equality between men and women with regard to labour market opportunities and treatment at j) work; k) the combating of social exclusion; l) the modernisation of social protection systems without prejudice to point (c). 2. To this end, the Council: a) may adopt measures designed to encourage cooperation between Member States through initiatives aimed at improving knowledge, developing exchanges of information and best practices, promoting innovative approaches and evaluating experiences, excluding any harmonisation of the laws and regulations of the Member States; b) may adopt, in the fields referred to in paragraph 1(a) to (i), by means of directives, minimum requirements for gradual implementation, having regard to the conditions and technical rules obtaining in each of the Member States. Such directives shall avoid imposing administrative, financial and legal constraints in a way which would hold back the creation and development of small and medium-sized undertakings. The Council shall act in accordance with the procedure referred to in Article 251 after consulting the Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions, except in the fields referred to in paragraph 1(c), (d), (f) and (g) of this article, where the Council shall act unanimously on a proposal from the Commission, after consulting the European Parliament and the said Committees. The Council, acting unanimously on a proposal from the Commission, after consulting the European Parliament, may decide to render the procedure referred to in Article 251 applicable to paragraph 1(d), (f) and (g) of this article.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
93
3. A Member State may entrust management and labour, at their joint request, with the implementation of directives adopted pursuant to paragraph 2. In this case, it shall ensure that, no later than the date on which a directive must be transposed in accordance with Article 249, management and labour have introduced the necessary measures by agreement, the Member State concerned being required to take any necessary measure enabling it at any time to be in a position to guarantee the results imposed by that directive.
4. The provisions adopted pursuant to this article: shall not affect the right of Member States to define the fundamental principles of their social security systems and must not significantly affect the financial equilibrium thereof, shall not prevent any Member State from maintaining or introducing more stringent protective measures compatible with this Treaty.
5. The provisions of this article shall not apply to pay, the right of association, the right to strike or the right to impose lock-outs.
3.6 Supervision
The Directive 2002/87/EC on the supplementary supervision of credit institutions, insurance undertakings and investment firms in a financial conglomerate introduces group-wide supervision of financial conglomerates and requires closer co-operation and information sharing among supervisory authorities across sectors. The directive also introduces initial steps to align the rules for financial conglomerates with those for homogeneous financial groups (dealing in a single financial sector, such as banking) so as to ensure equivalence of treatment and a level playing field. One can imagine using the framework of this Directive to supervise the activities of banks acting as intermediaries for the alternative investment industry. In that case, the Capital adequacy requirement directive (CRD) would be one tool. But in general, any thorough supervision of the funds themselves would require a specific regulatory framework because their characteristics differ from those of credit institutions or insurance companies. The national authorities would be the competent ones in this area, within the cooperation framework of CESR (Committee of European securities regulators).
The previous (1988) Basel Accord constitutes the international benchmark for capital adequacy and is agreed by the G-10 banking supervisors in the Committee on Banking Supervision of the Bank for International Settlements (known as the Basel Committee). Like the Basel Committees rules, the new EU capital standards aim to align regulatory capital requirements more closely with underlying risks and to provide institutions with incentives to move to higher standards of risk management. The Directive (CRD), which is one of the outstanding measures required to complete the EU Financial Services Action Plan, will modernise the
94
existing framework to make it more comprehensive and risk-sensitive and to foster enhanced risk management amongst financial institutions. This will maximise the effectiveness of the framework in ensuring continuing financial stability, maintaining confidence in financial institutions and protecting consumers. Improved risk-sensitivity in the capital requirements will facilitate more effective allocation of capital, contributing to boosting the competitiveness of the EU economy. A key aspect of the new framework is its flexibility. This provides institutions with the opportunity to adopt the approaches most appropriate to their situation and to the sophistication of their risk management. The new regime is also designed to ensure that the capital requirements for lending to smalland medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are appropriate and proportionate.
CESR is an independent Committee of European Securities Regulators. The Committee was established under the terms of the European Commissions Decision of 6 June 2001. It is one of the two committees envisaged in the Final Report of the Committee of Wise Men on the regulation of European securities markets, chaired by Baron Alexandre Lamfalussy. The report itself was endorsed by Heads of State in the European Council (Stockholm Resolution of 23 March 2001) and the European Parliament (European Parliament Resolution of 5 February 2002). In summary, the role of CESR is to: Improve co-ordination among securities regulators : developing effective operational network mechanisms to enhance day to day consistent supervision and enforcement of the Single Market for financial services; Having agreed a Multilateral Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) , CESR has made a significant contribution to greater surveillance and enforcement of securities activities; Act as an advisory group to assist the EU Commission: in particular in its preparation of draft implementing measures of EU framework directives in the field of securities; Work to ensure more consistent and timely day-to-day implementation of community legislation in the Member States: this work is carried out by the Review Panel under the Chairmanship of CESRs Vice Chairman, and by the two operational groups: CESR-Pol and CESR-Fin.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
95
Article 93 The Council shall, acting unanimously on a proposal from the Commission and after consulting the European Parliament and the Economic and Social Committee, adopt provisions for the harmonisation of legislation concerning turnover taxes, excise duties and other forms of indirect taxation to the extent that such harmonisation is necessary to ensure the establishment and the functioning of the internal market within the time limit laid down in Article 14.
The directives on the taxation of savings income (2003/48/EC) and the Parent subsidiary directive (2003/123/EC) should be relevant for the alternative investment sector. The former has the aim of taxing interest earnings at the actual place of residence of the beneficiary. Here it is not the investment companies but the investors themselves who are subject to the tax.
The aim of the Directive on the taxation of savings income is to enable savings income, in the form of interest payments made in one Member State to beneficial owners who are individual residents for tax purposes in another Member State, to be made subject to effective taxation in accordance with the laws of the latter Member State. The automatic exchange of information between Member States concerning interest payments is the means chosen to achieve effective taxation of these interest payments in the Member State where the beneficial owner is resident for tax purposes. Member States must therefore take the necessary measures to ensure that the tasks necessary for the implementation of this Directive cooperation and exchange of banking information are carried out by paying agents established within their territory, irrespective of the place of establishment of the debtor of the debt claim producing the interest. The Council Directive on the common system of taxation applicable in the case of parent companies and subsidiaries of different Member States as amended by Directive 2003/123/EC, is applicable by each Member State: 1) to distributions of profits received by permanent establishments situated in that State of companies of other Member States which come from their subsidiaries of a Member State other than that where the permanent establishment is situated; 2) to distributions of profits by companies of that State to permanent establishments situated in another Member State of companies of the same Member State of which they are subsidiaries.
In summary: For the regulation of investors, Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds, several legal bases are available, depending on the specific regulatory aim.
***
96
4. Conclusion: New Social Europe and the financial markets increasing contradictions!
In summarising our analyses in Part I, it is essential to understand that the alternative investment industry in the financial markets is not a phenomenon of marginal importance or just another time-limited bubble of interests, which will go away sooner or later. The HF and PE funds are dominant and fast growing actors in the European and global capital markets. Until recently, PE and HF only had real influence in the UK and Irish financial markets, as well as Luxembourg and Lichtenstein. This has changed fundamentally in the past ten years. The direction is clear. The big international funds, especially those based in the USA and the UK, have now really engaged in Europe, acquiring an increasing number of ever larger companies and projects on our continent. The figures speak for themselves: in the period 2002-2005 the PE funds invested 165 billion Euros in companies in Europe. In the single year of 2006, the target volume was 270 bn Euros. In 2007 the PE industry is planning for 580 take-overs worth of 380 bn Euros. Given that the average leverage compared to acquisition price is 75%, we can estimate the total volume of potential buy-out capacity at around 1,500 bn Euros. All the nuances of our analysis in part I suggest that the trends and developments of PE and HF have very clear common characteristics and implications. The rapid growth of the hedge fund industry is also raising important questions about systemic risks ie. the risk of destabilisation of the financial markets, market abuse, i.e. potential market price manipulation and insider trading, and misbehaviour in shareholder activism. Hedge funds have shown impressive growth to become a very important alternative investment instrument for good and, unfortunately, also for bad not only the risk of their destabilising the financial markets but also that its interests conflict with corporate businesss need for long-term investment in the global economic competition. The international character of hedge fund industry and its de facto unregulated activities, challenge our societies and authorities.
Part I Hedge funds and private equity funds how they work
The possible implications of hedge funds for financial stability are not only a problem for the hedge funds. If its risks are realised the consequences will be dire for corporate industries, employment, and other investment, well as pensioners savings. The PE industry, especially LBO funds, poses a number of serious questions to Europeans, their real economies and national policy makers. LBO activities have worrying implications for job creation, companies investments in training and education of the labour force, innovation, and corporate governance. They also have disturbing implications for public finances, the evolution of stock markets and protection of wage earners money in pension funds. Of equal concern are extreme management fees and the LBOs aggression towards target managements. All in all, there is a straightforward argument for reducing the risks and negative implications associated with the increasing role of HF and PE funds in the financial system. There has always been a good case for regulating banks and investment banks and other financial actors why should hedge funds and private equity be any exception?
97
Primarily, however, society must involve itself in how to avoid the negative consequences of the heavy leverage activities from LBOs. We can see from our case studies a substantial number of companies having serious difficulties after an LBO. Long-term investment in companies to strengthen global competitiveness becomes increasingly difficult to realise because of the desire for short-term financial gains. This is because every investment in the world of PE funds and LBOs is viewed as a portfolio of financial assets, not a place of employment. In the introduction to this part I, we posed the question: Does this new HF and PE industry respond to our investment needs for Europes knowledge-economy? After analysis the answer is that unfortunately, in far too many cases, there is a contradiction between the investment needs of the real economy, the way it works, and the cohesion between the different actors in the society and the financial market. There is, therefore, an increasing need for change and better regulation. ***
98
7845.35781499
101
We are concerned about the financial effects of the LBOs and hedge fund industries on some of the most important issues: The effects on the efficiency of capital markets. Lack of transparency, information asymmetry, insider trading all contribute to inefficiency and imperfect markets. Effects on the productivity and long-term growth of the firms and industries in which HF & LBOs invest. It increases financial risks requiring preoccupation with cash flow and reduces capacities to invest and manage long-term efficiency, productivity and innovation. The effects on our public sector and the special public-service obligations of firms in the infrastructure and public housing sectors. It minimises or abandons those obligations and undermines the risks allocated by public bodies through re-evaluations this is the basis for additional cash withdrawals to the LBO fund. The lack of transparency. This is not just an incidental characteristic of HF & LBOs. Unnecessary and costly complex holding structures are created effectively making it impossible for anyone to lift the corporate veil. This again has detrimental effects on all parties with an interest in the firm regulators, tax authorities, trade unions and others. One cannot rule out that it is a device LBOs use to weaken the negotiating position of everyone they deal with. The incentives created for CEOs of the target company are extremely high and threaten the efficient management of all potential target companies. Our case studies confirm the risks and negative impacts for our social Europe. The PES Group in the European Parliament has, in its report Europe of Excellence, highlighted our vision for a modern, coherent European knowledge economy in the globalisation era. The PES Group has also recently joined the roadmap for New Social Europe as decided at the PES Congress, in Porto December 2006. That is the basis for our six concerns as outlined here in Part II of the report: The economic viability of our private companies in member states all over Europe. Their investment capability, employees, education and qualifications, innovation and global competitiveness. Decent work and workers participation. Our public sector and services Employees, pension funds, investments and long-term real value Stability of financial markets Coherence, co-responsibility and ethics Our reflections on the implications on all of these six issues will also mirror our concerns for the social market economy as a whole, our social Europe. These concerns must be met with a new offensive response as we will show in Part III
102
In the case study of Deustche Brse it is described how hedge funds managed to fire the CEO, Werner Seifert, as he wanted the company to move into another direction than the hedge funds. In the case study of Stork it is described how the hedge funds have bought up a large amount of shares without disclosing this ownership to the public. The procedure used is under investigation.
As we have seen in Part I, the strategy of LBOs to take total corporate control after acquisitions creates a risk of deterioration in corporate governance. Funds tend to try to keep the conditions and form of their investments as opaque as possible with the justification that investors in such funds are professionals who are able to obtain the necessary information any time they want. The activities of such funds, however, are a matter of concern not only for the investors themselves but for the market and society as a whole since these activities can have wide-ranging effects. The approach to risk of investors and management alike, conditioned by the shareholder value approach, is further exacerbated by LBOs. As a result, management is increasingly frequently operating in grey areas. Regulatory measures are therefore also necessary in the interests of corporate governance and the stakeholders involved. However, there is more to corporate governance, or good business management, than merely looking after shareholders interests. It is a stakeholder-based approach and therefore widens the scope of a company. It cannot be evaluated purely in terms of performance or financial management, but must include the care of a companys human resources, employee participation and the pursuit of environmental and social goals. The experience of our case studies and numerous reports shows that LBOs are not motivated to take sufficient account of such interests. LBOs regular, brief interventions in management strategy and daily decision-making often do more harm than good in the quest for sustainable corporate development.
103
The impact of capital funds on the way that companies operate extends far beyond the until now relatively limited number of companies that have been bought out by private equity funds or suffered speculative attacks by hedge funds. Indeed it seems likely from theoretical considerations and some anecdotal evidence even if difficult to prove with hard data that the activities of such funds have affected the behaviour of a very large number of companies, both publicly-listed large and medium sized and family-owned SMEs. Indeed, in principle all but the smallest companies are affected, and thus the impact on the functioning of the economy as a whole can be expected to be substantial. This indirect effect results essentially in the preventive measures taken by managers and owners to ward off unwanted approaches by private equity and hedge funds. In many cases the negative impacts are similar, if less pronounced, than those identified in those firms actually taken over. In particular, incumbent managers of listed companies are expected to be increasingly concerned, if not obsessed, by the short run share price: a high share price is the best deterrent to a hostile takeover. A depressed share price for whatever reason will quickly attract the interest of capital funds looking for quick profits. This is likely to have a series of negative consequences. Large-scale investment projects, particularly those with a long payback period may be cancelled or postponed, as managerial planning horizons collapse to the demands of quarterly reporting deadlines and their priorities focus on the latest fad that, for a short period, is at the top of the likes or dislikes list of the market. In particular, jobs may be axed to offer investors some good news. Dividends are likely to be pushed up at the expense of real investment and the companys human capital. Some firms engage in macroeconomically irrational share buyback schemes. Others rush into mergers and takeovers that lack a genuine economic rationale merely to avoid an unwelcome takeover bid or speculative interest. Ultimately managers are forced into Enron-style false accounting. More generally the pressure on other stakeholders, and especially workers, as described in section 2, is likely to be ratcheted up.
In the case study of DT Group it is described how the number of employees has increased with 10% since the take over. However this is due to acquisitions of formerly privately owed building markets. Direct investment in property and equipment is lower than before the take over.
Even a comparison with all German companies is problematic. LBO funds deliberately select target enterprises that already promise success without their help and which are therefore already way above average. The turnover of these companies would have grown substantially
104
as a rule without any influence from LBOs. Here, too, the specific contribution of PE funds cannot really be proved and one certain effect of LBO-operations is that internal debt in the targeted companies is heavily increased and the future investment capability correspondingly deteriorates. Yet, even if it is assumed that the involvement of private equity investors in some cases can actually improve the efficiency of a business by breaking the managerial decision-making and supervisory monopoly, this statement frequently does not tell the whole story. In many instances, costs are not ultimately reduced but are merely offloaded by the company onto a third party. This means that, although the enterprise saves on labour costs by cutting jobs, it is not automatically strengthening the companys dynamics, qualifications and motivations. And it is effectively burdening society with the cost of the unemployment it creates. Small and medium-sized enterprises are caught in a dilemma. Because of the tighter creditworthiness requirements to be imposed on companies by the new rules on capital adequacy for financial institutions (Basel II), there will be more cases in which businesses can no longer obtain any credit from their banks, or can only borrow at very expensive rates. For such businesses equity investments most constructively in the form of venture capital often seem to be the only means of obtaining the capital they need to convert research findings or innovations into commercial products. It is also asserted that SMEs preferred source of funding, namely bank loans, are not suited to this purpose, since the risk of failure is high, and small businesses cannot provide the requisite security. Since many small and medium-sized enterprises have no access to the capital market either, private equity, in the form of venture capital, is an ideal way to bridge the gap. Existing owners may even preserve their own entrepreneurial autonomy if contracts are so formulated34. Unfortunately, venture capital funds play very little part in the total of PE fund operations in Europe. LBO investors, on acquisition of a listed company, generally have a short-term to medium-term stake meaning that the capital is not permanently available to the company. This creates comparative problems when long-term investment has to be decided and financed. Moreover, current examples testify to the fact that LBO-managers have high expectations of a companys short-term growth and profit potential. LBO investments are not suitable as a bridging facility to deal with cash-flow problems, and certainly could not serve as a universal solution to the shortage of equity among small and medium-sized businesses. Furthermore, acquired companies are themselves often dissatisfied with the contribution of LBO funds. This finding emerged from a study conducted by Wiesbaden University of Applied Sciences (Fachhochschule Wiesbaden) in 2003 on behalf of the private-equity firm Cornerstone Capital. The study examined the contribution of private-equity investors to increases in the value of companies. The researchers surveyed companies in which a LBO fund manager held shares and which had been sold within the previous four years. The respondents confirmed that the main contributions made by LBO investors were in the domains of finance, accounting and reporting. By contrast, 70% stated that they had received no support for the improvement of processes and structures. Cornerstone managing partner Pieter van Halem summarised the findings of the study by saying it showed that most LBO investors still saw themselves as providers of capital but were unable to offer any genuine strategic benefits35.
34 35
See German Private Equity and Venture Capital Association (BVK), Hintergrundinformation No 2, March 2004. See Brsen-Zeitung of 20 September 2003, p. 9.
105
Splitting up a business which has been taken over by selling off parts or individual assets. Cf. Die ZEIT of 12.5.2005, p. 28.
106
Here is a quite well known flow of decisions used by LBO funds to maximize their cash flow: Normally the target company is bought by a series of local holding companies. Each holding company is partly debt financed and owned by the next holding company, and the upper local holding company is owned by a Luxembourg holding company.
In the case study of Viterra it is described how 90 % of the leverage buyout was financed by loans an unusual high percentage for the purchase of stakes in a company.
The Luxembourg holding company is owned by the private equity fund, which is normally a limited partnership domiciled in an off shore centre. The limited partnership will distribute the profit of the investment to the participants in the partnership (the investors of the private equity fund). Soon after the acquisition of the target company, it is taken private and de-listed at the stock exchange. One of the purposes of this exercise is to avoid the disclosure regulations of a publicly listed company. Soon after the acquisition the balance sheet of the target company is pressed for liquidity, both in terms of assets and by new loans in the target company. All this money is distributed as dividend to the holding company, which is the direct owner of the target company. This holding company has often arranged bridge financing, and this bridge financing is redeemed. The direct holding company can also distributed the received dividend to the next holding company, which can redeem their financing or just pay the interest on its loan. By this the target company is in reality self-financing its own take-over. However, this type of financing is not only arranged through dividends. The takeover process included substantial expenses to financial advisers, lawyers and other consultants. Often the expenses of a take-over are about 5% of the sum of the acquisition of the target company. Traditionally such expenses should be paid by the buyer, but in cases of a leverage buy-out, the LBO manager decides that the target company will have to pay these expenses. This type of financing, where the target company actually pays for its own take over, is of course not without consequences. The target company will be much more dependent on the general economic climate, and it will have problems financing necessary investment for new markets and new products, innovations and R&D.
Part II Six concerns about our European social market economy
107
The increased level of debt resulting from LBOs leads to large-scale tax avoidance and a concomitant loss of revenue for the state. This in turn results in a reduction in state investment in infrastructure and education. It also leads to further weakening of the viability of state social security. LBO operations also require increased state expenditure due to job losses and reductions in purchasing power, placing additional burdens on government. If average job losses total 4% in a secondary buyout, we will see further examples of the social and fiscal consequences of the growing number of tertiary buy-outs as the exit cycle speeds up. *** Advocates of these financing models defend the high leverage ratios of business acquisitions by arguing that loans make sound business sense. Interest paid on these funds can be claimed as business expenditure, which reduces a companys liability for corporation tax and municipal trade tax. Besides, the debt is not serviced from the companys hidden reserves but from its free cash flow38. But this is a very narrow-minded and fragmented LBO argument. The fact is that LBO burdens the companies with the cost of borrowing the funds and companies ultimately fund the acquisition themselves and are heavily indebted as a result. According to the rating agency Fitch Ratings, the indebtedness of European companies acquired by private-equity firms has risen sharply. In the first quarter of 2005, Fitch Ratings assessed the liabilities assumed by companies at 5.5 times the value of their cash flow; this figure had peaked at 5.6 times cash flow in the fourth quarter of 2004. Major damage to national economies cannot be ruled out, should the private equity sector overheat many investment banks, rating agencies, central banks and even representatives of the sector itself could suffer. Risks could thus affect the banks involved in financing, or if they securitise these loans other capital market agents. And suddenly, we see the hedge funds and LBOs enforcing each other in a very unhealthy way: To a certain extent, the latter are hedge funds which already operate in high-risk areas, which could cause more significant disturbances in the capital markets in the event of LBO investments failing to pay out.
38
108
2.1 Jobs
It is often alleged in the business news pages that PE funds have triggered considerable corporate growth and created many new jobs. However, we are not aware of any serious academic findings that would support this position. Academic studies carried out to date have for the most part been commissioned by groups of investors. They suffer from a lack of representation and are based on scientifically assailable methods and often they wrongly compare various sorts of PE, including venture capital funds. Similarly, they do not separate organic growth from cases of mergers or changes in the macro-economic environment in different reference periods. The previously mentioned PwC study commissioned by the German organisation BVK is one example. The PwC management consultancy had a certain vested interest in the subject of the study, which differed from those of the independent universities. The studys methods were based on the evaluation of questionnaires sent to PE companies and their target enterprises. This raises doubts as to the reliability and objectivity of the answers and therefore the study as a whole. If the private equity market is broken down into the categories of seed, start-up, expansion/growth, turnaround and buyout, the examining institution concedes that in the instances of turnaround (the rescue of enterprises declared to be in critical difficulty), start-ups and buyouts (the most important segment), the rates of return are so low that no statistically valid statements are possible. It can generally be said that studies of the effects of LBO investments involve uncertainties. Hence the variables which, together with private equity, affect companies growth and the provision of jobs cannot really be checked. However, studies such as those referred to, for which many other examples can be given, have often been quoted in the press and used to support the ostensibly very positive effects of private equity. Representatives of the PE industry and institutions cooperating with them frequently give the impression that jobs are being created by the funds in PE funds target enterprises. It should, however, be pointed out that these jobs are only being recreated they were as a rule already in existence prior to the PE commitment.
In the case study of Friedrich Grohe it is described how 770 jobs are to be cut. In the case study of Viterra it is described how the plan is to sack a total of 500 of employees more than a quarter of the entire work force.
109
The case studies in this report show some negative effects on jobs. The example of the German company Grohe shows that in the private equity business a particular combination of various factors in this instance a secondary sale (increased pressure on the rate of return), an exorbitant level of debt and market slumps can lead to job losses. Even with PE commitments in a relatively good market situation and a stable company (take the investor KKRs involvement in MTU Aero Engines in Germany), PE funds take job cuts immediately into account. Exceptional cases in the PE sectors include KKRs takeover of the Linde-owned forklift division Kion in the autumn of 2006, in which the investor is continuing with the guarantee of jobs previously negotiated up to 2011 between the management and works council. If HFs and LBOs have brought uncertainty to the financial markets, their effect on jobs, while less documented, has been doubly severe. The stereotype of the private equity firm is not one that sits well with sustainable, decent employment. And the decisions on job cuts are made unilaterally and absent from public reporting, absent from social dialogue and only looking to the short term. The focus of the new LBO managers is commonly seen to be around the core business, resulting in the sale of saleable assets also in the group. This inevitably leads to even more job losses. On a more general level, the pressure exerted by private equity and particularly hedge funds, makes the collapse of a leveraged buy-out or a company with high alternative investment very likely. This is something that analysts have predicted for some time in connection to the debate on systemic risks39. The consequence for job losses would be serious. By making contingencies for and, in some cases, actively encouraging the falling share price, hedge fund managers are putting employment directly at risk. The industry itself often claims value-adding or job creation effects from private equity. Unfortunately, this is a disingenuous claim in the most part. While it is true that in some private equity buy-outs, the LBO managers see the value of expanding the company in advance of their exit, in the majority of cases full-time, sustainable jobs are lost. Job growth figures are constructed from the plethora of advisers, assistants and consultants brought in by the new LBO managers as well as from the creation of low-skill, often temporary and sometimes precarious employment (customer-based operations).
39
See, for example, The Financial Times UK watchdog warns collapse of big buy-out is inevitable 7 November 2006 and FSA sounds alarm on private equity 6 November 2006. Monks, J The Challenge of the New Capitalism Annual Bevan Lecture, Trade Union Congress, 14 November 2006.
40
110
The pension funds of companies being taken over by LBO are at risk of a deterioration in value if through recaps, special dividends or high consulting fees the companies are no longer in a position to finance pension funds. This is even worse if the pension fund is already under funded. *** As a rule, LBO investors very quickly begin to trim working conditions after entry in order to achieve greater efficiency and productivity. Thus the financial investor KKR announced, immediately after its entry into Kion, the forklift division formerly owned by Linde, in a case that was relatively positive for employees, that the latter had to work extra shifts each week in order to make greater use of the production lines.
In the case study of Autoteile Unger it is described how the working hours have been lengthened from 37 to 40 hours per week as a result of the buy-out.
In the vast majority of existing examples new owners have withdrawn from social dialogue and, in some cases, failed to honour existing collective agreements. LBOs have little or no experience in dealing with organised labour unions or employee representatives and often fail to live up to even the most basic requirements on information and consultation and restructuring41. Trade unions often have great difficulty in establishing a negotiating relationship owing to the mystery of who is genuinely in charge of the company.
In the case study of BTC it is described how the UNI-Europa and the ETUC complained to the Bulgarian government due to BTCs failure to respect its commitments according to the Bulgarian Labour Code and European directives on information and consultation of workers.
One example of this lack of transparency from the commerce/retail sector, where alternative investment is already prevalent is Somerfield Stores. Following purchase by the Apax group and subsequent de-listing from the stock exchange, Somerfield decided to withdraw from the Ethical Trading Initiative (a multi-stakeholder alliance including retailers, NGOs and trade unions), in order to reconsider short- and medium-term business priorities42. Europe already faces growing skills and training shortages, something likely to be exacerbated by the increasing prominence of alternative investment. The European Commission has already highlighted certain areas where skills shortages are of the most concern, notably ICT. Short-term approaches from equity groups threaten workers commitment to their company and their willingness to upgrade their company-specific skills. The failure of equity-backed companies to consider the long-term makes inward investment in training and personal innovation highly unlikely. The same can be said for boards under hedge-fund pressure. Sadly, the long-term yield from skilling and training workers is all too often seen as expendable in these cases.
41 42
For example, the European directives on collective redundancies (98/59/EC) and information and consultation (2002/14/EC). Schiller, B Trading down corporate responsibility in Ethical Corporation 14 November 2006.
111
In the case study of Gate Gourmet it is described how workers representatives have been let down by investors on a massive scale.
Recently, the fork lift division (Kion) of the German Linde Corporation was sold to a group of private equity funds. In this case co-determination had a notable effect on the deal that was struck. Various buyers also under pressure from CEO Reitzle were forced to present their
112
business plan for Kion to employee representatives. Moreover, the KKR -consortium that finally bought Kion only won the deal because it agreed to sign a contract regarding investments and employment from 2006 to 2011. Unfortunately the case of Kion appears to be an exception. Hedge funds and private equity funds often refuse to recognize their status as an employer, preferring to describe themselves as an asset class that is not bound by any of the legal obligations applicable to employers. Moreover, companies are portrayed as financial objects that are acquired to generate the maximum profit within a short (hedge funds) or medium (private equity funds) time horizon. Because in many EU member states there is strong and obligatory employee involvement from the workplace up to the boardroom, an entire proven system of how to conduct businesses is at risk. In 19 out of 27 EU member states legal provisions on employee board level representation exist for companies with more than 25 employees, as in Sweden, up to those with more than 500 as in Slovenia, Luxembourg and Germany. Having a voice and vote in the boardroom could be used to change the general orientation of decisions by new owners or, at least, to define conditions for a takeover by alternative investors in order to use the co-determination position to limit the worst excesses. Those conclusions were drawn recently (Dec 2006) from the examination of the German co-determination system by the academic members of the Biedenkopf-Commission, mandated officially by the German government. But the possibility of changing decisions on new ownership via intervention in boardrooms should not be overstated. One obstacle to using this more frequently might be that provisions on strong information and consultation, as well as board level representation, are limited to national borders. If a companys registration remains outside then those co-determination provisions do not apply or are blunted. It appears that a great many hedge funds and private equity funds do not see themselves as long-term strategic investors. They have little interest in the relationship with stakeholders such as employee representatives. Instead, there are numerous examples of fund managers who talk and act as if employees were a threat to the creation of shareholder value. This claim is supported by several of the cases presented in this report. In these cases employee representatives describe the relationship with hedge funds and private equity funds as non-existent, minimalist or adversarial (see for example the case studies of Friedrich Grohe and Mobilcom). The main interest of the latter tends to be financial key figures from which decisions about the production and employees can be deducted. The actual production processes, the human resources involved in them and the responsibilities towards employees and employee rights are considered secondary. We believe that this approach is detrimental to the long-term economic viability of companies. Moreover, we believe that the approach conflicts with the idea that possession of companies involves both rights and duties: rights for employees to join trade unions and to negotiate collective bargains with employers; duties to recognise these rights and enter negotiations from the side of the employers. These rights are recognised as fundamental human rights and are set out in a variety of regulatory instruments (Universal Declaration of Human Rights, Conventions of the ILO, etc), which both the EU and its member states are signatories and obliged to implement and defend.
113
In the case study of the DT Group it is described how the company, at the time listed usually declared a dividend at 10 15 mill pr year, while in the following two years after the take over the company declared a special dividend of 200 mill .
The rating agency Fitch makes the criticism that many enterprises run into debt in problematic areas after recapitalisation44. In the summer of 2006 the PE investor Terra Firma arranged for the equity invested in the German motorway services chain Tank & Rast to be repaid to the investor after only 18 months at one and a half times the amount with the help of a new loan, which had been imposed on the company. The high rates of return of PE funds on buyouts are justified by the LBO industry because of the alleged risk they take owing to their capital being committed for longer in a target enterprise, the future prospects of which cannot be accurately calculated. The funds risks, however, have actually been very low because of recapitalisations (recaps). According to a study by the Swiss business consultancy Strategic Capital Management (SCM), recapitalisations already provide 30 per cent of all backflows in the global PE sector45. Because of recapitalisations, funds risks have shifted to the banks providing the loans. In recent years the banks have for their part switched over to securitising loans in tradable securities, thereby transferring the risks to other market participants. Those buying the securities are often hedge funds, in which once again institutional investors and wealthy individuals have a stake, with the latter two ultimately bearing the risk. The rating agency Standard & Poors (S&P) warns that the level of debt of enterprises run for special distributions of funds leads to greater risks of credit loss46. According to S&P data, the number of recapitalisations between 2002 and 2005 increased tenfold to more than US$ 40 billion47. Equity capital is turned into borrowed capital through recapitalisation. This increases the risks for the target enterprises concerned and results in a poorer rating and therefore higher loan costs. All in all, recapitalisation makes the situation of the enterprises concerned considerably worse.
114
Die Aktiengesellschaft 16/2006, p. 579 Idem 45 Financial Times Deutschland 9.8.2006, p. 19 46 Financial Times Deutschland 14.8.2006, p. 18 47 Handelsblatt 15.8.2006, p. 23
44
The combination of increased indebtedness and the payment of extraordinary dividends mean that the capital fund does not need to find much money out of its own pocket to purchase the company. The company is to some extent bought with its own money. The reason why capital funds are able to increase the debt of the purchased company to this extent is that capital funds have the investment commitment of their investors behind them, which they can draw on if needed. This combination of own-capital distribution and resulting increased indebtedness also has a major influence on the amount of tax paid by the company. This is illustrated by the example in box 1 below. In the example, the companys tax payments are brought down by 33%. This brings a double benefit for a capital fund: the fact that a company can practically be bought with its own money and save on tax makes well-cushioned companies a particularly attractive purchase for capital funds. If this happened in a single closed economy, the companys interest expenditure would pop up as interest income in another place and be taxed there. But in a globalised world where loans to companies most frequently come from foreign lenders the state is very rarely able to benefit from this potential tax income. One possible source of tax income might also be from the capital fund and/or its beneficial owner. However, the capital funds themselves or strictly speaking the management companies behind them are often situated in low-tax countries. And the owners are often foreign pension funds.
Company has a total balance of EUR 1 billion. Before purchase, this comprises 80% of own capital, while loans account for 20%. After purchase the ratio changes to 20-80 thanks to payment of an extraordinary dividend and increased borrowing. The economic result of the financial account amounts to EUR 100 million. Assuming that the interest rate is 5% p.a.: Corporation tax before purchase: Result according to financial account (100 1000 x (20% x 0.05)) Corporation tax (90 x 0.28) Corporation tax after purchase: Result according to financial account (100-1000 x (80% x 0.05)) Corporation tax (60 x 0.28) Corporation tax saved after purchase (25.2 16.8)
This opportunity to save on tax by altering the companys capital structure is a result of the way in which corporation tax is constructed. Corporation tax taxes financial income and expenditure in line with the actual net increase in value in other words, the net profit generated by the commercial company in question.
115
The often highly aggressive yield targets of LBO funds mean that strategies to avoid paying tax to the government are used more intensively than by ordinary companies. The tax liability of the target enterprise is noticeably reduced by debt push-down and transfer of the acquisition debts of the funds acquisition vehicle to the target enterprise, which usually takes place via a merger of the target enterprise with the acquisition vehicle. Furthermore, taxation is avoided through the establishment of the PE funds intermediate holdings in countries with low or no tax liability, to which distributions and capital gains are transferred. Germany, for example, has concluded a double taxation agreement with fellow EU Member State Luxembourg. Dividends and capital gains are not taxed in Germany, since the intermediate holding is liable for tax in Luxembourg. And in Luxembourg this intermediate holding is usually exempt from tax.
In the case study of ISS it is described how the joint taxation of the two Danish holding companies and the ISS Danish group company reduces the tax revenue. At the same time the interest of the loans are now deducted from the taxable income of ISS. Finally it is expected, that the ISS from 2006 onwards will no longer pay company tax in Denmark.
Furthermore, the funds in many cases avoid tax by forming tax groups between several enterprises in their portfolio, through which they exchange accumulated losses. Therefore, LBO-fund activities should all in all lead to considerable tax deficits. It may also be noted that liquid assets flow out of Europe into the United States and are ploughed back by institutional investors there. The power to earmark these funds for investment purposes therefore drains away at the same time. Despite the evidence showing a decline in tax revenue, it has been argued by the private equity industry that the interest is instead taxed from the recipients, which in this case are banks and other financial institutions. But this is incorrect. The bank will, of course, only increase their taxable profit by the interest margin, and a lot of interest goes to non-taxable institutions and to institutions in tax havens. Furthermore, as the private equity funds are organised as limited partnerships, no tax regulator can ensure that the profit of the private equity fund is taxed correctly. Of course, most of the investors in the equity funds pay tax according to the tax rules of the domicile country. But in reality the tax authorities have no power to control where and how the profit of the equity fund is taxed. This situation is also very detrimental to the Welfare State in general. It is not just that companies after the buy-out are paying less in tax due to the level of debt but, in addition, dividends are paid mainly to foreign investors not subject to taxation. It is also that when the capital structure of companies is endangered and jobs are lost, the whole society is affected as unemployed people represent a cost for the State. The balanced role of the State in collecting taxes and redistributing wealth is in question in the long run and the issue of increased tax losses will certainly draw the attention of governments. ***
116
The EU has in the past tried to combat tax evasion. Rules of investment in tax havens have been implemented but drafted in such a way that investments in hedge funds and private equity funds are not fully included. The combination of a limited partnership, which is not a taxable body in itself and its domicile in an off shore financial centre, which is often a tax haven, means that the distribution of profit from the hedge fund and the private equity fund to the investors are normally out of the control of the tax authorities of the investor. In nearly all member states of the EU, there is a system of joint taxation. Under the different joint taxation regimes, the members of a group will have the right to be taxed as a group. In practice this means that the holding company or holding companies of the target company will be taxed in a group with the target company. According to EC directive a holding company is not taxed on the profit of the subsidiary when it holds 15 per cent of the subsidiary, and the subsidiary must not take withholding tax on the dividend to such holding companies. If the investments in the subsidiary are financed by debts, the holding company will pay interest, and it will have a negative taxable income a tax loss. But this tax loss will be part of the joint taxation with the target company and be offset in the taxable profit of the target company and it will by this means reduce the corporate tax burden of the target company. Because of the interest expenses of the target company and the interest expenses of the holding companies, which takes part in the group taxation, the corporate tax burden of the target company can be reduced significantly or even to zero.
In the case study of TDC it is described how one conservative estimate suggests that the Danish government will lose some EUR 270m in tax revenue.
The target company, which is forced to pay for many of the costs of the take over, will try to deduct these expenses, in reality the expenses of the purchasing private equity funds, from its taxable income.
Part II Six concerns about our European social market economy
A holding company or an equity fund does not normally pay VAT. But some part of the expenses (advisers fee etc) will be VAT-included. By letting the target company which is normally paying VAT pay the expenses of the take over, the target company will reduce its VAT obligation by the VAT paid on the expenses.
117
Private equity funds have increased their investments tenfold in state-owned companies Year 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 TOTAL Europe: Millions in EUR48 564 1623 1221 2088 7294 2336 5950 21706 Globally: Millions in EUR 1129 1638 1473 2273 7650 2926 10671 27760 Europe: Numbers of transactions 14 18 11 18 18 24 22 125 Globally: Numbers of transactions 17 20 14 27 30 40 46 194
Source: Published in Mandag Morgen the 22.nd of January 2007 based on figures from Thomson Financial
48
The exchange rate used is 100 EUR = 745,41 DKR. (source the 25th of January: http://www.nationalbanken.dk/dndk/valuta.nsf/side/Valutakurser!OpenDocument)
118
119
TDC case, Denmark TDC was taken over by a group of five foreign private equity firm specialists Apax Partners; Blackstone Group; Kohlberg Kravis Roberts; Permira; and Providence Equity in the largest takeover in Europe to date. For about 10.5bn, they purchased 88.2% of TDC shares It was financed by slightly more than 80% debt. Capital management fees are not specified, but experience suggest they will be in the tens of million of euros. The 2005 Annual Report notes significant TDC credit rating downgradings by the Standard and Poor and Moody Investor services as a result of the leverage buyout. The acquisition increases TDCs net debt to total assets ration from 18% to about 90% at interest rates substantially higher than those for the previously established debt. TDCs debt ratio is now 97% of capitalization. The new owners have been deliberately vague about why they have taken over TDC and what their plans are, stating only that they expect to own TDC for about five years. The evidence to date suggests that the TDC takeover has nothing to do with improving the efficiency of TDC. The new owners have no expertise in telecom and are relying virtually entirely on the previous management. The diversified stockholders were long term investors that left the management of the company to the managers. The immediate cash payout of almost half TDCs assets suggests a pretty clear case of asset stripping, and the offering of shares in NTCI to 41 senior executives of TDC provides a major benefit to TDC management for continuing efforts leading to further cash payouts. This is short-term disinvestment, not longterm investment. Observers can be thankful that the only reason all these details about the takeover activities are known is because the new owners were unsuccessful in their attempt to de-list TDC from the transparency requirements for public stock trading.
120
fulfilment of public service responsibilities, where Private Equity Funds are likely to maximise their discretion to minimise expenditure on service delivery; staffing and training where the short-term requirements of Private Equity Funds require significantly fewer resources than traditional infrastructure operators long-term development programs; services pricing strategy, where the long-term market and services development associated with long-term investment strategy of infrastructure operators conflicts with short-term pricing and cash generating strategy of Private Equity Funds. Given that infrastructure provision in some public utilities in some European countries is in need of significant improvement in managerial or operational efficiency, and that the degree of competition they face is relatively weak, one might expect Private Equity Fund take-overs to provide some unambiguous efficiency improvements. However, these same operators need dramatic increases in long-term investment to improve their relatively poor infrastructure networks. The distinctive characteristics and circumstances of infrastructure operators in Europe suggest that Private Equity Fund takeovers are likely to have negative effects on the longstanding public policy objectives for infrastructure operators, i.e., long term efficient infrastructure development in the public interest, and the provision of universal public services of a high quality, for the benefit of the economy and society.
The effect on public finances of the TDC purchase is, as yet, unclear. One conservative estimate, however, suggests that the Danish government will lose some 2 bn in tax revenue.
121
Investments in long-term staff development, research and development, upgrading the quality of service and restoring public service obligations are all likely to be necessary to return infrastructure operations to a level of preparedness for long-term development. Infrastructure operators with significant monopoly power may have to seek higher prices from consumers to help finance the restoring of infrastructure operator standards. In the circumstances of the public utilities, the entry of the Private Equity Funds is unlikely to bring strategies for long-term investment in infrastructure development. Rather it is likely to bring strategies for disinvestment through massive cash payouts. These in turn can be expected to have significant negative multiplier effects on economic growth for the economies dependent on the continued development of these infrastructure services.
122
The importance of Europes transition to an information society is documented in the EU Lisbon Agenda 2010 Information Society initiative launched in June 2006, which is a renewed commitment to the Lisbon reform agenda. It seeks to promote an open and competitive digital economy as well as an integrated approach to information society and audio media policies in the EU. This requires upgraded telecom networks across Europe that can provide the broadband capacity needed for information societies. There are three main priorities for Europes information society and media policies: 1) the completion of a single European information space which promotes an open and competitive internal market for information society and media; 2) strengthening innovation and investment in ICT research to promote growth and more and better jobs; 3) achieving an inclusive European information society that promotes growth and jobs in a manner that is consistent with sustainable development and that prioritises better public services and quality of life49. It is difficult to see how private equity ownership of telecom infrastructure operators will promote these objectives, and experience suggests that in many cases they would be acting contrary to these objectives.
Issues of the financial stability of some large infrastructure operators have risen, affecting their capabilities to invest in long term network development. To illustrate, in 1999 at the height of the dotcom stock market boom, British Telecom, France Telecom, Deutsch Telecom, KPN Netherlands, Vodafone and others all bid extraordinary sums for a limited supply of third generation (3G) mobile spectrum licenses. This raised their debt ratios and interest obligations to such a high level (the managements called them debt mountains) that they had to scale back their 3G investment programmes in major ways, significantly slowing economic growth in both the telecom services and equipment manufacturing sectors and delaying the introduction of new 3G mobile services for several years, until debt mountains were reduced to levels that would support sustained long term development. During this period Europe lost its global leadership in mobile telecom development to Asia, where operator investment plans were not constrained by debt mountains. As a result, investment in new European broadband telecom networks to provide enhanced Internet services for the future information economy, which was anticipated in the Lisbon Agenda targets for economic growth, have been slower than expected.
49
COM (2005) 229 i2010 A European Information Society for growth and employment. p. 4
123
There are three countries where there is experience with PEF takeovers of incumbent telecom operators. Ireland historically has had a relatively inefficient telecom infrastructure and was hoping that privatisation would stimulate significant improvement. Denmark has always had one of Europes leading telecom infrastructures. As a still developing country, Bulgarias telecom infrastructure needs major investment in network development. More detailed information about developments in these countries is provided in the Annex of this report dedicated to Case studies. *** The three country case studies of private equity involvement in the infrastructure providers in the telecom sector in Europe suggest the following: 1) private equity ownership can be attracted to incumbent telecom operators that are efficient (Denmark), inefficient (Ireland), and still in need of fundamental reform and network development (Bulgaria); 2) private equity ownership is not likely to foster a demonstrable efficiency improvement in a relatively inefficient operator, the network modernisation and expansion needed in a still developing country, or the maintenance of the leadership of one of Europes most efficient operators (Denmark); 3) long term investment in network development is not an evident priority of the private equity owners of the operators in any of the countries. Short-term gains from cash payouts and profitably turning around their investments are the priority; 4) the levels of debt left with the companies after the leverage buyout severely constrains long term investment capabilities for the future, and are incompatible with efficient long term investment; 5) private equity ownership is an exercise in disinvestment, the removal of capital, not new investment in growth and development; 6) the management of the utilities may be presented with a serious conflict of interest. Their personal rewards are greatest if they engage in inefficient practices to build cash and cashable assets that will invite private equity owners, facilitate the takeover and share in the very substantial payouts. In some circumstances, this could be a violation of their fiduciary responsibilities to the original public stockholders.
124
125
Indeed, it may well be that much of the added value of hedge funds which seems to have been identified in the past (ie. the investment out performance of the early adopters) has now been competed away by rival firms entering the market. As with many innovations in asset management, the added value lasts only as long as the general market remains unaware of trends (previous examples have included small company investments, momentum and value investing etc). Once the information is disseminated to the rest of the market this value dissipates. Moreover, there is some concern that the claims of out performance have been inflated because of survivorship bias within the universe of funds that have been used to measure performance. For example, investment bank Barclays Capital puts the typical level of overstatement of returns at 1 6 per cent a year, depending on the index51. Analysis produced by Vanguard Investments52, which adjusted the annual returns of the Tremont hedge fund index for the costs identified in Malkiel-Sahas work (see below), suggests that the actual returns achieved by hedge funds fall dramatically and seem to have produced returns well below those achieved by a simple portfolio of 50% bonds and 50% equities (see table below).
Hedge fund return comparison Average annual returns 1994-2003 Tremont hedge fund index: returns without Malkiel-Saha adjustment Tremont hedge fund index: returns with Malkiel-Saha adjustment 50% Dow Jones Wilshire 5000/ 50% Lehman Aggregate 1995-1999 2000-2002 2003
11.11
18.16
4.09
15.47
2.32
9.37
-4.66
6.72
9.30
17.41
-2.10
17.93
It is interesting that the adjusted hedge fund index returns are lower than the mixed portfolio over the whole period and when segmented into bull and bear equity markets.
The key concerns relate to biases that exist in the published indices of hedge fund returns these biases can lead to claims about investment performance being overstated. The main biases are called backfill and selection bias and survivorship bias. Furthermore, there are additional concerns about the persistence of returns and the attrition rates amongst hedge funds. Backfill and selection bias. Hedge funds are often established with seed-capital and will begin reporting on their results at a later date. But backfill and selection bias can occur because hedge fund managers are able to fill back only the most favourable investment returns into an index. This can result in returns being overstated. This effect was demonstrated in a study undertaken by Malkiel and Saha, which examined the hedge fund returns over the period 1995-200353. Malkiel and Saha used the TASS database (a
51 52
53
126
Hedge Funds: Risk and Return, Burton G. Malkiel and Atanu Saha, Financial Analysts Journal, Volume 61, Number 6, 2005, http://www.cfapubs.org/doi/pdfplus/10.2469/faj.v61.n6.2775
unit of Tremont Capital Management) to investigate the characteristics of hedge fund returns, and compared the backfilled returns with those that were contemporaneously reported to TASS. They concluded that the use of backfilled returns significantly biases the returns upwards. The arithmetic mean of the backfilled returns over the period 1994-2003 was 11.69%, while the mean for the contemporaneously reported returns was 5.95% a difference of 5.74%. Survivorship bias: This can occur because the published indices may not include the returns from hedge funds that previously existed but are not currently in existence (known as dead funds), or funds that do exist but no longer report their results (defunct funds). In the study mentioned above, Malkiel and Saha examined the effect of this survivorship bias by comparing the annual returns achieved by live funds with a universe of live and defunct funds over the period 1996-2003. The study found that the arithmetic mean of the annual returns of the live funds was 13.74% for the period whereas the arithmetic mean for all the funds (live and defunct) was 9.32% a difference of 4.42% over the period.54 All indices face problems with survivorship bias. However, Malkiel and Saha report that survivorship bias produced an overstatement of returns of 1.23% in mutual funds, compared to the 4.42% for hedge funds Attrition rates the proportion of funds that fail to survive is another cause for concern. Malkiel and Saha found that hedge fund attrition rates are three or four times greater than the mutual fund rates over the period 1994-2003, and the differences are highly significant. Risk and volatility: The other main perceived benefit of hedge funds relates to risk. Hedge funds tend to exhibit low standard deviations (volatility) and correlation with general equity indices offering significant potential for diversification. However, the investors need to be concerned about the risk of choosing a poor performing fund (known as cross-sectional distribution of returns).Malkiel and Saha examined the cross-sectional standard deviation of different hedge fund categories over the period 1996-2003. They found that the standard deviation of hedge fund returns is considerably higher than it was for mutual funds. In other words, the range of returns is much higher so while investors face high rewards for selecting top-performing funds, they also face a high risk of picking a dismal performer. Moreover, while the reported volatility of hedge fund returns appears to be comparatively low, care needs to be taken as concerns have been raised about valuation methodologies. These may result in the volatility of returns being understated. Valuation of assets: Concerns have been raised about the plausibility of the investment returns claimed by hedge fund managers because of the way assets are valued within hedge fund portfolios55. Traditional fund managers who invest in listed company shares do not face significant challenges when trying to obtain independent, fair value, and transparent portfolio valuations which reflect accurately the liquidity of the market in those shares. This may not necessarily be the case with hedge funds a survey by the Alternative Investment Management Association (AIMA) conducted in Q4 2004 estimated that 20% of assets held by hedge funds are hard to value securities. This figure relates to the market generally. Many hedge funds offer strategies focusing on specialist markets such as emerging markets so it would be possible for non-diversified hedge funds to be 100% exposed to hard-to-value securities. This raises issues in relation to governance, conflicts of interest, transparency and disclosure but also raises the possibility that investment performance may be artificially inflated by unrealistic portfolio valuations.
54 55
See Table 3, p83 and Table 4, p84 of report published in Financial Analysts Journal, Volume 61, Number 6, 2005
See Hedge Funds: Are their returns plausible. Speech by Dan Waters, Sector Leader Asset Management, Financial Services Authority, NAPF Conference, 16 March 2006
127
With regards to diversification benefits, it is not clear that hedge funds offer an intrinsic advantage over traditional asset management techniques that use diversification although to be fair it may be that in some cases hedge funds can offer a more cost effective way of executing that diversification. Therefore, overall it is not clear that hedge funds offer such added value potential for investors that it is imperative for EC policymakers to aggressively liberalise the market so that consumers can have access to these funds. After all, consumers are not exactly deprived of choice of retail investment funds in the UK alone there are 2,000 retail funds which invest solely or predominantly in UK shares yet only 800 shares in the main benchmark FTSE All Share Index which accounts for about 95% of the market capitalisation of the UK stock market. Choice per se is not necessarily beneficial for consumers, quality of choice is more important than the number of choices available. In complex markets, proliferation of products leads to oversupply which actually leads to distribution costs being pushed up unlike other consumer markets where oversupply leads to downward pressure on costs to consumers.
128
contractual issues e.g. Lock-in periods; weak legal and governance structures, and conflicts of interest which compound disclosure problems; prudential and corporate risks; tax and jurisdiction issues; conduct of business issues e.g. marketing, promotional activities, investor communications; intermediary competence complex investments require higher levels of intermediary competence and skills (intermediaries in this case being pension fund trustees, pension fund managers, collective investment scheme managers, financial advisers and sales staff); market distortions conflicts of interest have always existed in capital markets. But the nature of alternative investment funds (e.g. the use of performance related investment fees and investment tactics such as short-selling) and the current operational environment means that these conflicts of interest are magnified actions of the fund managers/ investors have the capacity to exert a major distorting effect on the investment chain. If these concerns are not managed properly, they give rise to a number of potential detriments for consumers and other stakeholders in the investment chain: unforeseen or unrecognised prudential/ capital risks; unexpected fluctuations in capital, volatility issues; misselling risks such as unsuitable or inappropriate product sales, expectations with regard to risk and reward not being understood; access to capital may be restricted because contractual terms, product design and fund risks are not understood; informational problems undermine effective competition with the result that there is a huge proliferation of fund managers charging high fees (compared to conventional asset management fees); performance expectations not met which can have serious consequences for pension scheme funding; the existence of alternative investment funds adds another layer in the investment chain. The extent to which current alternative investment funds market adds value is not clear. the operation and behaviour of alternative investment funds can have a destabilising effect on company performance and employee futures. Investors (owners of capital) such as retail investors or pension scheme beneficiaries may be unaware of the consequences of fund manager behaviour because of gaps in the reporting regime; alternative investment funds undermine market accountability. It is more difficult for ordinary investors (in many cases the ultimate owners of investment capital) to exert influence on markets investors have less say in decisions about how their investment capital is used. This has implications for regulation particularly with regards to promotions and marketing. It suggests that EU regulators would need to intervene to ensure that the information presented to consumers and their representatives is fair, accurate and not misleading. Otherwise, this will undermine the objectives of: promoting an appropriate degree of consumer protection; effective allocation of resources; and promoting justified confidence in the financial system. However, many of the key issues relating to the operation and security of hedge funds are outside the control of EU policymakers and regulators. This raises concerns about the legal protection and redress available to investors in the event of a hedge fund failing.
Part II Six concerns about our European social market economy
129
130
As many jurisdictions require beneficiary representation on the governing body of pension funds a representation that almost systematically falls on the shoulders of trade unions the role of the labour movement in contributing to the needed regulatory responses is indispensable. Part III sets out a series of proposals for regulating the alternative investment funds market to deal with these risks and detriments in a proportionate manner.
131
Stiglitz, J. (2000): Capital market liberalization, economic growth, and instability, in World Development, Vol. 28, No. 6, pp. 1075-1086.
Wall Street Journal (Phil Izzo) (2006, Oct. 13): Economic forecasting survey. Getting a grip on hedge fund risk, http://online.wsj.com/public/article/SB116058289284889490-P5gz1td28WJajNheo7gAUEzUtkY_20071012.html?mod=rss_free (16.11.2006). ECB (2006): Financial Stability Review, http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/other/financialstabilityreview200606en.pdf, p. 142 (12.11.2006)
58 59
FSA (2005): Hedge funds: A discussion of risk and regulatory engagement, http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pages/library/policy/dp/2005/05_04.shtml, item 3.2/p. 19 (06.11.2006).
60
132
E.g. speech by Sir John Gieve (Deputy Governor, Bank of England) at the 2006 Hedge Conference, http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2006/speech285.pdf (13.11.2006)
Expert Group claims with strikingly few references to empirical evidence that the LTCM crisis has prompted the tightening up of controls as investment banks have significantly improved the way in which they manage their exposures to hedge funds.61 Who is right? In the following we will argue that the crisis of LTCM and other hedge funds has proved to be only a temporary setback for the long-term growth of the hedge fund industry. In addition, several of the factors that played a central role in the LTCM crisis remain. Last but not least, regulators still find themselves in a situation with an enormous lack of transparency and reliable data on which to base informed decisions about threats. Consequently, it is difficult to take proportionate regulatory action to prevent or counter such treats. For these reasons, we side with those who believe that hedge funds have created substantial threats to global financial stability, threats for which there are currently too few remedies. We will return to the remedies, i.e. recommendations for voluntary and regulatory action in Part III. Thus the focus of this chapter and our fifth and last major concern is on the threats that hedge funds pose to financial stability. To structure the analysis, it seems useful to distinguish between six factors explaining why hedge funds may pose threats to financial stability. These factors are often related, meaning that a financial crisis may be escalated through mutual links among several factors. For instance, market risk, liquidity risks and leverage may interact. Ideally, a risk assessment ought to analyse such potential patterns of interaction. Yet, this is beyond the scope of this chapter. Here we will have to deal with the factors separately. The factors that we will deal with are:
1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Risk taking in the context of growing competition and high performance fees Growing assets under management Short selling Increasing correlations Concentration on less liquid markets High leverage and concentration in complex derivative products
Before we turn to our analysis of these factors two points ought to be made. First, it should be emphasised that some of these factors apply to both hedge funds and private equity funds. Thus, private equity funds may also pose threats to financial stability. However, we believe that the most alarming threats stem from the hedge fund industry. Consequently, this industry is the sole focus of this chapter. Secondly, hedge fund size and strategies vary a lot (see also part I). This in turn means that the threats hedge funds pose to financial stability vary a lot. It is beyond the scope of this chapter to make detailed descriptions of these variations and assess their implications on financial stability. Instead, we are forced to deal with a more generalised model of hedge funds.
5.1 Risk taking in the context of growing competition and high performance fees
More regulated financial institutions are normally reluctant to be exposed to the kind of risk to which many hedge funds expose themselves. By contrast, hedge funds have always tended to be risk takers in a number of markets. This is particularly the case in complex markets, where risks are difficult to quantify and hedge funds have a competitive edge because of their often superior models. The credit derivatives market that we turn to further below is just one example of such a complex market. There are several reasons why hedge funds and their managers are more prone to take risks. In this section we will address two important ones: the extensive use of performance fees in the remuneration packages of hedge fund managers and increasing competition in the hedge fund industry.
61
European Commission (2006): Report of the Alternative Investment Expert Group: Managing, Servicing and Marketing Hedge funds in Europe, http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/securities/docs/ucits/reports/hedgefunds_en.pdf, p. 12 (08.11.2006).
133
The rising number of active hedge funds is due to rising demand for hedge fund products. Yet, explanations of this ought also to focus on the supply side. Here management fees often seem to be considerably higher than for instance the fees paid to mutual fund managers. In an ironic comment on this point, Financial Time journalist Stephen Schurr recently wrote that It may take a genius to run a hedge fund successfully on the long haul but it does not take a genius to recognize that running a hedge fund with a 2 per cent management fee and a 20 percent performance fee is a better option than slugging it out at a mutual fund62. Normally, the hedge fund manager will receive both a management fee and a performance fee, with the latter playing the predominant role. As with other investment funds, the management fee is computed as a percentage of assets under management. Management fees might typically be 2 per cent but may range from 0 to 5 per cent. The typical performance fee amounts to at least 20 per cent of the gains above a specified benchmark over a comparatively short period of 3 to 12 months. Usually, the benchmark for the calculation of performance fees is the hedge funds net asset value at the beginning of the measurement period. Yet, sometimes the performance fees are levied only after a so-called performance hurdle such as the short- term interest rate has been met. It is also not un-common to link the payment of performance fees to so called high water marks. This means that a hedge fund manager does not receive incentive fees unless the value of the fund exceeds the highest value it has previously achieved. From the point of view of investors, this measure is intended to link the managers interests more closely to those of investors and to reduce the incentive for managers to seek volatile trades. Thus, if a high water mark is not used, a fund that ends alternate years at 100 and 110 would generate performance fees every other year, enriching the manager but not the investors. Performance fees of the types described here tend to encourage investment strategies that increase the probability of exceeding comparatively high return benchmarks. Such strategies are most likely to entail greater risk, risk that in the advent of failure could spark a crisis. Risk taking is also likely to be closely linked with competition in the hedge fund industry. In the recent decade, the hedge fund market has grown at a staggering pace in terms of the number of active hedge funds that we will turn to here and in terms of the assets under management, which we will return to further below (see table below). Hedge Fund Assets under Management and Number of Hedge Funds, 1950-200563
1000$ 900$ 800$ 700$
5,500 4,800 4,000 3,500 3,000 3,200 2,800 2,080 1,640 880 1 30 140 $3 $2 30 100 $20 $35 $50 1,100 $97 $99 $76 $130 $221 $210 $408 $324 $564 $592 7,000 $795 5,700 $934 8,050
Assets in billions
Jan-50 Jan-60 Jan-71 Jan-74 Jan-87 Jan-92 Jan-93 Jan-94 Jan-95 Jan-96 Jan-97 Jan-98 Jan-99 Jan-00 Jan-01 Jan-02 Jan-03 Jan-04 Jan-05
62
Financial Times (Stephen Schurr) (2006): Hedge funds need to sober up soon, July 3, p. 6.
134
63
The rising number of hedge funds appears to go hand in hand with increasing competition between hedge funds. The market for those hedge funds pursuing arbitrage strategies is but one example of this. Here, a massive inflow of money managed by a growing number of hedge funds appears to have competed away many arbitrage opportunities. Due to increasing competition hedge fund managers have engaged in a search for alternative ways to maintain or increase yields in a market where average yields seem to be sloping downwards. In this context, many hedge fund managers are likely to consider investment opportunities involving more risk than was the case in the past. At least this is what has happened in the past, for instance in the early 1970s. In his recent book Hedge Hogging, the hedge fund and Wall Street veteran Barton Biggs describes the years from 1970 to 1973 as a period in which increasing competition led many hedge fund managers to take ever greater risks, with facile hedges. As a consequence () many hedge funds crashed and burned because they were really just leveraged long funds and as a result suffered huge declines, Biggs writes, adding Other funds had bought private equity-venture deals that turned out to be totally illiquid when things got tough.64 This process of rise and fall does not seem to be historically unique. For instance, the period between 1995 and 2002, a period characterised by first an upward and later a downward sloping market had a failure rate of 32% among funds with assets under management lower than $ 50 million. The same happened to around two thirds of funds of a size between $ 50 million and $ 150 million. This percentage decreases significantly to less than 4% in the case of funds with more than $ 150 million assets under management. The highest failure rates are found in the field of managed futures (derivatives) that we turn to further below. By contrast, convertible arbitrage and event driven strategies appear to have considerably lower failure rates.65 Since 2002 the market has been sloping gradually upward for developed markets and rapidly upward for emerging markets, e.g. South-East Asia. Yet, this process might stop once more and lead to large-scale failures. It is difficult to assess when this could happen. And in the absence of regulation it is most likely that the failures will repeat themselves. Moreover, the failures may have a much more profound impact on financial stability than we have seen in the past. This is not least due to some of the factors that will be addressed in the rest of this chapter, among them the growing amount of assets under management.
Part II Six concerns about our European social market economy
The Presidents Working Group on Financial Markets (1999): Hedge Funds, Leverage, and the Lessons of Long-Term Capital Management, http://www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/reports/hedgfund.pdf, p. viii (17.11.2006).
135
Based on this observation, one could conclude that the potential impact of failing hedge funds remains small. By contrast, the FSA argues that a hedge fund with say $1 billion of assets under management may have a far greater market impact than a traditional investment fund with the same amount of assets under management.67 Besides the absolute and relative growth in the assets under management, this is due to several of the factors that we turn to in the next subsections.
Wall Street Journal (2006): Double trouble valuing the hedge-fund industry, July 8/9, 2006, p. B3. FSA (2005): ibid., item 3.29.
Financial Stability Forum (2000): Report of the Working Group on Highly Leveraged Institutions, http://www.fsforum.org/publications/Rep_WG_HLI00.pdf (02.12.2006) E.g. Counterparty Risk Management Policy Group (2005): Toward greater financial stability: A private sector perspective, July, p. 48.
136
69
time peak in 2005. It is important to note the fact that correlations are rising not only within some strategies, but also among strategies, raising concerns that some triggering event could lead to highly correlated exits. Furthermore, the ECB has stressed that the levels reached in late 2005 exceeded those that prevailed just before the near-collapse of the LTCM 70.
Medians of pair wise correlation coefficients of monthly hedge fund returns within strategies
(Jan. 1995-Dec. 2005, monthly net of all returns in USD)
0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Fund of funds Convertible arbitrage (3%) Long/short equity hedge (32%) Multi-strategy (13%)
Sources: ECB Financial Stability Review, June 2006. (Numbers in parentheses after strategy indicate the share of total capital under management (excluding FOHFs) at the end of 2005.)
There may be a number of reasons for high correlations. In the case of the LTCM crisis (see box 1) many of the virtual, statistical models used by hedge funds and other players in financial markets led to the same kind of behaviour. In the case of LTCM it also seems as if the brokers, who received order flow information through their dealings with LTCM, took similar positions alongside their client. In the more recent case of the hedge fund Amaranth (see box 2), the reason for its default does not appear to lie especially in excess of leverage but in an unsatisfactory management approach, which underestimated the correlation among different bets and the problematic concentration on a single thin market like the market for natural gas. Amaranths position represented a significant share of the whole market. Consequently, it was difficult to unwind the funds portfolio when things begun to get worse. Despite the increasing correlations, the more recent default of the hedge fund Amaranth did not appear to have threatened or even influenced financial market stability (see box 2). Thus, there has been an absolute absence of contagion spreads over the other financial markets: No volatility spikes were registered during September 2006, neither on the stock markets, nor on the bond markets. Furthermore, the commodity market itself did not show any sign of fear as the ordinary price behaviour of the CRB index in September 2006 testifies. Nonetheless the absence of contagion spreads in the Amaranth case is no assurance that hedge funds have become any more robust. One of several important differences to the LTCM crisis of 1998 was the situation of global financial markets. In 1998 they were under extreme stress in the aftermath of the Russian crisis. In 2006 they were awash with cash after many years of loose monetary policy.
70
137
138
139
73 The Presidents Working Group on Financial Markets (1999): Hedge Funds, leverage, and the lessons of Long-Term Capital Management, http://www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/reports/hedgfund.pdf, p. viii (17.11.2006). See also Krugman, P. (1999): The Return of Depression Economics, London: Allen Lane. 74 75
140
ECB (2005): Occasional Paper No. 34, August 2005, p. 32f. The conclusions made by the ECB have also been reached by McGuire et al. (2005) from the BIS.
gies, size and age. For instance, it is worth noting that the hedge funds with the largest amount of assets under management also seem to operate with relatively high levels of leverage. Contrary to the FSA and ECB, the German Bundesbank has warned against a growing use of leverage76. The latter view is supported by several observers of the financial markets. In a cautionary essay from April 2006 the renowned hedge fund manager Jonathan Bailey wrote that hedge funds have rarely been longer, more levered and less hedged than they are today.77 In a comment from January 2007 Financial Times, editor Gillian Tett made a similar point. In addition, she suggested that much of the rising leverage and leverage risk remains undisclosed because hedge funds obtain leverage in ways that are difficult for outsiders to monitor and comprehend (see box 3). Why is there such a significant difference in the assessments of the current levels of leverage and leverage risk in the hedge fund industry? Indeed, it might be as Gillian Tett suggests that we experience an unnoticed boom in leverage and risk without knowing it, because the boom is occurring in an area where there is little available information. In addition, there are a number of possible measures of, and methodological problems with the measurement of leverage.78 To understand this argument it seems helpful to take a closer look at the concept and sources of leverage. Leverage (or gearing) can be defined as the use of given resources in such a way that the potential positive outcome of the use is magnified. Thus, leverage allows greater potential return to the investor than otherwise would have been available. However, the potential for loss is also greater because loans and other sources of leverage need to be repaid. The classic source of leverage is loans. Yet, there are also a number of other ways to obtain leverage. According to the ECB hedge funds tend to prefer, a) arrangements where positions are established by posting margins rather than the full value of a position, or b) derivatives. By contrast, direct credit in the form of loans is rather uncommon, although credit lines for liquidity purposes are widely used.79 Generally, margin buying and derivatives offer the greatest possibility to capitalise on leverage. Yet, margin buying and derivatives are also likely to be associated with much greater risks. Moreover, the risks inherent in these activities may not be fully recognized. A look at derivatives and the market for credit derivatives can serve to illustrate this point. Derivatives allow leverage without borrowing explicitly. However the risk of borrowing is implicit in the price of the derivative. Derivatives such as futures, options and swaps are financial instruments derived from some other asset. Rather than trading or exchanging an asset itself, market participants enter into an agreement to exchange or to have the possibility to exchange money, assets or some other value at some future date. A simple example is a futures contract, i.e. an agreement to exchange the underlying asset at a future date. The markets for derivatives are generally growing at an extraordinary pace. This is not least the case with the market for credit derivatives. Credit derivatives allow default risk to be transferred without modifying the legal ownership of the underlying assets and without having to refinance the loan. As a result, this market is booming and notional amounts outstanding rose from less than $ 1,000 billion in 2001 to $ 26,000 billion at the end of June 2006.80 Hedge funds are increasingly active in the markets for credit derivatives. Fitch Ratings estimates their share of derivatives trading at 25%. In addition, it is assumed that hedge funds trade mainly in the riskiest segments of the market.81
76 Deutsche Bundesbank (2006): Risiken im Finanzsystem. Herausforderungen fr die Bankenaufsicht, in Festvortrag von Dr. h. c . Edgar Meister (Mitglied des Vorstandes der Deutschen Bundesbank) anlsslich der ordentlichen Generalversammlung der sterreichischen Bankwissenschaftlichen Gesellschaft in Wien am Montag, 16. Oktober 2006, http://www.bundesbank.de/download/presse/reden/2006/20061016_meister.pdf (05.01.2007). 77 78 79 80 81
Bailey, J. (2006): Hedgehog, Wealth Management Survey (Spear Media), April Edition. ECB (2005): ibid., p. 30f. ECB (2005): ibid., p. 28f. Banque de France, Financial Stability Review, No. 9, December 2006, p. 18.
Fitch Ratings (2006): Global Credit Derivatives Survey: Risk Dispersion Accelerates, http://www.fitchratings.com/corporate/search/results.cfm (15.01.2007, subject to fee).
141
Generally credit derivatives serve the transfer risk from one party to another. One party gets rid of (or hedges) credit risk while the other party takes on the risk with the possibility of making a profit or a loss. The possibility of transferring risks has encouraged banks, in particular the largest ones, to change their behaviour substantially. Thus, they have started moving from strategies in which they kept credit risk on their balance sheets for several years, to strategies in which they trade with risk or pass it on to other players in the financial market. This allows them to shift to activities that generate fees and commissions (consultancy, intermediation and structured finance activities). At the same time risks are spread among more (new) players in financial markets, including hedge funds. On the one hand, credit derivatives may make a significant contribution to the improvement of risk allocation. Greater risk dispersion among financial market players may also reduce the vulnerability of the financial system as a whole. The Banque de France for instance argues that the latter was corroborated by the fact that no systemic impact was observed on credit markets in the wake of the difficulties experienced in 2005 by large corporate issuers such as General Motors and Ford, whose ratings were downgraded and Delphi, which went bankrupt. These shocks were limited, admittedly, but no spill-over was observed, volatility remained in check and market82. On the other hand, the trade of credit derivatives (and other derivatives) have generated a hitherto unseen opacity in the financial system. On the other hand, the trade of credit derivatives (and other derivatives) have generated an hitherto unseen opacity in the financial system. The opacity is first and foremost due to the fact that most transactions are conducted in so-called over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives. OTC-derivatives are traded (and privately negotiated) directly between two parties, without going through an exchange or other intermediary. Currently, the issuing and trade of OTC-derivatives is not recorded in a centralised manner. Moreover, risks are usually transferred by banks, which are regulated and transparent, to entities that are barely regulated or not regulated at all and are not required to disclose their positions. While risk from these transactions may appear to be widely distributed it is often impossible for regulators and market participants to ascertain the identity or situation of the ultimate risk holders. Finally, a number of additional factors makes it very difficult to analyse the sparse information available and if required to take timely action. The most important factors are the enormous size of the broader derivatives market and the more narrow market for credit derivatives, the high velocity with which derivatives are traded, the complexity of the derivatives issued and the opacity of the strategies pursued with the derivatives. In sum, it is disputed that the use of leverage and the risk stemming from it has declined. We have argued that a boom in leverage and risk may go by unnoticed, because the boom is occurring in areas characterised by great opacity, e.g. the market for credit derivatives. If indeed the level of leverage has declined slightly, the potential for forced sales of hedge fund positions in the context of crisis may be lower today than it was at the time of the LTCM crisis. Yet, even with a lower level of leverage, there are situations where even more moderate price swings could force hedge funds to sell their leveraged positions to meet margin calls, potentially leading to a domino effect across markets. Moreover, much lending is short term, which in combination with high leverage, further decreases the ability to wait until a possible price recovery.
82
142
143
144
force a hedge fund to default on its obligations to prime brokers and other financial institutions thereby setting in motion a domino effect threatening financial stability. Having summarised the hedge fund related factors that we believe could pose a threat to financial market stability we would like to emphasise the great lack of information regarding many of these factors. Without transparency and reliable data it is difficult to take make informed conclusions about threats and to take proportionate regulatory action to prevent or counter those threats. The main reason for the lack of information is the extra territoriality of many hedge funds. Another important reason is the fear that regulatory measures to improve the level and quality of information, could result in even more hedge funds going off-shore. So far these problems and the work of a strong hedge fund lobby have led to a kind of regulatory nihilism, claiming that most regulation has negative results, so therefore the hedge funds are better off with no regulation at all. We believe that a cautionary regulatory stance is more appropriate that hedge funds have created substantial threats to global financial stability, threats for which there are currently too few remedies.
145
146
Private equity especially in the form of LBO takes more and more clearly the form of a rearrangement of claims, which allow value capture and value extraction for a relatively small number of fund managers. The LBO industry emphasises the social benefits of private equity as well as the returns to investors from increasing leverage. But the real effects, as seen in many case studies, are rather helping to normalise a culture of value extractions (see study by CRESC, the University of Manchester, February 2007 that increasingly views companies as bundles of assets and liabilities to be traded. The small elite of LBO managers are guaranteed extremely high fees and moreover they will be taken out not as income, but as capital gains. This has huge tax advantages when the rate of income tax is high as in the UK 40%. The Financial Times reports rumours that leading British LBO partners pay taxes of no more than 4-5% on multi-million incomes. These facts threaten coherence and co-responsibility among stakeholders and social partners in our societies. Given these extremely high fees, how can we seriously ask employees and wage earners to show responsibility for society as a whole during trade union are negotiations? Fees and performance remuneration could take up to 50% of the cash-flow of a target company. This is giving rise to extremely high earnings. partners normally take 20% of the total yields (the so-called carry). One of the leading managers within the PE industry, Nicolas Ferguson, estimates that the PE managers in the period 1996-2006 have altogether picked up a yield/fee of around $430 bn. This is creating new trends of inequality in our societies and threatening the coherence and coresponsibility. No one can defend such huge yields to such a small group. It creates a moral dilemma: how can we argue for coherence and co-responsibility among all groups in our social Europe when fund mangers can make more money in an afternoon than ordinary workers can earn in several years? This question is doubly important because it is cohesion and co-responsibility form the glue keeping together our societies in the global economy.
147
148
finance infrastructure through long-term investment programmes. This is a clear example of how the short-term strategies of private equity funds and the long-term development of infrastructure operators are in direct conflict. Furthermore, it is to be expected that private equity funds leave infrastructure operators in a condition where their capabilities for pursuing their long-term objectives have been severely weakened. Employees pension fund investments are also major concerns. Investors in this sense are defined as being ordinary retail investors such as collective investment scheme investors, pension scheme beneficiaries (and their agents such as trustees), and insurance fund policyholders. While the expert report from the European Commission argued that investors would gain added value by investing in hedge funds, alternative investment funds in the form of structured products have the potential to offer ordinary retail investors a product with a return that would be between bonds and equities on the risk spectrum. However, all in all it is not clear that hedge funds offer such added value potential for investors and therefore it is not clear why retail investors should have access to these funds. While it is difficult to identify the benefits of retail investors entering the market of hedge funds, it is easy to point to the problems. Lack of transparency and disclosure even when it comes to basic operations of alternative investment funds, is just to mention one aspect. Finally, the stability of financial markets is not the least of our concerns. Six factors have been presented as potentially impediments to the financial stability of the overall market. The industrys growth and the extensive use of performance fees are likely to go hand in hand with increased competition and risk taking. Sometimes the incentive is just too big, pushing hedge fund managers to take unnecessary risks. The amount of assets under management has become more significant, and a hedge fund failure with the same amount of assets under management as a traditional fund may have a far greater market impact. In the light of the current size of assets under management, there can be little doubt that some hedge funds using strategies such as short selling can influence prices independent of fundamentals and cause financial instability. A key concern regarding hedge fund and financial market stability is related to increasing similarities or correlation among hedge fund strategies. In addition to increasing correlations, observers have stressed that the liquidity of many hedge fund investments may be decreasing. We have argued that a boom in leverage and risk may go unnoticed, because the boom is originating from markets characterised by great opacity, e.g. the market for credit derivatives. Finally regulators are finding themselves in a vacuum where they are unable to react, as they are placed in a situation with an enormous lack of transparency and reliable data. This means that it is extremely difficult to make informed decisions about financial threats. So we believe that hedge funds create substantial threats to the global financial stability. Coherence and co-responsibility are threatened by the extreme management fees and remuneration of partners within the HF and PE industry. All the issues raised in this part of the report challenge the achievement of the Lisbon goals. More precisely, what are the perspectives in terms of innovation, Research and Development, new technologies, development of infrastructures and networks if the real economy is eaten, bite by bite, by financial market operative models? Our European economies need resources, brains and the means to function and develop in our globalised environment. How will we build on the future if the creation of wealth goes to very few, to the detriment of the many? We have to reconcile long-term needs of businesses and societies in general with the short-termism of more and more investors, prominently among them alternative funds. While promoting investments has always been a credo of the Lisbon agenda, not all investments are productive and those that are clearly destructive must be prevented.
149
There is enormous potential for all of us in Europe in bringing our New Social Europe and the global economy together in a new dynamic interplay. But there is also a need for change to ensure a sustainable New Social Europe in relation to the financial markets. In Part III we deal with the regulation issues: What to do?
150
153
But if we in Europe and hopefully globally can regulate the financial markets to make them subordinate to the real economy, without negative implications, there are enormous realeconomic opportunities ahead of us, for the future of the whole of Europes of population. That is why we need a new strategy for the financial markets in member states and the European Union. Part III is going to focus on possible legal instruments for responding to the impact of private equity fund and hedge fund ownership. The various consequences of their investment strategies range from declining tax revenues and offshore placement, lack of transparency and loss of information, reducing the capacity of target companies to invest, encouraging job cuts and worsening working conditions, an aggravated long-term investment situation and risks for financial stability. Taking into account these negative consequences it is crucial to recognise that something has to be done in order to protect the European market economy and European society in general. But not only to protect first and foremost in order to create the conditions for realising the enormous potential for smart, green growth and new, better jobs ahead of us. In this part, legal instruments, incentives and proposals for regulation will be presented in connection with specific policy areas like taxation, corporate governance, social responsibility, supervision, etc. In addition, we want to underline that ideally each proposal should be examined for its national and EU-level implications. There is no single combination of regulations that can answer all the new challenges. Instead they need a coherent mix of over national, European and possibly global levels, as these funds are operating worldwide. Therefore where no competence is granted to the EU, we would encourage national action, based on common ground, to promote a common approach and avoid harmful competition. A successful concept designed at national level should serve as an example to other countries, whatever the policy area touched upon. The example of the US system should be kept in mind as regulation on such issues is centralised and quite efficiently implemented. To play down any need for public inquiry the HF and PE industries claim: we are efficiencyenhancing. This contention is repeated ad nauseam. It is supposed to be self-evident and is thus brandished like a talisman against any attempt to discuss the opportunity of shedding some light on HF and PE for the sake of the lay investor. But the efficient market hypothesis (EMH) is beyond the reach of any empirical evidence. So, if HFs and PEs enjoy the unique privilege of always being efficiency-enhancing, it follows that they should not be investigated, or transparent, or regulated. In their investment strategies, hedge funds either make directional bets on futures markets or on the future values of macroeconomic variables, or exploit price inefficiencies, or exploit specific situations (event-driven, merger arbitrage, distressed securities). To support the contention that hedge funds are always efficiency-enhancing one must demonstrate that they always have incentives to act as contrarians. Therefore pro-HF and PE supporters go on repeating the following assertions: In their directional bets on future market trends, they take advantage of mean-revertingprocesses and subsequently enforce adjustment to price equilibrium. In bridging the gaps between segments of markets that would be too shallow or even nonexistent without them, they contribute to completeness in the whole set of markets. In bringing liquidity in corporate deals that are always beneficial for the economy as a whole, they not only contribute to market efficiency, but also to economic efficiency.
154
Furthermore, since their strategies cannot be deciphered because of their opacity, they must keep those stabilising processes rolling on through their own market power, not through market discipline. This is where the argument goes astray. To insist that HFs and PEs enhance efficiency by themselves is a strange argument. If they can drive the market on their own, it is through sheer market power. Whenever a particular group has market power, it has the incentive to exploit the market in order to draw a quasi-rent at the expense of other market participants. How can it be beneficial for market efficiency and, further, for the whole economy? Market dominance should in theory be eliminated by competition between hedge funds and the outcome should always be equilibrium, just as it should if market transparency disseminated information to all market participants. (If the alternative investment industry is still of the same opinion, why are they against transparency and disclosure?) The lesson of LTCM, for instance, is that it entailed the Feds extraordinary lender-of-the-lastresort intervention to forestall the impending flight to quality. Observing that the same outcome was not needed in May 2005, in the turmoil provoked by the slump in GM and Ford derivative contracts after the downgrade in their rating, is no assurance that hedge funds have gotten more robust or society responsible. The difference between 2005 and September 1998 was the situation of global financial markets. In 1998 they were under extreme stress in the aftermath of the Russian crisis. In 2005 they were awash with cash after many years of loose monetary policy. While the investment industry keeps on repeating that maximum value should be returned to shareholders, because shareholder decisions are inevitably beneficial to society as a whole; and that taking companies private shields managers from the short-term pressures of financial markets all the evidence contained in this report suggests the contrary. The question of appropriate regulation basically depends on what kind of investment strategy is desired in Europe and that is directly defined in our Lisbon goals and New Social Europe for the development of our societies in the next decade. Some HFs and PEs would argue that regulations would force them to seek out other locations outside Europe. We think there are three answers to this attitude: Europes single market is the worlds largest economy (10% bigger than that of the US). This market is enormously attractive for foreign investors and with the high growth rates of the new member states, its importance will increase in the coming years. Creativity and financial engineering to avoid the effect of regulators will always be a fact of life. As we have learned from national experience, regulation is an ongoing, permanent process during a changing environment.
Part III Lessons to be drawn for future regulation
We are aiming for appropriate and carefully targeted regulations, not disproportionate, general prohibitions or over-detailed regulations. The aim of regulation in this sector of the financial market should be to exclude certain characteristic risks and to compare results with preordained aims or have the ability to influence the development in the interest of society. No company should have substantially worse results due to LBO in its results, than before. No company that is the object of LBO should lose assets or sacrifice labour standards because its financial assets are plundered due to unwarranted charges and fees or predominantly debt-based financing. Better investor protection, proper corporate governance, long-term investment and prospects of safe and decent jobs should be our road map for reforming the real economy as well as regulating the financial markets.
155
After the Stock market crash of October 1987, a US presidential task force on market mechanisms, chaired by Senator Nicholas Brady, was set up to investigate on what went wrong. It was known as the Brady Commission. Among other disturbing factors, the inquiry revealed the strength of bandwagon effects triggered by portfolio insurance. These are non-anticipated risk measurement models used by banks as supervisors require them capital adequacy provisions. More precisely, it is the value of losses that could be over passed only a certain % of time. For instance, the value of losses that could be over passed only 1% of working days.
84
156
Transparency and disclosure are simply preconditions but not sufficient conditions to ensure positive solutions to our concerns as explained in part II. When considering better regulation of alternative investment it would help to answer the following questions in detail:
How to make sure to only attract desired investment and ward off unwelcome financing?
Investors
Investor Protection
Balancing
Companies
Good Corp Governance
Longterm Interests
Stakeholders
Functioning of financial markets Employee protection/participation Debtor protection Social impacts of risky investments
1) How do we ensure long-term investments to promote our goals, the Lisbon strategy and New Social Europe? 2) How do we avoid a clash between short-term financing and long-term investment needs in the real economy as a part of our efforts to make European companies compete globally on the basis of our common values? 3) How can we ensure financial stability and eliminate systemic risk? 4) How would European regulation reach investors, whether institutional or private, who have their company and business base outside the EU, as is often the case in the area of hedge funds and private equity? Is there a basis for an agreement encompassing the whole of Europe on how companies with this form of alternative investment can be handled? The optimal solution would be to have regulation internationally, at the highest level possible. A case could be made for regulation of the risk management system through the Bank for International Settlements in Switzerland the Central Bank of the Central Banks, under whose auspices the Basel Capital Adequacy Agreements were reached. The case could be made that, even though the alternative investment fund might be registered offshore, the manager is (i) raising money in and (ii) investing in Europe and (iii) therefore potentially posing a danger to the stability of the European financial system. 5) To what extent can employees social rights be called into play for the socially acceptable regulation of alternative investment?
157
Considering the fact that a large proportion of capital in global financial markets is owned by workers, one could raise the question of whether this ownership could be organised, in particular, in the regulation of financial institutions and markets and within the framework of coordinated macroeconomic policies. We could rule at EU level to give labour a voice by ownership in supervisory bodies on the financial markets. In doing so you could refer to the example of the German BAF in (the Federal Financial Supervisory Authority) which has representatives of trade unions and (non-autonomous) pension funds on its general and insurance advisory councils, as well as employee representatives on its takeover council. Moreover, we have the example of the French AMF (Autorit des Marchs Financiers), which provides a seat on its board for a representative of the employee shareholders85.
85
This idea goes back to Hans-Michael Trautwein, Oldenburg, as explained to the ETUC/SDA Path to Progress project, forthcoming 2006, Brussels.
158
3. Hedge funds
We have seen from Part I and Part II that there are important concrete arguments for transparency and adequate regulations: 1. It is important to enhance the transparency of the hedge funds because of overall financial stability in the EU. This is important because it allows the monetary authorities to have a fair picture of the collective hedge funds investments and commitments, which in turn would allow the monetary authorities to assess the consequences to the financial markets of the hedge funds transactions and future transactions. 2. Transparency should be introduced in the hedge funds in order to protect investors. 3. Many of the hedge funds are in practice functioning more or less like traditional investment funds. 4. Many hedge funds are based in offshore jurisdictions, including hedge funds active in the EU. The problems relating to tax control, when investors based in EU Member States invest in hedge funds based in offshore centres, are crucial. The offshore centres often do not have tax control, nor are they obliged to provide information to the tax authorities concerning these investments. 5. Companies are not protected from short-term thinking of hedge funds and LBOs. This is creating problems for public companies competing globally as a part of our general promotion of New Social Europe.
Even the narrower view of indirect regulation is questionable. Banks do not simply lend money to hedge funds. This plain type of leverage is properly accounted for in computing bank leverage, at least in principle. But it is superseded by financial leverage through securities lending and derivatives that is less so. Financial leverage is due to exposures created by off-balance sheet positions ahead of the cost of derivative contracts. Prime brokers provide high leverage through reverse repos, using assets as collateral in non-tractable transactions that are not reported by the banks. At best, regulators can only know the total net exposure of a bank to all hedge funds. But they do not know the exposure of any hedge fund provided by all counterparties. Therefore the nature and the ever-changing size of HFs liabilities to their lenders make illusory the knowledge of the relevant indicator of leverage risk due to hedge funds, which is potential future credit exposure.
159
Furthermore investment banks are not under bank supervision at all. They are under SEC rules and only for their brokerage activities. All other business goes totally unsupervised. It ensues that the feasibility of indirect regulation via banks is dubious, at least debatable. In any case it cannot be taken for granted. And even if it were, banks have no incentives to be the regulators scrutineers of hedge funds for two reasons: On the one hand, banks are busy acquiring or setting up hedge funds themselves. They are doing so to boost profits by all means, prodded as they are by shareholder value incentives. On the other hand, prime brokerage for hedge funds is sold with a whole bundle of services (clearing, settlement of transactions, custody of assets, research, legal advices and the like). This is a very profitable, risk-free fee business. Likewise, securities lending earns interest on the process of short selling by hedge funds. The more business volume they get the better. There is a blatant conflict between banks incentives and regulators goals.
As shown in Part II, hedge funds invest massively in risky strategies. Indeed the anti-regulation rhetoric for hedge funds has always been eager to point out that hedge funds specialise in arbitrage between market segments. Therefore they take no bet on the direction of markets. Having
160
no correlation with market indexes, it goes without saying that they are suitable for portfolio diversification with few risks when they anticipate the narrowing of spreads. However as LTCM revealed, high returns on those strategies imply a large leverage and both legs of the investment are losing if spreads widen in disorderly market conditions. Even seemingly careful strategies might put HFs in jeopardy if they indulge in high leverage. But arbitrage strategies have always made a modest proportion of HF investments and this proportion is shrinking for both structural and cyclical reasons. Directional bets are dominant and deliver mediocre results in adverse macroeconomic conditions. Nonetheless hedge funds developed massively after 2000 while rates of interests slipped downwards and equity markets plummeted. Institutional investors were looking for a dual strategy: A benchmarked passive portfolio to cover their costs An active management portfolio in the hope of boosting their overall return. To try to achieve their goal they invested both in funds of funds and in individual hedge funds. Controlling their active portfolios raises new problems of performance measurement (taking account of the probability of extreme losses) and risk assessment. It is quite plain that the opacity of hedge funds deprives institutional investors of any meaningful quantitative risk control. The more hedge funds rely on fathomless investment strategies that increase markedly in weight according to table 2 (specifically multi strategies and event-driven), the more their institutional clients have to rely on the good faith of fund managers. The only control institutional investors can engineer is upstream. They should develop networks of acquaintances to facilitate reference checking in order to get a thorough understanding of the would-be fund managers investment operations. It is awfully costly and time-consuming. Often pension fund trustees have neither the organisational resources nor the ability to run the investigation in-house. They must resort to counsellors biased towards getting more business for hedge funds. It should be commonsense that a reasonable policy of market transparency would improve the principal agent relationship inherent in delegated management. Hedge funds are going to manage more and more public money and a significant retailisation is under way. The call for some regulation will gain momentum. In the EU, as far as UCITS III allows mutual funds to indulge in hedge fund-type strategies, the need for a common regulation regime addressing hedge funds and their managers becomes pressing. Three motives for regulation are financial stability, investor protection and market integrity (against frauds, market abuse and money laundering).
Part III Lessons to be drawn for future regulation
Financial regulation is most effective when it targets the conflicts of interest between market participants, risks, and stress points within the financial services supply chain. The supply chain for the hedge fund market is particularly complex when compared to the traditional asset management industry because of the use of various counterparties (often unknown to the investor) and due to anomalies such as fund managers and actual funds being regulated in onshore and off-shore jurisdictions. The supply chain approach to regulation allows policymakers to identify the areas in the market which are most likely to give rise to detriment, recognise the different levels of sophistication of various market participants, and deploy targeted, proportionate regulatory interventions.
161
162
Beside the comparability of existing national regulatory frameworks, it would also be necessary to formalise a set of product clusters in order to enhance the scope for investors to compare different products returns and to formalise a shared and comprehensive method of calculating hedge funds indices which could become the sectors benchmarks. This would provide basic information as far as investment strategies are concerned. *** The transparency and disclosure regime relating to alternative investments needs to be improved to enhance governance and accountability and ensure a high degree of consumer protection. As the PES group has pointed out, the recommendations of the hedge funds expert group are intended to ease regulatory burdens on hedge funds and make the industrys products more widely available, in particular on cross-border marketing and portfolio construction. The expert group makes a number of claims such as: the hedge fund business is maturing in a way that does not give rise to any need for additional specific or targeted legislation of hedge fund participants or investment strategies at a European level; the existing light touch regulatory approach has, in the view of the Group, served the industry, its investors and the wider market well; additional regulation .is likely to fail and will do little to further protect investors compared with the status quo. The expert group report also urges regulators not to control sales and distribution of hedge funds through product regulation or registration but instead focus on regulating the intermediaries that sell investment products to investors. The report also says that many of the restrictions on insurance companies, pension funds and banks investing in hedge funds should be lifted. These claims must be dealt with head-on if an appropriate and proportionate consumer protection regime is to be created. The recurring argument made by industry that further regulation would drive the business and its investors offshore must be challenged. To this end, the EC should draw up minimum reporting standards covering: reporting frequency; investment strategies; full details of assets and investments held by the fund (or private equity firm); full disclosure of the risk management model adopted by the investment managers this should include modelling of potential risks, management fees, stress testing of portfolios plus descriptions of contingency plans to contain risks; managements incentive structure to help investors better understand potential conflicts of interest. *** To detect liquidity risk the aggregate positions of all hedge funds in key markets should be made known to bank supervisors. Those data, indicatively not to be publicly disclosed, should be shared by prime brokers and bank supervisors. Such a requirement would help central banks to implement monetary policy fully conscious of the hedge fund industrys exposure to main financial risks and, even more, allow prime brokers to have a full understanding of their operational activity and to drive their decision-making, limiting credit line extension to single funds, with multiple prime brokerage agreements, that show stressed or deteriorated financial health.
163
Recently in most European countries we have seen an effort by domestic supervisory bodies to regulate the hedge fund industry through the introduction, country by country, of new specific investment schemes. These domestic regulatory innovations provided final investors with financial products perceived as useful and effective by the market but only in the field of FOHFs. Effectively in this specific segment of the European onshore hedge funds industry we see, with some minor exceptions, a regulatory architecture really able to grant investor safety. Otherwise any attempt by local supervisory bodies to introduce regulated schemes in the field of the onshore single strategy products has been substantially unsuccessful as the persistent prevalence (in terms of aggregated AUM) of the offshore vehicles testifies. *** In our view, if we want to promote European sector regulation aiming to make the current offshore hedge fund industry an onshore one, it has to be assumed that single strategy funds are essentially the expression of a cross-border market, hardly possible to regulate at a national level. We are fully aware of the political difficulty of introducing a common supervision of such products undertaken by a unique Supervisory Body (for instance a dedicated division of the ECB). Nevertheless, we consider such a hypothesis as the only effective way of achieving such an aim. Therefore, our target would be the introduction of a specific family of registered European single strategy funds whose products and managers should be authorised and monitored by a unique, specialised and highly professionalised Authority, operating to reduce (and not to increase) the regulatory arbitrage provided by the main offshore locations (for instance in terms of length of the time to authorisation for new products or new investment companies). The second leg of this new European regulatory architecture should be the elimination of all the fiscal transparency incentives granted to the investment undertaken by institutional players (onshore FOHFs included), in vehicles not belonging to the above mentioned new family of European registered funds. *** As far as investor protection is concerned, the focus should be on information for institutional investors. They should be able to assess and compare financial returns and risks of the different types of management. Transparency requires more frequent disclosure of returns and risk characteristics, the storage of those data in a public database available to all investors, the computation of hedge fund indices and the disclosure of all management costs and fees charged on their clients. Information should be available about the appointment of a custodian bank, common and effective rules for management relating to portfolios market pricing, public communication and disclosure of attained financial returns. Beside the information disclosed to the supervisors, the disclosure of information to the public in general is in the common interest. Therefore, hedge funds should be obliged to release general information about the inflow/outflow of money after their deals have been completed. This type of information would make the influence they have on financial markets more transparent and readable. *** New standards relating to the sale and promotion of alternative investment products need to be developed to protect consumers from mis-selling and misrepresentation of risk. These include: minimum investments for retail investors purchasing alternative investments directly without regulated advice. A minimum investment of Euro 100,000 is appropriate;
164
rules should be developed to ensure that claims relating to investment performance and risks are honestly and clearly communicated to consumers. This means that promoters or intermediaries should not be allowed to be selective about the time periods used in promotions. Moreover, the use of independent benchmarks should be stipulated to prevent promoters selecting favourable investment universes to compare products; rules on the disclosure of total charges to retail investors should be agreed to allow for objective and accurate comparison of charges especially where fund of hedge funds are involved. Illustrations and projections should be provided on a consistent basis to allow investors to compare the offerings of different fund managers that is, funds with a similar investment strategy should be required to use the same projected investment growth rates net of actual total expenses and charges; the EC should ensure that the content and presentation of risk warnings in any marketing or promotional material should be clear, fair and conform to minimum standards. *** Funds that are eligible for marketing to retail investors should conform to a number of safeguards including: the need for an independent depositary; retail investors should have access to alternative investments only under certain conditions for example, as part of a fund of hedge funds or within a portfolio of conventional assets; even then restrictions should apply with regards to diversification, limits on exposure, and liquidity criteria. Transparency alone does not guarantee high standards of governance and accountability (other measures such as rules on fair treatment of separation of duties and independent audits are needed). But greater transparency allows for other stakeholders in the investment chain to understand the risks involved and be more aware of the impact and consequences of investment decisions made on their behalf. *** A number of concerns have been raised about the valuation of assets within alternative investment funds (see elsewhere in the report). The plausibility of the investment returns (and therefore the validity of performance related fees) claimed by investment managers may be questioned as a result of incorrect valuations. In addition, inconsistent valuation methodologies undermine the ability of investors to assess risk, and can lead to differential treatment of classes of investors. It is all about avoiding market abuse and ensuring asset valuations as correct as possible. In summary, these concerns relate to: the valuation methodologies used by investment managers; the need for clearly defined responsibilities when valuing assets to deal with potential conflicts of interest within fund management organisations; the availability of independent and reliable sources of market prices; independent and regular reviews of valuations; a number of process issues including: timing of closing prices, dealing with pricing errors, verification procedures.
165
The European Commission should establish robust minimum standards with respect to the following: rules on valuing hard-to-value, illiquid assets so that investors can be reassured that asset prices used in valuations are fair and independently obtained. These rules should apply to all internal and external parties in the valuation chain including fund managers, administrators, providers of market prices, verification staff, and auditors; the frequency and basis of valuations; the use of portfolio stress testing to establish valuation parameters; the relationship between internal and external parties involved in the valuation process to manage conflicts of interest and ensure a clear separation of duties between fund managers and those providing support services; the use of independent ratings and valuation agencies to communicate overall risk to investors. The EC should set up an independent expert working group consisting of consumer and public interest, representatives from corporate business, social partners and industry representatives to establish proposals for these minimum standards.
166
portfolios. Possible minimum standards relating to product features and unfair contract terms for alternative investment products sold to retail investors should be envisaged. These standards should cover: investment fees, retail charging structures, and limit unreasonable and unfair lockin periods so that consumers can have access to capital. *** To assess the credit risk of hedge funds an international credit register should track all counterparties exposure on individual hedge funds.
167
The EC should also create a framework to allow alternative investment funds to be classified and rated according to investment strategy and risk. This would allow for improved evaluation of comparative risk and return, better communication to investors, and promote more efficient competition as performance fees could be challenged. Precedents exist which allow for conventional investment funds to be classified according to portfolio asset allocation for example, bond funds, equity funds, balanced funds and so on. The EC should establish an independent working group consisting of consumer and public interest groups to develop a classification system to encompass alternative investments. Alternative investment fund managers should be required to have funds evaluated by an independent ratings agency. Furthermore, to deal with additional risks relating to marketing and promotional practices, conduct of business rules, and risk assessment and disclosure consideration should be given to having the MiFID (Markets in Financial Instruments Directive) cover hedge funds. This Directive does not take into consideration the fact that many public financial institutions now invest in hedge funds and no clear rules exist regarding the information to be provided by these financial institutions to their investors or members about this type of investment. *** The European Commission should also reflect upon the conduct of business rules enacted by the financial community. These rules should include strong sanctions modelled on the City Code on Takeovers and Mergers of the London Stock Exchange. The EC could at least threaten to enact a strong regulatory regime within the Common Market if the financial community does not live up to its promises within precisely defined deadlines. The sanctions included in the conduct of business rules must be a credible threat. *** Beside corporate governance requirements to be fulfilled by hedge funds themselves, their counterparts and the companies in which they invest could also be submitted to a set of rules: Knowing the aggregate exposure of hedge funds and knowing that their supervisors know, prime brokers should have the duty of limiting credit line extension to any single fund whose potential future credit exposure appears excessive. Constructing a suitable regulatory framework for managing the risks associated with alternative investments requires wider reforms to the way these investments are used by investors. Addressing the specific risks through UCITS or MiFID will be insufficient. Measures should be introduced through the insurance and occupational pension funds regulatory framework to ensure that high standards of due diligence are undertaken when alternative investments are included in pension fund or insurance fund portfolios. Trustees and other intermediaries should ensure they have reporting and risk assessment systems in place to allow them to understand the consequences of investment decisions, and ensure they are accountable to end-investors. In particular, investor representatives should pay close attention to liquidity risks and lack of transparency associated with alternative investments.
168
Reporting requirements should include not only a detailed assessment of risk and return but also a corporate social responsibility report to allow investors to understand the impact on other stakeholders in the investment chain (such as target companies and employees). As part of the due diligence framework, regulators should ensure that intermediaries such as trustees or sales advisers are trained to a sufficiently high standard to understand risks and make informed and responsible decisions on behalf of the clients/ investors they represent. There is a need to know about the outflow of money when it comes to institutional investors. One can ask this legitimate question: what are the institutional investors doing with other peoples money86? Qualified investors (= institutional investors) do not need protection. But they are not the ultimate investors in reality. They use other peoples money when they buy high risk/highly leveraged products. Guidance relating to portfolio diversification is required to ensure that the end-investor is not exposed to undue risk. *** We can consider the introduction at European level of some regulatory quantitative or principlebased constraint to the alternative investments exposure of pension funds and other collective investment schemes such as mutual or insurance. But at this stage, before setting quantitative constraints, we should promote a reinforced prudent person approach, especially when considering the growing size of investments made by pension funds in hedge funds. The EC should investigate the need for prescriptive limits because there are major informational problems which undermine the ability of investors to undertake due diligence within the prudent person framework. If approved, it could be useful in the case of HF to introduce diversification/ low concentration constraints. For instance an option would be to limit the investments of the pension funds in single Hedge funds at 2.5% of the net asset value (NAV)87 . This would go hand in hand with the promotion of onshore hedge funds in comparison to off shore ones. European pension funds would therefore be encouraged to invest only in onshore/regulated ones in order to have stronger guarantees. In addition, all shareholdings of 1 percent or larger that institutional investors or private parties acquire in publicly listed firms should be disclosed to the appropriate national security exchange commission.
To introduce a fiscal discrimination, to include FOHFs and all tax-exempt organisations, against offshore products (i.e. to confirm the principle that FOHFs and pension funds are fiscally transparent, but limiting such transparency to the treatment of onshore single strategy funds holding.). To address the risks associated with offshore jurisdiction, consideration should be given to changing the tax rules so that the location of the manager determines the tax position of hedge funds.
86 87
Cf. Louis Brandeis: Other People Money and How the Bankers Use it. Boston 1995: St. Martins Press (1st edition 1914). NAV: Net Asset Value: The value of a funds investments.
169
170
http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2006/2006-208.htm
171
to create incentives for longer-term investment, with the hope that longer-term investors have more interests in common with employees than shorter-term investors: There must be an overall effort to ensure the further development of the Rhineland model of public companies. This model ensures engagement of all stakeholders not only shareholders, but also management, employees, and other investors in the interplay between the public company and corporation with the public sector on further education and qualification of employees etc. Beside creating incentives for long-term investments, the long-term investors should be rewarded. This can be done by permitting weighting of voting rights according to duration of shareholding and by means of differentiated taxation of (capital and dividend) income from shareholdings. Golden employee-owned shares are also an option to be further examined. Minimum holding periods eligible for tax exemption should be considered. Rules on better investor protection could include regulations on the limitation of voting rights or on dividend bonuses for shareholders who turn up and exercise their voting rights. Organised investors such as banks could be obliged to exercise their voting rights at general meetings in order to hinder minority shareholders from directly influencing the business policy of a company in their particular interests. In order to prevent value extraction, limitations on the withdrawal of liquid assets from the target company should be introduced. In particular, the financing of dividend payouts via the imposition of additional debt on the companys assets (leveraged recap) must be stopped. Most countries have rules here and we should propose a Moratorium on loosening of such rules. The Commission should undertake a comparative study of their effectiveness and propose EU-wide minimum standards. One could also imagine restricting owners freedom to set managers remuneration packages (stock-options) autonomously. At the very least an EU-wide code of good conduct should be drawn up to assure that managerial interests are best aligned with the long-term interests of the company. This could be a start for moving towards full disclosure on all kinds of management remuneration. It would be even better to have some sort of rating system/seal of approval of remuneration structures. The desired character of investment could also be channelled in the right direction by capital maintenance provisions which prescribe a limitation on the transfer of debts to companies that are the object of investment through the restriction of credit financing. What would be a sensible cap as a percentage of market value: 50%? Or would it be better to impose the minimum equity capital requirement at the level of the PEF? Here, one has to examine the tax deductibility of interest payments that subsidises the use of debt over equity. The Commission should undertake a study to assess whether the need to tackle these issues should be considered on an EU basis or a national basis. *** In order to ensure better protection of pension funds investing in LBOs, we can consider some regulation at European level: Regulatory quantitative or principle-based constraint to the alternative investments exposure of pension funds. Such constraints in absolute terms could be meaningful especially in the case of the PE funds, given the low level of liquidity (scarcely considered as a major risk by the industry practitioners) of such financial instruments. (For instance, in Italy the pension funds investments in closed-end funds, the PE funds, are subject to a 10% constraint). Anyway a regulation aimed to favour pension funds investments in early stage / expansion
172
PE funds should be seriously considered and the growing involvement of pension funds in the alternative field could help force increasing transparency of the alternative investment industry. These regulatory constraints should also apply to Banking, Insurance, and public funds and could take the form of: tolerable leverage stability of capital base risk assessment procedures information standards for investors safeguards against collusion and insider trading.
Consulting fees exceeding this ceiling may be paid by private equity managers, but they are taxed twice: Once as capital gains of the private equity fund, a second time as income of lawyers, consultants, etc.
173
policy are not being met. This regulation is not directed at the Private Equity Funds financing activities, but rather at the implications of the complete range of Private Equity Fund managerial decisions upon the infrastructure operators public service responsibilities. *** Regarding the financing activities of public utilities, industry-specific regulation will continue to be based on an assumption of effective financial governance of Private Equity Funds. In addition, governments may wish to consider whether they should retain a golden share of equity in all public utilities, including a seat on the board. Such shares were retained by many governments in the early stages of public utility privatisations, and some still hold them. This ensures government is informed of the utilitys plans and major decisions, and reserves the power to veto decisions they believe are contrary to the public interest. This is justified because of the importance to the general public, the economy and society of the major decisions of public utility managers and owners. However, a more effective approach may be to strengthen the industry-specific regulation in the infrastructure industries, establishing specific powers to regulate the financial as well as the operational activities of infrastructure providers. The initial requirement is to ensure full transparency to the regulator and the public with respect to all transactions that affect the implementation of the operators public service responsibilities, including financial transactions. For all its major financing activities, the infrastructure operator could be required to obtain advance approval from the regulator that they are in the public interest. The regulator would need broad powers to require the operator to supply all the information necessary to make the necessary public interest judgments. The strengthened regulators powers suggested here are not without precedent. In the past, most regulatory agencies in the US and Canada had similar strong financial regulatory powers over public utilities precisely because they were businesses in which there was a public interest. Some of these regulators retain financial powers today. A leverage buyout of an incumbent public utility operator could not take place in the US today without advance approval from one or more industry regulatory authorities. *** To promote the Rhineland model of public companies, thereby ensuring co-responsibility of all stakeholders for the future performance of the company, we could propose further initiatives: One other potential mechanism for regulating operations in the financial sector concerning employees social rights is the Transfers of Undertakings Directive 77/187 of 1977 (ARD). The ARD incorporates two central principles of the social acquis communautaire: protection of individual employees and a role for collective labour representatives, and entitlement to information and consultation90. Enterprise restructuring driven by mergers and acquisitions following the transformation of capital markets and the invention of new mechanisms of corporate finance and credit instruments allowing for the financing of takeovers raises the question of whether the Transfers of Undertakings Directive 77/187 of 1977 (ARD) could be adapted to this new environment. ***
90
The idea goes back to Brian Bercusson, London, as explained to the ETUC/SDA Path to Progress project, forthcoming 2006, Brussels.
174
The ARD covers only transfers from one employer to another, not where the undertaking is transferred through a share purchase. In light of the role of financial capital in restructuring operations, this loophole should be removed by a reinterpretation or revision so that transfers of undertakings achieved through transfers of shares are covered. These purely *financial dealings with a direct impact on workers could fall under the ARD and be subject to the requirements of prior disclosure of all relevant information to employee representatives, prior consultation with employee representatives, and protection of the individual employees affected: in other words, no transfer of risk to employees. It would mean defending and extending the existing national systems of co-determination and worker participation. In particular, issues of take-overs and leveraging should be incorporated in the substantive fields where workers representatives already have information or consultation rights. The strengthening of trans-national workers participation could take place through the revision of the European Working Council Directive. Employee representatives of firms involved in (leveraged) buy-out deals should be informed about where the money comes from. Who are the ultimate investors? This change in the scope of the ARD would mean a foothold gained for worker involvement in share transfers on the stock market. This would be a first step in the participation of labour in financial operations. However, it should be said that the directive only covers entities resident in the EU, while many alternative investment companies have their base outside the EU. To that extent direct regulation of investment companies will frequently fail to achieve its ends. Therefore this change in the scope of the ARD should be accompanied with the creation of a kind of passporting procedure to cover foreign alternative funds.
175
Acquisitions by private equity funds in recent years have been accompanied by leverage. This means that both the acquired company and associated holding companies have contracted a considerable amount of interest-bearing debt. Since it is possible in most countries to establish joint taxation or tax consolidation, the acquired company is allowed to deduct the interest expenditure incurred and its tax base is eroded. Common rules should therefore be introduced in the EU countries to counteract such tax erosion. This cannot be done by lowering the taxation of interest in some countries since this simply means that the interest expenditure is transferred to allied companies in other countries. Rules should instead be introduced limiting deductions for expenditure on interest in the target company, its holding companies and its subsidiary companies once the target company has been taken over by one or more equity funds. The limitation could take the form of no deductions being allowed for interest expenditure by the local holding companies that have been established to carry out the takeover and of removal of the deduction for interest expenditure by the target company in respect of interest on the debt incurred in order to pay an extraordinary dividend after the company has been taken over by equity funds. This can in practice be achieved by calculating what has been allocated by way of dividend in excess of the current profit. This then becomes the apportionment of equity created prior to the takeover. The entitlement to deduct interest expenditure by the target company should subsequently be limited so that overall interest expenditure is restricted in proportion to how great the apportionment of equity is in relation to total interest-bearing debt.
Example
A company has acquired a target company for 100 million. The company is purchased by an equity fund which not only establishes two holding companies that incur debts of 40 million but also pays out 40 million from the target company itself. The interest expenditure on the borrowing by the holding company should not be deductible and the interest expenditure by the target company should be limited so that there is no deduction for interest on a borrowing of 40 million.
The opportunity to save on tax by altering the companys capital structure is a result of the way in which corporation tax is constructed. Corporation tax taxes financial income and expenditure in line with the actual net increase in value in other words, the net profit generated by the commercial company in question (e.g. telecommunications services). There are various protection rules to prevent the crass over-exploitation of tax saving opportunities. For example there are limits on how much one is allowed to lend a company (the rules on thin capitalisation) and it is possible to set limits on how much of the companys money may be transferred abroad through exorbitant consultancy fees or exaggerated interest payments on the companys debt (the transfer pricing rules).
176
However, the fundamental reason these tax savings are possible lies in the very nature of corporation tax, which consists of deductions from financial expenditure and conversely of taxes on financial income. As described above one possible way to deal with the eroded tax base is to limit the form of deductions allowed for interest expenditure by the local holding companies established to carry out the takeover. Another possibility is to reduce the tax gains achieved through increased indebtedness. In practice this would be to reduce corporation tax while at the same time supplementing it with a tax on gross business capital. Such a tax would tax only the companys primary earnings, i.e. the financial account before taxation. Introducing a new tax to stem tax profits obtained through capital fund purchases may seem like using a sledgehammer to crack a nut. However, a tax on gross business capital has other features in its favour: It does not distort companies investment decisions, which corporation tax does. It makes it possible to reduce the taxation of financial capital, which is becoming increasingly mobile and international It is easy to collect, since the tax basis consists of the VAT basis minus wage expenditure. The companies and the tax authorities thus already have the necessary information. However, a tax on gross business capital is not entirely without its problems. Since it is founded on the VAT basis, and does not include financial income in its tax basis, finance companies and the VAT-exempt sector will be taxed at a lower rate if no compensatory taxation is imposed by other means.
177
178
in the lowering of social and labour standards as a direct consequence of the manner of financing. The door should clearly be left open to desirable investment strategies. In the following section, priority proposals to be supported by the PES Group are set out.
179
rules on the disclosure of total charges to retail investors should be agreed to allow for objective and accurate comparison of charges especially where fund of hedge funds are involved. Illustrations and projections should be provided on a consistent basis to allow investors to compare the offerings of different fund managers that is, funds with a similar investment strategy should be required to use the same projected investment growth rates net of actual total expenses and charges; the EC should ensure that the content and presentation of risk warnings in any marketing or promotional material should be clear, fair and conform to minimum standards.
180
Tax treatment
Introduce a fiscal discrimination, to including FOHFs and all tax-exempt organisations, against offshore products and change the tax rules so that the location of the manager determines the tax position of hedge funds.
181
have rules here and we should propose a Moratorium on loosening of such rules. The Commission should to undertake a comparative study of their effectiveness and propose EU-wide minimum standards. One could also imagine restricting owners freedom to set managers remuneration packages (stock-options) autonomously. At the very least an EU-wide code of good conduct should be drawn up to ensure that managerial interests are best aligned with the long-term interests of the company. Capital maintenance provisions prescribing a limitation on the transfer of debts to companies that are the object of investments, through the restriction of credit financing, is a way of channelling investment in the right direction. In this regard one has to examine the tax deductibility of interest payments that subsidise the use of debt over equity. The Commission should undertake a study to assess whether these issues should be tackled on an EU basis or a national basis. We can consider the introduction at European level of some regulatory quantitative or principlebased constraint to the alternative investments exposure of pension funds. Such constraints in absolute terms could be meaningful especially in the case of the PE funds given the low level of liquidity (scarcely considered as a major risk by the industry practitioners) of such financial instruments. Consulting fees paid out of the cash flow of the firm should be limited to a certain percentage (varying with the amount of the deal). Fees exceeding this upper limit should not be acknowledged as costs for tax purposes.
Social rights
The Transfers of Undertakings Directive 77/187 of 1977 (ARD) should be revised so that transfers of undertakings achieved through transfers of shares were covered. These purely financial dealings with a direct impact on workers could fall under the ARD and be subject to the requirements of prior disclosure of all relevant information to employee representatives, prior consultation with employee representatives, and protection of the individual employees affected: in other words, no transfer of risk to employees. It would mean defending and extending the existing national systems of co-determination and worker participation. In particular, issues of take-overs and leveraging should be incorporated in the substantive fields where workers representatives already have information or consultation rights.
Tax policy
A uniform progressive capital gains tax rate should be applied in all member states. The progressive rate should be very high for short-term arbitrage deals to discourage the short-term buying and selling of firms on the market for corporate control. Taxes should be paid in the country where the object of the transaction is located. Rules should be introduced to limit deductions for expenditure on interest in the target company, its holding companies and its subsidiary companies once the target company has been taken over by one or more equity funds. The limitation could take the form of no deductions being allowed for interest expenditure by the local holding companies that have been established to carry out the takeover, and removal of the deduction for interest expenditure by the target company in respect of interest on the debt incurred in order to pay an extraordinary dividend after the company has been taken over by equity funds.
182
In order to prevent the crass over-exploitation of tax saving opportunities, one can imagine, for example, putting limits on how much one is allowed to lend a company (the rules on thin capitalisation) and it is possible to set limits on how much of the companys money may be transferred abroad through exorbitant consultancy fees or exaggerated interest payments on the companys debt (the transfer pricing rules).
Table 1. Sources of capital (% of total) 1996 Individuals Funds of funds Pension funds Corporations and financial institutions Endowments and foundations
Hennesse Group LLC, IFSL estimates
2005 44 30 12 7 7
62 16 5 10 7
Table 2. Assets under management by investment objective (% of total) Investment objectives Long short equity Global macro Emerging markets Managed Future Dedicated short bias Total directional Fixed income arbitrage Equity market neutral Convertible arbitrage Total arbitrage Multi strategy Event Driven
Source:TASS, Grail Partners analysis
June 2002 42.6 9.3 3.4 3.2 0.3 58.8 5.7 6.8 8.6 21.1 0.8 19.4
June 2005 30.6 9.7 4.9 4.3 0.2 49.7 7.9 5.1 3.9
Part III Lessons to be drawn for future regulation
183
7845.35781499
AA Autoteile Unger Bulgarian Telecommunications Company Deutsche Brse DIS DT-Group eircom Frans Bonhomme Friedrich Grohe AG Gate Gourmet ISS Denmark Linde Mrklin Mobilcom Peguform Picard Stork TDC Telecom Italia Group TUI AG Viterra
189 191 193 195 197 199 200 203 205 209 211 212 216 218 221 223 225 228 231 234 238
AA
1. Company description
The Automobile Association is the UKs largest motoring organisation going back to the start of the Twentieth Century. Formerly a member-driven association it was demutualised in 1999 and sold to the Centrica Group for GBP 1.1 bn. In 2004 it was sold on to two European PE funds, CVC and Permira for GBP 1.75 billion.
2.2 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investment in innovation
Since CVC and Permira bought the AA for [pound]1.75bn from the utility giant Centrica in September 2004, the workforce has been trimmed by 3,000 to 7,000. Within that, the frontline workforce was cut from 3,500 to 3,000. The GMB, which accused the AAs owners of assetstripping, argued that the figures underestimated the cutbacks. Unprofitable service stations were closed with the loss of 1300 jobs Total job losses (including 500 front-line road mechanics staff) totalled 3-3400 out of a workforce of 10-11000. (GBP 100m in redundancy payments) In an audiotape obtained by The Independent the chief executive of the AA, Tim Parker, admits that the amount of workers getting sacked was too many or as he put it You get a few of them (decisions) wrong and I think in the rush for the hills we probably reduced out patrol force more than we should have done.92
Annex 21 Case studies
GMB general union said patrolmen currently applying to take leave were being told the holiday book was closed until March because of insufficient staff.
91 92
Source: http://www.cvceurope.com/about AA Boss admits cutting too many jobs - Independent 27th November 2006
189
2.5 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programmes, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
In the spring of 2006 a further GBP 500 m was to be raised in order to make a special dividend payout. Tim Parker, AA Chief executive, is reputed to have earned GBP 20 m in bonuses, with a further handsome payout when the AA is floated off. Mr Parker, who previously ran Kwik-Fit, also for CVC, is reckoned to have bagged [pound]20m after he cut the workforce there from 10,000 to 7,000 and sold the car repair business to French private equity house PAI. A sale of the AA would lead to another multi-million pound windfall for Mr Parker.93
93
AA Boss admits cutting too many jobs - Independent 27th November 2006
190
Autoteile Unger
1. Company description
The auto parts company A.T.U. operates a chain of accessory stores for motorists and car repair shops. In 2002 A.T.U. had 13 000 employees and a turnover of 1.2 billion. A.T.U. has 14 branches in Austria and intends to focus sharply on foreign markets in the future.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
The private equity investors have changed the accounting and financial structure of the company considerably. The activity of Doughty Hanson led to a sharp increase in the companys leverage ratio to 88% of the balance sheet total. By the end of 2003, the groups equity ratio was down to 6.8%. This was a result of the high percentage of borrowed funds in the purchase price that Doughty Hanson had paid. Because of fairly high operating profits and a good cash flow, Doughty Hanson was already in a position to repay many of its loans. One particular feature of its stewardship was a positive cash flow from investment activity, which is unusual. This came about because the companys own cars were sold off and the vehicle pool was restocked with leased vehicles. This created a one-off liquidity boost, which was used to service the companys borrowings. Nothing is known of the precise motives for the acquisition of A.T.U. by the second private equity investor, KKR. It may be assumed that, even after the activity of Doughty Hanson, KKR considered that there was still scope for further growth and efficiency gains. After the buy-out, KKR undertook considerable restructuring of the company in terms of its legal status, which is common practice in leveraged buy-outs. KKR also financed the bulk of the purchase with borrowed funds. When KKR took over, all of the old borrowings were replaced with new loans or equity. The degree of leverage in the purchase price is not known, but it probably amounted to about 81%. KKR further increased the companys debts by 500 million at the end of 2004, making
191
a total of 1 327 million. Since there was a positive cash flow, KKR was able to deal with the planned debt servicing. The equity ratio was increased slightly to 9.8%. The number of branches, which currently stands at 525, is to be increased to 800 by 2014.
2.3 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
KKR has wielded considerably more influence than Doughty Hanson on the companys internal organization. It has removed board members and introduced an extensive reporting system and now employs stringent targets to exert pressure at the operational level. Although the number of branches has been increased by 10%, the manpower ceiling has been maintained, which means that staff productivity has been considerably enhanced. The working week has been lengthened from 37 to 40 hours. The feeling among the workforce is that the company has lost some of its corporate identity. KKR shows little willingness to share information with the works council.
References:
Finance 09/04, p. 28 f.; Wirtschaftwoche 02.09.04, p. 78; Brsenzeitung 14.10.04, p. 17; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 02.05.05, p. 13; Handelsblatt 06.05.05, p. 3
192
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
Details on BTCs debt structure are difficult to attain but it is instructive that refinancing on the debt has already taken place. In March 2005 Bulgarian BTC refinanced its debt to one of the original backers in the equity deal, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) by drawing a EUR 285m loan. The original EUR 123m loan has, therefore, more than doubled. Putting up the new funds are: Bank Austria Creditanstalt; Citibank; EFG Telesis Finance; and ING. In terms of fees recurred, again, figures are difficult to acquire. However, the advisers on the original privatisation deal were: Cameron McKenna (legal and tax) for Advent; Georgiev, Toderov & Co. and Lega Interconsult (legal); PA Consulting (commercial); PricewaterhouseCoopers (due diligence). The Bulgarian government was advised by Deutsche Bank (financial), Denton Wilde Sapte (legal) and Djingov, Goiuginski, Kyutchukov & Velichkov (legal). Advisers on the Viva Novator deal were: CMS Cameron McKenna for Advent; Linklaters for Novator; and Clifford Chance for Citigroup.
193
194
Deutsche Brse
1. Company description
Deutsche Brse AG is a marketplace organizer for the trading of shares and other securities. It also is a transaction services provider. Deutsche Brse AG operates the Frankfurt Stock Exchange, which is one of the worlds largest trading centres for securities. With a share in turnover of around 90 percent, it is the largest of the eight German stock exchanges. Deutsche Brse employs more than 3,200 people, that service customers in Europe, the U.S. and Asia. It has locations in Germany, Luxembourg, Switzerland and Spain, as well as representative offices in London, Paris, Chicago, New York, Hong Kong, and Dubai. In 1993 Werner Seifert became the chief executive of Deutsche Brse. He focused the stock exchange sharply on growth. After creating the Xetra electronic trading system, which was displacing floor trading and the regional stock exchanges, he had amalgamated the local systems for securities clearing and settlement in the hands of a subsidiary, Clearstream, thereby carving out a monopoly in Germany. He also oversaw the merger of the Swiss and German futures exchanges to become Eurex, the worlds largest derivatives market. After failing to take over the London Stock Exchange in the year 2000, Seifert tried a second time in 2005.
195
The massive interference of shareholders in matters of firm strategy had so far been unusual and practically unheard of in Germany. In response to it the supervisory board brought legal action against the foreign fund companies, alleging that they had acted in concert. It was claimed, that these investors, whose combined stake in Deutsche Brse exceeded 30%, had coordinated their actions with a view to exerting jointly a controlling influence, that was not warranted by the size of their holding alone. Acting in concert is not permitted in Germany. If it nevertheless happens, the holders of the combined stake are required to make an offer to the remaining shareholders for the purchase of their shares. The supervisory board was unable to prove that the fund companies had acted in concert, since the fund companies had no need to strike any such deals, because their views largely coincided anyway. The intervention of the hedge funds in the dealings of the German stock exchange had a very serious consequence: Now the stock market scenery in Europe was anew sorted without participation of Deutsche Brse AG. The prevention of the purchase of the LSE by the German stock exchange was one of the important reasons that subsequently now American stock exchanges received unchecked influence on the big European stock exchanges. Whether this was one of the destinations of the hedge funds beside the income return destinations, is not known.
References
Handelsblatt 10.05.05, p. 18; Brsenzeitung 11.05.05, p. 1, p. 5; Sddeutsche Zeitung 11.05.05, p. 30; Die Welt 12.05.05, p. 3; Handelsblatt 18.05.05, p. 25; Wirtschaftswoche 19.05.05, p. 48 ff.; Brsenzeitung 20.05.05, p. 2, p. 4, p. 9; Sddeutsche Zeitung 20.05.05, p. 25; Handelsblatt 20.05.05, p. 1; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 23.05.05; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 24.05.05, p. 29; Brsenzeitung 24.05.05, p. 3; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 27.05.05, p. 25; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 28.05.05, p. 21; Handelsblatt 12.09.05, p. 24
196
DIS
1. Company description
The DIS Deutscher Industrie Service AG is one of the five largest providers on the German market for temporary employment. Through its specialization in the qualified segment DIS AG is clearly differentiated from the rest of the market. DIS is based in Duesseldorf and it has 161 branches in 73 cities and 7 300 employees. The strategy of DIS AG is based on the concentration on the German market, increasing market share, the provision of qualified personnel services in five clearly separated business divisions and the performance-oriented remuneration of employees.
2.2 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
At the general meeting of 8 June 2006, DIS wanted its shareholders to take decisions to delist the company and cut its dividends. Small investors employed stratagems involving the tabling of numerous motions to ensure that these main items of business could not be discussed on the day of the meeting. The decisions in question were not taken until the early hours of 9 June, whereas the general meeting had been scheduled for 8 June. The Higher Regional Court in Dsseldorf ruled in favour of the litigants who challenged the validity of these decisions, and DIS had to remain a listed company. At the general meeting, Elliott International managed to secure the appointment of a special representative to examine claims for damages. Allegations were raised that DIS chief executive Dieter Scheiff and his head of finance, Dominik de Daniel, who also switched to Adecco, may have divulged trade secrets to DISs former competitor. Adecco had not yet consolidated its position as majority shareholder in the group by means of a control agreement. DIS commissioned a specialists report, which valued the company at 51.82 per share. The offer made to the minority shareholders amounted to 58.50 per share. On 7 June 2006,
197
the day before the general meeting, however, DIS shares had a stock exchange value of 74. The big difference between the two sums is the reason the hedge funds kept their shares with hopes of making a higher profit from their investment.
References
Handelsblatt, 22.02.06, p. 14; Brsenzeitung 23.03.06, p. 20; Brsenzeitung 13.04.06, p. 12; Brsenzeitung 22.04.06, p. 9; HB 07.06.06, p. 12; Brsenzeitung 09.06.06, p. 10; Brsenzeitung 10.06.06, p. 13; HB 12.06.06, p. 19; HB 21.06.06, p. 16; Brsenzeitung 12.07.06, p. 13; Brsenzeitung 04.11.06, p. 13
198
DT-Group
1. Company description
DT Group A/S imports wood and trades building materials (special wood products) and runs chains of building markets. It provided building materials and tools etc to professionals and private in Denmark and Sweden. Turn over is 2 bn and numbers of employed 8.000. DT Group was in many years listened at the Copenhagen Stock Exchange under the name Det Danske Trlastkompani (Danish Wood traders). The DT Group A/S was listened at the Copenhagen Exchange
199
eircom
1. Company description
Eircom is the former national operator in Ireland. In 1983-84 it was set up as a semi state enterprise. Eircom is the principal provider of fixed-line telecommunications services in Ireland with approximately 2.2 million fixed-lines. Eircom is, further to this, the designated universal service provider in the country. The mobile division, Meteor is the third largest mobile operator in Ireland. Meteor has approximately 683,000 mobile subscribers, which includes approximately 5,000 eircom customers.
200
share alternative. At that time the ESOT beneficiary held 21.4% of the ordinary shares. The bid was successful and today the ESOT holds a 35% stake in the company with Babcock & Brown controlling the rest. The sale of eircom was conducted on the terms of a recommended offer under which Babcock & Brown and the eircom Employee Share Ownership Trust jointly making the offer. BCM is an Australian based investment fund that is listed on the Australian stock exchange. BCM is permitted to invest in both Australian and overseas companies and in both listed and private entities. The focus of BCM is on a concentrated portfolio with a flexible investment horizon. For the financial year 2006 results, shared revenue for the period of 1,693m (2005 figure was 1,598m) and EBITA before restructuring pay costs, non cash pension charges and profit on disposal of property and investments of 601m (2005 610m) resulting in an EBITA margin on the same basis of 35%. Eircoms basic earnings per share was 0.08 and net debt as of March 2006 was 2,111m euros.
201
The ESOT was a key aspect of the agreement entered into in 1999 between eircom and the union coalition. This agreement was the blueprint for transforming the state owned company into an entity capable of prospering in the emerging competitive telecommunications market in Ireland. The union coalition is entitled to appoint a majority of the directors to the board of the ESOT. This is a board of seven, four union coalition members, one independent director and two company representatives. The ESOT will have a significantly enhanced ability to influence the business following the most recent purchase. This will be particularly valuable against the unprecedented challenges arising from technological and regulatory developments. Each change recognises that such significant and rapid change requires considerable support from the workforce.
202
Frans Bonhomme
1. Company description
Frans Bonhomme was founded as a family owned business in 1935 when the first shop was open. In 1989 the company became almost completely owned by the Bollore Group. In 1994 the company became by private equity owned, and has since undergone four LBOs. Frans Bonhomme, with more than 120,000 customers in France and more than 30,000 items in its catalogues, is the leader in the distribution of plastic pipes and their accessories destined to construction and public works professionals as well as plumbing tradesmen. Frans Bonhomme is the only specialist player in its field and has a strong position throughout the French territory due to its network of 284 points of sale. The company had a turnover of 538 million in 2004.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
Royal Bank of Scotland provided the debt of the latest LBO.
2.3 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investment in innovation
Thanks to changes in strategy implemented by private equity investors and consequently a renewed management team, Frans Bonhomme has succeeded in achieving its development programme of outlet openings in France and in launching an international expansion. It has now a network of 300 shops compared to 145 in 1998. Geographic expansion was followed by a significant increase in employment level.
203
2.6 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programmes, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
With the fourth LBO the number of employees participating in the transaction has been increased from 500 to 800.
204
Friedrich Grohe AG
1. Company description
The Friedrich Grohe company is a manufacturer of sanitary and kitchen fittings with a 10% share of the world market. In 1968 Friedrich Grohe sold 51% of his shares to the American group ITT. This sale improved the international position of the company. In 1983 Friedrich Grohes sons bought back the shares from ITT. In 1991 Grohe was converted into a joint stock company, and in the same year it was floated on the stock exchange. At the end of 2004 the company had 5 800 employees.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
Before the private equity investment firms took it over, the Grohe company had a rather high equity ratio, which averaged 50% in the years from 1994 to 1998. The free cash flow was also high. The company had been profitable for a long time before the investors moved in. When the first private equity fund made its investment, the equity ratio fell to 6.2% by 2003. There even was a negative leverage effect; in other words, the overall return on investment fell below the interest payable on the borrowed capital. The reason for this was the high leverage ratio and the consequent interest burden. There was no option for the fund but to reduce the planned investments of the company. In 2003 not even the curtailed investment could be funded from the cash flow. Although turnover increased considerably from 769 million in 1999 to 911 million in 2004, and the companys performance in terms of earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortisation (Ebitda) improved from 126 million to a record high of 185 million, record losses of 100 million were nevertheless posted under the management of the second private equity investors in 2004 because of the heavy interest burden.
Annex 21 Case studies
Industry experts believe that the purchase price paid by the second group of investors was far too high. The following reasons were probably crucial in their decision to buy out the company: They sensed, that there was good growth potential in the company, which enjoyed an international reputation. Also they saw good prospects for further expansion in what was considered
205
to be a lucrative German market, and they hoped to find further hidden reserves in the company, but these no longer existed, having been unlocked long before by BC Partners. Along with the negative leverage effect, returns on equity also slipped into minus figures. Because of the high purchase price that TPG and CSFB paid BC Partners, Grohes level of debt, which had already been high, underwent another steep increase. That caused the rating agency Moodys to reduce Grohes credit rating. Moodys finds fault in the high interest and restructuring costs and claims, that they will probably continue to absorb a significant part of the operative cashflow. The turnover in the third quarter in 2006 rose by 15.3% on 900 Mil. EUR, the EBITDA on the basis of reorganisation expenses only about 14%. In January, 2007 a variably bearing interest loan (floating rate note) was brought in the volume of 800 Mil. EUR by Grohe to the capital market. Together with a new credit line of 150 Mil. EUR the whole bank debts were replaced with it. Already in 2004 a loan of the same sort was transferred. Both loans have together a volume of 1,135 Bn. EUR and are payable in 2014. An analyst from S&P means, the new loan would improve Grohes liquidity position significantly. 80 Mil. EUR of credit line and 30 Mil. EUR of liquid means would be available with it to the company. Besides, the credit conditions were less strict than with bank loan. But on the other side the risks implied by the financial instruments are very high and the term of the loan will not coincide with the term of the involvement of the PE-investor.
2.3 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investments in innovation
Under the first private equity investor, BC Partners, there were very encouraging developments: further progress was made in internationalising the company, its organisational structure was modernised, new products were put on the market more quickly, the product range was diversified, and expenditure on research and development was increased.
2.4 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
In respect to its rising level of debt the company was close to saturation point. This was to have serious repercussions at a time when commodity prices were rising, the industry was entering a difficult period, and competition in general was becoming tougher. One of the companys responses was to shift a large part of its production to low-wage countries. In the view of industry experts, that was a strategic error. They believe it could damage the prestigious Grohe brand, which might lead to a sharp fall in sales. By now this danger has also been recognised by Grohes management. The brand Grohe is to be maintained as a premium brand. Thats why the chairman of the board, Haines, does not plan to cut back any more jobs in Germany. In the course of their restructuring drive, the second set of private equity investors have constantly sought to play off the companys various locations and their workforces against each other. The workforces in the companys plants and their works councils concede that they have not cooperated as closely with each other as they might have done. The works councils interviewed describe the representatives of the private equity investors as people who have no emotional bond with the Grohe brand and the companys products. They do not identify with the company and its staff but regard Grohe as nothing more than a financial asset. While the works councils were still able to cooperate in a professional manner with BC Partners, they describe
206
their relations with TPG and CSFB as adversarial and say that cooperation between management and labour has deteriorated dramatically. TPG and CSFB were now intervening heavily in the operational and strategic management of the company. Major changes have been made at senior management level. When the company dropped into the red, the private equity investors brought in McKinsey management consultants to identify non-essential expenditure. The consultants proposed an accelerated internationalisation drive, relocation of numerous production facilities to other countries, a tighter purchasing policy, a smaller range of products and a slimmer administration. The main brunt of restructuring was to be borne by the staff in Germany, many of whom would lose their jobs. The plants at Lahr in the Black Forest, Herzberg and Porta Westfalica would be closed down, leaving only the Hemer and Ludwigsfelde factories in Germany. More than half of the jobs in Germany, totalling 2 700, would be axed. The works council commissioned its own specialists report, which proposed the preservation of the plants in Hemer, Lahr and Porta Westfalica. The report also proposed that there should only be 842 job cuts. It recommended a considerably smaller degree of relocation abroad than McKinsey had proposed. In June 2005, the works council and the company management reached an agreement whereby 943 employees would be made redundant by the end of 2006. Natural wastage would account for another 290 jobs. The company would continue to operate at all of its locations except Herzberg. In August of 2006 it became known, that due to good going business Grohe will lay off less employees than agreed. Instead of 943 workers only 770 will have to leave the company. Nevertheless the dubious actions of the private equity investors had serious repercussions for the companys workforce, which has been suffering for years from the uncertainty of becoming redundant.
207
References
Wirtschaftswoche 02.09.04, p. 78; Frankfurter Rundschau 09.06.05, p. 9; Handelsblatt 09.06.05, p. 11; Der Spiegel 02.05.05, p. 134; Handelsblatt 06.05.05, p. 3; Sddeutsche Zeitung 07./08.05.05, p. 27; Handelsblatt 24.05.05, p.17; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 24.05.05, p. 18; Sddeutsche Zeitung 31.05.05, p. 28, Sddeutsche Zeitung 01.09.05, p. 30. Financial Times Deutschland 24.08.06, p. 3; Brsenzeitung 10.01.07, p. 13; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 10.01.07, p. 19; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung net 15.01.07.
208
Gate Gourmet
1. Company description
For a long time Gate Gourmet was considered SwissAirs Crown Jewel. The company was worth roughly 6 billion Swiss Francs before the bankruptcy of Swissair and the 9/11 impact on the aviation sector. Gate Gourmet, was bought by Texas Pacific Group in 2002 for around CHF 1 billion. Gate Gourmets then CEO welcomed the sale with these words: Through a combination of strategic acquisitions and organic growth, Gate Gourmet should experience continued success. At the time of its acquisition by Texas Pacific Group, Gate Gourmet employed over 26,000 workers in 33 countries with 144 flight kitchens. As Gate Gourmet was formerly the wholly-owned airline catering division of SwissAir, Gate Gourmet were publicly listed. After the Texas Pacific Group acquisition Gate Gourmet is now a privately held company. In practice this means that almost none financial details concerning the company are disclosed.
2.2 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investment in innovation
Workers at Gate Gourmet have experienced severe job cuts since being acquired by Texas pacific group. At the time of the acquisition, Gate Gourmet employed 26 000 workers operating 144 flight kitchens. The company today operates 97 flight kitchens with 20 000 employees, despite the fact that airline traffic has recovered from the 9/11 shock. On March 2, 2006, Reuters reported the following: A day after Texas Pacific Group joined other powerful private equity houses in a call for more transparency; the firms mystery sell-off of Gate Gourmet reveals just how much work the industry has ahead of it. TPG, which bought the airline catering firm in late 2002 from Swissair, has quietly reduced its stake in the business over the past year without any disclosure, selling the last piece to Merrill Lynch on Thursday. Gate gourmet employees learned about it through the press. Especially one round of job cuts has caught the attention of the media and public: In August 2005 some 800 workers were sacked by the airline caterer Gate Gourmet at London Heathrow airport. The Transport and General Workers Union (T&G) had been in negotiations with Gate Gourmet since February over measures to deal with a massive projected operating loss at Heathrow. A rescue package was put forward in June, but when it became clear that management was excluded from the cost-cutting measures, the workforce rejected the package. In
209
August, Gate Gourmet announced their intention to hire 120 temporary workers while permanent staff continued to work under the threat of being made redundant. The company ignored calls for discussions and brought in the temporary workers. Workers on sick leave and holiday were informed by letter that they had been sacked. In addition Gate Gourmet also found themselves in a bitter labour dispute in the United States in the summer of 2005. Unions presenting Gate Gourmet employees successfully sued to get their health benefits after the company tried to eliminate them.
2.4 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programmes, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
Gate Gourmet, which has sought concessions on wages and benefits averaging from 2535% at all its operations since being acquired by TPG in 2002, illustrates well the heightened aggressiveness and willingness to attack established industrial relations norms by corporate managements imposing radical restructuring programs to meet the demands of the new private equity owners. EU legislation on information and consultation were of no help in curbing management aggression either in the UK or in Germany. Workers reported that relations with managers had deteriorated in the months preceding the disputes. In order to make cost savings, Gate Gourmet management reportedly cut sick pay entitlement, intensified work, by requiring workers to service a greater number of flights, and reduced overtime rates.
210
ISS Denmark
1. Company description
The ISS-group is an international service group, which provides different services, primarily cleaning. The group operate in many countries, and have 370.000 employees, mostly unskilled and often people of foreign origin. The turn over was 7 bn and the profit nearly 6% of turnover before the LBO. The group have an important and comprehensive internal education program (The International Cleaning academy) and have little turnover of employees compared with other service groups. The ISS group is known for its important social responsibility for the employees and their families. The ISS was listed at the Copenhagen Stock Exchange up to the take-over.
211
Linde
1. Company description
Linde is a traditional conglomerate, which was founded in 1879. Its four business areas until 2003 were: industrial gases, materials-handling (fork lift trucks and pallet trucks), engineering and refrigeration (refrigeration equipment for food retailers). Linde took over AGA the largest Swedish industrial gases producer in 2000, making it one of the top five companies in this sector. The post-war period saw the company emerge as a potential take-over target on a number of occasions. At this time board chairmen persuaded large German financial institutions to take substantial shareholdings in the company. The result was that about 25 years ago Deutsche Bank and Commerzbank each acquired 10% of the shares and Allianz-Versicherung 12.5%.94 In the more recent period analysts and representatives of capital markets repeatedly called on the company to concentrate on its strongest business area industrial gases and to sell the other parts of the group. They calculated that the conglomerate status of the company reduced its stock market value by about 30%. As the large financial institutions of the old Germany AG have been making efforts to sell their holdings in industrial companies, it became clear that Linde would sooner or later come under pressure. Institutional investors in the USA and the UK built up their holdings in the German company from 14% to a total of 24%. US investors accounted for one-third of the total holdings of the institutions. At the start of 2003 Wolfgang Reitzle became the new CEO. He responded to the capital market pressure and stated that he wanted the group to concentrate solely on industrial gases.
94
This pattern, with German financial groups holding substantial stakes in German industrial companies, was at one time a key feature of the countrys corporate structure old Germany AG.
212
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
Linde took on 3.4 billion debt to pay for the take-over of the Swedish company AGA, which has largely been paid off. It planned to finance the take-over of BOC from a range of sources: first, through a 1.8 billion increase in capital through the issue of new shares; second, through a hybrid bond worth 1 billion; third by taking on 9 billion debt; and fourthly by selling parts of the group, in particular the materials-handling business (now renamed the Kion Group), as well as some smaller parts of BOC. In addition the competition authorities have required Linde and BOC to dispose of businesses in specific regions of the world where previously both companies were represented. Linde and BOC are in very good shape, with both sales and profits rising sharply recently. Operating income in the new company will be approximately 1.8 billion, so the debt could be paid off in around five years. Linde is behaving in a way which is very similar to that of a private equity fund and is using almost the same leveraged buyout (LBO) methods. During the take-over period, funds investing on a short-term basis are estimated to have held some 30% of the shares. This repeatedly spurred on market excitement, keeping the share price of both BOC and Linde at high levels.95 In November 2006 Linde AG sold its forklift section to KKR and Goldman Sachs. . Private equity funds were interested in the materials-handling business, as the constantly high cash flow provides them with a good basis to take on a high level of debt for an LBO. The risks for both company and shareholders are relatively low. In the bidders fight had also taken part: Permira/alliance Capital, partner / Apax BC and CVC. In the purchase price of 4 Bn. euros 400 Mil. net finance debts which covered pension and leasing liabilities were included. The purchase was financed to three quarters with debts. The repayment of the debt admission for Kion was arranged final-due. In the hold phase by the financial investors only the interest is to be paid. This should permit more flexibility and higher investments. But the loan has to be paid back at a term where the investors probably will have exited. There should not be a refinancing about special dividends with Kion according to KKR.
2.3 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investments in innovation
Following the sale of the refrigeration business to the US group Carrier, there were massive job cuts in this area in Germany, as large parts of the production were transferred abroad. The new CEO has introduced programmes in all areas to improve effectiveness. Organisation has been improved and earnings have been reduced and in part linked to company performance. Working time has been lengthened and made more flexible and more shifts have been introduced to improve the utilisation of the companys assets. Reitzle has emphasised that the merger with BOC will not lead to the loss of any jobs in either Germany or the UK. However, the sale of individual parts of the business means that these jobs will be located in other companies or will become the responsibility of financial investors. And it is impossible to predict how employment in these areas may develop in the future. Reitzle promised the German works council that Kion, the materials-handling business, would not be broken up before it was sold; in addition there is an agreement between the management and the works council the employment guarantee under which there can be no dismissals for economic grounds until 2011. The trade union IG Metall and the works council have forced that this agreement be also valid for any purchaser of the business something which was a barrier for financial investors before the deal. Both new owners of Kion are bound to the agreement.
95
Brsen-Zeitung 21.02.2006
213
Some difficulties can be expected over the next two years because of friction between cultures as the two companies merge. However, planned innovations and investments seem likely to be continued. For example, a new plant near Munich, producing pure gases for the semi-conductor industry, has recently been brought into operation.
2.6 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
Under Reitzle the board of Linde has fostered good contacts with the representatives of the workforce and given them extensive information. This will be the same in the new company.
214
References
Sddeutsche Zeitung 09.06.05, p. 24; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 29.06.05, p. 12; Brsenzeitung 05.09.06, p. 13; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 22.09.06, p. 17; Financial Times Deutschland 19.10.06, p. 3; managermagazin11/06, p. 91ff.; Brsenzeitung 01.11.06, p. 11; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 01.11.06, p. 18; Handelsblatt 01.11.06, p. 17; Financial Times Deutschland 02.11.06, p. 10; Sddeutsche Zeitung 02.11.06, p. 28; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 02.11.06, p. 18; Handelsblatt 07.11.06, p. 21; Financial Times Deutschland 07.11.206, p. 1, p. 10; Brsenzeitung 07.11.06, p. 1, p.11; Handelsblatt 07.11.06, p. 1; Financial Times 07.11.06, p. 13; Financial Times Deutschland 17.11.06, p. 10; Brsenzeitung 23.11.06, p. 9; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 24.11.06, p. 18; Brsenzeitung 28.11.06,p. 9; Brsenzeitung 22.12.06, p. 10; Brsenzeitung 09.01.06, p. 9; Brsenzeitung 09.01.07, p. 9.
215
Mrklin
1. Company description
Mrklin is the worlds largest manufacturer of model railways. It bought up Trix, which used to be the second-largest model railway manufacturer. At the present time, Mrklin has 1 000 employees in Germany and another some 300 in a plant in Hungary. The company has production facilities at three locations in Germany. In 2005 Mrklins turnover fell to 123 million, compared with 148.5 million in 2004 and 164.4 million in 2003. Group losses amounted to 6.8 million in 2005. The company had a credit line of 60 million with several banks. Having taken up 55 million of this facility, it had almost exhausted its credit.
2.2 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investments in innovation
Before the acquisition by Kingsbridge Capital 340 employees had been dismissed in 2004. Directly after the acquisition the financial investors made at first no statements about activity changes. In January, 2007 the company for the current year announced a planned place reduction of 310 of a total of 1340 employees. After the turnover would be stabilised, now one goes to the cost structures, said the manager anew named in September, 2006 Jan Kantowsky. The most important measure is the reorganisation of the manufacture with the reduction on two of four locations up to now. The plants in Thuringian Sonneberg with 220 employees and in Nrnberg with 60 employees are closed down, other 60 colleagues in the home office Gppingen will lose their workplace. The more slender manufacturing processes and the allocation of works on supplier should provide from now on also for higher efficiency like new machines.
216
2.3 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
The investor has appointed two new members to the board: a new financial director and a director responsible for the restructuring process. The former CEO Paul Adams, has left the company half a year later, after helping them to develop a capital spending plan. The investors strategy involves trying to rekindle interest in model railways among the young generation. This is likely to prove difficult. Children and young people prefer to devote their leisure time to the use of technological products computer games and mobile phones being the current favourites. The investor also wants to improve marketing outside Germany and to boost sales in numerous European countries. Production and marketing are to be rationalized. Also the corporate management contemplates opening an amusement park around the theme of model railways. It is to be opened in 2009, when Mrklin celebrates its 150th birthday. Many workers oppose the idea, because they believe, that it is meant as a distraction from cuts in production. Adding to that, one earns less selling candy in an amusement park than being a skilled worker in production. Besides there are already two amusement parks in the area and they dont operate profitably. The first destination after the acquisition by the investor is the stabilization of the turnovers. The production and the distribution should become more effective. As the first measure the sales were strongly upgraded at own account about an online shop in the Internet and in the factoryowned museum loading. This led to strong criticism of the specialist suppliers who saw own position weak. After a clearing discussion the dealers from the single point-of-sales should be incorporated in the Internet business. The toy turnover could be increased in 2006 by about 4%. Nevertheless, 2006 was closed again with a loss. In total the investments are increased in 2007 towards in 2006 by 50% on 15 Mil. EUR.
References
Wirtschaftswoche 11.12.03, p. 60f.; Mrklin Presseinfo 16.12.2005, www.mrklin.com; Financial Times Deutschland 19.12.05, p. 6; Financial Times Deutschland 17.03.06, p. 7; Sddeutsche Zeitung 18/19.03.06, p. 25; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 21.03.06, p. 18; Handelsblatt 27.03.06, p. 12f. ; Sddeutsche Zeitung 26.04.06, p. 28; Financial Times Deutschland 26.04.06, p. 7; Financial Times Deutschland 08.05.06, p. 8; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 11.05.06, p. 18; Brsenzeitung 13.05.06, p. 9; Handelsblatt 15.05.06, p. 14; focus online. 17.05.06; Sddeutsche Zeitung 26.05.06, p. 23; Handelsblatt 16.10.06, p. 14; managermagazin 12/2006, p. 120; Financial Times Deutschland 06.12.06, p. 4; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 07.12.06, p. 18; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 11.01.07, p. 12; Handelsblatt 11.01.06, p. 16; Sddeutsche Zeitung 11.01.06, p. 21.
217
Mobilcom
1. Company description
Mobilcom is a listed mobile communications company. It does not have its own network but buys blocks of airtime from other carriers and resells them to its own customers. Its subsidiary freenet.de is an Internet service provider. In 2000 the company took part in the Federal Governments auction of UMTS licenses (Mobile broadband network) and obtained an operating license for 8 billion. Its turnover in the past few years has amounted to some 2 billion.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
Before the planned merger with Freenet, Mobilcom once more had a high liquidity ratio as a result of the disposal of its debts. Mobilcoms routine business yielded steady operating profits. This aroused the interest of the private equity investor, as did the fact that the book values of Mobilcoms assets were set very low in relation to their real current value. A merger with Freenet would offer the opportunity to convert the balance sheet from book values to current values. This
218
would have unlocked hidden reserves of 800 to 1 000 million euros, providing an opportunity to pay special dividends or to raise the leverage ratio by means of new borrowing. TPG was firmly resolved to pay out several hundred million euros to shareholders in the form of special dividends. The dividends have yet to be paid, perhaps because TPG is marking time in the face of the wide publicity given to its aggressive recapitalization plans. Thorsten Grenz, chief executive of Mobilcom, wanted nothing to do with this windfall and resigned his post.
2.3 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investments in innovation
In the merger agreement between Mobilcom and Freenet it was laid down that there were to be no merger-related job cuts. This arrangement would probably be respected in the initial stages if Mobilcom and Freenet actually merged. Nothing is known of any other effects on the workforce.
2.4 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
In July 2005 a merger agreement was concluded between Mobilcom and Freenet and ratified by a general meeting. Numerous shareholders brought legal actions in a bid to stop the merger. The opponents of the merger stated that the special dividends on which TPG was particularly insistent were the main bone of contention. They wanted a contractual guarantee that special dividends could not be paid before 2010. They doubted TPGs declarations of its intent to foster the growth of Mobilcom. Eckhard Spoerr, head of Mobilcom, offered a binding embargo on special dividends for the period from 2006 to 2008, but only if the payment of such dividends would prevent acquisitions. The legal disputes over Mobilcom are obstructing all the major activities of the mobile telecommunications company and its ISP subsidiary. Major acquisitions are rendered impossible, and all for want of access to the pooled finances of the two companies this in 2006, at a time when Mobilcom has a high liquidity ratio. Due to the judicial problems Mobilcom has lost the strategic scope of one year. Thats why analysts and shareholders ask themselves the question, which advantage the fusion of Freenet and Mobilcom will bring in the face of current market conditions. In this situation a notably smaller company put Mobilcom on the spot. In October of 2006 the mobile radiotelephone service provider Drillisch has surprisingly taken over a 10.37% share of Mobilcom. Drillisch wants to create one mega-provider out of the four biggest service providers in Germany. The goal is to get the competitors Debitel and Talkline as well as the own company to operate under the name of Mobilcom. Therefore the CEO of Drillisch wants the fusion of Freenet and Mobilcom to fail, so that Freenet can be sold to the highest bidding. Regardless of the wishes of Drillisch, as Mobilcoms supervisory board stated on the 6th of November, management is to stay focused on a fusion with its subsidiary company Freenet.
Annex 21 Case studies
The sale of the stake held by France Tlcom was linked with the shareholders claims for damages against the French telecommunications group. As a party to the dispute, FT was unable to take part in the vote in April 2004. At the extraordinary general meeting in October 2005, the new owner of its former block of shares, TPG, was not bound by this restriction since it was not a party
219
to the dispute. TPG moved that the decision taken in April 2005 to press claims for 3.7 billion in damages against FT be overturned. The shareholder structure at the time of the October EGM was as follows: 60% of the shares were spread among numerous smaller investors, TPG held 28.7%, Henderson Global Investors held 6%, and Hermes Focus Management held 5.3%. The second main item on the agenda of the EGM in October 2005 was a motion for approval of the merger of Mobilcom and Freenet. The motion was carried. Shareholding staff members at Mobilcom now brought court actions against the merger too. Despite statements to the contrary from the company management, they feared that the merger would lead to substantial job cuts. In December 2005 a court ruled that the decision taken by the general meeting in 2003 approving the compromise deal with France Tlcom had been invalid. Although the deal remained in effect, the board of Mobilcom was ruled to have been solely responsible for the situation leading to the withdrawal of FT. This meant that shareholders were now able to claim damages against the Mobilcom board. The Schutzvereinigung der Kleinaktionre (SdK), a group dedicated to the protection of small shareholders, exercised this right and brought an action for damages against the board of Mobilcom.
References
managermagazin 06/2001, p.102ff; managermagazin 01/2003, p. 50ff. ; Financial Times Deutschland 05.05.05, p. 3; Brsenzeitung 08.06.05, p. 11; Spiegel, 11.07.05, p. 105; Financial Times Deutschland 11.07.05, p. 3; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, 12.07.05, p. 15; Brsenzeitung 12.07.05, p. 9; Financial Times Deutschland 21.07.05, p. 14; Brsenzeitung 16.07.05, p. 13; Wirtschaftswoche online 05.08.05; Die Welt 18.08.05, p. 15; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 18.08.05, p. 12; taz 24.08.05, p. 8; Handelsblattonline 24.08.05, Sddeutsche Zeitung 24.08.05, p. 20; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 09.11.05, p. 20; Financial Times Deutschland 09.21.05, p. 4; Welt 15.02.06, p. 39; Sddeutsche Zeitung 01.03.06, p. 22; Handelsblatt 09.05.06, p. 26; Handelsblatt 10.05.06, p. 20; Handelsblatt 20.06.06, p. 14; managermagazin 7/2006, p. 22 f.; Financial Times Deutschland 09.08.06, p. 4; Handelsblatt 16.08.06, p. 12; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 22.08.06, p. 12; Handelsblatt 22.08.06, p. 14; Handelsblatt 23.08.06, p. 12; Handelsblatt 31.08.06, p. 12; Brsenzeitung 14.09.06, p. 12; Handelsblatt 25.09.06, p. 19; Handelsblatt 10.10.06, p. 19; 09.11.06, p. 5; Brsenzeitung 09.11.06, p. 10; Brsenzeitung 01.12.06, p. 11; Handelsblatt 17.01.07; p. 16.
220
Peguform
1. Company description
The history of Peguform started in 1959 with the Baden-Plastic Werke in Btzingen which produced plastic products (films and household goods). However, it was first in 1978 that the company name Peguform-Werke AG was introduced. At the same time the company entered the automotive market (bumpers, exterior systems, cockpits and instrument panels and interiors), which is today the single focus of Peguform. In 1999 Venture Industries, an American auto supplier, took over the Peguform Group. In May 2002 the management of the German companies applied for preliminary insolvency. In October 2002 the insolvency procedure was opened. After reorganization, which was possible due to participation by employees and financial guarantees provided by customers, the American private equity fund Cerberus took over the Peguform Group (Germany, Spain, Mexico, and Brazil).
2.2 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investment in innovation
After filing for insolvency in 2002, the well-known insolvency administrator Dr. Jobst Wellensiek together with the Rothschild Investment Bank drew up a list of potential buyers. Three financial investors and three strategic investors made offers and the offer of Cerberus was accepted. All potential buyers required a reduction of operating costs. They all required from employees a reduction in personnel costs of 40 million euros, which represented approximately one sixth of the total personal cost of 260 million euros. This was agreed in a reorganization collective contract together by the IG BCE employees and Cerberus. For the most part, an increase in working time to 39 hours per week without an increase in salary, and an income reduction of 4 percent was established. Also agreed was a reduction of Christmas and holiday pay. Thus the burden was around 10 percent per employee, including those not covered by the collective contract and senior managers. The contract is valid for five years. Collective pay raises will only be implemented by half. Lay offs are possibly only with the consent of the works council. For reductions in capacity due to the evolution of the auto industry, personnel adoptions are possible in accordance with an opening clause.
221
Restructurings at the expense of employees were part of the sale agreements. In the first round, 500 jobs were eliminated. A second wave of layoffs will soon take place. However, the employees do not blame the job cutback only on the financial investor. Rather they are to a greater extent economically determined by a slump in sales among the auto manufacturers. For that reason there is a fundamental understanding of the need to back jobs.
2.4 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programmes, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
In the Supervisory Board and the works council there have been cultivated a culture of consensus which have stood the test of time. This is based on the understanding that the Peguform plants should not be played off against each other. Problems at individual plans have been and are quickly discussed at the company-wide level. The prevailing belief is that problems of profitability at individual locations must be solved together by all plants.
222
Picard
1. Company description
Picard was created in 1973 by Armand Decelle who acquired a small home delivery business based in Fontainbleau. In 1994 the company was sold by Carrefour and in 2001 bought out by management and members of the founding family backed by the private equity investors being Candover, Chevrillon, Montagu and Astorg. In 2004 a second LBO took place, it was led by BC Partners and management still headed by a member of the Decelle family. The company now has a market share of more than 16% and is the major frozen food retailer in France. Its sales network consists of 640 stores and over 20 home delivery centers in France and 42 shops in Italy. Picard also offers a home delivery service in London. The pace of organic growth in France is of 40 stores per year. Picard offers a range of more than 1,000 basic and ready-made products. Five warehouses, two of which are directly managed by Picard, ensure the stores supply.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
Calyon and RBS provided the debt of the second LBO.
2.3 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investment in innovation
Since the first buyout Picard has developed its network from 441 shops in 2002 to 640 in 2006 which represents a 45% growth and has a clear impact on the employment level. In 2002 firms headcount was of 2200 which has increased by 59% and totaled 3500 in 2006. With 40 new shops every year, Picard is a constantly developing enterprise that still retains a human dimension. Picard invest more than 2.5% of its total payroll in training to enable the employees to evelop skills either in the sales network (shops and home services) or in relation to backup roles (human resources, expansion, communication, purchasing, logistics, IT).
Annex 21 Case studies
223
From the beginning of LBO ownership, Picard has increased its market share and strengthen its brand thanks to the quality products resulting from its large focus on innovation.
224
Stork
1. Company description
The industrial firm Stork consists of three divisions: Aerospace, Food and Prints. Stork is planning to sell the Prints division, but because of the high prices of nickel (an important input), the selling is until now not successful. In the past years, Stork made excellent returns. Nowadays however, the company is faced with more difficult market circumstances, because of the very small profit margins in the Food and Aerospace industries. Moreover, theres uncertainty about delays with Airbus and the development of the European transport chopper NH90.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
At this moment, Stork is in good financial health. How this will change after a possible splitting up, is not known.
Annex 21 Case studies
225
2.3 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investments in innovation
The comment of the Dutch labour union (FNV Bondgenoten) is as follows: Centaurus and Paulson have imperceptible increased their shares in Stork. They were able to do that without publicity, because they bought their shares by means of sorts of Ltd.s. As long as one Ltd. has no more than 5% of total shares in a company, you are not obliged to report your ownership to the authorities. By now, the hedge funds own rather 30% of the shares and use their shareholder power to have Stork splitted up. They want the divisions Food and Technological Services (Prints) to be sold; Stork should specialize on Aerospace. When this happens, FNV Bondgenoten fears that employment will disappear. Moreover, Dutch labour unions investigate whether Dutch pension funds have shares in Paulson and Centaurus. The pension fund of the metal industry is not willing to sell of their investments in Paulson.
2.5 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programmes, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information.
Stork asked for some time for reflection to think about the motion. But everyone knew that the board of directors does not see any prospect in the proposed splitting up. The board of directors indeed rejected the motion. As reaction to this, Paulson and Centaurus asked for a third extraordinary shareholders meeting in which they ask for two measures: 1) To abandon the confidence in the board of commissioners; 2) To have all spendings above 100 million euro approved of by the shareholders. In the meantime, the board of directors of Stork asked the law court of Amsterdam to start an investigation whether the hedge funds complied with the duty to report about their shareholdings. They may have been broken the law. On December 21 and January 17 witness hearings will take place. Also, the board of directors planned to use a so-called poisson pill: Stork would offer new shares to the Stichting Stork, a organization that has only one goal: protecting Stork from a violent bid. Stichting Stork would then have a majority vote on the shareholders meeting. Dutch judge president Willems of the Law Court decided the following to overcome the impasse: Stork is not allowed to emit new shares to Stichting Stork. The hedge funds are not allowed to send off the board of commissioners. Instead, the Law Court appointed three men to become
226
special members of the board of commissioners: former president of Akzo Kees van de Lede, former prime-minister Wim Kok and former cfo of Philips Dudley Eustace. They have to find a solution for the conflict. Both Stork and the hedgefunds were happy with this judgement. Also the labor unions were happy. On the one hand, a firm as Stork is not allowed to make use of some protection construction; this means more power to (hostile) shareholders. On the other hand, shareholders have to consider also the interests of employees. On this moment, the three special commissioners are doing their job. The final result is not known yet. In the meantime, Stork announced to do some small and big takeovers this year.
227
TDC
1. Company description
TDC is the former national operator in Denmark. As well as continuing dominance of the Danish market, the company has expanded its portfolio to include significant holdings in Switzerland and Central Europe. In 2005 TDC employed some 20,000 staff, 2/3 of which are based in the domestic business and 1/3 internationally. Revenue in 2005 stood at EUR 6,245m while net income was just under EUR 1,000m. TDC is organized as six main business lines: TDC Solutions, TDC Mobile International, TDC Switzerland, TDC Cable TV, TDC Directories, and TDC Services. TDC was partly privatised in 1994 and fully privatised in 1998.
228
EUR 5.1 billion private equity fund. The investors in the fund are mostly pension funds and other institutional investors based primarily in Europe and the United States. The Permira Funds have since their inception had a strong focus on telecoms and technology investing over 30% of all investments in this sector. Providence is a global private investment firm specializing in equity investments in media, communications and information companies around the world. The principals of Providence Equity manage funds with over USD 9.0 billion in equity commitments, including Providence Equity Partners V, a USD 4.25 billion private equity fund, and have invested in more than 80 companies operating in over 20 countries since the firms inception in 1990.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
TDCs purchase, for just under EUR 12bn, at the time the largest LBO ever seen in Europe, was based on slightly more than 80% leverage (just over EUR 9bn) and 20% equity from the five purchasers. Capital management fees are still unclear at this stage but will be in the tens of million of euros area. According to the prospect of the LBO the cost for legal and financial advisers will be 524 mill . Probably some part of the fees will go to the 5 equity funds and the managing partners in the funds.
2.3 Effects on job creation, investment in training and education of labour force, investment in innovation.
Already before the LBO, the TDC have stated a planned reduction of the workforce. This plan will be carried on, and it seemed that the new management will speed up the plan. It seemed, that the TDC will now stop investment in minority interests in foreign mobile telephone companies, and will sell the actual portfolio of minority interests I different European mobile telephone companies.
229
2.5 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on Board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
The TDC management and board, which had espoused the sound financial position of the company before the takeover, have seen significant personal returns on their holdings in the company while TDC has seen debt, interest rates and risk exposure rocket and investment capacity crumble. Following the takeover, TDCs new owners were awarded an immediate cash dividend four times annual earnings already paid. The April 2006 dividend was worth some EUR 5.9bn to the new owners.
230
Price/earnings ratio: derives from the ratio between the stock market capitalisation and net profit. Indicates the level at which the market values earnings.
231
try, in conjunction with the Minister of Telecommunications, had a specific political idea, namely that Telecom Italia would become the first Italian public company to bring together small savers and the capital market, which at that point was under-developed by comparison with its European partners. There were two types of ownership structure which could be used as a basis: the Anglo-Saxon public company and the typically French hard core structure. While the first would ensure widespread share ownership with good protection for minority shareholders, it would also have made the Telecom Italia Group excessively vulnerable, exposing it to acquisitions by foreign companies (something that the Government did not welcome in such a strategic sector). The public company model also had many negative aspects with regard to corporate governance, such as the agency costs associated with the marked separation between ownership and control, which could lead to opportunistic behaviour on the part of management. Adoption of the hard core structure, on the other hand, would undoubtedly have brought about greater involvement of a stable shareholder base in the companys performance, but would have run counter to the principle underlying privatisation itself. Although the privatisation of Telecom Italia was adjudged a success from the purely technical point of view, given the large number of savers who bought into it, the same cannot be said about the choice of ownership structure. Negative signs of instability, unmanageability, and the lack of a leading shareholder with experience of the industry who would pursue a clear, agreed goal all emerged in short order. In October 1998, although the company still actually benefited from a monopoly position and high cash flow, it was valued at a multiple of only 1.9 times its net worth, compared with a figure of 3 for Deutsche Telekom (DT) and more than 4 for France Tlcom (FT) and British Telecom (BT). The P/E ratio96 was 19, compared with 22 for BT and 28 for FT and DT. Franco Bernab took the helm at the Telecom Italia Group in January 1999; he was a manager whom the market appeared to favour, given his previous success with restructuring ENI. However, international investors criticised the Groups financial structure, which carried too little debt by comparison with what could be regarded as the optimum level. The Groups low level of debt, together with its high and stable cash flow (from TIM, especially), were the factors which opened up the possibility of a stock market raid, using high financial leverage. This situation thus made Telecom Italia a potential target. Towards the end of November 1998 it attracted the attention of Roberto Colaninno, the Managing Director of Olivetti; in February 1999, following a series of rumours of a possible stock market raid, he launched a hostile takeover bid.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees required by LBO
The operation envisaged the involvement of a new company (Tecnost), to be used as vehicle to take on the debts generated by the operation, which would then be transferred to Telecom Italia through a future merger, which then never took place. In theory the acquisition should have been followed by the merger between Tecnost and Telecom Italia, resulting in the latter shouldering the debt used to acquire it. According to the analyses carried out by the advisers the debt taken on by new Telecom was supposed to be 38 billion ( 5.5 inherited from the pre-acquisition situation, and 32.5 bn from the bank loans and bonds constituting the Tecnost dowry). Net borrowings are now close to 40 000 m.
232
233
TUI AG
1. Company description
TUI AG is Europes largest travel group, with its main offices in Hanover and Berlin. It employs 63,000 people worldwide, and in 2005 it had a turnover of 19,610 million and profits of 495 million. The company emerged from the former steel group Preussag AG, an industrial conglomerate with a number of holdings. Under the leadership of management board chairman Michael Frenzel, the company was transformed in just under ten years into an integrated travel group, able to offer all the services in the tourism value chain travel agencies, airlines, hotels from a single source. In order to diversify risk, TUI has a two-pillar business strategy: it focuses its activities on the core areas of tourism (providing 72% of turnover and 57% of earnings before tax in 2005, with around 50,000 employees) and shipping (19.5% of turnover and 44% of earnings before tax). With seven airlines in six countries and 116 aircraft, TUI is among Europes largest airline companies. Among others, it owns the airline Hapagfly (HLF) and low-cost airline Hapag-LloydExpress (HLX). The two areas of the shipping business container ships and cruise liners are brought together as Hapag-Lloyd AG, based in Hamburg, with around 7,000 employees.
234
from the tourism business, which is closely linked to the business cycle, with better results from shipping. However, as Hapag-Lloyd had moved into loss owing to higher fuel cost and lower freight prices, this strategy was now questioned by the investment funds. The employee representatives on the supervisory board produced a statement in September 2006, expressing their support for the concept of an integrated tourism business and the twopillar strategy. In addition, trade union representatives have already sought a meeting with the mayor of Hamburg and further measures are being prepared. In January, 2007 Richard Mayer, an infamous private investor, as a TUI stockholder appeared. This had provided in the past at numerous companies as an uncomfortable and critical stockholder for headlines. Mayer demands in the same way like some institutional investors, among them DWS and Hermes, the splitting off and the sales of Hapag-Lloyd. At the beginning of February the press for 2006 announced an expected loss of the TUI AG of about 900 Mil. EUR. In 2005 TUI had achieved one more profit of 495 Mil. EUR. Following causes were responsible for the high loss: An Impairment test to IFRS, the international balance standard, proved goodwill depreciations at the rate of 700 Mil. EUR. The biggest interest (500 Mil. EUR) of the depreciations arises by the goodwill depreciations on the British Thomson Travel Group assumed in 2000. Other 60 Mil. EUR came at by goodwill depreciation of the French subsidiary firm Nouvelles Frontieres. In addition, the result is loaded by high expenditures of 100 Mil. EUR for the reorganisation of the tourism business and 110 Mil. EUR for the integration of the Canadian CP Ships assumed in 2005. The company capital rate thereby falls on approx. 20%.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
The transformation of the steel company Preussag AG into the tourism business TUI AG resulted in a sharp increase in the companys level of debt, in which a substantial proportion of the external capital provided was refinanced through bonds issued on the capital market. After a period in which the company consistently reduced its level of debt, with the aim of obtaining as positive a credit rating as possible, in 2005 it issued further bonds to finance the purchase of the Canadian shipping company CP Ships, for which it paid approximately 2 billion. On 31 December 2005 the level of debt was about 64%.
2.3 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investments in innovation
The aim of the management board chairman, Michael Frenzel, is to double operating earnings to 1.3 billion, something which cannot be achieved with the tourist business alone, given its low margins. Under the pressure of the capital markets, the company has for years implemented cost reduction and restructuring programmes. Its current programme One Company is intended to save around 50 million. The plans include slimming down and providing a new organisation for the travel business, particularly in the main market, Germany. Since 2002 some 6,000 jobs have already gone in the tourism division. A further 2,000 jobs are to be lost worldwide as a result of the takeover of the Canadian shipping company at the end of 2005, although 100 additional jobs are to be created in the Hamburg headquarters.
235
Executives have also been affected by the cost-cutting reorganisation. The plans foresee up to 400 of them losing their jobs, while others are to be demoted or will have to accept reductions in salary.
2.5 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on Board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
In October of 2006 several investors wrote an open letter, in which they challenged the chairman of the board Michael Frenzel to split up the TUI group. They wanted management to officially announce a timetable for the split up of the tourism and shipping divisions within the next 6 to 18 months. Furthermore they already discussed their strategy proposal with the head of the supervisory board Jrgen Krumnow. In their meeting with Krumnow the shareholders demanded a stop of acquisitions and the election of new members for the supervisory board, who are experts for shipping and tourism. Author of the open letter is the British asset manager Hermes, who has invested in shares of TUI for the pension funds of British Telecom. Supposedly the British have got the backup of DWS, a subsidiary company of the Deutsche Bank and the leading provider of collective investment schemes in Germany. The step they have taken is a form of escalation in matters of firm-shareholder-relations, that is virtually unheard of in Germany. Usually investors discuss their ideas with the operative management. If they are very displeased, they then seek the publicity of a general meeting to enforce their arguments. The open letter raises the pressure for Frenzel to take action until the next general meeting in May of 2007. Statements several investors have made, seem to indicate, that a significant part of the shareholders will try to force the dismissal of Frenzel, if he doesnt act as they wish.
236
The consequences for jobs in Hamburg if Hapag-Lloyd were to be sold are also unclear. There are several possible purchasers, including the Oetker group in Bielefeld, which owns the shipping company Hamburg Sd, and the Danish shipping group AP Mller-Maersk, although the latter company has denied any intention of buying. The TUI group calculates its current tax liability on its consolidated earnings for 2005 at 87 million. TUI AG on its own shows a tax liability of around 10 million in its profit and loss accounts. The consequences for the public finances of a break-up of the company cannot be estimated at this stage or, to be more precise, they depend on the future location of current operations.
References
Handelsblatt 11.05.05, p. 25; Wirtschaftswoche 12.05.05, p. 113 f.; Hannoversche Allgemeine Zeitung 02.12.04, p. 11; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 29.08.05, p. 12;Financial Times Deutschland 04.09.06, p. 17; Brsen-Zeitung 28.09.06, p. 8; finance 10/06, p. 7274; Financial Times Deutschland 16.10.06, p. 1;Brsen-Zeitung 17.10.06, p. 9; HAZ 07.11.06, p. 9; Sddeutsche Zeitung 10.11.06, p. 25; Financial Times Deutschland 10.11.06, p. 8; Brsen-Zeitung 10.11.06, p. 10; Hannoversche Allgemeine Zeitung 14.11.06, p. 9; Brsen-Zeitung 08.12.06, p. 9; Financial Times Deutschland 08.12.06, p. 6; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 08.12.06, p. 19; Sddeutsche Zeitung 08.12.06, p. 21; Sddeutsche Zeitung 11.12.06, p. 21; Handelsblatt 14.12.06, p. 14; Handelsblatt 14.12.06, p. 13; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 15.12.06, p. 22; Handelsblatt 15./16.12.06, p. 16; Handelsblatt 16.12.06, p. 18; Brsen-Zeitung 16.12.06, p. 1, p. 11; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 16.12.06, p. 15; Sddeutsche Zeitung 16./17.12.06, p. 25; Wirtschaftswoche 18.12.06, p. 80-82; Handelsblatt 18.12.06, p. 18; Financial Times Deutschland 18.12.06, p. 6; finance 12/06, p. 66-68; Brsen-Zeitung 11.01.07, p. 11; Sddeutsche Zeitung 15.01.07, p. 19; Financial Times Deutschland 30.01.07, p. 11; www.Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung.net 01.02.07, 08:56 bzw. 09:46 Uhr.
237
Viterra
1. Company description
Viterra is a residential property company that was owned by E.on and had a stock of 150 000 housing units. E.on is Germanys largest energy group. Its areas of activity are electricity generation and distribution and the sale of natural gas to households and businesses. In recent years, E.on had been tidying up its portfolio of companies, hiving off the parts of the group that were not in the energy business, including Viterra.
2.2 Debt structure, alteration of company capital management fees requested by LBO
According to the German edition of the Financial Times, 90% of the purchase was made with debt capital an unusually high percentage for purchases of stakes in companies. The fact that interest rates were at one of their lowest points ever was conducive to the high leverage ratio. The loans were made available by the Citigroup financial services company. As part of the deal, it acquired a minority stake of about 17.5% in Annington through its subsidiary Citigroup Property Investors. According to official statements, Citigroup intended to support the growth of Annington in collabouration with Terra Firma. The private equity firms Fortress and Cerberus had been interested in acquiring Viterra but had bid only 6 billion. The reason why Terra Firma and Deutsche Annington were able to make such a high offer was evidently that the Citigroup investment bank had arranged debt financing on quite reasonable terms.
2.3 Effects on job creation, investments in training and education of labour force, investments in innovation
Before the deal, Deutsche Annington had 400 employees. The purchase of Viterra added a further 1 500. The plan is now to offload a total of 500 of these employees, in other words more than a quarter of the entire staff. Annington and E.on had not negotiated any employment guarantees for the Viterra workforce.
238
2.5 Management policies and shareholder activism: stock option programs, effects on board and CEOs, management fees, employee information
The strategy of investment companies like Terra Firma, which specialize in the acquisition of residential property, consists in reselling the purchased dwellings singly or in smallish packages. Deutsche Annington gave assurances that it would offer to sell its dwellings in the first instance to tenants living in the vicinity of the dwellings in question. Where third parties purchased dwellings, the tenants were to be protected for ten years from termination of the lease on grounds of the owners wish to use the properties themselves. If a tenant had already reached the age of 65, he or she would apparently enjoy lifelong security of tenure. These contractually agreed conditions are largely in line with the tenants minimum rights enshrined in German housing legislation.
239
sold them on to the private equity investment firm Mira. Since then there have been no more investments in the area. Nor have the private equity investors done anything to improve the residential environment. Even in the smaller blocks on the same estate, many dwellings have proved unsaleable.
References
Die Zeit 23.06.05, p. 22; Handelsblatt 18.05.05, p. 13, Brsenzeitung 18.05.05; Financial Times Deutschland 19.05.05, p. 22; Sddeutsche Zeitung 20.06.05, p. 25; Brsenzeitung 11.08.05, p. 6; Financial Times Deutschland 19.08.05, p. 17; Financial Times Deutschland 30.08.05, p. 2; Sddeutsche Zeitung 07.09.05, p. 24; company annual report Dt. Annington 2005; press release Dt. Annington, 17.01.07.
240
GLOSSARY
7845.35781499
Absolute returns The return that an asset achieves over a period of time. This measure simply looks at the appreciation or depreciation (expressed as a percentage) that an asset usually a stock or a mutual fund faces over a period of time. Absolute return differs from relative return because it is concerned with the return of the asset being looked at and does not compare it to any other measure. Absolute return funds look to make positive returns whether the overall market is up or down, while index tracking funds try to beat the index they are tracking. Alternative investments Usually refers to investments in hedge funds. Many hedge funds pursue strategies that are uncommon relative to mutual funds. Examples of alternative investment strategies are: longshort equity, event driven, statistical arbitrage, fixed income arbitrage, convertible arbitrage, short bias, global macro, and equity market neutral. AMF Autorit des marchs financiers, French Securities supervisor Asset stripping Asset stripping is the practice of buying a company in order to sell its assets individually at a profit. Attrition The reduction in staff and employees in a company through normal means, such as retirement and resignation. This is natural in any business and industry. Bafin German securities supervisor Basel Committee The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision is an institution created by the central bank Governors of the Group of Ten nations. It was created in 1974 and meets regularly four times a year. Its membership is now composed of senior representatives of bank supervisory authorities and central banks from the G-10 countries (Belgium, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States), and representatives from Luxembourg and Spain. It usually meets at the Bank for International Settlements in Basel, where its 12 member permanent Secretariat is located. The Basel Committee formulates broad supervisory standards and guidelines and recommends statements of best practice in banking supervision (see bank regulation or Basel II, for example) in the expectation that member authorities and other nations authorities will take steps to implement them through their own national systems, whether in statutory form or otherwise.
Glossary
243
Bond A debt investment with which the investor loans money to an entity (company or government) that borrows the funds for a defined period of time at a specified interest rate. Carried interest A bonus entitlement accruing to an investment fund manager company or individual members of the fund management team. Carried interest (typically up to 20% of the profits of the fund) are payable once the investor have achieved repayment of their original investment in the fund plus a defined hurdle rate. CESR Committee of European Securities Regulators Derivatives Security, such as an option or futures contract, whose value depends on the performance of an underlying security or asset. Futures contracts, forward contracts, options, and swaps are the most common types of derivatives. Derivatives are generally used by institutional investors to increase overall portfolio return or to hedge portfolio risk. Dividend Distribution of a portion of a companys earnings, decided by the board of directors, to a class of its shareholders. The amount of a dividend is quoted in the amount each share receives or in other words dividends per share. EBITDA Earnings Before Interest, Taxes, Depreciation, and Amortization. An indicator of a companys financial performance calculated as: Revenue Expenses (excluding tax, interest, depreciation, and amortization). EBITDA can be used to analyze the profitability between companies and industries, because it eliminates the effects of financing and accounting decisions. ECB European Central Bank Emerging markets The financial markets of developing economies or industries. Equities A type of security that signifies ownership in a corporation and represents a claim on part of the corporations assets and earnings. There are two main types of stock: common and preferred. Common stock usually entitles the owner the right to vote at shareholder meetings and to receive dividends that the company has declared. Preferred stock generally does not have voting rights, but has a higher claim on assets and earnings than the common shares. For example, owners of preferred stock receive dividends before common shareholders and have priority in the event a company goes bankrupt and is liquidated.
244
FED (also the Federal Reserve; informally The Fed) The FED is the central banking system of the United States. The Federal Reserve System is a quasi-governmental banking system composed of (1) a presidentially-appointed Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, D.C.; (2) the Federal Open Market Committee; (3) twelve regional Federal Reserve Banks located in major cities throughout the nation; and (4) numerous private member banks, which own varying amounts of stock in the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Futures A financial contract that obligates the buyer (seller) to purchase (sell and deliver) financial instruments or physical commodities at a future date, unless the holders position is closed prior to expiration. Futures are often used by mutual funds and large institutions to hedge their positions when the markets are rocky, preventing large losses in value. The primary difference between options and futures is that options provide the holder the right to buy or sell the underlying asset at expiration, while futures contracts holders are obligated to fulfil the terms of their contract. FSA Financial Services Authority, UK Hedge fund Fund whose manager receive performance-related fees and can freely use various active investment strategies to achieve positive absolute returns, involving any combination of leverage, long and short positions in securities or any other assets in a wide range of markets. Hurdle rate A rate of return that must be achieved before the manager becomes entitled to carried interest payments from a fund Hostile takeover A takeover attempt that is strongly resisted by the target firm. Info ratio statistics The Information Ratio is a commonly used statistic by the long only industrys (UCITS) practitioners in order to measure the efficiency of an investment policy, considering not only the excess of return versus the adopted benchmark, but also the risk assumed against it. Under a purely technical viewpoint the Information Ratio is the ratio between the annualized excess of return over the benchmark attained by the manager along a given timeframe and the funds Tracking Error. In the tables of this paragraph we assumed as hypothetical benchmark for the different categories of hedge funds the JP Morgan US bond index. Institutional investors A non-bank person or organization that trades securities in large enough share quantities or dollar amounts that they qualify for preferential treatment and lower commissions. Institutional investors face less protective regulations because it is assumed that they are more knowledgeable and better able to protect themselves.
Glossary
245
Investment vehicle This term is used very broadly. It refers to anyplace you can put your money. For example: stocks, bonds, mutual funds, options, futures, etc. Youll often hear it used in sentences like this: Mutual funds are a good investment vehicle for beginning investors who arent confident enough to pick stocks themselves. IOSCO The International Organization of Securities Commissions IPO (initial public offering) A companys first sale of stock to the public. Securities offered in an IPO are often, but not always, those of young, small companies seeking outside equity capital and a public market for their stock. Investors purchasing stock in IPOs generally must be prepared to accept considerable risks for the possibility of large gains. IPOs by investment companies (closed-end funds) usually include underwriting fees that represent a load to buyers. Leverage Leverage is generally considered to exist when: (a) an institutions financial assets exceed its capital; (b) an institution is exposed to the change in value of a position beyond the amount, if any, initially paid for the position; (c) an institution owns a position with embedded leverage, i.e. a position with a price volatility exceeding that of the underlying market factor. Leverage effect The leverage effect explains a companys return on equity in terms of its return on capital employed and cost of debt. The leverage effect is the difference between return on equity and return on capital employed. Leverage effect explains how it is possible for a company to deliver a return on equity exceeding the rate of return on all the capital invested in the business, i.e. its return on capital employed. When a company raises debt and invests the funds it has borrowed in its industrial and commercial activities, it generates operating profit that normally exceeds the interest expense due on its borrowings. The company generates a surplus consisting of the difference between the return on capital employed and the cost of debt related to the borrowing. This surplus is attributable to shareholders and is added to shareholders equity. The leverage effect of debt thus increases the return on equity. If the return on capital employed falls below the cost of debt, then the leverage effect of debt shifts into reverse and reduces the return on equity, which in turn falls below return on capital employed. Limited partners Limited partners or investors are the private suppliers of capital for private equity or venture capital funds. Most limited partners are pension funds, banks, insurance companies, and funds of funds. Liquidity The ability to convert an asset to cash quickly. It is safer to invest in liquid assets than illiquid ones because it is easier for you to get your money out of the investment. Examples of assets that are easily converted into cash include blue chip and money market securities. Also known as marketability. Management fee Compensation received by a private equity fund manager company. This annual management charge is equal to a certain percentage of the investors commitments to the fund.
246
MiFID The Markets in Financial Instruments Directive MiFID. With the Directives a single market and regulatory regime for investment services across the 25 member states of the European Union was introduced. The key objectives behind the Directive are threefold: 1) to complete the EU single market for investment services and 2) to respond to changes/innovations in the securities markets and 3) to protect investors. Mutual fund A security that gives small investors access to a well-diversified portfolio of equities, bonds and other securities. Each shareholder participates in the gain or loss of the fund. Shares are issued and can be redeemed as needed. Merger The combining of two or more companies, generally by offering the stockholders of one company securities in the acquiring company in exchange for the surrender of their stock. Offshore Located or based outside of ones national boundaries. The term offshore is used to describe foreign banks, corporations, investments, and deposits. A company may move offshore for the purpose of tax avoidance or relaxed regulations. Prime brokerage A special group of services that many brokerages give to special clients. The services provided under prime brokering are securities lending, leveraged trade executions, and cash management, among other things. Prime brokerage services are provided by most of the large brokers, such as Goldman Sachs, Paine Webber, and Morgan Stanley Dean Witter. Private equity fund A private equity investment fund is a vehicle for enabling pool investment by a number of investors in equity and equity-related securities of companies. They are generally private companies whose shares are not quoted on a stock exchange. The fund can take either the form of a company or of an unincorporated arrangement such as a Limited partnership. Recapitalisation Restructuring a companys debt and equity mixture often with the aim of making a companys capital structure more stable. Shareholder value Refer to the concept that the primary goal for a company is to enrich its shareholders (owners) by paying dividends and/or causing the stock price to increase. SEC (Securities & Exchange Commission) A federal agency that regulates the US financial markets. The SEC also oversees the securities industry and promotes full disclosure in order to protect the investing public against malpractice in the securities markets. Short Selling The selling of a security that the seller does not own, or any sale that is completed by the delivery
Glossary
247
of a security borrowed by the seller. Short sellers assume that they will be able to buy the stock at a lower amount than the price at which they sold short. Selling short is the opposite of going long. That is, short sellers make money if the stock goes down in price. Stock option An individuals right to purchase a share at a fixed price. Stock options are a widely used form of employee incentive and compensation. The employee is given an option to purchase shares at a certain price (at or below the market price at the time the option is granted) for a specified period of years. Stress test A simulation technique used on asset and liability portfolios to determine their reactions to different financial situations. Stress-testing is a useful method of determining how a portfolio will fare during a period of financial crisis. The Monte Carlo simulation is one of the most widely used methods of stress testing. Systemic risks Risk common to a particular sector or country. Often refers to a risk resulting from a particular system that is in place, such as the regulator framework for monitoring of financial institutions. Tax transparency A fund structure or a vehicle is transparent when the fund itself is not subject to taxation and the investment in an underlying company is treated as if it would be a direct investment for the initial investor (the limited partner) who is taxed only when the investment structure distributes its gains and revenues. Tracking error The Tracking Error is a commonly used statistic by the long only industrys (UCITS) practitioners in order to measure the volatility of a portfolio / fund versus its benchmark. Under a purely technical viewpoint the Tracking Error is the annualized standard deviation of the difference between the periodic returns of a portfolio and those of its benchmark on a given timeframe. In the tables of this paragraph we assumed as hypothetical benchmark for the different categories of hedge funds the JP Morgan US bond index. UCIT Undertakings for the Collective Investment of Transferable Securities UCITS. A public limited company that coordinates the distribution and management of unit trusts amongst countries within the European Union. Venture Capital Financing for new businesses. In other words, money provided by investors to startup firms and small businesses with perceived, long-term growth potential. This is a very important source of funding for startups that do not have access to capital markets and typically entails high risk for the investor but has the potential for above-average returns. VaR model Value at Risk model VaR model. Procedure for estimating the probability of portfolio losses exceeding some specified proportion based on a statistical analysis of historical market price trends, correlations, and volatilities.
248