Great Depression
Great Depression
Great Depression
Christina D. Romer
December 20, 2003
Great Depression
worldwide economic downturn that began in 1929 and lasted until about 1939. It was the longest
and most severe depression ever experienced by the industrialized Western world. Although the
Depression originated in the United States, it resulted in drastic declines in output, severe
unemployment, and acute deflation in almost every country of the globe. But its social and
cultural effects were no less staggering, especially in the United States, where the Great
Depression ranks second only to the Civil War as the gravest crisis in American history.
Economic history
The timing and severity of the Great Depression varied substantially across countries.
The Depression was particularly long and severe in the United States and Europe; it was milder
in Japan and much of Latin America. Perhaps not surprisingly, the worst depression ever
experienced stemmed from a multitude of causes. Declines in consumer demand, financial
panics, and misguided government policies caused economic output to fall in the United States.
The gold standard, which linked nearly all the countries of the world in a network of fixed
currency exchange rates, played a key role in transmitting the American downturn to other
countries. The recovery from the Great Depression was spurred largely by the abandonment of
the gold standard and the ensuing monetary expansion. The Great Depression brought about
fundamental changes in economic institutions, macroeconomic policy, and economic theory.
return to the gold standard with an overvalued pound. Britain did not slip into severe depression,
however, until early 1930, and the peak-to-trough decline in industrial production was roughly
one-third that of the United States. France also experienced a relatively short downturn in the
early 1930s. The French recovery in 1932 and 1933, however, was short-lived. French industrial
production and prices both fell substantially between 1933 and 1936. Germanys economy
slipped into a downturn early in 1928 and then stabilized before turning down again in the third
quarter of 1929. The decline in German industrial production was roughly equal to that in the
United States. A number of countries in Latin America slipped into depression in late 1928 and
early 1929, slightly before the U.S. decline in output. While some less developed countries
experienced severe depressions, others, such as Argentina and Brazil, experienced comparatively
mild downturns. The depression in Japan started relatively late (in early 1930) and was, by
comparison, mild.
The general price deflation evident in the United States was also present in other
countries. Virtually every industrialized country endured declines in wholesale prices of 30
percent or more between 1929 and 1933. Because of the greater flexibility of the Japanese price
structure, deflation in Japan was unusually rapid in 1930 and 1931. This rapid deflation may
have helped to keep the decline in Japanese production relatively mild. The prices of primary
commodities traded in world markets declined even more dramatically during this period. For
example, the prices of coffee, cotton, silk, and rubber were reduced by roughly half just between
September 1929 and December 1930. As a result, the terms of trade declined precipitously for
producers of primary commodities.
The U.S. recovery began in the spring of 1933. Output grew rapidly in the mid-1930s:
real GDP rose at an average rate of 9 percent per year between 1933 and 1937. Output had fallen
so deeply in the early years of the 1930s, however, that it remained substantially below its longrun trend level throughout this period. In 193738 the United States suffered another severe
downturn, but after mid-1938 the American economy grew even more rapidly than in the mid1930s. U.S. output finally returned to its long-run trend level in 1942.
Recovery in the rest of the world varied greatly. The British economy stopped declining
soon after Britains abandonment of the gold standard in September 1931, though genuine
recovery did not begin until the end of 1932. The economies of a number of Latin American
countries began to strengthen in late 1931 and early 1932. Germany and Japan both began to
recover in the fall of 1932. Canada and many smaller European countries started to revive at
about the same time as the United States, early in 1933. On the other hand, France, which
experienced severe depression later than most countries, did not firmly enter the recovery phase
until 1938.
substantial increases in farm debt in the 1920s, together with U.S. policies that encouraged small,
undiversified banks, created an environment where such panics could ignite and spread. The
heavy farm debt stemmed in part from the response to the high prices of agricultural goods
during World War I. American farmers borrowed heavily to purchase and improve land in order
to increase production. The decline in farm commodity prices following the war made it difficult
for farmers to keep up with their loan payments.
The Federal Reserve did little to try to stem the banking panics. Milton Friedman and
Anna J. Schwartz, in the classic study, A Monetary History of the United States, argue that the
death of Benjamin Strong, the governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, was an
important source of this inaction. Strong had been a forceful leader who understood the ability of
the central bank to limit panics. His death left a power vacuum at the Federal Reserve and
allowed leaders with less sensible views to block effective intervention. The panics caused a
dramatic rise in the amount of currency people wished to hold relative to their bank deposits.
This rise in the currency-to-deposit ratio was a key reason why the money supply in the United
States declined 31 percent between 1929 and 1933. In addition to allowing the panics to reduce
the U.S. money supply, the Federal Reserve also deliberately contracted the money supply and
raised interest rates in September 1931, when Britain was forced off the gold standard and
investors feared that the United States would devalue as well.
Scholars believe that such declines in the money supply caused by Federal Reserve
decisions had a severe contractionary effect on output. A simple picture provides perhaps the
clearest evidence of the key role monetary collapse played in the Great Depression in the United
States. Figure 1 shows the money supply and real output over the period 1900 to 1940. In
ordinary times, such as the 1920s, both the money supply and output tend to grow steadily. But,
in the early 1930s, both plummeted. The decline in the money supply depressed spending in a
number of ways. Perhaps most importantly, because of actual price declines and the rapid decline
in the money supply, consumers and business people came to expect deflation that is, they
expected wages and prices to be lower in the future. As a result, even though nominal interest
rates were very low, people did not want to borrow because they feared that future wages and
profits would be inadequate to cover the loan payments. This hesitancy, in turn, led to severe
reductions in both consumer spending and business investment spending. The panics surely
exacerbated the decline in spending by generating pessimism and a loss of confidence.
Furthermore, the failure of so many banks disrupted lending, thereby reducing the funds
available to finance investment.
international gold flows. For example, in the mid-1920s intense international demand for
American assets such as stocks and bonds brought large inflows of gold to the United States.
Likewise, a decision by France after World War I to return to the gold standard with an
undervalued franc led to trade surpluses and substantial gold inflows. ( balance of trade.)
Britain chose to return to the gold standard after World War I at the prewar parity.
Wartime inflation, however, implied that the pound was overvalued, and this overvaluation led to
trade deficits and substantial gold outflows after 1925. To stem the gold outflow, the Bank of
England raised interest rates substantially. High interest rates depressed British spending and led
to high unemployment in Great Britain throughout the second half of the 1920s.
Once the U.S. economy began to contract severely, the tendency for gold to flow out of
other countries and toward the United States intensified. This took place because deflation in the
United States made American goods particularly desirable to foreigners, while low income
reduced American demand for foreign products. To counteract the resulting tendency toward an
American trade surplus and foreign gold outflows, central banks throughout the world raised
interest rates. Maintaining the international gold standard, in essence, required a massive
monetary contraction throughout the world to match the one occurring in the United States. The
result was a decline in output and prices in countries throughout the world that also nearly
matched the downturn in the United States.
Financial crises and banking panics occurred in a number of countries besides the United
States. In May 1931 payment difficulties at the Creditanstalt, Austrias largest bank, set off a
string of financial crises that enveloped much of Europe and were a key factor forcing Britain to
abandon the gold standard. Among the countries hardest hit by bank failures and volatile
financial markets were Austria, Germany, and Hungary. These widespread banking crises could
have been the result of poor regulation and other local factors, or simple contagion from one
country to another. In addition, the gold standard, by forcing countries to deflate along with the
United States, reduced the value of banks collateral and made them more vulnerable to runs. As
in the United States, banking panics and other financial market disruptions further depressed
output and prices in a number of countries.
materials, which caused severe balance-of-payments problems for primary-commodityproducing countries in Africa, Asia, and Latin America and led to contractionary policies.
Sources of recovery
Given the key roles of monetary contraction and the gold standard in causing the Great
Depression, it is not surprising that currency devaluations and monetary expansion became the
leading sources of recovery throughout the world. There is a notable correlation between the
time countries abandoned the gold standard (or devalued their currencies substantially) and a
renewed growth in their output. For example, Britain, which was forced off the gold standard in
September 1931, recovered relatively early, while the United States, which did not effectively
devalue its currency until 1933, recovered substantially later. Similarly, the Latin American
countries of Argentina and Brazil, which began to devalue in 1929, had relatively mild
downturns and were largely recovered by 1935. In contrast, the Gold Bloc countries of
Belgium and France, which were particularly wedded to the gold standard and slow to devalue,
still had industrial production in 1935 well below its 1929 level.
Devaluation, however, did not increase output directly. Rather, it allowed countries to
expand their money supplies without concern about gold movements and exchange rates.
Countries that took greater advantage of this freedom saw greater recovery. The monetary
expansion that began in the United States in early 1933 was particularly dramatic. The American
money supply increased nearly 42 percent between 1933 and 1937. This monetary expansion
stemmed largely from a substantial gold inflow to the United States, caused in part by the rising
political tensions in Europe that eventually led to World War II. Worldwide monetary expansion
stimulated spending by lowering interest rates and making credit more widely available. It also
created expectations of inflation, rather than deflation, and so made potential borrowers more
confident that their wages and profits would be sufficient to cover their loan payments if they
chose to borrow. One sign that monetary expansion stimulated recovery in the United States by
encouraging borrowing was that consumer and business spending on interest-sensitive items
such as cars, trucks, and machinery rose well before consumer spending on services.
Fiscal policy played a relatively small role in stimulating recovery in the United States.
Indeed, the Revenue Act of 1932 increased American tax rates greatly in an attempt to balance
the federal budget, and by doing so dealt another contractionary blow to the economy by further
discouraging spending. Franklin Roosevelts New Deal, initiated in early 1933, did include a
number of new federal programs aimed at generating recovery. For example, the Works Progress
Administration (WPA) hired the unemployed to work on government building projects, and the
Agricultural Adjustment Administration (AAA) gave large payments to farmers. However, the
actual increases in government spending and the government budget deficit were small relative
to the size of the economy. This is especially apparent when state government budget deficits are
included, because those deficits actually declined at the same time that the federal deficit rose.
As a result, the new spending programs initiated by the New Deal had little direct expansionary
effect on the economy. Whether they may nevertheless have had positive effects on consumer
and business sentiment remains an open question. United States military spending related to
World War II was not large enough to appreciably affect total spending and output until 1941.
The role of fiscal policy in generating recovery varied substantially across other
countries. Great Britain, like the United States, did not use fiscal expansion to a noticeable extent
early in its recovery. It did, however, increase military spending substantially after 1937. France
raised taxes in the mid-1930s in an effort to defend the gold standard, but then ran large budget
deficits starting in 1936. The expansionary effect of these deficits, however, was counteracted
somewhat by a legislated reduction in the French workweek from 46 to 40 hoursa change that
raised costs and depressed production. Fiscal policy was used more successfully in Germany and
Japan. The German budget deficit as a percent of domestic product increased little early in the
recovery, but grew substantially after 1934 as a result of spending on public works and
rearmament. In Japan, government expenditures, particularly military spending, rose from 31 to
38 percent of domestic product between 1932 and 1934, resulting in substantial budget deficits.
This fiscal stimulus, combined with substantial monetary expansion and an undervalued yen,
returned the Japanese economy to full employment relatively quickly.
Economic impact
The most obvious economic impact of the Great Depression was human suffering. In a
short period of time world output and standards of living dropped precipitously. As much as onefourth of the labour force in industrialized countries was unable to find work in the early 1930s.
While conditions began to improve by the mid-1930s, total recovery was not accomplished until
the end of the decade.
The Depression and the policy response also changed the world economy in crucial ways.
The Great Depression hastened, if not caused, the end of the international gold standard.
Although a system of fixed currency exchange rates was reinstated after World War II under the
Bretton Woods system, the economies of the world never embraced that system with the
conviction and fervour they had brought to the gold standard. By 1973, fixed exchange rates
were abandoned in favour of floating rates.
Both labour unions and the welfare state expanded substantially during the 1930s. In the
United States, union membership more than doubled between 1930 and 1940. This trend was
stimulated both by the severe unemployment of the 1930s and the passage of the National Labor
Relations (Wagner) Act (1935), which encouraged collective bargaining. The United States
established unemployment compensation and old age and survivors insurance through the
Social Security Act (1935), which was passed in response to the hardships of the 1930s. It is
uncertain whether these changes would have eventually occurred in the United States without the
Depression. Many European countries had experienced significant increases in union
membership and had established government pensions before the 1930s. Both of these trends,
however, accelerated in Europe during the Depression.
In many countries, government regulation of the economy, especially of financial
markets, increased substantially during the Great Depression. The United States, for example,
established the Securities and Exchange Commission in 1934 to regulate new stock issues and
stock market trading practices. The Banking Act of 1933 (also known as the Glass-Steagall Act)
established deposit insurance in the United States and prohibited banks from underwriting or
dealing in securities. Deposit insurance, which did not become common worldwide until after
World War II, effectively eliminated banking panics as an exacerbating factor in recessions in
the United States after 1933.
The Depression also played a crucial role in the development of macroeconomic policies
intended to temper economic downturns and upturns. The central role of reduced spending and
monetary contraction in the Depression led British economist John Maynard Keynes to develop
the ideas in his General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936). Keyness theory
suggested that increases in government spending, tax cuts, and monetary expansion could be
used to counteract depressions. This insight, combined with a growing consensus that
government should try to stabilize employment, has led to much more activist policy since the
1930s. Legislatures and central banks throughout the world now routinely attempt to prevent or
moderate recessions. Whether such a change would have occurred without the Depression is
again a largely unanswerable question. What is clear is that this change has made it unlikely that
a decline in spending will ever be allowed to multiply and spread throughout the world as it did
during the Great Depression of the 1930s.
TABLE 1
Dates of the Great Depression in Various Countries
(In Quarters)
Country
Depression Began
Recovery Began
United States
Great Britain
Germany
France
Canada
Switzerland
Czechoslovakia
Italy
Belgium
Netherlands
Sweden
Denmark
Poland
Argentina
Brazil
Japan
India
South Africa
1929:3
1930:1
1928:1
1930:2
1929:2
1929:4
1929:4
1929:3
1929:3
1929:4
1930:2
1930:4
1929:1
1929:2
1928:3
1930:1
1929:4
1930:1
1933:2
1932:4
1932:3
1932:3
1933:2
1933:1
1933:2
1933:1
1932:4
1933:2
1932:3
1933:2
1933:2
1932:1
1931:4
1932:3
1931:4
1933:1
TABLE 2
Peak-to-Trough Decline in Industrial Production in Various Countries
(Annual Data)
Country
Decline
Unites States
Great Britain
Germany
France
Canada
Czechoslovakia
Italy
Belgium
Netherlands
Sweden
Denmark
Poland
Argentina
Brazil
Japan
46.8 %
16.2 %
41.8 %
31.3 %
42.4 %
40.4 %
33.0 %
30.6 %
37.4 %
10.3 %
16.5 %
46.6 %
17.0 %
7.0 %
8.5 %
Years
1940
1935
1930
5.5
1925
1920
6.5
1915
1910
1905
1900
7.0
5.0
Real GDP
4.5
6.0
4.0
Money Supply
3.5
3.0
5.0
2.5
4.5
2.0
4.0
1.5
Bibliography
The Great Depression in the United States
MILTON FRIEDMAN and ANNA JACOBSON SCHWARTZ, A Monetary History of the United
States, 18671960 (1963, reissued 1993), chapter 7, The Great Contraction, is the single most
important study of the Great Depression in the United States, detailing ways in which banking
panics and monetary contraction contributed to the economic downturn.
Scholarly studies that analyze the role of particular factors in the American Depression
include: BEN S. BERNANKE, Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of
the Great Depression, American Economic Review, 73(3):257276 (June 1983); STEPHEN G.
CECCHETTI, Prices During the Great Depression: Was the Deflation of 1930-1932 Really
Unanticipated? American Economic Review 82(1):141-156 (March 1992); CHRISTINA D.
ROMER, The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great Depression, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 105(3):597624 (August 1990); and PETER TEMIN, Did Monetary Forces Cause the
Great Depression? (1976). JOHN KENNETH GALBRAITH, The Great Crash, 1929 (1954, reissued
1997), is a riveting account of the 1929 stock market crash, one of the events leading up to the
Great Depression in the United States.
World Depression
BARRY EICHENGREEN, Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression,
19191939 (1992, reissued 1995), is a monumental study of the functioning and effects of the
international gold standard in the interwar era. W. ARTHUR LEWIS, Economic Survey, 19191939
(1949, reissued 1969), while somewhat dated, is an exceedingly useful survey of the nature and
causes of the Depression in Great Britain, Germany, Russia, France, Japan, and the United
States.
Other works analyzing the Depression outside the United States include: HAROLD JAMES,
The German Slump: Politics and Economics, 19241936 (1986); CHARLES P. KINDLEBERGER,
The World in Depression, 19291939, rev. and enlarged ed. (1986); and ROSEMARY THORP (ed.),
Latin America in the 1930s: The Role of the Periphery in World Crisis (1984).
includes a series of papers by distinguished scholars on the long-run impact of the Great
Depression in the United States. JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES, The General Theory of Employment,
Interest, and Money (1936, reissued 1997), is the pathbreaking work of economic theory that was
inspired by the Great Depression and led to the rise of stabilization policy in the postwar era.
Sources used
Bernanke, Ben S. Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great
Depression. American Economic Review 73 (June 1983): 257-276.
Bernanke, Ben, and Harold James. The Gold Standard, Deflation, and Financial Crises in the
Great Depression: An International Comparison. In Financial Markets and Financial
Crises edited by R. Glenn Hubbard. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for NBER,
1991, pp. 33-68.
Bordo, Michael D., Claudia Goldin, and Eugene N. White. The Defining Moment Hypothesis:
The Editors Introduction. In The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the
American Economy in the Twentieth Century edited by Michael D. Bordo, Claudia
Goldin, and Eugene N. White. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for NBER, 1998,
pp. 1-22.
Brown, E. Cary. Fiscal Policy in the Thirties: A Reappraisal. American Economic Review
46 (December 1956): 857-879.
Cameron, Rondo. A Concise Economic History of the World. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1993.
Campa, Jos Manuel. Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s: An Extension to
Latin America. Journal of Economic History 50 (September 1990): 677-682.
Cecchetti, Stephen G. Prices During the Great Depression: Was the Deflation of 1930-1932
Really Unanticipated? American Economic Review 82 (March 1992): 141-156.
Chandler, Lester V. Americas Greatest Depression, 1929-1941. New York: Harper & Row,
Publishers, 1970.
Cowles, Alfred, and Associates. Common-Stock Indexes. Bloomington, Indiana: Principia
Press, 1939.
della Paolera, Gerardo, and Alan M. Taylor. Economic Recovery from the Argentine Great
Depression: Institutions, Expectations, and the Change of Macroeconomic Regime.
Journal of Economic History 59 (September 1999): 567-599.
Daz Alejandro, Carlos F. Latin America in the 1930s. In Latin American in the 1930s: The
Role of the Periphery in World Crisis edited by Rosemary Thorp. New York: St.
Martins Press, 1984, pp. 17-49.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Jeffrey Sachs. Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s.
Journal of Economic History 45 (December 1985): 925-946.
Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939.
New York: Oxford University Press, 1992.
Freeman, Richard. Spurts in Union Growth: Defining Moments and Social Processes. In The
Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American Economy in the Twentieth
Century edited by Michael D. Bordo, Claudia Goldin, and Eugene N. White. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press for NBER, 1998, pp. 265-296.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States,
1867-1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press for NBER, 1963.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. Monetary Statistics of the United Sates:
Estimates, Sources, Methods. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1970.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. Monetary Trends in the United States and the
United Kingdom: Their Relation to Income, Prices, and Interest Rates, 1867-1975.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press for NBER, 1982.
Galbraith, John Kenneth. The Great Crash, 1929. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1988.
Gordon, Robert J. and James A. Wilcox. Monetarist Interpretations of the Great Depression:
An Evaluation and Critique. In The Great Depression Revisited edited by Karl Brunner.
Boston: Martinus Nijhoff, 1981, pp. 49-107.
Irwin, Douglas A. The Smoot-Hawley Tariff: A Quantitative Assessment.
Economics and Statistics 80 (May 1998): 326-334.
Review of
James, Harold. The German Slump: Politics and Economics, 1924-1936. New York: Oxford
University Press, 1986.
Kindleberger, Charles P. The World in Depression, 1929-1939. Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press, 1986.
League of Nations. World Economic Survey, 1931-32. Geneva, 1932.
League of Nations. World Economic Survey, 1932-33. Geneva, 1933.
League of Nations. World Production and Prices, 1935/36. Geneva, 1936.
Lewis, W. Arthur. Economic Survey, 1919-1939. London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd.,
1949.
Meltzer, Allan H. A History of the Federal Reserve.
University of Chicago Press, 2003.
Volume 1:
1913-1951.
Chicago:
Richardson, H.W. Economic Recovery in Britain, 1932-9. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson,
1967.
Romer, Christina D. The Prewar Business Cycle Reconsidered: New Estimates of Gross
National Product, 1869-1908. Journal of Political Economy 97 (February 1989): 1-37.
Romer, Christina D. The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great Depression. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 105 (August 1990): 597-624.
Romer, Christina D. What Ended the Great Depression? Journal of Economic History 52
(December 1992): 757-784.
Romer, Christina D. The Nation in Depression. Journal of Economic Perspectives 7 (Spring
1993): 19-40.
Schwartz, Anna J. Understanding 1929-1933. In The Great Depression Revisited edited by
Karl Brunner. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff, 1981, pp. 5-48.
Temin, Peter. The Beginning of the Depression in Germany. Economic History Review, New
Series, 24 (May 1971): 240-248.
Temin, Peter. Lessons from the Great Depression. The Lionel Robbins Lectures for 1989.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989.
U.S. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Banking and Monetary Statistics.
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1943.
U.S. Bureau of the Census. Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970.
Washington, D. C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975.
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. The National Income and Product Accounts of the United
States, 1929-82: Statistical Tables. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing
Office, September 1986.
U.S. President. Economic Report of the President, 2001. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office, 2001.