A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street
By Andrew W. Lo and A. Craig MacKinlay
3/5
()
About this ebook
For over half a century, financial experts have regarded the movements of markets as a random walk--unpredictable meanderings akin to a drunkard's unsteady gait--and this hypothesis has become a cornerstone of modern financial economics and many investment strategies. Here Andrew W. Lo and A. Craig MacKinlay put the Random Walk Hypothesis to the test. In this volume, which elegantly integrates their most important articles, Lo and MacKinlay find that markets are not completely random after all, and that predictable components do exist in recent stock and bond returns. Their book provides a state-of-the-art account of the techniques for detecting predictabilities and evaluating their statistical and economic significance, and offers a tantalizing glimpse into the financial technologies of the future.
The articles track the exciting course of Lo and MacKinlay's research on the predictability of stock prices from their early work on rejecting random walks in short-horizon returns to their analysis of long-term memory in stock market prices. A particular highlight is their now-famous inquiry into the pitfalls of "data-snooping biases" that have arisen from the widespread use of the same historical databases for discovering anomalies and developing seemingly profitable investment strategies. This book invites scholars to reconsider the Random Walk Hypothesis, and, by carefully documenting the presence of predictable components in the stock market, also directs investment professionals toward superior long-term investment returns through disciplined active investment management.
Read more from Andrew W. Lo
Adaptive Markets: Financial Evolution at the Speed of Thought Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Healthcare Finance: Modern Financial Analysis for Accelerating Biomedical Innovation Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Econometrics of Financial Markets Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5
Related to A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street
Related ebooks
Mathematical Techniques in Finance: Tools for Incomplete Markets - Second Edition Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsHandbook of Fixed-Income Securities Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Asset Price Dynamics, Volatility, and Prediction Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Fortune's Formula: The Untold Story of the Scientific Betting System That Beat the Casinos and Wall Street Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Winning the Loser's Game: Timeless Strategies for Successful Investing, Eighth Edition Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Hedge Fund Mirage: The Illusion of Big Money and Why It's Too Good to Be True Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsEfficiently Inefficient: How Smart Money Invests and Market Prices Are Determined Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Irrational Exuberance: Revised and Expanded Third Edition Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Art Of Speculation Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Anatomy of the Bear: Lessons from Wall Street's four great bottoms Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Risk-Return Analysis: The Theory and Practice of Rational Investing (Volume One) Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsQuantitative Investing: Strategies to exploit stock market anomalies for all investors Rating: 2 out of 5 stars2/5Money Mania: Booms, Panics, and Busts from Ancient Rome to the Great Meltdown Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Trading at the Speed of Light: How Ultrafast Algorithms Are Transforming Financial Markets Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Indomitable Investor: Why a Few Succeed in the Stock Market When Everyone Else Fails Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Stocks for the Long Run 5/E: The Definitive Guide to Financial Market Returns & Long-Term Investment Strategies Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsAsset Pricing: Revised Edition Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Myth of the Rational Market: A History of Risk, Reward, and Delusion on Wall Street Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Fischer Black and the Revolutionary Idea of Finance Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Contrarian Investment Strategies: The Psychological Edge Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Finding Alphas: A Quantitative Approach to Building Trading Strategies Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Why Stock Markets Crash: Critical Events in Complex Financial Systems Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Invisible Hands: Top Hedge Fund Traders on Bubbles, Crashes, and Real Money Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsPractical Speculation Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Money Formula: Dodgy Finance, Pseudo Science, and How Mathematicians Took Over the Markets Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Next Perfect Trade: A Magic Sword of Necessity Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Capital Wars: The Rise of Global Liquidity Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsGood Stocks Cheap: Value Investing with Confidence for a Lifetime of Stock Market Outperformance Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratings
Investments & Securities For You
Buy, Rehab, Rent, Refinance, Repeat: The BRRRR Rental Property Investment Strategy Made Simple Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Don't Start a Side Hustle!: Work Less, Earn More, and Live Free Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Intelligent Investor, Rev. Ed: The Definitive Book on Value Investing Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Principles: Life and Work Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Buy Then Build: How Acquisition Entrepreneurs Outsmart the Startup Game Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Day Trading For Dummies Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Little Book of Common Sense Investing: The Only Way to Guarantee Your Fair Share of Stock Market Returns Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Girls That Invest: Your Guide to Financial Independence through Shares and Stocks Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5How to Invest: Masters on the Craft Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Stock Investing For Dummies Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Only Investment Guide You'll Ever Need Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Just Keep Buying: Proven ways to save money and build your wealth Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Options Trading Crash Course: The #1 Beginner's Guide to Make Money with Trading Options in 7 Days or Less! Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5How to Invest in Real Estate: The Ultimate Beginner's Guide to Getting Started Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Long-Distance Real Estate Investing: How to Buy, Rehab, and Manage Out-of-State Rental Properties Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The ABCs of Real Estate Investing: The Secrets of Finding Hidden Profits Most Investors Miss Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsSeries 7 Exam 2022-2023 For Dummies with Online Practice Tests Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsBest Loser Wins: Why Normal Thinking Never Wins the Trading Game – written by a high-stake day trader Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5
Reviews for A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street
10 ratings0 reviews
Book preview
A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street - Andrew W. Lo
1987
Preface
A volume of collected works is almost always a bad sign for one's research trajectory, an indication of declining productivity as much as professional recognition. We hope to be the exception that proves this rule because neither of us is willing to concede that we have reached the apex of our careers. However, we do think that the papers collected in this volume form a coherent and exciting story, one that bears retelling now that we have the luxury of seeing the forest for the trees. When we began our collaboration over a decade ago, we certainly had no intention of embarking on as ambitious a research agenda as this volume might imply. And although we are still actively engaged in exploring these issues, when we were presented with the opportunity to bring together a group of our papers, we simply could not resist. Whether by design or by coincidence, here we are with eleven papers and an introduction, the running total of our research on the Random Walk Hypothesis and predictability in financial markets.
Although we were sorely tempted to revise our papers to incorporate the benefits of hindsight, we have resisted that temptation so as to keep our contributions in their proper context. However, we do provide general introductions to each of the three parts that comprise this collection of papers, which we hope will clarify and sharpen some of the issues that we only touched upon when we were in the midst of the research. Also, we have updated all our references, hence on occasion there may be a few temporal inconsistencies, e.g., citations of papers published several years after ours.
We hope that this volume will add fuel to the fires of debate and controversy, and expand the arena to include a broader set of participants, particularly those who may have more practical wisdom regarding the business of predicting financial markets. Although Paul Samuelson once chided economists for predicting five out of the past three recessions
, our research has given us a deeper appreciation for both the challenges and the successes of quantitative investment management. As for whether or not this little book contains the secrets to greater wealth, we are reminded of the streetwise aphorism that the first principle of making money is learning how not to lose it. Indeed, although there are probably still only a few ways to make money reliably, the growing complexity of financial markets has created many more ways to lose it and lose it quickly. We have argued that our research has not uncovered tremendous untapped profit opportunities, but on the other hand, our research does provide some guidance on how not to lose money. What more can one expect?
During the course of our research we have accumulated a number of intellectual debts—fortunately, they bear no interest otherwise we would have become insolvent years ago. First and foremost, we thank our advisors— Andy Abel and Jerry Hausman (AWL), and Gene Fama and Arnold Zellner (ACM)—who gave us the training and guidance that launched our careers and continue to sustain us.
We are also grateful to our many friends and colleagues who provided us with support and stimulus from our graduate-student days to the present— Marshall Blume, John Cox, Richard Caves, Bruce Grundy, Chi-fu Huang, Dale Jorgenson, Nobu Kiyotaki, Bob Merton, Krishna Ramaswamy, Robert Stambaugh, and Phil Vasan.
Our families have been an enormous and continuing source of inspiration throughout our careers, and we thank Mom, Martin, Cecilia, Nancy, and Derek (AWL), and Tina, Andrew, and Catie (ACM) for their love and patience during this and other projects that may have taken our attention away from them on occasion.
We thank our editor, Peter Dougherty, and Princeton University Press for their unflagging enthusiasm for our work, and Stephanie Hogue, Lori Pickert, and the staff at Archetype for their skills and patience in producing this book. We were also blessed with the very able assistance of Stephanie Hogue, Li Jin, Fiona Wang, and Wesley Chan in proofreading the final version of the manuscript.
We wish to acknowledge the financial support of several organizations— the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation, Batterymarch Financial Management, the Geewax-Terker Research Program at the Rodney White Center, the MIT Laboratory for Financial Engineering, the National Bureau of Economic Research, the National Science Foundation, and the John M. Olin Foundation. Without their combined support over the years, the research contained in this volume would not have been possible.
Finally, we thank the following sources and co-authors for allowing us to reprint our articles as chapters in this book:
Chapter 2: Review of Financial Studies, Volume 1, 1988.
Chapter 3: Journal of Econometrics, Volume 40, 1989.
Chapter 4: Journal of Econometrics, Volume 45, 1990.
Chapter 5: Review of Financial Studies, Volume 3, 1990.
Chapter 6: Econometrica, Volume 59, 1991.
Chapter 7: Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 38, 1995.
Chapter 8: Review of Financial Studies, Volume 3, 1990.
Chapter 9: Macroeconomic Dynamics, Volume 1, 1997.
Chapter 10: Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 31, 1992 (coauthored with Jerry Hausman)
Chapter 11: Review of Financial Studies, Volume 1, 1988 (co-authored with Krishna Ramaswamy).
Chapter 12: Journal of Finance, Volume 44, 1989 (co-authored with Marshall Blume and Bruce Terker).
1
Introduction
¹
ONE OF THE EARLIEST and most enduring models of the behavior of security prices is the Random Walk Hypothesis, an idea that was conceived in the sixteenth century as a model of games of chance.² Closely tied to the birth of probability theory, the Random Walk Hypothesis has had an illustrious history, with remarkable intellectual forbears such as Bachelier, Einstein, Lévy, Kolmogorov, and Wiener.
More recently, and as with so many of the ideas of modern economics, the first serious application of the Random Walk Hypothesis to financial markets can be traced back to Paul Samuelson (1965), whose contribution is neatly summarized by the title of his article: Proof that Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly.
In an informationally efficient market—not to be confused with an allocationally or Pareto-efficient market-price changes must be unforecastable if they are properly anticipated, i.e., if they fully incorporate the expectations and information of all market participants. Fama (1970) encapsulated this idea in his pithy dictum that prices fully reflect all available information.
Unlike the many applications of the Random Walk Hypothesis in the natural and physical sciences in which randomness is assumed almost by default, because of the absence of any natural alternatives, Samuelson argues that randomness is achieved through the active participation of many investors seeking greater wealth. Unable to curtail their greed, an army of investors aggressively pounce on even the smallest informational advantages at their disposal, and in doing so, they incorporate their information into market prices and quickly eliminate the profit opportunities that gave rise to their aggression. If this occurs instantaneously, which it must in an idealized world of frictionless
markets and costless trading, then prices must always fully reflect all available information and no profits can be garnered from information-based trading (because such profits have already been captured). This has a wonderfully counter-intuitive and seemingly contradictory flavor to it: the more efficient the market, the more random the sequence of price changes generated by such a market, and the most efficient market of all is one in which price changes are completely random and unpredictable.
For these reasons, the Random Walk Hypothesis and its close relative, the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, have become icons of modern financial economics that continue to fire the imagination of academics and investment professionals alike. The papers collected in this volume comprise our own foray into this rich literature, spanning a decade of research that we initiated in 1988 with our rejection of the Random Walk Hypothesis for US stock market prices, and then following a course that seemed, at times, to be self-propelled, the seeds of our next study planted by the results of the previous one.
If there is one central theme that organizes the papers contained in this volume, it is this: financial markets are predictable to some degree, but far from being a symptom of inefficiency or irrationality, predictability is the oil that lubricates the gears of capitalism. Indeed, quite by accident and rather indirectly, we have come face to face with an insight that Ronald Coase hit upon as an undergraduate over half a century ago: price discovery is neither instantaneous nor costless, and frictions play a major role in determining the nature of competition and the function of markets.
1.1 The Random Walk and Efficient Markets
One of the most common reactions to our early research was surprise and disbelief. Indeed, when we first presented our rejection of the Random Walk Hypothesis at an academic conference in 1986, our discussant-a distinguished economist and senior member of the profession-asserted with great confidence that we had made a programming error, for if our results were correct, this would imply tremendous profit opportunities in the stock market. Being too timid (and too junior) at the time, we responded weakly that our programming was quite solid thank you, and the ensuing debate quickly degenerated thereafter. Fortunately, others were able to replicate our findings exactly, and our wounded pride has healed quite nicely with the passage of time (though we still bristle at the thought of being prosecuted for programming errors without probable cause
). Nevertheless, this experience has left an indelible impression on us, forcing us to confront the fact that the Random Walk Hypothesis was so fully ingrained into the canon of our profession that it was easier to attribute our empirical results to programming errors than to accept them at face value.
Is it possible for stock market prices to be predictable to some degree in an efficient market?
This question hints at the source of disbelief among our early critics: an implicit-and incorrect-link between the Random Walk Hypothesis and the Efficient Markets Hypothesis. It is not difficult to see how the two ideas might be confused. Under very special circumstances, e.g., risk neutrality, the two are equivalent. However, LeRoy (1973), Lucas (1978), and many others have shown in manyways and in many contexts that the Random Walk Hypothesis is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for rationally determined security prices. In other words, unforecastable prices need not imply a well-functioning financial market with rational investors, and forecastable prices need not imply the opposite.
These conclusions seem sharply at odds with Samuelson's proof
that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly, an argument so compelling that it is reminiscent of the role that uncertainty plays in quantum mechanics. Just as Heisenberg's uncertainty principle places a limit on what we can know about an electron's position and momentum if quantum mechanics holds, Samuelson's version of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis places a limit on what we can know about future price changes if the forces of economic self-interest hold.
Nevertheless, one of the central insights of modern financial economics is the necessity of some trade-off between risk and expected return, and although Samuelson's version of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis places a restriction on expected returns, it does not account for risk in any way. In particular, if a security's expected price change is positive, it may be just the reward needed to attract investors to hold the asset and bear the associated risks. Indeed, if an investor is sufficiently risk averse, he might gladly pay to avoid holding a security that has unforecastable returns.
In such a world, the Random Walk Hypothesis-a purely statistical model of returns-need not be satisfied even if prices do fully reflect all available information. This was demonstrated conclusively by LeRoy (1973) and Lucas (1978), who construct explicit examples of informationally efficient markets in which the Efficient Markets Hypothesis holds but where prices do not follow random walks.
Grossman (1976) and Grossman and Stiglitz (1980) go even further. They argue that perfectly informationally efficient markets are an impossibility, for if markets are perfectly efficient, the return to gathering information is nil, in which case there would be little reason to trade and markets would eventually collapse. Alternatively, the degree of market inefficiency determines the effort investors are willing to expend to gather and trade on information, hence a non-degenerate market equilibrium will arise only when there are sufficient profit opportunities, i.e., inefficiencies, to compensate investors for the costs of trading and information-gathering. The profits earned by these industrious investors may be viewed as economic rents that accrue to those willing to engage in such activities. Who are the providers of these rents? Black (1986) gives us a provocative answer: noise traders, individuals who trade on what they think is information but is in fact merely noise. More generally, at any time there are always investors who trade for reasons other than information-for example, those with unexpected liquidity needs-and these investors are willing to pay up
for the privilege of executing their trades immediately.
These investors may well be losing money on average when they trade with information-motivated investors, but there is nothing irrational or inefficient about either group's behavior. In fact, an investor may be trading for liquidity reasons one day and for information reasons the next, and losing or earning money depending on the circumstances surrounding the trade.
1.2 The Current State of Efficient Markets
There is an old joke, widely told among economists, about an economist strolling down the street with a companion when they come upon a $100 bill lying on the ground. As the companion reaches down to pick it up, the economist says Don't bother-if it were a real $100 bill, someone would have already picked it up.
This humorous example of economic logic gone awry strikes dangerously close to home for students of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, one of the most important controversial and well-studied propositions in all the social sciences. It is disarmingly simple to state, has far-reaching consequences for academic pursuits and business practice, and yet is surprisingly resilient to empirical proof or refutation. Even after three decades of research and literally thousands of journal articles, economists have not yet reached a consensus about whether markets-particularly financial markets-are efficient or not.
What can we conclude about the Efficient Markets Hypothesis? Amazingly, there is still no consensus among financial economists. Despite the many advances in the statistical analysis, databases, and theoretical models surrounding the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, the main effect that the large number of empirical studies have had on this debate is to harden the resolve of the proponents on each side.
One of the reasons for this state of affairs is the fact that the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, by itself, is not a well-defined and empirically refutable hypothesis. To make it operational, one must specify additional structure, e.g., investors' preferences, information structure, business conditions, etc. But then a test of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis becomes a test of several auxiliary hypotheses as well, and a rejection of such a joint hypothesis tells us little about which aspect of the joint hypothesis is inconsistent with the data. Are stock prices too volatile because markets are inefficient, or is it due to risk aversion, or dividend smoothing? All three inferences are consistent with the data. Moreover, new statistical tests designed to distinguish among them will no doubt require auxiliary hypotheses of their own which, in turn, may be questioned.
More importantly, tests of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis may not be the most informative means of gauging the efficiency of a given market. What is often of more consequence is the relative efficiency of a particular market, relative to other markets, e.g., futures vs. spot markets, auction vs. dealer markets, etc. The advantages of the concept of relative efficiency, as opposed to the all-or-nothing notion of absolute efficiency, are easy to spot by way of an analogy. Physical systems are often given an efficiency rating based on the relative proportion of energy or fuel converted to useful work. Therefore, a piston engine may be rated at 60% efficiency, meaning that on average 60% of the energy contained in the engine's fuel is used to turn the crankshaft, with the remaining 40% lost to other forms of work, e.g., heat, light, noise, etc.
Few engineers would ever consider performing a statistical test to determine whether or not a given engine is perfectly efficient-such an engine exists only in the idealized frictionless world of the imagination. But measuring relative efficiency-relative to a frictionless ideal-is commonplace. Indeed, we have come to expect such measurements for many household products: air conditioners, hot water heaters, refrigerators, etc. Therefore, from a practical point of view, and in light of Grossman and Stiglitz (1980), the Efficient Markets Hypothesis is an idealization that is economically unrealizable, but which serves as a useful benchmark for measuring relative efficiency.
A more practical version of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis is suggested by another analogy, one involving the notion of thermal equilibrium in statistical mechanics. Despite the occasional excess
profit opportunity, on average and over time, it is not possible to earn such profits consistently without some type of competitive advantage, e.g., superior information, superior technology, financial innovation, etc. Alternatively, in an efficient market, the only way to earn positive profits consistently is to develop a competitive advantage, in which case the profits may be viewed as the economic rents that accrue to this competitive advantage. The consistency of such profits is an important qualification-in this version of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, an occasional free lunch is permitted, but free lunch plans are ruled out.
To see why such an interpretation of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis is a more practical one, consider for a moment applying the classical version of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis to a non-financial market, say the market for biotechnology. Consider, for example, the goal of developing a vaccine for the AIDS virus. If the market for biotechnology is efficient in the classical sense, such a vaccine can never be developed-if it could, someone would have already done it! This is clearly a ludicrous presumption since it ignores the difficulty and gestation lags of research and development in biotechnology. Moreover, if a pharmaceutical company does succeed in developing such a vaccine, the profits earned would be measured in the billions of dollars. Would this be considered excess
profits, or economic rents that accrue to biotechnology patents?
Financial markets are no different in principle, only in degrees. Consequently, the profits that accrue to an investment professional need not be a market inefficiency, but may simply be the fair reward to breakthroughs in financial technology. After all, few analysts would regard the hefty profits of Amgen over the past few years as evidence of an inefficient market for pharmaceuticals-Amgen's recent profitability is readily identified with the development of several new drugs (Epogen, for example, a drug that stimulates the production of red blood cells), some considered breakthroughs in biotechnology. Similarly, even in efficient financial markets there are very handsome returns to breakthroughs in financial technology.
Of course, barriers to entry are typically lower, the degree of competition is much higher, and most financial technologies are not patentable (though this may soon change) hence the half life
of the profitability of financial innovation is considerably smaller. These features imply that financial markets should be relatively more efficient, and indeed they are. The market for used securities
is considerably more efficient than the market for used cars. But to argue that financial markets must be perfectly efficient is tantamount to the claim that an AIDS vaccine cannot be found. In an efficient market, it is difficult to earn a good living, but not impossible.
1.3 Practical Implications
Our research findings have several implications for financial economists and investors. The fact that the Random Walk Hypothesis hypothesis can be rejected for recent US equity returns suggests the presence of predictable components in the stock market. This opens the door to superior long-term investment returns through disciplined active investment management. In much the same way that innovations in biotechnology can garner superior returns for venture capitalists, innovations in financial technology can garner equally superior returns for investors.
However, several qualifications must be kept in mind when assessing which of the many active strategies currently being touted is appropriate for an particular investor. First, the riskiness of active strategies can be very different from passive strategies, and such risks do not necessarily average out
over time. In particular, an investor's risk tolerance must be taken into account in selecting the long-term investment strategy that will best match the investor's goals. This is no simple task since many investors have little understanding of their own risk preferences, hence consumer education is perhaps the most pressing need in the near term. Fortunately, computer technology can play a major role in this challenge, providing scenario analyses, graphical displays of potential losses and gains, and realistic simulations of long-term investment performance that are user-friendly and easily incorporated into an investor's world view. Nevertheless, a good understanding of the investor's understanding of the nature of financial risks and rewards is the natural starting point for the investment process.
Second, there are a plethora of active managers vying for the privilege of managing institutional and pension assets, but they cannot all outperform the market every year (nor should we necessarily expect them to). Though often judged against a common benchmark, e.g., the S&P 500, active strategies can have very diverse risk characteristics and these must be weighed in assessing their performance. An active strategy involving high-risk venturecapital investments will tend to outperform the S&P 500 more often than a less aggressive enhanced indexing
strategy, yet one is not necessarily better than the other.
In particular, past returns should not be the sole or even the major criterion by which investment managers are judged. This statement often surprises investors and finance professionals-after all, isn't this the bottom line? Put another way, If it works, who cares why?
. Selecting an investment manager this way is one of the surest paths to financial disaster. Unlike the experimental sciences such as physics and biology, financial economics (and most other social sciences) relies primarily on statistical inference to test its theories. Therefore, we can never know with perfect certainty that a particular investment strategy is successful since even the most successful strategy can always be explained by pure luck (see Chapter 8 for some concrete illustrations).
Of course, some kinds of success are easier to attribute to luck than others, and it is precisely this kind of attribution that must be performed in deciding on a particular active investment style. Is it luck, or is it genuine?
While statistical inference can be very helpful in tackling this question, in the final analysis the question is not about statistics, but rather about economics and financial innovation. Under the practical version of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, it is difficult-but not impossible-to provide investors with consistently superior investment returns. So what are the sources of superior performance promised by an active manager and why have other competing managers not recognized these opportunities? Is it better mathematical models of financial markets? Or more accurate statistical methods for identifying investment opportunities? Or more timely data in a market where minute delays can mean the difference between profits and losses? Without a compelling argument for where an active manager's value-added is coming from, one must be very skeptical about the prospects for future performance. In particular, the concept of a black box
-a device that performs a known function reliably but obscurely-may make sense in engineering applications where repeated experiments can validate the reliability of the box's performance, but has no counterpart in investment management where performance attribution is considerably more difficult. For analyzing investment strategies, it matters a great deal why a strategy is supposed to work.
Finally, despite the caveats concerning performance attribution and proper motivation, we can make some educated guesses about where the likely sources of value-added might be for active investment management in the near future.
The revolution in computing technology and datafeeds suggest that highly computation-intensive strategies-ones that could not have been implemented five years ago-that exploit certain regularities in securities prices, e.g., clientele biases, tax opportunities, information lags, can add value.
Many studies have demonstrated the enormous impact that transactions costs can have on long-term investment performance. More sophisticated methods for measuring and controlling transactions costsmethods which employ high-frequency data, economic models of price impact, and advanced optimization techniques-can add value. Also, the introduction of financial instruments that reduce transactions costs, e.g., swaps, options, and other derivative securities, can add value.
Recent research in psychological biases inherent in human cognition suggest that investment strategies exploiting these biases can add value. However, contrary to the recently popular behavioral
approach to investments which proposes to take advantage of individual irrationality,
I suggest that value-added comes from creating investments with more attractive risk-sharing characteristics suggested by psychological models. Though the difference may seem academic, it has far-reaching consequences for the long-run performance of such strategies: taking advantage of individual irrationality cannot be a recipe for long-term success, but providing a better set of opportunities that more closely matches what investors desire seems more promising.
Of course, forecasting the sources of future innovations in financial technology is a treacherous business, fraught with many half-baked successes and some embarrassing failures. Perhaps the only reliable prediction is that the innovations of future are likely to come from unexpected and underappreciated sources. No one has illustrated this principal so well as Harry Markowitz, the father of modern portfolio theory and a winner of the 1990 Nobel Prize in economics. In describing his experience as a Ph.D. student on the eve of his graduation in the following way, he wrote in his Nobel address:
…[W] hen I defended my dissertation as a student in the Economics Department of the University of Chicago, Professor Milton Friedman argued that portfolio theorywas not Economics, and that they could not award me a Ph.D. degree in Economics for a dissertation which was not Economics. I assume that he was only half serious, since they did award me the degree without long debate. As to the merits of his arguments, at this point I am quite willing to concede: at the time I defended my dissertation, portfolio theory was not part of Economics. But now it is.
It is our hope and conceit that the research contained in this volume will be worthy of the tradition that Markowitz and others have so firmly established.
¹Parts of this introduction are adapted from Lo (1997a,b) and Lo and MacKinlay (1998).
²See, for example, Hald (1990, Chapter 4).
Part I
THE FIVE CHAPTERS IN THIS FIRST PART focus squarely on whether the Random Walk Hypothesis is a plausible description of recent US stock market prices. At the time we started our investigations—in 1985, just a year after we arrived at the Wharton School—the Random Walk Hypothesis was taken for granted as gospel truth. A number of well-known empirical studies had long since established the fact that markets were weak-form efficient
in Roberts's (1967) terminology, implying that past prices could not be used to forecast future prices changes (see, for example, Cowles and Jones (1973), Kendall (1953), Osborne (1959, 1962), Roberts (1959, 1967), Larson (1960), Cowles (1960), Working (1960), Alexander (1961, 1964), Granger and Morgenstern (1963), Mandelbrot (1963), Fama (1965), and Fama and Blume (1966)). And although some of these studies did find evidence against the random walk, e.g., Cowles and Jones (1973), they were largely dismissed as statistical anomalies or not economically meaningful after accounting for transactions costs, e.g., Cowles (1960). For example, after conducting an extensive empirical analysis of the runs' of US stock returns from 1956 to 1962, Fama (1965) concludes that,
…there is no evidence of important dependence from either an investment or a statistical point of view."
It was in this milieu that we decided to revisit the Random Walk Hypothesis. Previous studies had been unable to reject the random walk, hence we surmised that perhaps a more sensitive statistical test was needed, one capable of detecting small but significant departures from pure randomness. In the jargon of statistical inference, we hoped to develop a more powerful
test, a test that has a higher probability of rejecting the Random Walk Hypothesis if it is indeed false. Motivated partly by an insight of Merton's (1980), that variances can be estimated more accurately than means when data is sampled at finer intervals, we proposed a test of the random walk based on a comparison of variances at different sampling intervals. And by casting the comparison as a Hausman (1978) specification test, we were able to obtain an asymptotic sampling theory for the variance ratio statistic almost immediately, which we later generalized and extended in many ways. These results and their empirical implementation are described in Chapter 2.
In retrospect, our motivation for the variance ratio test was completely unnecessary.
Although Merton's (1980) observation holds quite generally, the overwhelming rejections of the Random Walk Hypothesis that we obtained for weekly US stock returns from 1962 to 1985 implied that a more powerful test was not needed—the random walk could have been rejected on the basis of the simple first-order autocorrelation coefficient, which we estimated to be 30 percent for the equal-weighted weekly returns index! We were taken completely by surprise (and carefully re-checked our programs several times for coding errors before debuting these results in a November 1986 conference) . How could such compelling evidence against the random walk be overlooked by the vast literature we were fed as graduate students?
At first, we attributed this to our using weekly returns—prior studies used either daily or monthly. We chose a weekly sampling interval to balance the desire for a large sample size against the problems associated with high-frequency financial data, e.g., nonsynchronous prices, bid/ask bounce,
etc. But we soon discovered that the case against the random walk was equally compelling with daily returns.
This puzzling state of affairs sparked the series of studies contained in Chapters 3 to 6, studies that attempted to reconcile what we, and many others, viewed as a sharp contradiction between our statistical inferences and the voluminous literature that came before us. We checked the accuracy of our statistical methods (Chapter 3), we quantified the potential biases introduced by nonsynchronous prices (Chapter 4), we investigated the sources of the rejections of the random walk and traced them to large positive cross-autocorrelations and lead/lag effects (Chapter 5), and we considered statistical fractals as an alternative to the random walk (Chapter 6). Despite our best efforts, we were unable to explain away the evidence against the Random Walk Hypothesis.
With the benefit of hindsight and a more thorough review of the literature, we have come to the conclusion that the apparent inconsistency between the broad support for the Random Walk Hypothesis and our empirical findings is largely due to the common misconception that the Random Walk Hypothesis is equivalent to the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, and the near religious devotion of economists to the latter (see Chapter 1). Once we saw that we, and our colleagues, had been trained to study the data through the filtered lenses of classical market efficiency, it became clear that the problem lay not with our empirical analysis, but with the economic implications that others incorrected attributed to our results—unbounded profit opportunities, irrational investors, and the like.
We also discovered that ours was not the first study to reject the random walk, and that the departures from the random walk uncovered by Osborne (1962), Larson (1960), Cootner (1962), Steiger (1964), Niederhoffer and Osborne (1966), and Schwartz and Whitcomb (1977), to name just a few examples, were largely ignored by the academic community and unknown to us until after our own papers were published.³ We were all in a collective fog regarding the validity of the Random Walk Hypothesis, but as we confronted the empirical evidence from every angle and began to rule out other explanations, slowly the fog lifted for us.
In Niederhoffer's (1997) entertaining and irreverent autobiography, he sheds some light on the kind of forces at work in creating this fog. In describing the Random Walk Hypothesis as it developed at the University of Chicago in the 1960's, he writes:
This theory and the attitude of its adherents found classic expression in one incident I personally observed that deserves memorialization. A team of four of the most respected graduate students in finance had joined forces with two professors, now considered venerable enough to have won or to have been considered for a Nobel prize, but at that time feisty as Hades and insecure as a kid on his first date. This elite group was studying the possible impact of volume on stock price movements, a subject I had researched. As I was coming down the steps from the library on the third floor of Haskell Hall, the main business building, I could see this Group of Six gathered together on a stairway landing, examining some computer output. Their voices wafted up to me, echoing off the stone walls of the building. One of the students was pointing to some output while querying the professors, Well, what if we really do find something? We'll be up the creek. It won't be consistent with the random walk model.
The younger professor replied, Don't worry, we'll cross that bridge in the unlikely event we come to it.
I could hardly believe my ears—here were six scientists openly hoping to find no departures from ignorance. I couldn't hold my tongue, and blurted out, I sure am glad you are all keeping an open mind about your research.
I could hardly refrain from grinning as I walked past them. I heard muttered imprecations in response.
From this, Niederhoffer (1997) concludes that As usual, academicians are way behind the form
and with respect to the Random Walk Hypothesis, we are forced to agree.
But beyond the interesting implications that this cognitive dissonance provides for the sociology of science, we think there is an even more important insight to be gleaned from all of this. In a recent update of our original variance ratio test for weekly US stock market indexes, we discovered that the most current data (1986-1996) conforms more closely to the random walk than our original 1962-1985 sample period. Moreover, upon further investigation, we learned that over the past decade several investment firms—most notably, Morgan Stanley and D.E. Shaw—have been engaged in high-frequency equity trading strategies specifically designed to take advantage of the kind of patterns we uncovered in 1988. Previously known as pairs trading
and now called statistical arbitrage,
these strategies have fared reasonably well until recently, and are now regarded as a very competitive and thin-margin business because of the proliferation of hedge funds engaged in these activities. This provides a plausible explanation for the trend towards randomness in the recent data, one that harkens back to Samuelson's Proof that Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly.
But if Morgan Stanley and D.E. Shaw were profiting in the 1980's from the predictability in stock returns that is now waning because of competition, can we conclude that markets were inefficient in the 1980's? Not without additional information about the cost and risk of their trading operations, and the novelty of their trading strategies relative to their competitors'.
In particular, the profits earned by the early statistical arbitrageurs may be viewed as economic rents that accrued to their innovation, creativity, perseverance, and appetite for risk. Now that others have begun to reverse engineer and mimick their technologies, profit margins are declining. Therefore, neither the evidence against the random walk, nor the more recent trend towards the random walk, are inconsistent with the practical version of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis. Market opportunities need not be market inefficiencies.
³In fact, both Alexander (1961) and Schwartz and Whitcomb (1977) use variance ratios to test the Random Walk Hypothesis, and although they do not employ the kind of rigorous statistical inference that we derived in our study, nevertheless it was our mistake to have overlooked their contributions. Our only defense is that none of our colleagues were aware of these studies either, for no one pointed out these references to us either before or after our papers were published.
2
Stock Market Prices Do Not Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test
SINCE KEYNES' (1936) NOW FAMOUS PRONOUNCEMENT that most investors' decisions can only be taken as a result of animal spirits—of a spontaneous urge to action rather than inaction, and not as the outcome of a weighted average of benefits multiplied by quantitative probabilities,
a great deal of research has been devoted to examining the efficiency of stock market price formation. In Fama's (1970) survey, the vast majority of those studies were unable to reject the efficient markets
hypothesis for common stocks. Although several seemingly anomalous departures from market efficiency have been well documented,¹ many financial economists would agree with Jensen's (1978a) belief that there is no other proposition in economics which has more solid empirical evidence supporting it than the Efficient Markets Hypothesis.
Although a precise formulation of an empirically refutable efficient markets hypothesis must obviously be model-specific, historically the majority of such tests have focused on the forecastability of common stock returns. Within this paradigm, which has been broadly categorized as the random walk
theory of stock prices, few studies have been able to reject the random walk model statistically. However, several recent papers have uncovered empirical evidence which suggests that stock returns contain predictable components. For example, Keim and Stambaugh (1986) find statistically significant predictability in stock prices by using forecasts based on certain predetermined variables. In addition, Fama and French (1988) show that long holding-period returns are significantly negatively serially correlated, implying that 25 to 40 percent of the variation of longer-horizon returns is predictable from past returns.
In this chapter we provide further evidence that stock prices do not follow random walks by using a simple specification test based on variance estimators. Our empirical results indicate that the random walk model is generally not consistent with the stochastic behavior of weekly returns, especially for the smaller capitalization stocks. However, in contrast to the negative serial correlation that Fama and French (1988) found for longer-horizon returns, we find significant positive serial correlation for weekly and monthly holding-period returns. For example, using 1216 weekly observations from September 6, 1962, to December 26, 1985, we compute the weekly first-order autocorrelation coefficient of the equal-weighted Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) returns index to be 30 percent! The statistical significance of our results is robust to heteroskedasticity. We also develop a simple model which indicates that these large autocorrelations cannot be attributed solely to the effects of infrequent trading. This empirical puzzle becomes even more striking when we show that autocorrelations of individual securities are generally negative.
Of course, these results do not necessarily imply that the stock market is inefficient or that prices are not rational assessments of fundamental
values. As Leroy (1973) and Lucas (1978) have shown, rational expectations equilibrium prices need not even form a martingale sequence, of which the random walk is a special case. Therefore, without a more explicit economic model of the price-generating mechanism, a rejection of the random walk hypothesis has few implications for the efficiency of market price formation. Although our test results may be interpreted as a rejection of some economic model of efficient price formation, there may exist other plausible models that are consistent with the empirical findings. Our more modest goal in this study is to employ a test that is capable of distinguishing among several interesting alternative stochastic price processes. Our test exploits the fact that the variance of the increments of a random walk is linear in the sampling interval. If stock prices are generated by a random walk (possibly with drift), then, for example, the variance of monthly sampled log-price relatives must be 4 times as large as the variance of a weekly sample. Comparing the